Media Disruption Exacerbates Revolutionary Unrest

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 8/3/2019 Media Disruption Exacerbates Revolutionary Unrest

    1/43

    Media Disruption Exacerbates Revolutionary Unrest:

    Evidence from Mubaraks Natural Experiment

    Navid Hassanpour

    [email protected]

    August 07, 2011

    Abstract

    Conventional wisdom suggests that lapses in media connectivity - for example, disruption

    of Internet and cell phone access - have a negative effect on political mobilization. I argue

    that on the contrary, sudden interruption of mass communication accelerates revolutionary

    mobilization and proliferates decentralized contention. Using a dynamic threshold model

    for participation in network collective action I demonstrate that full connectivity in a social

    network can hinder revolutionary action. I exploit a decision by Mubaraks regime to disrupt

    the Internet and mobile communication during the 2011 Egyptian uprising to provide an

    empirical proof for the hypothesis. A difference-in-difference inference strategy reveals the

    impact of media disruption on the dispersion of the protests. The evidence is corroborated

    using historical, anecdotal, and statistical accounts.

    Keywords: Revolution, Social Networks, Learning, Media Disruption, Political Violence, Cas-

    cade, Egyptian Uprising 2011, Mobilization

    The author would like to thank Craig Calhoun, Alexandre Debs, Stefan Eich, Stephen Farrell, Stathis Kalyvas,Ellen Lust, Sergio Pecanha, Nicholas Sambanis, Jason Stearns, Sekhar Tatikonda, Elisabeth Wood, and participantsin APSA meetings of 2010 and 2011, EITM workshop 2011, and Berlin Summer School in Social Sciences 2011 fortheir helpful comments on this project.

    1

  • 8/3/2019 Media Disruption Exacerbates Revolutionary Unrest

    2/43

    Following three days of unrest and to counter the growing urban protests across Egypt, in

    early hours of January 28th Mubaraks regime shut down the Internet and cell phone networks

    across the country. The surprising events of the next day suggest the incumbents tactics were

    misguided. The protests in Cairo which were contained in Tahrir square and surroundings up to

    that day, proliferated across the city and flared in every corner of Cairo. By 6 P.M. on January

    28th, the police forces were overwhelmed, and the military was called in to replace the police. In

    the following days a practically neutral military played a major role in the political developments

    of the country resulting in the ouster of Mubarak on February 11th. The expansion of the protests

    on the 28th questions common wisdom on the role of social media in civil unrest. The disruption

    of the media across Egypt at early morning hours of January 28th, proliferated the unrest and

    exacerbated the decentralized nature of revolutionary contention. In the course of this study I

    examine the role of media at the time of revolutionary unrest and argue that disrupting social and

    mobile media, contrary to Mubaraks intent, fostered more contention of a decentralized nature.

    Disrupting media is a common characteristic of many revolutionary situations. Sometimes it is a

    byproduct of the paralyzing unrest; often it is the result of a governmental crackdown. In both

    cases, I will argue that the disruption acts as a catalyst of the revolutionary process and hastens

    the disintegration of the status quo. The recent Egyptian uprising provided a unique opportunity

    to put such a hypothesis to test.

    The disruption of media prior to major revolutionary upheavals is not limited to the case of

    the Egyptian Revolution of the 2011, but the evidence is not as clear-cut. On November 6, 1978,

    in solidarity with the other factions of the Iranian society and in opposition to the Shahs newly

    appointed military government, Iranian journalists and newspaper staffers announced an indefinite

    strike plunging the country into an information blackout for two months till the reopening of the

    press on January 05, 1979. The largest demonstration of the Iranian revolution of 1979 took place

    during this news industry hiatus on December 10 and 11, 1978 (Historical New York Times n.d.).

    The information vacuum was filled with audio-cassettes, pamphlets and other decentralized means

    of face-to-face communication. Not surprisingly, during Tehrans post-election protests of 2009,

    the authorities repeatedly disrupted mobile communications and Internet-based social media, but

    2

  • 8/3/2019 Media Disruption Exacerbates Revolutionary Unrest

    3/43

    never imposed a universal blackout.

    Similarly on the 25th of February 1917, in the midst of an urban revolt, Petrograd newspapers

    ceased publication just a few days before the Dumas dissolution. They resumed circulation on

    the first of March, after which the Duma acted quickly to limit and control the actions of the press

    (Historical New York Times n.d.). The proliferation of protests happened on the 26th immediately

    after the disruption of normal communications across the city on the 25th. The violent response

    to the unrest on the 26th culminated in an army rebellion and the take over of the Duma on the

    27th (Hasegawa 1981, Wade 2005). Both of the above examples hint at the disruption of media

    as a revolutionary catalyst but do not present a fully convincing evidence. Instead the abundance

    of microlevel information on the Egyptian case provides a reliable test for the hypothesis.

    In the following I argue that the disruption of media can fuel revolutionary unrest. Using

    a network stylization I detail situations in which higher connectivity can stall collective action.

    After proposing a social network formalization, I employ statistical evidence as well as micro-level

    data on the extent of contention during instances of revolutionary unrest to back the hypothesis.

    In particular, the Egyptian media disruption of January 28, 2011 is examined in greater detail to

    provide an account of underlying processes that increase the dispersion of protests.

    1 Dissent and the Media

    The debate on the role of the media in social unrest was revitalized during the Arab Spring and

    in the ensuing debates. In the past two decades, the rise of the Internet and decentralized online

    communication coincided with numerous instances of mass uprisings across the world. Many

    analysts have taken the social media to be an indispensable part of the mobilization process in

    mass protests in places as diverse as Ukraine, Iran, Moldova, Thailand, and Egypt. Various

    arguments have been put forward: some suggest that the new technology makes coordination

    easier, while others highlight the role the media play in broadcasting scenes of confrontation to

    the outside world, thereby encouraging the aggrieved population. Monitoring communication in

    the context of the social media also seems to be more difficult.

    The proponents of such arguments overlook several facts. Social media can act against grass

    3

  • 8/3/2019 Media Disruption Exacerbates Revolutionary Unrest

    4/43

    roots mobilization. They discourage face-to-face communication and mass presence in the streets.

    Similar to more traditional and highly visible media, they create greater awareness of risks involved

    in protests, which in turn can discourage people from taking part in demonstrations. In the

    following I will argue that lack of credible information at times benefits cascades of contention. 1

    Kern and Hainmueller (2009) cite similar processes as an explanation for why watching West

    German television broadcasts might have discouraged East Germans from applying for visas to

    travel to the West: once they saw it on television, they were less likely to embark on a personal

    exploration to see the unknown. Similarly knowing about the situation on Facebook and Twitter

    and having access to news propagation sources may make personal moves and physical presence

    unnecessary.

    The lack of the intermediary sources of communication between the state and the people

    fosters local news production and propagation on the individual level, deprives the state of a

    normalizing apparatus, and sets the stage for cascades of collective action. I would like to argue

    that the paralyzing mass demonstrations and widespread antagonistic uprisings in question would

    not have happened if the media had continued channeling their supervised, censored, and perhaps

    realistic narration of the events.

    In the absence of the mass media, information is communicated locally. Without state in-

    tervention, crowds shape an idea of risk that is independent from the government, testing their

    perceptions by staging demonstrations. The governments response to the acts of public defiance

    signals either weakness or strength on the side of the state (Chwe 2001, Kuran 1991). If the

    demonstrators speculations about the weakness of the incumbent regime turn to be correct as it

    did in Tehran in December 1978 or Leipzig in 1989-90 (Lohmann 1994), the cascade of events can

    grow to unanticipated dimensions.2

    1In fact a number of mass uprisings in the Eastern Block were initiated by rumors. See section (1.1).2On the difference between revolutions and riots: in this study revolution is defined as a mass violent act targeted

    at the governing body, intended to topple the incumbent regime. Mass uprisings under the title revolutions showdistinctive common traits: they are large in scale (thousands involved if not millions); their major aim is todismantle the political status quo and the ruling apparatus; the new rulers (in the case of successful execution)would be the prior underclass; the ruling elite would be confiscated from their political and economic power; andfinally successful revolutions bring vast and far reaching changes in legal and judicial practice. Defined as such,revolutions are rare events. They are different from riots in several aspects. First, they affect lives of a sizablepopulation inside the domestic polity, second the stakes are higher. Participants face higher risks, their ultimategoal being a stand off against the ancien regime. Both of these characteristics are in contrast with the defining

    4

  • 8/3/2019 Media Disruption Exacerbates Revolutionary Unrest

    5/43

    1.1 Revolutions and Misinformation

    The Weberian definition of the state (Weber 1958) anticipates such destabilizing moments. The

    state is defined as the monopoly over physical force and bureaucracy. In addition to the military

    and police, the press act as a proxy for the states control bureaucracy, hence any interruption of

    this industry would alter the functionality of the state. Webers definition is also in line with the

    transformation of the press after the French Revolution. While decentralized pamphleteering was

    a common practice among the revolutionaries, the state they created moved to standardize and

    regulate the process.

