427
SHADOWS IN THE FOREST: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA by PETER DAUVERGNE B.A., Carleton University, 1987 M.A., Carleton University, 1991 A THESIS SUBMITTED IN PARTIAL FULFILMENT OF THE REQUIREMENTS FOR THE DEGREE OF DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY in THE FACULTY OF GRADUATE STUDIES (Department of Political Science) We accept this thesis as conforming to t required st ndar THE UNIVEROIT July 1995 © Peter Dauvergne, 1995

JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    1

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

SHADOWS IN THE FOREST:

JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA

by

PETER DAUVERGNE

B.A., Carleton University, 1987M.A., Carleton University, 1991

A THESIS SUBMITTED IN PARTIAL FULFILMENT OF

THE REQUIREMENTS FOR THE DEGREE OF

DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY

in

THE FACULTY OF GRADUATE STUDIES

(Department of Political Science)

We accept this thesis as conformingto t required st ndar

THE UNIVEROIT

July 1995

© Peter Dauvergne, 1995

Page 2: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

In presenting this thesis in partial fulfilment of the requirements for an advanced

degree at the University of British Columbia, I agree that the Library shall make itfreely available for reference and study. I further agree that permission for extensive

copying of this thesis for scholarly purposes may be granted by the head of mydepartment or by his or her representatives, It is understood that copying or

publication of this thesis for financial gain shall not be allowed without my writtenpermission.

(Signature)

______________________

Department of Political Science

The University of British ColumbiaVancouver, Canada

Date July 26, 1995

DE-6 (2/88)

Page 3: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

SHADOWS IN THE FOREST:

JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA

ABSTRACT

This dissertation creates two new theoretical tools to analyze

connections between politics and environmental change. The first

section develops the concept of Northern ‘shadow ecologies’ to

understand the environmental impact of a Northern state on Southern

resource management. A Northern shadow ecology is the aggregate

environmental impact of government aid and loans; corporate

investment and technology transfers; and trade, including

purchasing practices, consumption, export and consumer prices, and

import tariffs. After outlining Japan’s shadow ecology, the next

part constructs an analytical lens to uncover salient Southern

political causes of timber mismanagement. This spotlights modern

patron-client links between Southern officials and private

operators that debilitate state capacity to implement resource

policies.

Using these analytical tools, and building on extensive

primary sources and more than 100 in-depth interviews, the

remainder of the thesis examines the two most important factors

driving commercial timber mismanagement in Indonesia, Borneo

Malaysia, and the Philippines: pervasive patron-client ties between

Southeast Asian officials and timber operators; and the residual

and immediate environmental impact of Japan. In a continual

ii

Page 4: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

struggle to retain power in societies with fragmented social

control, Southeast Asian state leaders build potent patron-client

networks that syphon state funds, distort policies, and undermine

supervision of state implementors. In this setting, the state is

often unable to enforce timber management rules as implementors --

in exchange for gifts, money, or security - - ignore or assist

destructive and illegal loggers, smugglers, and tax evaders.

Japan’s shadow ecology has expedited timber mismanagement, and

left deep environmental scars that impede current efforts to

improve timber management. Post-1990 Japanese government and

corporate policy changes to integrate environmental concerns have

marginally improved forestry ODA, and contributed to token

corporate conservation projects. As well, there is now less

Japanese investment, technology, and credit linked to logging. But

massive timber purchases from unsustainable sources, wasteful

consumption, timber prices that ignore environmental and social

costs, import barriers that deplete Southern revenues, and the

residual impact of past Japanese practices continue to accelerate

destructive logging in Southeast Asia.

Sustainable tropical timber management will require

fundamental changes to Japan’s shadow ecology. It is also

imperative to confront Southern political forces driving

deforestation. While reforms will certainly face formidable --

perhaps insurmountable -- political and economic barriers, unless

the world community tackles these issues, the remaining primary

forests of Southeast Asia will soon perish.

iii

Page 5: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

TABLE OF CONTENTS

ABSTRACT iiTABLE OF CONTENTS ivLIST OF FIGURES viiiACKNOWLEDGEMENTS ix

Chapter OneNORTHERN SHADOW ECOLOGIES

INTRODUCTION 1RATIONALE FOR THE EMPIRICAL CASE STUDIES 4RESEARCH PARAMETERS 6POLITICAL ECOLOGY STUDIES OF SOUTH-NORTH RELATIONS 10NORTHERN SHADOW ECOLOGIES 11ODA, GOVERNMENT LOANS, TECHNOLOGY AND THE ENVIRONMENT 15MUlTINATIONAL CORPORATIONS AND THE ENVIRONMENT 18TRADE AND THE ENVIRONMENT 19

A. Consumption 21B. Price 22C. Southern Export Restrictions 25D. Northern Tariffs and Import Restrictions 26

CONCLUSION 28

Chapter TwoJAPAN’S SHADOW ECOLOGY

INTRODUCTION 30ENVIRONMENTAL IMPACT OF JAPANESE ODA AND GOVERNMENT

LOANS 32ENVIRONMENTAL AID 40BATTLES OVER ENVIRONMENTAL AID 42THE OECF, THE EXIM BANK, JICA, AND THE ENVIRONMENT 46ENVIRONMENTAL IMPACT OF JAPANESE CORPORATIONS 52GREENING CORPORATE JAPAN 56CONCLUSION 62

Chapter ThreeA MODEL OF RESOURCE MANAGEMENT IN CLIENTELIST STATES

INTRODUCTION 65PATRON-CLIENT MODEL OF ASSOCIATION 66ADVANTAGES OF PATRON-CLIENT ANALYSIS 69MODERN PATRON-CLIENT RELATIONS IN SOUTHEAST ASIA 75NEO-PATRIMONIAL STUDIES 79STRONG SOCIETIES AND WEAK STATES 82CLIENTELIST STATES AND POLICY 89PATRON-CLIENT RELATIONS AND SYSTEMIC ‘CORRUPTION’ 92LEADERS AND LOW STATE CAPACITY 93PATRON-CLIENT TIES AND STATE IMPLEMENTORS 95CONCLUSION 97

iv

Page 6: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

Chapter FourJAPAN, PATRON-CLIENT POLITICS,

AND THE MISMANAGEMENT OF INDONESIAN TIMBER

INTRODUCTION 100TRADITIONAL AND MODERN PATRON-CLIENT RELATIONS IN

INDONESIA 103PATRON-CLIENT TIES AND THE INDONESIAN STATE 107CHINESE BUSINESS CLIENTS 115MILITARY 117BUREAUCRACY 120JAPAN AND PATRON-CLIENT RELATIONS 122SOCIETAL STRUCTURE AND POLICY IMPLEMENTATION 123PATRON-CLIENT POLITICS AND TIMBER MANAGEMENT IN

INDONESIA 125Background 125POLITICIANS, PATRONAGE, AND CHINESE TIMBER CLIENTS . . . 128MILITARY LEADERS AND TIMBER 131FORESTRY POLICIES AND PATRON-CLIENT POLITICS 133

A. Logging Rules and Concession Distribution . . . 133B. Licence Fees, Royalty Policies, and Timber

Taxes 140C. Foreign Investment Policies 143D. Processing Policies 145E. Conservation, Reforestation, and Timber

Plantations 151F. Plantations and the Pulp and Paper Industry . . 153

STATE ATTEMPTS TO IMPROVE TIMBER MANAGEMENT 156JAPANESE INVESTMENT AND TECHNOLOGY TRANSFERS 160JAPANESE ODA AND TIMBER MANAGEMENT 169TRADE: APKINDO, NIPPINDO, AND THE BATTLE FOR JAPAN’S

PLYWOOD MARKET 171JAPANESE TARIFF BARRIERS 177CONCLUSION 178

Chapter FiveJAPAN, CLIENTELISM AND DEFORESTATION IN BORNEO MALAYSIA

INTRODUCTION 185PATRON-CLIENT RELATIONS IN BORNEO MALAYSIA 187PATRON-CLIENT POLITICS AND TIMBER IN BORNEO MALAYSIA . . 195Background 195STATE PATRONAGE AND TIMBER IN SABAH 201POLITICAL LEADERS, PATRONAGE, AND TIMBER IN SARAWAK . 206PUBLIC OPPOSITION AND PATRON-CLIENT POLITICS IN BORNEO

MALAYSIA 212ROLE OF FORMAL INSTITUTIONS, REGULATIONS, AND POLICIES . 215

A. Background 215B. Logging Guidelines in Borneo Malaysia 217C. Tax and Royalty Policies 220D. Political Concessionaires, Chinese Clients, and

Sub-contracting 223

V

Page 7: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

E. Log Export Restrictions and ProcessingPolicies 227

F. Conservation, Reforestation, TimberPlantations 233

G. Recent Attempts To Improve Timber Management . 235JAPANESE ODA IN BORNEO MALAYSIA 242JAPANESE CORPORATE INVESTMENT IN BORNEO MALAYSIA’ S

TIMBER INDUSTRY 245JAPANESE COMPANIES AND CONSERVATION IN BORNEO MALAYSIA . 249JAPANESE TIMBER PURCHASES FROM BORNEO MALAYSIA 252JAPAN, TARIFF BARRIERS, LOG PRICES, AND SUSTAINABLE

MANAGEMENT 256CONCLUSION 257

Chapter SixJAPAN, PATRON-CLIENT POLITICS,

AND THE COLLAPSE OF THE PHILIPPINE TIMBER INDUSTRY

INTRODUCTIONTRADITIONAL AND MODERN PATRON-CLIENT RELATIONSPATRON-CLIENT RELATIONS (1898-1972)MARCOS AS SUPREME PATRON (1972-19 86)PATRON-CLIENTELISM AND THE FALL OF MARCOSPATRON-CLIENT NETWORKS AND PATRONAGE SINCE 1986PATRONS AND TIMBERFORESTRY POLICIES AND PATRON-CLIENT POLITICS

A. BackgroundB. Timber Concessionaires and Legal LoggingC. Illegal LoggingD. SmugglingE. Tax and Royalty EvasionF. Log Export Restrictions, Logging Bans,

Processing PoliciesG. Local Power and Forest Management .

H. Conservation, Reforestation, and TimberPlantations

THE PHILIPPINES AND JAPAN’S SHADOW ECOLOGYA. Japanese Investment and TechnologyB. Japanese TradeC. Japanese Forestry and ‘Environmental Aid’

CONCLUSION: A LOOK TO THE YEAR 2000

ConclusionJAPAN’S ECOLOGICAL SHADOW OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA

INTRODUCTIONJAPANESE TECHNICAL ASSISTANCE, GRANTS, LOANS AND

TROPICAL FORESTSJAPANESE ENVIRONMENTAL AID AND TROPICAL FORESTS . .

JAPANESE CORPORATE INVESTMENT AND TECHNOLOGY TRANSFERSJAPAN’S TIMBER TRADE IN SOUTHEAST ASIA

A. Japanese Corporate Purchasing Practices . .

and

• . . 263• . • . 267• . . . 271• . . . 273

278• . . . 279

284290

• . . 290• . • 293

298305307

and309311

312315316319322327

333

335341342344344

vi

Page 8: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

B. Export and Consumer Prices, Consumption, and LowState Revenue 350C. Indonesian Plywood Exports and Japanese Import

Barriers 351JAPANESE ENVIRONMENTAL GUIDELINES AND THE TIMBER TRADE . 353JAPAN AND SOUTHEAST ASIAN TIMBER MANAGEMENT:

RECOMMENDATIONS 358A. Reform Japanese Aid 358B. Trade: Corporate Purchasing Practices 360C. Trade: Import Restrictions 362D. Trade: Purchases, Import Volumes, Prices, and

Consumption 364LESSONS FOR NORTH-SOUTH INTERACTION AND ENVIRONMENTAL

MANAGEMENT 367

ACRONYMS ND INDIGENOUS TERMS 371

BIBLIOGRAPHY 374

NEWSPAPERS ND MAGAZINES CONSULTED 411

INTERVIEWS 413

A. INDONESIA 413B. JAPAN 414C. PENINSULAR MALAYSIA 415D. PHILIPPINES 415E. SABAH, MALAYS IA . 416F. SARAWAK, MALAYSIA 422

vii

Page 9: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

LIST OF FIGURES

Figure 1. Japanese Log Imports From SE Asia 349

viii

Page 10: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS

This dissertation was supported by generous funds from anAlcan Fellowship in Japanese Studies (1991-92) and an Eco-ResearchDoctoral Fellowship (1992-95), a cross-disciplinary award from theSocial Sciences and Humanities Research Council of Canada, theNatural Sciences and Engineering Research Council of Canada, andthe Medical Research Council of Canada. A 1994 Canada-ASEAN CentreTravel Grant supplied crucial financial assistance for research inSoutheast Asia, and the Institute of Social Science, University ofTokyo, provided subsidized housing and institutional support forresearch in Tokyo.

I am deeply indebted to my dissertation supervisor, ProfessorIvan L. Head. Considering the interdisciplinary range of myresearch, I was exceedingly fortunate to find any advisor -- letalone one with his breadth of knowledge. His careful edits andthoughtful suggestions were invaluable. Using kindness and tact,he somehow managed to push me to revise and revise and revise. . .yetremarkably I never felt despondent. I am also indebted toProfessor Diane K. Mauzy for her kind and skilled guidance throughthe diverse Southeast Asian political systems and dense literatureon patron-client theory. She has been - - in only the best sense ofthe word -- my patron, defending my interests and promoting mycareer. In return, she received only the thankless task ofploughing through lengthy chapters. I am also grateful toProfessor Brian Job for his generous support and expert advice. Aswell, I want to thank my external examiners, Professor John R.Wood, Professor han Vert±nsky, and Dr. Arthur Hanson for theirvaluable input. Finally, I am indebted to numerous peoplethroughout Southeast Asia and Japan whose ideas and data are thebackbone of this thesis.

