176
Corso di Laurea magistrale in Economia e Finanza Tesi di Laurea Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the Banking Union Relatore Ch.mo Prof. Dino Martellato Correlatori: Ch.mo Prof. Paolo Biffis Ch.mo Prof. Giancarlo Corò Laureanda Ilaria Capuzzo Matricola 816720 Anno Accademico 2013 / 2014

Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    4

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

Corso di Laurea magistrale in Economia e Finanza Tesi di Laurea

Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the Banking Union Relatore Ch.mo Prof. Dino Martellato Correlatori: Ch.mo Prof. Paolo Biffis Ch.mo Prof. Giancarlo Corò

Laureanda Ilaria Capuzzo Matricola 816720 Anno Accademico 2013 / 2014

Page 2: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the
Page 3: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

Acknowledgements

I would like to thank my guide Prof. Dino Martellato, whose constant

assistance, supervision and enthusiastic encouragement were

fundamental in making this dissertation a reality. I am grateful for his

invaluable insights.

I would like to express my gratitude to Prof. Paolo Biffis for his

academic support and intellectual stimulation. His regular suggestions

made an invaluable contribution to this work.

I am indebted to all my friends who were always so helpful in numerous

ways. Special thanks to Maria, Sidney, Enrica Marianna, Giulia,

Eleonora, Elena and Andrea.

Last but not least, I would also like to say a heartfelt thank you to my

Mum, Dad, Daniel and Arianna for always supporting me.

Page 4: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

1

Content

List of Abbreviations………………………………………………...3

List of Figures………………………………………………………..5

Introduction……………………………………………………….....7

1. Conceptions of money...............................................................13

1.1. Basic conceptions of money: money as unit of account,

store of value and medium of exchange...............................13

1.2. Two different types of money: inside and outside money.....17

1.3. Monetary aggregates in the European Union and

two different streams: horizontalists and verticalists.................22

1.4. How does the creation of money start?................................32

1.5. Ways in which banks’ and social behavior can

affect monetary aggregates and destroy deposits.................37

1.6. Constraints to the money creation mechanism...................40

2. Financial stability in the European Economic and

Monetary Union......................................................................49

2.1. The European pattern: an historical preface.......................49

2.2. The establishment of the European Central Bank.............56

2.3. Two – pillars approach and monetary policy tools

Page 5: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

2

of the European Central Bank……………….…………63

2.4. The European Central Bank weapons…………………...71

2.4.1. Long – Term Refinancing Operations………….....74

2.4.2. ECB’s balance sheet and the monetary aggregates

evolution………………………………………....77

2.4.3. Interest rate policy………………………………..84

2.4.4. Outright Monetary Transactions...………………..89

2.5. The European Stability Mechanism……………………..92

3. The Banking Union as a regulatory response to the financial

crisis and expected outcomes in the monetary system………96

3.1. An overview of the new regulatory framework…………96

3.2. Banking Union and financial stability …………………...101

3.3. The Financial Trilemma……………………………….103

3.4. The Single Rulebook…………………………………..108

3.5. Three pillars approach:………………………………...111

3.5.1. The Single Supervisory Mechanism…………….112

3.5.2. The Single Resolution Mechanism……………...117

3.5.3. The Common Deposit Guarantee Scheme……...125

3.6. Advantages, disadvantages and risks…………………...129

Conclusion………………………………………………………....148

Bibliography……………………………………………………….155

E-library and Databases..…………………………………………173

Page 6: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

3

List of Abbreviations

BIS Bank of International Settlement

BM Monetary Base

BOE Bank of England

BRRD Bank Recovery and Resolution Directive

CB Central Bank

CET1 Common Equity Tier 1

CRD IV Capital Requirements Directive IV

CRR Capital Requirements Regulation

DGS Deposit Guarantee Scheme

DGSD Deposit Guarantee Schemes Directive

EBA European Banking Authority

EBU European Banking Union

EC European Commission

ECB European Central Bank

ECSC European Coal and Steel Community

EEC European Economic Community

EFSF European Financial Stability Facility

EMS European Monetary System

EMU Economic and Monetary Union

EONIA Euro OverNight Index Average

ERM Exchange Rate Mechanism

ESCB European System of Central Banks

ESM European Stability Mechanism

EU European Union

EURIBOR European Interbank Offered Rate

FED Federal Reserve System

FSIs Financial Soundness Indicators

HICP Harmonised Index of Consumer Prices

IMF International Monetary Fund

IOU I Owe You

Page 7: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

4

LTRO Long Term Refinancing Operation

M0 Monetary aggregate M0

M1 Monetary aggregate M1

M2 Monetary aggregate M2

M3 Monetary aggregate M3

MBC Monetary Base Control

MMF Monet Market Fund

MOU Memorandum of Understanding

MRO Main Refinancing Operation

NCBs National Central Banks

OCA Optimum Currency Area

OMT Outright Monetary Transactions

QE Quantitative Easing

RWAs Risk-weighted assets

SRB Single Resolution Board

SRF Single Resolution Fund

SRM Single Resolution Mechanism

SSM Single Supervisory Mechanism

TFUE Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union

USA United States of America

USD United States Dollar

Page 8: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

5

List of Figures

Figure 1: Definitions of money………………………………………24

Figure 2: Money creation process……………………………………35

Figure 3: The Convergence Criteria………………………………….52

Figure 4: Inflation rates in the Euro area…………………………….61

Figure 5: ECB’s open market operations and standing facilities. …….64

Figure 6: M3 growth rate in the Euro area…………………………...68

Figure 7: M3 total amounts in some Euro countries…………………69

Figure 8: M3 in some Euro countries (Index: 1999)………………….70

Figure 9: The Euro's three crisis……………………………………..72

Figure 10: LTROs and deposit facility use…………………………....76

Figure 11: Deposit facility use………………………………………..76

Figure 12: Total assets of the ECB…………………………………...78

Figure 13: Monetary base of the ECB………………………………..78

Figure 14: Monetary base and M3 in the Euro area…………………..80

Figure 15: Monetary aggregates in the Euro area……………………..80

Figure 16: Monetary aggregates growth in the Euro area……………..81

Figure 17: Money multipliers in the Euro area………………………..83

Figure 18: Interest rate policy at the ECB……………………………88

Figure 19: Cross - border interbank lending in the Euro area……….100

Figure 20: The Financial Trilemma…………………………………103

Page 9: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

6

Figure 21: The instability mechanism……………………………….105

Figure 22: Italian banks under the SSM……………………………..116

Figure 23: Bail-in in different resolution procedures………………..122

Figure 24: The Single Resolution Mechanism………………………124

Figure 25: The Deposits Guarantee Scheme process………………..128

Figure 26: CET1 of Italian banks…………………………………...130

Figure 27: Regulatory capital scheme……………………………….132

Figure 28: Regulatory capital to RWAs within the EU……………...139

Figure 29: Tier 1 Capital to Regulatory Capital within the EU……...141

Figure 30: Bank capital to assets ratio in the Euro area……………..143

Figure 31: Financial Soundness Indicators for 63 Italian banks…….144

Page 10: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

7

Introduction

After having reached in 2012 the agreement on the Single Supervisory

Mechanism which will entrust the ECB of the prudential control over

Europe’s largest banks, by mid-March 2014 the European Parliament

and Government leaders approved the Single Resolution Mechanism in

order to deal with failing or likely to fail banks. The decision was

considered as an essential step towards a more effective integration

between the Member countries of the European Economic and

Monetary Union. The so-called Banking Union has been hoped and

warmly awaited since the financial crisis and the ensuing debt crisis

unveiled flaws in the system and troubles in a few European banks.

The Banking Union, however, will start functioning only slowly, and also

appears to be funded quite modestly which made commentators greet it

as weak, imperfect, even flawed. Bank’s bond holders will be bailed-in

besides stock holders, as the Bank Recovery and Resolution Directive

provides a clear “cascade of liabilities” scheme which is supposed to act as

the main tool in the resolution framework. The Single Resolution Fund

is set to reach only 20€ bn by 2020: too little and too late. The final

amount should be 55€ bn. Besides providing limited source to back the

Single Resolution Mechanism, the Banking Union appears timid in not

establishing a Common Deposits Guarantee Scheme for bank

depositors, which could be bailed-in during a bank failure, to a some

Page 11: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

8

degree. After the agreement, national governments and tax payers are

still called into question at least in part, but national banks’ supervisors

are largely replaced (considering the total banks’ assets) by the European

Central Bank as the top supervisor. After the agreement, the European

Monetary Union, nevertheless, is a little closer to a real banking and

monetary system where the existing integration is set to reduce risks,

rather than amplify them.

The purpose of this work is not a comprehensive evaluation of all

aspects of the Banking Union but rather to look at the new regulatory

framework for the banking system and assess its potential monetary

implications. This new initiative integrates the conventional and

unconventional monetary measures launched by the European Central

Bank since 2011 as it aims at reducing risks and thus reducing the

likelihood of bank failures and the costs of bank failures.

In the work it is argued that besides breaking the dangerous link between

the balance sheets of banks and their customers (governments included),

the Banking Union addresses the problem of monetary fragmentation

which is an issue in the two-tier monetary system wherein the European

Central Bank provides the common monetary policy while the National

Central Banks retain the supervision of domestic banks. Modifying the

current regulatory framework and the existing European two-tier

Page 12: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

9

banking system appears to be necessary to increase the soundness of the

system.

In order to describe and evaluate the issue of successfully implementing

a Banking Union within a Monetary Union, we analyse some of the major

aspects likely to be affected by this innovation and in particular we focus

on the role of money, the monetary policy, central banks’ operations as

well as the new regulatory framework through which Basel III will be

implemented.

In chapter 1 we start by distinguishing inside from outside money. This

distinction dates back at least to seventy years ago (Kalecki, 1944 Professor

Pigou on “The Classical Stationary State”, Economic Journal, Vol. 54 No.

213, April) but remained alive over the decades and central in debates

about important notions such as wealth, neutrality of money ─ Kaldor

(1970), Friedman (1970) ─ and endogenous money creation ─ e.g.

Moore (1988) and Goodhart (1989). In this chapter we focus precisely

on the money creation process about which the Bank of England has

clearly taken position (BoE, 2014) by stating that: “The majority of money in

the modern economy is created by commercial banks making loans”.

We then come up in chapter 2 with an extensive analysis on the

European Central Bank approach regarding its monetary policy

Page 13: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

10

conduction. In this regard, we start by stating its approach on the short

and medium term, considering the change in the method adopted before

and after the crisis since 2008. In the background there is a simple idea:

before the crisis, banks have mismanaged the credit extension

somewhere and the National Central Banks’ supervision has been

discovered to be weak in some cases. This impaired the endogenous

money creation process in the single countries and in the EMU, as the

existing credit excess that some countries experienced has affected

significantly the monetary aggregates. Then the ECB was well aware of

the systematic excess of the level of M3 over the desired threshold, but it

had only interest rate and monetary base policies at its disposal.

Interestingly, some national banks were not afraid to remark this

problem (e.g. Banca d’Italia, Moneta e Banche, No. 35, 2014). After that,

this paper gives emphasis on the latest measures provided by the

European Central Bank in order to tackle the “Eurozone crisis” started in

2009 and thus foster liquidity to the European banks to compensate the

jump in the unit demand for monetary base observed in the system. The

jump reflected the fall in the value of the money multiplier.

The conclusion focus is on the European Banking Union, the massive

project which aims to (i) foster financial integration, (ii) limit financial

instability and (iii) break the negative loop between the sovereigns and

banks. We delineate the Single Rulebook and describe in great details the

Single Supervisory Mechanism and its potential implication for reducing

monetary fragmentation in the Euro area. We furthermore provide a

Page 14: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

11

critical discussion also about the other two pillars of the Banking Union,

the Single Resolution Mechanism and the Common Deposits Guarantee

Scheme.

Finally, this work provides data on prudential ratios regarding banks

settled in different countries within the European Union. A

comprehensive analysis has been conducted about pros and cons of the

European Banking Union project whose conclusion is that its main

advantage could be the reduction of monetary fragmentation and of

banks’ risks ahead rather than lower costs of banks failures.

Page 15: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

12

Page 16: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

13

1. Conceptions of Money

1.1. Basic conceptions of money: money as unit of account, store of

value and medium of exchange

Money has a long history behind. The definition of money, namely,

according to the Oxford Dictionary is “a current medium of exchange in the

form of coins and banknotes”. Thus, whenever a person uses money in order

to buy goods or assets, he basically exchanges one good (money) for

another one (i.e. wheat, salt, anything). As a result, money – which is

recognized and accepted by official authorities such as central banks –

acts as a perfect medium of exchange in the global economy, for all types

of transactions.

According to the standard definitions, money accomplishes three

specific functions: unit of account, store of value and medium of

exchange.

As already mentioned above, one primary function of money is that it

acts as a medium of exchange. To be more precise, people hold money in

order to swap it for something else. In other words, money is a general

medium of exchange and an object which is “habitually, and without

hesitation, taken by anybody in exchange for any commodity” (Wicksell, 1906;

1967: 17). At some point in time and in the absence of money, other

Page 17: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

14

goods may become a regular medium of exchange as well. For instance,

this has been the case with cigarettes during the Second World War,

whenever even non-smokers were willing to hold cigarettes to swap

them subsequently for any goods they wanted or needed (BoE, 2014).

Back in time, when people were using barter to trade, the commodity

used to facilitate the commerce was known as a medium of exchange

and was called commodity money1.

Thus, the term commodity money refers to goods or commodities which are

not traded for consumption or use in production, but to further facilitate

trade (Kiyotaky and Wright, 1989). Alternatively, if an object has no

intrinsic value, but is nevertheless exchanged and used as medium of

exchange, then it is referred to as fiat money2.

As stated by central banks, the main reason why fiat money is accepted as

medium of exchange even without having an intrinsic value lays on the

fact that it is accepted by everyone in the economy. It is important to

mention that the widespread acceptance of this type of money primarily

resulted from the commerce practice3. As fiat money is debt issued by the

central bank, the central bank can always repay the debt by issuing more

fiat money. However, even central banks have some limits regarding the

amount of money that they can print. These limitations lead to the

1 According to the major central banks’ definitions, commodity money is a commodity which has an intrinsic value of its own. This was used as money because it fulfilled the main functions — such as gold coins (BoE, 2014). 2 According to the major central banks’ definitions, fiat money is irredeemable paper money — it is only a claim on further fiat money (BoE, 2014). 3 Gold didn’t operate well to smooth trade exchanges.

Page 18: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

15

question of which goals and targets a central bank has to pursue. We will

develop this topic in greater detail later on in this chapter.

Another function concerning money is to act as unit of account.

Depending on the country or the market in which transactions take

place, the different goods and services are priced in terms of unit of

currency. Every unit of currency can then be valued in terms of another

currency, depending on the exchange rate. The rate fluctuates on a daily

basis and is influenced by many factors, such as the balance of trade, the

balance of capital, inflation, to mention but a few.

As money is supposed to retain its value in a reasonably reckonable way

over time, a wider function typically associated with money is that it acts

as store of value (BoE, 2014). This estimation has to take into account

the inflation – the average increase in the price level over one period –

that is also the opportunity cost of holding cash over a period.

Thus, when inflation reaches very high levels, money tends to lose this

function because of the fact that with the same amount of money people

are now able to buy less, as price level increased. In such a scenario of

high inflation, people could for instance decide to invest in precious

metals, i.e. gold and silver. Such metals are often considered as good

store of value due to fact that their intrinsic value is not easily perishable.

Page 19: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

16

However, with the rise of new forms of liquid assets within the financial

market, the store of value function is undoubtedly on the way out

(Cecchetti, 2006: 23).

A more logical way in order to qualify this particular asset consists in

defining money whatever serves as money. If that is the case, then

money is not created solely by the central banks (i.e. let us think about

bitcoin). Alternatively, we could define currency (which is just a portion

of money) as the means of payment considered as legal tender, a means

which cannot be rejected and must be accepted in order to fulfill a debt

by everyone. In this case, the currency considered as legal tender can be

created solely by central banks. The central bank considers money as all

the amounts that can be used in order to build up reserves. However, it

will be shown later in this chapter that there are many measurements it

contemplates in order to refer to it.

In all these cases should be nevertheless clear that money is not a

synonym for cash. As it will be described more in detail in this chapter,

currency (which can be used as an alternatively word for cash) counts

just as a portion of the overall aggregate considered as money by the

central banks.

Page 20: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

17

1.2. Two different types of money: outside and inside money

Besides defining money according to its practical uses and the

impossibility to be refused4, we define it according to its source or

creator. We refer to it using the following two main categories: outside

money and inside money.

Outside money is made by the sum between currency and central bank

reserves. Base money, monetary base and high-powered money are other

nouns which refer to the same object. It refers to exogenous money,

which is the amount which is not coming from the market and the

private agents’ willingness to lend. The amount of outside money is

subject to the decisions of the ultimate monetary authorities which are

regulating this early stage of the stock of money.

Currency refers to money in circulation, flowing in the economy in the

forms of banknotes and coins. It is clear debt (or IOU5) of the central

bank to the rest of the economy. Some people prefer to hold cash

because they perceive it as safer to grasp a “tangible” amount instead of

having electronic currency6. In short some of them feel more protected

by having money in their own pockets instead of having money in their

4 Through the “force of law”. 5 I Owe yoU means debt. It’s a situation where a person owes money to another one. 6 Eletronic money, accordingly to the European Commission definition, is a digital amount of cash collected in electronic devices or in remote servers.

Page 21: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

18

own bank accounts. Commercial banks also have to hold some cash

reserves in order to be able to meet the deposit withdrawals that

customers require every day. Currency is a “promise to pay”7 the bearer8,

on demand, the nominal amount stated in the banknotes or coins. This

promise has been made by the central bank9 (in our case, the European

Central Bank). This is also the reason why currency is considered a legal

tender. This means that it has to be accepted by everyone as a repayment

of a debt. Because the currency is issued by central bank, it figures on the

liability side of their balance sheets. Conversely for households and

businesses, that as currency holders, it lays on the asset side.

Currency is used in economic transactions as a result of commercial and

social convention. This fiat money works just because people decide to use

it and accept it in exchanges besides the required acceptance through the

“force of law”. Historically, the state plays a huge role to the expansion of

currency usage (Goodhart, 1998; Wray 1998) and the fact that currency

is accepted for tax payments, enabled the spread of the fiat money system.

Despite the absence of a basic value, allowing people to pay their taxes

with currency, lead to an increase in their confidence and trust.

7 In some paper money we can still find some expression referring to this. For instance, in the 10£ banknote we can read “Bank of England – I promise to pay the bearer on demand the sum of” ten pounds; whereas in the USD banknotes we can read “United States Federal Reserve System – This note is legal tender for all debts, public and private”. 8 The holder (or depositor) of that notes. 9 The goldsmith-bankers, by issuing notes through the storage of gold coins provided by their customers, played a role in the spreading the use of the so-called paper money. These notes, which were receipts given for gold coins, quickly began to circulate as medium of exchange.

Page 22: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

19

Central bank reserves are another type of liability of the central bank.

Together with currency it forms the “outside money” in the economy.

These reserves are IOU of the central bank and are divided into different

bank accounts for every individual bank which have these reserves at its

“disposal”. With respect to these accounts, banks have to meet the

specific reserve requirement for every liability they create. Nowadays the

reserve requirement which is demanded by the ECB is 1%10. Every bank

is thus required to have 1% of some liabilities issued in the central bank

account, as a proof of liquidity. The central bank can also implement a

contractionary (through an increase in the reserve requirement) or an

expansionary (through a decrease in the reserve requirement) monetary

policy dealing with this ratio. This is however not the main way in which

central banks affect monetary policy.

A bank which holds an account at the central bank can not only its

minimum reserves requirement but also the excess reserves (additional

amounts over the minimum requirement of 1%) to make payments to

other banks. In every case, the central bank will transfer money between

these two by adjusting their respective reserves. The minimum

requirement is thus a floating amount which needs to be accomplished

on average during the reserve maintenance period (Biffis, 2011).

Inside money for his part refers to some bank deposits. To be more

precise, it consists in the amount of credit extended by banks to

10 ECB [website], accessed on 8.06.2014 at <http://www.ecb.europa.eu/mopo/implement/mr/html/calc.en.html>

Page 23: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

20

households, firms and governments. It is called inside money because it

is money which is created inside the private sector (Lagos, 2006).

The main difference between money created outside and inside the

private sector is that on one hand, outside money is issued by an

authority (i.e. a central bank) and is backed by some assets. As a result,

the net worth of these assets in question is not zero within the private

sector. Inside money on the other hand is issued and backed by private

agents (i.e. banks making loans). Because of the fact that an agent’s

liability is another agent’s asset, the net worth within the economy is zero

(Lagos, 2006).

Bank deposits are very important as lots of people make transactions

without using currency. For instance, if a person has to pay someone and

both agents hold an account in a commercial bank (not necessarily the

same – can be bank x for one and bank y for the other one), the person

can transfer money just through these two accounts. In case both agents

hold their account at the same commercial bank, the bank simply adjusts

the two different accounts. If both accounts are held in different banks,

the application will be transferred to the suitable clearing house11 that

will reduce the amount of the first person against a payment to the other

person.

11 Clearing house: a financial institution which is in charge of the clearing of the economic monetary transactions, setting credits and debits within the participants.

Page 24: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

21

Bank deposits thus act as a medium of exchange and the figurative

medium of exchange “currency” accounts for just a small part of the

overall money exchanged in the economy. Whenever a consumer makes

a deposit of a certain amount within a bank, the exchange will be

assembled by swapping a central bank IOU for a commercial bank IOU

(BoE, 2014).

As banks create inside money (Desai, 1989), this type of medium must be

considered as endogenous money. In order to be more precise, it is

called endogenous money because it comes from the interaction between

banks’ and individuals’ choices. It is nevertheless important to mention

that some banks will only act as lenders if they benefit from according

loans, thus only if loans are profitable. However, this occurrence and its

extent rely on the behavior of the banking system as a whole, which is

also determined by the well-functioning not only of the money, but also

of interbank markets.

Page 25: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

22

1.3. Monetary aggregates in the European Union and two different

streams: horizontalists and verticalists

Formally established with the Treaty of Maastricht in 1998, the

European Central Bank (ECB) actually started operating on January 1,

1999. Since 1999 it has the responsibility of providing the system with

the currency (legal tender) and conduct the monetary policy. Since 2014

it is also in charge of the supervision on the banking system. Chapter 3

will cover this new challenge.

The term Euro zone refers to the European countries which allowed the

ECB to conduct their monetary policy and adopted a common currency

– the euro. Nowadays, this subset of the Economic and Monetary Union

(EMU) of the European Union consists of the following 18 member

countries: Austria, Belgium, Cyprus, Estonia, Finland, France, Germany,

Greece, Ireland, Italy, Latvia, Luxembourg, Malta, the Netherlands,

Portugal, Slovakia, Slovenia and Spain.

We will return to this subject at a later stage, when it will be described

and discussed in greater detail the implementation of the European

Banking Union within the European Union.

