51
Center for Financial Studies an der Johann Wolfgang Goethe-Universität ? Taunusanlage 6 ? D-60329 Frankfurt am Main Tel: (+49)069/242941-0 ? Fax: (+49)069/242941-77 ? E-Mail: [email protected] ? Internet: http://www.ifk-cfs.de No. 2003/16 The Role of Accounting in the German Financial System Christian Leuz, Jens Wüstemann

ke toan duc

Embed Size (px)

DESCRIPTION

tài liệu là nguồn thông tin hữu ích cho những ai đang học tập và nghiên cứu về kế toán

Citation preview

  • Center for Financial Studies an der Johann Wolfgang Goethe-Universitt ? Taunusanlage 6 ? D-60329 Frankfurt am Main

    Tel: (+49)069/242941-0 ? Fax: (+49)069/242941-77 ? E-Mail: [email protected] ? Internet: http://www.ifk-cfs.de

    No. 2003/16

    The Role of Accounting in the German Financial System

    Christian Leuz, Jens Wstemann

  • * Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania. ** Business School, University of Mannheim. Draft of Chapter 14 of the book "The German Financial System", edited by Jan P. Krahnen and Reinhard H. Schmidt, forthcoming with Oxford University Press, London 2003. We thank Karl-Herrmann Fischer, Jan Krahnen and Harry Schmidt for helpful comments on earlier versions.

    CFS Working Paper No. 2003/16

    The Role of Accounting in the German Financial System

    Christian Leuz*, Jens Wstemann**

    This version June 2003

    Abstract: This chapter analyzes the role of financial accounting in the German financial system. It starts from the common perception that German accounting is rather uninformative. This characterization is appropriate from the perspective of an arms length or outside investor and when confined to the financial statements per se. But it is no longer accurate when a broader perspective is adopted. The German accounting system exhibits several arrangements that privately communicate information to insiders, notably the supervisory board. Due to these features, the key financing and contracting parties seem reasonably well informed. The same cannot be said about outside investors relying primarily on public disclosure. A descriptive analysis of the main elements of the Germany system and a survey of extant empirical accounting research generally support these arguments. JEL Classification: M41, G3, D82, K0

    Keywords: Accounting, Disclosure, Germany, Standards, Survey

  • 1

    I. INTRODUCTION: ACCOUNTING MYTHS

    Conventional wisdom has it that financial accounting in Germany is

    uninformative, or at least not as informative as in Anglo-American countries. The

    main complaints are that German accounting is very conservative, too heavily

    influenced by tax avoidance strategies, offers too much discretion allowing firms to

    build large hidden reserves, and lacks detailed disclosures.1 Although these

    characterizations may be correct, they generally evaluate German accounting and

    disclosure from the perspective of outside investors trading in public debt or equity

    markets and relying on publicly available information. In Germany, however, stock

    markets are comparatively small, corporate ownership is concentrated, and firms rely

    heavily on bank loans and other forms of private debt (Chapters 2, 5 and 10 of this

    book). Moreover, the above characterizations narrowly focus on the financial

    statements, i.e., on elements of the system that publicly disseminate information. They

    rarely consider institutional arrangements privately communicating information, such

    as the extensive German audit report (Prfungsbericht), to which the attribute

    uninformative certainly does not extend.

    A countrys accounting and disclosure system is part of its financial system and

    more generally its institutional infrastructure. Economic theory suggests that, in well-

    functioning economies, the elements of the institutional infrastructure evolve to fit

    and reinforce each other. Thus, the accounting system is likely to be geared towards

    the informational and contracting needs of the key parties in the economy. For this

    reason, it is important to understand the role of financial accounting in a countrys

    1 See e.g., Investors Chronicle. 1994. Whose Bottom Line Is It Anyway? Financial Times Business Reports. 14 January 1994: 64; Evans. 1996. Brave New Welt: German companies finally become more shareholder-friendly; Barrons. 23 December 1996: 24; Review and Outlook (Editorial). 1997. Shake it Up. WSJ: A18.

  • 2

    institutional infrastructure and, in particular, its role in corporate governance and

    capital markets. Thus, a key question in evaluating an accounting system is whether it

    satisfies the needs of the economys main contracting parties and, in the context of

    financial systems, whether the relevant financing parties are well informed.

    Using these questions as guiding principle, this chapter describes the main

    elements of the German financial accounting and disclosure system. We take a

    broader view and cover public as well as less-known private informational

    arrangements, which are integral parts of the German accounting system. We discuss

    the role of the various elements in the German financial system and analyze how they

    provide information to the key financing parties. Given the nature of the German

    financial system, which is often described as an insider system, we expect that

    information asymmetries are primarily resolved via private information channels

    rather than public disclosure. Thus, the accounting system likely exhibits elements

    that support insider governance and relationship-based contracting. Our institutional

    analysis confirms these expectations.

    Due to the existence of private information channels, financial statements are less

    important in terms of monitoring economic performance and assume other roles, such

    as determining dividends. However, for this reason, arms length or outside investors

    relying primarily on public disclosures are not as well informed in the German system

    as they are in Anglo-American economies. To support this claim, we survey empirical

    accounting research using German data. We argue that the findings are generally

    consistent with this hypothesis as well as several other expectations for the German

    accounting system.

    The following section develops hypotheses about the role and properties of

    accounting in the German financial system. Section 3 describes the key elements of

  • 3

    the German accounting system and ties them in with the financial system. Section 4

    reviews empirical accounting research on Germany and discusses to what extent the

    findings are consistent with our hypotheses and the institutional analysis. The chapter

    concludes with a brief summary and some suggestions for future research.

    II. FINANCIAL ACCOUNTING AND THE INSTITUTIONAL FRAMEWORK

    In this section, we discuss the link between the accounting system and the

    institutional framework and, in particular, the financial system. We develop

    hypotheses about the properties of German accounting based on the idea that, in well-

    functioning economies, the elements of the institutional infrastructure evolve to fit

    each other. These hypotheses guide our institutional analysis and empirical survey in

    subsequent sections.

    Accounting and financial contracting

    Accounting information plays an important role in financial contracting (e.g. Watts

    and Zimmerman 1986). Financial claims and control rights are often defined in

    accounting terms. For instance, debt contracts use accounting numbers and financial

    ratios to specify when a corporate borrower is in default. In determining dividend

    payments to shareholders, firms frequently refer to past and current accounting

    earnings. Investors in public equity markets use financial statements to monitor their

    claims, make investment decisions or exercise their rights at shareholder meetings.

    Given this role, it is reasonable to expect that accounting systems evolve such that

    they facilitate financial transactions and contracting. Moreover, standardizing

    accounting, either by regulation or private standard setting, is likely to reduce

    transaction costs. It seems cheaper to provide a common set of measurement rules for

  • 4

    all or many contracts, rather than to negotiate a particular set of measurement rules on

    a contract-by-contract basis (e.g. Ball 2001). To capitalize on this effect, accounting

    standards are geared towards the informational and contracting needs of the key

    parties in an economy which are also likely to be the main lobbying parties (McLeay

    et al. 2000). That is, the accounting system is likely to reflect ownership and

    governance structures and the financing patterns in a country.

    However, the properties of an existing accounting system can also shape financial

    contracting. A comparison of debt contracting in Germany and the US provides an

    illustrative example in this regard (Kbler 1989; Leuz 1996; Leuz et al. 1998;

    Wstemann 1996, 1999 and 2002a). German accounting has traditionally been

    governed by prudence and creditor protection, i.e., measurement rules that are

    favorable to creditors and limit payouts to shareholders. As a result, German debt

    contracts generally do not have extensive debt covenants restricting dividends to

    shareholders; they simply rely on the legal restrictions imposed by the accounting

    rules. In contrast, US-GAAP is not geared towards debt contracting. Not surprisingly,

    US debt contracts generally include extensive debt covenants, such as accounting-

    based payout restrictions, and in some cases even specify modifications of US-GAAP

    to take into account the needs of debt contracting.

    In summary, the accounting system is a subsystem of the financial system

    interacting with the other subsystems (e.g. equity and credit markets, corporate

    governance). Ideally, the accounting system is complementary to the other elements

    of the institutional framework.2 This fit between the accounting system and a

    2 Note, however, that we do not take a stance on the bigger question whether the German system is efficient or not. We simply analyze whether German accounting informs the key parties in the system, taking other elements of the institutional structure as given, whether they are efficient or not.