This project would have been impossible without theintellectual and emotional support of my entire family. My wife,Cayte, was indefatigably patient and loving, even on the days Iwanted to quit, the days I was too distracted to listen, the daysI was too tired to drag myself out of bed and soothe our cryingson. Through all this she was my toughest editor and my bestfriend. My son Duncan -- although he denies responsibility for anyerrors -- had perhaps the greatest influence on my work. Before hecould even walk, he volunteered to be my research assistant inTokyo. After he learned to walk, his help became indispensable ashe strategically shuffled and hid key documents, and studiouslyshredded any irrelevant or misleading information. He was,however, far more than an able researcher -- every day hedemonstrated that life is much more than one myopic dissertation.Without this perspective, I would still be at my computer,mesmerized by the vision that I would write a great work, insteadof mired in the humbling world of diapers and messy drafts.

ix

Page 11: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

Chapter One

NORTHERN SHADOW ECOLOGIES

Annual tropical deforestation is around 17 million hectares.’

Despite incremental improvements, illegal and legal logging remain

a key cause of deforestation in Southeast Asia. Asian governments

target the year 2000 for sustainable management of tropical timber.

There is almost no hope of reaching this goal. Primary rain

forests continue to be cut and sustainable yields remain as elusive

as ever.2 There are both direct agents and indirect forces

contributing to rapid, careless, short-sighted extraction. While

Southern state managers and timber operators play direct roles,

Northern money, consumption, technology, and trade practices are

crucial factors supporting and driving mismanagement. These

indirect Northern forces cast an oppressive shadow that constrains

Southern decisions, provides incentives for quick profits, and

accelerates the process of deforestation.

This dissertation concentrates on the most important Northern

force behind logging mismanagement in Southeast Asia -- Japan --

and the central Southern factor -- politics and policy

implementation. I argue that current and past Japanese government

‘Food and Agriculture Organization (FAO) data in NationalScience Teachers Association, World Resources 1992-93. A Guide tothe Global Environment (Washington: National Science TeachersAssociation, 1992), p.118. Deforestation is defined as thecomplete loss of the original forest eco-system.

2Little has apparently changed since the International TropicalTimber Organization estimated in 1989 that less than one percent oftropical timber is managed at sustainable yields.

1

Page 12: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

policies, corporate practices, and trade combine to act as a

catalyst driving commercial timber mismanagement in Indonesia, the

Borneo Malaysian states of Sabah and Sarawak, and the Philippines.3

These policies and practices limit state decisions, provide

incentives for destructive extraction, and support unsustainable

timber export rates. In recent years, the Japanese government and

major corporations claim that significant moves have been made to

integrate overseas environmental concerns. I examine the new

Environment Law, and policy changes at key ministries, the aid and

loan agencies, and general trading companies. I show that these

policies -- while providing marginal contributions to conservation

and reforestation -- have conspicuous flaws: wording is vague,

there are few enforcement mechanisms, and sanctions are unclear.

Seen in light of the consequences of Japan’s historical practices,

and of contemporary problems, these efforts are essentially

cosmetic. More disturbingly, they create a smokescreen that

obscures the more important consequences of wasteful Japanese

consumption, export and consumer prices that ignore environmental

costs, import tariffs that syphon Southern revenues, log purchases

from unsustainable sources, and the residual environmental effects

of past practices.

Japan’s impact on Southeast Asian timber management can easily

be exaggerated or oversimplified and must be understood in the

context of Southeast Asian politics. To uncover the salient

3For simplicity, the term Southeast Asia refers primarily tomy case studies. Notably, I do not examine Thailand since Japan hashad a smaller role in driving extensive deforestation in Thailand.

2

Page 13: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

domestic causes of timber mismanagement, I develop an analytical

lens that focuses on the links between patron-client relations and

policy implementation. I argue that Southeast Asian leaders -- in

a constant struggle to retain power in societies with fragmented

social control -- build powerful patron-client networks and allow

material-based patron-client ties to flourish at all levels of the

state and society. These pervasive clientelist ties -- often

sustained by timber profits -- distort policies, deplete state

revenues, obscure responsibility, channel profits to an

unaccountable elite, and undermine supervision of state

implementors. In this context, the state is too weak to respond to

the environmental crisis in forestry, and to control destructive

timber operators, illegal loggers, smugglers, and tax evaders.

Understanding Japan’s impact on timber management in this

setting leads to some important conclusions. Higher international

prices for tropical timber, greater Southern timber revenues,

revised Overseas Development Assistance (ODA), compensation for

past practices, and increased environmental investment, while in

theory essential for sustainable logging, will not automatically

improve timber management. Increased Southern revenue may simply

add to the wealth of a small elite, or to investments outside of

the forestry sector, and do little to improve management. In the

context of Southeast Asian politics, higher prices could even

increase incentives to mine the forests and make quick money.

Sustainable management will require the world community to confront

Southern political forces that disable state policy implementation,

3

Page 14: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

undercut state revenue, and drive mismanagement. Unfortunately,

there are few optimistic signs. Japanese corporations continue to

thrive in the political setting of Southeast Asia, importing vast

tracts of remarkably cheap timber from unsustainable sources. With

powerful business, military, bureaucratic, and political patron-

client networks fuelled by timber, states unable or unwilling to

halt the ensuing destruction, and Japan accelerating the process,

it is hardly surprising to find rampant deforestation.

RATIONALE FOR THE CASE STUDIES

Comparing the impact of Japan on tropical timber management in

Indonesia, Borneo Malaysia, and the Philippines is logical for

several reasons. From the 1950s to the beginning of the 1990s,

these three areas supplied around 90 percent of Japan’s tropical

log imports from Southeast Asia. They have also been the major

hardwood exporters of Southeast Asia, accounting for over half of

world exports; meanwhile, since the 1960s, Japan has consistently

remained the world’s largest importer of tropical timber, today

consuming nearly one-third of the world total.4 As a result,

Japanese government and corporate practices have had significant

environmental and economic consequences for Southeast Asian timber

management.

Focusing on areas with similar cultural backgrounds and

4japan consumes more than Belgium, Denmark, France, WestGermany, Greece, Ireland, Italy, Luxembourg, Netherlands, Portugal,Spain, and the United Kingdom put together. Kenton Miller andLaura Tangley, Trees of Life: Saving Tropical Forests and TheirBiological Wealth (Boston: Beacon Press, 1991), p.30.

4

Page 15: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

similar historical, political, and economic ties to Japan reduces

the number of divergent variables surrounding my analysis,

therefore making it easier to generalize and evaluate whether

Japanese practices are changing. There have been marginal

improvements to Japanese forestry aid and some token corporate

conservation projects. As well, there are now fewer tropical

logging investments and technology transfers. But Japan’s basic

pattern is consistent: to facilitate rapid, destructive cutting

techniques; support unsustainable timber production; maximize high-

quality log imports at the lowest possible price; protect Japanese

plywood processors that feed on cheap tropical logs; and syphon

Southern revenues essential for sustainable management. As

commercial forests inevitably disappear, or when Southern

governments sever supply lines, Japanese trading companies have

simply moved to new sources. This pattern has been remarkably

consistent. At present, as imports from Borneo Malaysia drop,

Japanese companies are moving to Papua New Guinea and the Solomon

Islands. Japanese companies are also preparing for the worldwide

collapse of tropical timber supplies, developing techniques to

substitute softwood from places like Russia, New Zealand, China,

Canada, and the United States.

These cases also reveal notable differences in the

environmental and economic impact of Japan depending on the

reactions of Southeast Asian governments. In the Philippines,

taking advantage of greedy elites and inadequate state supervision,

Japanese companies purchased massive volumes of logs to supply

5

Page 16: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

domestic plywood processors. By the time the Philippine government

banned log exports in 1986, the commercial timber industry had

collapsed. In sharp contrast, as multinational companies financed

and accelerated destructive logging in Indonesia, the Indonesian

government gradually banned log exports in the first half of the

1980s, severed most foreign timber investments, and provided strong

incentives to process logs locally. As a result, Indonesia became

the world’s dominant tropical plywood producer. Japan now imports

a significant quantity of Indonesian plywood, forcing many Japanese

plywood processors out of business. In Sabah and Sarawak, Japanese

traders again funded and supported log export operations similar to

those that devastated the Philippines. In 1993, after the near

exhaustion of valuable commercial timber, the Sabah government

banned log exports, attempting to establish a processing industry

similar to Indonesia’s. Sarawak is now the main source for

Japanese tropical logs. Sarawak has also imposed some restrictions

on log exports, but unlike Indonesia, the Philippines, or Sabah,

government leaders perceive Japanese log purchases as beneficial

and there are no plans to ban exports.

RESEARCH PARAMETERS

The boggling array of factors that influence Southeast Asian

timber management and the potential for endless diversions has

forced me to focus my research. I concentrate on commercial

logging in primary and secondary forests, and to a lesser extent on

6

Page 17: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

the management of plantations.5 Reaching sustainable timber

production, reducing destructive logging, and protecting primary

forests are my main environmental concerns;6 my primary economic

concern is maximizing the amount of money invested in sustainable

Southern timber management. Without denying their importance for

sustainable tropical forestry, only passing references are made to

land use rights, indigenous rights, swidden farming, and social and

community forestry. Addressing these issues would make my project

too unwieldy and divert attention from my central concern, the

impact of Japan and Southern politics on commercial timber

management.

I also do not address Japanese contributions to multilateral

institutions. Although these are undoubtedly important -- Japan is

the biggest contributor to the Asian Development Bank (ADB), the

5Logging in Southeast Asia is a critical agent behinddeforestation. Logging of primary forests -- which createssecondary forests -- routinely causes degradation. (Degradation isdefined as a partial change to a forest eco-system that reduces itseconomic, biological, or environmental value.) In some cases,loggers clear-cut forests, although this is generally limited toareas designated for agriculture or large-scale developmentprojects (e.g. hydroelectric dams). Logging is usually the firststep in a process that leads to deforestation: by establishingroads that provide access to slash-and-burn farmers; by leavingdebris and creating open spaces that make secondary forestssusceptible to fires; and by decreasing the economic value of theforest, providing incentives to convert logged areas to other landuses.

6Sustainable timber production is defined as doing nothing thatwill “irreversibly reduce the potential of the forest to producemarketable timber.” Duncan Poore, “The Sustainable Management ofTropical Forest: the Issues,” in Duncan Poore, ed., No TimberWithout Trees: Sustainability in the Tropical Forest. A Study forITTO. (London: Earthscan Publications Ltd., 1989), p.5. Pooreexplains this concept in detail.

7

Page 18: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

second largest to the International Monetary Fund and the World

Bank, and strongly backs organizations like the International

Tropical Timber Organization (ITTO) -- it is exceedingly difficult

to determine the extent to which Japanese money shapes the policies

and practices of these organizations.7 Reluctantly, to avoid

diluting an understanding of Japan’s bilateral impact on timber

management, I also do not delve into the role of related pressures

created by Southern debt, though this hovers in the background.

While foreign debts undeniably create incentives to export

resources to meet payments,8 it is quite difficult to isolate and

analyze Japan’s contribution to these debts. It is equally

difficult to determine the role this then has on the management of

one resource. Also lingering in the background, but not directly

analyzed, is the importance of population growth, poverty, non-

forestry policies, low status of environmental concerns in the

bureaucratic hierarchy, as well as the impact of other

industrialized countries, international financial organizations,

and world pressure to ‘develop’. These factors are certainly

important. But directly tackling them would push my work toward

7The ADB is sometimes portrayed as being under Japan’s thumb.Yet it is simplistic to equate Bank policies with Japaneseinterests. According to a Bank official, Japan does not shapepolicy; rather, the Japanese government has ‘piggy-backed’intellectually on the policies of the Bank. Interview, Senior ADBofficial, Manila, 31 January and 4 February 1994. Similar commentswere made about Japan’s influence over the ITTO. Interview, ITTOofficial, Tokyo, 6 April 1994.

8See for example, Patricia Adams, Odious Debts: loose lending,corruption, and the Third World’s environmental legacy (Toronto:Earthscan Canada, 1991); and Susan George, The Debt Boomerang: HowThird World Debt Harms Us All (London: Pluto Press, 1992).

S-

Page 19: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

ground already well covered by other writers and deflect me from

the largely unexplored terrain of the environmental impact of

bilateral South-North relations on the commercial management of one

Southern resource.

Other authors point to the power of the North to shape

resource management in the South; yet, most resort to general,

sometimes glib, connections. A precise assessment is difficult,

demanding extensive background on Southern political settings and

Northern policies. Chapter Two describes recent changes to

Japanese corporate and government policies that shape Southern

resource management. Chapter Three builds a comparative framework

-- the patron-client model modified to give more focus on the state

and policy implementation -- to analyze the connections between

domestic politics and resource management in Southeast Asia.

Chapters Four to Six outline the politics of timber management in

Indonesia, Borneo Malaysia, and the Philippines with particular

attention to Japan. The Philippine chapter begins the ascent to

the conclusion and sketches the key Southern political factors

driving timber mismanagement in Southeast Asia. Building on these

empirical studies, and in the context of recent Japanese policies,

the conclusion assesses the impact of Japan on Southeast Asian

timber management and explores possible reforms to reshape the

environmental impact of Japanese aid, investment, and trade. To

maintain focus throughout this project, I concentrate mainly on

political factors, contributing to the emerging sub-field of

9

Page 20: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

political ecology.9

POLITICAL ECOLOGY STUDIES OF SOUTH-WORTH RELATIONS

Academics concerned with natural resource management

increasingly see political forces as critical factors driving

environmental degradation. Political ecology studies broadly

examine connections between politics and environmental change.

These studies are diverse, addressing a range of issues, dealing

with local, national, and international politics, and reaching a

variety of conclusions. Specific political features examined

include: local -- often indigenous -- conflict over access to land

and water; Southern policies, practices, and elite corruption;

Northern ODA, multinational corporations (MNC5) and trade;

interstate war; Southern debt and pressures by multilateral

financial and technical organizations; capitalism and its

accompanying world system; and complex combinations of these

variables 10

A neglected area of political ecology studies is the peaceful

9This helps fill a gap in the literature on forestrymanagement. Until recently, scholars have focused on technical oreconomic factors behind logging mismanagement with relativelylittle attention to political fdrces. Furthermore, internationalforums and publications have avoided sensitive discussions ofpolitical connections.

