28
1 Macro-economics The national economy pages introduce macro-economic concepts, models, and theories, and explains how macro- economic problems are analysed, and policies evaluated. Macro-economic theory Macro-economics is traditionally broken down into macro- economic theory and macro-economic policy. Macro-economic theory involves the construction and use of models of the whole, ‘macro’, economy. Economists build such models so that they can explain the structure of an economy, and the role and significance of the parts that make up this structure. Macro-economic models also help the economist understand how the separate components of the macro- economy are related. Macro-economic models are also used to help economists and policy makers make predictions, or forecasts, about the economy, and about the effect of changes in one economic variable, such as exchange rates, on other variables, such as prices and output. Macro-economic policy objectives Macro-economic policy refers to how governments and other policy makers compensate for market failures in order to improve economic performance and well-being. Improvements in performance begin with the setting of policy objectives, which include the achievement of sustainable economic growth and development, stable prices and full employment. Some of the objectives set are potentially in conflict with each other, which means that, in attempting to achieve one objective, another one is ‘sacrificed’. For example, in attempting to achieve full employment in the short-term price inflation may occur in the longer term. Policy targets In order to achieve policy objectives, policy makers will set targets to aim for. Targets are often fixed, and widely known, such as the current UK inflation target of 2%, but they may also be flexible and less widely known, such as exchange rate and employment targets. Policy instruments Once policy objectives and targets are established, policy makers need to choose between alternative policy tools, or instruments. These instruments are the levers of control of the macro-economy and include monetary instruments such as interest rates, and fiscal instruments such as tax rates and government spending. Policy disagreements Policy disagreements occur for a number of reasons. Macro- economic policy is often shaped by long held normative beliefs about what is essential, and this influences the choice of model, objective, target, and instrument. For example, some economists put the eradication of poverty above the maximisation of corporate profits, and this will strongly influence their belief about how the tax system should be used. In addition, different economists may use different economic models and forecasting techniques, and this may lead them to disagree about the need for, size of, or timing of policy changes. Market Failures Types of market failure A market failure is a situation where free markets fail to allocate resources efficiently. Economists identify the following cases of market failure: Productive and allocative inefficiency Markets may fail to produce and allocate scarce resources in the most efficient way. Monopoly power Markets may fail to control the abuses of monopoly power. Missing markets Markets may fail to form, resulting in a failure to meet a need or want, such as the need for public goods, such as defence, street lighting, and highways. Incomplete markets Markets may fail to produce enough merit goods, such as education and healthcare. De-merit goods Markets may also fail to control the manufacture and sale of goods like cigarettes and alcohol, which have less merit than consumers perceive. Negative externalities Consumers and producers may fail to take into account the effects of their actions on third-parties, such as car drivers, who may fail to take into account the traffic congestion they create for others. Third-parties are individuals, organisations, or communities indirectly benefiting or suffering as a result of the actions of consumers and producers attempting to pursue their own self interest. Property rights Markets work most effectively when consumers and producers are granted the right to own property, but in many cases property rights cannot easily be allocated to certain resources. Failure to assign property rights may limit the ability of markets to form. Information failure Markets may not provide enough information because, during a market transaction, it may not be in the interests of one party to provide full information to the other party. Unstable markets Sometimes markets become highly unstable, and a stable equilibrium may not be established, such as with certain agricultural markets, foreign exchange, and credit markets. Such volatility may require intervention.

Macro Econ

Embed Size (px)

DESCRIPTION

Macro Economics I for University Learners

Citation preview

  • 1

    Macro-economics

    The national economy pages introduce macro-economic

    concepts, models, and theories, and explains how macro-

    economic problems are analysed, and policies evaluated.

    Macro-economic theory

    Macro-economics is traditionally broken down into macro-

    economic theory and macro-economic policy. Macro-economic

    theory involves the construction and use of models of the

    whole, macro, economy. Economists build such models so that they can explain the structure of an economy, and the role

    and significance of the parts that make up this

    structure. Macro-economic models also help the economist

    understand how the separate components of the macro-

    economy are related.

    Macro-economic models are also used to help economists and

    policy makers make predictions, or forecasts, about the

    economy, and about the effect of changes in one economic

    variable, such as exchange rates, on other variables, such as

    prices and output.

    Macro-economic policy objectives

    Macro-economic policy refers to how governments and other

    policy makers compensate for market failures in order to

    improve economic performance and well-being. Improvements

    in performance begin with the setting of policy objectives,

    which include the achievement of sustainable economic growth

    and development, stable prices and full employment. Some of

    the objectives set are potentially in conflict with each other,

    which means that, in attempting to achieve one objective,

    another one is sacrificed. For example, in attempting to achieve full employment in the short-term price inflation may

    occur in the longer term.

    Policy targets

    In order to achieve policy objectives, policy makers will set

    targets to aim for. Targets are often fixed, and widely known,

    such as the current UK inflation target of 2%, but they may

    also be flexible and less widely known, such as exchange rate

    and employment targets.

    Policy instruments

    Once policy objectives and targets are established, policy

    makers need to choose between alternative policy tools, or

    instruments. These instruments are the levers of control of the

    macro-economy and include monetary instruments such as

    interest rates, and fiscal instruments such as tax rates and

    government spending.

    Policy disagreements

    Policy disagreements occur for a number of reasons. Macro-

    economic policy is often shaped by long held normative beliefs

    about what is essential, and this influences the choice of model,

    objective, target, and instrument. For example, some

    economists put the eradication of poverty above the

    maximisation of corporate profits, and this will strongly

    influence their belief about how the tax system should be used.

    In addition, different economists may use different economic

    models and forecasting techniques, and this may lead them to

    disagree about the need for, size of, or timing of policy

    changes.

    Market Failures

    Types of market failure

    A market failure is a situation where free markets fail to

    allocate resources efficiently. Economists identify the

    following cases of market failure:

    Productive and allocative inefficiency

    Markets may fail to produce and allocate scarce resources in

    the most efficient way.

    Monopoly power

    Markets may fail to control the abuses of monopoly power.

    Missing markets

    Markets may fail to form, resulting in a failure to meet a need

    or want, such as the need for public goods, such as defence,

    street lighting, and highways.

    Incomplete markets

    Markets may fail to produce enough merit goods, such as

    education and healthcare.

    De-merit goods

    Markets may also fail to control the manufacture and sale of

    goods like cigarettes and alcohol, which have less merit than

    consumers perceive.

    Negative externalities

    Consumers and producers may fail to take into account the

    effects of their actions on third-parties, such as car drivers,

    who may fail to take into account the traffic congestion they

    create for others. Third-parties are individuals, organisations,

    or communities indirectly benefiting or suffering as a result of

    the actions of consumers and producers attempting to pursue

    their own self interest.

    Property rights

    Markets work most effectively when consumers and producers

    are granted the right to own property, but in many cases

    property rights cannot easily be allocated to certain resources.

    Failure to assign property rights may limit the ability of

    markets to form.

    Information failure

    Markets may not provide enough information because, during a

    market transaction, it may not be in the interests of one party to

    provide full information to the other party.

    Unstable markets

    Sometimes markets become highly unstable, and a stable

    equilibrium may not be established, such as with certain

    agricultural markets, foreign exchange, and credit markets.

    Such volatility may require intervention.

  • 2

    Inequality

    Markets may also fail to limit the size of the gap between

    income earners, the so-called income gap. Market transactions

    reward consumers and producers with incomes and profits, but

    these rewards may be concentrated in the hands of a few.

    Remedies

    In order to reduce or eliminate market failures, governments

    can choose two basic strategies:

    Use the price mechanism

    The first strategy is to implement policies that change the

    behaviour of consumers and producers by using the price

    mechanism. For example, this could mean increasing the price

    of harmful products, through taxation, and providing subsidies for the beneficial products. In this way, behaviour is changed through financial incentives, much the same way that

    markets work to allocate resources.

    Use legislation and force

    The second strategy is to use the force of the law to change

    behaviour. For example, by banning cars from city centers, or

    having a licensing system for the sale of alcohol, or by

    penalising polluters, the unwanted behaviour may be

    controlled.

    In the majority of cases of market failure, a combination of

    remedies is most likely to succeed.

    Exchange rate policy

    The exchange rate of an economy affects aggregate demand

    through its effect on export and import prices, and policy

    makers may exploit this connection.

    Deliberately altering exchange rates to influence the macro-

    economic environment may be regarded as a type of monetary

    policy. Changes in exchanges rates initially work there way

    into an economy via their effect on prices.

