List of Most Common Behavioral Economics Obstacles

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 8/9/2019 List of Most Common Behavioral Economics Obstacles

    1/9

    List of Behavioral Economics Principles that can Inform Energy PolicySebastien Houde, Annika Todd

    questions: [email protected] Energy Efficiency Center at Stanford University

    2/17/2010

    WORK IN PROGRESS

    1. FramingFraming of information can bias choice in systematic and predicted ways. Well-known framing effects that

    have implications for energy programs are listed below.

    Framing Effects Reference / Example Implications for energy use

    Loss aversion:

    people focus on losses

    much more than on gains.

    when given a choice between surgeryand radiation therapy, describing

    surgery outcome statistics as a 90%

    survival rate yielded a significantly

    higher preference for surgery thanwhen described as a 10% mortality

    rate (McNeil et al. 1982)

    Framing problems in slightly differentways, such as placing decisions in a

    positive frame versus a negative

    frame, has been shown to change

    decisions by around 26% in several

    studies (Tversky and Kahneman 1981;

    Kahneman, Knetsch, and R. H. Thaler

    1991; Cormier O'Connor et al. 1985).

    energy information should beframed as preventing a loss,

    rather than incurring a gain;

    This appliance is 6 times less

    efficient than the best in class orYou are currently loosing $5

    every month by not consistently

    turning off your lights is more

    motivating than This appliance

    is 2 times more efficient than the

    average appliance or You could

    gain $5 every month by

    consistently turning off your

    lights.

    Have a graph with moneysaved or energy saved on the

    Y axis so that using more energy

    visually looks like a loss.Presentation of technical

    information can induce

    more deliberative

    thinking.

    Suggests that displaying KhWcould have some benefits

    trade-off with the fact that

    people may no clues

    Mental Accounts people

    tend to group spending

    into different accounts

    People often have a separate budgetfor food, clothing

    Energy costs can be monitoredjointly with other, more salient,

    expenses, such as savings, food

    calories.

    Frame energy savings in specificways. E.g. UK's Winter Fuel

    Allowance, British ColumbiaClimate credit

    Sunk Costs - If people

    have already paid for

    something, they feel more

    attached and more

    invested in it.

    Classic example is people buy a ticketto a concert, in the first 15 minutes

    you realize the concert is terrible, but

    you feel obligated to stay for the rest

    of it anyways because you already

    paid for the ticket.

    This makes it hard to get peopleto throw out non-efficient items

    such as incandescents.

    Frame information to reduce thesalience of capital costs for

    durables. Framing of incentives,

  • 8/9/2019 List of Most Common Behavioral Economics Obstacles

    2/9

    e.g. cash for clunkers

    People that pay for a HAN aremore likely to try to really get

    some use out of it by saving

    electricity.

    Segregation and

    Integration of monetarylosses and gains -

    Presenting a small cost on

    its own is more salient

    than embedding it within

    a larger cost.

    This is because of utility concavity. If you want to emphasize thecost, present it on its own, if youwant to de-emphasize the cost,

    embed it.

    You are currently loosing $5every month by not consistently

    turning off your lights is more

    effective than You could reduce

    your $125 electricity bill to $120

    if you consistently turned off

    your lights

    On the other hand, if the hiddencosts are large for a target

    behavior, aggregation of smallamounts is desirable. (Save

    $100/year by buying EE fridge

    rather than save $0.30 per day)

    Reference Dependent

    Preferences - people

    judge their well being

    relative to some reference

    point, which could be

    what they expect, what

    they have habitually

    experienced, or what

    other people are doing

    for social example, see prosocialbehavior below

    A consumers energy use shouldbe framed relative to an effective

    reference point. Show their

    energy use:

    o Relative to the goal of 10%reduction from last year.

    o Relative to those who areusing less energy.

    o If people use above theaverage amount ofenergy, use the average as

    the benchmark, but if they

    use less than the average

    amount, use the best

    household as the

    benchmark.

    o If people set a goal, makesure that the goal is hard

    to attain or else they will

    stop after the goal has

    been reached

    Defaults / Endowmenteffect / Status Quo

    For example, in countries where thedefault option is to donate organs(presumed consent), participation

    rates are 25-30% higher than

    countries in which not donating is the

    default (informed consent),

    controlling for other factors (Abadie

    and Gay 2006).