Page 26: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

23

There are several measures which may be used in order to count money.

These are called monetary aggregates and are referred to in the

international practice as M0 (monetary base), M1, M2, M3 (and so on,

depending on the monetary system12) , according to their degree of

liquidity.

The European Central Bank, in order to define money, employs the

following definitions:

M1 as monetary base (also called narrow money);

M2 as intermediate money;

M3 as broad money.

In every monetary system, the rule through which it can be immediately

perceive the main difference between monetary aggregates is the level of

liquidity considered within each cluster. The higher the number near

letter M, the lower level of liquidity will be considered into the measure.

The following table gives an overview of the definitions provided by the

European Central Bank13:

12 I. e. in United States and United Kingdom it is likely to encounter also M4 (“building societies” deposits , shares and CDs) and M5 (which contains also treasury bills, banks bills and so on). 13 European Central Bank [online], available at http://www.ecb.europa.eu/stats/money/aggregates/aggr/html/hist.en.html

Page 27: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

24

European Central Bank liabilities * M1 M2 M3

Currency in circulation X X X Overnight deposits X X X Deposits with an agreed maturity up to 2 years X X Deposits redeemable at a period of notice up to 3 months

X X

Repurchase agreements X Money market fund (MMF) shares/units X Debt securities up to 2 years X

* Liabilities of the money-issuing sector and central government liabilities with a monetary

character held by the money-holding sector

Fig. 1: Definitions of Money (own figure according to ECB 2014)

As has been reported from the European Central Bank, M1 consists of

currency and overnight deposits. The latter are deposits with a maturity

of only one-night. Therefore they are considered as having the same

moneyness’ quality as in the case for currency (banknotes and coins).

Overnight lending typically occurs between financial institutions (mainly

banks, but also mutual funds), which are willing to borrow or lend

additional funds. As the borrower has to repay the loan the following

business day, these funds are perceived as highly liquid assets.

The monetary aggregate M2 involves – in addition of M1 – some sorts

of deposits: funds with a maturity up to 2 years and redeemable funds

Page 28: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

25

with a period of notice of up to three months14. Whereas the monetary

aggregate M3 – including the M2 cluster – counts funds with a maturity

of up to two years.

Special attention should be drawn on the monetary base topic, as there

has been the general misconception that the central authority has the

control on the quantity of money. However, the theory of the monetary

base control has already been rejected multiple times in the past by many

economists and the issue is well drawn in several textbook. The

following part will briefly outline the main features of this argument.

Let us introduce it using the words of Charles Goodhart,

“virtually every monetary economist believes that the CB [central

bank] can control the monetary base . . . Almost all those who have

worked in a CB believe that this view is totally mistaken”.

(Goodhart, 1994: 1424)

Considering this false hypothesis, authorities would have a good control

over the money stock if they denied an expansionary policy in order to

fit the money demand. Within this pattern, although commercial banks’

14 European Central Bank [online], available at http://www.ecb.europa.eu/stats/money/aggregates/aggr/html/hist.en.html

Page 29: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

26

balance sheets (individually taken) might change, these terms will not

affect the aggregate balance sheet. As a consequence, the stock of money

in the aggregate balance sheet will remain unchanged. In other words, if

the central bank will not support the increase in lending of commercial

banks, the single commercial bank’s balance sheet (a) will increase due to

an opposite movement in the other commercial bank’s balance sheet (b).

Thus, in presence of this constraint, the cleaning of the operation will

occur at the aggregate level, the lend approval (bank’s asset) shall match

by means of higher liabilities, which might come from other banks’

funds (which will lose deposits and then balances).

By looking at the monetary sector as a whole however, the attempt will

be self-defeating (Howells and Bain, 1990; 2007: 76) as long as the

improvement in a balance sheet will succeed just because b balance sheet

will deteriorate. Within this restraint, money supply is known to be

exogenously determined. In this system, money supply will result in a

vertical curve (Ms), which is also used to introduce the monetary policy

topic in the major textbooks.

However, as Goodhart has well written, central bankers do neither apply

this method, nor the so-called “Monetary base control” theory (MBC) based

on assumptions which have been rejected by central bankers themselves

as well as academics.

Page 30: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

27

In spite of this, the most famous mechanism (according to the

macroeconomics’ manual) used in order to introduce the monetary

policy’s subject is the so-called “money multiplier” concept.

Let us repeat that the monetary base can be controlled though this

method only if some specific assumptions hold. These will be clarified at

the end of the description.

Suppose that

M = Dp + Cp

where M is the money supply, Dp is the deposit held by the public and

Cp is the currency held by the public. Suppose also that

B = Db + Cb + Cp

where B stands for monetary base, Db and Cb are respectively deposits

and currency held by the banking system, and as before, Cp is the

currency held by the public. Let us call the portion detained by the

banking sector as R, reserves. Thus:

R = Db + Cb

thus,

B = R + Cp

Page 31: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

28

If we defined a as R/Db (the portion of reserves to deposits liabilities,

also known as “reserve ratio”) and b as Cb/Db (the portion of currency

to deposits, also known as “cash ratio”) and if we assume that these

ratios are steady, this mechanism will result in a predictable numerical

definition of the quantity of money which will be related to the quantity

of reserves provided. Therefore, as a result, the money multiplier can be

written as follows:

Dividing all terms by the amount of bank deposits, we will obtain

(

) (

)

(

) (

)

Simplifying terms with the ratios before defined,

And we can qualify the relationship between the quantity of money and

monetary base as follows:

Page 32: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

29

And therefore the change in M can be reformulated as:

The term represents the bank deposit multiplier. As

has been said before, under the assumptions of a and b steady, the

quantity of money can be predicted by setting the monetary base.

Unfortunately this is plainly impossible. In the contemporary

international system, trade and financial movements are totally free.

Thus the balance of foreign payments which are in foreign currencies

hinges on central exchange reserves, is out of control. This means that

surpluses translates in base creation and vice versa.

Then in reality central banks cannot control the quantity of money M, as

it depends on the attitude of the public towards holding cash instead of

deposits as well as on commercial banks’ perspective about the amount

of reserves related to the deposits’ liabilities.

Therefore, the level of monetary base results from commercial banks’

behavior through the demand for money and from central banks’

attitude in endorsing it. However, commercial banks’ behavior can be

affected by the central bank through the setting of the price of money.

When a central bank set the i level, the monetary base B is endogenously

defined. Furthermore, the money multiplier process had never been used

to control directly the stock of money (Goodhart, 2013).

Page 33: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

30

Let’s have a look to a more realistic situation: the shortage of liquidity is

avoided by central banks through the supply of money at a certain

interest rate.

In Euroland the lack of funds can be solved by the lending facilities

provided by the European Central Bank. Banks can borrow money

directly from the ECB by paying an interest for the loan, the so-called

refinancing rate (also known as “refi” rate). As long as this rate constitutes

the price of money in Eurozone, this rate can affect lots of other interest

rates. Examples would be the interbank interest rate, the rate required to

households and businesses for loans, or the rate provided in saving

accounts, to mention but a few.

In this case (setting the interest rate in order to affect the demand for

money), the money supply is known to be endogenously determined. In

most of the monetary systems, the regulation of money supply is

endogenous.

This fact lead us to the related economic debate, between verticalists and

horizontalists (Moore, 1988). The former concerns a vertical curve for Ms,

making implicit that the amount of money is settled by the central bank,

directly. Conversely, the latter concerns a horizontal curve for Ms,

Page 34: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

31

explaining that the amount of money is endogenously determined and the

central bank is only responsible for the setting of i (Palley, 2013). In this

sense, the monetary base is known to be perfectly elastic (Kaldor, 1982;

Moore 1988).

Regarding the concept of money, the economist Wray argued that “money

should be seen as credit money” (Wray, 2007), which is a IOU for the issuer

matched and an asset for the holder. And moreover, about the money

multiplier process:

“The notion of a simple deposit multiplier is rejected, and, indeed,

reversed. Bank reserves are not treated as the “raw material” from

which loans can be made; nor are bank deposits an intermediate good

used in the production of loans.” (Wray, 2007)

In order to reach a conclusion to the debate between horizontalists and

verticalists, it is reported the following statement of the economist Lavoie:

“loans make deposits and deposits make reserves” (Lavoie, 1984).

Page 35: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

32

1.4. How does the money creation start?

The larger part of the stock of money is created inside the private sector

as bank deposits i.e. assets that individuals desire to hold in their

portfolios15. This has the very important implication that monetary base

and money do not always move in the same direction an idea which is

normally purported in textbooks.

This statement sometimes may not be well understood because in some

economics textbooks people will easily find different definitions

concerning what money is as well as the process through which is

created. In particular, there are three economic descriptions which can

lead to confusion in comprehending the money mechanism. These can

be stated as follows:

1) Banks lend out deposits;

2) Banks lend out their reserves;

3) Central bank can fix the amount of money in circulation by its

own, as the “money multiplier” process operates with central

bank money.

15 Bank deposits are much strongly correlated with bank credit. More precisely, one cannot have the former without having the latter.

Page 36: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

33

These three common misconceptions, as reported by the Bank of

England, are well portrayed in its Quarterly Bulletin 2014 Q1, Vol. 54

No. 1.

The first can be descripted as a reply to the question “Where does the money

come from?”. The wrong statement that banks lend out deposits origins

from the naïf belief that banks act as intermediaries, collecting savings

from households and businesses and lending out afterward these

deposits. In reality this process operates in the opposite way. Actually,

“commercial banks are the creators of deposit money” (BoE, 2014: 15) and

money is endogenously credit-driven (Moore, 1988).

The entire stock of money does not consist of monetary base (M0, or

rather than M1 in the European case). In the Euro area M1 accounts for

55.7%16 of the overall aggregate M3, and the composition related to M3

is 9.4%17 for currency and 46.3%18 for overnight deposits. Accordingly,

the major amount of money is made up of units of debt (IOU) arranged

by commercial banks for households and businesses and not as widely

believed composed of units of debt (IOU) originated from central banks.

The process of money creation begins whenever a commercial bank

decides to approve a loan request. In more details, it starts exactly when

16 ECB, own calculation based on Q2 2014, Statistical Data Warehouse. 17 ECB, monthly bulletin June 2014, available at <https://www.ecb.europa.eu/pub/mb/html/index.en.html> 18 ECB, monthly bulletin June 2014, available at <https://www.ecb.europa.eu/pub/mb/html/index.en.html>

Page 37: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

34

an economic agent decides to use the money from a credit line. As the

bank comes to this “positive choice”, it charges its bank account with an

amount of deposits (liabilities) of the same size than the size of the loans

(assets). In figure 1 is illustrated how the creation of money works. Some

economists use the expression “fountain pen money” to refer to this

process, because money has been created “at the stroke of bankers’ pens when

they approve loans” (BoE, 2014: 16).

When a bank creates new loans, these will appears in the asset side of her

balance sheet and will be matched immediately afterwards by an increase

in new deposits on the liabilities’ side.

Page 38: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

35

Fig. 2: Money Creation Process (BoE, 2014)

The second misunderstanding concerns the reserves held by commercial

banks at the central banks. Commercial banks cannot lend money which

is registered as reserves within the central bank account. These

Page 39: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

36

“reserves” in question can only be used to accord loans in the following

two cases:

(i) if they hold reserves over and above the requested minimum;

(ii) just between banks (as this type of money can only be transferred

to subjects holding a reserve account at the central bank.

The last wrong assumption involves the role of the money multiplier.

There is a common belief that central banks select the amount of

reserves and regulate the quantity of loans and deposits in the economy

through the money multiplier mechanism. This is based on the

assumption that there is a steady relation between base money (M0) and

broad money (M3). In this sense, the constant ratio would multiply up

the amount of base money by an aforethought amount of loans and

deposits.

But as will be shown in Chapter 2, the money multiplier is not a constant

number. Dealing with it requires the central bank to consider many out-

of-its-control variables. In particular, the money multiplier is affected by

social behaviors, such as the public’s inclination to deposit or hold cash,

which in turn is affected by agents’ confidence in the banking system

(Goodhart, 2008). As it will be demonstrated this is not a fixed relation;

therefore central banks, in order to implement monetary policy’s goals,

prefer to control the interest rates.

Page 40: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

37

1.5. Ways in which banks’ and social behavior can affect monetary

aggregates and destroy deposits

There are two different ways through which agents could destroy newly

created purchasing power:

1) The repayment of the loan;

2) The sale of securities from the banking sector;

3) The issuance of long-term debt in the banking sector.

The first possibility lies on the people’s hands. As money can be created

by fountain pen of bankers which approve loans, money can also easily

be destroyed by the public through its willingness to pay back the loans.

This is the distinctive feature of the debt recession experienced by Japan

during the Nineties and the Noughties. In the banking sector, whenever

a person wants to repay a loan, the repayment will affect both the assets

and the liability side of the banks’ balance sheet. In particular, not only

the banks’ assets (loans) will decrease but also their liabilities (deposits)

will drop by the same amount.

This process becomes clearer in Sir Mervyn King’s speech, who had

been Governor of the Bank of England from 2003 to 2013:

Page 41: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

38

“What we were doing [referring to Quantitative Easing] is injecting

money into the economy, and what the banking sector has been doing

is destroying money [as existing loans were required to be repaid].

As they reduce the size of their balance sheet and deleverage, they’re

reducing not just the size of their assets but also the size of their

liabilities. And most of the money in our economy comprises

liabilities of banks in the form of bank deposits. So what we were

doing was partially to offset what would otherwise have been an even

bigger contraction.” (Mervyn King, 25 October 2011)

Another way to destroy deposits occurs when banks sell existing assets

to the markets. In this way, consumers or companies engage their money

by purchasing assets and securities. Thus, purchasing power shifts from

economic agents to the banking sector, destroying this amount of money

that before was circulating in the economy.

Normally banks affect the overall amount of money in circulation by

buying (creating) or selling (destroying) governments bonds.

Government debt is used also for liquidity purposes and usually a

commercial bank has some sovereign bonds at its disposal. This is due to

the fact that government bonds normally are risk free. This means that

the bank can be sure that in the case it has to sell some assets to meet its

liquidity requirements, it has the possibility to sell these risk-free

government bonds quickly and without saying that Treasury bills can be

Page 42: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

39

considered simply as money. Through this action however, the bank will

destroy purchasing power created before, as the public will pay for these

bonds with the money at their disposal.

For the same reason, money destruction takes place when banks issue

long-term debt and equity instruments. Because these represent long-

term investments, public’s willingness to underwrite these bonds or

equity instruments can destroy money through an exchange between

deposit (money) and non-deposit (financial instruments) liabilities.

Money is an endogenous variable because private agents and commercial

banks together fix its amount.

Page 43: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

40

1.6. Constraints to the money creation mechanism

As has already been explained, lending behavior of bank and non-bank

private sectors can affect the money creation mechanism. To be more

precise, this process can be influenced by:

1) Profitability, risks and regulatory policy which reshape commercial

banks’ behavior;

2) Households and businesses through their willingness to undertake

some destroying-money actions (i.e. repaying the loan);

3) Monetary policy, which can affect some variables (such as the

interest rate) that are likely to have an impact on behavior of the

private sector.

The first case refers to commercial banks’ attitude in extending loans. In

making this choice, a bank should consider the profitability of lending

money to the market. Profitability can be measured by the interest rate

(considered spread on the interbank rate or other interest rate on bank

liability and fees) at which the bank will grant a loan. The price of the

loan then will set the number of households and businesses that are

willing to borrow money at this threshold.

Page 44: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

41

There are however some limitations to this creation process for

commercial banks individually contemplated.

As it was well represented in the BoE’s scheme, the choice of making a

loan will be matched with an increase of deposits of the same amount

for the aggregate banking sector. But if we consider an individual bank

(a) which is approving a loan (let’s say a mortgage loan), after charging

the costumer’s account with the relative increase in deposits, it might be

true that this newly created money will be transferred from the buyer’s

account (a) to the seller’s account (b) which can be based in another

commercial bank (b).

If this is the case, bank A will face a situation with more assets than

liabilities in its balance sheet. At that moment, bank A will transfer

money to bank B through its reserves. Since banks generally approve

new loans during the day, it is likely that reserves will soon run out.

In order to tackle this issue, commercial banks try to (i) attract part of

this newly created money. In order to attract money, they are required to

pay a high interest rate in the costumers’ deposits, and this could

sometimes be impossible given that a commercial bank operates with a

spread (difference between interest rates on the loans and interest rates

on deposits) that is supposed to cover not only operational costs, but

also the riskiness of the operations and profits. Another possible way for

commercial banks that have to deal with the liquidity problem is to (ii)

borrow money from other banks in the interbank market.

Page 45: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

42

This is also affected by the profitability and the trust within the money

market (Bagehot, 1873). As a result, the gainfulness and the

competitiveness of the financial market act as a constraint or an

opportunity for the money creation mechanism.

Risk acts as another important holdback.

For any new loan created, the bank is required to manage risks involved

in this operation. The bank is required to have a huge basket of liabilities

in order to be able to deal with some specific risks (liquidity, credit and

market risks).

However, the balance sheet of a commercial bank is typically built-up

with long-term assets (loans) and short-term liabilities (deposits)19. This

mismatch in maturities is why a commercial bank is likely to face

liquidity problem: it is based on the traditional construction of its balance

sheet which has to consider the special activity they hold inside the

system. In order to deal with the so-called refinancing risk20, banks need to

match their gaps with risk management tools. Furthermore they need to

attract some “long-term deposits”21 and some liquid assets22, through

which they will be able to meet cash withdrawals.

19 As deposits are redeemable on demand (sight deposits). 20 Refinancing risk: a financial institution faces this risk when it holds assets with a greater maturity compared to the liabilities’ one. The risk refers to the fact that it might borrow deposits (liabilities) at a higher rate when the agreed ones expire. I.e. a bank which holds a 5-years maturity loan funded by a 1-year deposit will deal with this issue. 21 Fixed deposits for a certain period of time (BoE, 2014) 22 Assets which can be easily convertible into cash in a very short period of time, with a small loss at maximum.

Page 46: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

43

Another risk to consider when we are dealing with banks’ exposures is

the credit risk. This particular risk is the risk that borrowers are unable to

meet their obligations according to the agreed terms (BIS, 2000) and

cannot repay their loans. According to current rules, commercial banks

are required to have enough capital at their disposal in order to be able

to face exposures on their loans. Banks usually tackle this problem with

some measures which come from risk management tools. In order to be

more precise, credit risk can be considered as a feature which affects

individual loans or even the whole loan portfolio.

Referring to individual loans, in order to assess the creditworthiness of

the firm, commercial banks are likely to rely on Altman’s credit scoring

model23 (Saunders an Cornett, 1994; 2011: 339).

Otherwise if we consider the whole loan portfolio, banks need to

contemplate the loan concentration risk and, taking into account also the

correlation between different loans, they also need to diversify their

portfolio. In this case banks are likely to measure credit risk by applying

23 Accordingly to “Financial Institution Management” handbook (McGraw-Hill), Altman’s score is affected by five factors, which are the following:

X1 Working capital / total assets ratio; X2: Retained earnings / total assets ratio; X3: Earnings before interest and taxes / total assets ratio; X4: Market value of equity / book value of long – term debt ratio; X5: Sales / total assets ratio.

Page 47: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

44

the KMV approach24, known as Moody’s KMV Portfolio Manager Model

(Saunders an Cornett, 1994; 2011: 375).

These analyses help in evaluating credit risk and are useful also for

choosing the interest rate at which the bank should approve a loan

request. It typically charges an interest rate which compensates the

average level of credit losses that are likely to affect the loan portfolio

(BoE, 2014: 19).

Since all these risks (liquidity, credit and market risks) can strongly affect

the soundness and endurance of financial institutions, banks are required

to hold an appropriate capital buffer to face these exposures. In this

sense, regulatory requirements can be regarded as an additional

constraint to the lending development. It is however important to keep

in mind that they overlay a very important function considering the

specialness of the banking sector.

The second brake on money creation concerns households and

companies behavior. The non-bank private sector can significantly affect

the final stock of money in the economy (Tobin, 1963). Two different

scenarios might occur: (i) public and companies will destroy newly

24 Banks can also assess the credit risk on their loan portfolio with other approaches, such as CreditMetrics, CreditRisk+ and Credit Portfolio View from McKinsey and Company (Saunders an Cornett, 1994; 2011: 375).

Page 48: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

45

created money by paying back outstanding loans or (ii) public and

companies will consume and spend, spreading money in the economy.

In the first scenario money is smashed by non-bank private subjects.

This is also known as “reflux theory” from Nicholas Kaldor. When agents

repay loans, the whole balance sheet of consumers will return to the

initial position, so before the loan has been granted.

In the second scenario, however, money (which is always created by

bank making loans’ action) continues to circulate because households

and companies keep spending through their bank accounts. Then, if the

public spends and passes money to people who don’t want to pay back

existing debts, money will increase as every household and company will,

in turn, increase their own deposits or deposits in other accounts by

making other expenditures. This is also known as “hot potato effect” which,

as we said before, can lead to an increase in the money stock which in

turn can affect inflation.

The third constraint comes from the public will: monetary policy can act

either as a holdback or as a stimulus for the money creation process.

One of the main tools with which central banks affect the economic

system is the interest rate. By setting the short-term interest rates, the

price of money, the central bank (which has the monopoly of narrow

Page 49: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

46

money) affects the choices of commercial banks, the creators of broad

money (BoE, 2014).

Therefore, by setting the price of reserves, the central bank tries to

influence the private sector’s behavior and also affects the amounts

which will be exchanged in the money market25. Through these means,

monetary policy tries to impact on the creation of inside money.

However, it does not always achieve that. In the euro area, for instance,

the growth rate in the overall amount of money M3 almost always

exceeded the target rate (4.5%) until the 2008 – 2009 crisis. Since then,

the growth of M3 has always been subdued. More details and charts will

be provided on Chapter 2.

In the most famous manuals this process might not be very clear, as we

can easily find that central bank, through the multiplication of reserves

by a steady ratio (the money multiplier) will define the quantity of money

in circulation. Accordingly, these reserves will lead to a change in banks’

deposits which as a consequence will lead to an increase in lending, and

so on.

However, this is not how the real process operates. This is already made

clear by the mistaken belief that the money multiplier is a constant

parameter.

25 Markets in which central bank and commercial banks transfer money to each other and between financial institutions (BoE, 2014:21).

Page 50: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

47

The money supply is determined by banks through reserves and currency

demand, which they require in order to meet outstanding cash

withdrawals, clearing operations between banks as well as liquidity

requirements.

Therefore,

“The demand for base money is more likely to be a consequence

rather than a cause of banks making loans and creating broad

money” (BoE, 2014: 21).

So, even if the money multiplier allows us to define the ratio between

broad money and monetary base in terms of two parameters, it cannot

be assumed to be providing that the central bank has the capacity of

changing the amount of bank deposits i.e. broad money at its will.