    For example, if 1 exchanges for $1.50 on the foreign

    exchange market, a UK product selling for 10 in the UK will

    sell for $15 in New York. If the exchange rate now appreciates,

    so that 1 buys $1.60, the UK product in New York will now

    sell for $16. Assuming that demand in New York is price

    inelastic, this is good news for UK exporters because revenue

    in USDs will rise. However, if demand is elastic in New York,

    the effect of the appreciation of the Pound would be damaging

    to UK exporters.

    If the UK also imports goods from the USA, the rise in the

    exchange rate would mean that a $10 US product is now

    cheaper in London, falling from 6.67p to 6.25p. Importers do

    relatively well from the appreciation of the pound, in that the

    cost of imported raw materials or finished goods falls.

    Therefore, whenever the exchange rate changes there will be a

    double effect, on both import and export prices. Changes in

    import and export prices will lead to changes in import and

    export volumes, causing changes in import spending and

    export revenue.

    Exchange rates can be manipulated so that they deviate from

    their natural equilibrium rate. To stimulate exports, rates would

    be held down, and to reduce inflationary pressure rates would

    be kept up. While the Bank of England does not specifically

    target the exchange rate, the Monetary Policy Committee

    (MPC) will take exchange rates into account. Clearly, the MPC

    would prefer a relatively high rate, as this reduces the price of

    imports and works against inflationary pressure. However, the

    MPC must keep an eye on export competitiveness, and, if rates

    rise excessively, UK exports will become uncompetitive.

    How exchange rates are manipulated

    Exchange rates can be manipulated by buying or selling

    currencies on the foreign exchange market. To raise the value

    of the pound the Bank of England buys pounds, and to lower

    the value, it sells pounds. Rates can also be manipulated

    through interest rates, which affect the demand and supply of

    Sterling via their effect on inflows of hot money. Altering

    exchange rates is commonly regarded as a type of monetary

    policy.

    Effects of a reduction in the exchange rate

    Assuming the economy has an output gap, a reduction in the

    exchange rate will reduce export prices, and, assuming demand

    is elastic, export revenue will increase.

    A fall in the exchange rate will also raise import prices, and

    assuming elasticity of demand, import spending will fall. The

    combined effect is an increase in AD and an improvement in

    the UK balance of payments.

    Cost push inflation

    A fall in the exchange rate is inflationary for a second reason -

    the cost of imported raw materials adds to production costs and

    creates cost-push inflation.

  • 3

    Evaluation of exchange rate policy

    The main advantage of manipulating exchange rates is that,

    because a large share of UK output is traded internationally,

    changes in exchange rates will have a powerful effect on AD.

    For example, lowering exchange rates, called devaluation, can:

    1. Raise aggregate demand

    2. Increase national output (GDP)

    3. Create jobs, amplified through the multiplier effect

    4. In addition, assuming the demand for imports and exports are price sensitive (price elastic), devaluation

    will lead to an improvement in the balance of

    payments - although this can also lead to inflation

    Alternatively, raising exchange rates (revaluation) can:

    1. Help reduce excessive aggregate demand

    2. Keep inflation down

    3. Although the export sector may suffer and jobs might be lost

    On balance, UK policy makers in recent years have preferred

    to allow the financial markets to determine exchange rates,

    rather than manipulate them for policy objectives. The last time

    exchange rates were directly targeted was between 1985 and

    1992, when the UK shadowed movements in the Deutschmark,

    and then, from 1990 to 1992, when the UK became a member

    of the exchange rate fixing Exchange Rate Mechanism

    (ERM).

    Sustainable growth

    Economic growth occurs when real output increases over time.

    Real output is measured by Gross Domestic Product (GDP) at

    constant prices, so that the effect of price rises on the value of

    national output is removed.

    Sustainable economic growth means a rate of growth which

    can be maintained without creating other significant economic

    problems, especially for future generations. There is clearly a

    trade-off between rapid economic growth today, and growth in

    the future. Rapid growth today may exhaust resources and

    create environmental problems for future generations,

    including the depletion of oil and fish stocks, and global

    warming.

    Periods of growth are often triggered by increases in aggregate

    demand, such as a rise in consumer spending, but sustained

    growth must involve an increase in output. If output does not

    increase, any extra demand will push up the price level.

    Growth based on debt

    In terms of sustainability, it may be argued that growth based

    on short-term public debt, rather than long term productivity, is

    unsustainable - hence worries about the build-up of sovereign

    debt in Europe.

    PPFs and economic growth

    For an economy to continue to grow in the future, it needs to

    increase its capacity to grow. An increase in an economys productive potential can be shown by an outward shift in the

    economys PPF.

    Standards of living

    Gross domestic product per capita is often regarded as the key

    indicator of the standards of living of the citizens of an

    economy, and of their economic welfare, though broader

    measures of economic welfare are increasingly used in

    preference to narrow GDP measures.

    Measuring growth

    GDP is the official base measure of output used in most

    economies, including the UK. Gross measurements record the

    output of all goods and services, including capital goods which

    have been purchased to replace existing capital goods.

    Replacing capital is called capital consumption, or

    depreciation. The alternative to Gross output is Net output,

    which indicates that depreciation is taken into account and

    deducted from the gross measurement.

    Domestic product is the value of all UK goods and services

    produced, including those produced for export. It does not

  • 4

    include property income which flows into and out of the UK

    economy. Property income refers to income from various types

    of investment abroad, such as profits and dividends. When this

    is added, the measure becomes national product, called Gross

    National Product, GNP.

    Growth can be measured as an annual percentage increase in

    real GDP, and in terms of a general trend. The trend rate of

    growth is the long term non-inflationary average rate of growth

    for an economy. In the UK it is around 2.5% per year.

    Why is stable growth an economic objective?

    If growth rises significantly above or below the trend rate, the

    economy is experiencing excessive growth or low growth. If

    the rate becomes negative for at least 2 quarters in succession,

    the economy is in recession.

    The trade (growth) cycle

    Changes in real national income tend to be cyclical, but it is

    desirable that this cycle is stable rather than unstable. Unstable

    growth is popularly called boom and bust.

    Although an economys growth is cyclical in nature, the underlying trend can be derived from annual growth statistics. Trends can be calculated by using a technique called

    moving averages. The UK trend rate over the last 25 years is

    around 2.5%.

    Excessive growth can lead to:

    1. Goods and service inflation

    2. House price inflation

    3. Wage inflation

    4. Labour shortages

    5. Falling savings

    6. Excessive credit

    7. Trade difficulties

    Low or negative growth can lead to:

    1. Goods deflation

    2. House price deflation

    3. Labour surpluses

    4. Unemployment

    5. Excessive debt burden

    6. Public sector debt

    Predicting turning points

    Changes, or turning points, in the level of national income can

    be predicted and confirmed using economic indicators. Leading

    indicators typically monitor changes in interest rates, business

    confidence and new housing starts-ups - all of which provides

    clues to the next turning point in an economys growth cycle. Changes in these indicate that GDP is likely to change in 12 to

    18 months time. The OECDs main indicator, the Composite Leading Indicator (CLI), tracks deviations from the long-term

    trend, which provides an early warning system for policy

    makers.

    A short leading indicator can be used to monitor changes in

    consumer credit and new car registrations. A lagging indicator

    monitors changes in unemployment and real investment and

    confirms that the turning point has occurred. All indicators help

    policy makers decide when to implement a policy and by what

    degree.

    The advantages of growth

    Economic growth is associated with a number of material

    benefits which increase economic welfare. These include the

    following:

    Higher GDP per capita

    A rise in real national income means that wages and profits are

    likely to rise. Assuming a stable population, this will raise GDP

    per capita.

    More public and merit goods

    A growing economy means that the public sector can receive

    more tax revenue and more resources can be allocated to public

    and merit goods, such as more roads, hospitals and schools.

    Positive externalities

    Public and merit goods generate considerable external benefits.

    More hospitals and schools mean a healthier and better-

    educated population, which generates other economic benefits

    in terms of the effectiveness of the labour force, and increases

    in long-term aggregate supply.

    More employment

    Growth is clearly likely to stimulate demand for labour, and it

    is likely that more people will be employed and fewer

    unemployed.

    The disadvantages of growth

    Economic growth also brings some costs which reduce

    economic welfare, including:

    Negative externalities

    As production and consumption increase, negative

    externalities, such as pollution and congestion, are likely to

    arise. There is also the likelihood of increased depletion of

    non-renewable resources, such as fossil fuels.

    Inflation and balance of payments difficulties

    Too rapid a rate of growth can also lead to two significant

    economic problems: inflationary pressure and a balance of

    payments deficit, as imports rise to satisfy an increasingly

    active household sector.

