25

Click here to load reader

Joint optimal ordering and weather hedging decisions: mean-CVaR model

  • Upload
    fei-gao

  • View
    216

  • Download
    2

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Joint optimal ordering and weather hedging decisions: mean-CVaR model

Joint optimal ordering and weather hedging decisions:mean-CVaR model

Fei Gao • Frank Y. Chen • Xiuli Chao

Published online: 12 February 2011

� Springer Science+Business Media, LLC 2011

Abstract This paper considers the problem of hedging inventory risk for a seasonal

product whose demand is sensitive to weather conditions, such as the average seasonal

temperature. The newsvendor not only decides the order quantity, but also adopts a

weather hedging strategy. A typical hedging strategy is to use an option (weather

derivative) that is constructed on a weather index before the season begins, which will

compensate the buyer of the option if the actual seasonal weather index is above (or

below) a given strike level. We adopt the risk measure of Conditional-Value at Risk

(CVaR) and explore the joint decision problem in mean-CVaR criterion. We find that

the weather derivative hedging can increase order quantity. Furthermore, it can help

the risk-averse newsvendor improve both expected overall and downside profits.

Keywords Newsvendor � Weather risk hedging � Weather option �Mean-CVaR

1 Introduction

Firms are exposed to a wide variety of risks such as uncertainty about demand and

supply, exchange rate fluctuation, commodity-market volatility, and labor disruption.

F. Gao (&) � F. Y. Chen

Department of Systems Engineering & Engineering Management, Chinese University of Hong

Kong, Shatin, N.T., Hong Kong, China

e-mail: [email protected]

F. Y. Chen

e-mail: [email protected]

X. Chao

Department of Industrial & Operations Engineering, University of Michigan,

Ann Arbor, MI 48109-2117, USA

e-mail: [email protected]

123

Flex Serv Manuf J (2011) 23:1–25

DOI 10.1007/s10696-011-9078-3

Page 2: Joint optimal ordering and weather hedging decisions: mean-CVaR model

This paper is concerned with weather risk, the uncertainty in cash flow and earnings

caused by weather volatility, or the financial exposure that a business firm may have

to non-catastrophic1 weather conditions.

Weather affects the business of many companies. Take the following examples.

(1) To meet customer demand, a propane heating oil distributor must purchase

adequate inventory to cover the expected heating season. If the season is warmer

than normal, then the sales volume will decrease, which leaves the distributor with

excess inventory and the associated storage expenses (Malinow 2002). (2) Demand

for soft drinks is also weather sensitive. As shown in Fig. 1, sales of mineral water

in a German city were highly correlated with the weekly average temperature

(Rathke 2005). (3) A jacket firm located in the North of England reported a third

quarter drop in earnings of 12% compared with the third-quarter of the previous

year. It was also found that three years ago the third quarter earnings were lower by

as much as 14.5%. In both cases the firm believed that the losses were due to milder

than usual winters. Historical data indicates a 91% correlation between the

temperature and the number of items of cold weather clothing sold by the firm

(Speedwell Weather Derivatives Ltd 2003). Although these examples are mostly

related to the sales of consumer goods, the weather risk exists widely in many other

sectors, such as energy, agriculture, construction, outdoor sports, and service

businesses. According to an estimate by the U.S. Department of Commerce, nearly

one-third of the U.S. economy is at risk due to weather, and up to 70% of all

businesses face weather risk of some sort (Baker and Petrillo 2004).

Sophisticated firms, such as the above-mentioned heating oil distributor and

winter jacket manufacturer, have been using weather contracts/derivatives (options,

futures, combinations of both, etc.) to hedge against the financial impact of adverse

(but non-catastrophic) weather conditions, evening out their weather sensitive

earnings. (An example of a weather option will be described in Sect. 3.) Markets for

weather hedging products have emerged in the past decade, and weather risk

R2

15,0 20,0 25,0 30,0

= 0,9549

35,0 40,0

Temperature in °C

Sale

s in

%

Fig. 1 Sales of mineral water as percentage of those at 19�C

1 Examples of catastrophic weather conditions include natural disaster type weathers, such as cyclonic

storms, tornados, blizzards, etc.

2 F. Gao et al.

123

Page 3: Joint optimal ordering and weather hedging decisions: mean-CVaR model

derivatives/contracts have been traded both in exchanges and over-the-counter.

Since its launch on the Chicago Mercantile Exchange in 1997, the weather-

derivative trade has grown to a $45 billion per year industry in the U.S. (WRMA

2006). In addition, weather derivatives trading has spread from the U.S. to Europe

and Asia (Baccardax 2002).

This paper tries to address the joint determination of weather hedging and inventory

decisions in a newsvendor setting, where the newsvendor sells a seasonal product and

faces inventory risk due to weather uncertainty. In our model, a single type of hedge

contract, i.e., a weather call option, is considered. The risk-averse newsvendor needs to

jointly determine the production/ordering quantity and the number of options to buy.

Particularly, we analyze the problem with the risk measure of conditional value-at-risk

(CVaR). The CVaR criterion measures the average value of the profit falling below a

certain quantile level, or value at risk (VaR), which is defined as the maximum profit at

a specified confidence level (Jorion 2006). CVaR is a coherent risk measure for

quantifying risk and has better computational characteristics than VaR does (Artzner

et al. 1999), and thus CVaR has emerged as a practical approach for modeling risk

aversion. A vast literature of financial risk management has been developed based on

CVaR in recent years. However, an objective that is based solely on the conditional

value at risk may be too conservative. Hence, this paper considers the mean-risk

framework, i.e., the newsvendor’s objective is to balance the expected profit and the

conditional value at risk.

The rest of the paper is organized as follows. In the next section, we give a brief

literature review, which is followed by the formulation of the problem. Main

analysis and results are presented in Sect. 4. A summary is given in Sect. 5. All of

the technical proofs are included in the Appendix.

2 Literature Review

For production/inventory risk, as faced by the newsvendor in our problem, one

common hedging method is so-called ‘‘operational hedging’’ on which the research

is enormous. The term operational hedging is set apart from ‘‘financial hedging’’ as

follows. The latter is realized through financial tools, such as options and swaps,

whereas the former manages a firm’s risk operationally, such as delaying production

decisions until more accurate demand information is acquired or building a flexible

capacity to better match supply and demand. In a recent survey, Boyabatli and

Toktay (2004) provide an excellent summary and critique on the existing literature

on operational hedging. There are also some papers discussing the joint use of

operational and financial hedging. For example, Ding et al. (2004) study the

integrated operational and financial hedging decisions of a risk averse global firm

facing demand and exchange rate uncertainties. Chod et al. (2006) consider a two-

product newsvendor and discuss the interaction between the product flexibility and

financial hedging when product demands are correlated. For our problem, in which

the inventory risk is mainly associated with weather sensitive demand, we focus on

financial hedging to investigate the advantages of the newly developed financial

tools for hedging weather risk.

Joint optimal ordering and weather hedging decisions 3

123

Page 4: Joint optimal ordering and weather hedging decisions: mean-CVaR model

In the literature addressing financial hedging in line with operations management,

Caldentey and Haugh (2006) generally investigate the optimal control and hedging

of operations in the presence of financial markets. Their hedging strategy is built

upon the financial asset whose price affects the operating profit. Addressing the

quantity risk in the electricity market, the study of Oum et al. (2006) is also related

to our paper. In Oum et al. (2006), a hedging strategy is developed through a

portfolio of forward contracts and the call and put options of electricity. Their model

does not overlap with ours, because unlike weather, electricity itself has a market

price. Gaur and Seshadri (2005) is the study closest in spirit to our problem. They

address the problem of hedging inventory risk in a newsvendor setting, in which the

product demand is correlated with the price of a financial asset. In their mean-

variance objective model, the newsvendor makes joint decisions on the order

quantity and on the hedging strategy by constructing a portfolio, including the

financial asset, to replicate the newsvendor payoff function. However, in our model,

the weather index is not a tradable asset (Cao and Wei 2004). This makes the

replication approach infeasible, e.g., one cannot short-sell the weather index as a

tradable asset (Hull 2003). In their utility model, they investigate the problem under

general utility function while in our paper, we investigate the weather risk hedging

problem under mean-CVaR criterion.

It is known that there are two main approaches to incorporating risk in risk-

averse supply chain models: one is through utility maximization, and the other is

through the return-risk tradeoff. Lau (1980), Eeckhoudt et al. (1995), Bouakiz and

Sobel (1992), and Chen et al. (2007) study the newsvendor or multi-period

inventory models under the utility framework. In practice, however, utility functions

are too conceptual to identify. To deal with the tradeoff between reward and risk,

mean-variance analysis is an important approach. The mean-variance formulation

was first introduced by Markowitz (1952) for portfolio selection analysis, and

became a common criterion when addressing risk thereafter, not only in the

financial and economic areas, but also for operation and management issues (see

Chen and Federgruen 2000; Gaur and Seshadri 2005; Ding et al. 2004; Caldentey

and Haugh 2006; Seifert et al. 2004). However, it falls to distinguishing between

desirable upside and undesirable downside outcomes. In our paper, we take CVaR

as the risk measure. Compared to utility functions, CVaR is much easier to quantify,

because the only subjective parameter for CVaR is the confidence level, that is the

reason for a wide adoption of VaR and CVaR in the field of risk management. To

reflect the tradeoff between return and risk, we investigate our problem in mean-

CVaR criterion, which is indeed a convex combination of the upside and downside

returns (see Remark 1).

