Marxim Today II

  • Upload
    fattymv

  • View
    217

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 8/11/2019 Marxim Today II

    1/7

    183

    S t a g e s i n S o c i a l D e v e l o p m e n t

    Joan Simon

    (Secretary, History Group of the Communist Party)

    W

    HY is the establishment of stages in

    socia l development important? Perhaps

    this general question should be put before

    surveying the recent discussion in

    Marxism Today

    and summarising the day 's debate on the subject

    organised by the edi tor ia l board and the History

    Group of the Communist Party, a t Marx House on

    March 18th last .

    What i s a t i ssue here i s both the nature and suc

    cession of different forms of society, including ways

    in which the t ransi t ion from one to another takes

    placein other words, the movement and di rec t ion

    of human history. This is, of course, a very large

    subject indeed, and the historical materialist approach

    can hardly be summarised in a sentence . But Lenin,

    as usual, managed briefly to express the essence of

    the mat ter . Pre-Marxist histor iography,

    at best provided an accumulation of raw facts,

    collected at random, and a depiction of certain sides

    of the historical process. By examining theensemble

    of all the opposing tendencies, by reducing them to

    precisely definable conditions of life and production

    of the various classes of society, by discarding sub

    jectivism and arbitrariness in the choice of various

    'leading' ideas or in their interpretation, and by

    disclosing that all ideas and all the various tenden

    cies, without exception, have their roots in the

    condition of the material forces of production,

    Marxism points the way to an all-embracing and

    comprehensive study of the process of the rise,

    development, and decline of social-economic

    formations (The Teachings of Karl M arx, Little

    Lenin Library, p. 24).

    Marx and Engels themselves consistent ly empha

    sised that historical materialism is a scientific ap

    proach to generalisation from the facts. They were,

    therefore, well aware of the immense amount of

    historical research needed before the picture of

    successive social formations could be fil led out.

    Our conception of history is, above all , a guide to

    study, not a lever for construction after the manner

    of the Heg elians , wro te Engels in a letter in 1890.

    All history must be studied afresh, the conditions

    of existence of the different formations of society

    must be individually examined before the attempt

    is made to deduce from them the political, civil-

    legal, aesthetic, philosophic, religious etc. notions

    corresponding to them. Only a little has been done

    here up to now because only a few people have got

    down to it seriously {Selected Correspondence,

    p.473).

    During the present century, par t icular ly in recent

    decades, there has been a wide development of

    histor ica l research, ranging from anthropological

    and archaeological studies to the present day. In

    part icular , much mater ia l has been brought to l ight

    by histor ians working under new condi t ions in the

    U.S.S.R. , China , eastern Europe, India , Afr ica ,

    among them a great ly increased number of Marxist

    historians. The close examination of diflferent forms

    of society, the study of branches of history afresh,

    has ra ised new quest ions about the process of r i se ,

    development and decline of societies in history; in

    particular, about the successive stages in this process

    in the history of class society, after th e disin tegratio n

    of pr imi t ive communal ism.

    This succession has usually been defined in terms

    of a sentence taken from Marx's preface to the

    Critique of Political Economy (1859) in which he

    ends an exposition of the historical materialist

    approach wi th the words :

    In broad outline we can designate the Asiatic,

    the ancient, the feudal and the modern bourgeois

    methods (i.e. modes) of production as so many

    epochs in the progress of the economic formation of

    society. The bourgeois relations of production are

    the last antagonistic form of the social process of

    produ ction (Kerr ed. p. 13).

    The category As ia t ic suggests a regional form,

    thoug h one of major importance , so i t i s by no m eans

    clear that Marx is here designating successive stages

    to be found universally. Nevertheless, this is the

    impression of the Marxist viewpoint given in the

    Fundamentals of Marxism-Leninism (1961) sum

    marised in the phra se: Ma nkin d as a whole has

    passed through four formations^primitive-com

    mu nal, slave, feudal and capitaMst (p. 154). M arx 's

    Asia t ic mod e is , however , omit ted here . (This,

    i t may be note d, was also the case in theShort History

    of the

    C P S U

    (1939) where, in the section on

    historical materialism, the examples cited are that

    from disintegra t ing pr imi t ive communal ism slavery

    (the ancie nt mod e ) emerged, that feudalism is

    replaced by capitalism (p. 110).)