Indeed, bank deposits are decided by individuals while credits are

extended by banks and all the central bank can do is to check the

conditions at which commercial banks satisfy their demand for reserves,

given the decisions of households and companies. It is safe to assume

that during an expansion phase, and particularly when euphoria reins

markets26, individuals like to have more credit than what they actually get

from banks. During a recession, and particularly a balance sheet

26 Hyman Minsky [John Maynard Keynes, 1973, Columbia University Press] taught us that long phases of expansion easily induce market euphoria and excessive risk taking until the crisis breaks out.

Page 51: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

48

recession, it is the turn of banks to be rationed by depositors and

investors. Indeed, referring to the Japanese Great Recession, Richard

Koo27 has argued that over – indebted households, companies and banks

only want to reduce their exposure when asset prices fall. When the

value of assets has fallen below the value of liabilities, balance sheets are

broken and increasing debt exposure is pointless to households,

companies and banks as all merely seek to reduce leverage.

27 Richard Koo [Balance Sheet Recession, 2003 John Wiley] holds the idea that Balance-sheet recession is different from both Fisher’s Debt deflation (1933) and Keynes’s Liquidity Trap (1936) and also the wrong monetary policy of Friedman-Schwartz (1963) notions. The Balance-sheet recession basically depends on the shift from profit maximization to debt minimization which simultaneously takes place among so many companies. According to him, during the Japanese long recession, the priority was debt reduction and the cash flow and bank deposits were used to reduce debt. As investment and consumption suffer, public expenditure is the only remedy. Deflation appeared only when the government in charge tried to kill the economy with fiscal consolidation.

Page 52: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

49

2. Financial stability in the European Economic

and Monetary Union

2.1 The European Union pattern: an historical preface

“ […] only knowledge of the past enables us fully to understand the

present, the failure to read the past correctly warps our capacity to act

intelligently in the contemporary world. [...] The study of history has

been believed to provide a guide not simply to passive understanding of

the world, but to active political and moral action within it.”

(Howard, 1991)

The project of a Banking Union traces its origins from the past. Some of

the intellectuals and founding fathers which outlined this stately

common project were aware of the future developments that the

European Union would have to face. The EU started to build its

institutions after the tragedy of the World War II in order to escape from

the horrors which arose from nationalisms that had ruined our

continent. It lays its background in the words of Winston Churchill, who

stated in 1946 “we must re-create the European family” in order to avoid the

recurrence of past atrocities. Again, with the words of Robert Schuman,

Page 53: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

50

"World peace cannot be safeguarded without the making of creative

efforts proportionate to the dangers which threaten it. […] Europe

will not be made all at once, or according to a single plan. It will be

built through concrete achievements which first create a de facto

solidarity.” (Schuman, 1950)

However, the construction of Europe began already well before. In fact,

during the Middle Age, the developments of relationships between

merchants and writers became even greater and contributed to the

construction of an European consciousness (Rossi, 2014).

Linking that to the above mentioned arguments of Churchill and

Schuman, the social construction of the European society can be said to

have occurred in two different forms. Depending on the degree of the

relationships: (i) it has been built from people, by increasing commerce

practices, travels, cultural exchanges, knowledge sharing among the

countries or (ii) it has been created by the building of some common

institutions, rules and governance entities.

The European Union lays its fundamentals in the European Coal and

Steel Community (ECSC) and the European Economic Community

(EEC) which had been established by France, Italy, West Germany and

Page 54: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

51

Benelux (Belgium, Luxemburg and the Netherlands)28 in 1951 and 1957,

respectively. The EU was based on agreements which involved coal and

steel29. As stated by Schuman, it was important to found the European

project on an economic purpose, and to declare better the importance to

avoid wars.

The Union as we know it today however arises from the signing of the

Treaty of Maastricht, in 1992. At this date, the expression European

Community shifted in European Union. It entered into force in 1993

and laid down the foundations for the creation of the single currency,

the euro. Thus, in order to be able to join the third stage of the

Economic and Monetary Union (EMU) namely the Euro Zone and to

adopt the single currency, the countries are required to meet the specific

convergence criteria.

The five criteria, as reported by the European Commission, are the

following five:

28 The so – called “Inner six”. 29 Two materials, coal and steel, which were fundamental for the reconstruction of the nations: they were vital for energy production (coal) and the industry (steel). However, they were really basic also for the construction of weapons.

Page 55: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

52

What is measured:

Price stability

Sound public

finances

Sustainable public

finances

Durability of convergence

Exchange rate

stability

How it is measured:

Consumer price inflation rate

Government deficit as % of

GDP

Government debt as % of GDP

Long-term interest rate

Deviation from a central rate

Convergence criteria:

Not more than 1.5 percentage points above the rate of the three best performing Member States

Reference value: not more than 3%

Reference value: not more than 60%

Not more than 2 percentage points above the rate of the three best performing Member States in terms of price stability

Participation in ERM II for at least 2 years without severe tensions

Fig. 3: The convergence criteria (EC, 2014)

The common currency constituted a huge challenge for the countries

which were and are willing to join. Within the adoption of it, they will

entrust the European Central Bank – an independent decision-making

body of the European institutions established in 1998 – in charge of the

conduction of their own monetary policy in conjunction with other

countries.

This means that they will not be able to compensate their internal fiscal

shocks through monetary policies’ measures. Since the European Union

is not yet a fiscal union, the feature of having the same currency (and

Page 56: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

53

furthermore the fulfilment of fiscal constraints) can lead countries to

tackle many issues and to face asymmetric shocks. Asymmetric shocks have

been defined by economists as unexpected changes in the aggregate

supply and/or demand in one country which do not hit and affect the

one of its main trading partners (Blanchard, Amighini and Giavazzi

2010; 2013: 432). To illustrate this, consider for instance, a shock which

might occur in the wine demand in France (i.e. a deep decrease). Such a

shock is unlikely to have an influence on the aggregate demand in

Ireland. As French aggregate demand will fall whereas the Irish one will

be untouched by this circumstance, this is called asymmetric shock.

It has been already argued whether the Economic and Monetary Union

can be qualified as an Optimal Currency Area (Mundell, 1961), by

assessing and evaluating the types of shocks that might occur within

countries which found the European Economic and Monetary Union.

There is a wide range of opinions regarding the answer to this question

and the conclusion is still not straightforward. In analysing benefits

within the European Union, some economists define those as reduced

uncertainty, a drop in transaction costs, an increase in price transparency,

a shared anti-inflationary reputation (regarding the case of forming a

Union with a country which holds a good reputation with respect to

maintaining inflation at a low level), benefits from being an international

currency30 and some positive trade-effects31 (De Grauwe, 2000).

30 The good reputation of a currency might lead to an increase of the demand for it, and the currency area could benefit as the shares of the currency in the global reserves rise.

Page 57: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

54

Costs, as we have already delineated, are mostly the result of asymmetric

shocks which hit the member countries and cannot be solved by changing

the exchange rate (the issue is even more pronounced in the presence of

wage and price rigidity). Shocks which occur differently among countries

might need different stabilisation policies (Mundell, 1963). A further

cost, not entirely expected in 1992 when average inflation was above 2%,

is the difficulty of a un-competitive country B to increase its

competitiveness against a competitive country A by increasing its real

exchange rate when the latter (country A) is near deflation. This problem

is currently troubling the Eurozone.

The labour mobility is an important condition which might be able to

deal with these shocks. Getting back to the example mentioned above,

whenever a shock in the aggregate demand affects France instead of

Ireland, labour force should migrate to Ireland. If this is the case, France

will likely deal with a drop in its natural level of output whereas in the

meantime Ireland will likely face an increase in the same variable. As a

consequence, the equilibrium will be re-established without changing the

real exchange rate (Blanchard, Amighini and Giavazzi 2010; 2013: 433)

although the flexibility of the real exchange rate obviously is more easy

to obtain than the flexibility of work force location. In a deflationary

situation as the current one, even the flexibility of the real exchange rate 31 There are some studies which state that a Monetary Union might have positive effects for trade transactions within the member countries. It has been declared that the euro has increase the intra – euro area trade by 5 to 10% on average (Blanchard, Amighini and Giavazzi 2010; 2013).

Page 58: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

55

becomes difficult. Efforts to increase competitiveness impair the

capacity of the central bank to bring the inflation rate up i.e. towards 2%.

Another argument which could likely tackle asymmetric shocks is the fiscal

integration: large “federal” expenditures at regional and local level. In

other words, the lack of flexibility in the exchange rate might be settled

with budgetary policies which can “deal with the stubborn pockets of

unemployment” (Kenen, 1969).

Considering the presence of asymmetric shocks, limited cross-border

labour mobility within the European Union as well as an unwillingness

to make up common fiscal policies (Krugman, 2012), it becomes difficult

to argue that the Economic and Monetary Union (EMU) is an Optimal

Currency Area (OCA).

It is nevertheless important to mention that “optimal definitions” might

not be well suited to describe an imperfect real world. Most of the time

objects are not easy to define and state of affairs cannot be settled by

theories, even though enchanting. When it comes to defining areas and

unifications of nations, history and political issues need to be taken into

account.

Page 59: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

56

2.2 The establishment of the European Central Bank

As stated in the first chapter, the European Central Bank is the entrusted

institution in charge of the conduction of the monetary policy within the

European Economic and Monetary Union. It represents its centrepiece.

The conduction of the monetary policy is decided by the ECB for all the

countries which adopted the single currency. The implementation of the

monetary policy is however carried out at a decentralised national level,

through the National Central Banks. The National Central Banks (NCBs

of countries which adopted the euro) and the European Central Bank

(ECB) form the European System of Central Banks (ESCB), which the

treaty mainly refers to.

ECB has been established in 1998 and began its activity on the 1st

January 1999, thus in the third stage of EMU. This also corresponds to

the date at which the euro currency has been introduced within the

member countries. Its main tasks, as mentioned in the Article 127 of the

Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union, are the following:

i. the definition and implementation of monetary policy for the euro

area;

ii. the conduct of foreign exchange operations;

iii. the holding and management of the official foreign reserves of the

euro area countries (portfolio management);

Page 60: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

57

iv. the promotion of the smooth operation of payment systems.

(Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union, Article 127)

Furthermore other tasks carried out by the ECB can be defined as the

follows:

i. Being the issuer of the euro currency;

ii. Data collection and statistics publication;

iii. Financial stability and supervision, which will constitute even

more an important task within the implementation of the

European Banking Union;

iv. Maintenance of a well-functioning cooperation with

international and European relevant institutions.

To better describe the main goal pursued by the ECB, we need to

consider the fact that one of the most important reasons resulting in the

willingness to establish a common currency under a common central

bank has been the need of a stable exchange rate within the European

currencies32.

32 Currencies such as the German mark, the French franc, the Italian lira and the Spanish peseta, to mention but a few.

Page 61: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

58

In 1978, after the collapse of the Bretton Woods system33, the European

Monetary System – in which each European currency had been anchored

to the German mark – had been established34. It had been set

fluctuations of ±2.25% (narrow bands) and ±6% (wide bands) in order

to establish a range around a central rate within the different currencies

had to accomplish with (De Grauwe, 2003). Again, severe fluctuations

outside the bands and incompatible monetary policy goals across

countries forced some nations (i.e. Italy and United Kingdom) to be

forced out of the European Monetary System (Wyplosz, 1997). After

having raised the bands at ±15% in August 1993, the system ceased to

exist on the 1st of January 1999, when the euro has been implemented.

The non-alignment of the European currencies to the above-mentioned

fluctuation bands led the countries to face much devaluation against the

mark. This state of affairs in combination to the willingness to develop

the internal market convinced the European Economic and Monetary

Union to set the price stability as a priority for the new currency.

33 Which had been the monetary system from 1940 to 1971, establishing a peg between every currency and the US dollar. This had resulted into a fluctuation band of ±1.50% around a central rate, stating that every currency should had not deviate from the dollar by more than ±0.75%. 34 The mark (DM) started to fill the position and act as a role player in assessing the value of other currencies (as dollar used to do it during Bretton Woods’ period).

Page 62: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

59

Unlike the FED35 that has adopted a dual mandate taking into account

both inflation and employment, the ECB has chosen a more hierarchical

mandate and has stated to pursue the following objective:

“The primary objective of the European System of Central Banks

[…] shall be to maintain price stability. Without prejudice to the

objective of price stability, the ESCB shall support the general

economic policies in the Union with a view to contributing to the

achievement of the objectives of the Union as laid down in Article 3 of

the Treaty on European Union. The ESCB shall act in accordance

with the principle of an open market economy with free competition,

favouring an efficient allocation of resources, and in compliance with

the principles set out in Article 119.”

(Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union, article 127)

Thus even though the ECB has to contribute to the achievement of the

Union’s objectives (which includes an economic growth, a sustainable

development and the improvement of a competitive social market), the

primary goal that the ECB is required to pursue is price stability36.

35 Central Bank of U.S.A. 36 Heightened also by the second sentence, which starts with the statement “Without prejudice to the objective of price stability […]” (Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union, Article 127).

Page 63: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

60

Price stability has been defined by the ECB as “a year-on-year increase in the

Harmonised Index of Consumer Prices (HICP) for the euro area of below 2%”

(The ECB’s Governing Council). In addition, the pursued rate of

inflation37 has also been clarified more in greater detail by stating that

the aim is to maintain the above-mentioned rate “below, but close to 2%,

over the medium term”. Through the definition of this objective, the ECB

has also made clear that a potential deflation is against its goal. However,

inflation rates occurring at a national level within each member state may

still be different. The accomplishment of the ECB’s target in the short

term is thus not a straightforward task to do. The following figure

highlights the deviations from the target rate regarding some different

countries before and after the establishment of the single currency:

37 It is interesting to mention that the word “inflation”, which is generally explained as an increase of the price level, is also defined as a decrease in the value of money by some dictionaries (i.e. Longman).

Page 64: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

61

Fig. 4: Inflation rates, from 1997 to 2014 (own figure, Bloomberg dataset)

A stable inflation rate within the EMU can be achieved whenever it is

consistent with domestic inflation preferences (Mundell, 1997). The

latter is nevertheless affected by the expected inflation π* that agents will

forecast according to the output of the country (Debrun, 2001). The

common monetary policy goal will then be influenced by the different

inflationary biases (Barro and Gordon, 1983) occurring within the

countries.

-4

-2

0

2

4

6

8

2/1

/19

97

11

/1/1

99

7

8/1

/19

98

5/1

/19

99

2/1

/20

00

11

/1/2

00

0

8/1

/20

01

5/1

/20

02

2/1

/20

03

11

/1/2

00

3

8/1

/20

04

5/1

/20

05

2/1

/20

06

11

/1/2

00

6

8/1

/20

07

5/1

/20

08

2/1

/20

09

11

/1/2

00

9

8/1

/20

10

5/1

/20

11

2/1

/20

12

11

/1/2

01

2

8/1

/20

13

5/1

/20

14

Eurozone Mean UE DE IT SPA FR GRE

Inflation rates in the Euro area

Page 65: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

62

By analysing the previous graph on inflation rates, we can find a rate for

the Eurozone from 1999 until now of 1.98%. We need nevertheless to

mention that the Harmonized Index of Consumer Prices (HICP)

measures the inflation rate within a specified basket of goods and

services38 which does not take into account asset prices (or if

contemplated, the assigned weight is known to be too small). Goodhart

blames this to be the cause of “bubble and bust” in many instances

(Goodhart, 2001). Theoretical arguments in favour of including the

volatility of assets prices have been underlined by Alchian and Klein. In

their work “On a correct measure of inflation” they highlighted the risks that

inappropriate measures would have in pursuing the monetary policy

goals. Furthermore, they argue that the failure in considering futures and

assets prices can lead to a severe bias in the measure of the price level

(Alchian and Klein, 1973).

Even though one might agree on many of the arguments discussed in

the academic literature, there are nevertheless practical issues which let

us conclude that an implementation is difficult to achieve. The main

causes seem to be the difficulty in finding an appropriate weight for asset

prices in the index (Goodhart, 2001) as well as an adequate discount rate

to link to the above-mentioned weight (Cecchetti, 2000).

38 Which can be found at <https://www.ecb.europa.eu/stats/prices/hicp/html/hicp_coicop_inw_2014.en.html>

Page 66: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

63

2.3 Two – pillars approach and monetary policy tools of the European

Central Bank

Even though the Bank of England has stated that the monetary

aggregates do not play a clear role in the monetary policy conduction

(King, 2002), and despite the fact that the FED agrees with this

statement39 (Meyer, 2001), the method which has been selected by the

ECB disagrees with other central banks’ pattern. Conversely to them, it

underlines the prominent role of monetary aggregates in the conduct of

monetary policy (Issing, 2006).

The ECB adopts a range of monetary policy tools in order to transmit its

monetary policy choices to the financial institutions and to accomplish

its above-mentioned main objective. The instruments at its disposal are

the following:

i) Open market operations;

ii) Standing facilities;

iii) Minimum reserve requirements for credit institutions.

The following overview provided by the ECB describes in a more

detailed manner the open market operations and the standing facilities

39 “Money plays no explicit role in today’s consensus macro model, and it plays virtually no role in the conduct monetary policy.” (Meyer, 2001).

Page 67: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

64

tools, regarding the description of the transactions, the maturities, the

frequencies and the procedures adopted:

Monetary policy

operations

Types of transactions Maturity Frequency Procedure

Liquidity- providing

Liquidity- absorbing

OPEN MARKET OPERATIONS

Main refinancing operations

Reverse transactions

- One week Weekly Standard tenders

Longer-term refinancing operations2

Reverse transactions

- Three months Monthly Standard tenders

Fine-tuning operations

Reverse transactions

Reverse transactions

Non- standardised

Non-regular Quick tenders

Foreign exchange swaps

Collection of fixed-term deposits

Bilateral Procedures

Foreign exchange swaps

Structural operations

Reverse transactions

Issuance of debt certificates

Standardised/ non-standardised

Regular and non-regular

Standard tenders

Outright purchases

Outright sales

- Non-regular Bilateral Procedures

STANDING FACILITIES

Marginal lending facility

Reverse transactions

- Overnight Access at the discretion of counterparties

Deposit facility

- Deposits Overnight Access at the discretion of counterparties

Fig. 5: Eurosystem open market operations and standing facilities (ECB, 2014)

The minimum reserve requirement is requested by the ECB from their

counterparties in order to control the credit expansions of banks’

balance sheets. The minimum requirement has to be hold by every credit

institution within its own account at the national central bank (NCB).

The ratio has dropped to 1% from 18 January 201240 (ECB, 2013) in

order to contribute to the expansionary monetary policy which has been

40 Previously was set at 2%.

Page 68: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

65

adopted as a tool after the financial crisis (Deutsche Bank, 2014).

According to Friedman and Schwarz’s “Monetary theory” (1963), thus in

line with the ECB strategy, the ECB didn’t act as the FED after the crisis

of 1929, who rose the reserve requirements prematurely and drove the

financial system into an even greater depression (Goodhart, 2013).

Every instrument of the monetary policy conduction however has to be

implemented under the two – pillars approach which aim to achieve

price stability.

A two – pillar approach has been chosen by the ECB in order to

implement the monetary policy within the EMU. This strategy is in

charge of the assessment of the ECB’s main goal: the price stability.

Accordingly, the evaluations conducted by the ECB consist of:

i) An economic analysis;

ii) A monetary analysis.

The economic analysis is focused on short and medium term variables

which are likely to affect the price level. This research aims to find the

right relation between real activities and price developments. In order to

achieve this goal, the ECB analyses some variables within the Euroland,

such as outputs, labour market conditions, fiscal policies, balance of

payments and costs indicators, to mention but a few (ECB, 2014).

Page 69: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

66

The monetary analysis focuses more on the long run. The supervision of

the growth of monetary aggregates in order to assess the risks for the

price stability finds its reasons on the famous dictum of Milton Friedman

that “inflation is always and everywhere a monetary phenomenon” (Friedman,

1992) and in the assumptions behind its well – known “quantity theory of

money” which for his part in line is based on the equation of Irving

Fisher. In order to conduct this comprehensive monetary analysis, the

ECB takes into account a wide panel of instruments which is

continuously developed and improved. However, as this strategy is based

on the long – run neutrality of money theory41 and on the fact that there is an

high correlation between inflation and the monetary aggregates, this is

one of the most controversial and discussed elements of the ECB’s

approach.

The core of this research is nevertheless the previously defined monetary

aggregate M3. In order to achieve the price stability and meet the

convergence criteria signed into the Maastricht agreement, the target

growth for M3 has been set at a steady rate of 4.5%. The following

graphs show that this objective basically has never been reached neither

before nor after the financial crisis in 2008. An additional record of this

unsuccessful approach (based on a target growth rate on M3, a variable

that is out-of-the-control of the central bank) can be descripted as the

41 Which states that, in the long run, an increase in the money supply always turns into an increase in the price level.

Page 70: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

67

fact that immediately after the early stage of the Euroland, this rate has

been taken out of the official publications of the ECB itself.

In conclusion, the M3 growth cannot be considered as steady.

Furthermore, every country within the Euroland contributes in different

shares of the M3 growth (as reported by fig. 5-6), making it even more

difficult to achieve a European target related to the M3 growth.

That graph indeed shows us that M3 growth fluctuates very differently

from country to country. In Germany for instance, M3 has been steadily

increasing from 1999 to 2014, whereas in Greece it rose significantly

before 2009, and then dropped from 2009 to 2012. The most substantial

rise however has been awarded to Spain, a country which encounters a

sharp growth of the aggregate from 1999 to 2008, and then faced a slow

decrease until 2014.

Page 71: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

68

Fig. 6: M3 growth rate in the Euro area (own calculation, Thomson Reuters dataset)

-2

0

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

1/1

/19

99

10

/1/1

99

9

7/1

/20

00

4/1

/20

01

1/1

/20

02

10

/1/2

00

2

7/1

/20

03

4/1

/20

04

1/1

/20

05

10

/1/2

00

5

7/1

/20

06

4/1

/20

07

1/1

/20

08

10

/1/2

00

8

7/1

/20

09

4/1

/20

10

1/1

/20

11

10

/1/2

01

1

7/1

/20

12

4/1

/20

13

1/1

/20

14

%

M3 growth rate in the Euro area

M3 YoY M3 target rate

Page 72: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

69

Fig. 7: M3 total amounts in some Euro countries (own calculation, Thomson Reuters dataset)

0

500,000,000,000

1,000,000,000,000

1,500,000,000,000

2,000,000,000,000

2,500,000,000,000

3,000,000,000,0001

/1/1

99

9

10

/1/1

99

9

7/1

/20

00

4/1

/20

01

1/1

/20

02

10

/1/2

00

2

7/1

/20

03

4/1

/20

04

1/1

/20

05

10

/1/2

00

5

7/1

/20

06

4/1

/20

07

1/1

/20

08

10

/1/2

00

8

7/1

/20

09

4/1

/20

10

1/1

/20

11

10

/1/2

01

1

7/1

/20

12

4/1

/20

13

1/1

/20

14

M3 in some Euro countries (total amounts)

ITA SPA DE GRE FRA

Page 73: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

70

Fig. 8: M3 in some Euro countries, index 1999 (own calculation, Thomson Reuters dataset)

0

50

100

150

200

250

300

1/1

/19

99

9/1

/19

99

5/1

/20

00

1/1

/20

01

9/1

/20

01

5/1

/20

02

1/1

/20

03

9/1

/20

03

5/1

/20

04

1/1

/20

05

9/1

/20

05

5/1

/20

06

1/1

/20

07

9/1

/20

07

5/1

/20

08

1/1

/20

09

9/1

/20

09

5/1

/20

10

1/1

/20

11

9/1

/20

11

5/1

/20

12

1/1

/20

13

9/1

/20

13

Ind

ex

M3 in some Euro countries (Index=1999)

ITA SPA DE GRE FRA

Page 74: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

71

2.4 The European Central Bank weapons

After the outbreak of the Eurozone crisis at the early stages of 2009, the

European Central Bank has established and developed some

mechanisms destined to lower the risk premium of some southern

Member countries (Shambaugh, Reis and Rey, 2012) and to foster

financial stability across the European banking system. We will briefly

discuss these measures here below, considering them as part of the

greater aim in developing the financial stability within the European

outline.