    According to Schumpeter (1950) these notions extend to democracies and dictatorships alike.

    In a well functioning democracy the media are used to shape electoral opinion. Likewise in the

    Gramscis depiction of totalitarianism (Gramsci 1971), the media impose an aura of normalcy and

    oppressive calm under the cultural hegemony of the state. What is left out from Schumpeter and

    Gramscis accounts are the brief moments where the outreach of the media does not exist or is

    interrupted. When the normalizing force of the media collapses, production of opinion outside

    the reach of the incumbent regime can force the polity to change course under the pressure of an

    opposing public sphere.

    In a society on the verge of political unrest, the states control over news media prevents

    widespread dissatisfaction from turning into a united opposition. Media outlets are highly visible

    and not hard to control. The population that relies on the media for estimating the political atmo-

    sphere is provided with a view that is supervised by the ruling power. The elite use their influence

    to pacify the population or discourage sedition. Nevertheless, the widely acknowledged view of

    the role of the media in revolutions points at the opposite direction. Popkin (1995) among others,

    notes the positive impacts of the free media on bringing about revolutions. According to him

    print media disseminate knowledge and awareness. The constituents are informed about political

    possibilities and grievances; therefore they are more inclined to engage in a resurrection against

    oppression and incompetence. This argument is misguided on two grounds, first it overlooks the

    fact that most seditious communication is invisible to the ruling elite. If they were aware of it,

    factors of riots (Wilkinson 2009) as smaller gatherings, which although can be violent, are not of the magnitude ofrevolutionary movements and are not directed toward the demise of the principal political hegemony.

    5

  • 8/3/2019 Media Disruption Exacerbates Revolutionary Unrest

    6/43

    they would disrupt it. The centralized media, including semi-autonomous dailies, are too exposed

    to foster revolutionary violence. Second, those who engage in radical acts of dissidence usually are

    not primed by potential free discussions in the press. The free media excites the intelligentsia and

    is more likely to result in a political transition of more usual types. What incites mass revolts is

    misinformation properly defined.3

    To confirm such hypotheses and to add to the descriptive and speculative statements on the

    positive or negative role of the media on mass protests, one needs to find situations in which

    social media coverage changes sharply, then gauge the impact of such a change on the level of

    unrest. In fact authoritarian regimes repeatedly provide such a scenario: in the course of street

    protests, mobile communications are often disrupted and internet access is restricted. However

    ideally the disruption should be ubiquitous and universal and the level of confounding factors kept

    to the minimum for the conclusions to be meaningful. In the following I provide a stylization

    using a dynamic social network model and present a recent example of media disruption in Cairo

    as evidence.4

    1.2 Dynamic Models of Network Collective Action and Media Influ-

    ence

    Media disruption drastically changes the way information is transmitted in society. In response to

    such disruptions new links for imitation and deliberation are set up and new spheres of influence

    are created. In the following I propose a stylization of such dynamics. First I outline a dynamic and

    structural version of a well known threshold model of collective action proposed by Granovetter

    (1978) and Schelling (1978) and later expanded by Kuran (1989), Lohmann (1994), Gould (1993),

    and Siegel (2009) among others. According to the threshold model, individuals have different

    3Consider the case of the Czech Velvet Revolution. According to the recent accounts, the movement was ignitedby false rumors of the brutal death of a 19-year-old university student, see http://nyti.ms/2tioTq. At thetimes of civil unrest, exaggeration tactics are known to be highly effective. In a similar manner the fall of theBerlin Wall started with a false and ambiguous statement at a news conference, see http://wapo.st/4wXDkC. Avaguely communicated decision on the Eastern German television prompted protesters to demand free passage tothe Western side of Berlin.

    4The contingencies involved in a revolutionary event ask for very detailed accounts (Sewell 2005). Later in theempirics section I use journalistic reports to cope with such nuances in event research.

    6

    http://nyti.ms/2tioTqhttp://nyti.ms/2tioTqhttp://wapo.st/4wXDkChttp://wapo.st/4wXDkChttp://nyti.ms/2tioTq
  • 8/3/2019 Media Disruption Exacerbates Revolutionary Unrest

    7/43

    risk-taking habits represented with a personal participation threshold. If the percentage of ones

    network neighbors engaging in action exceeds ones threshold, she switches from inaction to action.

    Granovetters model can be improved upon by adding two components, first a model of social

    structure and second a model of threshold dynamics.

    Why structure? Taking the overall level of participation to be fully visible to all society

    members is an unrealistic assumption. An individuals perceived levels of participation can be

    quite myopic. In fact a major disruption of media and mobile communications does exactly that:

    it reduces a globally connected network relying on a backbone of information propagating nodes to

    a multitude of smaller local networks barely connected to each other. These local micronetworks

    are strongly influenced by patterns of interpersonal links and spatial confines. Because of the

    disproportionate size of the core of mobilization, structural patterns also represent the relations

    between protest leaders and the rest of the population. In the context of mass demonstrations often

    one needs to imitate, observe, and update beliefs based on the neighbors acts in a local network.

    Such modes of behavior based on limited information can result in a fast-paced contagion of

    political participation.

    Why dynamics? In addition to action, personal thresholds are also in flux. It is plausible

    to think that (1) while interacting with others one would be influenced by his network neighbors

    beliefs (2) when participating becomes prevalent, ones threshold could decrease; or as inaction

    becomes the norm, thresholds also increase. Kuran (1989) and Lohmann (1994) propose dynamics,

    while Gould (1993) and Siegel (2009) combine particular dynamic models with structural models.

    Hence the distinctive characteristics of mass collective action are products of two factors, first

    the structure of the social network and the characteristics of network relations underlying political

    action, and second dynamics of inter-personal learning, imitation, and influence. The following

    section contains a model for formalizing both components.

    2 The Model

    In this section I propose a formalization of the Granovetter threshold model for participation in

    collective action in networks, which takes both the network structure and belief updating into

    7

  • 8/3/2019 Media Disruption Exacerbates Revolutionary Unrest

    8/43

    account.5 In order to make verifiable predictions, I outline a graph theoretical model for threshold

    updating using DeGroot learning (see (Jackson 2008)). I demonstrate that full connectivity in

    a social network sometimes can hinder collective action. Later I will show that with some as-

    sumptions on the structure of the social network, repeated threshold updating takes the network

    to an equilibrium on the network graph; hence, the updating procedure acts as an equilibrium

    selection mechanism based on network parameters and initial participation thresholds. When

    these assumptions do not hold, cycles of participation and disengagement can occur. Unlike the

    Granovetter/Kuran model, this formalization predicts non-monotone participation levels and het-

    erogeneous outcomes at the final equilibrium, where some individuals act and some do not. Hence,

    it provides a more realistic model of mobilization dynamics, which can explain the ebb and flow in

    large-scale political demonstrations. Later I examine network transformation as a result of media

    disruption and hypothesize an increase in protest dispersion resulting from such a transformation.

    The empirics in the next section confirm the plausibility of the model.

    2.1 Formalization

    Each individual decides to either join a collective act of dissent or to stay put based on a personal

    threshold and the percentage of his acquaintances who have already joined in. If the percentageis above that threshold, he would join in, otherwise he would not act. The model is based on two

    parameters, the personal thresholds of each agent, and the social network structure which dictates

    the details of interpersonal influence. There are radicals with very small thresholds whose acts

    start the process.

    The network is represented by a graph G(I, E), where I is the set of all nodes in the network

    i = 1, . . . , n, and E is the set of all edges connecting these nodes. Each node represents an agent,

    and each link is a social connection. Edges can be directed, i.e. some can not see others acting,

    while they can be seen by others.6

    Each of the agents is deciding between taking (A) or not taking (N) actionthis is a binary

    choice between N and A. The decision is made based on the proportion of the network neighbors

    5Those not interested in technical details may skim through Notes 1 to 4 and skip to section (2.4).6There is always a self-loop, because everybody is aware of what he himself does, or what threshold one has.

    8

  • 8/3/2019 Media Disruption Exacerbates Revolutionary Unrest

    9/43

  • 8/3/2019 Media Disruption Exacerbates Revolutionary Unrest

    10/43

    players have identical thresholds , i.e. the threshold triplet is ( , , ). In this case the equilibria

    of the game are different from the previous case.

    N

    N N

    N N

    N

    AA A

    A

    AA > 1/2 > 1/2

    Figure 2: Equilibria for a network game, agents have thresholds ( , , )

    Here when < 1/2, there are only two equilibria (N ,N ,N ) and (A,A,A). When > 1/2,

    there are four, (N ,N ,N ), (A,A,A), (N,A,A), and (N,A,N), see figure (2).