    Widening income gap

    Growth can also widen the distribution of income, because

    some groups may benefit much more than others. Certainly in

    the UK, the relative income gap has widened during the growth

    years of 1992 to 2008.

    Limitations of using GDP per capita over time

    There are several limitations of using GDP statistics for

    comparing changes in economic well-being over time,

    including:

    Changes in the distribution of income

    Average GDP per capita may rise over time, but the

    distribution of income may widen. For example, a rise in the

    mean average income per head can be misleading because the

  • 5

    average may rise because just a few of the population increase

    their personal income. Indeed, the mean average can rise, but

    the median, the mid-point in a range of numbers, can fall.

    Differences in hours worked

    People may be working longer hours, in which case some of

    the growth may be through increased work, rather than through

    increased efficiency.

    Unpaid work is not recorded

    People may undertake unpaid work, and this may not be

    officially recorded.

    Price changes

    Prices are unlikely to remain constant over time, so GDP

    figures must be converted to at constant prices and measured

    from a base year. This process is called indexing and is required to avoid the distorting effects of inflation.

    Negative externalities

    The quality of life may suffer as GDP increases, although this

    is not included in GDP statistics. For example, more driving

    raises GDP, but also adds to CO2 emissions, which can reduce

    the quality of life.

    Changes in the quality of products

    Over time the quality of products tends to increase, so a given

    amount of income per capita in 2010 may purchase a higher

    quality product than it did in 2000. This is certainly true with

    high-technology consumer products, like PCs, laptops and

    mobile phones.

    Limitations of using GDP statistics for international

    comparisons

    Limitations of using GDP statistics for international

    comparisons include:

    Differences in the distribution of income

    Although two countries may have similar GDP per capita

    figures, the distribution of income in each country may be very

    different.

    Differences in hours worked

    As when comparing a country over time, the number of hours

    worked to generate a given level of income may be quite

    different. For example, workers in the UK tend to work longer

    hours than those in France, and this would falsely inflate the

    GDP figures in the UK relative to France.

    International price differences

    International prices will also vary. This is significant because

    an individual's purchasing power is based on price in relation to

    income. To solve this problem, GDP statistics can be re-

    calculated in terms of purchasing power. The purchasing power

    of a currency refers to the quantity of the currency needed to

    purchase a given unit of a good, or common basket of goods

    and services. Purchasing power is clearly determined by the

    relative cost of living and inflation rates in different countries.

    Achieving purchasing power parity means equalising the

    purchasing power of two currencies by taking into account cost

    of living and inflation differences.

    For example, if we simply convert GDP in Japan to US dollars

    using market exchange rates, relative purchasing power is not

    taken into account, and the validity of the comparison is

    weakened. By adjusting rates to take into account local

    purchasing power differences, known as PPP adjusted

    exchange rates, international comparisons are more valid.

    Difficulty of assessing true values

    The true value of public goods and merit goods, such as

    defence, education and transport infrastructure is largely

    unknown. This means that it is difficult to compare two

    countries with very different levels of spending on these goods

    and assets.

    The unofficial economy

    Similarly, the existence of a large unofficial economy may

    make comparisons based on official GDP very misleading. For

    example, comparing the official GDP of the UK and Russia

    may be misleading because of the size of Russia's unofficial

    economy. While all countries have unofficial economies, their

    size and significance can vary considerably.

    Currency conversion

    GDP figures for different countries must be converted to a

    common currency, such as the US dollar, and this may give

    misleading figures. For some countries, exchange rates against

    the US dollar may be unrepresentative of the true value of the

    currency, especially where international trade is relatively

    small. In such cases, converting to US dollars may significantly

    under-value national output. This explains why conversion to

    purchasing power parity is often preferred to conversion to US

    dollars.

    Sustainable development and quality of life

    In recognising that economic welfare is not simply about

    economic growth, in 1999 the UK government introduced a

    policy for sustainable development, and refined this further in

    2005.

    Sustainable development is considered in four main categories

    using 20 main indicators, and 68 indicators in total. The

    categories are:

    1. Sustainable consumption and production

    2. Climate change and energy

    3. Natural resource protection and enhancing the environment

    4. Creating sustainable communities and a fairer world

    National income

    National income is the total value a countrys final output of all new goods and services produced in one year. Understanding

    how national income is created is the starting point for

    macroeconomics.

    The national income identity

    This relationship is expressed in the national income identity,

    where the amount received as national income is identical to

    the amount spent as national expenditure, which is also

  • 6

    identical to what is produced as national output. Throughout

    macroeconomics the terms income, output and expenditure are

    interchangeable.

    See also: the circular flow of income

    National income accounts

    Since the 1940s, the UK government has gathered detailed

    records of national income, though the collection of basic data

    goes back to the 17th Century. The published national income

    accounts for the UK, called the Blue Book, measure all the economic activities that add value to the economy.

    Adding value

    National output, income and expenditure, are generated when

    there is an exchange involving a monetary transaction.

    However, for an individual economic transaction to be

    included in aggregate national income it must involve the

    purchase of newly produced goods or services. In other words,

    it must create a genuine addition to the value of the scarce resources. For example, a transaction that involves selling a

    second-hand good, and which was new two years ago does not

    add to national income, though the original production and

    purchase does. Transactions which do not add value are called

    transfers, and include second-hand sales, gifts and welfare

    transfers paid by the government, such as disability allowance

    and state pensions.

    The creation of national income

    The simplest way to think about national income is to consider

    what happens when one product is manufactured and sold.

    Typically, goods are produced in a number of 'stages', where

    raw materials are converted by firms at one stage, then sold to

    firms at the next stage. Value is added at each, intermediate,

    stage, and, at the final stage, the product is given a retail selling

    price. The retail price reflects the value added in terms of all

    the resources used in all the previous stages of production.

    Final output

    In accounting terms, only the value of final output is recorded.

    To avoid the problem of double counting, only the value of the

    final stage, the retail price, is included, and not the value added

    in all the intermediate stages - the costs of production, plus

    profits. In short, national income is the value of all the final

    output of goods and services produced in one year.

    Example

    For example, consider the production of a motor car which has

    a retail price of 25,000. This price includes 21,000 for all the

    costs of production (6,000 for components, 10,000 for

    assembly and 5,000 for marketing) plus 4,000 for profit. To

    avoid double-counting, the national income accounts only

    record the value of the final stage, which in this case is the

    selling price of 25,000.

    When goods are bought second-hand, the transaction does not

    add new value and will not be included in national output. If

    second-hand goods are included, double-counting will occur,

    and this would falsely inflate the value of national income.

    For example, if the car in question is sold in two years time for 15,000 it would provide the owner with money, but the sale

    will not add to national income. If it were included in national

    income, it would make the value of the car 35,000 - the initial

    25,000 plus the second hand value of 15,000. This is clearly

    not the case, so any future second-hand sales are not included

    when valuing national income. Such second-hand transactions

    are called transfers.

    Calculating national income

    Any transaction which adds value involves three elements expenditure by purchasers, income received by sellers, and the

    value of the goods traded. For example, if a student purchases a

    textbook for 30, spending = 30, income to the bookseller =

    30, and the value of the book = 30. All of the transactions in

    an economy can be looked at in this way, giving us three ways

    to measure national income.

    There are three methods of calculating national income:

    1. The income method, which adds up all incomes received by the factors of production generated in the

    economy during a year. This includes wages from

    employment and self-employment, profits to firms,

    interest to lenders of capital and rents to owners of

    land.

    2. The output method, which is the combined value of the new and final output produced in all sectors of the

    economy, including manufacturing, financial services,

    transport, leisure and agriculture.

    3. The expenditure method, which adds up all spending in the economy by households and firms on new and

    final goods and services by households and firms.

    Chained value measurement

    The components of national output are valued according to

    their importance to the overall economy. The weights used

    were based on estimates made every 5 years, but, from 2003,

    an annual adjustment to the weightings was introduced to

    improve the reliability of the weighting - a process called

    annual chain linking. This allowed for a more up-to-date, and

    therefore a more accurate measure of changes to the level of

    national income.

    The main components of UK National Income

    In 2010, UK Gross National income at current prices was

    1,458 billion, up from 1,392 in 2009.

    The percentage contribution of different components in the

    three different measures are shown below:

    National Income, by 'type' of income:

    GDP - Income method, 2010, BnTaxes - subsidies,

    179Other - inc rents, 168Corporate profits,

    307Wages and salaries, 799Taxes - subsidiesOther

    - inc rentsCorporate profitsWages and salaries

    With around 30m workers in the UK, and over 2m firms*,

    wages and profits contribute the majority of income in the UK.