  • 5

    countrys institutional infrastructure is likely to result in different accounting systems

    and informational regimes across countries.

    Stylized institutional frameworks and the role of accounting

    We illustrate the link between the accounting system and the other elements of the

    institutional infrastructure using two stylized financial systems. Following prior

    research, we distinguish between an arms-length or outsider system and a

    relationship-based or insider system (Franks and Mayer 1994; Berglf 1997;

    Schmidt and Tyrell 1997; Rajan and Zingales 1998; Allen and Gale 2000; Chapters 2

    and 16 of this book). The two systems differ in the way they channel capital to

    investment opportunities, how they ensure a return to investors and, most importantly

    for our purposes, in the way they reduce information asymmetries between

    contracting and financing parties.

    In an outsider system, firms rely heavily on public debt or equity markets in raising

    capital. Corporate ownership is dispersed and to a large extent in the hands of

    consumers that directly or indirectly via mutual funds invest their savings in public

    debt or equity markets. Investors are at arms length from firms and do not have

    privileged access to information. They are protected by explicit contracts and

    extensive investor rights, which are enforced by the legal system (e.g. LaPorta et al.

    1998). Public debt and equity markets and, in particular, the market for corporate

    control play a major role in monitoring managers and firms (e.g. Franks and Mayer

    1994). Consequently, financial disclosure is crucial as it enables investors to monitor

    their financial claims and exercise their rights. Disclosure is also important for a well-

    functioning takeover market. Thus, in an outsider system, information asymmetries

    between firms and investors are primarily resolved via public disclosure (e.g. Ball et

  • 6

    al. 2000). The accounting and disclosure system focuses on outside investors ensuring

    that they are reasonably well informed and, hence, willing to invest in the public debt

    and equity markets.

    In contrast, in a relationship-based system, firms establish close relationships with

    banks and other financial intermediaries and rely heavily on internal financing,

    instead of raising capital in public equity or debt markets. Corporate ownership is

    generally concentrated and characterized by substantial cross holdings. Corporate

    governance is mainly in the hands of insiders with privileged access to information

    (e.g. board members). Given the nature of the system, information asymmetries are

    resolved primarily via private channels rather than public disclosure (e.g. Ball et al.

    2000). Thus, the key contracting and financing parties are reasonably well informed,

    while outside investors face a lack of transparency. However, opacity is an important

    feature of the system because it provides barriers to entry and protects relationships

    from the threat of competition (e.g. Rajan and Zingales 1998). Opacity effectively

    grants the financing parties some monopoly power over the firm, which allows

    insiders to secure sufficient returns and in turn ensures insider financing to firms.

    In this system, the role of accounting is not so much to publicly disseminate

    information, but to facilitate relationship-based financing, for instance, by limiting the

    claims of outside shareholders to dividends, which protects creditors and promotes

    internal financing. In essence, as insiders have privileged access to information

    through their relationships, accounting can take on other roles such as the

    determination or restriction of payouts. The accounting system is also likely to

    support private channels of information.

    For these reasons, it is important to adopt a broader perspective when evaluating

    the overall performance of accounting systems. In insider economies, the key

  • 7

    elements of the accounting system may not be those that publicly disseminate

    information (even though they have been the focus of international accounting

    research). A more complete assessment includes private information channels and

    contracting roles of accounting.

    Implications and hypotheses for German accounting

    As the previous characterizations were stylized, real financial systems generally do

    not fit them in all respects. However, the UK or US are typically viewed as good

    examples of an outsider or arms-length system. Germany is often viewed as the

    prototype of a relationship-based or insider system. The German stock market is quite

    small in comparison to US or UK markets. The primary sources for German firms are

    internal and bank financing (e.g. pension liabilities, retained earnings, bank loans).

    Traditionally, firms have a close relationship with a bank, the so-called Hausbank.

    But banks not only play a major role in financing, they also control substantial equity

    stakes, either directly or indirectly through proxy voting. They are typically

    represented on the supervisory board (Aufsichtsrat)the main instrument of German

    corporate governance. Ownership is concentrated and many firms are still under the

    control of families. There are also substantial corporate cross holdings. Corporate

    governance and control are primarily in the hands of insiders.3

    Given these features of the German financial system, the key financing parties are

    expected to have little demand for public information. Their role in the corporate

    governance provides them with privileged access to private information. We therefore

    3 See Franks and Mayer (1994), Hackethal and Schmidt (2000), Naumann (2000), and several chapters, of this book, especially chapters 10 by Erik Theissen on the role and size of financial markets, chapter 7 by Elsas and Krahnen on bank-client relationships, and chapters 2 and 3 by Schmidt on corporate governance and on financing patterns, for more detailed characterizations of Germanys financial system.

  • 8

    expect the key financing parties to be reasonably well informed. Moreover, as much

    of the information is privately communicated, we expect the German disclosure

    system to be less developed than in outsider economies, i.e., disclosure levels to be

    relatively low and reported earnings to be less informative about firm performance.

    Consequently, outside investors are likely to be less informed than the key financing

    parties.

    Traditionally, outside investors have not been at the center of the German

    accounting system. Rather, the system is expected to exhibit elements that support

    insider governance and relationship-based contracting. That is, the system is likely to

    include institutional arrangements that ensure that the key financing parties privately

    obtain the necessary information to exercise their control rights. We expect it to

    assume roles other than the public dissemination of information. Finally, the

    enforcement of accounting rules is expected to be a function of internal corporate

    governance rather than of market governance.

    Recent changes in Germany

    In recent years, several elements of the German institutional framework have been

    subject to major reforms such as the 1994 Securities Act or the 1998 Corporate

    Control and Transparency Act (Section 3 of this chapter; Nowak 2001b). These

    reforms suggest that the German financial system is moving towards an arms-length

    system.

    These changes can be explained in part by the immense financing needs of the

    German economy created by the reunification in 1990. Shortly after the reunification,

  • 9

    Germanys total capital imports started to exceed its total capital exports.4 That is,

    after years of exporting capital, Germany became a net capital importer. This change

    implies that the German economy could no longer rely on the traditional sources of

    finance. As international capital markets are not relationship-based, German firms had

    to play by international rules and faced demands for reliable public information. The

    1998 Raising of Equity Relief Act, which allowed German firms that are listed on an

    exchange to furnish internationally accepted accounting standards, could be viewed as

    a reflection of this demand.5

    To what extend do these recent trends and reforms alter our preceding predictions

    for the German accounting system? In principle, they should work against our

    hypotheses. However, complementarities among the elements of the institutional

    framework make it unlikely that reforms take hold unless several other elements of

    the system are changed simultaneously (e.g. Ball, 2001; Schmidt and Spindler 2002).

    But complementarities in the infrastructure also imply that once a sufficient number

    of changes have been made there are strong economic forces to make the remaining

    ones.

    Thus, although we are skeptical that recent changes substantially alter our

    predictions based on the traditional features of the German financial system, we

    consider this possibility in the subsequent institutional analysis and analyze whether

    recent changes have fundamentally altered the accounting system or the financial

    systems reliance on private information channels and insider governance.

    4 See Bundesbank Statistics, EU time series 4628 and 4629 (http://www.bundesbank.de). We estimate a simple time-series model and confirm that net capital flows are significantly negative in the years after the reunification, even after controlling for a time trend and lagged net capital flows. 5 Even prior to this rule change, certain German firms that heavily relied on arms-length financing, e.g., because of non-traditional ownership structures or large financing needs, had strong incentives to commit to more disclosure in order to compensate the information deficits of outside investors and to reduce the associated premium in the cost of capital (e.g. Leuz and Verrecchia 2000).

  • 10

    III. INSTITUTIONAL ANALYSIS

    In this section we describe the key institutional features of the German accounting

    and disclosure regulation, which are presently subject to marked changes. We identify

    the relevant accounting and disclosure rules and briefly compare them in their legal

    quality to US GAAP. Throughout this section it is not our intent to cover accounting

    and disclosure rules in detail, but rather to analyze their relevant economic

    characteristics with respect to our hypotheses. More specifically, we summarize the

    role of German financial accounting in restricting and ensuring payments to owners

    and in tax accounting. We describe the channels that supply the public debt and equity

    markets with information. But we also identify and describe important sources of

    privateas opposed to publicinformation to key contracting parties, thereby

    putting unprivileged parties (e.g., outside investors) at an informational disadvantage.