    Employee participation in 401(k)

    Switch a program from opt-in(where the default is non-enrollment in the program) to

    opt-out (where the default is

    enrollment in the program).

  • 8/9/2019 List of Most Common Behavioral Economics Obstacles

    3/9

    plans increase from 37% to 86%

    under automatic enrollment

    (Madrian and Shea 2001).

    Pichert and Katsikopoulos (2008)present evidence from the field and

    from experiments demonstrating that

    the use of opt-out programsimproves enrollment in plans that

    charge extra for green energy.

    Setting the default temperature onwashing machines to cold was

    calculated to save 24% (McCalley

    2006).

    Real factory workers were either a)promised abonus if their productivity

    as above a certain threshold for a

    time period, b) given a provisional

    bonus that they could keep unless

    productivity went below a certain

    threshold. Both increased

    productivity over control, but b) was

    1% more productive than a). (Hossain

    and List)

    Risk seeking behavior for

    losses people would

    rather gamble to try to

    prevent any loss than take

    a small loss with certainty

    2. Choice Architecture and HeuristicsChoice architecture refers to the organization of the options, attributes and information constituting a

    choice set.

    Research has shown that rationally bounded decision-makers use different decision strategies to navigate

    through different choice architectures. Given that different strategies lead to widely different outcomes,

    there is then a room for interventions to construct choice sets that nudge decision-makers to beneficially

    outcomes. Research in this field is however still nascent. There are however a numbers of important

    principles that have emerged.

    Principles Example Implications

    Choice overload toomuch choice might be

    demotivating, and

    might induce people

    to do nothing (default

    or status quo

    behavior)

    Customers in a grocery store who werepresented with a display of six jams to

    taste were more likely to purchase jam

    (12% bought jam) than if there were 24

    jams to taste (2% bought jam) (Iyengar

    and Lepper 2000).

    People are less likely to opt-in to a

    program if, in order to do so, they must

    Too much choice might be demotivatingand induce the status quo.

    - Restrict the number of recommended

    target behaviors.

  • 8/9/2019 List of Most Common Behavioral Economics Obstacles

    4/9

    choose between too many options. For

    example, when the number of possible

    401(k) plans to choose from are

    increased, the likelihood of enrollment in

    any plan decreases. (Madrian and Shea

    2001)

    Choice framing:extremeness aversion,

    compromise effect

    and irrelevant

    alternatives.

    Individuals will tend to choose the optionthat represents a compromise (people

    wont buy the cheapest nor the most

    expensive item on a wedding registry).

    Also, adding an irrelevant alternative to a

    choice set may favor other options.

    Suppose that we have 2 recommended

    behaviors, A and B, where B has more

    impact but is more difficult to

    implement. We can propose a third

    option C that is even more difficult to

    implement (and even maybe less

    efficient) to make B more appealing.

    3. Prosocial BehaviorPro-social and especially pro-environmental behaviors may be important motivational factors for some

    households. Pro-social behaviors can be a complement to monetary-based motivations, but may also be a

    substitute. Providing monetary incentives may crowd out pro-social behaviors.

    In economics, a lot of research has been done on the theory of private contributions to public goods.

    There exists a wealth of experimental evidence in this domain.

    Principles Examples ImplicationsStatus and self-image

    - people are more

    likely to contribute

    when their actions

    are visible to others,

    when they can

    communicate with

    others, and where

    the users share a

    group identity

    In one field experiment on voting, researchersshowed that mailing letters that listed the voting

    record of every household in a neighborhood for

    a past election along with the promise of re-

    sending the list with updated records for an

    upcoming election improved voter turnout by

    8%, an effect which is comparable to direct

    contact by door-to-door canvassers and much

    cheaper (Gerber, Green, and Larimer 2008).