Recently, the CVaR measure has drawn much attention as a coherent and easily-

computed risk criterion in the portfolio management literatures (see Rockafellar and

Uryasev 2000, 2002; Acerbi and Tasche 2002a, b; Szego 2002). In the inventory

literature, a number of recent papers have begun to use the CVaR framework to

analyze the newsvendor and multiple period inventory models, e.g., Gotoh and

Takano (2007), Ahmed et al. (2007), Choi and Ruszczynski (2007), and Chen et al.

(2006). These papers, however, do not consider the risk hedging issue.

4 F. Gao et al.

123

Page 5: Joint optimal ordering and weather hedging decisions: mean-CVaR model

The weather risk management we discussed in this paper is receiving discussion

from other literature (e.g., Dischel 2001; Harrington and Niehaus 2003; Chen and

Yano 2010). Chen and Yano (2010) discuss the use of rebate in improving supply

chain’s profit with and without limiting risk under weather-related demand

uncertainty. Our paper does not consider the supply chain issue and discusses the

weather risk management with weather derivatives under the risk measure of CVaR.

The literature on pricing weather derivatives (e.g., Jewson and Rodrigo 2002;

Jewson 2003; Cao and Wei 2004) provide the foundation for weather risk hedging

from the financial perspective. However, little attention has been devoted to the

interaction between weather risk and operations management, which we address in

this paper.

3 Formulation and notation

Suppose that a newsvendor sells a seasonal product whose demand is contingent on

the seasonal weather, such as the average seasonal temperature. Favorable weather

generates strong sales and hence high revenue, whereas unfavorable weather

significantly shrinks demand, and sometimes even causes severe losses. To protect

his revenue, the newsvendor can buy a number of weather options in a weather

derivatives market that will pay him if the weather is unfavorable and thereby

compensates for weak revenue. (Take the excerpt from a disguised case study,

Dischel and Barrieu (2001), to motivate our model.) The level of compensation

depends on the number of options that the newsvendor purchases. The actual total

profit depends on the initial order quantity, the weather, the actual demand, and the

compensation level. Thus, the newsvendor needs to decide on both the number of

options to purchase (n) and the initial order quantity (Q) to maximize the value of

his objective function.

Let Dð�; tÞ denote the random seasonal demand parameterized by weather index

t and another random source �, which is independent of t. In this paper, t is taken as

the seasonal average temperature. We assume both the random variables and the

demand function are continuous. Assume Dð�; tÞ is stochastically decreasing in t.2

For notational simplicity, we hereafter drop off � in Dð�; tÞ. (Note for given t, D(t) is

still a random variable.) Thus for t1� t2, the random variable D(t1) is less than D(t2)

in a stochastic order. Then for any increasing (decreasing) function w, we have that

ED½wðDðt1ÞÞ� �ED½wðDðt2ÞÞ�: (ED½wðDðt1ÞÞ� �ED½wðDðt2ÞÞ�:) Further denote by

gð�; tÞ and Gð�; tÞ the density and cumulative distribution functions of Dð�; tÞ,respectively, when t is given. We also assume the distribution of t to be common

knowledge to both the option writer and the newsvendor.

The newsvendor can use weather call option to hedge the risk associated with

weather fluctuations. The structure of weather call option is illustrated in Fig. 2. To

2 For example, Dð�; tÞ ¼ a� bt þ �; b [ 0 and Dð�; tÞ ¼ ða� btÞ�; b [ 0�[ 0, for which the correlation

between the demand and temperature t is q ¼ �brtffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi

b2r2t þr2

p and q ¼ �bl�rt

rDð�;tÞrespectively, where r stands for

standard deviation and l stands for expected value. We see that the demand is negatively correlated with

temperature t.

Joint optimal ordering and weather hedging decisions 5

123

Page 6: Joint optimal ordering and weather hedging decisions: mean-CVaR model

get one unit of such an option, the newsvendor needs to pay a price of K. If the

realized seasonal average temperature is greater (lower) than �t, the strike average

temperature, then the newsvendor receives k for each unit of deviation ðt � �tÞþ(nothing), but the total amount is capped at �k. For simplicity, we let the risk-free

interest rate be zero. Then, the net payoff per option to the newsvendor is

minð�k; kðt � �tÞþÞ � K. Naturally, �k [ K. When demand is stochastically increasing

in the average temperature, a put option can be used to hedge the weather risk, and

the analysis in the sequel can easily be extended to such a case.

Each unit of sales earns the newsvender p. The pre-season purchasing cost is

c per unit of product. Any leftover at the end of the season will be salvaged at s. To

avoid triviality, assume that 0 \ s \ c \ p. As in most of the risk-averse inventory

models, we ignore the shortage cost (other than foregone profit p - c) for ease of

analysis. This assumption is without loss of generality but simplifies the technical

analysis and exposition.

Given Q, the order quantity and n, the number of options bought (selling option is

regarded as purchasing a negative number of options), the net profit of the

newsvendor at the end of the season is a random variable, which can be expressed as

PðQ; n;DðtÞÞ ¼ P1ðQ;DðtÞÞ þ nP2ðtÞ;

where

P1ðQ;DðtÞÞ ¼ � cQþ p minðQ;DðtÞÞ þ sðQ� DðtÞÞþ

¼ ðp� sÞDðtÞ � ðc� sÞQ� ðp� sÞðDðtÞ � QÞþ;

and

P2ðtÞ ¼ minð�k; kðt � �tÞþÞ � K: ð1Þ

Note that PðQ; n;DðtÞÞ is jointly concave in (Q, n). Given the option, denote by

Pl2 ¼ �Kð\0Þ; and Pu

2 ¼ �k � Kð[ 0Þ the minimum and maximum values of

P2ðtÞ, respectively.

Fig. 2 A weather call option

6 F. Gao et al.

123

Page 7: Joint optimal ordering and weather hedging decisions: mean-CVaR model

When the option is charged with price equal to the expected payoff (to the option

buyer), i.e., K ¼ E½minð�k; kðt � �tÞþÞ�, such that E½P2ðtÞ� ¼ 0, the option is called

fairly priced. With fair price, the option writer (seller) can only break even in the

long run. However in practice, the option writer would expect to obtain a risk

premium beyond the fair price for taking the risk of having to pay out. Hence it is

more reasonable that the option price would then be higher than the average payoff

of the option. Nevertheless, in a competitive market, the risk premium should not be

too high, as otherwise, over-supply will drive it to a lower level. A simple method

for determining the risk premium for weather options has been suggested as a

fraction of the standard deviation of the option payoff (see Jewson and Brix 2005).

However, there remains the issue of what fraction is appropriate.

Related literatures on financial hedging usually assume the derivatives analyzed

are fairly priced to draw analytical results for technical reasons (e.g., Gaur and

Seshadri 2005; Ding et al 2004). The fair price is also recommended for analysis on

weather options in Hull (2003). By assuming the option is fairly priced, i.e., the

expected value of the option is zero, the possibility of selling instead of buying options

is eliminated, and the risk reduction effect is emphasized. Therefore, in the sequel, to

draw insights into the impact of weather hedging on the utility value of the decision

maker and the optimal ordering quantity, we often analyze the case in which

E½P2ðtÞ� ¼ 0. This provides a reasonable approximation for cases when the risk

premium of the option is relatively small (as compared with the overall price K).

The model can also be modified for a situation in which the newsvendor is a

manufacturer who has to procure materials with long lead time, but the selling

season is relatively short.

4 Objective of mean-conditional value at risk

We study the problem under mean-CVaR criterion. To present the mean-CVaR

objective function, we first introduce CVaR and relevant VaR notions.

CVaR is defined based on the risk measure of Value-at-Risk (VaR) which is

commonly used by financial institutions and companies that are involved in trading

energy and other commodities, see, e.g., Jorion (2006) for detailed discussions. VaR

allows the decision maker to specify a confidence level b to expect that he can attain

a certain level of wealth. In general, the b-VaR of an investment is the value v such

that there is at least b percent chance that the profit from the investment will be no

less than v. For example, if we know for a confidence level of b = 0.96 that the VaR

or v = $1 million, then there is at least a 96% chance that the investment will gain $1

million or even more. In addition, for a confidence level of b = 0.90, if v =

-$0.5 million, then there is at most a 10% chance that the investment will lose

more than $0.5 million. The formal definition of b-VaR is given as follow.