    The section ends with an outline of German enforcement mechanisms.

    The relevant rules and standard setting institutions

    German accounting regulation in general is codified in the German Commercial

    Code (HandelsgesetzbuchHGB), which applies to all legal forms of economic

    undertakings such as corporations, partnerships and closed corporations. Important

    accounting principles are directly codified in the German Commercial Code, such as

    the principle of prudence, the realization principle, or the principle of timeliness.

    Those principles are of fundamental importance for the system of German Generally

    Accepted Accounting Principles (Grundstze ordnungsmiger Buchfhrung,

    German GAAP). The term German GAAP is nevertheless broader. It encompasses

    all legal rules, principles, standards and norms that have to be applied by a company

  • 11

    in the preparation of its financial statements. Unlike, for instance, in the United States

    these accounting rules govern purposes of corporation law as well as purposes of

    securities regulation.6

    German GAAP are a legal concept which means that they are ultimately subject to

    legislation and jurisdiction. German courts established a long time ago that accounting

    practice has some relevance in determining sound accounting principles, but that, in

    case of conflict, accounting would be considered a normative rather than a positive

    issue. In a leading decision, Germanys Federal Tax Court of Appeals

    (Bundesfinanzhof) stated as early as 1967 that, even though prevailing accounting

    practice could be considered in court, only practice leading to financial statements

    that are in conformity with the legally intended purpose of the stated accounting rules

    could become GAAP.7 The same applies to professional standards, such as accounting

    recommendations promulgated by the German Institute of Certified Public

    Accountants (Institut der Wirtschaftsprfer in Deutschland e. V.).

    From a legal point of view, the accounting principles and standards established in

    court decisions are part of German GAAP. Put differently, German courts determine

    GAAP, whereas US courts have to decide whether professional accounting standards

    such as US GAAP are appropriate under the circumstances (Wstemann 1999: 10ff.).

    In Germany, accounting principles are considered to be legal rules (Rechtsnormen)

    and not professional standards (Fachnormen). Consequently, and in accordance with

    the German constitution, the determination of German GAAP is for the most part a

    matter of legal interpretations (Ordelheide and Pfaff 1994: 87) and does not result

    6 See Siegel (1985) for a discussion of differences in state and federal regulation and Wstemann (1999: 91 ff.) for a comparison with German regulation. 7 Decision of the Federal Tax Court of Appeals on May 31, 1967 (I 208/63, BFHE 89, 191, 194).

  • 12

    from the activities of private standard setting bodies such as the Financial Accounting

    Standards Board (FASB) or the International Accounting Standard Board (IASB).

    The codified accounting principles, which are of a rather general nature, are

    interpreted and developed further by the courts.

    Over the last forty years, beginning with several leading decisions in the late

    sixties, courts reached a very high level of technical competence in accounting issues,

    which manifests itself in important journal articles by federal judges. In interpreting

    accounting rules, German courts havein literally thousands of court rulings

    established a system of sound accounting principles and detailed standards regarding

    the recognition and measurement of assets and liabilities (Beisse 1994; Euler 1996;

    Moxter 1985; Moxter 1999; Moxter 2003). This system minimizes legal risks and

    creates what could be called legal security (Rechtssicherheit) even in questions of

    detail.

    For these reasons, simply looking into Germanys Commercial Code provides only

    a rudimentary picture of German GAAP, missing the entire body of accounting case

    law. This predominance of law in the field of accounting regulation distinguishes the

    way in which accounting standards are determined in Germany from that, e.g., in the

    United States.

    Recent trends and their relation to the existing accounting system

    Responding to the pressures of multinational corporations a new legislative

    initiative in 1998 (the 1998 Raising of Equity Relief Act) permitted listed

    corporations for the first time to apply internationally accepted accounting principles

    instead of German GAAP for the preparation of group accounts. The intent of the

    legislation was to improve the ability of German multinationals to raise capital in the

    global equity markets. The law eliminated the burden of having to prepare two types

  • 13

    of financial statements, one for purposes of SEC-filing and one according to the

    German GAAP. Legislation made clear that both US-standards (US GAAP) and

    International Accouting Standards (IAS) are regarded as internationally accepted

    accounting principles, leaving also open the possibility of an acceptance of other

    national accounting systems. Note, however, that de lege lata only consolidated

    accounts (Konzernabschluss) can be prepared in conformity with US GAAP and

    IAS: The so called individual accounts (Einzelabschluss) are prepared for purposes

    of corporation law (e.g. distributions) and tax accounting, whereas groups must

    additionally prepare consolidated accounts for information purposes. Thus, the

    application of IAS by a German corporation does not have legal consequences for its

    tax payments and distributions to shareholders. However, it is likely to have factual

    consequences on its distributions to shareholders.

    It has to be emphasized that German accounting legislation is already the result of

    European harmonization efforts. To summarize very briefly, European Directives

    (particularly the 2nd, 4th and 7th Council Directive) have harmonized accounting and

    disclosure in Europe, requiring national governments to transform the Directives into

    national law. In Germany, this transformation took place with the 1985 Reform Act

    (Bilanzrichtlinien-Gesetz). Despite these harmonization efforts, the Directives left

    national choices and much discretion in the transformation. Moreover, it is neither

    historically nor currently clear, how much harmonization and standardization the

    European Union intends in accounting and disclosure matters (Fresl 2000). Recently,

    the European Union adopted a Directive stipulating the use of IAS for the

    consolidated financial statements of all publicly traded companies. The rules will

  • 14

    become effective for fiscal years beginning on or after January 1, 2005.8 Germany

    isfor the momentone of the few European countries that accept internationally

    accepted accounting standards as a real substitute for national accounting standards

    (and not as a set of additional financial statements).

    The legal character of German GAAP implies that only legislation and jurisdiction

    have, ultimately, the power to decide which accounting standards are to be applied.

    Nevertheless, the 1998 Corporate Control and Transparency Act established the

    German Accounting Standards Board (GASB). It is the function of this private

    standard setting body to advise the Ministry of Justice in matters relating to

    accounting issues and also to represent Germany in international private standard

    setting bodies such as the IASB. It also promulgates accounting standards for

    companies group accounts which are presumed to be in conformity with the law, but

    in principle could be challenged in court because as professional standards they

    cannot claim the same authority as legal accounting rules. The GASB surely has an

    important function in the harmonization of international accounting standards with the

    goal of ultimately arriving at a globally accepted set of accounting standards.

    Howeveras in the United States (e.g. Metcalf 1977), the formulation of

    accounting standards by a group of organized users with obvious self-interests in the

    solution of accounting issues is not unquestioned.

    So far, the GASB has issued 13 German Accounting Standards (GAS), covering

    mere disclosure issues (e.g. risk reporting, interim financial reporting, cash flow

    8 Article 9 of the Regulation (EC) No 1606/2002 of the European Parliament and of the Council of 19 July 2002 on the application of international accounting standards provides for an exception for companies whose securities are admitted to public trading in a non-member State and which, for that purpose, have been using internationally accepted standards since a financial year that started prior to the publication of this Regulation in the Official Journal of the European Communities. This article applies, for instance, to corporations that are registered with the SEC and obliged to provide financial statements in conformity with US GAAP.

  • 15

    statements, and segment reporting) and questions of recognition (e.g. accounting for

    investments in joint ventures in consolidated financial statements, non-current

    intangible assets). Given that the GASB took up its work only in 1998, it is still too

    early to pass judgment on the issues raised above. Furthermore, it is not quite clear

    whether there will even be a need for a traditional national standard setting body after

    the incorporation of IAS into European accounting law in 2005.

    The purposes of German accounting regulation

    German corporation law binds any distributions to owners to the existence of

    profits available for distribution in a companys individual accounts. The

    determination of distributable profits has to be in accordance with German GAAP.