    Chwe (1999) also studied games with a similar threshold strategy. In addition to Chwes

    analysis, Gould (1993) and Siegel (2009) consider dynamic versions of similar network games.

    In (Hassanpour 2010a,b), the DeGroot learning scheme (Jackson 2008) is superimposed on the

    threshold model. Again the learning dynamics acts as an equilibrium selection mechanism. The

    network game is played repeatedly, and the thresholds are updated at each iteration. In this model

    the asymptotic values of the thresholds and the agents final choices between A (action) and N

    (non-action) are of interest.

    In the following subsection I outline a dynamic model to explain transitions between two

    distinct equilibria.

    2.3 A Dynamic Model

    One expects that at each action period, agents revise their action thresholds based on the history

    of previous actions. If the majority of their neighbors in the network are eagerly active in collective

    action and have low participation thresholds, the agents update their thresholds accordingly and

    will be more prone to participation in the next round. In the case of inaction, the same mechanism

    is at work. Lohmann (1994) takes threshold updates to be Bayesian. I instead adopt an averaging

    mechanism based on the DeGroot model. Political actors need to approximate the situation and

    quickly extrapolate about future. It is plausible to assume that they simply adopt a weighted

    10

  • 8/3/2019 Media Disruption Exacerbates Revolutionary Unrest

    11/43

    average of their own thresholds with their neighbors. The weights are proportional to the level of

    interpersonal influences. The averaging weights between two agents is not necessarily symmetric.

    i can take js recommendation very seriously, while the opposite might not be true. An individual

    may closely watch the acts of an opinion leader, while the leader does not care as much about a

    followers beliefs. The weights individual i assigns to person j are taken to be ijs. I normalize

    the s so that

    j ij = 1. Note that ones neighbors thresholds are not always fully known, and

    are hard to exchange in the course of fast paced mobilization. Hence, actors have to infer the

    real value of thresholds from the acts of each of their neighbors. For example they can take i s

    threshold to be the the proportion of the times she has failed to act. Or if keeping a detailed

    history is implausible, one can make a coarse approximation and take is threshold to be 1 if i did

    not act in the previous round, and 0 if she did.

    In the following, I examine two updating mechanisms. One is based on averaging neighbors

    thresholds, and the other infers a neighbors threshold from his act in the previous round. I show

    that these two dynamics result in quite different asymptotic outcomes.

    2.3.1 First Model, Full Threshold Knowledge

    First type of dynamics is to replace ones threshold with a weighted average of ones own and

    neighbors thresholds; and act at each time t according to the threshold and the level of activism

    in ones neighborhood. Because of the continuous nature of political action, I take this process to

    be repeated multiple times. Ideally the objective is to use the model to find asymptotic acts and

    thresholds of each individual in the network.

    Dynamics of Thresholds: At time t, i updates his threshold to be a linear combination of

    his neighbors thresholds and his own. Define Matrix nn = [ij] equal to the weight that i gives

    to neighbor js threshold. Take n1(t) to be the vector of thresholds for individuals 1 to n at

    time t.

    11

  • 8/3/2019 Media Disruption Exacerbates Revolutionary Unrest

    12/43

    (t) = (t 1)

    i(t) =

    j:ijG

    ijj(t 1)

    Dynamics of Action: take An1(t) as the vector of individuals action. 1 implies action, and

    0 non-action. At each time t, individuals either join in collective action or refrain. The perceived

    level of participation for individual i, pi(t), can be a product of her personal network, or a number

    known to everybody and the same for all, pi(t) = p(t), i. The decision to act or not act is made

    based on the comparison of pi(t) and i(t). At time t, person i acts ifpi(t 1) i(t) and would

    not act if pi(t 1) < i(t). For the purpose of analysis in this paper I assume that pi(t) is the

    percentage of is neighbors acting at time t. Note that there could be various ways of modeling

    pi(t). For example we could assume a universally accepted p(t) or perceived participation levels,

    pi(t), that are different from real pi(t)s.

    We are interested in the dynamics of both and A, specifically their asymptotic behavior when

    t

    Note that in this model, the action vector A is a derivative of the threshold vector . Define

    D Dij=1

    deg(i I) + 1if ij E,

    Adding +1 for the self-loop. D is fixed for all t,

    A(t) = sgn(p(t 1) (t))

    = sgn(DA(t 1) (t)).

    sgn(t) is the sign function, sgn(t)=0 if t < 0, sgn(t)=1 if t 0. Therefore these two equations

    12

  • 8/3/2019 Media Disruption Exacerbates Revolutionary Unrest

    13/43

    together characterize the Markov dynamics of this system,

    (t) = (t 1) (1)

    A(t) = sgn(DA(t 1) (t)). (2)

    In the following examples we take = D, hence

    (t) = D(t 1) (3)

    A(t) = sgn(DA(t 1) (t)) (4)

    Initial conditions: i(0) is given. Ai(0) = 1 if i(0) = 0, otherwise Ai(0) = 0.

    Example: Consider the following two networks in figure (3). In this case, there is one radical

    agent with initial threshold 0 and two normal individuals with identical thresholds 0 < < 1.

    At each time unit, players update their thresholds and decide to act or not. The relations are

    symmetric. Which means ij = 1/(degree of i + 1). The initial thresholds and the configurations

    are as shown below.

    (, 2/3)

    (0, 2/3) (, 2/3)

    (, 0.57)

    (0, 0.57) (, 0.57)

    Figure 3: (initial threshold, steady state thresholds), full connectivity is not always helpful

    Note that for the fully connected graph, threshold updating gives (2/3, 2/3, 2/3) for time

    t = 1 onwards. For action set, if < 1/2 the final action profile will be (A,A,A) for t = 1 onwards;

    otherwise it is (N ,N ,N ) for t = 1 onwards.

    For the other network, the dynamics are not trivial. Applying the dynamic model in equation

    (1) gives the following progression in table (1),

    The asymptotic thresholds for both networks are reflected in figure (3). Note that the fully

    connected graph has a larger final threshold compared to the other one, i.e. full connectedness is

    13

  • 8/3/2019 Media Disruption Exacerbates Revolutionary Unrest

    14/43

    Thresholds Actions(1) = (2 /3, /2, /2) A(1) = (A,N,N)

    (2) = (5 /9, 7 /12, 7 /12) A(2) = (A,A,A) if < 1/2; o.w. = (N,A,A)(3) = (31 /54, 41 /72, 41 /72) A(3) = (A,A,A) if < 6/7; o.w. = (A,N,N)

    ......

    () = (0.57, 0.57, 0.57) A() = (A,A,A) if < 0.875; o.w. = (N ,N ,N )

    Table 1: Dynamics of the star network in figure (3)

    not always helpful.

    Note 1: Connectivity does not always help collective action. It is usually assumed that

    full connectivity among participants in collective action is beneficial to the act of mobilization.

    Now consider cases where there are few radicals who aim at recruiting ordinary individuals. Fur-

    ther connections among ordinary individuals can foster inaction. The above example in figure (3)

    shows that establishing separation among ordinary individuals can effectively help mobilization.

    This is inline with similar observations in (Gould 1993) and (Siegel 2009) and provides an intuitive

    explanation for why disrupting media and mobile communications can assist mobilization instead

    of impeding it. Removing regular communication channels provides radicals with more effective

    venues for organization and encourages citizens to frequently engage in face-to-face communica-

    tions. This all weakens the incumbents control and provides more opportunities for grass roots

    mobilization.

    Asymptotic Thresholds: Consider the thresholds at time t, (t) = (t 1) = t(0),

    with the condition that i, i(0) = 0. If the networks graph G is aperiodic and irreducible,7

    the steady state thresholds will be the same for all the individuals in the network and is equal

    to v where v is the normalized8 unit left eigenvector of the matrix (the left eigenvector with

    eigenvalue equal to 1) and the final threshold for each individual is (Jackson 2008)

    i() = vT.(0).

    7A graph is aperiodic if the greatest common divisor of all of its cycles is 1. This is true of all graphs discussedin this paper, because of the self-cycle (each individual counts her own threshold in her averaging). A graph isirreducible if there is a path from each node to any other node. Again it is true of all of the graphs in this studyunless it is stated otherwise.

    8Such that the final vector is stochastic i.e. its elements add to one.

    14

  • 8/3/2019 Media Disruption Exacerbates Revolutionary Unrest

    15/43

    Further derivations on i() in specific network configurations can be found in the appendix,

    section (6.1).

    Note that while the threshold perceptions are changing indefinitely (although converging), the

    actions might reach the steady state and remain the same. Here we have the private preferences

    changing while the actions remain the same.

    2.3.2 Dynamics, Second Model, Only Action Knowledge

    Dynamics: Consider a case where there is not enough information about personal thresholds of

    ones neighbors. It is usually the case that the agent has to infer the neighbors thresholds based

    on their actions. Take the coarse estimation of a neighbor js threshold at time t to be 1 ifj does

    not act at time t 1, and 0 if he does act.