    Exploit the fact that people contribute mo(i.e. provide greater effort for pro-social

    behavior) when others can observe their

    contributions.

    - Display a leaderboard, or a list of peoplewho have made significant conservation

    efforts.

    Free-riding one

    person has a lowmotivation to

    contribute to the

    public good (by

    reducing energy use)

    because it makes

    virtually no difference

    in world wide

    emissions

    Note that this is different that what is commonlyreferred to in the energy domain as free riding(where people who would have bought an ee

    appliance anyways use a rebate)

    Create sharing mechanisms that minimizefree-riding, e.g. fair lotteries.

    Create smaller groups/networks wherepeople contributions are made salient.

  • 8/9/2019 List of Most Common Behavioral Economics Obstacles

    5/9

    Fairness / Inequality

    /Punishment people

    tend to be averse to

    inequalities and

    unfair outcomes, and

    are willing to pay in

    order to reward orpunish others.

    People are willing to contribute to the publicgood, but only if others also contribute to the

    public good.

    The ability to punish others who do notcontribute can increase contributions to public

    goods. This is true whether the punishment is

    monetary or if it is in the form of disapprovalpoints, although it is higher with monetary

    punishment.

    Implement a Provision Point Mechanismwhich people contribute money towards

    goal, but are refunded their money if the

    isnt met. For example (Rose et al. 2002)

    Traverse City Light and Power in Michigan

    successfully built a windmill using this

    mechanism, and The City of Fort Collins inColorado raised money for three separate

    wind turbines in this way.

    Make it obvious that others in the commare making an effort to reduce energy us

    Other-Regarding

    Preferences / Social

    Norms / Social

    References (A specific

    form of Reference

    Dependent

    Preferences) - People

    care about levels of

    performance,

    possessions and well-

    being relative to

    others, rather than in

    absolute levels.

    Social references alone, without any feedback orother information, have been shown to achieve

    20-28% electricity and gas reductions in several

    studies (Nolan et al. 2008; Schultz et al. 2007;

    Goldstein, Griskevicius, and Cialdini 2007;

    Cialdini 2003).

    Feedback plus social references, includingfeedback about neighbors and communities,resulted in 27% reductions in electricity use in

    one study (Staats and Harland 1995).

    A 2008 study showed that utility customersreduced household energy consumption by 9%

    more when they learned that the vast majority

    of their neighbors were conserving, rather than

    when they were told about environmental

    benefits or about personal cost savings (Nolan et

    al. 2008). This finding has been replicated many

    times with hotel guests reusing their towels,

    national park visitors staying on trails, and in

    other situations (Goldstein, Griskevicius, and

    Cialdini 2007). Showing energy use relative to the average

    caused people who were above the average to

    lower their use, but caused people who were

    below the average to increase their use, unless

    counteracted with a smiley face (Schultz et al.

    2007).

    Providing information that all of yourneighbors are using less energy is much m

    motivating than providing info about

    environmental harm.

    Inducing competition and displaying rankisystems can cause the reference point to

    to focusing on other people

    Interpersonal

    communication

    Hood River weatherizing project, undertaken bythe NRDC and the Pacific Northwests electricity

    suppliers - initially, less than 10% of customers

    signed up for the program. However, when the

    project switched to relying heavily on local

    residents, such as speakers at schools andchurches, 85% enrolled in 2 years, and 95% by

    the end. Cavanagh and Hirst, 1987; Engels,

    Kaplan and Peach, 1987).

    A Canadian study of strategies to reducesummer use of water on residential lawns found

    that simply providing information on efficient

    use was not effective in reducing consumption,

    but when residents received a home visit and

    Use community groups such as churches,schools, community leaders to dissemina

    programs or information.

  • 8/9/2019 List of Most Common Behavioral Economics Obstacles

    6/9

    were asked to commit to reduced usage, three

    quarters of them made the commitment, and

    overall water consumption was reduced by

    more than 50% (Durham Region 1997).

