26
Multi-unit auctions & exchanges (multiple indistinguishable units of one item for sale) Tuomas Sandholm Computer Science Department Carnegie Mellon University

Multi-unit auctions & exchanges (multiple indistinguishable units of one item for sale)

  • Upload
    nhi

  • View
    29

  • Download
    1

Embed Size (px)

DESCRIPTION

Multi-unit auctions & exchanges (multiple indistinguishable units of one item for sale). Tuomas Sandholm Computer Science Department Carnegie Mellon University. Auctions with multiple indistinguishable units for sale. Examples IBM stocks Barrels of oil Pork bellies - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

Citation preview

Page 1: Multi-unit  auctions & exchanges  (multiple  indistinguishable  units of one item for sale)

Multi-unit auctions & exchanges

(multiple indistinguishable units of one item for sale)

Tuomas Sandholm

Computer Science Department Carnegie Mellon University

Page 2: Multi-unit  auctions & exchanges  (multiple  indistinguishable  units of one item for sale)

Auctions with multiple indistinguishable units for sale

• Examples– IBM stocks– Barrels of oil– Pork bellies– Trans-Atlantic backbone bandwidth from NYC to Paris– …

Page 3: Multi-unit  auctions & exchanges  (multiple  indistinguishable  units of one item for sale)

Bidding languages and expressiveness

• These bidding languages were introduced for combinatorial auctions, but also apply to multi-unit auctions– OR [default; Sandholm 99]– XOR [Sandholm 99]– OR-of-XORs [Sandholm 99]– XOR-of-ORs [Nisan 00]– OR* [Fujishima et al. 99, Nisan 00]– Recursive logical bidding languages [Boutilier & Hoos 01]

• In multi-unit setting, can also use price-quantity curve bids

Page 4: Multi-unit  auctions & exchanges  (multiple  indistinguishable  units of one item for sale)

Screenshot from eMediator[Sandholm AGENTS-00, Computational Intelligence 02]

Page 5: Multi-unit  auctions & exchanges  (multiple  indistinguishable  units of one item for sale)

Multi-unit auctions: pricing rules• Auctioning multiple indistinguishable units of an item• Naive generalization of the Vickrey auction: uniform price auction

– If there are m units for sale, the highest m bids win, and each bid pays the m+1st highest price

– Downside with multi-unit demand: Demand reduction lie [Crampton&Ausubel 96]:

• m=5• Agent 1 values getting her first unit at $9, and getting a second unit

is worth $7 to her• Others have placed bids $2, $6, $8, $10, and $14• If agent 1 submits one bid at $9 and one at $7, she gets both items,

and pays 2 x $6 = $12. Her utility is $9 + $7 - $12 = $4• If agent 1 only submits one bid for $9, she will get one item, and pay

$2. Her utility is $9-$2=$7• Incentive compatible mechanism that is Pareto efficient and ex post

individually rational – Clarke tax. Agent i pays a-b

• b is the others’ sum of winning bids• a is the others’ sum of winning bids had i not participated

– I.e., if i wins n items, he pays the prices of the n highest losing bids– What about revenue (if market is competitive)?

Page 6: Multi-unit  auctions & exchanges  (multiple  indistinguishable  units of one item for sale)

General case of efficiency under diminishing values

• VCG has efficient equilibrium. What about other mechanisms?

• Model: xik is i’s signal (i.e., value) for his k’th unit.

– Signals are drawn iid and support has no gaps– Assume diminishing values

• Prop. [13.3 in Krishna book]. An equilibrium of a multi-unit auction where the highest m bids win is efficient iff the bidding strategies are separable across units and bidders, i.e., βi

k(xi)= β(xi

k)

– Reasoning: efficiency requires xik > xi

r iff βik(xi) > βi

r(xi)• So, i’s bid on some unit cannot depend on i’s signal on another unit• And symmetry across bidders needed for same reason as in 1-object case

Page 7: Multi-unit  auctions & exchanges  (multiple  indistinguishable  units of one item for sale)

Revenue equivalence theorem (which we proved before) applies

to multi-unit auctions

• Again assumes that – payoffs are same at some zero type, and – the allocation rule is the same