    To update the threshold one takes an average of his own threshold and an estimation of his

    neighbors thresholds based on their prior acts. The dynamics of this new updating mechanism is

    i(t) = Dii.i(t 1) +

    j=i

    Dij.(1 Aj(t 1)) (5)

    A(t) = sgn(DA(t 1) (t)) (6)

    The initial conditions are the same as the previous case in section (2.3.1).

    The section (6.2) in the appendix contains the details of the asymptotic thresholds and actions

    for star and fully connected networks. There are a number of noteworthy points in section (6.2).

    First, the dynamics based on inference from actions results in oscillations, even in conventional

    topologies such as star networks. The periphery and the central agent switch between action and

    inaction. In the case of threshold based updating, such oscillations do not happen.

    Note 2: Incomplete information brings about oscillation. Dynamics are not always

    monotone. Protests and mass political acts ebb and flow through time.9 An exact or approximate

    knowledge of thresholds is usually unavailable. Instead, the actions of ones neighbors can give

    clues on the their proclivity for participating in mobilization. One expects that inference based on

    9Kuran (1989)s model predicts a monotonically increasing or decreasing level of participation.

    15

  • 8/3/2019 Media Disruption Exacerbates Revolutionary Unrest

    16/43

    only previous actions (not the thresholds themselves) slow down convergence toward a final steady

    state. In other words, oscillations are more likely when updating is based on speculations instead

    of accurate knowledge. For example Ermakoff(2008)10 observes series of vacillations among French

    parliamentarians in the process of voting to establish the Vichy government in July 1940. He takes

    these oscillations to be a product of insufficient communication among the members of the French

    parliament. The above stylized examples qualitatively confirm Ermakoffs speculations.

    Finally an observation on the size of critical mass (CM) in the 3-star and the triangle networks

    in figure (3). Note that for any 1/2 < < 0.875, the CM for the 3-star network is 1, i.e. one

    radical is enough to incite the whole network to act, while the CM for the fully connected network

    is larger than 1 because the asymptotic result of the dynamic is non-action for all.11

    Note 3: Size of critical mass is contingent upon network structure. The impor-

    tance of a body of radical actors who unconditionally engage in mobilization is well known

    (Marwell and Oliver 1993). A network model can predict the smallest size of such a group needed

    for engaging the whole population. Sudden changes in network structure, e.g. through media

    disruption, can change critical mass needed for universal participation. While before disruption

    radicals were not able to incite a rebellion, their influence grows in a highly connected news

    propagation/mobilization network on the local level.

    2.3.3 Finding Steady State Thresholds and Actions

    In the above equations (1), (2), (5), and (6) analytical expressions for the steady state vectors A

    and sometimes can be found by putting A(t) = A(t 1) and (t) = (t 1). For example one

    can find the steady state from equation (1) and substitute it in (2). Then one could simply try

    all of the 2n possibilities for A and find the ones that satisfy the identity A(t) = A(t 1). Because

    the size of the possible As is well bounded, finding the equilibria is feasible. Same techniques can

    be applied to the equations (5), and (6). In the case of dynamics in (5) and (6) such trials are

    particularly helpful because both equations are non-linear and finding closed-form solutions is not

    10Ruling Oneself Out Ch.911In the appendix (6.2) I show that in the fully connected network, the size of critical mass (CM) is at least half

    of the actors. In any network it is possible to find the minimum size of critical mass needed for inciting globalaction.

    16

  • 8/3/2019 Media Disruption Exacerbates Revolutionary Unrest

    17/43

    easy.

    Also note that any steady state is an equilibrium of the network game (excluding the cases

    leading to oscillation). If that is not the case, in the next period, all players choose actions that are

    in equilibrium, hence it is impossible to have a non-equilibrium outcome as the steady state. As

    it was mentioned before, the dynamics give us an equilibrium selection mechanism. At the same

    time, one can assume a particular action equilibrium A, and find s that result in that equilibrium.

    Hence one could design a network to achieve a desired action equilibrium.12

    Note 4: A dynamic model proposes an equilibrium selection mechanism. It is

    plausible to assume that there are multiple equilibria for the network game defined based on the

    threshold mechanism. Network dynamics act as an equilibrium selection mechanism.

    Along the same lines as the above mentioned notes, there are four ways through which a

    cataclysmic event such as disrupting connections across a society can change the levels of mo-

    bilization: through changing the patterns of news production and learning among individuals,

    through changing the amount of information one can acquire about the acts and intentions of

    ones social network neighbors, through changing the size of critical mass on the local level, and

    finally through changing the asymptotics by altering the dynamics.

    2.4 State, Media, and Citizens, A Network Threshold Game

    In section (1), I argued that media have a pacifying role in the societies facing mass political

    turmoil and their sudden disruption can aggravate the situation. Before continuing with histor-

    ical anecdotes and statistical evidence, I offer an explanation using the threshold network game

    described in the previous subsection.

    Consider a network model with three classes of actors, modeled in the context of a tree network.

    The sole central player is the state, the nodes connected to the state represent the media visible

    to the state and under its influence. Each of the media nodes provides a number of individuals

    with news and information on the revolutionary situation. See the topology in figure (4). Links

    here represent functional and behavioral influence. For example media are influenced by the state

    12Hence we can perform a structural mechanism design. Knowing the final outcome, we can find a networkconstruct that induces the desired equilibrium.

    17

  • 8/3/2019 Media Disruption Exacerbates Revolutionary Unrest

    18/43

    policy, hence the links from the state to the media nodes. Individuals level of risk taking is

    influenced by the content of the media, hence the links from the media to the individuals. Note

    that influence is not synonymous with control. A change in strategy on a Facebook page due

    to information security concerns amounts to a link between the incumbent and the social media,

    although the state does not dictate the pages content. Similarly the existence of the page provides

    citizens connected to it with a forum in lieu of face-to-face communication. Social media nodes that

    serve as news propagation forums often regulate news aggregation and oversee news distribution

    among the online population.

    More traditional venues such as printed press serve the same purpose but are not as affected by

    their audience as the novel social media. For the purpose of this study I examine two separate cases

    in turn. One is the traditional media such as the daily print press, where there is no established

    mechanism for channeling the opinion of the audience in real time. The second category contains

    new social media. Ideally they represent an aggregation of their audiences attitude toward risk

    besides serving as an information source for the users. The distinction between two media classes is

    not complete. There are cases in between, e.g. independent newspapers or a government sponsored

    blogosphere.

    Figure 4: The state, centralized media and citizens, represented as a tree graph

    18

  • 8/3/2019 Media Disruption Exacerbates Revolutionary Unrest

    19/43

  • 8/3/2019 Media Disruption Exacerbates Revolutionary Unrest

    20/43

    stronger than the relations between the citizens. Hence comparatively speaking, interpersonal

    links are non-existent. In such a situation, the state and the medias allegiances are static while

    the citizens thresholds can change. Ordinary citizens do not act, because all what they see are

    controlled sources of information. In the absence of connections with radicals, the majority of

    the population is not mobilized. Because of their isolation from the others, radicals action does

    not amount to much. At a stalemate, citizens learn from static media nodes and become more

    risk averse. The result would be a non-action equilibrium with a slight nuisance from the radical

    elements. After multiple updates, the thresholds tend to converge to the medias risk aversion

    levels.

    Case Two: The Social Media

    Decentralized media, e.g. Internet forums for communication, influence citizens inclination to

    risk in ways different from traditional media. Controlling news propagation on a grass roots level

    is much more difficult than policing newspapers, television, and radio broadcast. The political

    inclinations of the social media are often in line with the population majority, not the incumbent.

    To stylize the situation I take the configuration of the network to be the same as in figure (4), but

    in this case the threshold of the media nodes is the average of the thresholds of their neighboring

    citizens.

    Assume that the social media represent the average threshold of their correspondents, m =

    (

    i mi)/N. In line with the dynamics presented in equation (5), take action and thresholds to

    be reversely related Ai = 1 i. In the stylization, each individual sees the average threshold at

    the social media node and decides to act if i < 1 media threshold.14 Now according to this

    rule, at most half plus one individuals engage in action, while according to the threshold dynamics

    in equation (1), all of the thresholds are converging to the average threshold represented by the

    social media node.

    Note the difference between this scenario and a fully connected network of individuals. Here

    the social media node provides everybody with a view representing only the aggregate threshold.

    Individual thresholds are not visible to other members of the network.

    14The calculation behind this decision rule is straight forward: to act i c}. In this case for all s, k s r,s citizens acting is an equilibrium in the network threshold game.

    21

  • 8/3/2019 Media Disruption Exacerbates Revolutionary Unrest

    22/43

    Dispersion hypothesis: According to the above stylization disrupting the media and mo-

    bile communications promotes local mobilization, increasing the dispersion of protests. In

    the following section I exploit reports from the Egyptian uprising of 2011 to test the dispersion

    hypothesis.