    4. Commitment Mechanisms / Goal Setting / Time inconsistency

    People tend to procrastinate, and they tend to put off things that are costly. They want to save energy,

    but they want to install insulation next year (not this year). When next year comes, they want to put it off

    again. This problem can be solved by commitment mechanisms, in which individuals commit to

    performing some action by a specific date.

    We refer to commitment mechanisms as the terms of informal contracts that individuals voluntary agree

    upon. The aim of commitment mechanisms is to guide and incentivize individuals in the process of

    working through their goals.

    Principles Implications ExampleFirst-Cost Bias:

    Discount Rates, Time

    Inconsistency (First

    Cost Bias), and Self-

    Control.

    People are systematically biased in

    that they value immediate rewards

    (and dislike immediate costs) much

    more than they value future rewards

    (and dislike future costs), to a degree

    that is not explainable by any

    reasonable discount rate (Strotz 1955;

    Thaler 1981; Loewenstein and Thaler

    1992)

    Repackage costs so that the benefit is gainedup front, such as BerkeleyFirst.

    Use commitment mechanisms such as publicgoal setting /commitments

    Goal Setting setting

    goals can help people

    overcome

    procrastination andalso set a reference

    point.

    In two studies, feedback plus goalsetting mechanisms achieved around

    22% reduction in electricity and gas

    use (McCalley 2006; McCalley and

    Midden 2002).

    Setting personal or group goals for energyuse / reduction could be very effective

    Commitment Ask people to make commitmentshelps people overcome

    procrastination / time inconsistency

    issues

    Ask consumers to make a commitment toperform an energy efficient improvement at

    some point in the future. For example,

    people could be asked to commit today to

    replacing their fridge with an energy efficient

    one in one year.

    Commitment

    increases - Begin

    small, make it easy to

    say yes; merely sayingyes makes it very

    likely the individual

    will follow through.

    Then make larger

    requests.

    Once individuals have agreed tosmall behavioral changes, and taken

    those steps, the pro-

    environmentalist values becomeinternalized, and are made a source

    of personal identity and self-esteem.

    At this point they are likely to

    undertake more substantial changes

    in behavior.

    For example, Californiahomeowners asked to display a 3-

    inch square sign that read Be a Safe

    A commitment can also take the form ofthem engaging in one activity (installing a

    shower flow restrictor), pointing out other

    sustainable behaviors that they are alreadyengaged in.

  • 8/9/2019 List of Most Common Behavioral Economics Obstacles

    7/9

    Driver. 2 weeks later: asked to

    display a PSA billboard in the front

    lawn that read Drive Carefully

    (Freedman and Fraser 1966). Only

    asked to display billboard -- -- 17%

    complied. Asked first and second

    request -- -- 76% complied.

    5. IncentivesNot surprisingly, monetary incentives can have substantial impact upon behavior. However, in many cases

    the results are disappointing. There are several reasons for this. First, small piece-rate monetary

    incentives are typical, for example, in the form of rebates on compact fluorescent light bulbs. However,

    small piece-rate monetary incentives actually decrease desirable behaviors because the reward crowds

    out intrinsic motivations. Non-monetary social incentives such as cooperation, competition, and norms

    can be more effective than piece-rate monetary incentives (Lepper, Master & Yow, 2008).

    Principles Implications

    Crowding out - If

    people are

    intrinsically

    motivated to perform

    a behavior,

    introducing a small,

    piece-rate monetary

    reward may actually

    decrease the

    behavior

    For example, offering people $7 to donateblood actually decreases blood donation

    (Mellstrom and Johannesson 2008).

    In another example, people who wereoffered money in compensation for a

    nuclear waste facility in their area reported

    being less happy than those who were not

    offered the money (Frey and Goette 1999).

    This might only be true with small amounts(Gneezy, Rustuchini 2000)

    Offering a non-monetary, environmentalreward might not cause this crowding out.

    Reciprocity / Gift

    Exchange - people

    tend to want to repay

    gifts or efforts of

    others.