• Here it becomes a powerful tool for comparing expected revenues

Page 8: Multi-unit  auctions & exchanges  (multiple  indistinguishable  units of one item for sale)

Multi-unit auctions: Clearing complexity

[Sandholm & Suri IJCAI-01]

Page 9: Multi-unit  auctions & exchanges  (multiple  indistinguishable  units of one item for sale)
Page 10: Multi-unit  auctions & exchanges  (multiple  indistinguishable  units of one item for sale)
Page 11: Multi-unit  auctions & exchanges  (multiple  indistinguishable  units of one item for sale)
Page 12: Multi-unit  auctions & exchanges  (multiple  indistinguishable  units of one item for sale)

In all of the curves together

Page 13: Multi-unit  auctions & exchanges  (multiple  indistinguishable  units of one item for sale)
Page 14: Multi-unit  auctions & exchanges  (multiple  indistinguishable  units of one item for sale)
Page 15: Multi-unit  auctions & exchanges  (multiple  indistinguishable  units of one item for sale)
Page 16: Multi-unit  auctions & exchanges  (multiple  indistinguishable  units of one item for sale)

Page 17: Multi-unit  auctions & exchanges  (multiple  indistinguishable  units of one item for sale)
Page 18: Multi-unit  auctions & exchanges  (multiple  indistinguishable  units of one item for sale)
Page 19: Multi-unit  auctions & exchanges  (multiple  indistinguishable  units of one item for sale)
Page 20: Multi-unit  auctions & exchanges  (multiple  indistinguishable  units of one item for sale)
Page 21: Multi-unit  auctions & exchanges  (multiple  indistinguishable  units of one item for sale)

Multi-unit reverse auctions with supply curves

• Same complexity results apply as in auctions– O(#pieces log #pieces) in nondiscriminatory case

with piecewise linear supply curves– NP-complete in discriminatory case with

piecewise linear supply curves– O(#agents log #agents) in discriminatory case with

linear supply curves

Page 22: Multi-unit  auctions & exchanges  (multiple  indistinguishable  units of one item for sale)

Multi-unit exchanges• Multiple buyers, multiple sellers, multiple units for sale• By Myerson-Satterthwaite thrm, even in 1-unit case cannot obtain all of

• Pareto efficiency• Budget balance• Individual rationality (participation)

Page 23: Multi-unit  auctions & exchanges  (multiple  indistinguishable  units of one item for sale)

Supply/demand curve bids

profit = amounts paid by bidders – amounts paid to sellersCan be divided between buyers, sellers & market maker

Unit price

Quantity Aggregate supply Aggregate demand

One price for everyone (“classic partial equilibrium”):profit = 0

One price for sellers, one for buyers ( nondiscriminatory pricing ): profit > 0

profit

psell pbuy

Page 24: Multi-unit  auctions & exchanges  (multiple  indistinguishable  units of one item for sale)

Nondiscriminatory vs. discriminatory pricing

Unit price

Quantity

Supply of agent 1

Aggregate demand

Supply of agent 2

One price for sellers, one for buyers( nondiscriminatory pricing ): profit > 0

psell pbuy

One price for each agent ( discriminatory pricing ): greater profit

p1sell

pbuyp2sell

Page 25: Multi-unit  auctions & exchanges  (multiple  indistinguishable  units of one item for sale)

Shape of supply/demand curves

• Piecewise linear curve can approximate any curve• Assume

– Each buyer’s demand curve is downward sloping– Each seller’s supply curve is upward sloping– Otherwise absurd result can occur

• Aggregate curves might not be monotonic• Even individuals’ curves might not be continuous

Page 26: Multi-unit  auctions & exchanges  (multiple  indistinguishable  units of one item for sale)

Pricing scheme has implications on time complexity of clearing

• Piecewise linear curves (not necessarily continuous) can approximate any curve• Clearing objective: maximize profit• Thrm. Nondiscriminatory clearing with piecewise linear supply/demand: O(p log p)

– p = total number of pieces in the curves

• Thrm. Discriminatory clearing with piecewise linear supply/demand: NP-complete• Thrm. Discriminatory clearing with linear supply/demand: O(a log a)

– a = number of agents

• These results apply to auctions, reverse auctions, and exchanges• So, there is an inherent tradeoff between profit and computational complexity – even

without worrying about incentives