    The As iat i c M ode

    Robin Jardine drew attention to this divergence

    in the contr ibut ion that opened the discussion in

    these pages (July 1961), when he also raised the

    quest ion as to whether the ancient mo de has been

  • 8/11/2019 Marxim Today II

    2/7

    184

    MARXISM TODAY, JUNE 1962

    a universal stage in the history of socio-economic

    development ; whether , for instance , there was an

    epoch of slavery in India and China . Discussion

    has tended to centre around these quest ions. One

    contr ibutor remained unconvinced that there was

    any point at issue, dismissing all queries as fanciful

    specu lations, but his firm reassertion of the M arx ist

    view overcame the divergence between Marxist

    sources only by incorrectly equat ing Ma rx 's Asia t ic

    m od e wi th the stage of barbarism preceding c lass

    society (Sid Douglas, December 1961). On the other

    han d. Professor PuUey bank, professor of Chinese

    at Cambridge, not ing that Chinese and Japanese

    Marxist histor ians have dropp ed the Asia t ic mo de ,

    suggested that whether or not there have been uni

    versa l s tages i s a pseu do-p roblem ; implying that

    the very large questions involved in drawing com

    parisons and connect ions between the development

    of different civilisations cann ot usefully be ap proa che d

    in this way. All this raises important points.

    It would probably be true to say that, so far as the

    majority of Marxist historians are concerned, the

    Asia t ic mod e has long since tac it ly dropp ed ou t

    of use . M ore recently the ancie nt m od e or

    slavery has come openly into question. At the

    International Congress of Historical Sciences held

    at Stockholm in 1960, Academician Zhukov made

    clear that Marxist historians in the Soviet Union no

    longer regard slavery as a universal stage; for in

    stance, i t has not been found to have been the pre

    dominant mode of product ion in Russia a t any t ime,

    nor among the Germanic peoples. Was the f i rst

    civilisation to emerge in India, in the Indus river

    valley (2500-1500 B .C.) a slave society? De v Raj

    Chanana , i n Slavery in Ancient India (1960), only

    advances wi th a cer ta in amo unt of reserve the

    hypo thesis tha t slave labou r could have existed

    both in the country and towns of the Indus civilisa

    tion . Evidence from literary sources bears witness to

    various forms of slavery in India at later periods, but

    not, he suggests, to an epoch of slavery comparable

    with that of the classical period in Greece or Rome.

    In general, historians have found forms of chattel

    slavery nearly everywhere in pre-capitalist societies,

    but the existence of slaves by no means implies that

    slavery was the predominant mode of product ion.

    There was, of course, a marked degree of slavery in

    America in the modern age , but this does not deter

    mine classification as a slave society since the pre

    dominant product ive re la t ions were developing

    capi ta l i st re la t ions. A similar posi t ion probably

    existed in many parts of the world in antiquity, with

    slaves in domest ic work, agricul ture , perhaps even

    craf ts , wi thin the framework of other predominat ing

    product ive re la t ions. There is no evidence that the

    peoples of Afr ica passed through an epoch of

    slavery. On the other hand, Chinese Marxist histor i

    ans agreed that Ch ina has gone throug h an epoch

    of slavery and that the remains of slavery lasted for

    a long tim e after the collapse of slave so cie ty ;

    though i t would seem that there i s wide disagree

    ment on the dat ing of this epoch, some placing i t

    before the eleventh century B.C., others putting its

    lower limit in the period 770-206 B.C., and a third

    view holding that i t lasted up to and during the Wei

    period, A.D. 220-265.^

    What does all this add up to The Asia t i c m od e

    has dropped out , and only in cer ta in areas has

    slavery been shown to be important enough to form

    the basis of the economy. There remains, then, the

    basic succession of social-economic formations:

    pr imi t ive communal ism feudal ism capi ta lism. In

    pract ice this means that feudal ism , having become

    a sort of residuary legatee, now stretches over a vast

    expansefrom primit ive socie t ies up to the t r iumph

    of capitalism, which in some countries is in this

    century, and from China to West Afr ica , perhaps

    even to Mexico. In addition, where investigations of

    primitive societies have indicated the existence of a

    social division of labour the feudal stage has been

    pushed back into what had previously been regarded

    as the pr imi t ive com mu nal stage .