‘°Raymond L. Bryant, Political Ecology: An emerging researchagenda in Third-World studies,” Political Geography 11 (January1992), pp.12-36 reviews this literature. For a specific example ofa political ecology framework, see Nancy Lee Peluso, “The PoliticalEcology of Extraction and Extractive Reserves in East Kalimantan,Indonesia,” Development and Change 23, no. 4 (October, 1992),pp.49-74.

10

Page 21: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

interaction between states.” One reason is the difficulty of

isolating and clarifying important Northern factors that shape

resource management in the South. There is a danger of

exaggerating or oversimplifying the impact of the North as

variables are removed from the context of the world capitalist

system and Southern political settings. There is also a risk of

including too many aspects, diluting or diverting attention from

more important factors. To spotlight the most important elements

of bilateral Northern influence on Southern resource management, I

develop the concept of Northern shadow ecologies.

NORTHERN SHADOW ECOLOGIES

The genesis of the term ‘shadow ecology’ comes from the

argument that economically powerful industrialized countries

draw upon the ecological capital of all othernations to provide food for their populations,energy and materials for their economies, andeven land, air, and water to assimilate theirwaste by-products. This ecological capital,which may be found thousands of miles from theregions in which it is used, forms the ‘shadowecology’ of an economy. ... In essence, theecological shadow of a country is theenvironmental resources it draws from othercountries and the global commons.’2

“See Ibid., p.16.

12Jim MacNeill, Peiter Winsemius, and Taizo Yakushiji, BeyondInterdependence: The Meshing of the World’s Economy and the Earth’sEcology (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1991), pp.58-59. Theauthors argue that “oceans, the atmosphere (climate), and other‘commons’ also form part of this shadow ecology.” Ibid., p.58.However, because of the complexity of this topic, and since myempirical data relates to forestry, I will not examine aspectsconnected to the global commons but will limit my discussion tofactors that directly relate to interstate relations.

11

Page 22: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

As the authors note, a country like Japan, which has a limited

resource base, has developed an extensive shadow ecology to support

rapid industrial growth. Unfortunately, this idea is not examined

in detail. The goal in the following section is simple: to

delineate clear definitional boundaries to boost the heuristic

power of the term shadow ecology.

Environmental resources include water, trees, minerals, soil,

and air. Yet shadow ecologies are more than the number of trees

and minerals consumed, the amount of soil removed, and the extent

of water and air polluted. To fully understand the importance of

a Northern shadow ecology, it is imperative to go beyond merely

counting the amount consumed or destroyed and examine the price

paid and the impact on resource management. Given time, money and

knowledge, many environmental resources -- certainly conimercial

timber -- can be managed as a sustainable economic asset.

Accepting this assumption, a Northern country that consumes

enormous quantities without paying and without restoring degraded

areas draws far more environmental resources than another country

consuming the same amount, yet paying high prices for resources

from sustainable sources, and providing technical and financial

support. to facilitate better management. For this reason, the term

shadow ecology embraces the amount consumed, the price paid, the

source of the resource, and the effect of ODA, government loans,

corporate investment, technology transfers, and trade policies on

resource management. In other words, a Northern shadow ecology is

the aggregate environmental impact on the management of a Southern

12

Page 23: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

resource of three sets of factors: government assistance, including

ODA and loans; corporate investment and technology transfers; and

trade, including corporate purchasing practices, export and

consumer prices, amount and ‘type’ of consumption, and import

barriers. Japan’s ‘ecological shadow of timber’ in Southeast Asia

is the aggregate environmental impact of these factors on tropical

timber management.

Some caveats and boundaries further refine this definition.

First, actions of Southern governments, or international financial

pressures can aggravate or alleviate shadow ecologies. To create

a balanced perspective, it is imperative to view a shadow ecology

in the context of Southern politics, and keep in mind the role of

the world capitalist system in shaping attitudes and practices.

Second, an ecological shadow is a result of both intended and

unintended consequences of Northern government, corporate and bank

actions. It is not a result of a guided or conscious plan. This

is especially relevant for Japan where the decision making process

is fragmented - what Karl van Wolferen calls a “truncated

pyramid.”13 It is, however, still possible to control the

consequences. Public and private policies in both developed and

developing countries can significantly alter the impact of a

Northern shadow ecology on resource management in the South.

Third, the term shadow ecology implies a two way dependence.

A country like Japan relies on Southern raw materials, while the

‘3See Karel van Wolferen, The Enigma of Japanese Power: Peopleand Politics in a Stateless Nation (New York: Macmillan LondonLimited, 1989)

13

Page 24: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

South relies on Northern markets, technology, aid and investment.

This moves “beyond interdependence” in its limited economic sense,

and suggests a “meshing of the world’s economy and the earth’s

ecology.”4 The relationship, however, is asymmetrical since

environmental change more immediately affects the South. Economic

and ecological interdependence suggests an inevitable impact of

economic activity in the North on the environment of the South and,

furthermore, an inevitable impact of environmental change in the

South on the economies of the North.’5 Accepting this assumption,

it makes sense to conceive of shadow ecologies on a continuum where

sustainable activity falls on one end and environmental destruction

falls on the other end. The logical task for policy makers, then,

is not to eliminate shadow ecologies but to minimize and counteract

any negative consequences. Ideally, sustainable activity would

involve South-North interaction that encourages mutual and

equitable development, while environmental change is sustainable.

Fourth, shadow ecologies change intensity and composition.

The relative importance of various components depends on the states

involved, environmental attitudes and values, the resource sector,

and the historical period. For example, the relative importance of

factors (such as ODA/loans, consumption, corporate investment, or

trade practices) and the cumulative impact of Japan’s shadow

‘4Maurice Strong, Introduction to MacNeill, Winsemius, andYakushiji, Beyond Interdependence, p.v.

‘5See Ivan L. Head, On A Hinge Of History: The MutualVulnerability of South and North (Toronto: University of TorontoPress, 1991)

14

Page 25: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

ecology in the Philippines in 1975 is different from Indonesia in

1993. Finally, economic growth entails environmental costs.

Historically, shadow ecologies have transferred environmental costs

to the South of economic growth in the North. Yet, it is important

not to oversimplify and exaggerate. Northern ODA, investment,

technology, and trade are certainly important factors shaping

environmental management in the South. But these are only part of

the explanation, their importance varies depending on the context,

and they can simultaneously have both negative and positive

implications for management. Although South-North interaction has

had many destructive consequences in the past, a complete break

would not assure sustainable practices. Northern money,

information, technology and training -- modified to fit Southern

knowledge, experience, and conditions -- is the only practical

route to sustainable management.’6 For background and further

clarity, the next section examines some of the theoretical debates

regarding the environmental impact of ODA, Northern technology,

corporate investment, and trade on Southern resource management.

ODA, GOVERNMENT LOANS, TECHNOLOGY AND TIlE ENVIRONMENT

The environmental impact of ODA (grants, technical assistance,

and concessional loans) and government loans not qualifying as ODA,

‘6This is generally accepted by the South. Northern assistance-- especially technology transfers on noncommercial terms -- hasbeen a priority for developing countries during internationalenvironmental negotiations. Gareth Porter and Janet Welsh Brown,Global Environmental Politics (Boulder: Westview Press, 1991),p.129.

15

Page 26: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

have been extensively examined in recent years.’7 The media,

nongovernmental organizations (NGOs), and environmentalists have

scrutinized mega-development projects financed by multilateral and

bilateral aid which create sensational environmental change.

Popular interest in such schemes is further aroused by stories of

corruption, connections to Northern corporations, and destruction

of aboriginal cultures. Academic work has also looked closely at

the links between environmental destruction and poorly conceived

aid and loan priorities and projects, badly designed and managed

Northern aid agencies, and strategic use of aid and loans to

promote Northern business.18 Some scholars, however, are wary

about the connections made between ODA and environmental change.

According to William Adams, while clearly a factor, “it remains an

open question. . . as to how much influence aid agencies actually have

on the nature and course of development projects. The power of aid

donors is often exaggerated, and of course varies a great deal.”9

Moreover, it is important not to discount ongoing changes to aid

policies as environmental awareness grows, and aid is ‘greened’ 20

‘7Much of this research was sparked by the World Commission onEnvironment and Development, Our Common Future (Oxford: OxfordUniversity Press, 1987)

18For example, Teresa Hayter, Exploited Earth: Britain’s Aidand the Environment (London: Earthscan Publications, 1989).

‘9Wjlliam M. Adams, Green Development: Environment andSustainability in the Third World (London: Routledge, 1990), p.166,quoted in Bryant, p.16.

20Bryant, “Political Ecology,” p.16. See Czech Conroy andMiles Litvinoff, eds., The Greening of Aid: Sustainable Livelihoodsin Practice (London: Earthscan, 1988). Conroy and Litvinoffprovide thirty-four cases of aid projects with positive

16

Page 27: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

Assessing the environmental impact of ODA and nonconcessional

lending is clearly difficult, and its importance debatable. There

is a tendency -- especially in government publications -- to assume

all reforestation or environmental technologies are beneficial.

There is an equally dubious tendency among NGOs and

environmentalists to label all Northern aid as a capitalist ploy to

exploit the natural resources of the South. Since Northern money

has the potential for both negative impacts -- as when funding ill-

conceived dams, roads, and equipment purchases -- and positive

impacts -- as when funding conservation and environmental education

-- it is necessary to weigh each situation carefully, avoid

simplistic condemnations, and consider its importance relative to

the overall environmental problems.

Technological transfers -- by Northern governments through ODA

or loans, or by MNCs as part of investment -- can potentially

alleviate environmental problems by, for example, replacing

inefficient processing facilities and reducing pressure on a

resource.21 But technology can also create havoc by accelerating

extraction and production before effective plans and policies are

environmental consequences.

21Numerous influential studies argue that the diffusion ofenvironmentally sound technology is critical for Southernsustainable development. For example, see World Commission onEnvironment and Development, Our Common Future, p.87; and LindaStarke, Signs of Hope: Working Towards Our Common Future (Oxford:Oxford University Press, 1990), p.165.

17

Page 28: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

in place.22 Martin Khor Kok Peng, director of the Third World

Network, argues that “the importation of inappropriate Northern

technologies has progressively destroyed the more ecological

indigenous production systems in the south, besides simply

destroying natural resources.”23 As with aid and loans, technology

is a double-edged sword and the environmental consequences Iust be

weighed carefully.

MULTINATIONAL CORPORATIONS AND THE ENVIRONMENT

According to Nazli ChOucri, all theories of multinational

corporations, including international relations studies in

political science, “ignore the impacts of corporate activities on

the natural environment and on ecological balances.” These

theories seem to assume “private investments and actions crossing

borders are neutral relative to environmental, ecological, or

atmospheric impacts.” Of course, many less ‘theoretical’ studies

22For a general discussion of the relationship betweentechnology and the environment, see Amitav Rath and Brent HerbertCopley, Green Technologies for Development: Transfer, Trade andCooperation (Ottawa: International Development Research Centre[IDRCI , 1993)

23Martin Khor Kok Peng, “North-south relations revisited inlight of UNCED,” Briefing Paper for UNCED, no. 8, 1991, p.6. Fora critique of the environmental impact of Northern technologytransfers, see Ecologist, “Mainstream Solutions,” Ecologist 22, no.4 (July/August 1992), pp.187-192.

24Nazl± Choucri, “Multinational Corporations and the GlobalEnvironment,” in Global Accord: Environmental Challenges andInternational Responses (Cambridge: MIT Press, 1993), p.220.

18

Page 29: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

have examined the links between MLTCs and environmental change.25

Yet this gap in the MNC literature is indicative of a superficial

understanding of the connections between environmental change and

corporate investment and practices.

MC investors often create incentives and the means for rapid

exploitation of Southern resources. These firms also invest little

in environmental projects such as reforestation, which have low

profit margins, long-term returns, and high risks. As well,

multinational companies purchase enormous quantities of remarkably

cheap natural resources from unsustainable sources. Driven by

these investment and purchasing practices, Southern partners ignore

long-term management principles and quickly deplete resource

stocks. In the 1980s, MNCs became more conscious of environmental

issues. There is, however, little evidence of concrete changes to

multinational behaviour in the South.26

TRADE AND THE ENVIRONMENT

World trade swamps the financial flows of debt and aid.

Annual world trade in goods is US$3.5 trillion; including

commercial services it reaches US$4.3 trillion. In comparison,

total annual ODA is only US$55 billion, while Southern debt service

25For example, see the articles in Charles S. Pearson, ed.,Multinational Corporations, Environment, and the Third World:Business Matters (Durham: Duke University Press, 1987).

26Roger D. Stone and Eve Hamilton, Global Economics and theEnvironment (New York: Council on Foreign Relations Press, 1991),pp.42-43.

19

Page 30: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

stands at US$130 billion.27 After an initial spurt in the 1970s,

then a lull in the 1980s, there has been an explosion of writing in

the 1990s on the links between trade and environmental

management.28 Hal Kane argues that trade is essentially “taking

products made by using the environment, or taking the environment

itself, and sending it off to other countries.”29 Understood in

this way, trade inevitably creates environmental change. Yet

change itself is not a problem; even sustainable development

requires change. What is crucial is the impact of trade on

resource management -- whether it contributes to sustainability or

irreparable change. This discussion must be approached cautiously:

the arguments linking trade to the environment are complex and

“there are few absolutes.”3° Four key trade issues that shape

Southern resource management -- consumption, price, export

27Charles Arden-Clarke, “An Action Agenda for Trade PolicyReform to Support Sustainable Development: A United NationsConference on Environment and Development Follow-up,” in DurwoodZaelke, Paul Orbuch, and Robert F. Housman, eds. Trade and theEnvironment: Law Economics and Policy (Washington: Island Press,1993), p.72.