    3 Media Disruption and Dissent, Empirical Evidence

    In this section, I employ multiple methods to confirm the dispersion hypotheses. I start with

    a statistical analysis of revolutionary unrest in relation to media penetration followed by some

    suggestive archival evidence. Then I examine the case of the Egyptian uprising of 2011 in greater

    detail. In late January 2011, in response to demonstrations, Mubaraks regime disrupted commu-nication all together for a few days providing a unique opportunity for studying the role of media

    disruption in fostering unrest. The main criterion for testing the theory is the existence of a visible

    increase in the dispersion of protests after media interruption.

    3.1 Statistical Treatment

    The existing statistical studies of mass political violence do not directly address the link between

    media and dissent. For example the extensive study of Hibbs (1973) does not consider the media

    component among other economic indices. One way of linking media influence to the level of

    revolutionary activity is to compare the frequency of revolutionary unrest to the extent of the

    reach of centralized media using available country-year data. An index of media influence can be

    the number of newspaper copies per capita or prevalence of radio or television use in a country.

    According to the above argument I expect that the number of revolutionary resurrections to be a

    decreasing function of media penetration. I use country-year data from Banks (2009) to examine

    a potential inverse relation between media penetration and revolutionary unrest. Consider the

    following plots.16

    16Revolutions according to Banks (2009) are any illegal or forced change in the top government elite, anyattempt at such a change, or any successful or unsuccessful armed rebellion whose aim is independence from thecentral government. This definition includes more than so called social revolutions and emphasizes the violentnature of political takeover. Nevertheless it contains most of what constitutes a social revolution: its grass-roots

    22

  • 8/3/2019 Media Disruption Exacerbates Revolutionary Unrest

    23/43

    0 1000 2000 3000 4000 5000 6000 7000 8000 90000

    1

    2

    3

    4

    5

    6

    7

    8

    9Revolution count vs Newspaper copies per capita (Banks)

    Figure 6: Domestic mass political violence for state takeover versus newspaper copies per capita

    Now consider the following negative binomial regression (table (2)) of the number of revolutions

    over the number of radios, television sets, and newspaper copies per capita controlling for GDP per

    capita and a measure of democracy at each country-year point (see table (3) for more informationon the range of the parameters and scaling data).17

    As it was expected from the plots, the regression multipliers for printed media influence (news-

    paper copies per capita) are negative and strongly significant. Even after controlling for a democ-

    racy index and GDP per capita still the pacifying role of media penetration is evident and accounts

    for around at least 20 (and up to 40) percent of the dependent variable count (the average revo-

    lution count is 0.185, see table (3)).

    Low levels of civil disobedience is often linked to high levels of political and economic devel-

    opment. Controlling for GDP and a democratic index deals with the very same concern.18

    nature, its large scale, and its aim at toppling the incumbent regime.17The democracy index is effectiveness of legislature according to the Banks data set.18Huntington (1968) took mass violent takeovers of the polity to be the result of a gap between social and economic

    advancements and political modernization. Such an explanation can be improved upon because it does not clearlyspecify what the elements of political modernization are. According to Huntington, political development is a sourceof stability, and political institutionalization is an antidote to major reversals of power such as revolutions. While

    23

  • 8/3/2019 Media Disruption Exacerbates Revolutionary Unrest

    24/43

  • 8/3/2019 Media Disruption Exacerbates Revolutionary Unrest

    25/43

    Controlling for GDP and type of the state, the negative impact of newspaper penetration is

    robust and significant.19

    3.2 Historical Precedents

    Ubiquitous and abrupt changes in media coverage provide an opportunity for studying the role

    of connectivity or lack thereof in the course of mass protests. After the introduction of the new

    social media such disruptions have become more commonplace. In the face of civil unrest the

    authorities have frequently chosen to disrupt communication venues available to protesters. To

    gauge the impact of media interruption, I study examples of mass uprisings in which there is

    a sharp interruption in service and estimate the effects of the change in coverage. To mitigate

    the endogeneity concern, it is necessary to control for confounding parameters that alongside

    media disruption might have changed the level of protests. As it was mentioned above, the most

    visible change that can attest to the validity of the theory is an increase in the dispersion of

    protests. There are multiple reasons for adopting such a research design: first, media disruption

    has happened frequently during the recent years as a tactic against the the new social medias

    mobilizing capabilities, hence we know of multiple cases that can be used for the purpose of

    testing the theory. Second, because of the extent and accuracy of reports in recent years we havevery detailed accounts of protests preceding and ensuing breaks in media/mobile communication

    coverage. The same is true of confounding factors. In the course of my study of the Egyptian

    uprising of 2011, I will present a showcase of such a design, but before doing so I include some

    archival evidence suggesting that the same process may have been at work in other historical

    occasions as well.

    this is a plausible account, it fails to specify what these political institutions are and what constitutes a measure of

    political modernization. Taking development as a repellent of mass political instability is at best tautological. Itscredibility is proved when one finds the elements of political development, demonstrating the mechanisms throughwhich they contribute to political stability.

    19One caveat is effectiveness of the number of newspaper copies in relation to the rate of literacy in correspondingcountries. If the link between illiteracy and low GDP is strong, the impact of illiteracy is counted in when GDP isincluded as a control parameter.

    25

  • 8/3/2019 Media Disruption Exacerbates Revolutionary Unrest

    26/43

    3.2.1 From Pamphlets to Centralized Media

    One of the more interesting facts about the French Revolution is the prevalence of pamphleteering

    immediately before the revolution (Popkin 1990). While the established periodicals of the time,

    e.g. Gazette de France and Gazette de Leyde, mostly ignored the rebellion during the summer

    of 1789, many of the leaders of the Third Estate (and later revolutionary leaders during the

    struggle of summer 1789) published pamphlets to disseminate news and make their own take on

    the situation known to the public. At the beginning of the summer 1789, Louis XVI tried his best

    to block the growth of pamphleteering (Popkin 1990), but did not succeed. Later pamphleteers

    such as Mirabeau and Abbe sieyes lead the revolution. After victory, the revolution redefined the

    relation between the state and media; pamphleteering was discouraged. Instead the printed press

    with wider circulation replaced grass roots means of written communication and reporting.

    Prior to the culmination of the February 1917 unrest in Petrograd, the citys newspapers

    stopped circulation immediately before the Dumas dissolution on the 27th. They resumed on

    the first of March. Afterwards the Duma tried to maintain a monopoly on the press ( Wade 2005,

    Hasegawa 1981, Historical New York Times n.d.). Wade (2005) believes the confusion caused by

    the absence of printed media might have hastened the collapse of the ancien regime.20

    Similarly during the Iranian Revolution of 1978-79, the printed press stopped circulation on

    November 6th, 1978 and did not return to normal till two months later (Historical New York Times

    n.d., Historical Washington Post 1978, Kayhan 1978-9). The largest protests of the Iranian Revo-

    lution happened during the very same period when media coverage was at minimal levels and the

    scant broadcast of the state media was widely disregarded in favor of pamphlets, audio cassettes

    and foreign radio stations (Historical New York Times n.d., Kayhan 1978-9). Again in this case

    the spread of grass-roots rumors had a major impact on the success of revolutionary mobiliza-

    tion. Instead of the state setting the general political agenda across the society, the opposition

    encouraged repetitive cycles of rebellion.

    In both of the above cases it is difficult to estimate the impact of the absence of media because

    20It is necessary to mention that literacy rates among the urban Russian population around 1917 were around 70percent (Mironov 1991), i.e. the printed press as the sole formal news propagation mechanism (prior to televisionand radio broadcast) played a major role in everyday news learning. Their absence might have acted as a catalystfor the revolutionary unrest in Petrograd.

    26

  • 8/3/2019 Media Disruption Exacerbates Revolutionary Unrest

    27/43

    of confounding factors. The evidence we have is not accurate enough to test the dispersion

    hypothesis (see section (2.4)). Specially because the treatment (disruption of the media and

    cutting down venues for communication) was not always complete, i.e. did not include all means

    of news propagation. In more traditional societies constituents relied on a wide array of traditional

    communication processes, hence stopping a number of state controlled channels, e.g. newspapers

    might not have had the same impact as cutting all mobile/Internet communications overnight.

    Thats exactly what Mubaraks regime did at the early hours of January 28th, 2011.

    3.3 Mubaraks Natural Experiment in Media Disruption

    In response to the opposition staging demonstrations for three consecutive days in Tahrir Square

    and promising a yet larger demonstration on a Friday of Rage, Mubaraks regime shut down the

    Internet and cell phone coverage across the country at the early hours of January 28, 2011. In-

    stead of stalling demonstration in Tahrir, the consequences caught the regime by surprise. Protests

    flared across Cairo and other Egyptian cities including Alexandria and Suez. The protests were

    unusually diffuse and widespread and overwhelmed Mubaraks security forces by the end of the

    day (Historical New York Times n.d.). Around 7 PM on January 28th the military was brought

    into the scene to replace the dysfunctional police force. After deployment of the military, dynamicsof the interaction among the political players (the incumbent, the military, and the opposition)

    changed. The militarys inaction, accompanied with unexpected implications of the regimes bold

    experimentation with the mass media in the following days, put an end to Mubaraks thirty year

    rule. At the turning point of January 28th, lack of cell phone coverage and Internet connec-

    tion forced the population to find other means of communication, encouraging local mobilization.