    Obviously a socio-economic stage which covers

    both Ruanda-Urundi today and France in 1788,

    both C hina in 1900 and N orm an E ngland, i s in

    danger of losing any kind of specific character l ikely

    to assist analysis; rather, analysis can only remain

    extremely general unless some sub-divisions are

    arrived at. This is the problem that has, as i t were,

    come into being, no one having deliberately set out

    to extend feudal ism . I t is a problem w hich has

    not hitherto been systematically tackled by Marxists

    but is now a subject for discussion among historians

    in many different countries. This was the main

    question discussed at the meeting held on Ma rch 18th.

    Marx's Approach

    Prel iminary mater ia l prepared by members of the

    History Group, besides making some of the points

    a l ready made, a lso out l ined in more deta i l Marx 's

    own approach, which was anything but schemat ic

    ^

    An exception is N ambood iripad, The National

    Question in Kerala(1952), where an evolution of feudalism

    from the Asiatic mo de is suggested.

    ^

    These points are taken from an article summarising

    recent discussions published in Collectionfor D iscussion

    ofthe Periodisation of ncient Chinese History(1957, in

    Chinese), and translated into German in the G.D.R.

    journal, Zeitschrift filr Geschichtswissenschaft(1962).

    Professor PuUeybank, noting the complexities involved

    in assessing slavery in China, adds that Japanese Marxist

    historians have concluded that there was an epoch of

    slavery in Japa n durin g the millennium following the

    founding of the Ch'in emp ire in 221 B.C. and discerned

    the transition to feudalism during the Sung period from

    A.D. 960.

  • 8/11/2019 Marxim Today II

    3/7

    MARXISM TODAY JUNE 1962

    185

    and dogmatic. The phrase quoted from the preface

    of the Critique should, for instance, be put in

    context if i t is to be properly understood. In the

    int roduct ion to this work (unpubl ished during his

    lifetime) Marx does this, in the course of arguing

    against the bourgeois pol i t ica l economists who

    assume that capitalist productive relations are

    eternal.

    Whenever . . . we speak of production, we always

    have in mind production at a certain stage of social

    development. Hence, it might seem that in order to

    speak of production at all, we must either trace the

    historical process of development through its various

    phases, or declare at the outset that we are dealing

    with a certain historical period, as e.g. with modern

    capitalistic p roduction .

    Nevertheless, Marx continues, certain elements in

    product ion are common to a l l epochs, in that no

    production is conceivable without them; there is

    also, of course, a general uniformity in conditions

    of pro duc tion in so far as the subject, ma nk ind,

    and the object, nature, remain the same . All stages

    of produ ct ion, therefore , have cer ta in landma rks in

    common , comm on purposes . Wha t marks the

    specific characteristics of a particu lar stage are the

    points of departure from the genera l and common

    (pp. 268-269). After developing these points, Marx

    concludes:

    Bourgeois society is but a form resulting from

    the development of antagonistic elements, some

    relations belonging to earlier forms of society are

    frequently to be found in it but in a crippled state

    or as a travesty of their former self as e.g. communal

    property. . . . The last form always considers its

    predecessors as stages leading up to itself and per

    ceives them always one-sidedly, since it is very

    seldom and only under certain conditions th.it it is

    capable of self-criticism. . . . Bourgeois political

    economy first came to understand the feudal, the

    ancient and the oriental societies when self-criticism

    of bourgeo is society had comme nced (p. 301).

    In the published preface Marx turns this analysis

    rou nd of give the same stages preceding the dev eloped

    form of capitalism he is analysing du e weight in their

    own right. But that he himself did not regard this as

    a copmlete picture is made clear by a comment in

    the text of the Critique:

    A closer study of the Asiatic, especially of Indian

    forms of communal ownership, would show how

    from the different forms of primitive communism

    different forms of dissolution . . . developed

    (p .29 n).

    This comment is probably related to other notes

    Marx made when preparing this work (which were

    publ ished in German in 1939 but have not yet been

    transla ted). Here he tentatively distinguishes v arieties

    of the basic form of economy emerging from different

    forms of communal or tribal organisatione.g., in

    addition to the Asiatic (or oriental), the ancient (or

    slave), the Germanic, and possibly the Slavonic

    each tending to produce a somewhat different form

    of the social division of labour: e.g., the separation

    of town and country in the ancient mod e , the

    failure to separate agriculture and crafts in the

    Indian village community leading to a closed circuit

    and inabili ty to draw off the surplus except for

    marginal purposes. It was this last point, the specific

    nat ure of wh at he called the village system

    within Asiatic empires that underlay Marx's differen

    t ia t ion of the Asia t ic mo de .