    Offering people a monetary gift (notconditional on effort) is more motivating

    than a piece-rate (conditional on effort)

    reward.

    There is some evidence that this is only atemporary increase in effort, immediately

    after the gift is given (Gneezy, List 2006)

    For example, doctors were less likely toreturn a voluntary questionnaire if they

    were given a check to be cashed only upon

    completion rather than a check that could

    be cashed regardless of completion (Fehr

    and Falk 2002)

    Rather than offering monetary incentives foreach energy conserving behavior or each

    energy efficient purchase, an in-kind gift

    might be offered to consumers, with the

    suggestion that they then conserve energy.

    Utilities might match CO2 emissionsreductions of their customers by purchasing

    voluntary offsets.

    In kind gifts - Offeringpeople a gift in-kind

    a non-monetary gift

    is more motivating

    than giving people a

    monetary gift equal

    to the cost of the gift.

    For example, when students were asked tocatalog the books from a library, students

    who were given a gift of a thermos worth

    $10 upon arrival provided an average of

    30% more output than students who were

    given a gift of $10 upon arrival (Kube,

    Marchal, and Puppe 2008).

    see above (reciprocity).

    Tournament / A tournament style reward structure Competitions between neighborhoods or

  • 8/9/2019 List of Most Common Behavioral Economics Obstacles

    8/9

    Competition (where only the top performer receives a

    reward) is more motivating than a piece-

    rate reward structure (Gneezy, Niederle,

    and Rustichini 2003).

    Oberlin did a 2 week competition withstudents and found reductions (Petersen et

    al. 2007) Stanford has a competition during winter

    quarter each year, gets ~8% reductions

    (Annika and Carries unpublished)

    between cities to see who can reduce the

    most energy use. Prizes could be

    community prizes.

    Lotteries / Certainty

    Effect - people

    overestimate small

    percentages, and so

    believe that their

    chance of winning is

    higher than it actually

    is, and therefore are

    more motivated to

    put in effort in order

    to increase their

    probability of

    winning.

    Balaji Prabakhar did lotteries fortransportation (in India). Increased off-

    peak driving activity from 20% to 40%.

    Average commuting times for everyone

    were reduced by 24% (unpublished?).

    Result of prospect theory (Kahneman andTversky 1979)

    Rather than giving people appliance rebates,give them a lottery ticket that would make

    the entire appliance free.

    Endowment effect real factory workers were either a)promised a bonus if their productivity was

    above a certain threshold for a time

    period, b) given a provisional bonus that

    they could keep unless productivity went

    below a certain threshold. Both increased

    productivity over control, but b) was 1%

    more productive than a) (Hossain, List2009)

    Give people a reward, then take it away ifthey dont save enough energy.

    6. LearningPresumably, energy feedback will foster learning among consumers. How people learn is a vast topic, but

    two particular principles may be important to consider.

    First, learning often involves an exploration and exploitation trade-off. This type of trade-off consists of

    sample information sequentially explored until a certain knowledge capital is attained, after which

    individuals simply exploit the knowledge they already have. It is well known that this type of learning gives

    rise to skewed distributions, meaning that if people initially sample information that they found useless or

    unpleasant, they will simply stop exploring and switch to the exploitation stage. They will then have an

    incomplete distribution of the information. In this way, the first sessions that people interact with theinterface are crucial.

    The second principle is that imitation and social learning play an important role in the diffusion of

    technologies.

  • 8/9/2019 List of Most Common Behavioral Economics Obstacles

    9/9

    REFERENCESAbadie, A., and S. Gay. 2006. The impact of presumed consent legislation on cadaveric organ donation: a

    cross-country study.Journal of Health Economics 25, no. 4: 599-620.

    Durham Region. 1997. Durham Region Outdoor Water Conservation Pilot Study. Durham Region, Ontario,

    Canada: Author.

    Fehr, E., and A. Falk. 2002. Psychological foundations of incentives. European Economic Review46, no. 4-5:

    687-724.