    Meanwhile apolitical strata of the Egyptian society, aggrieved by the disruption, were pushed into

    joining the confrontation. Instead of protests only in and around Tahrir Square, sizable demon-

    strations appeared in many locations in Cairo (Historical New York Times n.d., Shehata et al.

    2011).

    As mentioned above, the Egyptian case offers a unique opportunity to test the plausibility of

    the dispersion hypothesis in a context similar to a natural experiment (alas run by Mubaraks

    27

  • 8/3/2019 Media Disruption Exacerbates Revolutionary Unrest

    28/43

    regime). The disruption was abrupt and its timing (1:30 AM on January 28th) rules out any

    preparation for countering the blackout on the previous day. Between 10 PM and 2 AM, SMS

    and Internet communications were shut down, more importantly cell phone communications were

    shut down during the 28th, see a timeline at table (5).21 While the regime had experimented with

    selectively disrupting network coverage and websites such as Twitter and Facebook, it was the

    first time a universal communication blakcout was imposed on the nation.

    Dismantling regular venues for communication incited Egyptians to find new ways of staying

    online or forgoing online communication altogether. During the social media hiatus, older mobi-

    lization tactics were used in conjunction with new means of mass communication. For example

    satellite television stations such as Al Jazeera broadcast news communicated to them via landline

    phones (Shehata et al. 2011). Al-Arabiya television station also started broadcasting informative

    tweets on radio. At the same time tweeting over the phone became a possibility using Googles

    Speak2Tweet (Dunn 2011a). In addition to these spontaneous innovations, the protests prolif-

    erated through much more mundane means. On the 28th those worried about their friends and

    family members participating in protests, could not reach them via cell phones, and had to join

    the crowds in streets to find out about their acquaintances (Shehata et al. 2011). In hazardous

    conditions of the ongoing stand off across the city, focal local points became gathering locations.

    Many congregated in local squares, strategic buildings, and mosques instead of trying to reach

    Tahrir (Historical New York Times n.d.)22.

    To summarize, the disruption of cell phone coverage and Internet on the 28th exacerbated

    the unrest in at least three major ways: it implicated many apolitical citizens unaware of or

    uninterested in the unrest; it forced more face-to-face communication, i.e. more physical presence

    in streets; and finally it effectively decentralized the rebellion on the 28th through new hybrid

    communication tactics, producing a quagmire much harder to control and repress than one massive

    gathering in Tahrir.23

    21sources: Ramy Raoof, Egyptian activist and blogger, the Lede Blog, Dunn (2011b), and Renesys.com amongothers (blog posts, video interviews, news reports)).

    22http://nyti.ms/gcHvjz23Even in Tahrir there was no single leadership (Shehata et al. 2011): Nobody was in charge of Tahrir, and

    a lot of those who joined the protests on January 25th in Tahrir were not aware of the Facebook campaign, theyhad heard about it from the protesters in the square and surrounding streets. According to Mourtada and Salem

    28

    http://nyti.ms/gcHvjzhttp://nyti.ms/gcHvjz
  • 8/3/2019 Media Disruption Exacerbates Revolutionary Unrest

    29/43

    3.3.1 Notes on the Dynamics of the Egyptian Unrest

    Four important cycles of unrest are evident during the 18 days of the Egyptian uprising, each

    of which starts with a significant media event. There are four cycles: January 25-27, January

    28-February 01, February 02-07, February 08-11.

    a) January 25-27: Initial mobilization on January 25th, the social media campaign

    b) January 28-February 01: Disruption of the media on January 28th and the proliferation of

    the protests, the military steps in and acts as a game changer during the following clashes between

    pro and anti-Mubarak crowds

    c) February 02-07: Provocative national address by Mubarak on late night February 01st (stat-

    ing he will stay in power till September and will die in Egypt), ensuing clashes on the 2nd and

    3rd, the militarys inaction emboldens prevailing opposition crowds, relative calm afterwards till

    the 8th

    d) February 08-11: Emotional appeal by Wael Ghonim on a late night television show on the

    7th and his follow up speech in Tahrir square in the morning of February 08th initiates the final

    phase of protests in Tahrir, eventual announcement of Mubaraks resignation by Suleiman on the

    11th.

    The above parsing of the events emphasizes the pivotal role of media operations during the

    unrest. Setting aside the militarys involvementitself brought about by the sudden disruption

    of all online communication meansthe role of the media is in full display. Dismantling the cell

    network in particular influenced mobilization on the local level. Egyptians had to revert to local

    interactions for gaining information. New local mobilization networks were formed that were

    smaller and better connected. Radicals became more effective on the local level, because they

    could directly contact more people on the ground. Moreover the networks underlying collective

    action and news propagation became smaller and more diffuse, making it more difficult to contain

    the protests.

    To overcome the endogeneity critique (that the government disrupted the media in anticipation

    of a major increase in the size of the protests, or that the closing down of the media was simply

    (2011) majority of respondents to an online survey on the role of the media disruption on the protests, believed ithad a positive effect on the demonstrations.

    29

  • 8/3/2019 Media Disruption Exacerbates Revolutionary Unrest

    30/43

    a by-product of the escalating unrest) one could show that the major prediction of the model, i.e.

    sharp increase in the dispersion of the protests is manifest and statistically significant even after

    controlling for other confounding factors. The fact that there were calls for attending a protest in

    Tahrir during the previous days does not account for a sharp jump in the number of locations

    in which the clashes on the 28th took place. The dependent variable here is the dispersion of the

    protests, not their total size. Furthermore, such proliferation never happened again during the

    course of the protests, in spite of the the return of the media and enduring contention in Tahrir,

    even when the numbers in Tahrir were unprecedented (e.g. upon the restoration of the Internet

    on February 2nd).

    In the following I outline the procedure for extracting protest location data using available

    journalistic reports (photos, wires, and blog posts), describe the media interruption timeline and

    present a statistical analysis for singling out the effect of disruption on protest dispersion. I show

    that the Mubarak experiment is yet the most convincing evidence on the dispersion hypothesis we

    have on file.

    3.4 Protest Dispersion in Cairo and Media Disruption

    In the following I outline the data on protest dispersion and media disruption during the 18 daysof the Egyptian uprising of 2011. I include four variable in the OLS regressions. The dependent

    variable is protest dispersion defined as the number of locations in Cairo where protests were

    happening each day. As independent variables I include a dummy for the treatment, i.e. media

    disruption, controlling for Fridays and national addresses via television. Controlling for Fridays is

    necessary because Friday is the Muslim weekly holiday and more people have the time and latitude

    for demonstration. Friday prayers also act as focal events. Media announcements are included as

    a control to estimate and control for the influence of mainstream media reporting. The details of

    protest locations are included in table (4), a log of state interruptions of media/cell coverage is

    included in table (5).

    A difference-in-difference strategy Here I regress daily differences in protest dispersion

    in Cairo on media disruption, controlling for Fridays and media announcements. First note the

    30

  • 8/3/2019 Media Disruption Exacerbates Revolutionary Unrest

    31/43

    Date Dispersion: Protest Locations

    January 25 1: TahrirJanuary 26 1: TahrirJanuary 27 1: TahrirJanuary 28 Friday 8: Tahrir-NDP headquarters-Egyptian National Museum/Kasr al-Nil bridge/

    6 October bridge/TV headquarters/Al Azhar mosque/Mohandeseen/Mustafa Mahmoud Mosque/l Istiqama Mosque

    January 29 4: Tahrir-NDP headquarters-Egyptian National Museum/Interior Ministry/Corniche al-Nil/Abu Zaabal

    January 30 3: Tahrir/Heliopolis/Abu ZaabalJanuary 31 3: Tahrir/ Mohandeseen/Arkadia Shopping CenterFebruary 01 2: Tahrir/Kasr al-Nil BridgeFebruary 02 3: Tahrir-Egyptian National Museum/Mohandeseen/Corniche al-NilFebruary 03 1: Tahrir-Egyptian National MuseumFebruary 04 Friday 1: Tahrir-Egyptian National MuseumFebruary 05 1: Tahrir-Egyptian National MuseumFebruary 06 1: Tahrir-Egyptian National Museum

    February 07 1: Tahrir-MugammaFebruary 08 2: Tahrir/ Egyptian ParliamentFebruary 09 4: Tahrir/ Zamalek/ Ministry of Health-Egyptian Parliament/