    Present t rends in Marxist histor iography, there

    fore , do not run counter to Marx but ra ther pursue

    lines upon which he himself had begun to embark.

    If there have been any un -M arxis t trends these lie in a

    too rigid and dogmatic use of a single sentence as

    comprising the whole of the Marxist approach.

    Earlier Forms

    In this connection it was underlined in discussion

    that one of the main dangers, when a t tempt ing to

    assess earlier forms of social development, is to look

    at them through the eyes of the present, in terms of

    conditions proper to the class struggle in capitalist

    society and the nature of the transition to socialism.

    As Marx and Engels always stressed, i t is only in the

    modern capitalist era that the class struggle is nar

    rowed down to the point where two great classes

    confront each other; capi ta l i st product ive re la t ions

    must be overthrown before socialist relations can be

    established. Before this epoch, however, there are

    often a variety of classes and class antagonisms on

    the basis of a variety of forms of ownership and

    exploi ta t ion, and new product ive re la t ions can grow

    within the old framework; i .e., capitalist relations of

    production develop within feudal society, which

    implies in turn a gradual and perhaps very lengthy

    disintegration of feudalism.

    It is, then, obviously incorrect to see the transition

    from one earlier stage of social development to

    another in terms of a straightforward clash in which

    the old ruling class is ousted by a new ruling class,

    already fully fledged, which forthwith assumes

    undisputed control of the sta te . There are no

    historical grounds for conceiving of slave-owners

    ousted in straight conflict with feudal lords, nor for

    that matter feudal lords deposed single-handed by

    the urban bourgeoisie . The same considera t ions

    extend to the realm of ideology. To regard new ideas

    which come to the forefront and play an important

    role as essentially the ideology of the rising exploiting

    class is to fly in the face of the historical record. In

    sixteenth-century Europe, for instance , Protestant

    ideas were primarily the property of the old exploited

    class,

    the peasantry and poorer ar t i sans, and came

    to the forefront as an expression of the tension of

    the times and general sharpening of various aspects

  • 8/11/2019 Marxim Today II

    4/7

    186

    MARXISM TODAY JUNE 1962

    of class Struggle. Only as the new exploiting class

    takes form and takes over does this ideology become

    transformed into a new ruling ideology. (There is a

    parallel in the early history of Christianity in the

    ancient world.)

    The bourgeois revolut ion in England may serve

    as an example . I f the work of Maurice Dobb and

    Christopher Hi l l has shown anything i t i s the com

    plexity of the developments leading up to this, in

    part icular , changing product ive re la t ions and c lass-

    differentiation, but also the role of the state and the

    development and interplay of religious ideas. There

    had been trade and towns for centuries (as of course

    al ready in the ancient world) but though merchant

    wealth and influence grew, i t did not necessarily find

    an out le t in indust ry; the merchant c lass was, to a

    considerable extent, parasitic on the ruling order and

    feudal society remained rooted in the land. It was, in

    fact, chang ing re la t ions of product ion in agriculture,

    spreading through the countryside , tha t were deci

    sive, that determined the possibili ty of a break

    through to which the towns only contr ibuted; whi le

    so far as indust ry was concerned i t was the upthrust

    of the pet ty commodi ty producer that counted most

    in the development of capitalist relationswhat

    Marx cal led the rea l ly revolut ionary way . Feud al

    powers had , to a considerable extent , become c entra l

    ised in the sta te , the mo narchy, w hich had taken over

    many of the functions of the old feudal ruling class;

    hence the revolut ion was di rec ted against the mon

    archy and the chief of these powers curbed or

    removed, clearing the way for the development of

    capi ta li st product ive re la t ions. But there remained a

    long format ive period before the indust r ia l bour

    geoisie came to maturi ty and to power.

    Productive Relations

    All this helps to get earlier stages of class society

    into perspective. Then productive relations in agri

    culture were also decisive, towns and trade usually

    marginal ( trading nations, properly so called, exist

    in the ancient world only in i ts interstices . Capital,

    I, 51), and the role of centralised states in maintain

    ing old forms of social organisation often important.