    These legal rules are a transformation of the legal capital scheme laid down in the 2nd

    European Directive into German law. However, the link between financial accounting

    and corporate distributions (e.g., dividends) is much older and constitutes an

    important element of the German institutional infrastructure.

    Ever since the 19th century, the connection between the accounting rules and

    distributions to shareholders has heavily influenced the nature of German accounting

    numbers. It was argued that if the profits of a company with limited liability are to be

    available for distribution, then German GAAP have to be interpreted in the light of

    precisely this purpose (the so-called teleological approach to law). This interpretation

    implies that the accounting rules must ensure payments to the owners but at the same

    time must also restrict payouts to the residual claimants. Payout determination

    (Ausschttungsbemessung) is therefore viewed as the primary purpose of the

    German individual accounts.

  • 16

    As a consequence of this primary purpose, German accounting regulation severely

    restricts the realization of revenues. For instance, benefits resulting from long-term

    construction type contracts can be realized only after final inspection and approval of

    the clientor, in other words, revenues can be realized only if it is as sure as possible

    that there is no significant remaining risk to the transaction. Also, holding gains from

    changes in the market value of securities must not be recognized; these gains only

    show up in the income statement when the securities are actually sold. On the other

    hand, lossesas a result of the predominant legal principle of prudencehave to be

    recognized as soon as they arise.

    Courts have developed a full scale of jurisprudence for accounting, which very

    often interprets accounting matters in the light of the underlying legal structure (e.g.,

    using the specific contractual structure to determine the relevant economic benefits

    and risks). This approach leads to an emphasis on the reliability and the verifiability

    of accounting numbers. It manifests itself also in a very strict asset-liability approach

    to the balance sheet: Tangible things as well as legal rights are normally considered to

    be assets; things that only have a certain economic use are subject to additional

    recognition criteria. Intangible fixed assets that are self-generated by the company

    must not be recognized; if they are not self-generated they can be recognized if and

    only if they stem from reciprocal contracts with a third (independent) party. Deferred

    chargeswhich have been characterized as a dumping ground for a number of small

    items (Kieso and Weygandt 1995: 590) in the United Statesmust not be included in

    the balance sheet because they lack the quality of an asset.

    Similarly, accounting for liabilities and contingencies under German GAAP can

    generally be characterized as being more prudent than under US GAAP or IAS due to

  • 17

    the legal concept that profits are available for distributions.9 However, the prudence

    principle does not imply that accounting for liabilities and contingencies is completely

    left to managements discretion. It must be kept in mind that accounting is also

    subject to court rulings in prior cases, which narrows managements room for

    accounting choices. The application of the principle of prudence is therefore limited

    from both directions.

    German GAAP also govern the determination of income taxes (principle of the

    authoritativeness of accounting for tax purposes). Income determination for tax

    purposes as laid down in the Federal Income Taxation Act specifically refers to

    commercial law (i.e., the HGB). Systematically, however, the reason for this principle

    was always grounded in the idea that it would be unjust if the treasury demanded tax

    payments from corporations on a basis larger than that available for distributions to

    shareholders. Likewise, there would be no reason why taxes to the treasury should be

    derived from a smaller basis. Thus, it was postulated that, legally, the purposes of

    accounting for distributions and tax accounting are identical (Dllerer 1971: 1334).

    However, this conclusion is not equally valid for the consolidated accounts.

    Distributions and taxes are legally not tied to the consolidated accounts, which have

    exclusively informational purposes.10

    In summary, recognition and measurement of assets and liabilities according to

    German GAAP is characterized by (1) the legal concept of distributable profits, (2)

    the principle of prudence, (3) the emphasis on objectification (Objektivierung)

    which often means a focus on the nature of contracts and things, as a

    9 Note however, that the 4th European Directive also says that the principle of prudence has to be regarded under all circumstances (Article 31). 10 Of course, legally, the individual accounts have a very important informational function, too.

  • 18

    counterbalance to this predominant civil law, (4) a substance-over-form approach and,

    finally, (5) a systematic and principles-based approach to accounting. Although the

    economic consequences of different modes of standard setting still need to be studied

    in greater detail, one should not underestimate the advantages of a legalistic concept,

    which lie in a systematic and principles-based approach and the resulting uniformity

    of terms across different fields of law.

    Information systems available to outside investors

    The fundamentals of German accounting and disclosure requirements are grounded

    in the regulations of the German Commercial Code and are equally binding for all

    legal types of firms (for details see Ballwieser 2001). The statutes oblige firms to keep

    books (HGB: 238), to draw up an inventory at the end of each financial year (HGB:

    240), and to annually prepare a balance sheet and a profit and loss account (HGB:

    242). Recognition and measurement of all elements of financial statements (assets,

    liabilities, revenues and expenses) have to be in accordance with German GAAP

    (HGB: 243). As indicated, the statutes and legal rules concerning recognition and

    measurement are supplemented by the exhaustive case law developed by the courts

    (predominantly tax courts), commentaries and the relevant literature of academic

    scholars (Moxter 2003: 9ff).

    In addition to these general requirements, all firms organized as corporations have

    to add notes to the financial statements and, with the exception of small corporations,

    must prepare a management report.11 The annual report comprises the balance sheet,

    the income statement and accompanying notes (HGB: 264). They constitute a

    11 This also applies to companies in other legal forms that are subject to the Public Disclosure Act because of their economic importance (Publizittsgesetz).

  • 19

    composite whole. The annual report has to give a true and fair view of the

    corporations financial position and results of operations. If the application of the

    relevant accounting and disclosure rules is not sufficient to give a true and fair view,

    additional information must be given (HGB: 264). For corporations, specific

    valuation rules, which are more investor-oriented than for those for non-corporations,

    apply (e.g. duty to reverse asset impairments if their reasons cease to exist, HGB:

    280). The legal rules also prescribe very detailed und uniform formal requirements

    (layouts) for the presentation of the balance sheet and the profit and loss account

    (HGB: 266, 275). The contents of the notes to the financial statements include

    details on the applied accounting policies, the individual positions of the balance sheet

    and the profit and loss account as well as on specific valuation methods (HGB:

    284). The disclosure rules further require information about specific items that are

    not in the financial statements, for instance, the total amount of financial

    commitments that are not included in the balance sheet, a detailed breakdown of

    revenues, the number of employees, and the total sum of managements compensation

    (HGB: 285). However, the corporation must not disclose facts that endanger

    national welfare and they may omit some of the required information if they are to the

    disadvantage of the corporation (HGB: 286). The management report must include

    (1) a fair report on the corporations prospects with particular emphasis on future risks

    (GAS 5), (2) a statement on material events that happened after the balance sheet date,

    and (3) a report on research and development activities of the corporation (HGB:

    289). In contrast to the financial statements, the management report presents results

    and prospects from managements viewpoint, and thereby complements the annual

    report.12

    12 It therefore can be compared with SECs MD&A disclosure.

  • 20

    In addition to the annual report for the individual accounts, a corporation that

    controls subsidiary undertakings has to draw up consolidated (or group) accounts and

    to provide a consolidated annual report (HGB: 290).13 The consolidated annual

    report comprises the consolidated balance sheet, the consolidated profit and loss

    account, and accompanying notes (HGB: 297; for details see Ordelheide 2001).

    Legal rules, commentaries, literature of academic scholars and GAS detail

    consolidation techniques as well as accounting and disclosure requirements. The

    consolidated report is again supplemented by a management report (HGB: 315). As

    mentioned before, the group accounts are neither the basis of dividends nor tax

    payments; they serve purely informational purposes. However, recent amendments to

    the German Corporation Code (AktiengesetzAktG) could give grounds for legal

    action against the management and the supervisory board on the basis of the

    consolidated annual report (AktG: 170, 171).

    As an alternative to German GAAP, corporations with publicly traded securities

    can prepare their consolidated annual reports in conformity with either IAS or US

    GAAP (HGB: 292a). The resulting choice between three different accounting and

    disclosure regimes for the consolidated annual report, which remains until 2004, is

    quite unique and may prove as an interesting field for future research in the field of

    regulatory competition of accounting regimes (e.g. Leuz and Verrecchia, 2000; Leuz,

    2003). The appendix to this chapter provides descriptive statistics on the application

    of the three accounting regimes in Germany.

    13 This requirement also applies to companies in other legal forms if they are subject to the Public Disclosure Act because of their economic importance.