Denote the probability of PðQ; n;DðtÞÞ not falling below a threshold v by

WðQ; n; vÞ ¼ PðPðQ; n;DðtÞÞ� vÞ: ð2Þ

For a confidence level b 2 ½0; 1Þ, the b-VaR of the profit associated with decisions

Q and n is the value

Joint optimal ordering and weather hedging decisions 7

123

Page 8: Joint optimal ordering and weather hedging decisions: mean-CVaR model

vbðQ; nÞ ¼ maxfvjWðQ; n; vÞ� bg: ð3Þ

The maximum in (3) is attained because WðQ; n; vÞ is nonincreasing and left-

continuous in v.

The b-CVaR then measures the average value of the profit falling below the vb

level. Denote by /b(Q, n) as the b-CVaR of the profit function PðQ; n;DðtÞÞassociated with the decision variables. The larger the b is, the larger the confidence

level for profit is set, hence the more risk averse the newsvendor is.

Rockafellar and Uryasev (2000, 2002) show that the optimization of b-CVaR can

be achieved by optimizing a much simpler auxiliary function without having to first

calculate the b-VaR on which the b-CVaR is defined. And instead, the b-VaR may

be obtained as a byproduct. For our problem setting, the auxiliary function is

FbðQ; n; vÞ ¼ v� 1

1� bE½v�PðQ; n;DðtÞÞ�þ: ð4Þ

It is concave in v, and

/bðQ; nÞ ¼ maxv2R

FbðQ; n; vÞ: ð5Þ

The set fvjv 2 arg maxvFbðQ; n; vÞg is a nonempty, closed, bounded interval

(perhaps reducing to a single point), and the b-VaR, vb(Q, n), is its upper endpoint.

Without option hedging, the b-CVaR of the newsvendor’s profit is

/bðQÞ ¼ maxv

FbðQ; vÞ ¼ maxvfv� 1

1� bE½v�P1ðQ;DðtÞÞ�þg: ð6Þ

As a coherent risk measure, CVaR is widely used in portfolio selection problems

for multiple decision variables. However, there are certain limitations for CVaR, the

major one of which is due to the fact that when being used as a single decision

criterion, it is too conservative for the decision maker because only the worst

outcomes are considered while the part of the profit distribution above VaR are

ignored. For large b, the b-CVaR criterion ‘‘underscores’’ risk-aversion but neglects

a large part of the profit distribution; whereas for small b, the b-CVaR criterion

encompasses a large part of the profit distribution and does not reflect the decision

maker’s real risk attitude. Indeed, as b approaches 0, the b-CVaR criterion will lead

to the same decision as in the risk-neutral case, as to be shown later.

To overcome this weakness of the CVaR criterion, we propose an objective

function which is a convex combination of the expected profit and b-CVaR. Such a

joint objective reflects the desire of the risk-averse retailer to maximize the profit on

the one hand, and minimize the downside risk of his profit on the other. In other

words, the retailer strikes a balance or tradeoff between profit and risk.

Then the objective function for the newsvendor can be expressed as

maxðQ;nÞ

kE½PðQ; n;DðtÞÞ� þ ð1� kÞ/bðQ; nÞ� �

¼ maxðQ;nÞfkE½PðQ; n;DðtÞÞ� þ ð1� kÞmax

vFbðQ; n; vÞg

¼ maxðQ;n;vÞ

fkE½PðQ; n;DðtÞÞ� þ ð1� kÞFbðQ; n; vÞg;

ð7Þ

8 F. Gao et al.

123

Page 9: Joint optimal ordering and weather hedging decisions: mean-CVaR model

where k is a weight, 0� k� 1. If k = 0, the objective function reduces to the

b-CVaR criterion; if k = 1, then the objective function reduces to the risk neutral

newsvendor model. When b = 0, it also reduces to the classical newsvendor model.

The smaller the weight k assigned to the expected profit and the larger the value of

the confidence level b is, the more risk averse the newsvendor is. Note that the risk

factor b also compromises the expected profit: the larger b becomes, the lower the

expected profit the newsvendor can get. Therefore, as a tradeoff objective, the value

of b in (7) should be chosen close to 1 to take account of the tail effect, i.e., to

capture the downside risk, whereas the value of k is chosen to reflect the weight

between the expected profit and risk.

For k 2 ð0; 1Þ, the optimization problem in (7) with the objective as a convex

combination of mean and CVaR can be rewritten as

maxðQ;n;vÞ

E½PðQ; n;DðtÞÞ� � 1� kk

~FbðQ; n; vÞ; ð8Þ

where ~FbðQ; n; vÞ ¼ �FbðQ; n; vÞ. Mathematically, (8) is equivalent to

max E½PðQ; n;DðtÞÞ�s.t.; ~FbðQ; n; vÞ� r;

ð9Þ

or

min ~FbðQ; n; vÞs.t.;E½PðQ; n;DðtÞÞ� � e:

ð10Þ

By optimization theory, if ðQ�; n�; v�Þ solves problem (8), then it solves (9) with

r ¼ ~FbðQ�; n�; v�Þ and it solves (10) with e ¼ E½PðQ�; n�;DðtÞÞ�. Same sort of

argument and formulation are used in Li and Ng (2000), who consider mean-

variance formulation. A frontier of solution can be generated by varying the value of

k. Note in our problem, Fb(Q, n, v) quantifies the downside profit, then ~FbðQ; n; vÞstands for the corresponding downside loss.

Without option hedging, the tradeoff objective of the newsvendor is

maxQ

kE½P1ðQ;DðtÞÞ� þ ð1� kÞ/bðQÞn o

¼ maxðQ;vÞfkE½P1ðQ;DðtÞÞ� þ ð1� kÞFbðQ; vÞg:

ð11Þ

Denote ðQ�; n�Þ and Q as the optimal solutions of (7) and (11), respectively.

Lemma 1 Fb(Q, n, v) is jointly concave in (Q, n, v).

With Lemma 1, the optimization of the mean-CVaR objective, i.e., (7), reduces

to a concave maximization problem by noting that the profit function PðQ; n;DðtÞÞis jointly concave in (Q, n). Without option hedging, it can be similarly proved that

the auxiliary function FbðQ; vÞ is jointly concave in (Q, v), thus (11) reduces to a

concave maximization problem also.

Joint optimal ordering and weather hedging decisions 9

123

Page 10: Joint optimal ordering and weather hedging decisions: mean-CVaR model

To better understand the meaning of the mean-CVaR tradeoff objective, we give

the following remark.

Remark 1 When the distribution of profit function has no probability atom

(Rockafellar and Uryasev 2002), the definition of b-CVaR of a profit function

Pð~x; ~yÞ, where ~x is decision vector, and ~y is random vector, reduces to

/bð~xÞ ¼ E½Pð~x; ~yÞjPð~x; ~yÞ� vbð~xÞ�:

Then the mean-CVaR tradeoff objective can be rewritten in the following way:

kE½Pð~x; ~yÞ� þ ð1� kÞ/bð~xÞ ¼ kð1� bÞE½Pð~x; ~yÞjPð~x; ~yÞ� vbð~xÞ�þ kbE½Pð~x; ~yÞjPð~x; ~yÞ[ vbð~xÞ� þ ð1� kÞE½Pð~x; ~yÞjPð~x; ~yÞ� vbð~xÞ�¼ ð1� kbÞE½Pð~x; ~yÞjPð~x; ~yÞ� vbð~xÞ� þ kbE½Pð~x; ~yÞjPð~x; ~yÞ[ vbð~xÞ�:

Thus, we can say approximately that the mean-CVaR tradeoff is a convex

combination of two conditional expected values: one is conditioned on the lower

profits, and the other is conditioned on the higher profits, which are discriminated by

the vb. The weights represent the retailer’s degree of risk aversion. h

Because the model without weather option hedging is easier to handle than that

with option hedging, and, moreover, its analysis also provides insights into the

analysis of the latter, we first carefully examine the model without options.

4.1 Without option hedging

Proposition 1 Under the objective of the tradeoff between expected profit and the

b-CVaR, the optimal order quantity without option hedging, Q, is determined by

Et½GðQ; tÞ� ¼ 1� c�skðp�sÞ k[ c�s

bðp�sÞ;

Et½GðQ; tÞ� ¼ ð1�bÞðp�cÞð1�kbÞðp�sÞ k� c�s

bðp�sÞ:

(

ð12Þ

Remark 2 From Proposition 1, the following observations can be made.

(a) When k = 0, the tradeoff objective is reduced to the maximization of b-CVaR.

The optimal order quantity, denoted as Q0, is characterized by

Et½GðQ0; tÞ� ¼ ð1� bÞp�cp�s.

(b) When k = 1, the tradeoff objective is reduced to the maximization of expected

profit, i.e., the risk neutral case. The optimal order quantity, denoted as Q1, is

determined by Et½GðQ1; tÞ� ¼ p�cp�s.

(c) For fixed b, the optimal order quantity is increasing in k, i.e., the more weights

the retailer puts on the expected profit, the more he will order since he is less

risk averse. Then Q0� Qk� Q1, where 0 \ k\ 1.

(d) For fixed k, when b [ c�skðp�sÞ, the optimal order quantity is independent of b;

whereas when b� c�skðp�sÞ, the optimal order quantity is decreasing in b.