    Dokki(organized labor protests)February 10 4: Tahrir/ TV Headquarters/ Egyptian Parliament/ Abdin PalaceFebruary 11 Friday 5: Tahrir/ TV Headquarters/Presidential Palace/

    Mustafa Mahmoud Mosque/ Egyptian Parliament

    Table 4: Source: The New York Times, The Lede Blog, See Section (5.1)

    31

  • 8/3/2019 Media Disruption Exacerbates Revolutionary Unrest

    32/43

    Date Type of Disruption or Restoration

    January 25 Twitter.com blockedBambuser.com (Live video streaming) blocked at 02:00 PMActivists mobile lines shut downNetwork coverage shut down in Tahrir

    January 26 Facebook.com blocked

    Blackberry services shut down 7:00 PMJanuary 27 SMS shut down 10:00 PMJanuary 28 Internet shut down-except one ISP, 1:30 AM

    Mobile phone calls shut down for one dayLandlines shut down in some areas

    January 30 Al-jazeera Cairo bureau shut downJanuary 31 Last ISP shut downFebruary 01 State media campaign against protesters (text messages)February 02 Internet service restored 12:30 PMFebruary 05 SMS restored 12:35 AM

    Table 5: All times are Egyptian local time, i.e. EST+7 in January/February 2011Source: RamyRaoof, Egyptian Activist and Blogger, Alix Dunn Blogger, Renesys.com23.51 Million Internetusers (30% penetration), 71.46 Million Mobile subscribers (90% penetration) in January 2011

    sharp jump in the number of protest locations on the 28th in figure (7). 28th was the first day of

    blanket disruption and the only day in which cell phone communications, Internet services, SMS,

    and occasionally landlines were unavailable (see table (5)). Lack of cell phone coverage is more far

    reaching among the population than the absence of the Internet. In January 2011, there were 23.51

    million Internet users compared to 71.46 million mobile subscribers.24 Hence compared to Internet

    outage, any disruption in mobile communications directly implicates a much larger portion of the

    Egyptian population. Also mobile phones are more effective means of communication on the fly

    during protests in streets. On the other hand, Internet disruption complicates longer term planning

    and organization. Cutting cell coverage has an immediate impact on personal communication in

    streets. Considering these issues and the fact that dismantling Egyptian online network cameas a surprise during the very first day of the outage, I code the treatment as a dummy on the

    28th (discon-diff)-Later I consider an extended version of the disruption variable. National media

    addresses by the heads of the state and the opposition (see appendix 5.2) are also coded as a

    24 23.51 Million Internet users (30% penetration), 71.46 Million Mobile subscribers (90% penetra-tion) in January 2011, from report by Egypts ministry of Communications and Information Technologyhttp://slidesha.re/mtrPuM

    32

    http://slidesha.re/mtrPuMhttp://slidesha.re/mtrPuM
  • 8/3/2019 Media Disruption Exacerbates Revolutionary Unrest

    33/43

    control variable in table (6). Using a difference-in-difference strategy, I regress the daily change

    in dispersion over the treatment (disruption) controlling for other variables. As can be seen in

    table (6) media interruption on the 28th had a statistically significant and relatively effective role

    in proliferating the protests in Cairo.25

    25 26 27 28 29 30 31 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11

    Protest Dispersion

    Date

    0

    2

    4

    6

    8

    All Products, Egypt Traffic Divided by Worldwide Traffic and Normalized

    Figure 7: Top: Protest Dispersion (Number of Distinct Protest Locations According to Table 4),Bottom: All Google Products, Egypt Traffic, from http://bit.ly/h3Q1FZ

    In addition to the difference-in-difference strategy in table (6), I also code the disruption acrossthe 5 day period of 28th to 01st. Taking the relative penetration of mobile devices to the Internet

    into account, I implement the treatment vector [3 1 1 1 1]. Note that this is an underestimation

    of the importance of the disruption on the 28th, because on the first day full disruption came as

    an utter surprise, hence its effect was more pronounced in the first day compared to the following

    25Similar results are obtained when the variable television announcement is excluded.

    33

    http://bit.ly/h3Q1FZhttp://bit.ly/h3Q1FZ
  • 8/3/2019 Media Disruption Exacerbates Revolutionary Unrest

    34/43

  • 8/3/2019 Media Disruption Exacerbates Revolutionary Unrest

    35/43

    appendix (5.2)). The contrast with the common view on the singular importance of the new social

    media in generating unrest in Cairo is thought provoking.

    3.4.1 Blocking the New Social Media for Stopping a Rebellion?

    From the above it is clear that disrupting the media (and to a lesser degree the ever present satellite

    television coverage of the events) charged the population and overwhelmed the authorities; but

    what are the conditions under which such disruptions might not be as mobilizing?

    An overview of the press at revolutionary times reveals that there are varying degrees of affinity

    between the press and the people. At times the press completely ignore the protests even till the

    very moment the ancien regime is about to collapse (Petrograd Gazette 1917, Gazette de France

    1789, Al-Ahram 2011). Sometimes they cautiously report on the unrest and sympathize with the

    protesters in a subtle tone (Kayhan, Iran 1978). Finally at times they fully support the protesters,

    reporting on their actions in detail, Al Jazeera Egypt 2011). There are multiple cases of failed

    rebellion during which access to the social media was highly restricted e.g. the post-election unrest

    in Iran 2009 and the Thailand Red Shirts rebellion of 2010. At the height of the protests in Tehran

    in June 2009, mobile communication was cut off and press reporters were banned. Opposition

    leaders communication with the outside world was very limited (Historical New York Times n.d.).

    In spite of limited access to social media at the time of the unrest, there was never a blanket

    interruption, but limitations were targeted, local, and temporary. Similarly in Thailand, the

    supervised flow of the opposition press allowed the government to suppress the opposition. The

    largest fatalities in one single protest event happened when the Red Shirts tried to take over

    the building housing the Peoples Television Station (a television station sympathizing with the

    Red Shirts). After an initial retreat from the premises, the government allowed for the stations

    operation but under strict supervisory26. In both cases a slow flow of supervised communication

    was allowed; on the other hand, face-to-face means of mobilization were actively disrupted.

    26Reports on the incident here http://nyti.ms/bP55zl and http://bbc.in/oMA7Wo

    35

    http://nyti.ms/bP55zlhttp://bbc.in/oMA7Wohttp://bbc.in/oMA7Wohttp://nyti.ms/bP55zl
  • 8/3/2019 Media Disruption Exacerbates Revolutionary Unrest

    36/43

    4 Conclusion: too many in too many places...

    In the above I showed that the favorable portrayal of social media in fostering unrest in the

    context of heterogeneous networks should be reconsidered. In other words, in the presence of

    a risk-averse majority and a radical minority, adding more links among the majority does not

    necessarily help mobilization. In the absence of centralized media, crowds risk-taking behavior

    becomes independent of the states intentions. Note that even the most authoritarian regimes

    prefer not to systematically bomb their own population, they instead use a threat of forceful

    military action in order to deter. When it is impossible to communicate the possibility of a

    painful military retaliation, the state is unable to dissuade the crowds. In fact protests proliferate

    when such threatening measures fail. In reaction to a shock similar to the one exerted on the

    Egyptian society on January 28th, the population can overwhelm the incumbent apparatus. The

    consequences of such an action were evident in the aftermath of the Egyptian media blockage.

    The Lede Blog reported from Alexandria on January 28th (emphasis is mine):

    Its clear that the very extensive police force in Egypt is no longer able to control

    these crowds. There are too many protests in too many places... said Peter Bouck-

    aert, emergencies director of Human Rights Watch, who observed the street battle in

    Alexandria on Friday[01/28/2011].

    5 Appendix 1: Event Data Collection: Egyptian Uprising

    of 2011

    5.1 Event Data Collection, Methodology

    In this appendix I outline the data collection procedure for the Egyptian uprising of 2011. In my

    reconstruction of the events, as for the location of protests, I used graphic designs from the New

    York Times website in addition to accounts from the Lede blog,27 for media disruption I have

    27Links to visual representations on The New York Times website:a. http://nyti.ms/gf4hzJ b. http://nyti.ms/g3LanI c. http://nyti.ms/fh5Ypb

    36

    http://nyti.ms/gf4hzJhttp://nyti.ms/g3LanIhttp://nyti.ms/fh5Ypbhttp://nyti.ms/fh5Ypbhttp://nyti.ms/g3LanIhttp://nyti.ms/gf4hzJ
  • 8/3/2019 Media Disruption Exacerbates Revolutionary Unrest

    37/43

    used online information from Egyptian bloggers28 and coded the data after crosschecks.