  • 21

    Although the fundamental accounting and disclosure requirements are set forth in

    corporate law, there are supplementary information requirements for listed

    companies, which are laid down in the German securities laws. The most important

    requirements can be organized along the following lines:

    (1) Recent amendments to the basic consolidated financial statements following

    the 1998 Corporate Control and Transparency Act: Listed companies have to present

    a statement of cash flows (GAS 2), segment reporting (GAS 3), and a statement of

    changes in equity (GAS 7). These statements form a separate part of the notes (HGB:

    297).

    (2) Prospectus: Corporations issuing shares have to file prospectuses. In these

    information tableaux (Hommelhoff 2000: 756), financial statements (both annual

    accounts and group accounts are required) serve only as one of the key pieces of

    information that shall enable investors to properly evaluate business and prospects of

    the issuing corporation (Stock Exchange Act (BrsengesetzBrsG): 30).

    (3) Interim financial reporting: Listed companies are also generally required to

    publish at least one set of interim financial statements during the financial year. The

    interim financial statements shall give a true and fair view of the firms financial

    position and the results of operations (BrsG: 40).

    (4) Ad-hoc disclosure: German securities law requires issuers to disclose any

    material new fact that is capable of considerably influencing its share prices (WpHG:

    15).

    (5) Disclosure requirement in specific equity market segments: Under public law, a

    listing in the Segment Prime Standard of the Frankfurt Stock Exchange requires, as

    an example, quarterly reports, application of international standards, and ad-hoc

    disclosure in English language (Frankfurt Stock Exchange Regulation

  • 22

    (Brsenordnung): 62, 63, 66).14 In addition, the stock exchange may prescribe

    alternative or supplementary disclosure requirements on the basis of private law. To

    be listed at the former New Market, for instance, the Frankfurt Stock Exchange

    required companies to prepare their financial statements in accordance with either US

    GAAP or IAS, and to publish quarterly reports.15

    In summary, the information system available to outside investors has two

    characteristics: First, at the company law level, the dissemination of information is

    highly harmonized and integrated for different legal types of economic firms. It gives

    investors a standardized set of financial information which is not dependent on, for

    instance, state regulation of corporation law. Second, at the level of securities

    regulation, diverse reporting requirements prevail. They certainly have important

    interdependences, but they are not fully integrated.16 We see this as a possible

    shortcoming of the information system available to outside investors in Germany.

    Moreover, the sanctions and liabilities are not dependent on any general type of

    misleading statements as they are in the USA by means of rule 10b-5 and rule 14a-9,

    which in principle even extends to oral statements by management.

    Private information systems

    According to our hypotheses, the key financing parties in an insider system are less

    reliant on public information of the type discussed so far because they have access to

    private information channels. In the following, we examine how German corporate

    governance allocates informational rights to the key contracting and financing parties

    14 See Chapter 10 of this book for details on the various segments of the German stock market. 15 See section 7.1 and 7.2.2 New Market Regulation. 16 The public disclosure system in German securities regulation (but not company law) somewhat resembles the situation in the U.S. before the reforms that led to the integrated disclosure system (see Loss and Seligman 1999: 606627; Wstemann 2002a: 132 ff.).

  • 23

    permitting and improving their control of management. These informational rights

    create several private information systems, which all reduce informational

    asymmetries between ownership and control. They constitute individual and separate

    information regimes (Hommelhoff 2000: 749).

    First, there exists a sophisticated system that confers informational rights on

    individual shareholders and does not depend on a controlling stake in the company

    (e.g. HGB: 325; AktG: 131). The group of shareholders encompassesas a result

    of the Treaty of the European Union and rulings of the European High Courtnot

    only current shareholders but also potential shareholders. However, there are certain

    informational rights that assume a factual position as shareholder and hence can not

    be viewed as part of the public information system. For instance, informational rights

    at the shareholders general meeting can only be exercised if one is already a

    shareholder of the company. In addition to the individual rights of all shareholders,

    there are informational rights, which are only attached to those shareholders who are

    members of the supervisory board. A membership in the supervisory board gives

    broad access to virtually any value-relevant information of the company. The legal

    rules explicitly oblige management to furnish this information. Its reporting duties

    cover, for instance, financing and investment decisions, human resource management,

    the corporations profitability and questions of corporate strategy (AktG: 90).

    As another important source of finance, creditors also have important

    informational rights: principal creditors mayand very often do indeedclaim a seat

    in the supervisory board. Creditors are not only entitled but required by German

    banking law to obtain detailed non-public information about a companys prospects

    for any credit exceeding 250,000 Euro (KWG: 18; Chapter 7 of this book). Finally,

    the German Hausbank system with its relationship lending ensures detailed cash-flow

  • 24

    information about all financial transactions handled by the Hausbank, thereby giving

    banks a broad database of historical information, e.g., a companys paying habits, to

    their default risks.

    A very important but less known private information channel in the system of

    German corporate governance is the audit report (Ballwieser 2001; Ordelheide and

    Pfaff 1994; Schmidt 1998; Baetge and Thiele 1998). Audit reports in German

    corporation law have to be distinguished from an audit opinion

    (Besttigungsvermerk). In the audit opinion the auditor briefly expresses whether he

    regards the companys accounting as conforming to German GAAP, often in a

    boilerplate fashion. Audit opinions are published in the annual report and are a part of

    the public disclosure system. In contrast, the audit report has to be submitted only to

    the managing board of directors and the supervisory board. Recent legislation has

    made clear that all members of the supervisory board have to be given copies of the

    audit report. In the past, practice of some firms has been to exclude some board

    members, especially labor representatives from the report (Schmidt 1998: 750). It is

    an interesting feature of Germanys system of corporate governance that the audit

    report is not available for common shareholders, not even at their general meeting. In

    the first part of the audit report, the auditor has to stress the companys future

    prospects and especially those factors which threaten its survival. In its main parts, the

    auditor has to describe and analyze all items on the balance sheet that have a material

    influence on the firms financial position. Moreover, the auditor has to evaluate the

    consequences of all significant accounting choices. This means, for example,

    explaining the effects of sale-and-lease-back transactions. The auditor also has to pass

    judgment on accounting choices within the managements discretion (e.g. overly

    optimistic but legally justifiable estimations of uncertain liabilities). An audit report of

  • 25

    a publicly traded DAX 30 company has the size of several hundred pages.

    Wstemann (2001) shows in his analysis of the relevant legal rules that an audit report

    leads to a much broader insight into a firms financial position and results than

    publicly available annual reports. For instance, the requirement to analyze the

    consequences of accounting choices on the firms financial position exceeds public

    disclosure requirements. In the notes to the public financial statements, such an

    analysis is not generally required, even if it was of legitimate interest to outside

    investors. Wstemann (2002b) argues that recent legislation has even strengthened

    these tendencies. The legal evidence indicates a relatively high stability of private

    information channels in the traditional German corporate governance and suggests

    rather constant informational asymmetries within the group of shareholders. These

    recent changes were expressly meant as a reinforcement of the (private) information

    flows within the firm and to the relevant monitoring parties (Reform Act

    (TransPuG) 2000: 18). They were rounded off by measures to increase information

    flows to outside investors as well (e. g. the requirement to disclose a statement of

    retained earnings for certain public corporations).

    Recent decisions of Germanys Supreme Court may serve as the last piece of

    institutional evidence on the relative importance of the channels that give insiders in

    the German financial system privileged information and control rights.17 In the

    underlying case, a legal norm was challenged which gives management the right not

    to answer any questions concerning the difference between the book value and the fair

    value of the assets at the shareholders general meeting (AktG: 131). Plaintiffs

    argued that without this information a control of management would not be effective

    17 See Decisions of the German Supreme Court from September 20, 1999 1 BvR 636/95 and 1 BvR 168/93.

  • 26

    since hidden reserves would distort a fair presentation of the companys financial

    position, thereby enabling management to draw on the reserves unnoticed and to

    cover up the firms true financial position. In its decisions the court pointed out that

    the legal guarantee of property rights includes the right to obtain information over

    matters of the company in which one is a shareholder. The right to obtain information

    is hence a material component of shareholder rights. According to the court ruling,

    however, managements right to refuse information ( 131 AktG) is the proper

    restraint of the former: Hidden reserves are viewed as a means to protect against

    possible risks of insolvency and to secure the corporation against general risks for

    which there would be no protection otherwise. That is, in the courts view, hidden

    reserves can be in the interest of the company (Gesellschaftsinteresse). The

    challenged disclosure of hidden reserves would complicate the necessary measures of

    precaution considerably. The court also pointed out that the existence of hidden

    reserves could be in the interest of controlling shareholders, for whom entrepreneurial

    aspects are more important than distributions. Thus, the court ruling explicitly

    acknowledges the existence of divergent interests of majority and minority

    shareholders, but it also identifies information and control rights that are only

    available to majority shareholders, thereby granting them legitimate ways of exerting

    insider control. This is consistent with our main hypothesis that institutional

    arrangements are geared towards the main contracting parties.