Even though the following measures are promoted for the same aim as

the one stated above, we can contemplate them into two different (but

undoubtedly interconnected) sections:

i) Tools focus on the governmental side;

ii) Tools focus on the banking system side.

Despite the fact that they have been arranged in order to break the

vicious cycle between banks and sovereigns, we could state that:

i) Long – term refinancing operations, balance sheet increases

and interest rate policies are addressed by the banking system;

ii) Outright Monetary Transactions and European Stability

Mechanism had been designed for governmental purposes.

Page 75: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

72

As a consequence, the weakening of the banking system due also to the

sovereign debt crisis has had negative impacts on the real growth of the

Euro zone. The relation among the above-mentioned three sectors find

an explanation on the following figure provided by Shambaugh (2012) in

his “The Euro’s three crisis” paper:

Fig. 9: The Euro's three crisis (Shambaugh, 2012)

Besides confirming the existence of the vicious cycle between banks and

sovereigns (European Commission, 2014), which the European Banking

Union is aiming to break, it provides evidence on how the relationship

banks and sovereigns can impact growth and competitiveness, through

Page 76: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

73

reducing lending to businesses and companies (Shambaugh, Reis and

Rey, 2012).

The relation among banks and sovereigns has nevertheless been

descripted as a “diabolical loop” by the Euro-nomics group42 and this

connection reflects heavily on austerity or future growth conditions

(Eichengreen, 2012), as banks are unable to extend credit due to fact that

they cannot expose their already weakened balance sheets to additional

risks. Moreover, the austerity conditions have a negative impact on the

capability of the private sector to pay back loans. This is indeed

responsible for the loop, as mentioned before.

42 A group formed by nine academic economists from several Euro members. More detail on their proposal can be found at the following link: <http://euronomics.princeton.edu/esb/>.

Page 77: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

74

2.4.1 Long – Term Refinancing Operations

With the acronym LTROs we refer to two operations built up by the

European Central Bank in order to provide liquidity for the money

market activity and to enhance bank lending. By these measures, the

ECB provided credit with a long maturity (3 years) at the refinancing

rate43 and lowered the quality required for collateral44. It set up these

transactions in December 2011 and in February 2012, and provided

liquidity for nearly 490 and 530 billion euros, respectively.

The ECB opted for this “weapon” after having noticed that trust faded

inside the interbank market and that as a consequence, banks were

unable to borrow money from their counterparts. The ECB still

continues to adopt these measures as a tool of monetary policy, even

after these two extraordinary cases.

However, as has been argued by some economists (Baglioni, 2012), even

though the ECB provided the two above mentioned lending facilities,

banks which held these loans increased the use of the deposit facility45

43 which was 1%. 44 More details can be found at the following link: <http://www.ecb.europa.eu/press/pr/date/2011/html/pr111208_1.en.html> 45 Deposit facility: a standing facility where counterparties of Eurosystem can deposit money overnight, at a certain interest rate to National Central Banks (NCBs). It is also a method through which banks avoid to put their additional liabilities into the interbank market and can still have a

financial return from it (but not in this time, as long as ECB set a negative interest rate on the deposit facility, in order to take action against the “credit crunch” behavior of banks due to the lack of trust.

Page 78: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

75

instead of using these amounts to lend to other banks in the interbank

channel. Research conducted by BIS in April 2012 shows that the

countries which massively used the deposit facility were Finland,

Germany and Luxembourg.

This financial behaviour, which is affected significantly by the

confidence within the system (Bagehot, 1873), taught us that even if the

main financial institution (i.e. the central bank) boosts the economy by

providing lending of huge amounts to an injured system, this is no

guarantee to turn the economy and the financial sector into a well-

functioning system. The latter can be affected exclusively by banks and

relies on their own behaviour. The goal will not be achieved whenever

banks hoard cash.

Page 79: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

76

60,5

16

33,4

10

24,1

28

20,2

34

24,6

05

15,9

20

37,7

80

104,

474

147,

362

196,

884

226,

072 32

3,36

8 47

3,44

5 48

0,94

0 78

2,56

4 76

7,51

3 77

3,20

3 76

8,08

9 49

5,90

8 32

1,88

7 32

1,39

6 26

6,71

1 24

0,57

9 23

4,76

8 21

9,63

0 15

6,89

5 13

5,01

5 11

9,75

6 95

,259

90

,387

88

,148

80

,122

65

,923

52

,071

50

,194

52

,170

53

,574

36

,669

29

,490

27

,067

28

,750

27

,007

0

100,000

200,000

300,000

400,000

500,000

600,000

700,000

800,000

900,000

Deposit facility use at the European Central Bank

Fig. 10: LTROs and deposit facility use (own calculation, Bloomberg dataset)

0

200

400

600

800

1,000

1,2001

/30

/19

99

1/3

0/2

00

0

1/3

0/2

00

1

1/3

0/2

00

2

1/3

0/2

00

3

1/3

0/2

00

4

1/3

0/2

00

5

1/3

0/2

00

6

1/3

0/2

00

7

1/3

0/2

00

8

1/3

0/2

00

9

1/3

0/2

01

0

1/3

0/2

01

1

1/3

0/2

01

2

1/3

0/2

01

3

1/3

0/2

01

4

€ b

illi

on

LTROs and deposit facility use

Deposit facility LTROs

Fig. 11: Deposit facility use (own calculation, Bloomberg dataset)

Page 80: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

77

2.4.2 ECB’s balance sheet and the monetary aggregates evolution

The latest developments of the ECB’s balance sheet outline the boost in

liquidity it provided within the financial market over the past months.

On the following figures we will provide evidence on the willingness of

the ECB to smooth financial operations. The ECB, in order to tackle the

lack of liquidity and the credit crunch, has adopted a wide range of

operations (i.e. Long Term Refinancing Operations and Eurosystem

Securities Market Program) being part of an expansionary monetary

policy. However, as we described in the first chapter, commercial banks

- through the accordance of loans – have the power in the money

creation process. Accordingly, an increase in the monetary base does not

always result in a rise of the money stock (De Grauwe, 2011), and

moreover, during periods of panic within the financial markets, these

two measures tend to follow two different paths.

As will be shown by one of the following graphs, setting the year 1999 as

100 (index), it will be clear that increases of the monetary base (BM)

have not always resulted into increases of the broader monetary

aggregate (M3).

Page 81: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

78

Fig. 12: Assets of the European Central Bank (own calculation, Bloomberg dataset)

Fig. 13: Monetary base of the European Central Bank (own calculation, Bloomberg dataset)

0

500

1,000

1,500

2,000

2,500

3,000

3,5001

/1/1

99

9

10

/1/1

99

9

7/1

/20

00

4/1

/20

01

1/1

/20

02

10

/1/2

00

2

7/1

/20

03

4/1

/20

04

1/1

/20

05

10

/1/2

00

5

7/1

/20

06

4/1

/20

07

1/1

/20

08

10

/1/2

00

8

7/1

/20

09

4/1

/20

10

1/1

/20

11

10

/1/2

01

1

7/1

/20

12

4/1

/20

13

1/1

/20

14

€ b

illi

on

Total assets of the ECB

Assets

0

200

400

600

800

1,000

1,200

1,400

1,600

1,800

2,000

2/1

/19

99

10

/1/1

99

9

6/1

/20

00

2/1

/20

01

10

/1/2

00

1

6/1

/20

02

2/1

/20

03

10

/1/2

00

3

6/1

/20

04

2/1

/20

05

10

/1/2

00

5

6/1

/20

06

2/1

/20

07

10

/1/2

00

7

6/1

/20

08

2/1

/20

09

10

/1/2

00

9

6/1

/20

10

2/1

/20

11

10

/1/2

01

1

6/1

/20

12

2/1

/20

13

10

/1/2

01

3

€ b

illi

on

Monetary base of the ECB

BM

Page 82: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

79

According to fig. 10, the ECB’s balance sheet has been subjected to a

substantial increase during the period 2011 – 2012. That increase has

been the result of an extraordinary expansionary monetary policy,

portrayed by fig. 11, which represents an increase of the monetary base

by almost 800 billion euro.

However, even though the monetary base has been subject to a

significant increase, that did not lead to a consequential rise in the

monetary aggregate M3, as shown by fig. 12. In other words, the

monetary aggregates do not respond coherently to changes in the

monetary base. Supported by fig. 13, we can state that monetary

aggregates move slowly during financial crises even if boosted by the

central bank’s action.

Page 83: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

80

Fig. 14: Monetary base and M3 in the Euro area (own calculation, Bloomberg dataset)

Fig. 15: Monetary aggregates in the Euro area (own calculation, Bloomberg dataset)

0

50

100

150

200

250

300

350

400

450

1/1

/19

99

9/1

/19

99

5/1

/20

00

1/1

/20

01

9/1

/20

01

5/1

/20

02

1/1

/20

03

9/1

/20

03

5/1

/20

04

1/1

/20

05

9/1

/20

05

5/1

/20

06

1/1

/20

07

9/1

/20

07

5/1

/20

08

1/1

/20

09

9/1

/20

09

5/1

/20

10

1/1

/20

11

9/1

/20

11

5/1

/20

12

1/1

/20

13

9/1

/20

13

5/1

/20

14

Ind

ex

Monetary Base and M3 in the Euro area 1999=100

BM M3

0

2,000

4,000

6,000

8,000

10,000

12,000

2/1

/19

99

10

/1/1

99

9

6/1

/20

00

2/1

/20

01

10

/1/2

00

1

6/1

/20

02

2/1

/20

03

10

/1/2

00

3

6/1

/20

04

2/1

/20

05

10

/1/2

00

5

6/1

/20

06

2/1

/20

07

10

/1/2

00

7

6/1

/20

08

2/1

/20

09

10

/1/2

00

9

6/1

/20

10

2/1

/20

11

10

/1/2

01

1

6/1

/20

12

2/1

/20

13

10

/1/2

01

3

€ b

illi

on

Monetary aggregates in the Euro area

M1 M2 M3

Page 84: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

81

Furthermore, the monetary aggregates’ annual growth (Year over Year)

represented in fig. 14 show a huge drop of the aggregates M2 and M3.

To be more precise, M3 growth fell from a value of 12.4 in 2007 to a

value of -0.4 in 2010. After reaching this negative growth minimum, M3

rose again until 2012, when it achieved a growth rate of 3.8%. After the

peak, the aggregate has suffered another drop which is still on going. The

data for M3 has been reported until May 2014 with a final percentage of

1.2.

Fig. 16: Monetary aggregates growth (own calculation, Bloomberg dataset)

-2

0

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

1/1

/19

99

9/1

/19

99

5/1

/20

00

1/1

/20

01

9/1

/20

01

5/1

/20

02

1/1

/20

03

9/1

/20

03

5/1

/20

04

1/1

/20

05

9/1

/20

05

5/1

/20

06

1/1

/20

07

9/1

/20

07

5/1

/20

08

1/1

/20

09

9/1

/20

09

5/1

/20

10

1/1

/20

11

9/1

/20

11

5/1

/20

12

1/1

/20

13

9/1

/20

13

5/1

/20

14

Monetary aggregates growth in the Euro area

M1 YoY M2 YoY M3 YoY

Page 85: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

82

Taking into account the remarks made in the first chapter, fig. 15

represents an assessment of the money multiplier, a variable treated

inherently as steady by central banks implementing a monetary targeting

strategy. According to fig. 15, after having reached a spike of 13.16 in

2002, the M3 money multiplier decreased to 10.1 in 2008.

Following 2008, the multiplier has witnessed unsteady fluctuations,

dropping to a value of 5.5 in 2012, figuring a financial turmoil within the

system. Since the cash ratio (chosen by the public) and the reserve ratio

(chosen by banks) play a large role in determining the level, the variable

is seriously affected by the confidence within the banking system. The

current value for the M3 money multiplier is nevertheless 8.50.

Page 86: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

83

Fig. 17: Money multipliers in the Euro area (own calculation, Bloomberg dataset)

0

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

2/1

/19

99

10

/1/1

99

9

6/1

/20

00

2/1

/20

01

10

/1/2

00

1

6/1

/20

02

2/1

/20

03

10

/1/2

00

3

6/1

/20

04

2/1

/20

05

10

/1/2

00

5

6/1

/20

06

2/1

/20

07

10

/1/2

00

7

6/1

/20

08

2/1

/20

09

10

/1/2

00

9

6/1

/20

10

2/1

/20

11

10

/1/2

01

1

6/1

/20

12

2/1

/20

13

10

/1/2

01

3

Money multipliers in the Euro area

Money multiplier M1 Money multiplier M2 Money multiplier M3

Page 87: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

84

2.4.3 Interest rate policy

The interest rate policy represents an important tool for the

implementation of the monetary policy and could predict the features of

the financial market.

The three interest rates set by the ECB within the Euro zone can be

descripted as follows:

i) Refinancing rate: also called “refi rate”, is the main

interest rate within the Union. It replaced the discount

rate. It represents the cost of money on the main

refinancing operations (MROs) which provide a huge

amount of liquidity in the banking sector (ECB, 2014).

It serves as a benchmark for the EONIA rate46 which

fluctuates around it. It represents the centre of the

interest rate corridor.

ii) Marginal lending rate: this is a provider of overnight

liquidity to the banking system. As this interest rate

represents the ceiling of the interest rate corridor, it is

not very beneficial for banks to call credit through this

channel. Thus, the use of this facility to apply for

46 EONIA: Euro OverNight Index Average.

Page 88: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

85

liquidity may show significant failures within the

interbank and financial system.

iii) The deposit facility rate: this is a standing facility

(window) on which banks can hold overnight deposits

within the Eurosystem. As it represents the floor of the

interest rate corridor, it is never convenient for banks to

hold their excess liquidity through this facility. Excess

liquidity can be more rewarded in the interbank market,

through the EONIA rate. Thus, the unconventional use

of this window (as we state previously for the marginal

lending facility) is a signal of the failure within the

financial system.

Conversely, the EONIA rate is the weighted average of the overnight

rates on the lending operations within the interbank market. The major

banks provide liquidity to themselves through deposit and lending

behaviour at the EONIA rate (or at the EURIBOR rate for funding at

longer maturity). It fluctuates around the refinancing rate set by the

ECB. The spread between the EONIA and the interest rate policy can

be a significant indicator of the existent pressure and uncertainty within

the banking system (Linzer and Schmidt, 2008) and may thus predict

financial turmoil (Soares, 2011).

Page 89: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

86

The graph shows us the interest rate policy undertaken by the ECB from

January 1999 to June 2014. The current rates47 are the following: a

refinancing rate of 0.05%, a marginal lending rate of 0.30% and a deposit

facility rate of -0.20%.

The ECB has implemented the so-called interest rate lower bound policy

in order to conduct a monetary policy accommodation (Woodford,

2012). Moreover, it set the negative rate for the deposit facility, stating

that a cash hoarding behaviour through the facilities provided by the

ECB is not in line with the ECB’s transmission mechanism scheme.

Thus, if the banking system prefers to deposit excess liquidity at their

central bank’s accounts instead of providing loans through the interbank

market (at the EONIA or EURIBOR interest rates), they will be

penalized by this choice.

Some reasons of this unconventional choice are provided by the ECB

itself. The above-mentioned path of the interest rates has been

influenced by the behaviour of banks which previously anchored their

excess liquidity to the deposit facility previously (ECBa, 2014).

The negative interest rate has been chosen to sustain growth in the Euro

zone and thus to “ensure price stability over the medium term” (ECBb, 2014).

47 ECB, [online] accessed on the 09.12.2014 at <https://www.ecb.europa.eu/stats/monetary/rates/html/index.en.html>

Page 90: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

87

As stated by the ECB itself, commercial banks which hold excess

liquidity and are not willing to lend to other commercial banks have two

different options: to hold liquidity at their own central bank account or

to hold it as cash. Both these strategies are not costless as for the former,

commercial banks have to pay an interest rate on the deposit window

(reward rate at -0.10%) and for the latter method they have to find a safe

storage for banknotes. In both cases, additional costs are the inflation as

well as the opportunity costs (ECBb, 2014).

Moreover, this interest rate policy has been implemented in order to

facilitate the substitution between the Eurosystem’s refinancing

operations to the interbank funding. As the official interest rates affect

all the other rates set by banks, a lower bound policy aims to ease and

smooth operations within the private sector.

Page 91: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

88

Fig. 18: Interest rate policy at the ECB (own calculation, Bloomberg dataset)

-1

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

1/3

0/1

99

9

1/3

0/2

00

0

1/3

0/2

00

1

1/3

0/2

00

2

1/3

0/2

00

3

1/3

0/2

00

4

1/3

0/2

00

5

1/3

0/2

00

6

1/3

0/2

00

7

1/3

0/2

00

8

1/3

0/2

00

9

1/3

0/2

01

0

1/3

0/2

01

1

1/3

0/2

01

2

1/3

0/2

01

3

1/3

0/2

01

4

Interest rate policy at the European Central Bank

Refinancing rate Deposit facility rate

Marginal lending rate EONIA

Page 92: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

89

2.4.4 Outright Monetary Transactions

The Outright Monetary Transactions (OMT), as reported by the ECB,

are one of the many measures undertaken to face the European

sovereign and banking crisis. These transactions are governmental

bonds’ purchasing operations, set in the secondary market in favour of

countries which are dealing with liquidity concerns and are willing to

underwrite a severe agreement (i.e. an European Financial Stability

Facility programme previously or an European Stability Mechanism

programme currently) involving not only the ECB and the countries

concerned, but also the International Monetary Fund (IMF).

The main reasons behind the establishment of this measure has been the

safeguard of the monetary policy transmission mechanism, which has

been seriously affected by the tight connection between sovereigns’ and

banks’ balance sheets and the stress occurred in the governmental bonds

and the interest rate requested by the market.

Through these operations, the ECB is allowed to buy governmental

bonds with a maturity reaching from one year up to three years within

the secondary market. This however fosters a large discontent within the

countries worried about the ECB to become a “Lender of Last Resort”48

and to break the rule stated at the Article 123 of the Lisbon Treaty. This

prohibits the ECB to “overdraft facilities or any other type of credit facility” to

48 The Economist, “Not too little, possibly too late”, 2012, accessed on the 08.03.2014 at <http://www.economist.com/blogs/freeexchange/2012/09/ecbs-new-bond-purchase-programme>

Page 93: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

90

any of the European bodies, institutional agencies, central, regional and

local governments.

The instrument has been launched by Mario Draghi with his famous

quote “Within our mandate, the ECB is ready to do whatever it takes to preserve

the euro. And believe me, it will be enough” (Draghi, 2012). These might be

considered as substitutes of the quantitative easing (QE) policy carried

out by almost every other central banks, such as for instance the Federal

Reserve System, the Bank of England and the Bank of Japan, to mention

but a few. However, even though OMTs have no limits beforehand

(ECB, 2013), the parallelism between OMTs and QE might be affected

by the presence of the following criteria which match the above

descripted operations:

i) The strict conditions which the countries need to meet before

receiving the financial assistance;

ii) the liquidity provided through these measures will be fully

sterilised.

However, even though OMTs have been set in order to reduce the

funding costs for central governments, the presence of the agreement

which has to be signed in addition to the assistance request (requiring

fiscal adjustments and austerity programmes within the countries) acts as

Page 94: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

91

an important constraint for the moral hazard consistent with this type of

tool.

But precisely because of these facts, such operations might not support

the countries which are facing troubles in a considerable manner.

Moreover, the application made by one country for the OMTs impacts

severely the chance to get any funds from the private capital market (El-

Erian, 2012), making it even more difficult for governments to request

financial assistance or in any case, making the countries consider this

opportunity too late (Ip, 2012).

Page 95: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

92

2.5 The European Stability Mechanism

In order to resolve the debt crisis which has been threatening for long

the Euro zone and to restore the financial stability within the banking

sector, the European legislator decided to turn the temporary bail-out

European Financial Stability Facility (EFSF) fund into the permanent

rescue European Stability Mechanism (ESM). The latter became

effective on October 201249.

The procedure has been created by the Euro zone member countries, in

line with the decisions made within the Ecofin Council which established

the EFSF. Since the ESM is an intergovernmental institution, the main

decision-making body within the ESM is the board of governors, which

is composed by the Ministers of Finance of every member country50.

This bailout mechanism has been created because of the political

willingness to lower the interest rates some member countries were

required to pay and to end the sovereign debt crisis (Gocaj and Meunier,

2013). Another key reason has been the need to assure the financial

stability. This stability has been threatened since the banking system has

been required to recapitalise the balance sheets and to prevent losses or

limitations within the private market due to the vicious cycle between

49 <http://www.efsf.europa.eu/about/index.htm>. 50 For the current group: <http://www.esm.europa.eu/about/governance/board-of-governors/index.htm>.

Page 96: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

93

sovereigns’ debt and banks’ portfolios (Gros, 2011). The impact of an

eventual sovereign insolvency on the banking system has been defined as

the main channel of contagion within the financial system (Micossi,

Carmassi and Peirce, 2011). Through the above mentioned fund the

European Union is allowed to underwrite sovereign debt from the

primary and the secondary market.

In order to require financial assistance through the ESM, however, the

countries are required to sign a Memorandum of Understanding (MoU),

which usually includes a set of fiscal adjustments and economic reforms

set to lower government debt. This agreement also involves the

instalment of the so-called Troika, namely, the European Central Bank

(ECB), the European Commission (EC) and the International Monetary

Fund (IMF). The balance between the moral hazard prevention and the

effectiveness of the above described measure is however not clear cut.

Many economists had opposing views about the austerity implications

which are outlined by this mechanism (Krugman, 2012) and the fact that

a call for assistance will probably end access to the private market of the

not performing member states51. This nevertheless seriously affects the

willingness and the timing of the member countries’ call.