    (*2.15m according to the ONS)

    National output, by sector of the economy:

    GDP - Output method, 2010, BnConstruction,

    90Water and services, 148Energy, 172Government

    inc education, 261Health activities, 104Distribution

  • 7

    and transport, 238Manufacturing, 131Mining,

    28Agriculture, 7.5ConstructionWater and

    servicesEnergyGovernment inceducationHealth

    activitiesDistribution

    andtransportManufacturingMiningAgriculture

    In terms of output, services dominate the UK economy, with

    manufacturing a distant second. However, this is a typical

    profile for a developed economy the more developed the economy the more that income is allocated towards purchasing

    services rather than manufactured goods.

    National spending, by sector

    GDP - Expenditure method, 2010, BnImports,

    %A3476bnExports, %A3436bnInvestment,

    %A3224bnGovernment, %A3338bnNon-profit

    organisations, %A338bnHousehold spending,

    %A3900bnImportsExportsInvestmentGovernmentNo

    n-profitorganisationsHouseholdspending

    In terms of spending, UK households account for the majority

    of spending, export spending the next most

    important. Spending on capital goods by firms, and spending

    on public goods, merit goods, and transfers by government

    accounts for the rest.

    Source - ONS

    Gross Domestic Product - GDP

    Gross Domestic Product (GDP) is the most important

    aggregate of national income for accounting purposes, and for

    economic analysis. In the UK, GDP is derived from the gross

    value added (GVA) of all the UK's individual producers,

    industries or sectors over one year, using the 'output' method.

    Current and constant prices

    As the level of economic activity between households and

    firms increases, output is also likely to increase. However,

    under certain circumstances the price level may also be driven

    up.

    The nominal value of national income, or any other aggregate,

    is the value of national output at the prices existing in the year

    that national income is measured - that is, at current prices. In

    simple terms the nominal value of national income can be found by multiplying the quantity of output by the retail

    (market) price of this output.

    If demand increases at an unsustainable rate, resources become

    increasingly scarce, and firms will raise prices. Similarly,

    wages are likely to rise as the labour market clears and

    unemployment falls. The more that workers are needed the

    higher the wage rate. This will act as an incentive for workers

    to enter this industry. The combined effect of higher wages and

    prices is that the nominal value of national output may be

    driven up, rather than its real value.

    To find the real value of changes in output under inflationary

    conditions, the effects of any general price increase (price

    inflation) must be taken into account. This is done by holding

    prices constant from a starting measure, called the base year.

    Example

    For example, if, in a hypothetical economy, 100 pens are

    produced and sold for 1 each in year 1, the nominal value of

    these transactions is 100. If, in year 2, inflation pushes prices

    up to 1.20p per pen, but, as in year 1, only 100 pens are sold,

    the nominal value at current (year 2) prices will rise to 120.

    However, the nominal value has only risen because of

    inflation, so to adjust the nominal value to find the real value

    we take the constant price of 1 which is the price of pens at the start of our measurement in the base year, year 1. However,

    if in year 3 110 pens are sold at 1.20, the nominal value at

    current prices will be 132 (an increase of 32%), but the real

    value at constant (year 1) prices will be only 110 (a real

    increase of only 10%). Therefore, to arrive at real values the

    economist must take out the effects of price inflation by

    holding prices constant in terms of the prices existing in the

    base year.

    Recent changes to UK national income

    After a sustained period of rising national income from the

    previous recession, which ended in 1992, the UK, like most

    other advanced economies, entered a recession in the third

    quarter of 2008. The recession lasted until the fourth quarter of

    2009. Growth returned in 2010, but, following negative growth

    in the fourth quarter of 2010, the UK economy failed to recover

    fully, with growth in the third quarter of 2011 a modest 0.5%,

    with a further drop to 0.2% in the last quarter of 2011.

    Performance indicators

    The performance of an economy is usually assessed in terms of

    the achievement of economic objectives. These objectives can

    be long term, such as sustainable growth and development, or

    short term, such as the stabilisation of the economy in response

    to sudden and unpredictable events, called economic shocks.

    Economic indicators

    To know how well an economy is performing against these

    objectives economists employ a wide range of economic

    indicators. Economic indicators measure macro-economic

    variables that directly or indirectly enable economists to judge

    whether economic performance has improved or deteriorated.

    Tracking these indicators is especially valuable to policy

    makers, both in terms of assessing whether to intervene and

    whether the intervention has worked or not.

    Useful indicators include:

    1. Levels of real national income, spending, and output. National income, output, and spending are three key

    variables that indicate whether an economy is

    growing, or in recession. Like many other indicators,

    income, output, and spending can also be measured in

    per capita (per head) terms.

    2. Growth in real national income.

    3. Investment levels and the relationship between capital investment and national output.

    4. Levels of savings and savings ratios.

    5. Price levels and inflation.

    6. Competitiveness of exports.

  • 8

    7. Levels and types of unemployment.

    8. Employment levels and patterns of employment.

    9. Trade deficits and surpluses with specific countries or the rest of the world.

    10. Debt levels with other countries.

    11. The proportion of debt to national income.

    12. The terms of trade of a country.

    13. The purchasing power of a country's currency.

    14. Wider measures of human development, including literacy rates and health care provision. Such

    measures are included in the Human Development

    Index (HDI).

    15. Measures of human poverty, including the Human Poverty Index (HPI).

    The circular flow of income

    National income, output, and expenditure are generated by the

    activities of the two most vital parts of an economy, its

    households and firms, as they engage in mutually beneficial

    exchange.

    Households

    The primary economic function of households is to supply

    domestic firms with needed factors of production - land, human

    capital, real capital and enterprise. The factors are supplied by

    factor owners in return for a reward. Land is supplied by

    landowners, human capital by labour, real capital by capital

    owners (capitalists) and enterprise is provided by

    entrepreneurs. Entrepreneurs combine the other three factors,

    and bear the risks associated with production.

    Firms

    The function of firms is to supply private goods and services to

    domestic households and firms, and to households and firms

    abroad. To do this they use factors and pay for their services.

    Factor incomes

    Factors of production earn an income which contributes to

    national income. Land receives rent, human capital receives a

    wage, real capital receives a rate of return, and enterprise

    receives a profit.

    Members of households pay for goods and services they

    consume with the income they receive from selling their factor

    in the relevant market.

    Production function

    The simple production function states that output (Q) is a

    function (f) of: (is determined by) the factor inputs, land (L),

    labour (La), and capital (K), i.e.

    Q = f (L, La, K)

    The Circular flow of income

    Income (Y) in an economy flows from one part to another

    whenever a transaction takes place. New spending (C)

    generates new income (Y), which generates further new

    spending (C), and further new income (Y), and so on. Spending

    and income continue to circulate around the macro economy in

    what is referred to as the circular flow of income.

    The circular flow of income forms the basis for all models of

    the macro-economy, and understanding the circular flow

    process is key to explaining how national income, output and

    expenditure is created over time.

    Injections and withdrawals

    The circular flow will adjust following new injections into it or

    new withdrawals from it. An injection of new spending will

    increase the flow. A net injection relates to the overall effect of

    injections in relation to withdrawals following a change in an

    economic variable.

    Savings and investment

    The simple circular flow is, therefore, adjusted to take into

    account withdrawals and injections. Households may choose to

    save (S) some of their income (Y) rather than spend it (C), and

    this reduces the circular flow of income. Marginal decisions to

    save reduce the flow of income in the economy because saving

    is a withdrawal out of the circular flow. However, firms also

    purchase capital goods, such as machinery, from other firms,

    and this spending is an injection into the circular flow. This

    process, called investment (I), occurs because existing

    machinery wears out and because firms may wish to increase

    their capacity to produce.

    The public sector

    In a mixed economy with a government, the simple model

    must be adjusted to include the public sector. Therefore, as

    well as save, households are also likely to pay taxes (T) to the

    government (G), and further income is withdrawn out of the

    circular flow of income.

    Government injects income back into the economy by spending

    (G) on public and merit goods like defence and policing,

    education, and healthcare, and also on support for the poor and

    those unable to work.

  • 9

    Including international trade

    Finally, the model must be adjusted to include international

    trade. Countries that trade are called open economies, the households of an open economy will spend some of their

    income on goods from abroad, called imports (M), and this is

    withdrawn from the circular flow.

    Foreign consumers and firms will, however, also wish to buy

    domestic products, called exports (X), and this is an injection

    into the circular flow.