    A variety of forms of ownership and exploitation

    often coexisted. How, in these circumstances, can the

    stage of socio-economic development be defined?

    The key, as Robert Browning st ressed (Marxism

    Today,

    October 1961) i s not the proport ion of the

    popula t ion engaged in part icular branches of pro

    duct ion, but ra ther the produc tive relations in those

    branches of production where high surplus values are

    produced .

    Thi s marks the

    predominant

    form of

    product ion which largely determines the whole

    comp lex of social institu tion s; i t is the basis on w hich

    there arises a whole superstructure of polit ical, legal

    and cul tura l forms.

    The way in which the surplus is

    appropriated has the c losest bearing on the nature

    and rate of social development.

    Technological advance is , of course , of pr imary

    importance . But the existence of cer ta in tools does

    not necessarily bear witness to a particular level of

    socia l organisa t ion, as Gordon Chi lde was a lways

    careful to point out. The discovery and use of iron

    made possible a great extension of the area under

    cul t ivat ionin Africa and Asia for instanceby

    comparison wi th the Bronze Age when cul t ivat ion

    was confined to narrow st r ips and developed most

    highly in ferti le river valleys. But new methods of

    product ion and socia l organisa t ion did not develop

    universally on similar l ines. Iron tools could, how

    ever, in favourable circumstances make for a high

    development of agricul tura l product ion and the

    increase of the surplus. These were the factors of

    impo rtance to econom ic and socia l development , i .e .,

    not the mere existence and use of the tools but the

    ways in which they could be and were put to use in

    the product ive process.

    Historical Material ism

    To begin at the beginning, the historical materialist

    approach dist inguishes product ion, which is the

    basic activity of human beings, as the foundation of

    all human societies. At a primitive stage of social and

    technological development m en engage in pro duct ion

    in common, having equal access to the means of

    produc t ion. This is the stage of pr imi tive co mm unal-

    ism which Engels, very much on the lines adopted by

    L. H. Morgan, divided into a lower stage of

    savag ery ( in turn sub-divided into a lower, middle

    and higher) and a mo re advanced stage of bar

    ba rism (with a similar triple sub-d ivision). Engels

    defines the primitive stages of humanity as those

    when men appropria ted f inished natura l products

    and acquired knowledge of cattle raising, agriculture

    and new methods of increasing the product ivi ty of

    nature by huma n agency(Origin of the Family (1884),

    ch. 1).

    Class society, the social division of labour, arises

    when a section of society gains control over the basic

    means of product ion and so over those engaged in

    product ion and the product . Men now stand in

    different relations to the means of production and so

    in different relations to each other, relations of

    dominance and dependency. These f ind expression

    in the fact that the surplus available from production

    is appropria ted, in kind or in money, by the exploi t

    ing class, either directly or through a state apparatus.

    There are, as Marx suggested, a variety of ways

    in which the process of disintegration of primitive

    comm unal ism m ay take place , just as there are vary

    ing forms of primitive society. The point emphasised

    in discussion was how relatively easy it is for old

    bonds to be loosened once product ion reaches a

  • 8/11/2019 Marxim Today II

    5/7

    MARXISM TODAY, JUNE 1962

    187

    certain level and a surplus becomes available, and

    for a primitive form of class society to emerge. For

    instance, a priesthood can gain special rights, elders

    can gain dom inatio n over junio rs, clan chieftains c an

    turn landlord. With the social division of labour,

    customthe oldest and strongest bond of primitive

    societiesgives place to differing rights and obliga

    tions enforced by new forms of government. It is not

    profitable to push back the frontiers of feudalism

    too far, wherever any form of social division of

    labour is found, for this is to deprive the term of all

    meaning. But as soon as the social division of

    labour comprises exploitation of a dependent class

    of producers this marks the first stage of class society.

    What form does this exploitation take? At this

    stage society is still predo mina ntly agraria n, e conom ic

    life is relatively regionalised and localised (though

    this does not exclude some trade and towns or even

    some form of money), technology is relatively back

    ward. The basic form of exploitation Is that of tillers

    of the soil by those who have succeeded in getting

    the community's rights over the land it tills vested in

    themselves, or are in a position to draw off the

    surplus, though this is not to say that there are not

    free commoners or peasant proprietors as well.