28For background, see Tom Wathen, “A Guide to Trade and theEnvironment,” pp.3-22 and Charles Pearson, “The Trade andEnvironment Nexus: What is New Since ‘72?” pp.23-32 in Zaelke,Orbuch, and Housman, eds., Trade and the Environment, and PatrickLow, “International Trade and the Environment: An Overview,” pp.1-14 and Judith Dean, “Trade and the Environment: A Survey of theLiterature,” pp.15-28, in Patrick Low, ed., International Trade andthe Environment (New York: World Bank, 1992).

29Ha1 Kane, “Managing Through Prices, Managing Despite Prices,”in Zaelke, Orbuch, and Housman, eds., Trade and the Environment,p.58.

30Zaelke, Orbuch, and Housman, eds., Trade and the Environment,p.xiv.

20

Page 31: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

restrictions, and import barriers -- are particularly contentious.

A. Consumption

For classical economists, rising consumption (demand) is a key

element for economic growth. This assumes consumption is good:

more food, more televisions, more luxurious homes and cars, all

lead to greater prosperity and happiness. This ingrained view is

increasingly being challenged, especially as the disparity

continues to grow between rich Northern consumers and destitute

Southern survivors. Cities are now polluted by swarms of vehicles;

dumps are full of old appliances; rivers, lakes, and oceans are

saturated with waste and chemicals; deserts are expanding and

forests disappearing. As environmental problems spread,

‘environmental economists’ have begun to question conventional

economic indicators and analysis. They argue that economic growth

and resources are finite; it is therefore essential to

differentiate between quality consumption and the quantity

consumed. ‘Wasteful’ consumption such as excessive packaging,

three car families, or disposable tropical wood products

contributes to mounds of garbage, pollution, and loss of

biodiversity. ‘Conscientious’ consumption can ‘save’ resources

which can be transferred to food, housing, medical facilities,

education, and improved resource management in the South. In this

view, shifting the pattern of world consumption from one of ‘blind’

consumption to ‘conscientious’ consumption is necessary for

21

Page 32: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

equitable and sustainable development.3’

B. Price

Consumption and price are inseparable: lower prices encourage

higher consumption while higher prices tend to lower consumption.

Conventional economists argue that free markets create a natural

equilibrium between supply and demand that generates a ‘fair’

price. Yet, according to environmental economists, free markets

fail “to properly value the services that the environment

provides.”32 Prices paid by Northern consumers do not reflect

environmental or social costs. Primary rain forest timber is

particularly underpriced.33 By treating the commons as a free

good, the market “‘externalizes,’ or transfers to the broader

community, the costs of resource depletion. . .in the form of damages

to ecosystems.” As a result, “today’s trade patterns contain a

massive transfer of the environmental costs of world GNP to the

31For a discussion of the links between Northern consumption ofluxury goods and Southern environmental degradation and humansuffering, see Martin Khor Kok Peng, “The global environmentcrisis: a Third World perspective,” Briefing Paper for UNCED, no.5, 1991; Jyoti Parikh and Kirit Parikh, “Consumption patterns: thedriving force of environmental stress,” Bombay, Indira GandhiInstitute of Development Research, 1991, in NGONET 0795, computerdatabase of the Alternative Conference at UNCED, Rio de Janerio,1992; and Bunker Roy, “Population or Over-Consumption: Which isDestroying the World?” India, SWRC, 1992, in NGONET 1251.

32Kane, “Managing Through Prices,” p.60.

33While perhaps extreme, the Center for Science and Environmentin New Delhi estimates a mature tree in India is worth US$50,000.Alan Them Durning, “Let’s Put a Proper Price on Trees,”International Herald Tribune, 3 February 1994.

22

Page 33: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

resource-based economies of developing countries.”34

Low resource prices, along with poor revenue capture and

subsidies by Southern governments,35 encourage even greater

extraction to earn foreign exchange, and preclude investment in

sustainable production. Furthermore, “underpricing. . .natural

resources encourages wasteful and environmentally destructive

patterns of consumption throughout the world.”36 For a realistic

chance of sustainable management, it is necessary to maintain

stable world commodity prices,37 and ‘internalize’ the cost of

traded resources -- that is, generate a price, perhaps through

trade measures, sufficient to support the added expense of careful,

long-term management and account for losses connected to inevitable

ecological changes .

34MacNeill, Winsemius, and Yakushiji, Beyond Interdependence,p.37 and p.21. For more detail, see Stewart Hudson, “Trade,Environment and the Pursuit of Sustainable Development,” in Low,ed., International Trade, pp.55-64.

35For a discussion of the links between Southern subsidies andresource depletion, see Edward B. Barbier, Joanne C. Burgess, andAnil Markandya, “The Economics of Tropical Deforestation,” Arnbio20, no.2 (April, 1991), p.55.

36Charles Arden-Clarke, “South-North Terms of Trade:Environmental Protection and Sustainable Development,”International Environmental Affairs 4, no. 2 (Spring 1992), p.124.

37See chapter three, “The Role of the International Economy,”World Commission on Environment and Development, Our Common Future.

38See Arden-Clarke, “South-North Terms of Trade,” pp.122-137.For a strong critique of ‘environmental economics’ -- especiallythe disregard for values and rights -- see Ecologist, “MainstreamSolutions,” pp.173-179. In my view, pointing to the need forprices to internalize environmental costs is not a monstrous visionreducing people and culture to money -- rather, it accepts the factthat money is necessary to implement policies to protect theenvironment.

23

Page 34: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

To combat ideological blinders behind policies of ever-higher

production and economic growth, there is a “world-wide effort. . .to

explore the possibility of modifying the conventional economic

accounts in order that they may better reflect environmental and

natural resource degradation. Robert Repetto argues that

“failing to allow for depreciation of natural resource stocks when

they are depleted or degraded disguises the sacrifice of future

consumption, overstates income and capital formation, and justifies

policies that waste natural resources in the name of economic

growth.”4° By expressing environmental losses in monetary terms,

economic statistics - - touted by many governments as proof of their

competence -- can be corrected to reflect environmental

degradation. Presumably, this will provide strong incentives to

improve management as governments strive to maximize these new

economic indicators. While technically difficult, the most

innovative attempts to revise economic accounting include “the

costs of environmental degradation and resource depletion occurring

outside the country but related to consumption within the country”

-- for example, when resources are imported “at a price below the

39Phil±ppine Department of Environment and Natural Resources,The Philippine Natural Resources Accounting Project: ExecutiveSummary (Manila: Department of Environment and Natural Resources,1991), p.1.

40Robert Repetto, Promoting Environmentally Sound EconomicProgress: What the North Can Do (Washington: World ResourcesInstitute, 1990) , p.3.

24

Page 35: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

costs of their sustainable exploitation.”4’ Ignoring these

overseas environmental costs inflates the estimate of annual

increases in gross domestic product.

C. Southern Export Restrictions

The environmental impact of Southern restrictions on resource

exports is confusing and the empirical evidence ambiguous. Putting

aside the possibility of a complete break in South-North trade

ties, there are three basic scenarios: no restrictions, a ban on

unprocessed exports, and partial restrictions on unprocessed

exports. Free market advocates argue that bans or partial

restrictions reduce competition and foreign demand, lower prices,

entrench domestic political interests and contribute to over-

exploitation of natural resources. A free market leads to economic

growth and provides sufficient income for effective management. At

the other extreme, many advocates of a ban on unprocessed exports

argue that free markets do not account for environmental and social

costs and contribute to the South remaining underdeveloped and

dependent on Northern markets and manufacturing. To add value and

break this dependency, it is essential to promote trade in

processed products. While temporary economic and environmental

setbacks may occur, processing generates jobs, adds value,

diversifies the economy, and creates incentives to sustain the

41Roefie Hueting, Peter Bosch, and Bart de Boer, Methodologyfor the Calculation of Sustainable National Income (Switzerland:WWF International, 1992), p.5. The authors use the term‘environmental burden’ to measure the impact of consumption onoverseas resource depletion and environmental change.

25

Page 36: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

resource in the long term. Recognizing the management problems of

a free market and of export bans, some analysts see partial

restrictions on unprocessed exports as the best of both worlds --

keep some foreign demand and competition to maintain higher prices,

yet still promote processing for economic development, more

employment, and long-term management incentives.

This theoretical debate seems unresolvable. There are

management benefits and drawbacks of free markets, export

restrictions, and processing. It is common for environmentalists

to call for export bans on unprocessed resources to enhance

environmental protection. Undeniably, countries with unrestricted

resource exports have serious management problems. Yet, setting

aside long-term economic considerations, it is also clear that

either full or partial Southern restrictions on unprocessed natural

resource exports and incentives to promote finished exports do not

immediately improve management. In short, whether processed, semi-

processed or unprocessed resources are exported does not have a

decisive impact on management. The quantity of exports, the export

and consumer prices, the source of the resource, and enforcement of

state regulations are far more important.

D. Northern Tariffs and Import Restrictions

Northern tariffs can reduce timber consumption and raise

Northern consumer prices. In theory, if Northern governments

transferred tariff revenues to the South, or if special tariffs

were imposed on timber from unsustainable concessions, then import

26

Page 37: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

charges could promote sustainable management. But this has never

occurred in practice. Instead, Northern tariffs -- which commonly

escalate with the degree of finishing -- have syphoned Southern

revenues, undermined local processors, and prevented Southern

economies from diversifying. Instead of protecting Southern

environments, Northern tariffs have contributed to over-

exploitation and mismanagement.

Unilateral Northern import bans and quotas can protect

endangered species and quickly reduce consumption. In theory,

import restrictions on resources produced from unsustainable

sources and open markets for resources produced from sustainable

areas could enhance management. But in practice, Northern

importers do not distinguish between the source of resources. For

this reason, import barriers are crude instruments that easily

misfire. Without compensation, Northern import restrictions can

create economic hardship in the South. These can lower Southern

resource prices and decrease the economic value of resource stocks.

As well, Northern import restrictions may only reduce consumption

temporarily as new markets absorb the slack. In the case of

tropical timber, a study for the ITTO concludes that there is a

need to “improve rather than restrict access to import markets for

tropical timber products.” The report argues that “by adding value

to forestry operations, the trade in tropical timber products could

act as an incentive to sustainable production forest management --

provided that the appropriate domestic forest management policies

27

Page 38: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

and regulations are also implemented by producer countries.”42

CONCLUS ION

In sum, a Northern ecological shadow takes the form of the

resources drawn from the global eco-system. More precisely, for

bilateral South-North interaction, it is the cumulative

environmental impact of aid, technology, corporations, and trade on

the management of a Southern resource. The intensity of shadow

ecologies and the relative impact of different components is shaped

by Northern policies and practices, Southern responses (such as

export or investment restrictions), the value of the resource, and

the historical period. To date, South-North economic and

ecological interdependence has supported massive purchases of

Southern resources from unsustainable sources and at prices that

ignore environmental and social costs. This must change. A

complete break is not a viable political or economic solution.

Instead, careful manipulation of shadow ecologies is essential for

sustainable resource management. Northern ODA, loans, technology

transfers, and corporate investment must focus on alleviating

environmental problems. Even more essential, corporations must

eventually limit resource purchases to sustainable sources,

consumer prices must rise high enough to slash wasteful

consumption, and sufficient revenue must be returned to the South

42Edward B. Barbier et. al., “The Economic Linkages Between TheInternational Trade in Tropical Timber and The SustainableManagement of Tropical Forests,” Final Report. ITTO Activity PCM(XI)/4, 19 March 1993, p.iv and p.v.

28

Page 39: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

to support sustainable management. Having outlined the broad

theoretical debate over the environmental implications of bilateral

South-North interaction, I now turn to look specifically at Japan’s

shadow ecology.

29

Page 40: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

Chapter Two

JAPAN’S SHADOW ECOLOGY

To provide a foundation for understanding the impact of

Japan’s shadow ecology on timber management in Southeast Asia, I

outline major features and criticisms of Japanese government

economic assistance, corporate practices, and trade. Since shadow

ecologies can be moulded by policy, I highlight recent moves by the

government and trading companies to integrate environmental

concerns. I argue that the 1993 Environment Law, the new

environmental guidelines at the aid agencies, and the

‘environmental aid’ program -- while contributing to incremental

increases in funding, research, and technical assistance for

environmental projects -- have conspicuous problems. The

Environment Law and ODA guidelines are vague, the procedures for

environmental reviews are unclear and convoluted, and there are no

enforcement mechanisms or penalties. Environmental aid is

partially a reclassification of traditional aid projects, such as

water and sewage systems, and does not increase environmental

funding as much as it appears at first glance. Moreover, this aid

is primarily inthe form of loans. Bureaucratic turf battles have

also undermined the effectiveness of environmental aid. The

Ministry of International Trade and Industry (MITI) has partially

hijacked this aid program to justify and support corporate

environmental technology exports. Meanwhile, the Environment

Agency has minimal input into the management and distribution of

30

Page 41: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

this aid while the Forestry Agency has shown little interest. In

this setting, only a small amount of environmental aid supports

forest conservation, reforestation, and improving tropical logging

techniques.

While government policies to improve the environmental

management of overseas projects have clear defects, and though

there is a tendency to exaggerate accomplishments, the discrepancy

between public bluster and policy substance is even greater in the

business world. Intense criticism of overseas environmental

practices ignited a public relations counter-attack by Japanese

corporations in the 1990s. This has translated into a few showcase

projects and a flood of grandiose claims of a new environmental

awareness. Yet there is a wide gap between these claims and

concrete procedures, mechanisms, and flow of money.

More perturbingly, government and corporate efforts to improve

overseas environmental policies focus on peripheral effects of

Japan’s shadow ecology. There are few genuine efforts to tackle

the key issues of ‘wasteful’ consumption, low purchase and consumer

prices, or import barriers that deplete Southern state revenue

essential for sustainable management. Although there are scattered

statements that trade has significant environmental consequences,

there are no comprehensive policies, or even consistent positions.