Another limitation of this mechanism has been found in the limited

resources that the fund carries. This constitutes a big constraint on the

51 The Economist, “Not too little, possibly too late”, 2012, accessed on the 08.03.2014 at <http://www.economist.com/blogs/freeexchange/2012/09/ecbs-new-bond-purchase-programme>.

Page 97: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

94

effectiveness of the measure and does not assure the credibility in the

market (De Grauwe, 2013). For this reason, the limitless OMTs are

regarded to be more robust measures to tackle the crisis than the ESM

financial assistance against the crisis. OMTs are very likely to gain

credibility within the market due to this “no limits beforehand” condition.

In order to set the differences between ESM and OMT, we could state

that the major one is that through the former the EU can legally buy

government bonds at the debt issuance whereas through the latter the

ECB can purchase government bonds only on the secondary market. In

addition, it is also important to mention that the institutions in charge of

carrying out these operations are different. Again, this constitutes the

basis for the wall which arose between the central governments and the

ECB.

Despite the fact, that many consider that through OMTs operations the

ECB would became a de facto Lender of Last Resort (De Grauwe, 2013),

not allowing the ECB to buy sovereign bonds at issuance, limits its

capability to act as such a lender for the government bonds’ market

(Bagehot, 1873).

The wide range of the previously outlined measures which have been set

up for the purpose of prompting the financial stability constitutes a

Page 98: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

95

proof of the willingness of the ECB to “preserve the euro, whatever it takes”

(Draghi, 2012). The difficulties arise mostly whenever the member

countries struggle and deal with dissimilar economic situations. In an

attempt to combat this issue, the European Banking Union – whose aim

is it to set common rules, common rescue plans and a common deposit

guarantee scheme in the banking system – constitutes a huge step

forward (ECB, 2014). The final chapter will be entirely dedicated to this

challenge.

Page 99: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

96

3. The Banking Union as a regulatory response to

the financial crisis and expected outcomes in

the monetary system

3.1 An overview of the new regulatory framework

The European Banking Union has been defined an outstanding project by

the European Commission (EC, 2012), whose aim is it to establish a

Banking Union within the EMU and strengthen prudential ratios (by

increasing the amount and the quality of capital) of the credit

institutions. It will be established within the those eighteen countries

which currently are in the third stage of the EMU and set the possibility

for the ECB to widen this supervisory role to countries, which demand

to join on it. It has been defined a mammoth project by Buch (Buch,

2014) as the new regulatory framework has been implemented with an

incredible speed.

In a speech given in February 2014, Mario Draghi emphasized the

important positive consequences, which the project is most likely to

induce. According to the ECB Chairman, the main advantage of the

EBU will be the reduction of the financial fragmentation. Furthermore,

he remarked that financial integration is crucial for an effective monetary

union as well as that “we can see the importance of financial integration all the

more in its absence” (Draghi, 2014).

Page 100: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

97

The financial integration can result in the following positive outcomes:

i) Increased portfolio diversification: whenever banks and

investors become more diversified across the countries,

they reduce the risk to incur in domestic shocks.

Lowering this risk exposure can be reflected in

increasing income and consumption risk sharing

(Demyanyk, Ostergaard and Bent, 2008). Diversification

might also increase risks of contagion. The ECB

supervision however will have a strong control over

those risks. A diversified portfolio across the countries

will also be crucial to the achievement of one of the

major goals proposed by the European Commission. To

be more precise, it will help to break the vicious circle

between banks and sovereigns (EC, 2014).

ii) Increased capital allocation efficiency: large cross –

border banks under the same supervision, resolution

and deposit guarantee mechanisms are likely to allocate

and channel capital and guide credit to the most

efficient firms, regardless of the countries in which

companies are settled. Whenever this works, the project

will likely lead to a substantial reduction of the

mispricing of investment risk (Giannetti and Ongena,

2009). However we should also mention that whenever

Page 101: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

98

the project will not achieve the goal stated above, credit

and market risks will not be reduced but simply spread

among European banks52.

iii) Economic growth: Funds would be allocated to the

most efficient and competitive firms, even if established

in less developed regions of Europe. In this sense,

financial integration will head to a better overall

economic performance.

iv) Market scale and bank size: last but not least, the

fundamental advantage of the single market is to make

the market larger and thus firms bigger to allow them to

exploit increased returns to scale. To compete in the

global financial arena, EU needs global banks, and a way

to get this result is to offer to the existing national banks

a larger integrated single market to reach the desired

scale. Unfortunately, we discovered that banks’ bigness

is a danger as banks can become “too big to fail” and

thus must be helped by taxpayers. Latest studies

however illustrate that the major risk described in the

quote “too big to fail” should be switched to “too

interconnected to fail” (Sordi and Vercelli, 2012).

52 For instance, with cross – border integration, German (foreign) banks are substituted for Italian ones. Thus, credit and market risks are not reduced but simply spread out among Italian and German banks. In 2012, risk perception increased and German banks quickly dumped the Italian sovereign bonds they had. This nevertheless worsened the crisis and was exactly what short sellers had planned and wished. The opinion is shared, inter alia, by Alan Blinder on his “After the music stopped: The financial crisis, the response, and the work ahead”, The Penguin Press (2013), p. 420.

Page 102: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

99

On the other hand however, financial integration, might also have some

negative drawbacks. Indeed, issues may arise due to the asymmetric

information that could trigger excessive cross-border risk-taking behaviour

for banks. In addition, another crucial question in a more integrated

financial world will be the assessment of the contagion risk (Draghi, 2014).

In light of the previously mentioned pitfalls however, it is important to

mention that although before the crisis erupted some were believing that

expected benefits of increased financial integration could offset expected

costs (e.g. Fecht, Grüner and Hartmann, 2007), the view is currently

under debate, to say the least. In 2008, the global, interconnected and

complex contemporary financial system has discovered to be very fragile.

In fig. 1, the cross – border interbank lending behaviour across banks set

in the Euro area has been outlined. After reaching a peak on the first and

second quarter of 2008, the trend has been reversed and started to

decrease in August 2008. The European Banking Union, as has been

argued by Mario Draghi in the speech given in February 2014, aims to

establish a sound financial integration across the countries, which will

generate the above-mentioned benefits.

Page 103: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

100

Fig. 19: Cross - border interbank lending in the Euro area (own calculation, SDW dataset)

0

500,000

1,000,000

1,500,000

2,000,000

2,500,0009

/1/1

99

7

7/1

/19

98

5/1

/19

99

3/1

/20

00

1/1

/20

01

11

/1/2

00

1

9/1

/20

02

7/1

/20

03

5/1

/20

04

3/1

/20

05

1/1

/20

06

11

/1/2

00

6

9/1

/20

07

7/1

/20

08

5/1

/20

09

3/1

/20

10

1/1

/20

11

11

/1/2

01

1

9/1

/20

12

7/1

/20

13

5/1

/20

14

To

tal a

mo

un

t

Cross - border interbank lending in the Euro area

Page 104: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

101

3.2 Banking Union and financial stability

Standardizing the supervision, resolution and guarantee schemes should

help the European Union to achieve the goal stated by the European

Commission, namely reestablishment of financial stability within the

Euro area (EC, 2014). The main supporting argument is that the new

regulatory framework will help to break the vicious circle, described in

Chapter 2. The main reasons outlined by the Commission why precisely

the EBU will be able to restore financial stability by breaking the

negative links between banks and sovereigns are the following:

i) Stronger banks will be more immune to shocks: in order

to face risks, the common supervision will enforce

banks to hold capital and liquidity requirements more

effectively (as Basel III will be implemented and

supervision will be given to the ECB).

ii) Bank resolution will minimize the intervention of

taxpayer money: the resolution of a bank will be funded

by a scheme bailing-in shareholders and creditors first.

Banks should thus not be resolved through public

finances. We will discuss this on the special section

dedicated to the SRM.

Page 105: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

102

iii) Banks will no longer be “European in life, but national

in death”: the new regulatory framework, through the

implementation of the SRM and the Common Deposit

Guarantee Scheme, will dramatically change this current

approach. Any failure and the corresponding procedure

will be managed at a European level.

In the next section we will expand this point issues stated by the

European Commission by considering the Financial Trilemma outlined

by Schoenmaker. Furthermore, the following section will also include a

report on Minsky’s financial instability hypothesis.

Page 106: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

103

3.3 The Financial Trilemma

An academic foundation for the financial stability matter can be found in

the “Triangle of incompatibility” built up by Schoenmarker (2005) and

Thygesen (2003). Financial stability can be described as a public good: it

is clearly a non-excludable and non-rival good (Schoenmarker, 2011). It

is a public good because nobody can be excluded from the consumption

and the benefits of it (1) and the consumption of one person does not

affect an others’ consumption (2). They argue that a single government

no longer can deliver stability within a global interconnected financial

world. They came up with the Financial Trilemma theory, which states that

the following three objectives are incompatible. In order to achieve two

of them, the regulator thus has to sacrifice one for the sake of the others

(Avgouleas and Arner, 2013). The trilemma, which replicates the old

Mundellian open economy’s trilemma, is so defined in fig. 2.

Fig. 20: The Financial Trilemma (Schoenmaker, 2011)

Page 107: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

104

The triangle of incompatibility states that financial stability and financial

integration cannot be pursued simultaneously while maintaining a

national financial regulation. These three objectives are incompatible. Fig

1 already demonstrated that cross – border lending has decreased from

2008, leading to increased financial fragmentation under a national

regulation policy.

Financial stability has been defined by Schoenmaker as taking into

account the externalities a bank failure could provoke. The author

pointed out that the national governments will not be affected by

negative externalities caused by a failure of an international bank.

Moreover, national governments will be focusing exclusively on

domestic effects. The territorial jurisdiction cannot provide

comprehensive solutions within an international integrated financial

contest. Additional difficulties might still arise whenever the failing bank

is too large to be saved by a single nation.

Explaining the trilemma with a mathematical game, Schoenmaker argues

that countries will arrive at a noncooperative Nash equilibrium

(Schoenmaker, 2013), characterized by a situation in which the single

nation will not contribute to the recapitalization the failing international

bank. This results holds even though cooperation is made more efficient

and coherent with public policy goals. Setting the banks under the same

regulatory framework and taking policy decisions at the European level

Page 108: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

105

will likely make integration and stability more compatible pursuits, not

only enable the achievement of financial stability but also of financial

integration.

The Banking Union is a step towards the issue of financial instability

raising from the interaction of debt and confidence remains. The

problem was investigated by Minsky since the 1970s. Within the

economic system there are three types of borrowers: hedge, speculative

and Ponzi firms (Minsky, 1992). These three types of finance units

borrow money from banks and markets.

According to the theory, stability is destabilizing as protracted stability

turns euphoria, soon or later. An euphoric lending environment reaches

a peak after which the excessive debt built up by firms will negatively

feed back on trust. The mechanism can be described as follows:

Fig. 21: The instability mechanism (own figure, according to Minsky's theory)

Leverage Confidence Credit Income Interest

rates

Page 109: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

106

Confidence can be described as the key variable in this framework.

Whenever there is a lack of confidence, credit expansion and leverage

will stop. This in turn, will negatively affect investments, which are

closely related to the production and income of firms. The interest rate

(r) will rise, which leads banks to ask an higher price for the attribution

of loans (Ps). Meanwhile, the price that banks are willing to pay (the price

that thus reflects the expected value of the future profits) in order to

increase the production will drop (Pd). The increase of r will furthermore

depress credit and investments even more. After having reached this

critical point, the negative feed-back will trigger an insolvency crisis for

firms, which will negatively affect the banks’ balance sheets.

According to Minsky’s theory, there will never be a steady equilibrium.

The irrational exuberance or animal spirits (Akerlof and Shiller, 2009) will

create a system on which phases of growth and downturns alternate

within the economic cycles.

This is the reason why creating a common banking regulatory framework

and allowing the European Central Bank to oversee the entire system

could likely decrease instability among a more integrated, complex and

dangerous environment.

Page 110: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

107

The Princeton’s Professor Alan Blinder recently humorously wrote that

“self-regulations in financial markets is an oxymoron, maybe even a cruel deception.

We need a real regulation, zookeepers watching over the animals” (Blinder, 2013:

434). In this sense, the European Central Bank, through the adoption of

the single rulebook (that will provide common prudential rules for banks

and will force them in implementing the capital requirements stated on

Basel III) might have an impact on the adverse effects of the bankers’

behavior with respect to over-lending (Goldsmith and Darity, 1992).

Page 111: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

108

3.4 The Single Rulebook

The European Banking Union relies on the Single Rulebook, a common

regulatory patchwork for the banking sector. The Rulebook aims to

implement the prudential capital ratios set in Basel III53. Within the

European Union, the European Commission chose to develop the

regulatory framework through a Directive and a Regulation. Each tool

differs from the other through the law’s implementation process. As is

well known, a EU regulation is a binding legislative act (EU, 2014), while

a directive sets the common goals but leaves countries the possibility of

freely choosing the implementation processes most suitable for them.

Through the implementation of a common capital adequate ratio, the

Single Rulebook aims to close the existing regulatory loopholes (EC,

2013), which pose regulatory arbitrage risks. Furthermore it will restrict

the possibility of gold-plating, a phenomenon which occurs within the

EU whenever a national government exceeds the terms of

implementation of a EU directive in order to achieve competitive

advantages (OECD, 2010). Common banking rules will be set through

the Capital Requirements Regulation (CRR) and the Capital

Requirements Directive (CRD IV). These two will transpose Basel III

into the European law.

53 BIS, [online], 2013, accessed on the 09.15.2014 at <http://www.bis.org/bcbs/basel3.htm>

Page 112: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

109

Little operational space however will be left to individual countries. To

be more precise, Member countries will only retain the chance to set

higher capital ratios in order to face unsynchronized or idiosyncratic

economic and fiscal shocks most effectively. Some useful flexibility while

ensuring the maintenance of a minimum level of regulatory capital will

be thus allowed (EBA, 2014). Stricter requirements however need to be

justified by national circumstances and must contribute to financial

stability with respect to the country’s or the bank’s balance sheet (EC,

2013).

The goals outlined by Basel III which have been incorporated in the

EBU regulation aim at making banks stronger (EC, 2013). This will be

obtained through:

1) an increase in the quality and quantity of the capital: in

order to be able to absorb losses during stress times, capital

needs to be adequate with respect to the both above

mentioned characteristics;

2) a balanced liquidity: new rules and ratios need to be

implemented in order to facilitate bankers to face cash flow

mismatches and to guarantee the market that they will have

Page 113: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

110

enough cash (or liquidity reserves) to meet creditors’

withdrawals54;

3) a leverage backstop: as already been reported in relation to

the Minsky’s theory, leverage can not only reinforce the

economic cycle but even induce financial instability.

Common rules will set prudential limits on the growth of

the banks’ balance sheets compared to own funds;

4) capital requirements for counterparty risk;

5) capital buffers.

Furthermore, CRD IV will also have an impact on supervisory reviews,

disclosures as well as large exposure limits. Despite the fact that solvency

ratios have strengthened since 2010 (Quignon, 2013), the

implementation of Basel III will reinforce the prudential ratios and create

higher quality as well as safer aggregates.

As the Single Rulebook will be applicable for all financial institutions

covered by the Single Market, the common regulatory framework is

likely to provide an harmonized prudential regulation across countries.

This in turn will foster the achievement of the financial integration

(Draghi, 2014).

54 as is well known that a Bagehot lender is not currently made available to European banks.

Page 114: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

111

3.5 Three pillars approach

The European Banking Union can be considered a mechanism based on

the following three strategic pillars: Single Supervisory Mechanism,

Single Resolution Mechanism and a Common System of Deposit

Protection (Cœuré, 2013). The Single Rulebook containing the Capital

Requirements Regulation (CRR), the Capital Requirements Directive

(CRD IV), the Bank Recovery and Resolution Directive (BRRD) and the

common Deposit Guarantee Scheme (DGSD), will ensure the

implementation of all three pillars of the strategy as well as a consistent

and efficient supervision of all banks. The following sections will be

dedicated to describe the building blocks in greater detail, whereas the

last section will be focused on a critical discussion of the advantages and

disadvantages, setting a balance on the new common regulatory

framework.

Page 115: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

112

3.5.1 The Single Supervisory Mechanism

The Single Supervisory Mechanism constitutes the first pillar of the

Banking Union (Cœuré, 2013). The role of the regulator will be

attributed to the European Central Bank, which will thus be responsible

for both the financial stability as well as the maintenance of the

soundness of the financial system within the Euro area. Supervision roles

will in consequence be upgraded to a centralized level and therefore the

regulation will be shifted over from National Central Banks (NCBs) to

the ECB. Supervision encounters a lot of functions and, according to the

literature, the ECB will be entrusted of the following functions (Recine,

2013):

i) Authorization and withdrawal of authorizations of

credit institutions;

ii) Assessment of applications for mergers and

acquisitions;

iii) Assessment of qualified holdings;

iv) Ensuring the compliance to prudential ratios and the

adequacy of capital;

v) Supervisory reviews on single banks;

vi) Consolidated supervision of banks;

In order to be able to assess the soundness of a credit institution, the

ECB will furthermore carry out tasks such as investigation and on-site

Page 116: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

113

inspection conductions, sanction applications, early intervention tools

applications, to mention but a few (Recine, 2013).

It is important to underline that not all the European banks will be under

the SSM, creating a risk of a two-tier system. As a matter of fact National

Central Banks will retain the supervisory role for banks which do not

pose systemic problems within the Euro area (Pisani-Ferry and Wolff,

2012). According to the criteria stated in Article 6(4) of the SSM

regulation (ECB, 2013), the banks that will be subjected of the ECB’s

supervision need to meet one of the following three features:

Total assets exceeding €30 billion or – unless the value of

total assets is below €5 billion – exceeding the 20% of its

national GDP;

Being one of the three largest banks within the member

state concerned;

Requesting or granting financial assistance from EFSF or

ESM.

Whenever a financial institution accomplish to one of these criteria, it is

clarified “significant” (Deutsche Bank, 2013). Around 130 banks will be

directly supervised from the ECB, leaving to the national supervisors

approximately 6.000 smaller banks. However, the significant banks will

account for almost the 85% of the aggregate bank assets within the Euro

area (Maldonado, 2014).

Page 117: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

114

It has been argued that leaving a considerable number of institutions to

the national authorities might pose a risk of a two-tier banking system

creation (Speyer, 2013). In order to be able to cope with the potential

issues raised by such a two-tier system, the ECB retains the ability to

directly supervise any “non-significant” banks whenever justified by the

retention of financial stability. Furthermore, the ECB, on its own

initiative, can classify a cross-border institution as significant even if it

does not meet the above mentioned criteria (Deutsche Bank, 2013).

Moreover, EU members which are not part of the EMU can join the

SSM through a close supervisory cooperation (EC, 2013).

Maldonado argued that a two-tier approach to supervision has both

practical and political reasons (Maldonado, 2014). Firstly, it has been

unmanageable for the ECB to handle all EMU banks in such an

extraordinary speed at which the Banking Union project is carried out.

This can be defined as a timing issue. Secondly, national authorities have

acquired extensive qualified supervision skills, which assure an efficient

performance of the supervisory task. Thirdly, some countries actually

prefer to retain the supervision of the so-called “non-significant” banks.

This statement is based on the assumption that smaller banks do not

pose systemic risks. This assumption however strongly depends on the

bank’s portfolio and can ultimately turn out to be incorrect.

Page 118: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

115

Recine (2013) nonetheless argued that, as the ECB will issue regulations,

guidelines and instructions to the NCBs – and furthermore could

exercise direct supervision of any bank by its own initiative – that cannot

be classified as a two-tier system. The supervision furthermore is based

on an unique approach, although with different degrees of centralization

(Maldonado, 2014). As authorities will be different, even if under the

same common rules, we cannot know whether the same common rules

will be inclusive enough in order to create a single system.

At this stage, the comprehensive assessment reports a list of the

European significant banks (ECB, 2013)55 that will be placed under the

ECB’s supervision. We report below the list of Italian banks that meet

the above mentioned criteria:

55 For further information see ECB [online], 2013, “Note – comprehensive assessment October 2013”, accessed on the 09.12.2014 at <https://www.ecb.europa.eu/pub/pdf/other/notecomprehensiveassessment201310en.pdf>.

Page 119: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

116

Italy

Banca Carige S.P.A. – Cassa di Risparmio di Genova e Imperia

Banca Monte dei Paschi di Siena S.p.A.

Banca Piccolo Credito Valtellinese, Società Cooperativa

Banca Popolare Dell'Emilia Romagna – Società Cooperativa

Banca Popolare Di Milano – Società Cooperativa A Responsabilità Limitata

Banca Popolare di Sondrio, Società Cooperativa per Azioni

Banca Popolare di Vicenza – Società Cooperativa per Azioni

Banco Popolare – Società Cooperativa

Credito Emiliano S.p.A.

Iccrea Holding S.p.A

Intesa Sanpaolo S.p.A.

Mediobanca – Banca di Credito Finanziario S.p.A.

UniCredit S.p.A.

Unione Di Banche Italiane Società Cooperativa Per Azioni

Veneto Banca S.C.P.A.

Fig. 22: Italian banks under the SSM (own figure according to ECB 2013)

Page 120: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

117

3.5.2 The Single Resolution Mechanism

The Single Resolution Mechanism (SRM) constitutes the second pillar of

the Banking Union (Barbagallo, 2014). It is the logical complement to

the SSM (Speyer, 2013): whenever the SSR fail to prevent banks’ failures,

the SRM has to take place. The Single Resolution Board will be entrusted

of being the decision-making body of the recovery rather than the

resolution of a bank that is failing or likely to fail (EC, 2014).

The independent EU agency delegated for the resolution mechanism will

be the European Resolution Authority. This EU agency will work in

close cooperation with its national “sisters”. In order to comprehend the

resolution regime that will be operational within the Banking Union, the

SRM constitutes just one part of the resolution method thought to fit the

European framework. In addition to the SRM, the Bank Recovery and

Resolution Directive provides arrangements about the resolution

funding. Nonetheless the proceedings a bank needs to fulfil (Speyer,

2013) when facing financial trouble are still not clear-cut.

Even though there is still a bit of uncertainty about the final resolution

scheme, guidelines have been shared and the SRM constitutes a big step

forward regarding the achievement of an increased financial integration.

This is especially true if we consider that some countries within the EU

did not even have explicit bank resolution arrangements prior to this

Page 121: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

118

mechanism (Pisani-Ferri, Wolff, 2012). Thus, according to the Financial

Trilemma theory, the SRM will help to define European decision-bodies

as well as responsibilities and in case of cross-border banks’ failures

(Schoenmaker, 2013). In fact the current regulatory framework is not apt

to handle the complexity of the financial system as we see it now

(Avgouleas and Arner, 2013). What is more, it has been argued that

“without a strong SRM complementing the SSM, the credibility and effectiveness of

the Banking Union would be jeopardized” (IMF, 2013).

Let us now imagine two different situations: (1) a recovery and (2) a

resolution, both faced by the Single Resolution Board.