    These are the characteristics of feudalism but as yet

    in a relatively embryonic form so that the earliest

    stage of class society may, perhaps, best be called

    proto-feudal .

    Development of Class Society

    From this first stage of class society there are

    various directions of development, depending on

    internal conditions, external factors, natural re

    sources. These may favour, for instance, a highly

    centralised appropriation of the surplus by a priestly

    order, appropriation by rising cities or other ruling

    groups, implying centralised forms of organisation

    and the early rise of forms of state power. Marx, for

    instance, emphasised the importance of certain

    physical resources, noting that it is the necessity of

    bringing a natural force under the control of society,

    of economising, of appropriating or subduing it on a

    large scale by the work of man's hand, that first

    plays the decisive part in the history of industry .

    As examples of resulting social relations he cited

    Egyp t and India, noting that the need to predict the

    rise and fall of the Nile created Egyptian astronomy

    and with it the domination of the priests, as directors

    of agriculture , while one of the material bases of

    the power of the state over the small disconnected

    producing organisms in India was the regulation of

    the water supply

    {Capital,

    I, pp. 521-523).

    The creation of a strong centralised state super

    imposed on a society with a low general level of

    economic development, and perhaps persisting forms

    of clan organisation, is likely to have a crystallising

    and arresting effect. For instance, the central govern

    ment in China controlled public works but other

    wise,

    a few larger towns excepted, the whole empire

    wa s resolved into villages ; this made for the

    retention of old forms of production unchanged, a

    tendency reinforced by the fact that state taxes were

    payable in kind

    {Selected Corr.

    p. 70). Here, then,

    Marx is ascribing the stability of despotic forms of

    rule predominantly to a form of the division of

    labour, dependent in part on such physical features

    as large tracts of fertile land, which remained rela

    tively constant, the methods of extracting the surplus

    being such as to consolidate old rather than develop

    new productive relations. Once, of course, there is a

    s trong s tate power the accumulat ion of merchant

    wealth and its flow into industry or agriculture can

    be checked, ways being found of siphoning back the

    surplus and maintain ing the t radi t ional balance.

    The Problem of Arrested Development

    This is the key problem that engaged Marx and

    must concern all Marxist historianswhy develop

    ment in the Orient, for so long so far in advance of

    the rest of the world, was arrested; why the full

    chain of development: earlier societiesfeudalism

    capitalism, was only completed in Europe. Here it

    was noted that Gordon Childe, broaching the

    question from the angle of pre-history, suggested the

    following factors: (a) natural unevenness of histori

    cal development, i .e., that only in certain regions are

    there the conditions for an initial development of

    civilisation;

    {b )

    the interaction between cultures

    drawn together by t rade, communicat ions , etc . ;

    (c) the leapfrogg ing whereby formerly back wa rd

    societies which escape the crisis and breakdown of

    older, more advanced, systems take over from them

    at a potentially higher level.

    An example Childe developed is that of Europe,

    profiting from the early development of a metallur

    gical industry in nearby Egypt and Mesopotamia

    where alone the economic and social preconditions

    for the initial foundation of a metallurgical industry

    existed . Tha t they could mak e use of the produc ts of

    this , and develop the mining of ore for a guaranteed

    market , exempted Europe ans from paying the

    heavy price of starting such an industry from

    scra tch in term s of the rigid class distinctions and

    despotic rule of Egypt of the Pharaohs, which

    eventually fettered development and ended in break

    down ( The Bronze Age ,

    Past and Present,

    No. 12,

    19571.

    The fact that any more elaborate society (before

    the industrial capitalist), when it collapses, tends to

    lapse into a feudal form also suggests that this is the

    most primitive form of class society^temples decay,

    trade an d towns deteriora te, leaving a set-up of a

    feudal type. On the other hand, where slavery

  • 8/11/2019 Marxim Today II

    6/7

    If

    MARXISM TODAY JUNE 1962

    develops as the basic form of productive relations in

    the classical world it is on the foundation of a

    relatively high level of development; for instance, of

    trade and of crafts, with the existence of a monetary

    system and a system of usury. The process in

    Europe was a ided by a varie ty of specia l condi t ions;