    In summary, our institutional analysis suggests that the key contracting parties in

    Germany are reasonably well informed once we consider both private and public

    sources of information. In fact, it seems plausible that they are at least as well

    informed as investors in an outsider system with extensive public disclosure

  • 27

    requirements.18 It has to be emphasized that the supply with information to controlling

    insiders and the supervisory board does not have an informal character but follows

    along legal rules, which ensures that the information flows areas legally protected

    interestsenforceable. However, the existence of private information regimes also

    implies an informational disadvantage of outside investors.

    Enforcement of accounting rules

    Enforcement of accounting and disclosure rules can be achieved either via

    corporate governance or market regulation. In Germany, enforcement is basically

    driven by corporate governance. We identify and discuss three main enforcement

    mechanisms, which all have been strengthened recently (2002 Reform Act). First,

    management itself is obliged by law to ensure proper application of accounting

    standards. The management also has to establish a monitoring system which enables it

    to detect developments that might endanger the economic survival of the corporation.

    Second, the supervisory board has to examine the financial statements, supported

    therein by the audit report and the auditor, either during meetings of the audit

    committee or in the general meeting of the supervisory board. Finally, it is the

    purpose of the statutory audit to guarantee that firms financial statements give a true

    and fair view of the companys financial position and results. In order to strengthen

    the auditors independence, the 1998 Corporate Control and Transparency Act

    introduced among other rules a rotation of the responsible auditor (but not the audit

    firm) after 6 years. The 1998 Corporate Control and Transparency Act also requires

    that the supervisory board hires the audit firm. Before the reform, the management

    18 In contrast, securities regulation in the U.S. stresses the importance of equally distributed disclosure (e.g. Regulation FD).

  • 28

    board hired the auditors, which raised questions concerning the auditors'

    independence. The enforcement of either IAS or US GAAP lies with the auditors,

    whose legal liability has considerably increased since an amendment of the German

    Commercial Code (HGB: 323) enacted by the 1998 Corporate Control and

    Transparency Act. In addition, auditors and directors could face criminal prosecution

    for misleading or fraudulent financial statements (HGB: 331, 332). It is also

    possible to sue for damages in civil courts, but only after a conviction in criminal

    proceedings.

    US-style litigation or SEC-like monitoring does not exist. But recent legislation

    has at least established certain elements of a market oriented enforcement of

    accounting standards. For the first time, shareholders in Germany can sue the

    company on the grounds of misleading statements resulting in losses from irregular

    share prices (Fourth Financial Market Reform Act 2002 (Viertes

    Finanzmarktfrderungsgesetz). In addition, it has been proposed to establish a private

    enforcement panel, following the British example of the Financial Reporting Review

    Panel (FRRP). This panel will investigate any complaints from private persons about

    violations of the accounting standards that materially affect a companys financial

    position. A possible establishment of a state agency like the SEC was discussed but

    rejected. Some enforcement is exercised by the monitoring activities of the State Bars

    of Certified Public Accountants (Wirtschaftsprferkammern), which regularly

    review published annual reports and which have established a system of peer reviews

    following the U.S. example (prior to the recent changes induced by the Sarbanes-

    Oxley Act). Limited enforcement could also result from the registration department of

    the stock exchanges, e.g., the Frankfurt Stock Exchange. Last, but not least, indirect

    enforcement of accounting rules results from the activities of tax authorities. Since the

  • 29

    individual accounts are authoritative for tax purposes, enforcement actions by the tax

    authorities regarding the tax accounts have repercussions for the underlying individual

    accounts (e.g. questions of recognition of assets, liabilities, revenues and expenses).

    Interestingly, this enforcement mechanism is weakened by recent trends towards

    international accepted accounting standards for the consolidated accounts.

    IV. EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE

    In this section, we provide a brief survey of the empirical accounting literature

    using German data (for earlier reviews Coenenberg et al. 1984; Mller and Keller

    1999). We review empirical studies on (1) financial statements, (2) other financial

    disclosures to the capital markets, (3) the role of accounting in contracting and

    corporate governance (4) earnings management and enforcement. We organize our

    review along six hypotheses, which are based on the preceding institutional analysis

    as well as extant accounting and finance research.

    Hypothesis 1 (Price-Earnings-Relations): The institutional analysis suggests that

    the key contracting and financing parties in Germany are reasonably well informed.

    Direct evidence supporting this prediction is likely to be limited since the information

    is communicated mainly via private channels. However, share prices can provide

    indirect evidence. If insiders can trade based on privately communicated information,

    prices should reflect this information in a timely fashion and well before it is

    incorporated in the accounting numbers and publicly disclosed.19 Thus, private

    information transmission in conjunction with insider trading reduces the

    contemporaneous association of accounting numbers with stock returns (i.e. their

    19 The information is eventually reflected in earnings, for instance, when the cash flows are realized.

  • 30

    value relevance) and increases the interval by which prices lead accounting

    numbers.20

    Several empirical studies suggest that, despite voluntarily adopted restrictions,

    insider trading was fairly widespread in Germany, at least until 1994, when insider

    trading became illegal (e.g. Seeger 1998). But even thereafter, reporting of insider

    trades was not required until 2002. The lack of reporting requirements and recent

    anecdotal evidence question whether insider trading was effectively curbed. We

    therefore expect that the contemporaneous association of earnings and stock returns is

    lower and that prices lead earnings over longer intervals in Germany than in countries

    with strictly enforced insider trading provisions.

    There are several studies examining the value relevance of earnings and

    shareholders equity of German firms. Joos and Lang (1994) find that the value

    relevance of earnings and book value of equity are comparable in Germany and the

    UK using price and 18-month return regressions. Harris et al. (1994) compare German

    and US accounting numbers and report that the value relevance of earnings is

    comparable, but that shareholders equity in Germany is significantly less associated

    with share price than in the US. In contrast, the results of Alford et al. (1993) suggest

    that German earnings are less value relevant than US (or UK) earnings because (a)

    they exhibit a significantly lower association with 15-month stock returns and (b) they

    capture a smaller proportion of the total information impounded in share price using a

    hedge portfolio approach. Ali and Hwang (2000) report that the value relevance is

    lower in bank-oriented financial systems, such as the German, than in market-

    oriented financial systems, such as the UK or the US, using several measures of

    20 See Kothari and Sloan (1992) for the idea of prices leading earnings. Jacobson and Aaker (1993) make a similar argument for Japan and present supporting evidence.

  • 31

    value relevance. Finally, Ball et al. (2000) analyze the timeliness of earnings across

    countries using reverse regressions (i.e. earnings on returns). They show that (a)

    earnings are significantly more timely in common-law countries, such as the US, than

    in code-law countries, such as Germany, and (b) that this finding is primarily driven

    by the timely recognition of economic losses in earnings, which is suggested to

    facilitate outsider monitoring.

    Studies explicitly comparing the lead-lag structure of stock returns and earnings for

    Germany and Anglo-American countries do not exist. However, Ali and Hwang

    (2000) document that the fraction of earnings information incorporated in leading-

    period (as opposed to contemporaneous) returns is greater for bank-oriented countries.

    This finding is consistent with German returns leading earnings over a longer interval

    than in the UK or the US.