1) Recovery: in order to go through this path, the concerned bank

must be (i) systematically relevant and (ii) have exhausted all the

other disposable financial tools. In particular it has to implement

firstly a bail-in strategy and secondly request financial support to

national mechanisms (Avgouleas and Arner, 2013). The ESM,

through the provision of financial assistance to countries on

which are based failing banks, can play a non-negligible role at this

stage56. Furthermore, it has been discussed if the ESM should be

entrusted of the direct recapitalization of the banks within the

Euro area (Véron, 2014). This proposal has however been seen as

a kind of mutualization of banks’ crisis and Members will not

56 However, we mentioned previously some critics about this tool.

Page 122: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

119

consider this event seriously unless the SSR will be established

and effective. In the case of a recovery, if all other funding

methods are exhausted, the SRM will be composed of the Single

Resolution Fund (SRF), which will have a €55 billion capability.

The amount will be formed through the imposition of a levy on

those credit institutions referred to by the SSR (Wolfers, Glos and

Raffan, 2014). The fund is predicted to reach its final volume in a

8 years time-horizon. Moreover, the fund will have to reach at

least 1% of the deposits of all the banks concerned.

2) Resolution: the Single Resolution Board can request a resolution

planning for all the banks under the SSM.

As has been outlined previously, the decision is solely based on the

systematic importance of the bank. In addition, the Single Resolution

Board is able to call banks for organizational changes and exposures’

reductions. In any case, financial support will not be given to ailing

banks (Speyer, 2013), and under Bagehot’s Dictum of 1873, the

European tools will take place only in case of liquidity crisis (Quignon,

2012).

The Bank Recovery and Resolution Directive need is the backbone of

the Single Resolution Mechanism (Wolfers, Glos and Raffan, 2014). The

Page 123: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

120

Directive has been approved on April 2014 and sets common rules for

all the 28 EU Members. It contains the common guidelines each EU

bank has to follow in terms of resolution procedures, financial

restructuring, bail-in tools, to mention but a few. It furthermore

comprehends arrangements for dealing with a failing bank, whenever the

failure is supposed to be critical at a national level or at a cross-border

level (EC, 2014). The Directive relies on a network of national

authorities and resolution funds, which can act as groups in case of

necessity. This chance has however been seen as a “won’t” by the some

economists (Speyer, 2013). Moreover the BRRD sets rules which aim to

keep the financial responsibilities of a bank failure at a national level,

involving firstly national funds, shareholders, creditors and depositors

(considering the amounts > €100.000) to resolve the bank.

There are numerous arrangements, which can help in managing a bank

crisis. To be more precise, the BRRD sets the following tools in order to

deal with a bank crisis (Avgouleas and Arner, 2013):

1) the sale of business: selling the bank or part of the failing

bank without having the shareholders’ approval;

2) the bridge bank constitution: identifying good assets and

the essential part of the bank and constituting the new bank

(the bridge – ); afterwards the bridge bank will be sold to

Page 124: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

121

another different entity and the ruins of it will be liquidated

under the normal insolvency regime;

3) the separation of the assets: dividing good from bad (toxic)

assets and transformation of the latter into asset

management vehicles; this tool thus is able to relieve the

bank’s balance sheet;

4) the bail-in: recapitalizing the bank through shareholders

and creditors values.

The main tool is the so called “bail-in” tool. Through this one the bank

is allowed to (i) wipe out or dilute shareholders’ stocks or (ii) reduce

claims or convert debt into equity for creditors. Furthermore, the bail-in

tool will involve depositors for those amounts exceeding the €100.000

threshold for insured deposits. This could significantly affect:

the cost of funding: as the bail-in tools become likely to be

implemented once the bank is facing problems, funding

cost for the bank should arise (Speyer, 2013) in order to

compensate the risk for investors to be involved in this

tool;

the inclination of depositors: as depositors will be part of

the bail-in procedure to resolve the bank, the rule could

Page 125: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

122

impair the willingness to hold cash as deposits. The money

multiplier could in consequence drop even more after the

Banking Union will be effective.

The presence of a clear “cascade of liabilities” could however, act

conversely to these costs. In fact, the reduction of uncertainty might

lower the risk premia requested by investors. The following figure (fig. 6)

illustrates the different procedures which have taken place during the

financial crisis in the absence of a common resolution scheme:

Spain Ireland Cyprus

Equity X X X

Hybrids /

preferred stock

X

Subordinated debt X X X

Senior debt X

Uninsured deposits X

Insured deposits

Fig. 23: Bail-in in different resolution procedures (own figure according to Speyer 2013)

The European Commission and the EU Council will be responsible for

the final decision regarding the recovery rather than the resolution of the

concerned bank, meaning that political issues will be included on the

final decision as a matter of facts. Whereas the Single Resolution Board

will be responsible of the resolution process of banks supervised by the

Page 126: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

123

ECB and of cross-border groups, national resolution authorities will

have the responsibilities for those which are not entitled as “significant”

(EC, 2014).

The Single Resolution Board, the competent resolution authority for all

the credit institutions within the SSM framework (Micossi, Bruzzone and

Carmassi, 2013) will be nevertheless composed differently in case of

plenary or an execution meeting. In the latter case, thus on a crisis time

frame, the board will be composed by the executive director, the vice

executive director and four members entitled by the Council on a

Commission’s proposal. The members will represent the Member state

concerned by a particular resolution decision (EC Council, 2013),

meaning that even though the resolution decision is shifted at a

European level, national reasons will not be left out from the decision.

In light of the above reported information, fig. 6 represents the Single

Resolution Mechanism.

Page 127: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

124

Fig. 24: The Single Resolution Mechanism (own figure according to European Commission

2014)

Bank crisis

Single Resolution

Mechanism (Board)

European Commission

EU Council

Single Supervisory

Mechanism (ECB)

Recovery Resolution

Bank

National Resolution

Authorities

Page 128: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

125

3.5.3 The Common Deposit Guarantee Scheme

The Common Deposit Guarantee Scheme traces its origins back to the

first process of harmonization in 1994 under the EU Directive

94/19/EC (IMF, 2013). The Deposit Guarantee Scheme however has

been significantly improved in 2010, when, due to the effects of the US

financial crisis, the Scheme provided a minimum level of harmonization

within the EMU Member States. In fact, at the end of 2010 the coverage

has been raised to €100.000 per depositor per bank and a maximum payout

period has been set to 20 working days (IMF, 2013).

Before the harmonization was implemented in 2010, the coverage

diverged significantly across the countries (Ehrmann, Gambacorta and

Martinez, 2001). In 2000 for instance the deposit guarantee was

established at:

€15.000 in Portugal;

€20.000 in Spain, Greece, Ireland, Austria, Netherland and

Belgium;

€25.000 in Finland;

€76.000 in France;

€103.000 in Italy;

Practically complete in Germany.

Page 129: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

126

Within the EU only two countries did not guarantee deposits, in two

different cases: Iceland broke the promises on insured deposits whereas

Cyprus imposed losses on uninsured deposits (Demirgüç-Kunt, Kane

and Laeven, 2014).

Then existing differences of insurance furthered cross-country capital

flows during stress periods for banks or sovereigns, as the national

deposits funds benefit from at least an implicit government guarantee

(Quignon, 2013). This mechanism thus highlighted even more the

negative loop between banks and sovereigns, which the Banking Union

aims to break. In the presence of regulatory arbitrage possibilities, the

differences in guaranteed amounts provoked severe capital flights from

countries with lower DGS levels to those with upper levels.

By insuring deposits, the legislator aims to reduce bank runs as well as to

spur trust and confidence across the system, in order to reduce the

likelihood of the former. The DGS thus intends “to protect depositors against

the unavailability of their deposits”, which could be the unlucky and the

inevitable consequence of a bank’s failure or a systemic crisis (Chesini

and Giaretta, 2014).

Page 130: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

127

Establishing a Common Deposit Guarantee Scheme, within the Banking

Union framework, will help in assuring people that “a euro in a bank

deposit in one banking union Member State is just as good as a euro in a bank

deposit in another banking union Member State” (Huertas, 2013), which

probably is not commonly believed. The pan-European scheme of

common insurance however will operate once the national funds have

been used up (Quignon, 2013). As a consequence, the insurance will

remain largely at a national level.

The credit institutions within the Banking Union framework with respect

to their risk profiles will fund the Common DGS. The scheme directs as

a goal the guarantee of repayments of the deposits in the event of an

insolvency crisis of a bank based on each Member country. The

proposed scheme should significantly reduce any taxpayers’ contribution

in case of a bank failure (D’Addio et al., 2014). The latest developments

of the DGS are illustrated on fig. 7.

While the Common DGS should be seen as one of the main features of

the European Banking Union, a clear priority has nevertheless been

given to the SSR and the SRM (IMF, 2013). Even though some

countries are strictly opposed to the Common DGS, some economists

argued that the pan-European fund should have been established before

the SSR and the SRM. If the implementation will take too long, diverging

the time horizons of the other two pillars, the effectiveness of the

Page 131: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

128

Banking Union could be significantly affected (Schoenmaker, 2013).

Whether implemented efficiently, the scheme will nonetheless enhance

the depositors’ level of insurance and act to foster the financial stability

within the Euro area.

Fig. 25: Deposits Guarantee Scheme process (own figure according to European Union, 2013)

Deposits Guarantee Scheme

Process of harmonization

2009:

Protection up to € 50.000

2010:

Protection up to € 100.000

2015 (expected):

Common "Deposit Guarantee Scheme Directive" in force

Page 132: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

129

3.6 Advantages, disadvantages and risks

The European Banking Union aims to further financial integration and

financial stability within the Euro area and break the vicious cycle

between banks and sovereigns (EC, 2014). If we should set a balance

regarding the goals pursued by the ECB under the governance of Mario

Draghi and by the EC, then:

setting common rules through the Single Rulebook,

directly supervising significant banks through the SSR,

establishing a common regime for the management of a bank crisis

through the SRM,

laying the foundations for a pan-European DGS,

the regulatory draft goes in the right direction in order to reach the goals

stated above.

The Single Rulebook, by establishing common rules for all the credit

institutions57 will limit the regulatory arbitrages that threatened the

financial integration. All banks will be forced to operate under the Basel

III prudential ratios and the CRD IV, which will strengthen capital

requirements aiming to prompt the financial stability within the

economy. As banks can approve loans whenever they hold enough

capital to face the risks they are assuming with them, capital

57 which will be implemented even though the bank is not under the ECB’s supervision.

Page 133: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

130

requirements have a limiting capping regulatory impact on the money

creation process. The twist is supposed to be positive, and even if an

higher capital obviously allows a proportional and potential higher

amount of loans, ceteris paribus, the new requirements should avoid the

cases of excessive credit creation seen in the past. Implementing both

CRD IV and CRR means that quite a few banks need to recapitalize

themselves in order to accomplish the common prudential law.

Furthermore, imposing common ratios might help in equalizing the

money creation process and reducing the financial fragmentation. Italian

banks however are moving towards the future prudential requirements.

Figure 1 shows this exactly. The Common Equity Tier 1 of the banks

increased significantly from 2010 (Banca d’Italia, 2013).

Dec 2010 June 2011 Dec 2011 June 2012 ∆

(from Dec 2010

to June 2012)

5 major banks 51.0 63.7 71.2 83.3 63%

Others 11.0 12.2 12.3 14.2 29%

TOTAL 62.1 75.9 83.5 97.5 57%

Fig. 26: Common Equity Tier 1 of Italian banks, in bn (own figure according to Banca d'Italia 2013)

Italian banks are clearly enhancing their solvency profile in order to

operate under Basel III requirements. However it seems significant the

difference between behavior of the 5 major Italian banks and the others.

Even though it appears that Italian banks increased their capital buffers

Page 134: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

131

(Banca d’Italia, 2013), the European framework is not yet levelled and

harmonized.

In this sub-chapter we will show some graphs which will prove that

(IMF, 2013) and highlight significant differences regarding the Financial

Soundness Indicators (FSIs) between Member countries. Before that, we

need nevertheless to define prudential ratios outlined by the BIS and

state the capital requirements that banks need to accomplish with.

Let us clarify what counts as capital for Basel III Regulation, thus for the

CRD IV and the CRR of the European law. The regulatory capital is

composed by the algebraic sum of (BIS, 2011):

1) Tier 1 Capital (which in turn is made by the Common Equity Tier

1 and the Additional Tier 1);

2) Tier 2 Capital.

The BIS has defined clearly the above mentioned capital requirements in

its “Basel III: A global regulatory framework for more resilient banks and banking

systems”, revised in June 2011. According to that, the following figure

illustrates the different components (BIS, 2011). Other criteria have to

be met and they will be considered below.

Page 135: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

132

Fig. 27: Regulatory capital scheme (own figure according to BIS 2011)

The Common Equity Tier 1 is the sum of the following elements (BIS,

2011):

Common shares issued by the bank that meet the criteria for

classification as common shares for regulatory purposes (or the

equivalent for non-joint stock companies);

Stock surplus (share premium) resulting from the issue of

instruments included Common Equity Tier 1;

Retained earnings;

Accumulated other comprehensive income and other disclosed

reserves;

Common shares issued by consolidated subsidiaries of the bank and

held by third parties (i.e. minority interest) that meet the criteria for

inclusion in Common Equity Tier 1 capital;

Regulatory adjustments applied in the calculation of Common

Equity Tier 1.

Regulatory Capital

Tier 1 Capital

Common Equity Tier 1

Additional Tier 1

Tier 2 Capital

Page 136: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

133

The qualitative criteria that instruments need to meet in order to

be qualified as Common Equity Tier 1 are reported on the CRR

(EU, 2013). To be more precise, instruments in CET 1 need to be:

a) Issued directly by the institution;

b) Paid up and their purchase is not funded by the institution itself;

c) Classified as equity under accounting standards;

d) Clearly and separately disclosed on the balance sheet;

e) Perpetual;

f) Principal not to be repaid except in cases of liquidation or reduction of

capital (consent of authority require);

g) No incentive to be repaid or reduced except in liquidation;

h) Distributions only from distributable items and with no restrictions or

preferential rights, non-payment is not event of default;

i) Instruments absorb the first a proportionately greatest share of losses;

j) Instruments rank below all other claims;

k) Not secured or guaranteed;

l) No arrangements that enhance seniority;

m) Special regulations for the instruments issued by mutual, cooperative

societies and similar institution.

(Regulation EU No 575/2013 of the European Parliament and

of the Council of 26 June 2013 on prudential requirements for

credit institutions and investment firms)

The Additional Tier 1 is therefore composed by (BIS, 2011):

Page 137: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

134

Instruments issued by the bank that meet the criteria for inclusion

in Additional Tier 1 capital (and are not included in Common

Equity Tier 1);

Stock surplus (share premium) resulting from the issue of

instruments included in Additional Tier 1 capital;

Instruments issued by consolidated subsidiaries of the bank and

held by third parties that meet the criteria for inclusion in

Additional Tier 1 capital and are not included in Common

Equity Tier 1;

Regulatory adjustments applied in the calculation of Additional

Tier 1 Capital.

The qualitative criteria that instruments need to meet in order to

be qualified as Additional Tier 1 are reported on the CRR (EU,

2013). To be more precise, instruments need to be:

a) Issued and paid up;

b) Not purchased by subsidiaries or participations > 20%;

c) Purchase of instruments not funded by the institution;

d) Rank below Tier 2 instruments in the event of insolvency;

e) Not secured or guaranteed;

f) No arrangements that enhance seniority;

g) Perpetual and no incentive to redeem;

h) Options only to be exercised at the sole discretion of the issuer;

i) Callable, redeemed or repurchased > 5 years after issuance;

Page 138: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

135

j) No indication that the authority would consent to a request to call,

redeem or repurchase;

k) Distributed only out of distributable items and with no restrictions,

cancellation of distributions does not constitute an event of default;

l) No considered as liabilities under a test of insolvency;

m) Written down or converted to CET upon the occurrence of a trigger

event;

n) No feature to hinder the recapitalization of the institution;

o) Where the instruments are not issued directly by an institution, the

proceeds are immediately available to the institution without limitation.

(Regulation EU No 575/2013 of the European Parliament and

of the Council of 26 June 2013 on prudential requirements for

credit institutions and investment firms)

Whereas the Tier 2 Capital is the sum of the following elements (BIS,

2011):

Instruments and subordinated loans issued by the bank that meet the

criteria for inclusion in Tier 2 capital (and are not included in Tier 1

capital);

Stock surplus (share premium) resulting from the issue of instruments

included in Tier 2 capital;

Page 139: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

136

Instruments issued by consolidated subsidiaries of the bank and held

by third parties that meet the criteria for inclusion in Tier 2 capital

and are not included in Tier 1 capital;

Certain loan loss provisions as specified in Basel regulation;

Regulatory adjustments applied in the calculation of Tier 2 Capital.

Also in the Tier 2 Capital, instruments need to meet several criteria. We

report them as follows (EU, 2013):

a) Issued and paid up;

b) Not purchased by subsidiaries or participations > 20%,

c) No direct or indirect funding by the institution;

d) Totally subordinated to claims of all non-subordinated creditors;

e) No secured or covered by guarantees of the issuer;

f) No enhancement of seniority of the claim;

g) Minimum maturity of five years;

h) No incentive to redeem;

i) Call options only to be exercised at the sole discretion of the issuer;

j) Callable after a minimum of five years (conditions apply);

k) No indication for early repurchase;

l) No rights for the investor to accelerate the repayment;

m) No credit sensitive dividend feature;

n) Where the instruments are not issued directly by the institution, the proceeds

are immediately available to the institution without limitation.

Page 140: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

137

(Regulation EU No 575/2013 of the European Parliament and of the

Council of 26 June 2013 on prudential requirements for credit

institutions and investment firms)

The above reported criteria will make the banks stronger as the different

types of capital will increase in quality. Furthermore, new and higher

capital requirements will be compulsory for banks. According to Basel

III regulation (BIS, 2010), the minimum prudential ratios will increase:

from 2% to 4.5% for the Common Equity Tier 1 / RWAs;

from 4% to 6% for the Tier 1 Capital / RWAs.

The Regulatory Capital to RWAs conversely remains steady at 8%, this

however need to be complied at all times. All these ratios nevertheless

will rise even further because a “capital conservation buffer” of 2.5% of

RWAs will be introduced in addition to the CET 1 requirement in order

to enable the bank to absorb losses at any time, especially in stressed

periods. Prudential ratios thus, considering the above mentioned buffer,

will increase up to 7%, 8.5% and 10.5%, respectively.

Page 141: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

138

Moreover, a countercyclical capital buffer can be set by each Member State in

order to achieve the broader macro-prudential goal and thus to face the

boom-bust evolution in the credit growth which threats the financial

stability (IMF, 2011). Basel III allows nations to establish a ratio which

ranges between 0% and 2.5%. In order to accomplish its function, the

countercyclical capital buffer will be gathered during periods of credit

growth whereas will be released during periods of economic downturns.

Average current prudential ratios in the different countries are ordered in

fig. 28. Even though countries are far above the minimum requirements

to face unexpected decreases in the quality of their assets, there are large

differences not only across countries but also across banks.

Page 142: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

139

Fig. 28: Regulatory capital to Risk-Weighted Assets within the EU (own calculation, IMF dataset)

A very important, although only potential, implication for the money

creation process and monetary policy is discernible in the adoption of

the new higher and uniform capital requirements. By ensuring

compliance with capital requirements and giving the supervision to the

ECB throughout the Single Supervisory Mechanism might provide to

help the central bank in having a more effective direct supervision on the

money creation process, which is always endogenous in the banking

system as a whole.

19.2 18.5 18.1 18.1 18.0 17.7 17.3 17.0 17.0

16.4 16.3 16.0 15.7 15.7 15.4 15.1 14.9 14.8

13.7 13.3 13.3 12.3 1

5.6

16

.9

14

.8 16

.5

15

.8

15

.8

13

.7

16

.5

16

.0

14

.1

14

.5

15

.2

15

.5

14

.2

13

.4

14

.2

11

.1

14

.1

10

.6

11

.9

11

.9

11

.1

0

5

10

15

20

25

%

Regulatory capital to Risk-Weighted Assets (RWAs)

Regulatory Capital to Risk-Weighted Assets

Regulatory Tier 1 Capital to Risk-Weighted Assets

Page 143: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

140

Thus, monitoring the quantitative requirements (ECB, 2014), the ECB

has the chance to set higher prudential ratios in singular cases and thus

to adopt the above mentioned requirements to the risk profile of the

credit institution (Quignon, 2012). This gives nevertheless the

opportunity to the ECB to oversee the lending behavior of banks

effectively. As banks can extend credit only if they have enough capital

to face the risks, by holding an information advantage regarding the

regulatory capital the ECB has in a much clearer view and control about

the money process within the Euro area. The following figure illustrates

the ratio between the Regulatory Tier 1 Capital and the Regulatory

Capital.

Page 144: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

141

Fig. 29: Tier 1 Capital to Regulatory Capital (own calculation, IMF dataset)

Although Tier 2 Capital could be at maximum equal to the Tier 1 Capital

in order to compose the Capital ratio required, the regulatory capital has

been made up differently within the countries. Most of them hold almost

(or above) the 90% of Tier 1 Capital in their Regulatory Capital, whereas

Hungary, Germany, Netherlands and Italy detain the lower ratios.

According to the graph, Italian banks compose their Regulatory Capital

with the lowest ratio of Tier 1 Capital, accounting for just the 77%.

It is a little surprising that Greece, which has a decent regulatory capital

on RWAs (fig. 27), holds the highest ratio (99%). We need nonetheless

to mention that even if Hungary, Germany, Netherlands and Italy hold

99% 97% 95% 95% 94% 94% 92% 91% 90% 90% 89% 89% 89% 89% 88% 87% 86% 82% 81% 80%

77%

0%

10%

20%

30%

40%

50%

60%

70%

80%

90%

100%

Tier 1 Capital to Regulatory Capital

Tier 1 Capital to Regulatory Capital

Page 145: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

142

the lower percentages, the former three retain their Regulatory Capital

far above the minimum required, whereas Italy holds the lower Tier 1

Capital to RWAs within the countries (10.6%) and a total Regulatory

Capital to RWAs of just 13.7%.

Another key indicator comes from the dataset made available by the

World Bank58. It reports the Bank capital to assets ratio (%) for every

country in the world. The ratio does not account for any prudential

requirement, but it is nonetheless interesting as it gives a precise

information on the relation between the total bank capital59 (comprising

the Regulatory Capital, thus Tier 1 and Tier 2 Capitals) and the total

assets, including all financial and nonfinancial assets.

Figure 29 illustrates the Bank capital to assets ratios. The graph shows

that Netherlands, Finland, Italy, Germany and France are holding the

lower coefficients. However, we cannot state whether this is due to the

liability or to the asset side, or to both of them. In any case, assets in fig.