These public statements appear designed to appease world and

domestic critics of overseas environmental practices. In private,

most Japanese government and business leaders downplay the impact

of trade, invariably diverting the conversation to the efforts to

31

Page 42: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

improve ODA or the showcase projects of the major trading

companies.

This chapter begins with essential background on Japanese aid

and loans. It outlines basic problems with ODA, particularly

administrative barriers to integrating environmental concerns. I

then evaluate recent efforts to improve ODA and loans, including

the environmental aid program, environmental guidelines and

assessments, and the new Environment Law. I examine the roles of

MITI, the Foreign Ministry, the Finance Ministry, the Environment

Agency, the Forestry Agency and the ODA implementing agencies. The

second half provides background on corporate Japan and evaluates

post-1990 efforts to develop environmental guidelines.

ENVIRONMENTAL IMPACT OF JAPANESE ODA AND GOVERNMENT LOANS

Japan’s aid program began in the l950s as reparation payments

to Southeast Asia. During the 1960s, it was designed to promote

Japanese exports; in the 1970s, particularly after the 1973 cii

shock, aid became part of efforts to secure natural resources; in

the l980s, in addition to its economic role, aid emerged more as a

tool of foreign policy, as part of ‘comprehensive security.’1

Today, in terms of quantity, Japan is an aid superpower,

1Robert M. Orr, Jr. and Bruce M. Koppel, “A Donor ofConsequence: Japan as a Foreign Aid Power,” pp.2-3, in Bruce Koppeland Robert M. Orr Jr., eds., Japan’s Foreign Aid: Power and Policyin a New Era (Boulder: Westview Press, 1993). On changes toJapanese aid in the late l980s, see “Beware the helping hand,” TheEconomist, 15 July 1989, pp.12-14. For a succinct summary of theevolution of Japanese aid, see William L. Brooks and Robert M. Orr,Jr., “Japan’s Foreign Economic Assistance,” Asian Survey 25, no. 3(March 1985), pp.322-340.

32

Page 43: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

H Hi

CtH

i(D

JII

H

CD

H ():i

pJ

‘dU)

CDO

iLi

H

ç1U)

H-

Ho

DP

’j - H

Hi

0

w‘-< o

r-I

dCD

(flI

U)C

I)H

-tfl H pC

DrI

-tn

H 0 1xj

H°tI

),rt

II 00

Hi

0 c-tx

iH C

D Ho H

i

H,

0C

r0

ot-

Hi

Il(Q

p.:ii

iIx

j

CDH

1:1

H-

NP)

H

0N

-H H

iiCI

-CD

Prt

o<1 CD

CD

I-CD

Ho

H-

Q1

0H

-<

HCD

Cr

(Cl

IICD

H-

U)(2

oCD

oH

jCl

)H

r-4

Cl)Lx

ir

U)0

•.

U)0

•H

-H

-i

o0

l1JH

-H

0r

(Q::y

CDH

CD

o0

0çi

0C

r

U) -pi C

rH

-ci) H

Cr

1xj

H

PH

qCD

d0

CDJ

Lxiii

iifl

rtCD

Fj

H-

U)—

ii

CD•

11) II Cr

H 0 H pi H H ii U) H pJ q uj ii CD U) CD 0 Li H ii H w pi (I) ci Cl)

H H a-,

H-

H H H 0 ii

=000

CD

CD

iiii

H-

H-

PJ

HIi

iiH

0L

Mi

H-H q

P)

t:;1

rt:

urt0d

‘t5

JH

iiU

)

HC

DIio

1L1

iI-

hQ

QP

)H

-‘

H-H

1CD

:p

j

U)O

r-r

iiH

-CD

w0ii

U)H

Ph

CDQ

coP

’I—

,H

Cri-

-C

DC

DO

CDH

-CD

Cl)

H.

H-

HL

QU)

‘H-

CD

U)

CD

•oii

Hi’

• qq

0P’

IP’

CD

PJP

JP

iiii

H

t1)U)

ii CD HP

’ çt

0 0 Hi

0 II H 0 Ii 0 H CD p.) CD CD Li P.) H-

H 0 ii H I- H LJ

‘—‘-

Hi

Mi

Ct

H-

r’c-

ICD

H-

PPi

CD5

II<

IIH

‘dH

-CD

H-

CDL

P30

P3U)

CD‘<

HH

Cr

U)C

rH

-CD

iiCD

H-

P)O

pCl)

P3p3

iiC

rM

i•.

Cr

CD

oW

Cr

IiH

H-

H-

H-

-C/2

Hii

iiCD

H-

CDH

U)U)

IC

rHI

H.!—

Ik-

P3CD

HiP

’H

CDCr

WC

rH 0

CD

CD

iiH

r-g

U)

orr

H-

0 iiii

iiii

H-

U)q

(0

CDU)

H-

0a-

,r-

tb

Ui

ciH

oCD

Mi

‘-<

iiII

Li

oCr

CD

Mi

<CD i

(Drr

CDl3

0CD

Cr

CD0

0Li

CrP3

Cr

iicr

H-

0H

-j

H-

10

H-

HH

-H

iii

U)H

-CD

Mi

CDH

-ii

CDH

-H

Mi

H-

p.

IiP.)

H-

Cr

CD

Cr (D

U)P3

H-

P3H

IiH

iH

Huii

Cr

U)U)

CD0

HCD

CDU)

HH

‘<C

rH

H-

CDCD

i-ii

I-CD

pjCD

H-

CDU)

iiH

-C

r0

c-I-

P.)P3

00

P30

IIII

<h

LiIi

U)C

rCD

k<

CDCD

U)>

ciC

r0

Page 44: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

International Cooperation Agency (JICA), which started in 1962 as

the Overseas Technical Cooperation Agency to administer grants and

technical assistance.6 The OECF is officially attached to the EPA,

although it is strongly influenced by the Finance Ministry. In

FY1992 OECF loans comprised around half of total Japanese ODA,

(around 10 percent of world ODA); approximately 51.5 percent of

this sum went to Southeast Asian countries.7 Annual OECF

development financing is equivalent to “the lending of the Asian

Development Bank, the Inter-American Development Bank, and the

African Development Bank combined.”8 These loans have relatively

high interest rates and tend to fund large infrastructure

projects.9 JICA is controlled mainly by the Ministry of Foreign

Affairs. However, MITI, or any ministry channelling its aid funds

through JICA, including the Ministry of Agriculture, Fisheries, and

Forestry, has influence over JICA projects.’°

6For a description of JICA, see Robert M. Orr Jr., TheEmergence of Japan’s Foreign Aid Power (New York: ColumbiaUniversity Press, 1990), pp.47-SO, for the OECF, pp.45-47.

7OECF, OECF Annual Report 1993 (Tokyo, OECF, 1993), p.3 andp.37. From 1961 to the end of March 1993, Indonesia, Thailand, thePhilippines, and Malaysia absorbed 40.9 percent of OECF loans.Ibid., p.37.

8Richard Forrest and Yuta Harago, Japan’s Official DevelopmentAssistance (ODA) and Tropical Forests (Gland, Switzerland: WWFInternational, 1990), p.8.

9Although officially in FY1990 31.5 percent of bilateral aidfunded infrastructure projects, Hiroshi Kanda claims it is actuallyaround half. Hiroshi Kanda, “A Big Lie: Japan’s ODA andEnvironmental Policy,” AMPO Japan-Asia quarterly Review 23, no. 3(1992), p.42.

10For background on JICA activities, see JICA, For The FutureOf The Earth (Tokyo: JICA, 1992).

34

Page 45: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

The Export-Import (EXIM) Bank of Japan provides project loans,

and export, import, and investment credits to foreign governments

and corporations and to Japanese businesses and trading companies

that do not qualify for ODA loans.” It is officially under the

control of the Finance Ministry, although MITI has significant

input. In FY1992 the Bank made US$16.5 billion worth of

commitments; at the end of the fiscal year, outstanding loans

reached US$71.4 billion, the highest in the history of the Bank.’2

The EXIM Bank is designed to “facilitate Japan’s economic

interchange with foreign countries through the provision of a wide

range of financial services to supplement and encourage financing

by commercial banks and other financial institutions in Japan.” A

central priority is the “development and import into Japan of

natural resources. 13

Like other donors, Japan’s lending policies and decision

making process have general problems that contribute to

difficulties in evaluating and incorporating environmental

11The distinction between OECF aid loans and EXIM loans is inmany ways purely definitional -- a small change in OECD DevelopmentAssistance Committee (DAC) guidelines could easily eliminate alarge percentage of OECF ‘aid’ and swell EXIM ‘loans’. For thisreason EXIM loans -- though not officially part of ODA -- canlogically be considered alongside a discussion of governmentoverseas economic assistance. For a description of DAC guidelinesfor economic assistance qualifying as ODA, see Orr and Koppel, “ADonor of Consequence,” p.16, footnote 3.

‘2EXIM Bank of Japan, The Export-Import Bank of Japan: AnnualReport 1993 (Tokyo: EXIM Bank, 1993), p.8.

‘3EXIM Bank of Japan, Guide To The Export-Import Bank of Japan(Tokyo: EXIM Bank of Japan, February 1994), p.1.

35 V

Page 46: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

concerns.’4 The greatest obstacles to improving ODA are

administrative fragmentation and an emphasis on increasing quantity

over clear goals and policies.’5 Battles between MITI (fighting

for business interests), Finance (stressing fiscal responsibility),

and Foreign Affairs (promoting foreign policy objectives) create

administrative paralysis, dilute policies, and foster ad hoc

solutions.’6 There is also little coordination between JICA and

the OECF.’7 One OECF official claimed: “We get better cooperation

with USAID [U.S. Agency for International Development] than we do

with JICA.”8 Efforts to tackle environmental concerns are further

weakened by already over-worked staff responsible for increasingly

large aid budgets.19 There are also few staff with environmental

‘4it should be emphasized that “few of the problems theJapanese development program faces are unique.” Alan S. Miller,and Curtis Moore, Japan And The Global Environment (Maryland:Center for Global Change, University of Maryland, 1991), p.20.

‘5During interviews in 1994, environment-oriented aidbureaucrats at the OECF and JICA expressed frustration with theomnipresent administrative obstacles. For a critique of ODAadministration, see chapter three in Alan Rix, Japan’s Foreign AidChallenge: Policy reform and aid leadership (London: Routledge,1993); for aid policy, see chapter four.

‘6The weakest central actor - the EPA - generally remainsneutral or sides with the Finance Ministry. Orr and Koppel, “ADonor of Consequence,” p.6. The role of these actors is discussedby Toru Yanagihara and Anne Emig, “An Overview of Japan’s ForeignAid,” in Islam, ed., Yen For Development, pp.53-58.

‘7interview, Forestry consultant, Japan Overseas ForestryConsultants Association (JOFCA) and USAID, 3 February 1994.

‘8Quoted in Orr, The Emergence of Japan’s Foreign Aid Power,p.50.

‘9”In 1990 each ODA administrator in Japan was responsible foran average of US$6.35 million in funds -- far more than aid staffin any other nation.” Richard Forrest, “Japanese Aid and the

36

Page 47: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

w

hJL

zJ

PJJ

LxlL

xi

CD

(Dcl<

ft

PiftH

CD

H-1

UhhH

-H

M)O

HC

)fti-

iH

-C

(D

H-H

C(D

WM

Cl)W

LC

)C

DM

ft(D

ftC

DC

Dt1

Cj)

•.Cl)

CDH

’dH

ZJft

Wo

M‘D1jH

--

f’H

-piC

CD

c

SQ

Lj

CD‘d )xj

JC

DC

H1Q

CD

‘H

MC

MW

Pc

P-M

pM

(DC

CD

MW1i’ ftH

;tl-

k<

H-

qP

).P

P3 H JH

P‘

rt

()1

JrF

WC

CD

IftM

CD

-

.Cl)

-(D

H-

CD

ri-

HW

cm

L’i

.0-.

HW

H-

H-

pj

(.QC

p.

-

°H

-q

Cl)

°i

CDH

ft..C

)j ft

ijQ

W.

MO

2H

-CD

HW

,H

iftj

CDM

i’<

HC

MH

i

CD‘

‘1Fx

jC

DH

—1

H-P

JQH

Mftf

txj

p.p

.C

D)Q

H H-A

CC

(DC

DM

iM

P)W

WC

CD

CD

CD

ftC

DM

rJ C ii CD C))

(t q CD (1) CD H p.

pi p.

(t CD Lxi

H ii C CD ft

Lxi

dC

Jui

‘‘t

iCl

)H

ft(I)

C)I-

CL)M

CC

C)I-

PiC

CC

CDCD

CC

<<

CH

ft<

MC)

H-

MPJ

IIC)

ftH

-b

H-

Cl)H

-ft

C<

ftft

PiH

-C

39)

CDII

HC)

H-

I-’

H-

9)U)

Cft

ft‘1

CCl)

H-

p.

H-C

CW

Cp.

p.

IICD

ftH

(Cl

Cl)9)

ftCD

ftCl)

CDH

-H

3Cl)

Cl)

9)U)

ftp

.CD

Mi

ftCD

H-

bC)

HCD

H9)

C)q

P.s

U]

Hi

CDft

H-C

Mi

Ci)H

‘dC

piCD

0II

po

CDft

‘ft

H-

Hl)

H-

9)

Lxi

U)p

.‘<

9)H

-p

.CD

Cl)CD

CH

CDH

-II

H-

C)H

-•

CD

CL

CDCD

U)M

CDCD

CDC

IIp

.CD

CDCD

IC9)

CDp

.C)

‘-“

U)

C9)

H-

<C)

ftç-

t9)

CDC)

Cl)CD

CC

IIq

H-

j-‘1

p.

I-<

iiC

1W‘.<

‘dH

iH

-H

p.