    for instance, there were in close proximity to Greece

    other societies at a much lower level from which

    slaves could be obtained. Hence the use-value of

    their labour power was increased by the mere fact

    of t ransport ing them to an area of more advanced

    technology, and since they were brought across the

    sea to a land encirc led by mou nta ins escape was n ot

    easy. This is one of the main contributory factors in

    ensuring that a high surplus value can be obta ined

    (otherwise slaves must be chained, which is a

    hindrance, or well treated which is expensive);

    while the other is that the general technical level of

    production should be relatively high. Here is the

    decisive reason for rejecting the view that slavery is

    the first stage of class society to develop. On the

    contrary, slavery develops within the framework of

    proto-feudal re la t ions, and only in part icular condi

    t ions becomes the predominant mode of product ion.

    Vv'hen it collapses, society lapses into a feudal form

    if at a potentially higher level of development.

    Turning to Africa , i t was noted that there are

    traceable forms of vassalage developing directly out

    of clan or tribal society, side by side with continuing

    primit ive forms of organisa t ion and government . As

    elsewhere in the ancient world, commodi ty produc

    tion was restricted, there were neither a reservoir of

    detribalised labour nor the techniques of using it .

    Early feudal ty pe states were very stable, lasting from

    800 to 900 years, with an eco nom y sufficiently

    developed to support a quite complex social system

    including an embryonic civil service and army.

    There was, however, a notable absence of free urban

    communi t ies. Moreover , forms of landholding and

    relations of dominance and dependency differed so

    greatly from those in feudal Europe that i t does not

    seem useful to apply the same term to them.

    To take another point, i t was suggested that i t is

    possible to part icular ise developments during the

    breakdown of pr imi t ive communal ism af ter the

    agrar ian revolut ion. Fi rst , there i s the consol idat ion

    of forms of clan society based on kins hip which cover

    some inequalit ies but can remain very stable over

    long periods, especially in out of the way conditions,

    e.g., Scotland. Second, the breakdown of clan society

    in the aspect that has been called the Heroic Age

    which often acts as a bridge to the establishment of

    feudal relations at a relatively high level. This is

    found at t imes of migration and new settlement, an

    essential condition being that tribal peoples are in a

    posi t ion to plunder and learn from older and

    richer societies; as, for instance, in the Greek

    Homeric period and the period when the Germanic

    t r ibes invested Rome and swept across Western

    Europe^while i t is possible that such a stage can be

    discerned in Africa, when the Polynesians broke out

    over the Pacific and so on.

    The Road to Feudal ism

    This was the direct road to feudalism as i t was

    traversed in parts of Europe after the collapse of the

    Roman Empire . There was a whole varie ty of

    factors contr ibut ing to cont inued advance in

    Europe, towards a developed form of feudal ism,

    which is of ten typifiedthough wi th much too mu ch

    emphasis on purely legal formsby Norman

    England. Precise ly because this i s the connota t ion

    of feudalism it is difficult to apply the term without

    much qualification to the Chinese Empire or to

    Africa . This i s now the main problem, wi th which

    presumably Marx was preoccupied when he postu

    lated several variations in the basic form of economy

    that emerges from disintegrat ing comm unal socie ties

    of different types. On these fronts a plea was made

    for rehabi l i ta tion of Ma rx 's Asia t ic mo de or

    even severa l modesto enable a separa t ion out of

    widely differing regional variations. At the same time

    it is essential to keep clear the basic common factors

    in such format ions even though they may exhibi t

    many secondary varia t ions; or , to put i t another

    way, the t ransi t ion from communal socie ty to the

    first stage of class society is fundamentally the same

    transition though it may take place in x number of

    ways.

    This is why it may be useful to postulate the

    development of a single basic stage of class society,

    ca l ling this perhaps proto-feu dal . F rom this

    regional variations may develop exhibiting essen

    tially the same basic form of exploitation but in

    which the creation and drawing off of the surplus

    diiTers, implying differing superstructures and rates

    of development.

    These were some of the viewspoints advanced

    which should be considered as such; there was no

    question of formulating a series of conclusions on

    which all those present agreed. The aim was rather

    to define a genera l approach to the problem, sup

    ported by evidence from various fields, which could

    serve as a contr ibut ion to the discussion here and

    the basis for further more specialised discussions in

    the future. Some of the points will be more fully

    developed in later articles, since this is only a digest

    from the record of a detailed exchange of views. It is

    a lso hoped that mater ia l f rom discussions in other

    countries will become available, for the important

    and interesting questions at issue can only be satis

    factorily hammered out as a result of international

    study and discussion.