29 are not risk-weighted. Thus, the context on which Germany and Italy

are holding the same Bank capital to assets ratio, both 5.5%, whereas

diverging in terms of Regulatory capital ratio, 19.2% for the former and

13.7% for the latter, might be for the weights that characterize the

58 The World Bank, [online] accessed on the 30.09.2014 at <http://data.worldbank.org/indicator/FB.BNK.CAPA.ZS/countries/DE-LU-LV-BE-NL?display=graph>. 59 “Capital and reserves include funds contributed by owners, retained earnings, general and special reserves, provisions, and valuation adjustments” (The World Bank).

Page 146: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

143

different types of assets which in turn rely on risks and losses the bank

should face.

* Slovenia has not been reported as data for the latest years were not available.

Fig. 30: Bank capital to assets ratio (own calculation, The World Bank dataset)

0.0

2.0

4.0

6.0

8.0

10.0

12.0

14.0

2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013

Bank capital to total assets ratio in the Euro area

Austria

Belgium

Cyprus

Estonia

Finland

France

Germany

Greece

Ireland

Italy

Latvia

Luxembourg

Malta

Netherlands

Portugal

Slovakia

Spain

Page 147: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

144

The previous graphs show that even though Italian banks – mostly the

main 5 – are moving and increasing their capitals towards the new

standards stated on Basel III and thus rising the eligibility of the

Common Equity Tier 1 instruments (Banca d’Italia, 2013), prudential

ratios are still in a relatively lower rank compared to the others. Since

throughout the Single Supervisory Mechanism the ECB will be entrusted

of the supervisory role of the so-called significant banks, the European

Banking Union could thus modify this situation. In the following figure

we report the key prudential ratios referring to 63 Italian banks, which

are on the move from 2007 (IMF, 2013)60:

Financial Soundness Indicators for 63 Italian banks

2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013

Capital ratio 9.8 10.4 11.6 12.1 12.7 13.4 13.7*

Tier 1 ratio 6.8 7 8.3 8.7 9.5 10.5 10.6*

Core Tier 1 ratio 6.3 6.3 7.4 7.5 8.7 10 **

* The ratios have been taken from another dataset (IMF) in order to give an indication regarding the prudential ratios in 2013. They are not referred to the above mentioned 63 banks;

** Aggregate data missing.

Fig. 31: Financial Soundness Indicators (own figure according to IMF 2013)

60 IMF, 2013, “Italy – a Technical Note on Stress Testing The Banking Sector”, [online] accessed on the 30.09.2014 at <http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/scr/2013/cr13349.pdf>.

Page 148: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

145

Through the SSM the ECB will have the direct supervision on 130

European banks, accounting for about the 85% of banks’ total assets.

This will reduce significantly the so-called “supervisory home bias” by

reducing the incentive that currently exists for a national central bank to

be lenient with national banks out of national concerns (Deutsche

Bundesbank, 2013). This in line could result in an enhanced financial

integration as banks will operate under a common regulatory framework

and then will be supervised by the same over-national-interests

institution. Prompting the financial integration might furthermore

positively affect cross-border transactions, which have experienced a

significant drop after the crisis in 2008.

Another advantage comes out from the “Triangle of incompatibility” already

discussed. Thygesen and Schoenmaker basically assume that financial

integration and financial stability are impossible in the existing

decentralized supervisory approach (Thygesen, 2003). Empirical studies

in USA (Aggraval et al., 2012) furthermore shows that the greater

proximity between supervisors and the supervised make the former less

alert (Quignon, 2012). In this sense, the European Banking Union aims

at increasing stability by creating a more effective supervision within the

banking system.

The legal basis of the Single Supervisory Mechanism have been often

debated. In fact, the mechanism has been established within the scope of

Page 149: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

146

the Art. 127 TFUE which states that the Council can “confer specific tasks

upon the European Central Bank concerning policies relating to the prudential

supervision of credit institutions and other financial institutions with the exception of

insurance undertakings” (Art. 127 (6), TFUE). Entrusting the ECB for the

supervisory role is thus in line with the above mentioned Article which

gives the Eurosystem the responsibility to “the smooth conduct of policies

pursued by the competent authorities relating to the prudential supervision of credit

institutions and the stability of the financial system” (Art. 127 (5), TFUE). The

legal foundations however have been criticized because of the restricted

coverage stated in the above mentioned Article.

Concerns furthermore have been expressed about the fact that the ECB

is going to add banking supervision to monetary policy conduction. It

has also been argued the context in which a rise in interest rates would

be suitable for the achievement of the price stability but might bring

some banks to failures as they cannot afford the interest rate required for

further liquidity61 (Quignon, 2013).

There might be thus a conflict of interests between the two function

attributed to the ECB. The supervision however has been designed to be

independent from the monetary policy conduction, with the creation of

distinct administrative divisions and structures that will carry out the new

task (EC, 2012). The legal basis of the European Banking Union

61 risks of failure would increase after an hypothetical CB’s rate hike.

Page 150: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

147

nevertheless make clear that the primary goal for the ECB is price

stability. Every further objective, even though stated on the TFUE, is

supposed to be subordinated to the achievement of the primary goal,

although we have tried to argue that by reducing fragmentation, the

ECD could improve its management of liquidity. Indeed it would be

inappropriate to subordinate price stability common good to the interest

of any single national “too big to fail” bank shareholders’ interests.

If the new regulatory framework will be able to foster the soundness of

the banking system creating a more effective transmission mechanism of

the monetary policy, the Banking Union will have a positive impact on

the monetary policy conduction. The ECB could thus benefit from the

information advantage regarding its new role of Supervisor. This

furthermore will allow the ECB to improve its supervision on the money

creation process , which will always rely on commercial banks’ lending

decisions. Monitoring from a vantage point of view gives the ECB

invaluable insights regarding the monetary policy actions that are

required to be implemented and supposed to fit better the European

framework.

Page 151: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

148

Conclusion

This work aimed at guessing whether the supervisory project proposed

by the European Commission in 2012 – the European Banking Union –

and the Single Supervisory Mechanism agreed in March 2014 could

improve the monetary policy conduction within the Euro area. The

current monetary fragmentation, i.e. structural differences in the

excess/rationing of credit in the Member countries, demonstrates that

some space for improvement certainly exists. To prove this, we started

recalling how money is endogenously created by the banking systems

within the Euro area and how the public by tuning cash reserve ratios

modulate the multiplier and the demand for monetary base. The money

multiplier has fluctuated between 13.16 in 2002 and 5.5 in 2012 in

relation to wildly different situations such as lack of confidence, liquidity

shortage, excess liquidity, inflation or deflation expectations, exchange

instability, non-conventional monetary policies, to mention but a few.

We conducted an analysis on the latest measures undertaken by the ECB

in order to face the crisis arose in 2009 within the EMU III area. What is

more, we reported some evidence regarding its expansionary measures

(an extraordinary increase on the monetary base) which however did not

resolve in an increase of the money stock. Indeed, it is well known that

the ECB has not been able to keep the stock of money (M3) sufficiently

Page 152: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

149

close to the target rate of 4.5%, neither in the aggregate Monetary Union

nor in the single Members countries.

We moreover analysed the weapons developed by the ECB to face the

crisis and divided the different tools into two sections: in the first section

we described instruments which are likely to tackle governmental issues

whereas in the second section we focused more on tools which are likely

to affect the banking system. We described and reported empirical data

related to: Long – Term Refinancing Operations, Outright Monetary

Transactions which all increase the size of the CB’s balance sheet, and

the interest rate policy likely to affect the banking system. We defined

furthermore the European Stability Mechanism, established by the

European Council, supposed to increase funding possibilities for the

Member countries.

Completing the extraordinary aid framework provided by the ECB, in

Chapter 3 we focused on the European Banking Union project which will

be established within the eighteen countries which are currently in EMU

III. The European Banking Union will entrust the ECB of the

supervision of 130 so-called significant credit institutions which will

account for approximately 85% of the total assets within the Euro area.

The chapter regarding this “mammoth project” has been developed

considering a “three pillars approach” based on the Single Rulebook. The

Single Supervisory Mechanism, the Single Resolution Mechanism and

Page 153: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

150

the Common Deposits Guarantee Scheme constitute the three different

pillars.

These pillars are intended to: (i) foster financial stability ensuring the

soundness of the banking system, (ii) restore financial integration after

having experienced a significant drop after 2008 and (iii) break the

vicious circle between sovereigns and banks; but we argued that by

forcing the implementation of prudential rules stated on Basel III they

perhaps could bear upon the money creation process positively. By

reducing differences across countries, centralized regulation could

hopefully stem excesses or deficiencies on the credit creation.

Regarding the goals stated by the European Commission and the

Chairman of the ECB, financial integration has been argued through the

cross-border interbank lending whereas financial stability has been

debated through the Financial Trilemma developed by Schoenmaker

(2005) and Thygesen (2003) keeping in mind the lectures made by

Minsky about the intrinsic presence of financial instability within the

economy, indagated by himself since the 1970s.

Creating a common banking regulatory framework and allowing the

European Central Bank to oversee the entire system could likely

decrease the intrinsic instability in a more integrated and complex

Page 154: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

151

environment. In this sense the European Central Bank, through the

adoption of the Single Rulebook (providing thus the common prudential

rules stated on Basel III and implementing the capital requirements

throughout the CRD IV and the CRR) might have an impact on the

adverse effects of the bankers’ behaviour with respect to over-lending.

The leverage of firms indeed significantly affect the confidence. The

latter acts as the key variable in the boom-bust evolution of the credit

growth.

After having discussed critically the Single Supervisory Mechanism, the

Single Resolution Mechanism and the Common Deposits Guarantee

Scheme we focused on the section which will likely affect the monetary

policy conduction: the Single Supervisory Mechanism. We reported

furthermore the new rules and capital ratios stated on Basel III. By

monitoring the prudential requirements, the ECB has the chance to set

higher capital ratios in singular cases and thus adopt them to the risk

profile of the credit institution. This gives nevertheless the opportunity

to the ECB to affect the lending behaviour of banks. As banks can

extend credit only if they have enough capital to face the risks, holding

the information advantage regarding the regulatory capital might confer the

ECB in a much clearer view about the money process within the EMU

III area.

Page 155: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

152

In conclusion, the money creation process relies on “the stroke of bankers’

pens when they approve loans” (BoE, 2014). Inside money, described in the first

Chapter, is created by the banking system and this has been the reason

why the stock of money significantly differed within the Member

countries. The chief Economics commentator at the Financial Time has

forcefully argued in his recent work (Martin Wolf (2014), The shifts and the

shocks – What we have learned and have still to learn from the financial crisis,

Penguin Books, London) that instead of adding macro prudential

policies to the traditional policies aimed at price stability a radical reform

is needed. His proposal is really radical and certainly hard to swallow for

bankers. Hyman Minsky could have subscribed it, I believe.

“A system that is based, as today, on the ability of profit-seeking institutions to create

money as a byproduct of often grotesquely irresponsible lending is irretrievable

unstable.” (Wolf, 2014: 350)

His recipe clashes with the one used by the European Union. As bankers

have understood that their debts are senior vis-à-vis public debt, money

creation should no longer be left to irresponsible bankers (and tax-payers

should not be asked to foot the outcome of such exuberant lending

behaviour).

Page 156: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

153

In my opinion, the money creation process is mostly affected by: (i) the

profitability pursued by the bank in approving the loans, (ii) the money

multiplier which in turn relies on the confidence within the banking

system and the perceived conditions about the soundness of it (it

nevertheless drops after a bank run) and (iii) the regulatory framework.

In order to be more precise, we stated above that banks can approve

loans only if they hold enough capital to face risks and potential losses

arising with them. Setting common rules and higher capital requirements

(through the CRD IV and the CRR) and giving the ECB the chance to

set higher capital ratios (only if that is required to the achievement of the

financial stability goal) could thus have an impact on a variable which

can likely affect the lending behaviour of banks.

If the new regulatory framework will be able to foster the soundness of

the banking system creating a more effective transmission mechanism of

the monetary policy, the European Banking Union will have a specific

impact on the monetary policy conduction. The ECB could thus benefit

from the information advantage regarding its new role of Supervisor.

This furthermore will allow the ECB to improve its supervision on the

money creation process, which relies on commercial banks’ lending

decisions. Monitoring from a vantage point of view gives the ECB

invaluable insights regarding the monetary policy actions that are

required to be implemented and supposed to fit better the European

framework.

Page 157: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

154

Page 158: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

155

Bibliography

[1] Agarwal, S. et al. (2012), Inconsistent Regulators: Evidence from Banking, National

Bureau of Economic Research, No. 17736, January 2012.

[2] Akerlof, G., & Shiller, R. (2009), Animal Spirits: How Human Psychology Drives

the Economy, and Why It Matters for Global Capitalism, Princeton University

Press.

[3] Alchian, A. A. and Klein, B. (1973), On a Correct Measure of Inflation, Journal of

Money, Credit and Banking, Vol. 5 No. 1, pp. 173-191.

[4] Avgouleas, E. and Arner, D. (2013), The Eurozone Debt Crisis and the European

Banking Union: A Cautionary Tale of Failure and Reform, University of Hong

Kong, Faculty of Law, Research Paper No. 2013/037.

[5] Bagehot, W. (1873), Lombard Street: a description of the Money Market, Reprinted

by Project Gutenberg.

[6] Baglioni, A. (2013), Il mito dei tassi BCE negativi, [online], Lavoce.info.

<http://www.lavoce.info/il-mito-dei-tassi-bce-negativi/>

[7] Banca d’Italia (2014), Supplementi al Bollettino Statistico. Indicatori monetari e

finanziari – Moneta e Banche, Banca d’Italia, No. 35, 8 Luglio 2014.

[8] Bank of England (1987), Measures of broad money, Bank of England Quarterly

Bulletin, pp. 212-219.

[9] Bank of England (2014), Quarterly Bulletin, Volume 54 No. 1, Bank of

England Quarterly Bulletin.

[10] Bank of International Settlements (2000), Principles for the Management of Credit

Risk, Basel Committee on Banking Supervision.

[11] Bank of International Settlement (2011), Basel III: A global regulatory framework

for more resilient banks and banking systems, Basel, June 2011.

Page 159: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

156

[12] Bank of International Settlements (2012a), International banking and financial

market developments, BIS Quarterly Review, March 2012.

[13] Bank of International Settlement (2012b), The policy implications of transmission

channels between the financial system and the real economy, BIS Working Paper No.

20, May 2012.

[14] Bank of International Settlement (2013), Basel III: The Liquidity Coverage Ratio

and liquidity risk monitoring tools, Basel, January 2013.

[15] Banque de France (2008), Financial Stability Review – Special Issue on Liquidity,

Banque de France, Financial Stability Review No. 11, February 2008.

[16] Barbagallo, C. (2014a), L’Unione Bancaria Europea, Intervento alla New

International Finance Association, “Verso l’Europa Unita. Gli obiettivi

raggiunti, gli ostacoli da superare, le nuove sfide”, 6 Maggio 2014.

[17] Barbagallo, C. (2014b), Le banche italiane e la Vigilanza nella prospettiva dell’Unione

Bancaria, Intervento all’Associazione Bancaria Italiana, “Basilea 3 – Risk and

Supervision 2014”, Rome, 16 June 2014

[18] Barro, R. J. and Gordon, R. (1983), A Positive Theory of Monetary Policy in a

Natural Rate Model, Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 91, pp. 589-610.

[19] Beck, G. and Wienland, V. (2008), Central Bank Misperceptions and the Role of

Money in Interest Rate Rule, European Central Bank, ECB Working Paper No.

967, November 2008.

[20] Biffis, P. (2009), Analisi del Merito di Credito, EIF-e.Book, Venezia.

[21] Biffis, P. (2011), Il Settore Bancario, IV edizione, EIF-e.Book, Venezia.

[22] Blanchard, O., Giavazzi, F. and Amighini, A. (2011), Macroeconomics: A

European Perspective, I edition, Financial Times/ Prentice Hall.

[23] Blinder, A. (2013), After the music stopped: The financial crisis, the response, and the

work ahead, The Penguin Press.

Page 160: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

157

[24] Borio, C. and Drehmann, M. (2009), Assessing the risk of banking crises – revisited,

BIS Quarterly Review, March 2009.

[25] Borio, C. and Zhu, H. (2008), Capital Regulation, risk-taking and monetary policy: a

missing link in the transmission mechanism?, BIS Working Paper No. 268,

December 2008.

[26] Bradford Delong, J. and Sims, C. A. (1999), Should We Fear Deflation?,

Brookings Institution Press, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Vol.

1999 No. 1, pp. 225-252.

[27] Breuss, F. (2013), European Banking Union, Österreichisches Institut für

Wirtschaftsforschung, WIFO Working Paper No. 454, September 2013.

[28] Buch, C. (2014), The banking union - setting the course for better integrated and more

stable financial markets in Europe?, BIS central bankers’ speeches, 19th

Handelsblatt Annual Conference, London, 4 September 2014.

[29] Cannata, F. et al. (2013), Looking ahead to Basel 3: Italian banks on the move,

Banca d’Italia Occasional Papers, No. 157, April 2013.

[30] Cecchetti, S. G. et al. (2000), Asset Prices and Central Bank Policy, International

Centre for Monetary and Banking Studies, addressed at the conference

“Central Banks and Assets Prices” held in Geneva, 5 May 2000.

[31] Cecchetti, S. G. (2006), Money, Banking and Financial Markets, McGraw-

Hill/Irwin.

[32] Chesini, G. and Giarretta, E. (2014), Towards a Pan European Deposit Guarantee

Scheme. How bank riskiness is relevant in the scheme?, University of Verona,

Department of Business Administration.

[33] Churchill, W. (1946), Speech to the academic youth at the University of Zurich, 19

September 1946, available at:

< http://europa.eu/about-eu/eu-history/founding-

fathers/pdf/winston_churchill_en.pdf>

Page 161: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

158

[34] Cœuré, B. (2013), The Single Resolution Mechanism: Why it is needed, speech at the

ICMA Annual General Meeting and Conference 2013, Copenhagen, 23 May

2013.

[35] D’Addio, E. et al. (2014), The Banking Union, Università degli Studi Roma Tre.

[36] De Cecco, M. (1984), International Economic Adjustment: Small Countries and the

European Monetary System, Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 22 No. 2, pp.

615-616

[37] De Grauwe, P. (2000), Economics of Monetary Union, IX edition, Oxford

University Press (2012).

[38] De Grauwe, P. (2011a), The Governance of a fragile Eurozone, University of

Leuven and CEPS, April 2011.

[39] De Grauwe, P. (2011b), The European Central Bank as a lender of last resort,

[online], Voxeu.org.

< http://www.voxeu.org/article/european-central-bank-lender-last-resort>

[40] De Grauwe, P. (2013), Design Failures in the Eurozone: Can they be fixed?, LSE

‘Europe in Question’ Discussion Paper Series, No. 57, February 2013.

[41] De Polis, S. (2014), Unione Bancaria e gestione delle crisis: un modello di Banca in

trasformazione, Intervento al XII PAN European Banking Meeting, Monza, 3

Ottobre 2014.

[42] Debrun, X. (2001), Bargaining Over EMU vs. EMS: Why Might the ECB Be the

Twin Sister of the Bundesbank?, Economic Journal, Vol. 111 No. 473, pp. 566-

590.

[43] Demirgüç-Kunt, A., Kane, E. and Laeven, L. (2014), Deposit Insurance

Database, IMF Working Paper, No. 14/118.

[44] Demyanyk, Y., Ostergaard, C. and Sorensen, B. (2008), Risk Sharing and

Portfolio Allocation in EMU, European Commission, Directorate General for

Economic and Financial Affairs, Economic Papers, No. 334, July 2008.

Page 162: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

159

[45] Desai, M. (1989), Endogenous and Exogenous Money, The New Palgrave:

Dictionary of Money and Finance.

[46] Deutsche Bank (2012), EU Banking Union: Do it right, not hastily!, in Böttcher,

B. (ed), DB Research, EU Monitor – European Integration, 23 July 2013.

[47] Deutsche Bundesbank (2013), European Single Supervisory Mechanism for Banks –

a first step on the road to a Banking Union, Deutsche Bundesbank Monthly

Report, No. 13, July 2013.

[48] Dominguez, K. M. E. (2006), The European Central Bank, the Euro, and Global

Financial Markets, Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 20 No. 4, pp. 67-

88.

[49] Draghi, M. (2012), [online], speech at the Global Investment Conference in

London, 26 July 2012.

[50] Draghi, M. (2014), [online], Financial Integration and Banking Union, speech for

the 20th anniversary of the establishment of the European Monetary Institute,

Brussels, 12 February 2014.

[51] Ehrmann, M. et al. (2001), Financial Factors and the Role of Banks in monetary

policy transmission in the euro area, ECB Working Paper No. 105.

[52] Eichengreen, B. (1993), European Monetary Unification, Journal of Economic

Literature, Vol. 31 No. 3, pp. 1321-1357

[53] Eichengreen, B. (2012), [online], Europe’s Vicious Spirals, Project Syndacate.

< http://project-syndicate.org/commentary/europe-s-vicious-spirals>

[54] El-Erian, M. A. (2012), [online] The Hazard of Second Best, Project Syndacate.

< http://www.project-syndicate.org/commentary/the-hazard-of-second-

best>

[55] European Banking Authority (2010), The Single Rulebook.

< https://www.eba.europa.eu/regulation-and-policy/single-rulebook>

[56] European Central Bank (2011), The Monetary Policy of the ECB 2011, European

Central Bank, Frankfurt am Main, January 2011.

Page 163: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

160

[57] European Central Bank (2012a), The Implementation of Monetary Policy in the Euro

Area, European Central Bank, Frankfurt am Main, January 2012.

[58] European Central Bank (2012b), Heterogeneity in Euro Area Financial Conditions

and Policy Implications, ECB Monthly Bulletin, Frankfurt am Main, August

2012, pp. 63-75.

[59] European Central Bank (2013a), Target balances and monetary policy operations,

ECB Monthly Bulletin, Frankfurt am Main, May 2013, pp. 103-114.

[60] European Central Bank (2013b), Note comprehensive assessment, October 2013.

[61] European Central Bank (2014a), Progress in the operational implementation of the

Single Supervisory Mechanism Regulation, SSR Quarterly Report, No. 2014/1.

[62] European Central Bank (2014), [online]

<http://www.ecb.europa.eu/stats/money/aggregates/aggr/html/hist.en.ht

ml>

[63] European Central Bank (2014), [online],

<http://www.ecb.europa.eu/mopo/implement/mr/html/calc.en.html>

[64] European Central Bank (2014), [online],

<https://www.ecb.europa.eu/mopo/implement/omo/html/index.en.html>

[65] European Central Bank (2014), [online],

<http://www.ecb.europa.eu/press/pr/date/2011/html/pr111208_1.en.html

>

[66] European Commission (2009), E-Money Directive, 2009/110/EC, Brussels.

[67] European Commission (2012), A Roadmap towards a Banking Union,

COM/2012/0510, Brussels.

[68] European Commission (2013), A comprehensive EU response to the financial crisis:

a strong financial framework for Europe and a banking union for the Eurozone,

MEMO/13/679, Brussels.