    For confirming the hypothesis on the role of the Egyptian media shut down on the unrest and

    the eventual ouster of Mubarak, I used the closest log to news wires I could find i.e. the Times

    Lede Blog and the aforementioned graphic designs to reconstruct a fine-grained description of the

    events. News blogs often can be valuable sources of information on protests. My reconstruction of

    the Cairo events has been mostly based on my readings of various blogs and inferences from news

    photos. The real-time evidence provided by blogs, twitter and Facebook updates, in addition to

    event photos provide an unprecedented level of accuracy in event reconstruction and enforce new

    ways of studying decentralized mass protests.

    5.2 Major Media Announcements During the Egyptian Protests

    Announcements are major addresses to the nation, broadcast from the state television or cable

    TV channels with a national audience. I have collected the following accounts from The New York

    Times Lede Blog. All times are Egyptian local time (EST+7 in January and February 2011).

    1. January 29th: at around 12:30 AM, Mubaraks late night address (coded as 29th), he gives

    concessions, dismisses the government, appoints a Vice President/ Obama talks to the press

    immediately after Mubaraks speech.

    2. February 01st: at around 10 PM (earlier that day the largest protest to date in Tahrir),

    Mubarak gives another speech on the state television. He announces he intends to remain

    in office until the end of his current term. Obama again speaks after Mubaraks speech.

    Note: Worst clashes start on February 02nd and last for two days (2nd and 3rd of February)-

    by 5th or 6th the situation has almost returned to normal.

    3. February 04th: Suleiman makes TV appearances the day beforetotal of two television

    appearances before Friday 04th.

    4. February 08th: Wael Ghonim gives an emotional interview on Monday night (07th) on a

    28See a timeline at: http://bit.ly/pNRvEH

    37

    http://bit.ly/pNRvEHhttp://bit.ly/pNRvEH
  • 8/3/2019 Media Disruption Exacerbates Revolutionary Unrest

    38/43

    cable TV channel and appears in Tahrir the next morning (08th) to give a speech addressing

    the massive crowd in the square.

    5. February 10th: Around 7 pm Egyptian state TV announces an address by Mubarak to be

    broadcast soon-Obama gives a speech around 8:30 PM, Egyptians are making history.Around 10 PM, Mubarak gives a speech on the state television, asserting that he is not

    stepping down and will remain in office till September.

    6. February 11th: Around 6 PM Suleiman gives an address on the state TV announcing that

    President Hosni Mubarak has resigned and handed over power to the countrys military.

    Obama gives a speech at 10 PM.

    6 Appendix 2: Dynamic Models

    6.1 First Dynamic Model, Asymptotics

    We would like to find final thresholds i() for the first dynamic model. In any connected

    network, the elements of the stationary transition matrix are

    =di + 1j(dj + 1)

    .

    In the case of the example in section (2.3.1) for the star network, v = [3/(3 + 2 + 2) 2/(3 + 2 +

    2) 2/(3 + 2 + 2)]T = [3/7 2/7 2/7]T and the final thresholds will be [3/7 2/7 2/7].[0 ]T =

    4 /7 0.57.

    Also as the number of elements in a star network increases, the threshold 2/3: using the

    same technique as above, the final threshold for a k + 1-star (the above example was a 2-star.)is (2k)/(3k + 1) which is always smaller than 2/3, but approaches 2/3 when k becomes large.

    Interestingly this is the final threshold for the fully connected graph with the number of nodes

    n = 3 (i.e. triangle).

    38

  • 8/3/2019 Media Disruption Exacerbates Revolutionary Unrest

    39/43

    6.2 Action Based Dynamics, Examples

    The general equilibrium solution was outlined in section (2.3.3). Here I include the details for a

    number of well-known topologies of networks under the action-based dynamics.

    6.2.1 Star Networks

    Starting at t = 0, the central nodes threshold is 0, the peripheral nodes thresholds are all taken

    to be . In a star network with n agents, at time t,

    if t is odd, the central nodes threshold is

    1 =n 1

    n(1 +

    1

    n2+ . . . +

    1

    (n2)t1

    2

    ),

    and the central node does not act (N). The peripheral nodes will have a threshold of

    i =

    2t+

    1

    4+ . . . +

    1

    4t1

    2

    ,

    and act, (A).

    If t is even (larger than 0), then the central nodes threshold is

    1 =n 1

    n2(1 +

    1

    n2+ . . . +

    1

    (n2)t2

    2

    )

    and the central node acts (A). The peripheral nodes will have a threshold of

    i =

    2t

    +1

    2

    (1 +1

    4

    + . . . +1

    4t2

    2

    ),

    and do not act (N).

    Note the asymptotic cases, when t . When t is odd, the central node does not act (N),

    and the peripheral ones act (A).

    1 n

    n + 1, i 1/3

    39

  • 8/3/2019 Media Disruption Exacerbates Revolutionary Unrest

    40/43

    when t is even, the central node acts (A), and the peripheral ones do not act (N).

    1 1

    n + 1, i 2/3

    6.2.2 Fully Connected Networks

    Consider the case in which the network is fully connected. If there is only one radical agent, then

    there will be no action starting from t = 1, and thresholds are

    n 1

    n(1 +

    1

    n+

    1

    n2+ . . . +

    1

    nt1) 1

    for the radical node. For the others, if t = 1, k(1) =n

    + n2n

    , and for t 2, k(t) is

    1

    nt1(

    n+

    n 2

    n) +

    n 1

    n(1 +

    1

    n+

    1

    n2+ . . . +

    1

    nt2) 1.

    The size of critical mass in a fully connected network in this model is m > n/2. In this case

    at time t the thresholds are

    k =1

    nt1

    (n m

    n

    )

    k =1

    nt1(

    n+

    n 1 m

    n)

    for the critical mass and the ordinary agents respectively. Both of the above go to zero as t .

    From t = 1 onwards both groups act (A).

    References

    Banks, A. S. (2009), Cross-National Time-Series Data Archive, Databanks International.

    http://www.databanksinternational.com.

    Chwe, M. (1999), Structure and strategy in collective action, American Journal of Sociology

    105(1), 12856.

    40

  • 8/3/2019 Media Disruption Exacerbates Revolutionary Unrest

    41/43

    Chwe, M. S. (2001), Rational Ritual, Culture, Coordination, and Common Knowledge, Princeton

    University Press, Princeton, NJ.

    Dunn, A. (2011a), How the internet kill switch didnt kill egypts protests.

    http://bit.ly/gAeqbu.

    Dunn, A. (2011b), Unplugging a nation: State media strategy during egypts january 25 uprising,

    The Fletcher Forum of World Affairs 35(2), 1524.

    Ermakoff, I. (2008), Ruling Oneself Out, A Theory of Collective Abdications, Duke University

    Press, Durham, NC.

    Gould, R. V. (1993), Collective action and network structure, American Sociological Review

    58(2), 182196.

    Gramsci, A. (1971), Prison Notebooks, International Publishers, New York, NY.

    Granovetter, M. S. (1978), Threshold models of collective behavior, The American Journal of

    Sociology 83(6), 142043.

    Hasegawa, T. (1981), The February Revolution: Petrograd, 1917, the University of Washington

    Press, Seattle, WA.

    Hassanpour, N. (2010a), Dynamic models of mobilization in political networks, in Proceedings of

    the 2010 Political Networks Conference, Duke University, Durham, NC.

    Hassanpour, N. (2010b), structural dynamics of collective action in political networks, inAPSA

    2010 Proceedings.

    Hibbs, D. A. (1973), Mass Political Violence: A Cross-National Causal Analysis, John Wiley &

    Sons, New York, NY.

    Historical New York Times (n.d.), The New York Times .

    Historical Washington Post (1978), The Washington Post .

    41

    http://bit.ly/gAeqbuhttp://bit.ly/gAeqbuhttp://bit.ly/gAeqbu
  • 8/3/2019 Media Disruption Exacerbates Revolutionary Unrest

    42/43

  • 8/3/2019 Media Disruption Exacerbates Revolutionary Unrest

    43/43

    Schelling, T. C. (1978), Micromotives and Macrobehavior, W. W. Norton, New York, NY.

    Schumpeter, J. A. (1950), Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy, Harper Prennial, New York, NY.

    Sewell, W. H. (2005), Logics of History: Social Theory and Social Transformation, University Of

    Chicago Press, Chicago, IL.

    Shehata, D., El-Hamalawy, H. and Lynch, M. (2011), Youth movements and social media: Their

    role and impact, Proceedings of From Tahrir: Revolution or Democratic Transition . Video-

    recordings available at http://bit.ly/pOy1QJ.

    Siegel, D. A. (2009), Social networks and collective action, American Journal of Political Science

    53(1), 122138.

    Wade, R. A. (2005), The Russian Revolution, 1917, Cambridge University Press, New York, NY.

    Weber, M. (1958), From Max Weber: Essays in Sociology, Oxford University Press, New York,

    NY.

    Wilkinson, S. (2009), Riots, Annual Review of Political Science 12, 32943.

    http://bit.ly/pOy1QJhttp://bit.ly/pOy1QJ