    The multiplier effect

    Every time there is an injection of new demand into the

    circular flow there is likely to be a multiplier effect. This is

    because an injection of extra income leads to more spending,

    which creates more income, and so on. The multiplier effect

    refers to the increase in final income arising from any new

    injection of spending.

    The size of the multiplier depends upon households marginal decisions to spend, called the marginal propensity to consume

    (mpc), or to save, called the marginal propensity to save (mps).

    It is important to remember that when income is spent, this

    spending becomes someone elses income, and so on. Marginal propensities show the proportion of extra income allocated to

    particular activities, such as investment spending by UK firms,

    saving by households, and spending on imports from abroad.

    For example, if 80% of all new income in a given period of

    time is spent on UK products, the marginal propensity to

    consume would be 80/100, which is 0.8.

    The following general formula to calculate the multiplier uses

    marginal propensities, as follows:

    1/1-mpc

    Hence, if consumers spend 0.8 and save 0.2 of every 1 of

    extra income, the multiplier will be:

    1/1-0.8

    = 1/0.2

    = 5

    Hence, the multiplier is 5, which means that every 1 of new

    income generates 5 of extra income.

    The multiplier effect in an open economy

    As well as calculating the multiplier in terms of how extra

    income gets spent, we can also measure the multiplier in terms

    of how much of the extra income goes in savings, and other

    withdrawals. A full open economy has all sectors, and therefore, three withdrawals savings, taxation and imports.

    This is indicated by the marginal propensity to save (mps) plus

    the extra income going to the government - the marginal tax

    rate (mtr) plus the amount going abroad the marginal propensity to import (mpm).

    By adding up all the withdrawals we get the marginal

    propensity to withdraw (mpw). The multiplier can now be

    calculated by the following general equation:

    1/1- mpw

    Applying the multiplier effect

    The multiplier concept can be used any situation where there is

    a new injection into an economy. Examples of such situations

    include:

    1. When the government funds building of a new motorway

    2. When there is an increase in exports abroad

    3. When there is a reduction in interest rates or tax rates, or when the exchange rate falls.

    The downward or 'reverse' multiplier

    A withdrawal of income from the circular flow will lead to a

    downward multiplier effect. Therefore, whenever there is an

    increased withdrawal, such as a rise in savings, import

    spending or taxation, there is a potential downward multiplier

    effect on the rest of the economy.

    Economic integration

    There are several stages in the process of economic integration,

    from a very loose association of countries in a preferential

    trade area, to complete economic integration, where the

    economies of member countries are completely integrated.

    A regional trading bloc is a group of countries within a

    geographical region that protect themselves from imports from

    non-members in other geographical regions, and who look to

    trade more with each other. Regional trading blocs increasingly

    shape the pattern of world trade - a phenomenon often referred

    to as regionalism.

    Stages of integration

  • 10

    Preferential Trade Area

    Preferential Trade Areas (PTAs) exist when countries within a

    geographical region agree to reduce or eliminate tariff barriers

    on selected goods imported from other members of the area.

    This is often the first small step towards the creation of a

    trading bloc. Agreements may be made between two countries

    (bi-lateral), or several countries (multi-lateral).

    Free Trade Area

    Free Trade Areas (FTAs) are created when two or more

    countries in a region agree to reduce or eliminate barriers to

    trade on all goods coming from other members. The North

    Atlantic Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) is an example of

    such a free trade area, and includes the USA, Canada, and

    Mexico.

    Customs Union

    A customs union involves the removal of tariff barriers

    between members, plus the acceptance of a common (unified)

    external tariff against non-members. This means that members

    may negotiate as a single bloc with 3rd

    parties, such as with

    other trading blocs, or with the WTO.

    Common Market

    A common market is the first significant step towards full

    economic integration, and occurs when member countries trade

    freely in all economic resources not just tangible goods. This means that all barriers to trade in goods, services, capital, and

    labour are removed. In addition, as well as removing tariffs,

    non-tariff barriers are also reduced and eliminated. For a

    common market to be successful there must also be a

    significant level of harmonisation of micro-economic policies,

    and common rules regarding monopoly power and other anti-

    competitive practices. There may also be common policies

    affecting key industries, such as the Common Agricultural

    Policy (CAP) and Common Fisheries Policy (CFP) of the

    European Single Market (ESM).

    Economic Union

    Economic Union is a term applied to a trading bloc that has

    both a common market between members, and a common trade

    policy towards non-members, but where members are free to

    pursue independent macro-economic policies.

    Monetary Union

    Monetary union is the first major step towards macro-economic

    integration, and enables economies to converge even more

    closely. Monetary union involves scrapping individual

    currencies, and adopting a single, shared currency, such as the

    Euro for the Euro-16 countries, and the East Caribbean Dollar

    for 11 islands in the East Caribbean. This means that there is a

    common exchange rate, a common monetary policy, including

    interest rates and the regulation of the quantity of money, and a

    single central bank, such as the European Central Bank or the

    East Caribbean Central Bank.

    Video

    Fiscal Union

    A fiscal union is an agreement to harmonise tax rates, to

    establish common levels of public sector spending and

    borrowing, and jointly agree national budget deficits or

    surpluses. The majority of EU states agreed a fiscal compact in

    early 2012, which is a less binding version of a full fiscal

    union.

    Economic and Monetary Union

    Economic and Monetary Union (EMU) is a key stage towards

    compete integration, and involves a single economic market, a

    common trade policy, a single currency and a common

    monetary policy.

    Complete Economic Integration

    Complete economic integration involves a single economic

    market, a common trade policy, a single currency, a common

    monetary policy (EMU) together with a single fiscal policy, tax

    and benefit rates in short, complete harmonisation of all policies, rates, and economic trade rules.

    Foreign Direct Investment (FDI)

    FDI refers to the flow of capital between countries. According

    to the United Nations Conference for Trade and Development

    (UNCTAD), FDI is 'investment made to acquire lasting

    interest in enterprises operating outside of the economy of the

    investor.'*

    FDI is distinguished from 'portfolio' investment in that, as well

    as being 'lasting', it means that the investor has control over the

    assets invested in. A single flow of capital between two

    countries is described as outward for the investing country and

    inward for the recipient country. FDI is undertaken by both

    private sector firms and governments.

    FDI associated with cross-border mergers and aquisions can be

    horizontal - where the firms are at the same stage of

    production; vertical - where firms are at different stages of

  • 11

    production; and conglomerate - where firms are in different

    industries.

    *Source: UNCTAD.ORG : http://www.unctad.org

    The growth of FDI has accompanied the rise of globalisation.

    According to the World Investment Report, FDI flows in 2013

    increased to $1.45 trillion, with developing countries

    increasing their share of inflows to (a record level of) 54 per

    cent, with Asia now ahead of both the EU and USA.

    The benefits of investing abroad

    Investing overseas can generate many benefits to multinational

    organisations, including:

    1. Transport costs can be reduced by locating manufacturing plant within a consuming country. This

    is especially important for bulk increasing products,

    such as motor vehicles.

    2. Inward investors gain easier access to a countrys markets, especially where the product can be made

    with local ingredients. For example, it makes clear

    commercial sense for McDonalds to establish local

    restaurants that use local ingredients, rather than

    export ingredients from the USA. In addition,

    investing firms gain access to a range of resources,

    including cheap or skilled labour and local knowledge

    and expertise.

    3. Firms that build factories and plant in other territories can exploit of economies of scope, such as spreading

    fixed management costs between territories, or where

    plant in one territory can be used to produce output for

    many territories.

    4. Firms based outside one trading bloc can avoid barriers to trade such as tariffs and quotas, as in the

    case of Japanese car producers, such as Toyota and

    Nissan, locating in the EU.

    Investment income

    Outward investment can lead to increased overseas investment

    income for a country, including:

    1. Profits from overseas subsidiaries.

    2. Dividends from owning shares in overseas firms.

    3. Interest payments, from lending abroad, such as lending by UK banks.

    FDI in the balance of payments accounts appears in two ways:

    1. The initial outflow of FDI is entered as an outflow (debit) on the capital account

    2. The resulting investment income is entered as an inflow (credit) on the current account.

    Inward investment

    Countries receiving inward investment gain in a number of

    ways, including:

    1. An increase in GDP, initially through the FDI itself, but this will be followed by a positive multiplier effect

    on the receiving economy so that the final increase in

    national income is greater than the initial injection of

    FDI.

    2. The creation of jobs.

    3. An increase in productive capacity, which can be illustrated by a shift to the right in the Aggregate

    Supply (AS) or the Production Possibility Frontier

    (PPF).