MIft

CD[1

PCD

9)C

CDCD

U)C

t’30

.pCD

CDp

.H

CDC

Hi

Hi

H-

Mi

HC)

H-

Cl)C

U)ft

CDM

iH

<C

‘xj

Cl)CD

HM

ftCD

HH

-—

9)H

-i

iCl

)C

p.C)

qft

MC

Mft

Mi

U)H

iC.Q

Mi

CDH

-9)

CDC

9)9)

CDC

ftft

9)H

ft‘<

CDU)

QCD

CDft

—ç

IiP.

sH

iH

CDCD

C)CD

‘ZS

ftCD

CDM

H-

Mi

H-

CDCD

qb

CD9)

pM

U)C

3CD

HH

-H

U)•

CH

U)ft

(.C

)H

=H

CDC

-

-CC

)H

-CD

r’H

-CD

Ci

PH

ftpi

Cft

CDft

C)C

MCD

<Cl)

p5H

iH

Ci)(t

WH

-ft

p.

Mi

p.

HCl)

CD—

9)C

HCl)

CM

CDCD

H.s

CDft

ftC

C)Cl)

HCD

CDH

•-

Cl)

-)

CDI

ftCD

CC

)CD

CD‘d

CDC

cM

Ci)

CD9)

CDH

MCD

3

Hft

H-

CII

H-

HH

-C

t’JCD

CDH

CDM

gc

PCD

HH

-<

CDCl)

ftCD

çuU

)CD

p.

Mft

ftC)

qCl)

9)C

CDU)

CL)

‘<Cl)

CDH

:ig

9)H

-U)

H-

ftq

(_)

HH

-H

-U)

HCl)

Mi

CDH

-L

’CD

C)

CH

-CD

p.

Mi

g‘1

‘dC

HU)

MC

HCD

HC

CDC)

CDH

iH

-C

9)ii

CH

iCl)

9)C

U)Y

‘r9)

CD-

CDCD

(0H

-i-

ftH

.H

MCD

U)U)

ftC)

H-

9)9)

CC

9)ft

09)

9)H

ftH

-II

C9)

CD9)

Ci)

3‘1

Hp

.CD

‘1II

‘1H

ftU)

CCD

CDp

.p

.‘<

CDCD

p.

ftCD

:iU)

Page 48: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

half of all ODA, more than any other country. With the rapid

appreciation of the yen over the last 20 years, these loans have

often been costly, and have contributed to pressures on Southern

governments, especially in Asia, to exploit natural resources to

service their debts. In addition to the stress on lending, critics

have pointed to poor pre-and-post-project evaluations,25 corruption

and incompetence, inappropriate technology transfers,26 the

drawbacks of a ‘request-based’ system,27 aid tied to corporate

interests,28 an emphasis on large-scale development schemes over

community based projects, and a lack of cooperation with NGO5.29

Analysts have been especially critical of the impact of aid on

tropical forests.

240rr and Koppel, “A Donor of Consequence,” p.3.

25Forrest, “Japanese Aid and the Environment,” pp.29-30.

26JICA technology transfers are often far too advanced. Twofactors make this difficult to overcome: Japanese technicians aremore comfortable with advanced equipment; and developing countriesoften insist on the most advanced equipment. Interview, Office ofOverseas Environmental Cooperation, Environment Agency, Tokyo, 5April 1994.

270rr and Koppel argue that ‘request based’ aid has “leftJapanese firms open to charges of manipulating requests moreconducive to corporate rather than recipient interests.” Orr andKoppel, “A Donor of Consequence,” p.9. As well, it “falls prey tothe desires of ruling elites in developing countries who requestlarge-scale, ultramodern ‘showcase’ projects often irrelevant tothe greatest needs of the people.” Forrest and Harago, Japan’sOfficial Development Assistance, p.12.

28See Forrest, “Japanese Aid and the Environment,” pp.26-27.

29For a general critique, see Mera Koichi, “Problems in the AidProgram,” Japan Echo 16, no. 1 (1989), pp.13-18, an abridgedtranslation of “ODA wa ‘senshinkoku kurabu no sankahi’ de wa nai,”Economic Today (Summer 1988), pp.88-97.

38

Page 49: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

In recent years, as attitudes change and world and domestic

scrutiny intensifies, the Japanese government has tried to tackle

some of the problems with its ODA. Although serious weaknesses

remain, incremental changes are occurring. According to Alan Rix,

although, “reform and innovation in policy have not moved as fast

as changes to public presentation of policy” there are micro-level

adjustments “in the management and operation of aid f lows.”30 In

addition, there has been some movement toward greater transparency,

more involvement of NGOs,3’ larger grants, more attention to basic

human needs, and less overtly tied aid.32 JICA now accepts the

need for ‘institution building’, ‘participatory development’, and

more careful allocation of grants to avoid past problems of

building facilities that remain empty, or sending equipment that is

never used.33 The Japanese government has also developed an

environmental aid program, and environmental guidelines and

departments at JICA, the OECF, and the EXIM Bank.

30Rix, Japan’s Foreign Aid, p.190 and p.8. He examines thesechanges throughout his book.

31While funding for NGOs has increased slightly, compared tothe overall aid budget, it is still “minuscule”. David Potter,“Assessing Japan’s Environmental Aid Policy,” Pacific Affairs 67(Summer 1994), p.203.

32Although officially much of Japanese aid has been untied,informal ties to business are still widespread, especially to yenloans. Orr and Koppel, “A Donor of Consequence,” p.10; and Koichi,“Problems in the Aid Program,” p.14.

33lnterview, Senior JICA official, Tokyo, 12 April 1994.

39

Page 50: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

ENVIRONMENTAL AID

Among ODA donors, there is no consistent definition of

environmental assistance. The Japanese Foreign Ministry defines it

as “assistance conducive to the resolution of environmental

problems” including “the improvement of the living environment,

forestry conservation and afforestation, disaster reduction,

pollution control, the conservation of the natural environment

(including the conservation of biological diversity) and the

protection of the ozone layer.”34 In 1989, Japan announced an

environmental aid target of 300 billion yen over the next three

years. To encourage requests for this aid, teams from JICA, the

OECF, Foreign Affairs, MITI, the Forestry Agency, and the

Environment Agency went on environmental missions, including one to

Southeast Asia.35 This environmental aid target was exceeded by

more than 100 billion yen. For FY1992, 16.9 percent of total ODA

was defined as environmental aid.36 Not all of this total

represents ‘new’ funds for environmental protection. Environmental

aid has been partially derived by reclassifying “infrastructure

development” or “irrigation and flood control” to ‘environmental

34Japanese Ministry of Foreign Affairs, Japan’s ODA 1993,p.175. Japan’s environmental aid policy -- based on declarationsat the 1989 Paris Summit and the 1991 London Summit -- is outlinedin Ibid., pp.l76-19l.

35Forrest and Harago, Japan’s Official Development Assistance,p.13.

36Japanese Ministry of Foreign Affairs, Japan’s ODA 1993, Table11-22, p.180.

40

Page 51: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

projects’ So far around half of environmental aid has funded

improvements to urban water and sewage systems.38 As a result,

about 70 percent of this aid has been in the form of loans.39

Environmental concerns gained momentum in Japan during 1992.

An Economic Council advisory subcommittee to the Prime Minister

called for better ODA guidelines to promote environmental

conservation.40 In June, Cabinet approved an ODA Charter; the

first Principle declares that “environmental conservation and

development should be pursued in tandem. ,,41 At the UN Conference

on Environment and Development, Japan promised 900 to 1000 billion

yen of environmental aid over the next five years, the largest by

any country.42 In early 1993, the Japanese government announced it

would expand environmental aid to the ASEAN countries.43 In

November 1993, the Japanese Diet passed the New Basic Law on the

37Potter, “Assessing Japan’s,” p.206. Also, Interview, Friendsof the Earth, Tokyo, 25 May 1994.

38Louise do Rosario, “Green at the edges,” FEER, 12 March 1992,p.39.

39Japanese Ministry of Foreign Affairs, Japan’s ODA 1993,p.178. Considering the links between Southern debt andenvironmental problems, it is debatable whether any loan should belabelled ‘environmental aid’.

40”ODA should be used to guard the environment, panel says,”The Japan Times, 27 May 1992, p.7.

41OECF, OECF Annual Report 1993, p.18.

42Shigeaki Fujisaki, “Environmental Issues in DevelopingCountries and the Role of ODA,” Japan Review of InternationalAffairs 7, no. 1 (Winter 1993) , p.75.

43Asahi Shimbun, 17 January 1993, in Potter, “AssessingJapan’s,” p.201.

41

Page 52: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

Environment. The law explicitly addresses environmental links to

ODA. Section one, article 35, reads:

The State, in implementing international cooperation,shall make efforts to consider global environmentalconservation etc. in the areas where its internationalcooperation is implemented.

BATTLES OVER ENVIRONMENTAL AID

Typical of Japan’s ODA administration, as funding and interest

have risen, “‘green’ aid has become the subject of intense

competition among various ministries involved in foreign

assistance.”45 In a struggle over environmental turf, Foreign

Affairs and MITI have become strong supporters of environmental

aid. The Foreign Ministry allocated 4 billion yen in FY1992 to

finance international organizations involved in environmental

programs. As noted earlier, however, the bulk of the Ministry’s

influence is through JICA.

MITI has aggressively staked out an environmental mandate.

MITI’s Environmental Policy Division emphasizes technological

solutions and corporate technology exports to tackle global

warming, and promote energy conservation and alternative energy

Government of Japan, The Basic Environment Law, Law No. 91,1993, effective 19 November 1993. For an overview of the new law,see Hidefumi Imura, “Japan’s Environmental Balancing Act:Accommodating Sustained Development,” Asian Survey 34, no. 4 (April1994), pp.355-368.

45Louise do Rosario, “Green at the edges,” FEER, 12 March 1992,p.39.

42

Page 53: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

sources.46 ‘New Earth 21’, a MITI backed proposal to the

international community, calls for the development and “world-wide

diffusion of environmentally sound technologies.”47 Specific MITI

projects all aim at a technological fix for global environmental

problems. The International Centre For Environmental Technology

Transfer (ICETT) -- a non-profit organization under MITI

jurisdiction and with local government, academic and industry

participation -- was established in 1991 to transfer Japanese

pollution technology to developing countries.48 In the same year,

MITI announced its Green Aid Plan. In FY1992, Green Aid provided

around 2.7 billion yen to support technological efforts to reduce

water and air pollution, and improve waste treatment, recycling,

and energy conservation in the South.49 The Research Institute of

Innovative Technology for the Earth (RITE) -- a foundation

administered by MITI - - supports a joint industry, academic, and

government research facility completed in 1993 to study

environmental technologies, particularly for energy conservation

and global warming.50 In 1993, MITI and the Agency of Industrial

46lnterview, MITI official, Environmental Policy Division,Tokyo, 27 April 1994.

47M1T1, “The New Earth 21,” internal document, supplied by aMITI official, April 1994.

48ICETT (Yokkaichi, Japan: International Centre ForEnvironmental Technology Transfer, June 1993).

49M1T1, “Green Aid Plan,” internal document, supplied by a MITIofficial, April 1994.

50For background, see RITE (Tokyo: Research Institute ofInnovative Technology for the Earth, March 1992).

43

Page 54: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

Science and Technology amalgamated three existing projects, forming

the New Sunshine Program “to develop innovative technology to

create sustainable growth while solving energy and environmental

issues. 1151

The Environment Agency -- historically a weak player in

ongoing bureaucratic struggles, especially over ODA -- has had

little input into overseas issues. There are some signs this may

be changing.52 Despite having no official mandate to impose

overseas environmental guidelines or control environmental aid, the

Environment Agency established a Global Environment division in

1990. This division tries to encourage overseas Japanese companies

to consider environmental factors; it is also directly involved in

some JICA projects.53 In addition, as part of global efforts to

reevaluate economic accounting, Environment Agency researchers are

trying to measure in monetary terms the effects of “economic

activities on foreign countries and the global environment,

and. . . the impacts of global environmental change on domestic

51MrrI, and the Agency of Industrial Science and Technology.New Sunshine Program (Tokyo: New Sunshine Program PromotionHeadquarters, 1993), p.4.

52These signs must be examined warily since, for favourablepublicity, it is sometimes useful for the more powerful ministriesto make it look like the Environment Agency is involved indecisions, perhaps even at the helm. Interview, Friends of theEarth, Tokyo, 25 May 1994.

53lnterview, Office of Overseas Environmental Cooperation,Environment Agency, Tokyo, 5 April 1994.

44

Page 55: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

economic activity.”54 Another possible sign of growing influence

is the 36 percent increase in the Environment Agency’s aid budget

in FY1991,55 though it is still one of the smallest. Perhaps more

significantly, Environment Agency officials claim that, despite

being quite critical of ODA environmental reviews, informal

influence is beginning to develop. There is also a possibility the

New Basic Environment Law will reinforce, perhaps even promote,

Environment Agency input.56 Not all trends, however, solidify the

growing influence of the Environment Agency. As the environmental

spark ignited by the 1992 UNCED Conference fades, momentum has been

lost in the Japanese Diet to make the Environment Agency a full

ministry. More importantly, funding and personnel are still too

limited for consistent influence.57

The Forestry Agency is quite conservative and has been less

eager to dive into the fray for environmental aid.58 In 1990 the

54Tsuneyuki Morita, “Environmental and Natural ResourceAccounting in Japan,” CIDIE Workshop on Environmental and NaturalResource Accounting, UNEP Headquarters, Nairobi, 1992, p.2. TheEconomic Planning Agency and the Ministry of Agriculture, Forestryand Fisheries are also studying resource accounting. Ibid., p.1.

55Rix, Japan’s Foreign Aid, p.125.

56lnterview with one of the drafters of the New BasicEnvironment Law, Environment Agency, Global Environment Department,Tokyo, 9 June 1994. Also see ICunitoshi Sakurai, “Japan’s NewGovernment and Official Development Assistance,” INTEP Newsletter,no. 3 (October, 1993), p.1

57Based on several interviews, Global Environment Department,Environment Agency, Tokyo, 9 June 1994.

58According to one source, it is a defensive, inflexible Agencylinked closely to the major trading companies. Interview, Friendsof the Earth, Tokyo, 25 May 1994.