Furthermore, Q! Q1 as b! 0. h

10 F. Gao et al.

123

Page 11: Joint optimal ordering and weather hedging decisions: mean-CVaR model

It is well known that the optimal ordering quantity for a risk-averse newsvendor

is lower than that for a risk-neutral newsvendor (see Eeckhoudt et al. 1995; Agrawal

and Seshadri 2002). We summarize the monotonicity of the optimal order quantity

in the tradeoff weight k and the risk parameter b in the following Corollary.

Corollary 2 (i) As k increases while b is fixed, i.e., as the newsvendor puts moreweight on the expected profit, a larger quantity will be ordered. (ii) As b. increaseswhile k is fixed, i.e., as the newsvendor becomes more risk-averse, a smallerquantity will be ordered.

With such monotonicity, note that the expected profit is concave in the order

quantity and it attains the maximum value at Q1 when k = 1 or b = 0, we have the

following monotone property for the expected profit in the optimal order quantity Q,

which we denoted as Qðk; bÞ.

Corollary 3 (i) E½P1ðQðk;bÞ;DðtÞÞ� is increasing in k for any given b 2 ð0; 1Þ.(ii) E½P1ðQðk; bÞ;DðtÞÞ� is decreasing in b for any given k 2 ð0; 1Þ.

Corollary 3 indicates that the larger the weight the newsvendor puts on the risk

measure CVaR, or the more the newsvendor is concerned with the downside risk,

the less profit he expects. These two corollaries are intuitive.

4.2 With option hedging

We now consider the mean-CVaR objective with option hedging, which is

represented by (7).

Proposition 4 If the option is fairly priced, i.e., E½P2ðtÞ� ¼ 0, then the optimalnumber of options n� � 0.

When the newsvendor is risk neutral, he has no incentive to buy the fairly priced

option, as it does not create any additional profit. However, when he is risk averse,

although the expected value of the option equals to zero, buying the option can

remove some of the downward risks.

Proposition 5 If G(y; t) is strictly increasing in y for any given t, then Q� � Q ;i.e., the newsvendor orders more in the presence of the weather option.

Proposition 5 can be expected intuitively, because for the maximization of the

expected profit, the newsvendor is risk neutral and will order the same with and

without option hedging, but for CVaR optimization, the newsvendor is risk averse

and will order less without option hedging. Therefore, weather hedging brings the

optimal ordering quantity closer to the risk-neutral profit-maximization quantity.

The technical importance of the result is that in searching for Q*, one can first find

Q, which can be determined almost by a closed form solution, and then starts with

Q ¼ Q upward.

However, for the problem with option hedging, a closed-form solution such as

(12) appears to be impossible. Moreover, an unambiguous monotonicity of the

Joint optimal ordering and weather hedging decisions 11

123

Page 12: Joint optimal ordering and weather hedging decisions: mean-CVaR model

optimal objective function in k and b is difficult to establish. Section 4.3 shows

some counter examples in which the optimal order quantity does not exhibit

monotonicity in k and b, neither does the optimal number of options, n*. This is

because the presence of the option complicates the structure of the optimal objective

function. (We expect such monotonicity properties may exist for some particular

financial instruments, but in this paper we focus on any fairly priced option.) We

also mention that since the correlation between the demand and the temperature is

not a simple parameter (refer to footnote 2), the general analysis of it’s impact on

the hedging effect is not straightforward. Our result that weather hedging increases

the newsvendor’s inventory level is in accordance with that in Gaur and Seshadri

(2005), where they investigate the inventory risk hedging problem using expected

utility. With the use of mean-CVaR criterion, we can observe the hedging effect on

the newsvendor’s risk-averse objective, which is also illustrated in Sect. 4.3.

4.3 Numerical examples

The main objective of the examples is twofold. First, we want to see the magnitude

of the impact of option hedging on the order quantity and objective value. Second,

we provide counterexamples to show non-monotonicity of the optimal solutions in kand b. The demand function is taken as an additive form, DðtÞ ¼ a� bt þ �; where

b [ 0. The average temperature t follows the normal distribution Nðlt; r2t Þ; and

� 2 ð�;��Þ is a uniformly distributed random variable. Let t * N(-5, 2). (Note the

normal distribution is truncated for tractability in our numerical analysis.) The

option is provided as �t ¼ �7; k ¼ 2; �k ¼ 8; with a fair price K = 4. Other

parameters are valued as a ¼ 10; b ¼ 1; � ¼ �1;�� ¼ 1; p ¼ 7; c ¼ 4; and s = 2.

The results for the examples are reported in Table 1a–d. For each combination of

k and b, we calculate the optimal solutions for the cases without/with option

hedging, and report them as QjðQ�; n�Þ in Table 1a. In Table 1b, the corresponding

optimal objective values are presented, from which, we calculate the percentage

gain in the objective value due to option hedging and report the results in Table 1c.

In Table 1d, the corresponding values of the mean and CVaR at the optimal solution

are presented as ðMean;CVaRÞ, where for each value of k, the first row corresponds

to the case without option hedging, while the second row corresponds to the case

with option hedging. Note that when k = 0 (1.0), the objective is reduced to the

maximization of b-CVaR (the risk-neutral newsvendor model, as the option is fairly

priced).

Compared with the case without hedging, the optimal order quantity is increased

with option hedging (see Table 1a). When with b-CVaR alone (i.e., k = 0), the

optimal order quantity can be as much as 50% larger with option hedging (see

Table 1a: the cell (k = 0, b = 0.99)). However, as Table 1a indicates, the optimal

order quantity with hedging is not monotonic in k and b. For example, for k, see the

columns with b = 0.3 and b = 0.9 in Table 1a; and for b, see the row with k = 0.1

in Table 1a.

The option hedging also increases the objective value of the risk averse retailer

(see Table 1b). Furthermore, in Table 1c, we observe that the percentage gain in the

12 F. Gao et al.

123

Page 13: Joint optimal ordering and weather hedging decisions: mean-CVaR model

Tab

le1

Op

tim

also

luti

on

and

op

tim

alo

bje

ctiv

ev

alu

e

kb 0

.10

.30

.90

.95

0.9

9

a.O

pti

mal

solu

tio

n

0.0

15

.15

|(1

5.1

5,

0.0

0)

14

.68

|(1

4.9

9,

0.7

1)

12

.62

|(1

5.9

7,

2.3

9)

12

.13

|(1

6.0

5,

2.5

5)

11

.17

|(1

6.0

8,

3.1

3)

0.1

15

.17

|(1

5.2

4,

0.4

0)

14

.74

|(1

5.0

6,

0.8

0)

12

.69

|(1

5.9

4,

2.3

6)

12

.20

|(1

6.0

4,

2.5

4)

11

.23

|(1

6.0

7,

3.1

2)

0.3

15

.21

|(1

5.2

3,

0.1

0)

14

.85

|(1

5.1

6,

0.9

6)

12

.87

|(1

5.8

4,

2.2

7)

12

.36

|(1

6.0

2,

2.5

2)

11

.37

|(1

6.0

4,

3.1

0)

0.5

15

.26

|(1

5.2

8,

0.1

9)

14

.97

|(1

5.2

5,

1.0

6)

13

.71

|(1

5.6

8,

2.1

4)

13

.71

|(1

5.7

9,

2.3

7)

13

.71

|(1

5.8

0,

2.9

5)

0.7

15

.31

|(1

5.3

3,

0.4

5)

15

.12

|(1

5.3

0,

1.1

3)

14

.72

|(1

5.5

0,

2.0

0)

14

.72

|(1

5.5

6,

2.2

2)

14

.72

|(1

5.5

6,

2.8

0)

0.9

15

.36

|(1

5.3

7,

0.5

3)

15

.29

|(1

5.3

6,

1.1

6)

15

.21

|(1

5.4

6,

2.0

0)

15

.21

|(1

5.4

2,

2.1

9)

15

.21

|(1

5.4

3,

2.7

2)

1.0

15

.39

|(1

5.3

9,

-)1

5.3

9|(

15

.39

,–

)1

5.3

9|(

15

.39

,–)

15

.39

|(1

5.3

9,

–)

15

.39

|(1

5.3

9,

–)

b.