    4. Producers have access to the latest technology from abroad.

    5. Less need to import because goods are produced in the domestic economy.

    6. The positive effect on the countrys capital account - FDI represents an inflow (credit) on the capital

    account.

    7. FDI is a way of compensating for the lack of domestic investment, and can help 'kick-start' the process of

    economic development.

    Global FDI

    Global FDI has declined as a result of the financial crisis and

    global recession.

    Comparative advantage

    It can be argued that world output would increase when the

    principle of comparative advantage is applied by countries to

    determine what goods and services they should specialise in

    producing. Comparative advantage is a term associated with

    19th Century English economist David Ricardo.

    Ricardo considered what goods and services countries should

    produce, and suggested that they should specialise by

    allocating their scarce resources to produce goods and services

    for which they have a comparative cost advantage. There are

    two types of cost advantage absolute, and comparative.

    Absolute advantage means being more productive or cost-

    efficient than another country whereas comparative advantage

    relates to how much productive or cost efficient one country is

    than another.

    Example

    In order to understand how the concept of comparative

    advantage might be applied to the real world, we can consider

    the simple example of two countries producing only two goods

    - motor cars and commercial trucks.

    Comparative advantage

  • 12

    Using all its resources, country A can produce 30m cars or 6m

    trucks, and country B can produce 35m cars or 21m trucks.

    This can be summarised in a table.

    In this case, country B has the absolute advantage in producing

    both products, but it has a comparative advantage in trucks

    because it is relatively better at producing them. Country B is

    3.5 times better at trucks, and only 1.17 times better at cars.

    However, the greatest advantage - and the widest gap - lies

    with truck production, hence Country B should specialise in

    producing trucks, leaving Country A to produce cars.

    Economic theory suggests that, if countries apply the principle

    of comparative advantage, combined output will be increased

    in comparison with the output that would be produced if the

    two countries tried to become self-sufficient and allocate

    resources towards production of both goods. Taking this

    example, if countries A and B allocate resources evenly to both

    goods combined output is: Cars = 15 + 15 = 30; Trucks = 12 +

    3 = 15, therefore world output is 45 m units.

    Opportunity cost ratios

    It is being able to produce goods by using fewer resources, at a

    lower opportunity cost, that gives countries a comparative

    advantage.

    The gradient of a PPF reflects the opportunity cost of

    production. Increasing the production of one good means that

    less of another can be produced. The gradient reflects the lost

    output of Y as a result of increasing the output of X.

    Having a comparative advantage in X, Country A sacrifices

    less of Y than Country B. In terms of two countries producing

    two goods, different PPF gradients mean different opportunity

    costs ratios, and hence specialisation and trade will increase

    world output.

    Only when the gradients are different will a country have a

    comparative advantage, and only then will trade be beneficial.

    Identical PPFs

  • 13

    If PPF gradients are identical, then no country has a

    comparative advantage, and opportunity cost ratios are

    identical. In this case, international trade does not confer any

    advantage.

    Criticisms

    However, the principle of comparative advantage can be

    criticised in a several ways:

    1. It may overstate the benefits of specialisation by ignoring a number of costs. These costs include

    transport costs and any external costs associated with

    trade, such as air and sea pollution.

    2. The theory also assumes that markets are perfectly competitive - in particular, there is perfect mobility of

    factors without any diminishing returns and with no

    transport costs. The reality is likely to be very

    different, with output from factor inputs subject to

    diminishing returns, and with transport costs. This

    will make the PPF for each country non-linear and

    bowed outwards. If this is the case, complete

    specialisation might not generate the level of benefits

    that would be derived from linear PPFs. In other

    words, there is an increasing opportunity cost

    associated with increasing specialisation. For

    example, it may be that the maximum output of cars

    produced by country A is only 20 million (compared

    with 30), and the maximum output of trucks produced

    by country B might only be 16 million instead of 21

    million. Hence, the combined output from trade might

    only be 46 million units (instead of the 51 million

    units initially predicted).

    4. Complete specialisation might create structural unemployment as some workers cannot transfer from

    one sector to another.

    5. Relative prices and exchange rates are not taken into account in the simple theory of comparative

    advantage. For example if the price of X rises relative

    to Y, the benefit of increasing output of X increases.

    6. Comparative advantage is not a static concept - it may change over time. For example, nonrenewable

    resources can slowly run out, increasing the costs of

    production, and reducing the gains from trade.

    Countries can develop new advantages, such as

    Vietnam and coffee production. Despite having a long

    history of coffee production it is only in the last 30

    years that it has become a global player. seeing its

    global market share increase from just 1% in 1985 to

    20% in 2014, making it the world's second largest

    producer.

    7. Many countries strive for food security, meaning that even if they should specialise in non-food products,

    they still prefer to keep a minimum level of food

    production.

    8. The principle of comparative advantage is derived from a highly simplistic two good/two country model.

    The real world is far more complex, with countries

    exporting and importing many different goods and

    services.

    9. According to influential US economist Paul Krugman, the continual application of economies of scale by

    global producers using new technology means that

    many countries, including China, can produce very

    cheaply, and export surpluses. This, along with an

    insatiable demand for choice and variety, means that

    countries typically produce a variety of products for

    the global market, rather than specialise in a narrow

    range of products, rendering the traditional theory of

    comparative advantage almost obsolete.

  • 14

    10. However, the underlying principle of comparative advantage can still be said to give some shape to the pattern of world trade, even if it is becoming less

    relevant in a globalised world.

    Trade liberalisation

    Two opposing forces have shaped the changing pattern of

    world trade over the last 200 years; the promotion of free trade

    and the protection against free trade. Trade protection is the

    process of erecting barriers to trade, such as taxes on imports,

    called tariffs, and trade liberalisation is the process of making

    trade free from such barriers.

    The advantages of free trade

    It can be argued that free trade creates the following

    advantages:

    Specialisation and comparative advantage

    Free trade encourages countries to specialise and benefit from

    the application of the principle of comparative advantage.

    Increased world output

    If countries specialise and trade, world output is likely to

    increase as scarce resources will be used more efficiently. Mass

    production will generate considerable economy of scale, which

    reduce average costs.

    Increased competition and lower prices

    Free trade increases competition, which generates further

    benefits, including lower prices, greater use of new technology

    and technology transfer between countries. Free trade will also

    encourage the breakdown of domestic monopolies, and provide

    greater choice for consumers and firms.

    Higher quality

    Open economies are likely to see an increase in the quality of

    products available as overseas firms compete on non-price

    factors, such as design and reliability.

    Terms of trade

    A countrys terms of trade measures a countrys export prices in relation to its import prices, and is expressed as:

    For example, if, over a given period, the index of export prices

    rises by 10% and the index of import prices rises by 5%, the

    terms of trade are:

    110 x 100 / 105

    = 104.8

    This means that the terms of trade have improved by 4.8%.

    When the terms of trade rise above 100 they are said to be

    improving and when they fall below 100 they are said to be

    worsening.

    Improving terms of trade

    If a country's terms of trade improve, it means that for every

    unit of exports sold it can buy more units of imported goods.

    So potentially, a rise in the terms of trade creates a benefit in

    terms of how many goods need to be exported to buy a given

    amount of imports. It can also have a beneficial effect on

    domestic cost-push inflation as an improvement indicates

    falling import prices relative to export prices.

    However, countries may suffer in terms of falling export

    volumes and a worsening balance of payments.

    The danger of an improving terms of trade is that it can worsen

    the balance of trade if UK and overseas consumers are elastic

    in their response to the relative export and import price

    changes.

    Worsening terms of trade

    A worsening terms of trade indicates that a country has to

    export more to purchase a given quantity of imports. According

    to the Prebisch-Singer hypothesis, this fate has befallen many

    developing countries given the general decline in commodity

    prices in relation to the price of manufactured goods. However,

    globalisation has tended to reduce the price of manufactured

    goods over the past 15 years, so the advantage that

    industrialised countries had over developing countries may be

    falling.

    The impact of globalisation has tended to halt the decline in the

    terms of trade of developing economies.

    The WTO

    The WTO attempts to promote free and fair trade an increasingly difficult task, which it undertakes with varying

    success. The WTO was established in 1995 when it replaced

    the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT). It has its

    headquarters in Geneva, Switzerland and, by 2012, had 153

    member countries, including China, which was the last major

    nation to join.

    The purpose of the WTO is to promote free and fair trade

    through multilateral talks and negotiations, and to arbitrate

    between countries that are in dispute. The WTO itself claims

    that, unlike GATT that preceded it, its rules of trade have been

    worked out by the direct involvement of all countries, and not

    just a few powerful ones.