    Overall, the evidence is consistent with the hypothesis that German accounting

    numbers are less value relevant and less timely in part because prices reflect

    information privately communicated to key parties. However, the value relevance of

    earnings and the lead-lag structure with prices are also affected by other factors (e.g.

    poor accounting quality and earnings management), making it difficult to attribute the

    results solely to the transmission of information via private channels.21

    Hypothesis 2 (Announcement Returns): A further implication of private

    communication (and insider trading) is that the information content of accounting

    numbers at the time of their public announcement is low. That is, the stock market

    reaction to the public announcement is weak because insiders already possess the

    21 Comparative value relevance studies often ascribe their findings to differences in accounting quality. However, differences in information channels are an equally plausible explanation.

  • 32

    information contained in the accounting numbers and have traded on it. Based on this

    logic, we expect the information content of financial statements to be lower in

    Germany than, for example, in the US.

    There are several event studies examining the information content of various

    German accounting reports (e.g. Coenenberg and Mller 1979; Keller and Mller

    1993). They generally conclude that unexpected realizations of accounting numbers

    lead to significant stock market reactions around the event date. However, it is

    difficult to compare these reactions and the implied information content to findings in

    other countries. The stock market reaction at the announcement is not only a function

    of how much private information is already impounded in prices. Other factors are

    likely to differ across countries and may even pull in opposite directions. For instance,

    poor quality of the announced information and high quality interim disclosures both

    reduce the information content of announcements. Thus, it is again difficult to

    attribute differences in information content solely to the channels of information

    transmission.

    Extant studies nevertheless provide several indications that the information content

    of German accounting numbers at the time of their public announcement is relatively

    low, consistent with our hypothesis. First, early German event studies do not use the

    press release date, but define preceding ones, such as the supervisory board meeting

    or the completion of the audit. These event dates are explicitly chosen to address

    information leakage and insider trading (e.g. Keller and Mller 1992; Seeger 1998).

    Recent changes in the securities laws (notably WpHG: 15) that stipulate ad-hoc

    disclosure of price-relevant information are likely to mitigate these problems (Nowak

    2001a). Second, even after these changes in 1995, event studies continue to exhibit

    relatively low significance levels. Only a small fraction of the market reactions

  • 33

    (frequently less than 10% of the sample) are individually significant (Nowak 2001a).

    These findings are likely to reflect the difficulty of measuring the information content

    of news announcements in an environment where the key financing parties have

    private access to information.22

    Hypothesis 3 (Transparency): Given that the key contracting parties are less reliant

    on public information, the level and the quality of financial disclosures of German

    firms are likely to be low compared to other countries where arms-length investors

    play a larger role.

    Consistent with this hypothesis, several international comparisons document that

    the level of financial disclosure is low in Germany compared to the UK or the US. For

    instance, the disclosure index developed by Saudagaran and Biddle (1992) ranks

    Germany only seventh out of eight countries, whereas the US is first and the UK

    third. Similarly, the CIFAR disclosure index reported in La Porta et al. (1998) assigns

    only rank 25 (out of 41) to Germany, whereas the UK and the US take the places 4

    and 11, respectively. These studies generally rely on indices of disclosure practice and

    hence measure both mandatory and voluntary disclosures. Cooke and Wallace (1990)

    focus specifically on disclosure regulation and find that Germany has fewer mandated

    disclosures than the UK or the US. More recently, La Porta et al. (2002) conduct a

    comprehensive survey of disclosure requirements prior to security offerings in 49

    countries. Germany ranks only in 39th place and exhibits lower disclosure

    requirements than most developed countries. All these findings are consistent with the

    view that, in Germany, public disclosure plays a minor role in informing the key

    22 Another problem is the correct specification of the markets expectations. Even the more recent convention to use analysts forecasts as a proxy is unlikely to solve the problem as analysts expectations may not reflect the marginal investors expectation in insider economies.

  • 34

    financing and contracting parties. Interestingly, this view seems to be shared by both

    firms and regulators.

    However, there are also studies suggesting that disclosure levels may not be low

    for every information type. For instance, Frost and Ramin (1997) report that German

    firms provide more earnings and sales forecasts than UK or US firms.23 On one hand,

    this finding is consistent with the low risk of shareholder litigation in Germany. But

    on the other hand, such disclosures are less likely to be important in the German

    environment. Consistent with the latter view, Meek and Gray (1989) and Baetge et al.

    (1997) find that forward-looking disclosures in German annual reports are particularly

    poor. More research is necessary to resolve this apparent contradiction.

    Hypothesis 4 (Voluntary Disclosures): Although the typical German firm is

    characterized by concentrated ownership and strong reliance on private financing,

    there are German firms with less traditional capital and ownership structures. As these

    firms rely more on arms length financing, they have stronger incentives to

    communicate information publicly. Economic theory suggests that these firms

    voluntarily provide additional information and exceed mandatory disclosures. They

    could also adopt more informative accounting standards or cross list in the UK or the

    US, thereby committing to higher disclosure standards.

    Studies using firm-level data reveal considerable cross-sectional variation in the

    disclosure practice across German firms (e.g. Coenenberg et al. 1984, for a survey of

    earlier studies). The results, which are generally consistent with disclosure theory and

    evidence in other countries, suggest that external financing needs, dispersed

    23 Along the same lines, Meek and Gray (1989) compare voluntary disclosures of European firms listed at the London Stock Exchange and find that German firms are particularly forthcoming in their employee disclosures, social and environmental reporting, but not in their financial disclosures.

  • 35

    ownership, and foreign listings are among the key determinants of voluntary

    disclosures in Germany. For instance, Leuz (2003a) presents evidence that firms trade

    off capital-market benefits (e.g. external financing) and proprietary costs in deciding

    whether to disclose segment information. Leuz (2000) analyzes the adoption pattern

    of voluntary cash flow statements that are in line with international practice. He finds

    that German firms facing pressures in the international capital markets are among the

    first to voluntarily disclose such statements, followed by firms that are likely to have

    relatively high benefits in the domestic capital markets.

    The latter study also suggests a trend towards improved disclosure. Disclosure

    index studies conducted at regular intervals confirm that German disclosure practice

    is steadily improving (Baetge et al. 1997). In particular, the number of firms

    presenting financial statements in accordance with international standards, such as

    IAS and US GAAP, is rapidly increasing (see also our Appendix). Leuz and

    Verrecchia (2000) document that German firms voluntarily adopting financial

    statements in accordance with international standards, such as IAS or US GAAP,

    garner substantial capital-market benefits. Although these trends are consistent with

    Germanys recent movements towards a more capital-market oriented financial

    system, more research is necessary to establish whether these developments are in fact

    fundamental changes in firms disclosure policies or whether the documented

    economic benefits are based on perhaps unwarranted expectations. In this regard, the

    now closed New Market at the Frankfurt Stock Exchange provides an interesting

    example (Leuz 2003b).

    Hypothesis 5 (Dividend Restrictions): The institutional analysis in Section 3

    emphasizes the important role of German accounting numbers in determining payouts

  • 36

    (e.g. dividends, taxes). In particular, the fact that accounting rules are geared towards

    restricting dividends to shareholders is likely to be reflected in German debt contracts.

    There are few studies that systematically study the use of earnings and other

    accounting numbers in contracts for German firms. One reason is that there is no

    disclosure requirement for bonus or debt contracts, which is not surprising given the

    nature of the German institutional framework.24 However, there are several studies

    that provide indirect evidence supporting hypothesis 5. First, Harris et al. (1994) find

    that the dividend payout level is significantly higher in Germany than in the US. This

    finding highlights the importance of dividends and payout determination in Germany.

    Second, Ball et al. (2000) report that, in Germany, dividends are timelier than

    earnings, i.e., dividends incorporate a larger proportion of economic income as

    measured by the stock return. This finding again emphasizes the special role of

    dividends in Germany.

    More direct evidence on the role of accounting in German debt contracting

    provides a study by Leuz et al. (1998). They compare legal and contractual dividend

    restrictions in the UK, the US and Germany and find that contractual restrictions are

    very rare in Germany and used only in special circumstances. This result is in contrast

    to the ubiquity of dividends constraints in UK and US debt agreements. However,

    German corporate law imposes detailed payout restrictions and the accounting rules

    are geared towards the problem of restricting dividends to shareholders. Survey

    evidence and the fact that these legal restrictions are similar to the contractual

    constraints in the UK and the US suggest that the existence of relatively strong legal

    24 Schwalbach and Grahoff (1997) report based on estimates by Kienbaum Consulting that roughly 90% of Germanys top executives receive (variable) incentive packages amounting to about 25-40% of the total compensation. But they do not report how incentive compensation is determined.