Op

tim

alo

bje

ctiv

ev

alu

e

0.0

41

.61

|41

.61

40

.72

|40

.75

35

.90

|37

.38

34

.62

|36

.60

32

.07

|34

.53

0.1

41

.65

|41

.65

40

.82

|40

.87

36

.09

|37

.83

34

.80

|37

.12

32

.22

|35

.25

0.3

41

.73

|41

.73

41

.04

|41

.12

36

.53

|38

.72

35

.22

|38

.15

32

.59

|36

.70

0.5

41

.81

|41

.81

41

.28

|41

.38

37

.22

|39

.65

36

.05

|39

.21

33

.78

|38

.17

0.7

41

.90

|41

.90

41

.55

|41

.63

38

.87

|40

.59

38

.17

|40

.32

36

.80

|39

.69

0.9

41

.99

|41

.99

41

.86

|41

.90

40

.93

|41

.55

40

.69

|41

.46

40

.24

|41

.25

1.0

42

.03

|42

.03

42

.03

|42

.03

42

.03

|42

.03

42

.03

|42

.03

42

.03

|42

.03

c.P

erce

nta

ge

gai

nin

ob

ject

ive

val

ue

by

hed

gin

g

0.0

0.0

0%

0.0

7%

4.1

2%

5.7

2%

7.6

7%

0.1

0.0

0%

0.1

2%

4.7

4%

6.6

7%

9.4

0%

0.3

0.0

0%

0.1

9%

6.0

0%

8.3

2%

12

.61

%

0.5

0.0

0%

0.2

4%

6.5

3%

8.7

7%

13

.00

%

0.7

0.0

0%

0.1

9%

4.4

3%

5.6

3%

7.8

5%

0.9

0.0

0%

0.1

0%

1.5

1%

1.8

9%

2.5

1%

Joint optimal ordering and weather hedging decisions 13

123

Page 14: Joint optimal ordering and weather hedging decisions: mean-CVaR model

Tab

le1

con

tin

ued

kb 0

.10

.30

.90

.95

0.9

9

1.0

0.0

0%

0.0

0%

0.0

0%

0.0

0%

0.0

0%

d.

Val

ue

of

(Mea

n,

CV

aR)

ato

pti

mal

solu

tio

n

0.0

(42

.00,

41

.61

)(4

1.7

2,

40

.72

)(3

7.6

5,

35

.90

)(3

6.2

9,

34

.62

)(3

3.4

9,

32

.07

)

(42

.00,

41

.61

)(4

1.9

3,

40

.75

)(4

1.8

2,

37

.38

)(4

1.7

7,

36

.60

)(4

1.7

4,

34

.53

)

0.1

(42

.00,

41

.61

)(4

1.7

6,

40

.71

)(3

7.8

5,

35

.89

)(3

6.4

9,

34

.61

)(3

3.6

6,

32

.06

)

(42

.02,

41

.61

)(4

1.9

6,

40

.75

)(4

1.8

4,

37

.38

)(4

1.7

7,

36

.60

)(4

1.7

5,

34

.53

)

0.3

(42

.01,

41

.61

)(4

1.8

5,

40

.69

)(3

8.3

1,

35

.77

)(3

6.9

4,

34

.49

)(3

4.0

7,

31

.95

)

(42

.02,

41

.61

)(4

2.0

0,

40

.74

)(4

1.9

0,

37

.36

)(4

1.7

9,

36

.59

)(4

1.7

7,

34

.53

)

0.5

(42

.02,

41

.60

)(4

1.9

2,

40

.64

)(4

0.2

8,

34

.16

)(4

0.2

8,

31

.83

)(4

0.2

7,

27

.30

)

(42

.02,

41

.60

)(4

2.0

2,

40

.74

)(4

1.9

8,

37

.32

)(4

1.9

3,

36

.49

)(4

1.9

2,

34

.42

)

0.7

(42

.03,

41

.59

)(4

1.9

9,

40

.54

)(4

1.7

4,

32

.16

)(4

1.7

4,

29

.82

)(4

1.7

4,

25

.28

)

(42

.03,

41

.60

)(4

2.0

3,

40

.72

)(4

2.0

2,

37

.25

)(4

2.0

1,

36

.38

)(4

2.0

1,

34

.28

)

0.9

(42

.03,

41

.58

)(4

2.0

3,

40

.38

)(4

2.0

1,

31

.17

)(4

2.0

1,

28

.84

)(4

2.0

1,

24

.30

)

(42

.03,

41

.59

)(4

2.0

3,

40

.70

)(4

2.0

3,

37

.23

)(4

2.0

3,

36

.33

)(4

2.0

3,

34

.23

)

1.0

(42

.03,

–)

(42

.03

,–

)(4

2.0

3,

–)

(42

.03,

–)

(42

.03,

–)

(42

.03,

–)

(42

.03

,–

)(4

2.0

3,

–)

(42

.03,

–)

(42

.03,

–)

14 F. Gao et al.

123

Page 15: Joint optimal ordering and weather hedging decisions: mean-CVaR model

objective value increases in b, which indicates that when the retailer is concerned

with a more adverse scenario, the weather option’s contribution becomes more

extant. However, the percentage profit gain first increases and then decreases in k,

which can be explained as follows. When k increases, the option hedging can

increase the percentage gain in the objective value because it increases the optimal

order quantity and then improves the expected profit, which occupies a larger

fraction of the total objective value with higher value of k. On the other hand, as kcontinues increasing, the problem is more like profit maximization, and the effects

of option hedging on the objective value diminishes.

From the results given in Table 1d, we see that for most examples, the option

hedging not only increases the total expected profit due to the increase in the

ordering quantity, but also improves the value of CVaR, i.e., the average value of

the profit below the vb level. For both cases with and without option hedging, the

frontier of mean-CVaR changes in k and b with same pattern. For fixed k, both the

expected profit and the CVaR value decrease in b, which is intuitive because when

the newsvendor sets a larger confidence level for the profit, he can only expect a

smaller profit value, and the CVaR is taken average below a smaller vb value. For

fixed b, the expected profit is increasing in k while the CVaR is decreasing in k. In

other words, larger total expected profit corresponds to a smaller average downside

profit. However, from the results we also see that with option hedging, either the

mean or the CVaR value is less sensitive to k and b.

In the end of this section, we make a note that when the demand is stochastically

decreasing in temperature t, the option with ‘‘lower’’ strike temperature is seemingly

more preferred, because such an option has more chances of paying out to the

newsvendor. However, the option’s cost, when it is fairly priced, must be higher,

and hence the resulting impact on the newsvendor is unclear. This is substantiated

by the examples shown in Table 2, where Option 1 is �t ¼ �7; k ¼ 2; �k ¼ 8 with fair

price K = 4, and Option 2 is �t ¼ �5; k ¼ 2; �k ¼ 8 with fair price K = 1.13. Other

parameter values are kept unchanged from the basic parameter set. k and b are fixed

as 0.5 and 0.9 respectively. We see that Option 1, which has a lower strike

temperature, has a worse hedging effect than Option 2.

5 Summary

This paper proposes an inventory model with financial hedging by weather

derivatives for seasonal products. The demand for the product is influenced not only

by inherent randomness but also by the weather during the selling season. With the

Table 2 Hedging effects of options with different strike temperatures

Without option With option 1 With option 2

Q Objective value ðQ�; n�1Þ Objective value ðQ�; n�2Þ Objective value

13.71 37.22 (15.68, 2.14) 39.65 (14.43, 2.84) 40.42

Joint optimal ordering and weather hedging decisions 15

123

Page 16: Joint optimal ordering and weather hedging decisions: mean-CVaR model

existence of weather hedging markets, a risk averse newsvendor can use a weather

option to hedge the financial risk caused by unfavorable weather conditions. The

newsvendor’s problem is to make a joint order-quantity and hedging decision to

optimize his objective value.

Analytical results have been established under the mean-CVaR criterion. It has

been shown that the risk averse newsvendor who is conservative with ordering for

fear of large leftovers due to adverse weather will order more with option hedging.

Numerical analysis confirms the analytical results that the optimal order quantity

and objective value are increased with the option hedging. Furthermore, the optimal

order quantity does not exhibit definite monotonicity in the risk-parameters, and the

option hedging may help the risk averse retailer improve both the expected overall

profit and the average downside profit for undesired situation.

Acknowledgments The authors are grateful to the Editor in Chief Professor Hans-Otto Guenther, the

anonymous SE and two reviewers for their constructive comments. The authors also benefited from

discussions with Professors Minghui Xu, Simai He, Janny Leung and Sridhar Seshadri. The research of

Frank Y. Chen was supported in part by the Hong Kong Research Grants Council under grant no.

CUHK411105. The research of Xiuli Chao was partially supported by the NSF under CMMI-0800004

and CMMI-0927631.

Appendix

Proof of Lemma 1 For any k 2 ½0; 1�, and any two different points ðQ1; n1; v1Þand ðQ2; n2; v2Þ,

FbðkðQ1; n1; v1Þ þ ð1� kÞðQ2; n2; v2ÞÞ¼ FbðkQ1 þ ð1� kÞQ2; kn1 þ ð1� kÞn2; kv1 þ ð1� kÞv2Þ¼ kv1 þ ð1� kÞv2 � ð1� bÞ�1

E½kv1 þ ð1� kÞv2

�PðkQ1 þ ð1� kÞQ2; kn1 þ ð1� kÞn2;DðtÞÞ�þ:

As PðQ; n;DðtÞÞ is jointly concave in (Q, n),

PðkQ1 þ ð1� kÞQ2; kn1 þ ð1� kÞn2;DðtÞÞ¼ PðkðQ1; n1Þ þ ð1� kÞðQ2; n2Þ;DðtÞÞ� kPðQ1; n1;DðtÞÞ þ ð1� kÞPðQ2; n2;DðtÞÞ:

Hence,

½kv1 þ ð1� kÞv2 �PðkQ1 þ ð1� kÞQ2; kn1 þ ð1� kÞn2;DðtÞÞ�þ

� ½kv1 þ ð1� kÞv2 � kPðQ1; n1;DðtÞÞ � ð1� kÞPðQ2; n2;DðtÞÞ�þ

¼ ½kðv1 �PðQ1; n1;DðtÞÞÞ þ ð1� kÞðv2 �PðQ2; n2;DðtÞÞÞ�þ

� k½v1 �PðQ1; n1;DðtÞÞ�þ þ ð1� kÞ½v2 �PðQ2; n2;DðtÞÞ�þ;

the last inequality holds due to the convexity of function ½��þ.