    Evaluation of the WTO

    Trade liberalisation clearly brings many economic and political

    benefits, but many argue that the WTO has had limited success

    in certain areas. The main criticisms are:

    Too few agreements

    Critics argue that the number of trade disputes settled through

    the WTO's DSU (Dispute Settlement Understanding) is

    inadequate given the number of disputes. However, the number

    of settlements did rise from 20 in 1990 to 157 in 2007. But

    still, by January 2008, only 136 of the 370 cases had reached

    the full panel process.

    (Sources: UNCTAD and WTO).

    Failure to confront ethical issues

    Many argue that the WTO has failed to confront ethical issues,

    such as the use of child labour and poor working conditions in

    developing economies.

    Failure to tackle environmental issues

  • 15

    Similarly, many argue that it has failed to tackle environmental

    issues, such as the depletion of global fish stocks,

    deforestation, and climate change.

    Takes too long to arbitrate

    Critics also complain that the WTO takes too long to arbitrate

    and settle disputes. For example, it can take over five years

    from the initial receipt of a complaint from one member to the

    final panel ruling.

    See: Example of WTO process

    Favours the powerful

    Critics also argue that the WTO has an inbuilt bias favouring

    developed and powerful nations and trading blocs such as the

    USA and the EU, and operating against weaker, developing

    ones.

    Failure to promote multilateralism

    Despite the WTO operating as a multilateral organisation,

    many member countries and trading blocs favour bilateral

    discussions with partners or competitors. This is because

    bilateral negotiations can be fully focussed and relatively quick

    to complete. The result is that many countries prefer to bypass

    the WTO process, and deal directly with other countries. The

    failure of the most recent round of WTO negotiations, the

    Doha round, is widely regarded as evidence of the inherent

    problems of multilateral discussions. While the WTO is likely

    to argue that it encourages such agreements when they do not

    have a negative impact on third parties, it is very difficult to

    find cases where third-party countries are not, at least

    indirectly, negatively affected by a specific bilateral agreement.

    The Doha round

    The most recent round of talks is the Doha Round, which

    began in 2001, with major summit meetings in Cancun,

    Mexico, Hong Kong, and Davos in 2003, 2005, and 2007

    respectively. The Doha round of talks is also called the

    development round, reflecting its emphasis on promoting free

    trade for the benefit of developing nations. In particular, the

    Cancun talks focussed on three areas: reducing agricultural

    subsidies and industrial tariffs imposed by developed nations,

    which limit the market access of developing nations;

    harmonising competition rules within different countries; and

    helping poor countries.

    The talks collapsed for a number of reasons. Significantly,

    while the US and EU failed to agree reductions in agricultural

    support, many developing countries refused to agree new

    investment rules which would make it easier for multinationals

    to invest in their countries. Since the collapse, the USA and EU

    have returned to bilateral agreements with favoured nations,

    rather than entering into multilateral agreements. This

    highlights a major limitation of the WTO in not gaining a

    complete consensus that multilateral negotiations should be the

    method of choice of its members.

    The failure of the Doha round means that the rich countries of

    the world still protect themselves from goods produced by the

    poor nations. By 2005, average agricultural tariffs imposed by

    the USA and EU were 60%, against average industrial tariffs of

    only 5%*.

    Trade protectionism

    Trade protection is the deliberate attempt to limit imports or

    promote exports by putting up barriers to trade. Despite the

    arguments in favour of free trade and increasing trade

    openness, protectionism is still widely practiced.

    The motives for protection

    The main arguments for protection are:

    Protect sunrise industries

    Barriers to trade can be used to protect sunrise industries, also

    known as infant industries, such as those involving new

    technologies. This gives new firms the chance to develop,

    grow, and become globally competitive.

    Protection of domestic industries may allow they to develop a

    comparative advantage. For example, domestic firms may

    expand when protected from competition and benefit from

    economies of scale. As firms grow they may invest in real and

    human capital and develop new capabilities and skills. Once

    these skills and capabilities are developed there is less need for

    trade protection, and barriers may be eventually removed.

    Protect sunset industries

    At the other end of scale are sunset industries, also known as

    declining industries, which might need some support to enable

    them to decline slowly, and avoid some of the negative effects

    of such decline. For the UK, each generation throws up its own

    declining industries, such as ship building in the 1950s, car

    production in the 1970s, and steel production in the 1990s.

    Protect strategic industries

    Barriers may also be erected to protect strategic industries,

    such as energy, water, steel, armaments, and food. The implicit

    aim of the EUs Common Agricultural Policy is to create food

    security for Europe by protecting its agricultural sector.

    Protect non-renewable resources

    Non-renewable resources, including oil, are regarded as a

    special case where the normal rules of free trade are often

    abandoned. For countries aiming to rely on oil exports lasting

    into the long term, such as the oil-rich Middle Eastern

    economies, limiting output in the short term through

    production quotas is one method employed to conserve

    resources.

    Deter unfair competition

    Barriers may be erected to deter unfair competition, such as

    dumping by foreign firms at prices below cost.

    Save jobs

    Protecting an industry may, in the short run, protect jobs,

    though in the long run it is unlikely that jobs can be protected

    indefinitely.

    Help the environment

    Some countries may protect themselves from trade to help limit

    damage to their environment, such as that arising from CO2

    emissions caused by increased production and transportation.

    Limit over-specialisation

    Many economists point to the dangers of over-specialisation,

    which might occur as a result of taking the theory of

    comparative advantage to its extreme. Retaining some self-

  • 16

    sufficiency is seen as a sensible economic strategy given the

    risks of global downturns, and an over-reliance on international

    trade.

    In addition to the economic arguments for protection, some

    protection may be for political reasons.

    Economic development

    Economic development is a broader concept than

    economic growth and reflects social and economic

    progress and requires economic growth. Growth is an

    important and necessary condition for development, but it

    is not a sufficient condition. Growth alone cannot

    guarantee development.

    Indicators of development

    The extent to which a country has developed may be assessed

    by considering a range of narrow and broad indicators,

    including per capita income, life expectancy, education, and

    the extent of poverty.

    The Human Development Index (HDI)

    The HDI was introduced in 1990 as part of the United Nations

    Development Programme (UNDP) to provide a means of

    measuring economic development in three broad areas - per

    capita income, health and education. The HDI is used to track

    changes in the global position of specific countries over time.

    Each year the UNDP produces a development report providing

    an update of changes during the year, along with a report on a

    special theme, such as global warming and development, and

    migration and development.

    The introduction of the index was an explicit acceptance that

    development is a considerably broader concept than growth and

    should include a range of social and economic factors.

    The HDI has two main features:

    A scale from 0 (no development) to 1 (complete development).

    A composite index based on three equally weighted

    components:

    1. Longevity, measured by life expectancy at birth

    2. Knowledge, measured by adult literacy and number of years children are enrolled at school

    3. Standard of living, measured by real GDP per capita at purchasing power parity

    What the figures mean:

    An index of 0 0.6 means low development - for example, in 2006 Ethiopia had an index number of

    0.38 while in Bangladesh it was 0.51

    An index of 0.61 0.85 means medium development for example, in 2006 Croatia had an index of 0.85, while Brazil and the Ukraine had 0.80 and 0.79

    respectively.

    An index of greater than 0.90 means high development - for example, the HDI for France and

    the UK in 2006 were 0.95 and 0.94. respectively.

    The HDI is a very useful means of comparing the level of

    development of countries. GDP per capita alone is clearly too

    narrow an indicator of economic growth, and fails to indicate

    other aspects of development, such as enrolment in school and

    longevity. Hence, the HDI is seen as a broader and more

    encompassing indicator of development than GDP, though

    GDP still provides one third of the index.

    Life expectancy

    A variety of factors may contribute to differences in life

    expectancy, such as the stability of food supplies, war and the

    incidence of disease and natural disasters.

    According to World Bank figures, between 1980 and 1998

    average life expectancy rose from 61 to 67 years, with the

    largest increases occurring in low and middle income

    countries. However, the changes are not evenly distributed, and

    in many countries in sub-Saharan Africa, life expectancy is

    falling due to the AIDS epidemic.

    (Source: www.worldbank.org/depweb/)

    Adult literacy

    Adult literacy is usually defined as the percentage of those

    aged 15 and above who are able to read and write a simple

    statement on their everyday life.

    More extensive definitions of literacy include those based on

    the International Adult Literacy Survey. This survey tests the

    ability to understand text, interpret documents, and perform

    simple arithmetic.

    GDP per capita

    GDP per capita is the commonest indicator of material

    standards of living, and hence is included in the index of

    development. It is found by measuring Gross Domestic Product

    in a year, and dividing it by the population.