45

Page 56: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

Agency published a position paper on tropical forests calling for

large-scale tree plantations, more cooperation with NGOs, and

timber purchases from sustainable sources.59 Strangely,

considering these kinds of reports tend to be full of fluff, it

does not emphasize protecting biodiversity and primary forests or

seriously consider the implications of tropical timber consumption.

Instead, it advocates exporting Japanese forestry expertise,

stimulating consumption, and expanding trade in timber.6°

THE OECF, THE EXIM B2NK, JICA, AND THE ENVIRONMENT

The OECF, JICA, and the EXIM Bank have all developed

environmental departments and guidelines since the late 1980s. The

OECF now has “an environment advisor, an Environment Committee and

a senior manager in charge of environmental problems.”61 In 1989,

the OECF established environmental guidelines to encourage

environmentally sound Southern loan requests, and provide the OECF

with criteria to evaluate applications.62 Generally, before an

official request is made, a Japanese fact finding mission is sent

to evaluate the feasibility of Southern proposals. At this stage,

59While these are all positive proposals (although plantationsmust be managed with great care), as we will see in later chapters,the Forestry Agency has not actively pursued these goals.

60My summary is based on Forrest and Harago, Japan’s OfficialDevelopment Assistance, pp.10-11.

61Rix, Japan’s Foreign Aid, p.125.

62lnterview, OECF Environment and Social Development Division,Tokyo, 11 April 1994. Also see OECF, OECF Environmental Guidelines(Tokyo: OECF, 1989). For a review of OECF environmental projects,see OECF, OECF and The Environment (Tokyo: OECF, 1993).

46

Page 57: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

based on a check list, OECF officials apparently encourage

prospective borrowers to consider environmental factors. According

to an OECF official, as a result of this process, actual loan

applications are rarely rejected for environmental reasons.63

OECF environmental guidelines could certainly be strengthened.

Forrest argues that these guidelines “seem to be no more than a

vague menu of items which should be considered, rather than

conditions required to ensure environmental damage will not result

before OECF provides funding.”TM Rix notes that the “environment

is just one aspect of OECF appraisal of projects, and no strict

impact statement is required.”65 Indicative of the weak

environmental review process is one of the six main items for

assessing applications, the lame question: “Is there sufficient

environmental consideration in the project?”66 Also indicative is

the lack of any revision to the original guidelines, despite the

mollifying, and now somewhat embarrassing note in the preface of

the 1989 OECF Environmental Guidelines: “This is a first version,

63lnterview, OECF official, Tokyo, 11 April 1994. There arecases of the OECF suspending a project after severe criticism byenvironmentalists and NGOs, although these suspensions were notbased on violations of OECF environmental guidelines. Examplesinclude the Sardar Sardovar dam project in India (1990), theMindanao geo-thermal power project in the Philippines (1991), andthe US$80 million loan for the Calaca II power plant in Luzon(1992). Potter, “Assessing Japan’s,” p.202.

64Forrest and Harago, Japan’s Official Development Assistance,P.S.

65Rix, Japan’s Foreign Aid, pp.125-26. Evaluated fromOperational Guidance on OECF Loans, March, 1991, Tokyo, p.19.

66Quoted in Rix, Japan’s Foreign Aid, p.126.

47

Page 58: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

and we plan to make such improvements as prove necessary, with a

view to making them more comprehensive and effective.”67

The EXIM Bank first developed environmental guidelines in

1989; these were updated and made more stringent in late 1991.

Little is known about these guidelines. They are confidential;

even the Ministry of Finance has not seen a copy.68 In theory, the

Bank as a whole reviews environmental guidelines. In each loan

department there is a senior official responsible for assessing

environmental aspects. However, for many applications -- such as

importing aircraft technology -- there is no environmental

assessment since the proposal is not deemed to have any

environmental implications. Though rare, if an application has

obvious environmental problems it is rejected.69 When an

application has unclear environmental implications, it is referred

to the Environmental Affairs Section.

From April 1993 to April 1994, the Environmental Affairs

Section reviewed about a dozen applications, one relating to

67As of April 1994, no revisions had been published.

68lnterview, Senior official, Environment Section, EXIM Bank,Tokyo, 11 April 1994. The Ministry of Finance has shown littleinterest in environmental issues. According to one source,officials are “arrogant and authoritarian” and unlike the otherministries, there is not even a superficial attempt to bother withpublic relations. Interview, Friends of the Earth, Tokyo, 25 May1994.

69Revealingly, I was unable to obtain statistics on the numberof applications rejected at this stage. Though unverifiable, anEXIM official claimed that loan applications are almost neverturned down since, if Bank officials consider the projectenvironmentally unsound, the loan is quietly, informally rejected;the applicant then formally withdraws the request to save face.

48

Page 59: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

logging in Sarawak. None of these was rejected. Instead,

conditions were set. According to a Bank official in the

Environment Section, if these conditions are violated, then the

Bank can force early repayment of the loan. In addition, there is

an informal understanding that it would be difficult to receive

future loans.70 Besides these apparent environmental checks, the

Bank claims that it now lends more money to improve environmental

management. But without access to confidential Bank records, it is

impossible to assess comprehensively the environmental guidelines,

the review process, or the environmental loans. Secret rules, weak

penalties, vague lines of accountability, and few, if any, examples

of applications rejected for environmental reasons all suggest the

Bank’s environmental record has serious shortcomings. An

intuitive, precursory assessment is that the Bank is more concerned

with avoiding environmental scandals and public embarrassment than

with genuine reviews of loan applications.7’

While OECF and EXIM Bank environmental guidelines appear

largely cosmetic, more concrete, though incremental changes have

occurred at JICA. In 1989, JICA established an Environment Section

of the Planning Department. Based on OECD Development Assistance

Committee recommendations, in 1990 JICA introduced environmental

70lnterview, Senior official, Environment Section, EXIM Bank,Tokyo, 11 April 1994.

7’One indication is the rationale for reviewing the loggingproject in Sarawak. A central concern was the publicity andscrutiny given to logging in Sarawak, not specific problems withthe loan proposal. Interview, Senior official, EnvironmentSection, EXIM Bank, Tokyo, 11 April 1994.

49

Page 60: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

guidelines for development initiatives including dams, agricultural

estates, and forestry projects. Since then JICA has tried to

incorporate more environmental factors into grants and technical

assistance; conserving primary tropical forests and rehabilitating

secondary forests have apparently been a major focus of these

efforts.72 In FY1992, 17.4 billion yen, or 13.5 percent of total

JICA expenditures, went to the environmental sector, up from 8.1

billion yen in 1988. These funds trained 722 people in Japan, sent

129 experts overseas, and supported 67 development studies and 47

technical cooperation projects. In the same year, environmental

specialists reviewed 108 projects.73

Despite more support for environmental projects, and plausible

attempts to incorporate environmental factors into decision making,

there are serious problems with implementing environmental

guidelines. The Environment Section, along with a regional

division of the Planning Department, determine whether a project

requires an environmental Impact Assessment (EIA). If necessary,

one of JICA’s sector-based departments -- such as forestry -- then

identifies the scope of the assessment. The actual EIA is handled

by a team of private consultants and JICA officials who often have

little experience with environmental or tropical forestry

management. The environmental guidelines are “non-binding

reference materials,” and are optional at all stages of the

72lnterview, Senior JICA official, Tokyo, 12 April 1994.

73Hiroshi Enomoto, JICA, Division of the Environment,“Environmental Cooperation and The Japan International CooperationAgency,” INTEP Newsletter, no. 4 (February 1994), pp.6-7.

50

Page 61: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

process. Details on specific projects are confidential and there

is no post-project evaluation of environmental changes.

Furthermore, environmental reviews do not consider alternatives to

the proposed project and give little consideration to indirect

social and environmental implications.74 Specific problems with

JICA’s environmental guidelines and procedures are exacerbated by

the fragmented ODA administration. The OECF and JICA have not

consolidated environmental guidelines and do not coordinate

environmental reviews. As a result, standards may change as a

project progresses.75 This problem is unlikely to be resolved

soon. Environmental guidelines and aid plans vary across

ministries, and despite the new Environmental Law, there is little

chance of developing a unified environmental aid policy.

Problems with environmental planning at JICA and superficial

changes at the OECF and EXIM Bank lead Hiroshi Kanda to pan

environmental aid. He argues “there is no remarkable difference

between ‘Environment ODA’ and ‘regular ODA.’ They both tend to

support Japanese industry and Japanese economic aims.”76 This

seems too harsh. It would be naive to assume the new rhetoric

equals improved practices; but it is equally facile to assume these

new policies have no practical effects. Environmental aid, policy

changes at MITI and Foreign Affairs, and decisions by JICA, the

summary of Forrest and Harago, Japan’s Official DevelopmentAssistance, pp.6-7.

75Potter, “Assessing Japan’s,” p.2O8.

76ICanda, “A Big Lie,” p.45.

51

Page 62: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

OECF, and the EXIM Bank to create environmental committees and

sections, and to revise guidelines, indicate, at a minimum, a

recognition of a need to be more sensitive to environmental

concerns, at least in public statements. Evaluating the extent of

concrete changes -- rather than paper ones -- is far from easy. As

will be seen in later chapters, there have been marginal

improvements to Japanese forestry aid and loan projects in

Southeast Asia, although these changes are certainly far behind the

policy rhetoric. The gap between glossy policy declarations and

substantive procedural changes is even greater f or Japanese

corporations.

ENVIRONMENTAL IMPACT OF JAPANESE CORPORATIONS

Together Japanese government and corporate financial flows to

the South are the largest in the world. In 1987, Japanese private

investment, commercial loans, and official aid amounted to US$22.5

billion, a quarter of all Northern financing in the South.77 The

distinction between the environmental impact of government and

private economic activity is rather artificial, especially in Japan

where there are close personal links between bureaucratic,

political and business elites. Like other Northern donors,

Japanese aid is tied closely to corporate investment and trade.78

One structural reason is the custom of senior aid officials

77Forrest, “Japanese Aid and the Environment,” p.24.

78This is a key theme of the articles in Koppel and Orr, eds.Japan’s Foreign Aid.

52

Page 63: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

retiring “to lead aid consulting associations and companies working

to gain ODA contracts.”79 In the cases of the Philippines,

Indonesia and Malaysia, ODA has “lowered the cost” of Japanese

corporate investment “by providing essential infrastructure for

host economies.”8° Strategically allocated ODA has contributed to

Southeast Asia being a crucial zone of investment, led by giant

trading companies.

The label ‘trading company’ (sogo shosha) is somewhat

misleading. For the ‘big six’ -- Itochu, Mitsui, Marubeni,

Sumitomo, Mitsubishi, and Nissho Iwai -- trade is only a portion of

their activities.8’ These are complex conglomerates and all meet

“the criteria set by international specialist literature for

multinational or transnational concerns.”82 In many cases, a

trading company is the ‘core’ or the ‘command centre’ of a powerful

industrial group. These “spiders at the centre of Japan’s global

economic web. . .are intermediaries for about half the country’s

79Forrest, “Japanese Aid and the Environment,” p.26.

80Wendy Dobson, Japan in East Asia: Trading and InvestmentStrategies (Singapore: Institute of Southeast Asian Studies, 1993),p.67.

811n terms of sales, these were the six largest companies inAsia in 1993. “The Asiaweek 1000,” Asiaweek, 23 November 1994,p.50. For recent background on these corporations, see SamJameson, “Trading Companies Power Tokyo’s Economic Expansion,”Daily Yomiuri (Los Angeles Times World Report), 11 June 1994, p.8A.

82Max Eli, translation by Michael Capone, Tristam CarringtonWindo, and Charles Foot, Japan Inc.: Global strategies of Japanesetrading corporations (London: McGraw-Hill Book Company, 1990),p.103.

53

Page 64: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

exports and two-thirds of its imports.”83 These companies have

impressive con-irnunication and information systems at theirdisposal. They have sales and procurement networks invirtually every country in the world and they organizethird-country trade. [They] also play an important rolein exploiting raw material resources in other countries.They control large segments of national distribution,operate banks and lending institutions, develop newtechnologies and create new industrial sectors.84

Trading companies perform vital functions. They purchase and

distribute almost every imaginable good, provide information (in

some cases ‘better than the CIA’), act as ‘quasi banks’, invest in

joint ventures, and transport and market raw materials.85 For

Japanese business empires, trading companies provide stable

resource stocks, and sometimes take short-term losses to help

absorb fluctuations in currency exchanges and resource supplies.

This does not translate, however, into stable Southern prices since

trading companies “themselves provoke speculative moves in

international commodity markets, which they later smooth down in

Japan.”86 According to L. B. Krause and S. Sekiguchi, trading

companies “follow-the-leader.” “If one company, thinking a product

is in short supply, makes anticipatory purchases, the others will

follow suit, causing an excess of quantity requirements, rapid

escalation in prices, and market instability; ultimately, the

83”Japanese trading companies: the web rips,” The Economist, 8August 1992, p.68.

Max, Japan Inc., p.103.

85Ibid., pp.107-113.

86Francois Nectoux, and Yoichi Kuroda, Timber From The SouthSeas: An Analysis of Japan’s Tropical Environmental Impact (Gland,Switzerland: World Wildlife Fund International, 1990), p.64.

54

Page 65: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

excess must be sold back into the market, causing a collapse in

price. “

Trading companies and their subsidiaries extract, transport,

import, distribute, process, and market Southern natural resources.

They provide money and technology to start projects, and a stable

buyer to support rapid extraction. As part of a wider corporate

strategy, these companies emphasize a steady flow of huge

quantities at low profit margins. According to Francois Nectoux

and Yoichi Kuroda, as a result, “rather than concentrating on long-

term -- or even short-term -- returns of high value products,

[trading companies] are often prepared to use the ‘grab it and run’

strategy. ,,88 Understandably, these economic powerhouses create

deep environmental reverberations.