Page 164: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

161

[69] European Commission (2014), Banking union: restoring financial stability in the

Eurozone, MEMO/14/294, Brussels.

[70] European Commission (2014), [online]

<http://ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/euro/adoption/who_can_join/indi

i_en.htm>

[71] European Parliament (2013a), Directive 2013/36/EU on access to the activity of

credit institutions and the prudential supervision of credit institutions and investment firms,

European Parliament and European Council, 26 June 2013.

[72] European Parliament (2013b), Regulation (EU) No 575/2013 on prudential

requirements for credit institutions and investment firms, European Parliament and

European Council, 26 June 2013.

[73] Farag, M. (2013), Bank capital and liquidity, Bank of England, BOE Quarterly

Bulletin, Vol. 53 No. 3, 2013.

[74] Fecht, F., Grüner, H. P., and Hartmann, P. (2007), The Welfare Effects of Cross-

Border Financial Integration, CEPR Discussion Paper No. 6311.

[75] Federal Reserve Bank of Boston (1995), Is Bank Lending Important for the

Transmission of Monetary Policy?, in Peek, J. and Rosengren, E. S. (eds), FED

Conference Series No. 39, June 1995.

[76] Federal Reserve bank of Chicago (1953), Two Faces of Debt, Debt – Jeckyl and

Hyde, V edition, Reprint, 1992.

[77] Financial Stability Board (2012), Thematic Review on Deposit Insurance Systems,

Peer Review Report, 8 February 2012.

[78] Fischer, B. et al. (2006), Money and monetary policy: The ECB experience 1999-

2006, European Central Bank, 15 December 2006.

[79] Friedman, M. and Schwartz, A. J. (1963), A Monetary History of the United

States, 1867-1960, Princeton University Press for the NBER.

[80] Friedman, M. and Kenneth N. (1992), Money, Income, Prices and Interest Rates,

American Economic Review, Vol. 82, pp. 472-492.

Page 165: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

162

[81] Gerlach, S. (2004), The Two Pillars of the ECB, Hong Kong Institute for

Monetary Research, University of Basel and CEPR, 39th Panel Meeting of

Economic Policy, Dublin, 16-17 April 2004.

[82] Giannetti, M. et al. (2002), Financial Market Integration, Corporate Financing and

Economic Growth, European Commission, Directorate General for Economic

and Financial Affairs, Economic Papers, No. 179, November 2002.

[83] Giannetti, M. and Ongena, S. (2009), Financial Integration and Firm Performance:

Evidence from Foreign Bank Entry in Emerging Markets, Review of Finance, Vol.

13, pp. 181-223.

[84] Gocaj, L. and Meunier, S. (2013), Time Will Tell: The Efsf, The Esm, And The

Euro Crisis, Journal of European Integration, Vol. 35 No. 3, pp. 239-253.

[85] Goldsmith, A. H. and Darity, W. A. Jr. (1992), Social psychology, unemployment

exposure and equilibrium unemployment, Journal of Economic Psychology,

Elsevier, Vol. 13 No. 3, pp. 449-471.

[86] Goodfriend, M. (2000), Overcoming the Zero Bound on Interest Rate Policy, Journal

of Money, Credit and Banking, Vol. 32, No. 4, Part 2, pp. 1007-1035.

[87] Goodhart, C. A. E. (1994), What should central banks do? What should be their

macroeconomic objectives and operations?, Economic Journal, Vol. 104, pp. 1424-

1436.

[88] Goodhart, C. A. E. (1998), The two concepts of money: implications for the analysis of

optimal currency areas, European Journal of Political Economy, Volume 14, pp.

407-432.

[89] Goodhart, C. A. E. (2001), What Weight Should Be Given to Asset Prices in the

Measurement of Inflation?, Economic Journal, Vol. 111, pp. 335-356

[90] Goodhart, C. A. E. (2008), The Regulatory Response to the Financial Crisis, CESifo

Working Paper Series No. 2257.

[91] Goodhart, C. A. E. (2010), The Changing Role of Central Banks, LSE Financial

Market Group, Special Paper No. 187, December 2010.

Page 166: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

163

[92] Goodhart, C. A. E. (2013a), Powers and scope of the macro-prudential authority,

Edward Elgard Publishing, pp. 29-42.

[93] Goodhart, C. A. E. (2013b), The Potential Instruments of Monetary Policy, Central

Bank Review, Vol. 13 No. 2, May 2013, pp. 1-15.

[94] Goodhart, C. A. E. (2013c), Lessons for Monetary Policy from the Euro Area Crisis,

Special Conference Paper, Bank of Greece, “The crisis in the euro area”, 23-

24 May 2013.

[95] Goodhart, C. A. E. and Schoenmaker, D. (1995), Should the Functions of

Monetary Policy and Banking Supervision be separated?, Oxford Economic Papers,

No. 47, pp. 539-560.

[96] Goodhart, C. A. E. and Schoenmaker, D. (2009), Fiscal Burden Sharing in Cross-

Border Banking Crises, International Journal of Central Banking, March 2009.

[97] Graziani, A. (1994), La Teoria Monetaria della Produzione, Banca Popolare

dell’Etruria e del Lazio, Collana Studi e Ricerche, Arezzo.

[98] Gros, D. and Mayer, T. (2011), What to do when the euro crisis reaches the core,

CEPS Commentary, Brussels, Centre for European Policy Studies.

[99] Guala, F. (2006), Filosofia dell’Economia, Il Mulino, Bologna.

[100] Heffernan, S. (2005), Modern Banking, England, John Wiley and Sons.

[101] Howard, M. (1991), Lessons of history, Yale University Press.

[102] Howells, P. (2007), On some slippery slopes: horizontalists, structuralists and diagrams,

University of the West of England, School of Economics, March 2007.

[103] Howells, P., Bath, K. (1990), Financial Markets and Institutions, V edition,

Reprint, Pearson Education (2007).

[104] Howells, P., Bath, K. (1998), The Economics of Money, Banking and Finance. A

European text, IV edition, Reprint, Pearson Education (2008).

Page 167: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

164

[105] Huertas, T. F. (2013), Banking Union, Banco de España, Revista Estabilidad

Financiera, No. 24, May 2013.

[106] Illes, A. and Lombardi, M. (2013), Interest rate pass-through since the financial crisis,

BIS Quarterly Review, September 2013, pp. 57-66.

[107] International Monetary Fund (2013a), A Banking Union for the Euro Area, IMF

Discussion Note, February 2013.

[108] International Monetary Fund (2013b), European Union: Publication of Financial

Sector Assessment Program Documentation – Technical Note on Deposit Insurance,

Country Report No. 13/66.

[109] International Monetary Fund (2013c), Italy: Financial System Stability Assessment,

IMF Country Report No. 13/300, Washington, September 2013.

[110] International Monetary Fund (2013d), Italy – a Technical Note on Stress Testing

The Banking Sector, IMF Country Report No. 13/349, Washington, December

2013.

[111] International Monetary Fund (2014), [online], Financial Soundness Indicators.

<http://elibrary-data.imf.org/FindDataReports.aspx?d=33061&e=171851>

[112] Ip, G. (2012), Not too little, possible too late, [online], The Economist.

< http://www.economist.com/blogs/freeexchange/2012/09/ecbs-new-

bond-purchase-programme>

[113] Issing, O. (2006), The ECB's Monetary Policy Strategy: Why Did We Choose a Two-

Pillar Approach?, address at the Fourth ECB Central Banking Conference, 9-

10 November 2006.

[114] Kaldor, N. (1982), The Scourge of Monetarism, II edition, Reprint, Oxford

University Press (1986).

[115] Kaldor, N. and Trevithick, J. (1981), A Keynesian perspective on money, Lloyds

Bank Review, No. 1, pp. 1-19.

[116] Kalecki, M. (1944), Professor Pigou on “The Classical Stationary State”. A comment,

The Economic Journal, Vol. 54 No. 213, pp. 131-132.

Page 168: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

165

[117] Kenen, P. (1969), The Theory of Optimum Currency Areas: An Eclectic View, in

Mundell, R. and Swoboda, A. “Monetary Problems of the International

Economy”, University of Chicago Press, pp. 41-60.

[118] Kenen, P. (2007), The Benefits and Risks of Financial Globalization, Cato Journal,

Vol. 27 No. 2, pp. 179-183.

[119] Keynes, J. M. (1930), A treatise on Money, The Collected Writings of J. M. K.,

Vol. 5-6, London, MacMillian, 1971.

[120] Keynes, J. M. (1936), The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money,

London, MacMillian.

[121] King, Mervyn A. (2002), Governor of the Bank of England, No Money, No

Inflation – The Role of Money in the Economy, Bank of England Quarterly

Bulletin, pp. 162-177.

[122] King, Mervyn A. (2011), Governor of the Bank of England, speech on

Quantitative Easing, 25 October 2011.

<http://www.publications.parliament.uk/pa/cm201012/cmselect/cmtreasy

/uc1576-i/uc157601.htm>

[123] Kiyotaki, N. and Wright, R. (1989), On money as a medium of exchange, Journal

of Political Economy, Volume 97 No. 4, pp. 927-954.

[124] Kiyotaki, N. and Wright, R. (1991), A contribution to the Pure Theory of Money,

Journal of Economic Theory, Elsevier, Volume 53 No. 2, pp. 215-235.

[125] Koo, R. (2003), Balance Sheet Recession, John Wiley.

[126] Kopf, C. (2011), Restoring financial stability in the euro area, CEPS Policy Briefs,

No. 237, 15 March 2011.

[127] Krugman, P. (2012a), [online], Revenge of the Optimum Currency Area, NBER

Macroeconomics Annual 2012, pp. 439-448.

< http://krugman.blogs.nytimes.com/2012/06/24/revenge-of-the-

optimum-currency-area/?_php=true&_type=blogs&_r=0>

Page 169: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

166

[128] Krugman, P. (2012b), [online], Europe’s Austerity Madness, NY Times, 27

September 2012.

< http://www.nytimes.com/2012/09/28/opinion/krugman-europes-

austerity-madness.html>

[129] Lagos, R. (2006), Inside and Outside Money, The New Palgrave Dictionary of

Economics, II edition.

[130] Lane, P. R. (2012), The European Sovereign Debt Crisis, The Journal of

Economic Perspectives, Vol. 26 No. 3, pp. 49-67

[131] Lavoie, M. (1984), The Endogenous Flow of Credit and the Post Keynesian Theory of

Money, Journal of Economic Issues, Vol. 18 No. 3, pp. 771-797.

[132] Linzert, T. and Schmidt, S. (2008), What explains the spread between the euro

overnight rate and the ECB’s policy rate?, ECB Working Paper Series, No. 983,

December 2008.

[133] Maldonado, L. (2014), The Banking Union, under way and here to stay, PwC and

IE Business School Centre for the Financial Sector, Madrid, February 2014.

[134] Mancini, M. (2013), Dalla vigilanza nazionale armonizzata alla Banking Union,

Banca d’Italia, Quaderni di Ricerca Giuridica, No. 73, Settembre 2013.

[135] Mayer, T. (1980), David Hume and Monetarism, The Quarterly Journal of

Economics, Oxford University Press, Vol. 95, No. 1 (Aug., 1980), pp. 89-101

[136] McLeay, M., Radia, A. & Thomas, R. (2014), Money creation in the modern

economy, Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin, Volume 54 No. 1, Bank of

England Publications.

[137] Merrick, J. J. and Sauders, A. (1985), Bank Regulation and Monetary Policy,

Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Vol. 17 No. 4, Part 2, pp. 691-717

[138] Mersch, Y. (2013), Towards a European Banking Union, ECB keynote speech at

the Bridge Forum Dialogue, Luxembourg, 30 September 2013.

[139] Meyer, Laurence H. (2001), Does Money Matter?, Federal Reserve Bank of St.

Louis Review.

Page 170: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

167

[140] Micossi, S., Bruzzone, G., and Carmassi, J. (2014), The New European

Framework for Managing Bank Crises, CEPS Policy Briefs, Centre for European

Policy Studies, No. 304, Brussels, November 2013.

[141] Micossi, S., Carmassi, J. and Peirce, F. (2011), On the Tasks of the European

Stability Mechanism, CEPS Policy Briefs, Centre for European Policy Studies

Brussels.

[142] Minsky, H. P. (1975), John Maynard Keynes, New York, Columbia University

Press.

[143] Minsky, H. P. (1986), Stabilizing an Unstable Economy, Washington University,

Economics Department.

[144] Minsky, H. P. (1992), The Financial Instability Hypothesis, The Jerome Levy

Economics Institute Working Paper No. 74. In: Arestis, P., Sawyer, M. and

Elgar, E. (eds), Handbook of Radical Political Economy.

[145] Moore, B. (1988), Horizontalists and Verticalists: the macroeconomics of credit money,

Cambridge University Press.

[146] Moore, B. (1991), Money supply endogeneity: ‘reserve price setting’ or ‘reserve quantity

setting’, Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, Vol 13 No. 3, p. 404-413.

[147] Moore, C. H. and Russell, A. E. (1987), Money. Its Origin, Development and

Modern Use, Carl H. Moore, McFarland, Jefferson.

[148] Mundell, R. A. (1961), A Theory of Optimum Currency Areas, The American

Economic Review, Vol. 51 No. 4, pp. 657-665.

[149] Mundell, R. A. (1963), Inflation and Real Interest, Journal of Political Economy,

University of Chicago Press, Vol. 71 No. 3, pp. 280-283.

[150] Mundell, R. A. (1997), Currency Areas, Common Currencies, and EMU, The

American Economic Review, Vol. 87 No. 2, pp. 214-216.

Page 171: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

168

[151] New Palgrave, The (1989), Money, in Eatwell, J., Milgate, M. and Newman, P.

(eds), MacMillian, London.

[152] O’Rourke, K. and Taylor, A. M. (2013), Cross of Euros, The Journal of

Economic Perspectives, Vol. 27 No. 3, pp. 167-191.

[153] Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (2010), OECD

Economic Surveys: Euro area 2010, OECD Publishing.

[154] Padoa Schioppa, T. (2004), L’euro e la sua Banca Centrale. L’unione dopo l’Unione,

il Mulino, Bologna.

[155] Palley, T. I. (2013), Horizontalists, verticalists, and structuralists: The theory of

endogenous money reassessed, Review of Keynesian Economics, Edward Elgar,

Vol. 1 No. 4, pp. 406-424.

[156] Pisani-Ferri, J. and Wolff, G. B. (2012a), The Fiscal Implications of a Banking

Union, Bruegel Policy Brief, No. 2012/02, Bruegel.

[157] Pisani-Ferri, J. and Wolff, G. B. (2012b), What kind of European Banking

Union?, Bruegel Policy Contribution, No. 2012/12, Bruegel.

[158] Plihon, D. (2013), The Banking Union in the context of the EUcrisis, Paris Nord

University, Euromemo Conference, London, 2013.

[159] Quignon, L. (2012), Why Banking Union is inevitable, BNP Paribas Economic

Research, pp. 5-7.

[160] Quignon, L. (2013), The challenges of Banking Union, BNP Paribas Economic

Research, Conjoncture, pp. 20-34.

[161] Recine, F. (2013), EU Banking Union, European Central Bank, DG Financial

Stability, FinanceMalta 6th Annual Conference, Malta, 26 April 2013.

[162] Rodrik, D. (2000), Institutions for High-Quality Growth: What They are and How to

Acquire Them, NBER Working Paper No. 7540, February 2000.

[163] Rossi, S. (2014), Intervento del Direttore Generale della Banca d’Italia, Verso

l’unione bancaria europea: in fondo a una strada lunga e tortuosa, Università degli

Page 172: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

169

Studi di Modena e Reggio Emilia.

[164] Santos, A. O. and Elliott, D. (2012), Estimating the Costs of Financial Regulation,

IMF Staff Discussion Note, September 2012.

[165] Sapir, A. and Wolff, G. B. (2013), The neglected side of banking union: reshaping

Europe’s financial system, Bruegel Note at the ECOFIN, 14 September 2013,

Vilnius.

[166] Saraceno, P. (1992), L’attività bancaria, Utet, Torino.

[167] Saunders, A. and Cornett, M. (1994), Financial Institutions Management: A Risk

Management Approach, VII edition, Reprint, McGraw-Hill/Irwin (2011).

[168] Schoenmaker, D. (2005), Central banks and financial authorities in Europe: what

prospects?, In: Masciandaro, D. (Ed.), The Handbook of Central Banking and

Financial Authorities in Europe, Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, pp. 398-456.

[169] Schoenmaker, D. (2011), The financial trilemma, Economic Letters, Elsevier,

Vol. 111, pp. 57-59.

[170] Schoenmaker, D. (2013a), An Integrated Financial Framework for the Banking

Union: Don’t Forget Macro-Prudential Supervision, European Commission,

Directorate General for Economic and Financial Affairs, Economic Papers,

No. 495, Brussels, April 2013.

[171] Schoenmaker, D. (2013b), Governance of International Banking. The Financial

Trilemma, Oxford University Press, Oxford.

[172] Schooner, H. M. and Taylor, M. W. (2010), Global Bank Regulation. Principles

and Policies, Elsevier, London.

[173] Shambaugh, J.C. et al. (2012), The Euro’s Three Crises, Brookings Papers on

Economic Activity, Spring 2012, pp. 157-231.

[174] Shuman, R. (1950), The Schuman Declaration, 9 May 1950.

< http://europa.eu/about-eu/basic-information/symbols/europe-

day/schuman-declaration/index_en.htm>

Page 173: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

170

[175] Signorini, L. F. (2012), L’unione bancaria, Audizione del Direttore Generale per

l’Area Vigilanza Bancaria e Finanziaria della Banca d’Italia, Camera dei

Deputati, Rome, 22 November 2012.

[176] Soares, C. and Rodrigues, P. M. M. (2011), Determinants of the EONIA spread

and the financial crisis, Banco de Portugal, Economics and Research

Department, Working Paper No. 12, April 2011.

[177] Solow, Robert M. (1982), On the lender of last resort. In Financial Crises: Theory,

History and Policy, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press

[178] Sordi, S. and Vercelli, A. (2012), Heterogeneous expectations and strong uncertainty in

a Minskyian model of financial fluctuations, Journal of Economic Behavior &

Organization, Elsevier, Vol. 83 No. 3, pp. 544-557.

[179] Speyer, B. (2013), EU Banking Union. Right idea, poor execution, Deutsche Bank

Research, EU Monitor European Integration.

[180] Thornton, H. (1802), An Enquiry Into the Nature And Effects Of The Paper Credit

in Great Britain, Reprinted in Hayek, F. A. (ed), LSE, London, 1939.

[181] Thygesen, N. (2003), Comments on the political economy of financial harmonisation in

Europe. In: Kremers, J., Schoenmaker, D., Wierts, P. (Eds.), Financial

Supervision in Europe, Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, pp. 142-150.

[182] Tobin, J. (1963), Commercial banks as creators of “money”, Cowles Foundation

Discussion Papers No. 159.

[183] Tobin, J. (1969), A General Equilibrium Approach To Monetary Theory, Journal of

Money, Credit and Banking, Vol. 1 No. 1, pp. 15-29.

[184] Tobin, J. (1992), Money, The New Palgrave Dictionary of Money and Finance,

Vol. 2, London, MacMillian.

[185] Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union, consolidated version

(2012), available at < http://eur-lex.europa.eu/legal-

content/EN/TXT/?uri=CELEX:12012E/TXT>

Page 174: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

171

[186] Trichet, J. C. (2010), State of the Union: The Financial Crisis and the ECB’s

Response between 2007 and 2009, Journal of Common Market Studies, JCMS

Vol. 48 Annual Review, pp. 7-19.

[187] Véron, N. (2013), A realistic bridge towards European Banking Union, Bruegel

Policy Contribution, No. 2013/09, Bruegel.

[188] Visco, I. (2011), Key issues for the success of macroprudential policies, BIS Paper No.

60, May 2011.

[189] Wicksell, K. (1906), Lectures on Political Economy – Volume II: Money, Reprint,

Fairfield, Augustus M. Kelley Publishers, 1978.

[190] Wientraub, R. E. (1976), Monetary Aggregates and Monetary Policy, Journal of

Money, Credit and Banking, Vol. 8 No. 3, pp. 401-406.

[191] Wolf, M. (2014), The shifts and the shocks – What we have learned and have still to

learn from the financial crisis, Penguin Books, London.

[192] Wolfers, B., Glos, A. and Raffan, M. (2014), Banking Union – Single Resolution

Mechanism (SRM) and Single Resolution Fund (SRF), Freshfields Bruckhaus

Deringer, May 2014.

[193] Woodford, M. (1996), Control of the Public Debt: a requirement for price stability?,

NBER Working Paper No. 5684, July 1996.

[194] Woodford, M. (2008), How Important is Money in the Conduct of Monetary Policy?,

Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Vol. 40 No. 8, pp. 1561-1598.

[195] Woodford, M. (2012), Methods of Policy Accommodation at the Interest-Rate Lower

Bound, presented at the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Symposium on

“The Changing Policy Landscape”, Jackson Hole, Wyoming, 31 August 2012.

[196] World Bank, The (2014), [online], Bank capital to assets ratio.

< http://data.worldbank.org/indicator/FB.BNK.CAPA.ZS/countries/DE-

LU-LV-BE-NL?display=graph>

[197] Wray, L. R. (1998), Modern Money, The Levy Economics Institute, Working

Paper No. 252.

Page 175: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

172

[198] Wray, L. R. (2007a), A Post-Keynesian View of Central Bank Independence, Policy

Targets, and the Rules-versus-Discretion Debate, Journal of Post Keynesian

Economics, Vol. 30 No. 1, pp. 119-141.

[199] Wray, L. R. (2007b), Endogenous Money: Structuralist and Horizontalist, The Levy

Economics Institute, Working Paper No. 512.

[200] Wyplosz, C. (1997), EMU: Why and How It Might Happen, The Journal of

Economic Perspectives, Vol. 11 No. 4, pp. 3-21.

[201] Yellen, J. L. (2009), A Minsky Meltdown: Lessons for Central Bankers, 18th Annual

Hyman P. Minsky Conference on the State of the U.S. and World

Economies, “Meeting the Challenges of the Financial Crisis”, Levy

Economics Institute of Bard College, 16 April 2009.

Page 176: Monetary policy of the ECB: future perspectives for the

173

E-library and Databases

[1] Banca d’Italia – Statistical Database

<https://infostat.bancaditalia.it/inquiry/#eNorSazI1y%2FLTEnNT9dPTsxJzUvR

Ty2w8nG2dfXTcfULs%2FXxDHPVcQ6JsHXxdHPTBwB51Q6%2F>

[2] Bloomberg

<http://www.bloomberg.com/>

[3] ECB – Statistical Data Warehouse

<http://sdw.ecb.europa.eu/>

[4] IMF e-library

<http://www.elibrary.imf.org/>

[5] Thomson Reuters Eikon

<http://financial.thomsonreuters.com/en/products/tools-

applications/trading-investment-tools/eikon-trading-software.html>

[6] World Bank (The)

<http://data.worldbank.org/>