    Evaluation of the HDI

    Despite the widespread use of the HDI, there are a number of

    criticisms that are often made. These include:

    1. The HDI index is for a single country, and as such does not distinguish between different rates of

    development within a country, such as between urban

    and traditional rural communities.

    2. Critics argue that the equal weighting between the three main components is rather arbitrary.

    3. Development is ultimately about freedom, and there is nothing in the index which directly measures this. For

    example, access to the internet might be regarded by

    many as a freedom which improves the quality of

    individual's lives.

    4. As with GDP per capita, the more narrow measure of living standards, there is no indication of the

    distribution of income.

  • 17

    5. In addition, the HDI excludes many aspects of economic and social life that could be regarded as

    contributing to or constraining development, such as

    crime, corruption, poverty, deprivation and negative

    externalities.

    6. GDP is calculated in terms of purchasing power parity, and this value can frequently change.

    Poverty

    The alleviation of poverty is increasingly seen as a

    fundamental economic objective. Poverty creates many

    economic costs in terms of the opportunity cost of lost output,

    the cost of welfare provision, and the private and external costs

    associated with exclusion from normal economic activity.

    These costs include the costs of unemployment, crime, and

    poor health. In addition, the poor have little disposable income,

    and so cannot spend and generate income for firms and jobs for

    other individuals.

    Widespread poverty is also an important constraint preventing

    economic development.

    There are two ways to define poverty:

    Absolute poverty

    Absolute poverty is poverty that is unrelated to a particular

    economic or social context. In other words it is a general

    definition of poverty which is valid at all times and for all

    economies. Agreeing such a definition is extremely hard to do.

    One straightforward definition of absolute poverty is being unable to subsist that is, unable to eat, drink, have shelter and clothing. A common universal measure of extreme poverty

    is .receiving less than $1.25 a day. Extreme poverty if defined

    as not being able to buy enough food to survive.

    Relative poverty

    It can be argued that poverty is best understood in a relative

    way what is poor in New York is not the same as in Mumbai.

    One approach is to look at deprivation, the poor being defined as those who are deprived from the benefits of a

    modern economy, such as clean water and education.

    The Human Poverty Index - HPI

    The Human Poverty Index (HPI), which was introduced in

    1997, is a composite index which assesses three elements of

    deprivation in a country - longevity, knowledge and a decent

    standard of living.

    There are two indices; the HPI 1, which measures poverty in developing countries, and the HPI-2, which measures poverty

    in OCED developed economies.

    HPI-1 (for developing countries)

    The HPI for developing countries has three components:

    1. The first element is longevity, which is defined as the probability of not surviving to the age of 40.

    2. The second element is knowledge, which is assessed by looking at the adult literacy rate.

    3. The third element is to have a decent standard of living. Failure to achieve this is identified by the

    percentage of the population not using an improved

    water source and the percentage of children under-

    weight for their age.

    As a region of the world, Sub-Saharan Africa has the highest

    level of poverty as a proportion of total population, at over

    60%. The second poorest region is Latin America, with 35% of

    its population living in poverty.

    HPI-2 (for developed - OECD countries)

    The indicators of deprivation are adjusted for advanced

    economies in the following ways:

    1. Longevity, which for developed countries is considered as the probability at birth of not surviving

    to the age of 60.

    2. Knowledge is assessed in terms of the percentage of adults lacking functional literacy skills, and;

    3. A decent standard of living is measured by the percentage of the population living below the poverty

    line, which is defined as those below 50% of median

    household disposable income, and social exclusion,

    which is indicated by the long-term unemployment

    rate.

    Part 2: IS Curve

    This video is the second in a set of four explaining

    the Hicks-Hansel model of Keynes' theory of Aggregate

    Demand, specifically the IS-LM interpretation. This model

    is very important to short run macroeconomics and

    attempts to explain shifts in the aggregate demand curve.

    These topics are usually taught in an intermediate

    Macroeconomics class, and these videos are intended as

    a visual aid to further your understanding of the

    models.This video covers the investment demand curve,

    integrates investment into the aggregate demand curve,

    introduces the IS-curve and provides an overview of the

    factors that determine the slope and position of the IS

    curve. If you did not view the introductory video, you can

    find it here

    The I - S stands for Investment and Saving and the IS

    curve displays the equilibrium in the goods and service

    market for various interest rates.

    Investment

  • 18

    To begin we revisit the aggregate demand equation.

    While investment was previously considered to be

    exogenous, we're going to see how it relates to interest

    rate, so it becomes endogenous and loses the bar above

    the variable.

    There is, however, still a portion of investment that is

    unaffected by interest rate. It is represented by "I-bar"

    and called exogenous investment. Next we have interest

    rate, represented by "i". And as you see by the minus

    sign, investment is negatively related to the interest rate.

    The degree to which firms adjust investment spending

    relative to the interest rate is called interest sensitivity

    which is represented by "b". This coefficient will be

    anywhere between zero and one.

    Investment Curve

    Now we'll examine this relationship graphically.

    Investment is on the x-axis and interest rate is on the y-

    axis. Typically the independent variable (in this case,

    investment) is put on the Y-axis, but we will be using

    interest rate as the independent variable when we graph

    the IS curve, so it's put here now for consistency.

    Exogenous investment determines the initial level. Again,

    a higher interest rate results in lower investment

    spending. A high interest rate means firms reduce their

    investment spending to avoid high interest payments. A

    low interest rate means firms can increase their capital

    spending and pay relatively low interest.

    Slope & Position

    The slope of the investment curve is determined by the

    interest sensitivity coefficient. A high interest sensitivity

    results in a more gradual slope. In this case, there is a

    drastic increase in investment spending in reaction to a

    relatively small reduction in the interest rate, because of

    the higher sensitivity.

    The position of the curve is determined by the exogenous

    investment. An increase would result in an outward shift

    of the curve.

    Incorporated Investment into the Aggregate Demand

    Equation

  • 19

    Now we're going to incorporate this investment function

    into the aggregate demand equation. Recall in the first

    video we separated the components into exogenous and

    endogenous to arrive at this formula. Investment was

    previously grouped with the exogenous components, but

    our new formula has endogenous as well as exogenous

    components. The "I-bar" will go back into the exogenous

    group, while the interest and sensitivity coefficient move

    to the back of the equation.

    Review: AD for aggregate demand. A-bar for exogenous

    demand, lower case c is the marginal propensity to

    consume. lower case t for tax rate, Y for income, lower

    case b for interest sensitivity and i for interest rate. You

    will notice that all of the lower case variables are rates

    between zero and one.

    Aggregate Demand Curve with Investment

    We're going to display this function graphically, and just

    as before the 45 degree line where aggregate demand =

    income is our equilibrium criteria. Here is upward sloping

    demand function. Higher levels of national income lead to

    higher levels of aggregate demand. The y-intercept is

    given by exogenous demand minus interest rate *

    sensitivity. The intersection of the lines gives us the

    equilibrium level of national income.

    Reduction in Interest Rate

    A reduction in the interest rate results in an upward shift

    in the aggregate demand curve. This results in a higher

    equilibrium level of national income. So the interest rate

    went down and the equilibrium income went up.

    Increase in Interest Sensitivity

    An increase in interest sensitivity results in a downward

    shift in both aggregate demand curves. The downward

    shift is more pronounced for the curve with the higher

    interest rate (i-1). This means that the distance between

    the two resulting equilibrium levels of income is larger.

    IS Curve

  • 20

    Now we can move on to the IS Curve, which denotes the

    equilibrium levels of national income for different interest

    rates. Just as we did in the previous slide, we will be

    graphing the aggregate demand curve for different

    interest rates in the top graph. The bottom graph also has

    income on it's x-axis and will show the different interest

    rates.

    Here is the curve for interest rate #1. The equilibrium

    level of income is the same for both graphs. When we put

    interest rate #1 on our bottom graph we have the first

    point of our IS curve. The second aggregate demand

    curve has a lower interest rate, so its parallel and higher

    up. On the lower graph the intersection of interest rate #2

    and equilibrium income #2 produce the second point of

    the IS curve. This could be repeated for every different

    interest rate in this range to produce the IS curve. Since

    this model only uses linear curves, we need a minimum

    of two points to graph the IS curve. There you have it, at

    any point on this IS curve the goods & services market is

    in equilibrium.

    Slope of IS Curve - Interest Sensitivity

    Now we're going to discuss the determinants of the IS

    curve's slope. Holding other factors constant, an increase

    in interest sensitivity will result in a more grad