  • 8/11/2019 Marxim Today II

    7/7

    189

    T h e W e e k o f M a r x i s t T h o u g h t

    i n F r a n c e

    Phyl Gr iffi th-Hentge s

    D

    URING the past few months pol i t ical l i fe

    in France has been galvanised into action

    unprecedented for ma ny years . The central

    problems wereand indeed remainthe s i tua

    tion in Algeria, the danger of fascism created

    by the O.A.S., and the fight to restore democracy.

    The atmosphere became part icularly tense in

    February (a mil l ion Paris ians at tended the funeral

    of the eight anti-fascists brutally killed at a big

    ant i -O.A.S.

    demonstrat ion) and tension s lackened

    only when the cease-fire was signed between de

    Gaulle and the Provis ional Government of the

    Algerian Republic .

    m the middle cf il .is period the Week of

    Marxis t Thought was organised in Paris (Decem

    ber 7th-14th) around the j;eiicral theme:

    Hu ma nism and Dialect ics . This crystal l ised an

    upsurge of intellectual reflection provmg the need

    for a discussion of the philosophical problems of

    the day associated with the increasing political

    activity of the working class and the people as

    a whole.

    I t showed the at t ract ion that Marxism holds

    not only for the working class, but for large

    numbers of in tel lectuals and profess ional people

    doctors , schoolteachers , technicianswho, un

    decided as to their future in present-day France,

    seek a new way forward.

    The result was that 6,000 students and intellec

    tuals gathered on the first day to hear Roger

    Garaudy and Jean Pierre Vigier debate with Jean

    Paul Sartre and Jean Hyppoli te . Never had the

    hal ls of the Mutual i te , t radi t ional meet ing house

    in the Lat in Quarter , seen such crowds. There

    were students on the stairs, in the corridors, in

    annexeswherever they could hear the over-flow

    loudspeakers, and it was a long time before the

    queues in the street gave up the idea of getting in.

    These young people, reputed by some to be twis t-

    crazy, turbulent hoodlums, l is tened to two hours

    of debate on the dialectics of nature in total

    silence.

    In all, some 20,000 people attended the various

    conferences during this Week, organised by the

    Centre d 'Etudes et de Recherches Marxis tes

    (C.E.R.M.) together with the Paris Dis tr ict Com

    mit tee of the French Communis t Party and the

    Union of Communis t Students .

    There were five big meetings which took the

    form of a debate between Marxis ts and non-

    Marxis ts :

    Are dialectics merely a law governing history

    or also a natural law?

    The historian and his time;

    Humanism and Cinema;

    Humanism and the human being;

    Conduct of revolt and militant action.

    At the final meeting at the Mutualite, Roger

    Garaudy, d irector of the C.E.R.M. and member of

    the pol i t ical bureau of the Comm unis t Party ,

    summed up the results of the Week, and Waldeck

    Rochet , deputy general secretary of the Party con

    cluded on the theme: The Communis t Party and

    Culture.

    At the same time., the big debates were accom

    panied by forty-odd study circles for students at

    which Marxist university professors led the dis

    cussion on various subjects connected with the

    univers i ty programmes. Here the aim was nei ther

    a debate nor a purely university course, but rather

    to give the students a Marxist orientation on a

    given subject and to discuss questions of method.

    The wide range of these study circles can be

    judged by taking a few of the subjects at random:

    The ethics of Kant and Marx;

    Can a Marxist understand Pascal?

    The role of the state budget;

    Phenomenology and praxis;

    The role of nucleic acids in heredity;

    Pavlov's theory applied to obstetrics;

    Mayakovsky;

    The class struggle in ancient Greece and Rome;

    The crisis of colonialism and problems of under

    developed countries.

    The organisers decided to draw in to the work

    of the Week not only intellectuals but a much

    wider general public, and for this they sought the

    help of

    rUniversite Nouvelle,

    already well know n

    for i ts courses on Marxism. Three conferences

    were held at which the teachers of

    I'Universite

    Nouvelle

    answ ered questions arising from the big

    debates , explain ing the basic principles of M arxism

    in history, science and philosophy.