  • 37

    restrictions is responsible for the lack of contractual dividend restrictions in

    Germany.25

    Finally, McLeay et al. (2000) present indirect evidence of a different sort. They

    analyze constituent lobbying and its impact on the development of financial reporting

    regulation in Germany. Studying commentaries on draft accounting legislation, they

    identify three primary constituencies: (1) industry and banks, (2) auditors and (3)

    academic experts. Of the three groups, the first exerts the strongest influencein

    particular with respect to disclosure issues. Noteworthy and consistent with the

    (contracting) role of accounting in the German economy is the absence of financial

    analysts and arms length investors in the political process.

    Hypothesis 6 (Earnings Management and Enforcement): Based on the role of

    reported earnings in the German institutional setting, we conjecture that earnings

    management is more prevalent in Germany than in outsider economies. First, as the

    key contracting parties rely less on reported earnings to make investment decisions or

    monitor firms, there is less demand for earnings that accurately reflect a firms

    operating performance (Ball et al. 2000; Ball 2001). Second, insiders enjoy higher

    private control benefits in the German setting than in outsider economies and hence

    have a greater need to conceal or obfuscate firm performance to reduce outsider

    interference (Leuz et al. 2003).

    There is ample anecdotal evidence of earnings management. German firms are

    frequently criticized for their hidden reserves used to manipulate earnings

    (Coenenberg et al. 1984; Harris et al. 1994: 188). But there are also several empirical

    25 The institutional comparison of legal payout restrictions in the US and Germany by Wstemann (1996) further supports this view. He concludes that the US restrictions in state corporation law are relatively weak, which essentially leaves the problem to debt contracting.

  • 38

    studies providing evidence consistent with our hypothesis. For instance, Keller and

    Mller (1992) compare financial reports of industrials and banks in terms of their

    information content. They document that the reports information content is

    considerably lower for banks than industrials. As German banks have more discretion

    in valuing their assets (e.g. loan loss reserves) than industrials, they view their finding

    as evidence of substantial earnings management, but it could also reflect the opaque

    nature of banks. The findings in Ball et al. (2000) on the properties of earnings are

    consistent with the hypothesis that German firms engage in more earnings

    management than firms in the US or the UK. Analyzing the degree of flexibility

    embedded in the accounting standards, dArcy (2000) shows that the codified rules

    grant managers more accounting choices than UK or US standards, which could give

    rise to more earnings management. However, as explained in Section 3, German

    GAAP are not determined by the codified rules alone, making a comparison difficult.

    More directly addressing the hypothesis, Leuz et al. (2003) examine the

    pervasiveness of earnings management across 31 countries. Their evidence suggests

    that the level of earnings management and income smoothing is higher in Germany

    than in outsider economies like the UK or the US. The study also documents that

    earnings management is negatively associated with outside investor protection and

    positively associated with private control benefits. Thus, it should not come as a

    surprise that Germany exhibits relatively high levels of earnings management.

    The reliance on insider control and the relatively low demand for public

    information that accurately reflect firms operating performance is also reflected in

    the enforcement of accounting rules. Anecdotal evidence suggests that the level of

    enforcement in the area of consolidated financial accounting is rather low (e.g.

    Ordelheide 1998). Recent studies by Glaum and Street (2003) and Gebhardt and

  • 39

    Heilmann (2003) show that there is considerable cross-sectional variation in firms

    compliance with German and international accounting standards, which is also

    consistent with low enforcement. Unfortunately, an empirical study that explicitly

    compares the level of accounting enforcement across countries does not exist.

    In summary, we find that the extant literature broadly supports our hypotheses. In

    many areas, however, more research is necessary to explicitly address these

    hypotheses and to improve our understanding of the links between accounting,

    disclosure and the financial system in Germany (and elsewhere).

    V. CONCLUSION

    This chapter analyzes the role of financial accounting in the German financial

    system. We begin our analysis by noting that the widespread characterization of

    German accounting as rather uninformative stems from an implicit or explicit

    comparison with accounting systems in outsider economies like the US and the UK.

    We therefore adopt a broader perspective and include public disclosure and private

    information channels in our institutional analysis of the German accounting system.

    Confining the comparison to financial statements and disclosure, outside investors

    relying primarily on public information seem not as well informed in the German

    system as they are in the Anglo-American economies. However, the German

    accounting system exhibits several arrangements that privately communicate

    information to insiders, notably the supervisory board. Due to these features, the key

    financing and contracting parties seem reasonably well informed. Thus, the

    informativeness of the German accounting system depends on which elements of the

    system and which parties are included in the analysis.

  • 40

    Our survey of extant empirical accounting research generally supports these

    arguments. The evidence is consistent with the notion that the German accounting

    system is not geared as much towards arms length investors as the US or the UK

    system. It suggests that the level of public disclosure is lower in Germany and that

    financial statements of German firms are generally less informative than those of UK

    or US firms. Moreover, stock price reactions to and associations with accounting

    numbers are consistent with the notion that a substantial amount of information is

    communicated via private channels. However, there is little research that directly

    addresses the informedness of arms length investors in Germany and even less direct

    evidence on how well insiders are informed. Our conclusions should therefore be

    viewed as hypotheses and as motivation for future research, rather than answers to the

    questions posed in the introduction.

    Areas for future research also arise from recent institutional reforms in Germany

    and Europe such as the adoption of IAS. We argue that these changes have not yet

    fundamentally altered the German accounting system and its reliance on private

    information channels and insider governance. Complementarities among the elements

    of the institutional framework make it unlikely that reforms take hold unless several

    other elements of the system are changed simultaneously (e.g. Ball 2001). Although

    the process towards an outsider system seems to have been set in motion and several

    elements of the German institutional framework have been reformed, there are still

    many areas, which are crucial to an outsider system but are largely unchanged (e.g.,

    enforcement of accounting rules and shareholder litigation).

    Before these reforms take place, we are skeptical that the recent changes have

    fundamentally and lastingly altered the German accounting system and its

    informational properties. Frankfurtsnow closedNew Market provides a case in

  • 41

    point. The experience with this stock market segment illustrates the importance of

    enforcement and that changing the accounting standards is unlikely to be sufficient to

    ensure high-quality information to outside investors. In fact, recent studies provide

    evidence that accounting quality is largely determined by firms reporting incentives,

    and not the accounting standards per se (e.g. Ball and Shivakumar 2002; Ball et al.

    2003; Leuz 2003b; Leuz et al. 2003). The idea is that accounting standards necessarily

    leave discretion and that this discretion is used (or abused) depending on controlling

    insiders incentives, which in turn are shaped by corporate governance and

    institutional factors. These findings suggest that if accounting and disclosure practice

    is to be improved, the emphasis should not be on reforming accounting standards, but

    on improving firms reporting incentives by changing the institutional framework and,

    in particular, corporate governance. Advancing our understanding of these links is an

    important area for future research.

  • 42

    References

    ALFORD, A., J. JONES, R. LEFTWICH, AND M. ZMIJEWSKI. 1993. The Relative Informativeness of Accounting Disclosures in Different Countries. Journal of Accounting Research 31. Supplement: 183-223.

    ALI, A., AND L. HWANG. 2000. Country-Specific Factors Related to Financial Reporting and the Value Relevance of Accounting Data. Journal of Accounting Research 38: 1-23.

    ALLEN, F., AND D. GALE. 2000. Comparing Financial Systems. Cambridge: MIT Press. BAETGE, J., AND S. THIELE. 1998. Disclosure and Auditing as Affecting Corporate

    Governance., In Comparative Corporate Governance, eds. K. J. Hopt et al. Oxford: Oxford University Press: 719741.

    BAETGE, J., K. ARMELOH, AND D. SCHULZE. 1997. Empirische Befunde ber die Qualitt der Geschftsberichterstattung brsennotierter deutscher Kapitalgesellschaften. Deutsches Steuerrecht 35: 212-219.

    BALL, R. 2001. Infrastructure requirements in the area of accounting and disclosure policy