    Freedman, J. L., and S. C. Fraser. 1966. Compliance without pressure: The foot-in-the-door technique.

    Journal ol Personality and Social Psychology4, no. 2: 155-202.

    Frey, B. S., and L. Goette. 1999. Does pay motivate volunteers. Unpublished manuscript, Institute for

    Empirical Economic Research. University of Zurich.

    Gerber, A. S., D. P. Green, and C. W. Larimer. 2008. Social pressure and voter turnout: Evidence from a

    large-scale field experiment.American Political Science Review102, no. 01: 33-48.

    Gneezy, U., M. Niederle, and A. Rustichini. 2003. Performance in Competitive Environments: Gender

    Differences*. Quarterly Journal of Economics 118, no. 3: 1049-1074.

    Goldstein, N. J., V. Griskevicius, and R. B. Cialdini. 2007. Invoking Social Norms: A Social Psychology

    Perspective on Improving Hotels' Linen-Reuse Programs. Cornell Hotel and Restaurant

    Administration Quarterly48, no. 2: 145.

    Hossain, T., and J. A. List. The Behavioralist Visits the Factory: Increasing Productivity Using SimpleFraming Manipulations.

    Iyengar, S. S., and M. R. Lepper. 2000. When choice is demotivating: Can one desire too much of a good

    thing?Journal of personality and social psychology79, no. 6: 995-1006.

    Kahneman, D., and A. Tversky. 1979. Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica:

    Journal of the Econometric Society: 263-291.

    Kube, S., M. A. Marchal, and C. Puppe. 2008. The Currency of Reciprocity-Gift-Exchange in the Workplace.

    Loewenstein, G., and R. H. Thaler. 1992. Anomalies: Intertemporal Choice. Quarterly Journal of Economics

    107: 573-597.

    Madrian, B. C., and D. F. Shea. 2001. The Power of Suggestion: Inertia in 401 (k) Participation and Savings

    Behavior*. Quarterly Journal of Economics 116, no. 4: 1149-1187.

    McCalley, L. T. 2006. From motivation and cognition theories to everyday applications and back again: the

    case of product-integrated information and feedback. Energy Policy34, no. 2: 129-137.

    McNeil, B. J., S. G. Pauker, H. C. Sox, and A. Tversky. 1982. On the elicitation of preferences for alternativetherapies. The New England Journal of Medicine 306.

    Mellstrom, C., and M. Johannesson. 2008. Crowding out in blood donation: was Titmuss right?Journal of

    the European Economic Association 6, no. 4: 845-863.

    Nolan, J. M., P. Schultz, R. B. Cialdini, N. J. Goldstein, and V. Griskevicius. 2008. Normative social influence

    is underdetected. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin 34, no. 7: 913.

    Petersen, J. E., V. Shunturov, K. Janda, G. Platt, and K. Weinberger. 2007. Dormitory residents reduce

    electricity consumption when exposed to real-time visual feedback and incentives. International

    Journal of Sustainability in Higher Education 8, no. 1: 16-33.

    Pichert, D., and K. V. Katsikopoulos. 2008. Green defaults: Information presentation and pro-

    environmental behaviour.Journal of Environmental Psychology28, no. 1: 63-73.

    Rose, S. K., J. Clark, G. L. Poe, D. Rondeau, and W. D. Schulze. 2002. The private provision of public goods:

    tests of a provision point mechanism for funding green power programs. Resource and EnergyEconomics 24, no. 1: 131-156.

    Schultz, P. W., J. M. Nolan, R. B. Cialdini, N. J. Goldstein, and V. Griskevicius. 2007. The constructive,

    destructive, and reconstructive power of social norms. Psychological Science 18, no. 5: 429-434.

    Strotz, R. H. 1955. Myopia and inconsistency in dynamic utility maximization. The Review of Economic

    Studies: 165-180.

    Thaler, R. H. 1981. Some Empirical Evidence on Dynamic Inconsistency. Economic Letters 8: 201-207.