Then, substituting the above inequality into (13) yields

16 F. Gao et al.

123

Page 17: Joint optimal ordering and weather hedging decisions: mean-CVaR model

FbðkðQ1; n1; v1Þ þ ð1� kÞðQ2; n2; v2ÞÞ� kv1 þ ð1� kÞv2 � ð1� bÞ�1

Efk½v1 �PðQ1; n1;DðtÞÞ�þ

þ ð1� kÞ½v2 �PðQ2; n2;DðtÞÞ�þg ¼ kfv1 � ð1� bÞ�1E½v1 �PðQ1; n1;DðtÞÞ�þg

þ ð1� kÞfv2 � ð1� bÞ�1E½v2 �PðQ2; n2;DðtÞÞ�þg

¼ kFbðQ1; n1; v1Þ þ ð1� kÞFbðQ2; n2; v2Þ:

Thus, Fb(Q, n, v) is jointly concave in (Q, n, v). h

Proof of Proposition 1 Note the objective in (11) for the case without option

hedging,

maxQfkE½P1ðQ;DðtÞÞ� þ ð1� kÞ/bðQÞg

¼ maxQfkE½P1ðQ;DðtÞÞ� þ ð1� kÞmax

vFbðQ; vÞg

¼ maxQfmax

vfkE½P1ðQ;DðtÞÞ� þ ð1� kÞFbðQ; vÞgg

¼ maxðQ;vÞfkE½P1ðQ;DðtÞÞ� þ ð1� kÞFbðQ; vÞg:

Let Fðb;kÞðQ; vÞ ¼ kE½P1ðQ;DðtÞÞ� þ ð1� kÞFbðQ; vÞ ¼ kE½P1ðQ;DðtÞÞ� þ ð1� kÞfv� ð1� bÞ�1

E½v�P1ðQ;DðtÞÞ�þg: Denote by Dl(t) and Du(t) the lower and

upper bounds of D(t), respectively. For fixed Q,

oFðb;kÞðQ;vÞov

¼ð1�kÞ 1� 1

1�bE½1v[P1ðQ;DðtÞÞ�

� �

¼ð1�kÞ 1� 1

1�bEt

Z

Q

DlðtÞ

1v[ðp�sÞx�ðc�sÞQ �gðx;tÞdxþZ

DuðtÞ

Q

1v[ðp�cÞQ �gðx;tÞdx

2

6

4

3

7

5

8

>

<

>

:

9

>

=

>

;

¼ð1�kÞ 1� 1

1�bEt

Z

minðQ;vþðc�sÞQp�s Þ

DlðtÞ

gðx;tÞdxþZ

DuðtÞ

Q

1v[ðp�cÞQ �gðx;tÞdx

2

6

6

4

3

7

7

5

8

>

>

<

>

>

:

9

>

>

=

>

>

;

¼ð1�kÞ 1� 1

1�bEt

R

vþðc�sÞQp�s

DlðtÞgðx;tÞdx

2

4

3

5

8

<

:

9

=

;

ifv�ðp�cÞQ;

ð1�kÞ � b1�b

h i

ifv[ðp�cÞQ:

8

>

>

>

>

<

>

>

>

>

:

At the point (p - c)Q,

Joint optimal ordering and weather hedging decisions 17

123

Page 18: Joint optimal ordering and weather hedging decisions: mean-CVaR model

o�Fðb;kÞðQ; vÞov

jv¼ðp�cÞQ ¼ ð1� kÞ 1� 1

1� bEt

Z

Q

DlðtÞ

gðx; tÞdx

2

6

4

3

7

5

8

>

<

>

:

9

>

=

>

;

;

oþFðb;kÞðQ; vÞov

jv¼ðp�cÞQ ¼ ð1� kÞ � b1� b

� �

� 0:

(1) Ifo�Fðb;kÞðQ;vÞ

ov jv¼ðp�cÞQ\0, the maximizer v of Fðb;kÞðQ; vÞ satisfies v\ðp� cÞQand is determined by

1� 1

1� bEt

Z

vþðc�sÞQp�s

DlðtÞ

gðx; tÞdx

2

6

6

4

3

7

7

5

¼ 0: ð13Þ

In this case,

Fðb;kÞðQ; vÞ¼kE½p1ðQ;DðtÞÞ�

þð1�kÞ v�ð1�bÞ�1Et

Z

vþðc�sÞQp�s

DlðtÞ

ðvþðc�sÞQ�ðp�sÞxÞgðx;tÞdx

2

6

6

4

3

7

7

5

8

>

>

<

>

>

:

9

>

>

=

>

>

;

dFðb;kÞðQ; vÞdQ

¼oFðb;kÞðQ; vÞ

oQþ

oFðb;kÞðQ; vÞov

ov

oQ

¼kf�cþsþðp�sÞE½1DðtÞ[Q�gþð1�kÞ

ð1�bÞ�1ð�cþsÞEt

Z

vþðc�sÞQp�s

DlðtÞ

gðx;tÞdx

��

þ0

¼kf�cþsþðp�sÞE½1DðtÞ[Q�gþð1�kÞð�cþsÞ¼kf�cþsþðp�sÞð1�Et½GðQ;tÞ�Þgþð1�kÞð�cþsÞ¼kðp�cÞ�kðp�sÞEt½GðQ;tÞ��ð1�kÞðc�sÞ:

Then Q satisfies Et½GðQ; tÞ� ¼ kðp�cÞ�ð1�kÞðc�sÞkðp�sÞ ¼ 1� c�s

kðp�sÞ, where k[ c�sbðp�sÞ to

make the conditiono�Fðb;kÞðQ;vÞ

ov jv¼ðp�cÞQ\0 hold true.

(2) Ifo�Fðb;kÞðQ;vÞ

ov jv¼ðp�cÞQ� 0, note that the auxiliary function is concave in v, then

v ¼ ðp� cÞQ. In this case,

Fðb;kÞðQ; ðp� cÞQÞ ¼ kE½P1ðQ;DðtÞÞ�

þ ð1� kÞ ðp� cÞQ� ð1� bÞ�1Et

Z

Q

DlðtÞ

ððp� sÞQ� ðp� sÞxÞgðx; tÞdx

2

6

4

3

7

5

8

>

<

>

:

9

>

=

>

;

;

18 F. Gao et al.

123

Page 19: Joint optimal ordering and weather hedging decisions: mean-CVaR model

then

dFðb;kÞðQ; ðp� cÞQÞdQ

¼ kf�cþ sþ ðp� sÞE½1DðtÞ[ Q�g þ ð1� kÞ(

ðp� cÞ

� ð1� bÞ�1ðp� sÞEt

"

Z

Q

DlðtÞ

gðx; tÞdx

#)

¼ kf�cþ sþ ðp� sÞð1� Et½GðQ; tÞ�Þg

þ ð1� kÞfðp� cÞ � ð1� bÞ�1ðp� sÞEt½GðQ; tÞ�g¼ ðp� cÞ � ðkþ ð1� kÞð1� bÞ�1Þðp� sÞEt½GðQ; tÞ�:

Then Q satisfies Et½GðQ; tÞ� ¼ ð1�bÞðp�cÞð1�kbÞðp�sÞ, where k� c�s

bðp�sÞ to make the conditiono�Fðb;kÞðQ;vÞ

ov jv¼ðp�cÞQ� 0 hold true.

From the above analysis, the optimal order quantity without option hedging

under the tradeoff criterion, Q, is determined by (12). h

We give here Lemma 2 which will be repeatedly used in the proofs of the results

to follow.

Lemma 2 Let G1ð�Þ and G2ð�Þ be two integrable functions. If they have contrarymonotonicity, then E½G1ðtÞG2ðtÞ� �E½G1ðtÞ�E½G2ðtÞ�, and if they have samemonotonicity, then E½G1ðtÞG2ðtÞ� �E½G1ðtÞ�E½G2ðtÞ�; where t is a continuousrandom variable.

Proof If G1ð�Þ and G2ð�Þ have contrary monotonicity, for any realizations t and s,

we have ½G1ðtÞ � G1ðsÞ�½G2ðtÞ � G2ðsÞ� � 0) G1ðtÞG2ðtÞ þ G1ðsÞG2ðsÞ�G1ðtÞG2ðsÞ þ G1ðsÞG2ðtÞ. Assuming the density function of t to be f ð�Þ;

E½G1ðtÞ�E½G2ðtÞ� : ¼ E½G1ðtÞ�E½G2ðsÞ�

¼Z

t

G1ðtÞf ðtÞdt

Z

s

G2ðsÞf ðsÞds

¼Z

t

G1ðtÞf ðtÞ�

Z

s

G2ðsÞf ðsÞds

dt

¼Z Z

t�s

G1ðtÞG2ðsÞf ðtÞf ðsÞdsdt

¼Z Z

t�s

G1ðtÞG2ðsÞ þ G1ðsÞG2ðtÞ2

f ðtÞf ðsÞdsdt

�Z Z

t�s

G1ðtÞG2ðtÞ þ G1ðsÞG2ðsÞ2

f ðtÞf ðsÞdsdt

¼Z

t

G1ðtÞG2ðtÞf ðtÞdt

¼ E½G1ðtÞG2ðtÞ�;

Joint optimal ordering and weather hedging decisions 19

123

Page 20: Joint optimal ordering and weather hedging decisions: mean-CVaR model

i.e., E½G1ðtÞG2ðtÞ� �E½G1ðtÞ�E½G2ðtÞ�: Similarly, if G1ð�Þ and G2ð�Þ have same

monotonicity, it holds that E½G1ðtÞG2ðtÞ� �E½G1ðtÞ�E½G2ðtÞ�. h

Proof of Proposition 4 Note the objective in (7) for the case with option hedging,

maxðQ;nÞfkE½PðQ; n;DðtÞÞ� þ ð1� kÞ/bðQ; nÞg

¼ maxðQ;nÞfkE½PðQ; n;DðtÞÞ� þ ð1� kÞmax

vFbðQ; n; vÞg

¼ maxðQ;n;vÞ

fkE½PðQ; n;DðtÞÞ� þ ð1� kÞFbðQ; n; vÞg:

Let Fðb;kÞðQ; n; vÞ ¼ kE½PðQ; n;DðtÞÞ�þ ð1� kÞFbðQ; n; vÞ ¼ kE½PðQ; n;DðtÞÞ� þð1� kÞ fv� ð1� bÞ�1

E½v�PðQ; n;DðtÞÞ�þg:oFðb;kÞðQ; n; vÞ

onjn¼0 ¼ kE½P2ðtÞ� þ

1� k1� b

E½P2ðtÞ � 1P1ðQ;DðtÞÞ\v�:

Both P2ðtÞ and ED½1P1ðQ;DðtÞÞ\vjt� are increasing in t (It is easy to check that for

given Q;P1ðQ; �Þ is an increasing function and 1P1ðQ;�Þ\v is a decreasing function

then ED½1P1ðQ;DðtÞÞ\vjt� is increasing in t by the assumption that D(t) is stochastically

decreasing in t.), so by Lemma 2, if E½P2ðtÞ� ¼ 0,

oFðb;kÞðQ; n; vÞon

jn¼0�1� k1� b

E½P2ðtÞ�E½1P1ðQ;DðtÞÞ\v� ¼ 0:

By concavity of Fðb;kÞðQ; n; vÞ; n� � 0. h

Proof of Proposition 5

oFðb;kÞðQ; n; vÞov

¼ ð1� kÞf1� ð1� bÞ�1E½1v [ PðQ;n;DðtÞÞ�g

¼ ð1� kÞ(

1� ð1� bÞ�1Et

"

Z

Q

DlðtÞ

1v [ ðp�sÞx�ðc�sÞQþnP2ðtÞ � gðx; tÞdx

þZ

DuðtÞ

Q

1v [ ðp�cÞQþnP2ðtÞ � gðx; tÞdx

#)

¼ ð1� kÞ(

1� ð1� bÞ�1Et

"

Z

minðQ;vþðc�sÞQ�nP2ðtÞp�s Þ

DlðtÞ

gðx; tÞdx

þZ

DuðtÞ

Q

1v [ ðp�cÞQþnP2ðtÞ � gðx; tÞdx

#)

:

ð14Þ

20 F. Gao et al.

123

Page 21: Joint optimal ordering and weather hedging decisions: mean-CVaR model

If n [ 0;oFðb;kÞðQ;n;vÞ

ov jv¼ð�cþsÞQþnPl2¼ 1� k; and

o�Fðb;kÞðQ; n; vÞov

jv¼ðp�cÞQþnPu2

¼ ð1� kÞ 1� ð1� bÞ�1Et

Z

Q

DlðtÞ

gðx; tÞdxþZ

DuðtÞ

Q

1Pu2 [ P2ðtÞ � gðx; tÞdx

2

6

4

3

7

5

8

>

<

>

:

9

>

=

>

;

¼ ð1� kÞ 1� ð1� bÞ�1Et GðQ; tÞ þ 1Pu

2 [ P2ðtÞð1� GðQ; tÞÞh in o

;

oþFðb;kÞðQ; n; vÞov

jv¼ðp�cÞQþnPu2

¼ ð1� kÞ 1� ð1� bÞ�1Et

Z

Q

DlðtÞ

gðx; tÞdxþZ

DuðtÞ

Q

gðx; tÞdx

2

6

4

3

7

5

8

>

<

>

:

9

>

=

>

;

¼ ð1� kÞð1� ð1� bÞ�1Þ\0:

From Proposition 1,

Et½GðQ; tÞ� ¼ 1� c�skðp�sÞ[ 1� b; k[ c�s

bðp�sÞ;

Et½GðQ; tÞ� ¼ ð1�bÞðp�cÞð1�kbÞðp�sÞ � 1� b; k� c�s

bðp�sÞ:

(

(1) If k [ c�sbðp�sÞ, then

o�Fðb;kÞðQ; n; vÞov

jv¼ðp�cÞQþnPu2�ð1� kÞf1� ð1� bÞ�1

Et½GðQ; tÞ�g\0

by noticing that Et½1Pu2 [ P2ðtÞð1� GðQ; tÞÞ� � 0: Thus, v�ðQ; nÞ 2 ðð�cþ sÞQþ

nPl2; ðp� cÞQþ nPu

2Þ, and by (14),

E½1v�ðQ;nÞ[ PðQ;n;DðtÞÞ� ¼ 1� b;

(2) If k� c�sbðp�sÞ, and if

o�Fðb;kÞðQ;n;vÞov jv¼ðp�cÞQþnPu

2� 0, then v�ðQ; nÞ ¼ ðp� cÞQþ

nPu2, and

Joint optimal ordering and weather hedging decisions 21

123

Page 22: Joint optimal ordering and weather hedging decisions: mean-CVaR model

Fðb;kÞðQ; n; vÞjv¼ðp�cÞQþnPu2¼ kE½PðQ; n;DðtÞÞ� þ ð1� kÞfðp� cÞQþ nPu

2

� ð1� bÞ�1Et

"

Z

Q

DlðtÞ

ððp� sÞðQ� xÞ þ nðPu2 �P2ðtÞÞÞgðx; tÞdx

þZ

DuðtÞ

Q

nðPu2 �P2ðtÞÞgðx; tÞdx

#)

;

oFðb;kÞðQ; n; v�ðQ; nÞÞoQ

jQ¼Q ¼ kfp� c� ðp� sÞEt½GðQ; tÞ�g

þ ð1� kÞ ðp� cÞ � ð1� bÞ�1ðp� sÞEt

Z

Q

DlðtÞ

gðx; tÞdx

2

6

4

3

7

5

8

>

<

>

:

9

>

=

>

;

¼ ðp� cÞ � 1� kb1� b

ðp� sÞEt½GðQ; tÞ� ¼ 0;

(3) If k� c�sbðp�sÞ, and

o�Fðb;kÞðQ;n;vÞov jv¼ðp�cÞQþnPu

2\0, then v�ðQ; nÞ 2 ðð�cþ sÞQþ

nPl2; ðp� cÞQþ nPu

2Þ, and

E½1v�ðQ;nÞ[ PðQ;n;DðtÞÞ� ¼ 1� b:

For the cases (1) and (3), i.e., E½1v�ðQ;nÞ[ PðQ;n;DðtÞÞ� ¼ 1� b;

oFðb;kÞðQ; n; vÞoQ

jQ¼Q ¼ kEoPðQ; n;DðtÞÞ

oQ

" #

þ 1� k1� b

E 1v [PðQ;n;DðtÞÞoPðQ; n;DðtÞÞ

oQ

" #

¼ kfðp� cÞ � ðp� sÞEt½GðQ; tÞ�g

þ 1� k1� b

E½1v [ PðQ;n;DðtÞÞðp� c� ðp� sÞ1DðtÞ\QÞ�

¼ kðp� cÞ � kðp� sÞEt½GðQ; tÞ�

þ 1� k1� b

fðp� cÞE½1v [ PðQ;n;DðtÞÞ�

� ðp� sÞE½1v [PðQ;n;DðtÞÞ1DðtÞ\Q�g:

When k [ c�sbðp�sÞ;Et½GðQ; tÞ� ¼ kðp�cÞ�ð1�kÞðc�sÞ

kðp�sÞ , and

oFðb;kÞðQ; n; v�ðQ; nÞÞoQ

jQ¼Q� kðp� cÞ � kðp� sÞEt½GðQ; tÞ� þ 1� k1� b

fðp� cÞE½1v�ðQ;nÞ[ PðQ;n;DðtÞÞ� � ðp� sÞE½1v�ðQ;nÞ[ PðQ;n;DðtÞÞ�g

¼ ð1� kÞðc� sÞ þ 1� k1� b

fð�cþ sÞE½1v�ðQ;nÞ[ PðQ;n;DðtÞÞ�g ¼ 0:

22 F. Gao et al.

123

Page 23: Joint optimal ordering and weather hedging decisions: mean-CVaR model

When k� c�sbðp�sÞ;Et½GðQ; tÞ� ¼ ð1�bÞðp�cÞ

ð1�bkÞðp�sÞ, and

oFðb;kÞðQ; n; v�ðQ; nÞÞoQ

jQ¼Q� kðp� cÞ � kðp� sÞEt½GðQ; tÞ�

þ 1� k1� b

fðp� cÞE½1v�ðQ;nÞ[PðQ;n;DðtÞÞ� � ðp� sÞE½1DðtÞ\Q�g

¼ kðp� cÞ � 1� bk1� b

ðp� sÞEt½GðQ; tÞ� þ 1� k1� b

ðp� cÞE½1v�ðQ;nÞ[ PðQ;n;DðtÞÞ�

¼ ðk� 1Þðp� cÞ þ 1� k1� b

ðp� cÞE½1v�ðQ;nÞ[ PðQ;n;DðtÞÞ� ¼ 0:

In all, for all cases (1), (2) and (3),oFðb;kÞðQ;n;v�ðQ;nÞÞ

oQ jQ¼Q� 0.

When n \ 0, similar analysis can be conducted by inter-changing the roles of Pl2

and Pu2 in the above proof, and when n = 0,

oFðb;kÞðQ; 0; v�ðQ; 0ÞÞoQ

jQ¼Q ¼oFðb;kÞðQ; vðQÞÞ

oQjQ¼Q ¼ 0:

By concavity of F(b, k)(Q, n, v), we have Q� � Q. This completes the proof.

Note the condition in this proposition, G(y;t) is strictly increasing in y for given t,

is to get a unique solution Q for the unhedged case. Generally without this

condition, assume Q and Q* are the largest solutions for the unhedged and hedged

cases respectively, we still have the result that Q� � Q: h

References

Acerbi C, Tasche D (2002a) On the coherence of expected shortfall. J Bank Finance 26:1487–1503

Acerbi C, Tasche D (2002b) Expected shortfall: a natural coherent alternative to value at risk. Econ Notes

31:379–388

Agrawal V, Seshadri S (2002) Impact of uncertainty and risk aversion on price and order quantity in the

newsvendor problem. Manufact Service Oper Manage 2:410–423

Ahmed S, Cakmak U, Shapiro A (2007) Coherent risk measures in inventory problems. Eur J Oper Res

182:226–238

Artzner P, Delbaen F, Eber JM, Heath D (1999) Coherent measures of risk. Math Finance 9:203–228

Baccardax M (2002) The temperature’s rising. http://www.cfoeurope.com/displaystory.cfm/1738060.

Accessed 5 May 2006

Baker B, Petrillo N (2004) Value of weather risk management contracts reaches all-time high.

http://www.wrma.org/wrma/library/file677.doc. Accessed 29 March 2010

Bouakiz M, Sobel MJ (1992) Inventory control with an expected utility criterion. Oper Res 40:603–608

Boyabatli O, Toktay LB (2004) Operational hedging: a review with discussion. Working paper, INSEAD,

France

Caldentey R, Haugh M (2006) Optimal control and hedging of operations in the presence of financial

markets. Math Oper Res 31:285–304

Cao M, Wei J (2004) Weather derivatives valuation and market price of weather risk. J Fut Markets

24:1065–1089

Chen F, Federgruen A (2000) Mean-variance analysis of basic inventory models. Working paper,

Graduate School of Business, Columbia University

Chen Y, Yano CA (2010) Improving supply chain performance and managing risk under weather-related

demand uncertainty. Manage Sci 56: 1380-1397

Joint optimal ordering and weather hedging decisions 23

123

Page 24: Joint optimal ordering and weather hedging decisions: mean-CVaR model

Chen Y, Xu M, Zhang G (2006) A risk-averse newsvendor model under the CVaR decision criterion.

Oper Res (forthcoming)

Chen X, Sim M, Simchi-Levi D, Sun P (2007) Risk aversion in inventory management. Oper Res 55:

828–842

Chod J, Rudi N, Van Mieghem JA (2006) Operational flexibility and financial hedging: complements or

substitutes? Working paper

Choi S, Ruszczynski A (2007) A risk-averse newsvendor with law invariant coherent measures of risk.

Oper Res Lett (forthcoming)

Ding Q, Dong L, Kouvelis P (2004) On the integration of production and financial hedging decisions in

global markets. Oper Res (forthcoming)

Dischel B (2001) Weather risk management at the frozen falls fuel company. http://www.cmegroup.

com/trading/weather/files/WEA_weather_risk.pdf. Accessed 29 March 2010

Dischel B, Barrieu P (2001) Weather hedging at the hot air gas comapny. Electronic Journal:

Erivativesreview.com

Eeckhoudt L, Gollier C (1995) Schlesinger H. Risk averse (and prudent) newsboy. Manage Sci

41:786–794

Gaur V, Seshadri S (2005) Hedging inventory risk through market instruments. Manufact Service Oper

Mange 7:103–120

Gotoh J, Takano Y (2007) The downside risk-averse newsvendor minimizing conditional value-at-risk.

Eur J Oper Res 179:80–96

Harrington S, Niehaus G (2003) United grain growers: enterprise risk management and weather risk. Risk

Manage Insurance Rev 6:193–208

Hull J (2003) Options, futures, and other derivatives, 5th edn. Prentice Hall, Singapore

Jewson S (2003) Closed-form expressions for the pricing of weather derivatives: part 1-the expected

payoff. Availabe at Social Science Research Network. http://ssrn.com/abstract=436262

Jewson S, Brix A (2005) Weather derivative valuation. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

Jewson S, Rodrigo C (2002) The use of weather forecasts in the pricing of weather derivatives. Availabe

at Social Science Research Network. http://ssrn.com/abstract=405780

Jorion P (2006) Value at risk: a new benchmark for managing financial risk. McGraw Hill, New York

Lau H (1980) The newboy problem under alternative optimization objectives. J Oper Res Soc 31:525–535

Li D, Ng WL (2000) Optimal dynamic portfolio selection: multi-period mean-variance formulation. Math

Finance 10:387–406

Malinow M (2002) End-users (chapter 5). In: Banks E (ed) Weather risk management. Palgrave, New

York

Markowitz H (1952) Portfolio selection. J Finance 7:77-91

Oum Y, Oren S, Deng S (2006). Hedging quantity risks with standard power options in a competitive

wholesale electricity market. Naval Res Logist 53:697–712

Rathke M (2005) Weather exposure of the beverage industry. The Meteo Consult Group, MC-Wetter

GmbH. http://www.knmi.nl/mureau/ECAM/Economy/Rathke.pdf. Accessed 29 March 2010

Rockafellar RT, Uryasev S (2000) Optimization of conditional value-at-risk. J Risk 2:21–42

Rockafellar RT, Uryasev S (2002) Conditional value-at-risk for general loss distributions. J Bank Finance

26:1443–1471

Seifert RW, Thonemann UW, Hausman WH (2004) Optimal procurement strategies for online spot

markets. Eur J Oper Res 152:781–799

Speedwell Weather Derivatives Ltd (2003) How a fleece jacket manufacturer uses a PUT to protect

against a mild winter. http://www.weatherderivs.com/ WDExamples.htm. Accessed 23 Oct 2007

Szego G (2002) Measure of risk. J Bank Finance 26:1253–1272

WRMA: Weather Risk Management Association (2006) Trading weather risk: 2005/06 survey (April

2005–March 2006). http://www.wrma.org/wrma/index.php?option=com_content&task=view&id=

74&Itemid=33. Accessed 12 Nov 2006

Author Biographies

Fei Gao received doctoral degree from the Chinese University of Hong Kong. Her doctoral research was

focused on interfaces between operations and finance/marketing.

24 F. Gao et al.

123

Page 25: Joint optimal ordering and weather hedging decisions: mean-CVaR model

Frank Y. Chen is an associate professor at the Department of Systems Engineering and Engineering

Management, the Chinese University of Hong Kong. His current research is focused on interfaces

between operations and marketing, and inventory models with risk considerations.

Xiuli Chao is a professor in the Department of Industrial and Operations Engineering at the University of

Michigan, Ann Arbor. His research interests include queueing, scheduling, financial engineering,

inventory control, and supply chain management. He received doctoral degree in Operations Research

from Columbia University.

Joint optimal ordering and weather hedging decisions 25

123