Besides a few showcase projects, multinational corporations

around the world have shown little practical interest in supporting

or funding environmental conservation.89 Japanese companies are no

exception, focusing instead on exporting environmental technology

developed to tackle pervasive pollution in the early 1970s.9° MITI

87L. B. Krause and S. Sekiguchi, “Japan in the World Economy,”in H. Patrick and H. Rosovsky, eds., Asia New Giant; How theJapanese Economy Works (Washington: The Brookings Institute, 1976),quoted in Nectoux and Kuroda, Timber From The South, p.64.

88Nectoux and Kuroda, Timber, p.64.

89Choucri, “Multinational Corporations,” p.212.

90For a discussion of Japanese government policies and businessefforts to tackle industrial pollution in the 1970s, see PeterDauvergne, “Japanese Domestic Environmental Policy Making: AnExamination of the Role of the Liberal Democratic Party.” M.A.Research Essay, Ottawa, Carleton University, Department ofPolitical Science, 1991.

55

Page 66: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

predicts overseas environmental protection will become a lucrative

business and vigorously backs these corporate efforts. While there

is strong government support for environmental technology exports,

there is little, if any, pressure on Japanese companies to monitor

the environmental effects of general technology transfers.

MITI, Keidanren (Federation of Economic Organizations), and

the most powerful companies have become increasingly worried about

Japan’s corporate image as environmentalists and NGOs depict

Japanese companies as ‘eco-outlaws.’ To counter mounting criticism

of corporate environmental practices, the Japanese government,

Keidanren, and the trading companies have launched a major campaign

to ‘green’ corporate Japan.

GREENING CORPORATE JAPAN

As environmental criticism mounted in the 1980s and early

l990s, Keidanren and key trading companies counter-attacked,

creating new environmental sections, guidelines, conservation

projects, and public relations brochures. In late 1990, Keidanren

organized a ‘1% Club’, and requested member firms and individuals

to donate “one percent of their annual income to support socially

beneficial activities.”9’ In 1991, Keidanren proclaimed a Global

Environmental Charter. A year later, a Keidanren poii claimed that

70 percent of companies “had already used the charter to strengthen

91Yoichi Nakamura, “The Ecobusiness Logic,” MPO Japan-AsiaQuarterly Review 23, no. 3 (1992), p.56. Also see Tomoya Inyaku,“A Step Forward? Debt-for-Nature Swaps,” ANPO Japan-Asia QuarterlyReview 23, no. 3 (1992), pp.48.

56

Page 67: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

their ability to tackle environmental issues.”92 However, even if

this optimistic claim is accepted, the Charter has clear

weaknesses, making its ability to ‘strengthen’ anything debatable.

While it contains commendable principles, the wording is often

vague and irresolute.93 More importantly, there is no specific

enforcement mechanism. According to a Keidanren official, the

guidelines are designed to encourage companies to consider overseas

environmental factors; while compliance is ‘expected’, it is not

mandatory, and leeway is provided.94 In 1994, Keidanren reiterated

its environmental stance, calling on Japanese companies “to work to

protect the global environment” as part of “corporate

responsibility. However, despite these lofty principles,

without any means to monitor and enforce regulations, many Japanese

observers see the Charter as little more than a public relations

ploy.96

92Keidanren, Towards Preservation of the Global Environment,Tentative Translation (Tokyo: Keidanren, 27 May 1992), p.1. MITIhas also encouraged businesses to “formulate voluntary plans on theenvironment.” MITI, “Voluntary Plans for the Environment,” 12October 1992, internal document, supplied by a MITI official, April1994, p.2.

93See Keidanren, Keidanren Global Environment Charter (Tokyo:Keidanren, April 1991).

94lnterview, Global Environment Department, Keidanren, Tokyo,7 April 1994.

95Keidanren, “Keidanren Policy and Activities for 1994,”Internal document. Tentative Translation (Tokyo: Keidanren, 4January 1994), p.3.

96Many Japanese academics, NGO representatives, and evengovernment insiders are quite critical of the Charter. Interviews,Tokyo, April to July 1994. Besides developing the Charter in 1992,Keidanren also established the Nature Conservation Fund to finance

57

Page 68: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

Since the early 1990s, Japan’s six largest trading companies

have established environmental sections. These are remarkably

similar and cooperate closely, perhaps to increase communication

and maximize resources, perhaps, more cynically, to minimize

competition and avoid a costly race to be the most ‘environmentally

friendly’. Mitsubishi’s Environmental Affairs Department is

typical. According to a spokesman, it has three aims: to raise the

environmental consciousness of employees; to contribute to

environmental projects in developing countries; and to share

Japanese knowledge and experience of environmental protection while

being careful to sell appropriate technology.97 All of the

environmental departments have developed environmental guidelines,

though like the Keidanren Charter there is far more flowery

language than concrete procedures.98 Besides these guidelines, the

largest trading companies have modestly increased funding for

environmental projects in the South and for research in Japanese

universities. Some trading companies have also instituted

environmental reviews. For example, at Itochu the Global

Environment Department evaluates a proposal when there is concern

nature conservation projects, particularly in tropical rainforests. Though commendable, the amount distributed is stillrelatively small. In its first year, the Fund supplied 100 millionyen to projects in Palau, Sulawesi, Tanzania, Ecuador and Vietnam.Keidanren, “Keidanren Nature Conservation Fund Makes First Pledgeto Conservation Projects,” internal document (Tokyo: Keidanren,undated, acquired by the author April 1994).

This Department was created in 1990. Interview, MitsubishiCorporation, Environmental Affairs Department, Tokyo, 5 April 1994.

98For example, see Marubeni, “Guidelines on GlobalEnvironmental Issues,” internal document (Tokyo: Marubeni, 1991)

58

Page 69: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

it may harm the environment. However, the process and criteria are

vague and there is no reliable evidence that proposals are ever

rejected on environmental grounds.99 Starting in FY1994, Marubeni

plans to conduct an annual review of the environmental impact of

its business activities,100 although like Itochu, the criteria and

process are opaque.

A vital function of the new environment departments is to

improve corporate images. According to corporate representatives,

Japan’s wealth, powerful public relations sections of Western M[\TCs,

the tendency among the international community to avoid criticizing

developing states, and a Japanese cultural proclivity to accept

criticism have all contributed to an unbalanced, simplistic, even

inaccurate picture of the environmental record of Japanese

corporations)0’ One example is a 1993 New York Times

advertisement by the Rainforest Action Network that claims

Mitsubishi is destroying tropical forests and calls for a boycott

of their products.’°2 Through a worldwide publicity campaign,

meetings with NGOs, distributing information packages, and

99A spokesman was unable to provide a single example of aproject rejected for environmental reasons. Interview, Departmentof Global Environment, Itochu Corporation, Tokyo, 12 April 1994.For details on Itochu’s environmental guidelines and theenvironmental management and assessment system, see Itochu. “GlobalEnvironment Problem and Itochu Corporation,” internal document(Tokyo: Department of Global Environment, 30 November 1993).

‘°°Marubeni, Marubeni Corporation: Annual Report 1993 (Tokyo:Marubeni, 1993), p.35.

‘°‘This point was most cogently made by an official atKeidanren, Tokyo, 7 April 1994.

102New York Times, Monday, 10 May 1993.

59

Page 70: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

responding to letters, the trading companies are trying to

counteract what they consider unjustified and outrageous

allegations 1O3

Japanese companies have generally avoided investment or

research in reforestation since primary forests have provided

immediate and abundant high-quality tropical logs while

reforestation is expensive, demands long-term commitments and

planning, and profits are unpredictable. Nevertheless, the effort

to improve Japan’s corporate environmental image -- coupled with

some government financial and technical support -- has produced a

few small reforestation projects.’°4 There is also some support

for research in tropical reforestation. In 1991, nine private

enterprises, in conjunction with the Ministry of Agriculture,

Forestry and Fisheries, established the Research Association for

Reforestation of Tropical Forest (RETROF) with a five-year mandate.

RETROF receives half its funding from private companies and half

from the government. It coordinates, reviews, and advises specific

corporate projects.’°5 It is designed to transfer Japanese

knowledge and technology to tropical reforestation projects,

‘°3Based on interviews at the Environment Departments ofMitsubishi, Marubeni, Nissho Iwal, Sumitomo, and Itochu, Tokyo,April-June, 1994. Also see Nissho-Iwai, “Environment 21: NisshoIwai Corp,” internal document (Tokyo: Environmental 21 Division,Nissho-Iwai, 12 February 1991).

‘°4There are government plans to increase assistance for largescale reforestation in degraded areas. Government of Japan,National Action Plan for Agenda 21, internal document supplied bya MITI official (Tokyo: Government of Japan, January 1994), p.62

‘°5lnterv±ews, Senior officials, RETROF, Tokyo, 27 April 1994.

60

Page 71: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

especially for developing mixed species plantations.106 Despite

token corporate conservation projects and research on tropical

reforestation, as we will see in later chapters, the impact of

Japanese corporate research and investment in reforestation --

driven more by a desire to generate favourable publicity than by a

desire to support sustainable commercial timber operations -- is

limited.

The Japanese government has been criticized for ignoring, or

even encouraging, destructive corporate environmental practices.

The new Environment Law addresses the role of the government in

monitoring the impact on the environment of overseas corporations.

Article 35, section 2 states:

The State shall make efforts to take necessary measures e.g.providing information to corporations, so that thecorporations can properly consider global environmentalconservation etc. in the areas outside Japan where thesecorporations conduct their businesses.’07

The impact of this article is not yet clear. The Environment Law

has no enforcement clause, and the example of “providing

information to corporations” is weak. At a minimum, it sends a

signal to corporations to pay attention to environmental factors.

At a maximum, it could provide a future means to require

corporations to follow stricter overseas environmental

a

‘°6RETROF, “Research Association For Reforestation of TropicalForest,” internal document (Tokyo: RETROF, October 1991).

107Government of Japan, The Basic Environment Law, Law No. 91,1993, Government of Japan, effective 19 November 1993.

61

Page 72: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

regulations.’°8 But this seems unlikely. Moreover, even if the

Japanese government starts to monitor and regulate corporations, it

would still leave untouched the critical impact of wasteful

consumption, low consumer and export prices, import barriers, and

the residual consequences of past practices.’°9

CONCLUS ION

In sum, the new Environment Law, the creation of environmental

guidelines and departments for loan and aid agencies, and

environmental aid demonstrate that the Japanese government

recognizes the need to address overseas environmental problems.

Yet there is more rhetoric than substance. The new law, and OECF,

EXIM Bank, and JICA guidelines are vague and non-binding.

Environmental reviews are poorly coordinated, and there are no

enforcement mechanisms, transparent procedures, or concrete

penalties. As well, environmental aid is not clearly defined. A

portion is merely a reclassification of convntional projects

rather than a substantial reallocation of funds. As a result, so

far the bulk has been in yen loans and primarily funded water and

sewage systems. Overseas environmental assistance is further

undermined by a fractured administration dominated by economic

‘°8lnterview with one of the drafters of the New BasicEnvironment Law, Environment Agency, Global Environment Department,Tokyo, 9 June 1994.

‘°9The Japanese government and trading companies havesporadically mentioned the importance of these factors for tropicaltimber management. But, as the final chapter demonstrates, theseare superficial gestures with little practical impact on SoutheastAsia’s forests.

62

Page 73: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

interests. Despite marginal increases in input, the Environment

Agency, while an earnest supporter of better overseas environmental

guidelines, still has relatively little influence. The Forestry

Agency has not aggressively tackled environmental issues, and

instead cautiously promotes tree plantations, a transfer of

silvicultural expertise, and expanded trade and consumption.

Meanwhile, MITI has staked out environmental turf to promote

technology transfers and business initiatives. Given this context,

it is not surprising that even though Japan relies heavily on

natural resource imports, conservation, reforestation, and resource

management are peripheral to government overseas environmental

policies.

Beginning in the early 1990s, the private sector, led by

Keidanren and the major trading companies, counter-attacked

domestic and world environmental critics, producing a deluge of

flowery policy statements, corporate brochures, and public

advertisements. Although a tiny amount of money has shifted to

environmental research and showcase projects, these cosmetic

policies contain few concrete mechanisms or sanctions to control

overseas environmental impacts. Finally, while new government and

corporate environmental policies only provide marginal benefits for

Southern resource management, they serve an inauspicious function,

creating a diversionary smokescreen that obscures the far more

important consequences of Japanese wasteful consumption, low prices

for raw materials, unsustainable purchasing practices, import

barriers, and the residual effects of past practices. During 1994

63

Page 74: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

discussions, government and business leaders pushed conversations

away from these crucial factors and toward the content of the new

environment law, the ‘comprehensive’ environmental guidelines, the

‘extensive’ investments in environmental projects, the

‘influential’ environmental departments, and perhaps most

consistently, Japan’s ‘impressive’ environmental aid. In short,

the rhetoric enveloping Japanese overseas activities undeniably

shifted in the early l990s; but the accompanying policies are too

diluted, inconsistent, and marginal to alter the nucleus of Japan’s

shadow ecology, and only minor, peripheral changes have occurred.

Before turning to a specific analysis of the impact of Japan’s

shadow ecology on timber management in the Philippines, Indonesia,

and Borneo Malaysia, the next chapter outlines a framework to

understand the politics of resource management in Southeast Asia.

64

Page 75: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

Chapter Three

A MODEL OF RESOURCE MANAGEMENT IN CLIENTELIST STATES

The allocation and management of natural resources in

developing countries has gained increased attention in the last

decade as worldwide scarcity and environmental catastrophe loom.

Forestry management and the causes of tropical deforestation have

received particular attention as loss of these trees has been

linked to siltation, erosion, flooding, and most ominously, global

warming. Most explanations of forestry problems have focused on

technical or economic factors, the content of specific policies,

the role of international organizations and finance,’ and the

impact of poverty and population growth. Surprisingly little

attention has been given to the role of domestic political forces

in the South, even though in many situations this appears to be a

key factor.2

‘As noted in chapter one, while scholars have analyzed linksbetween multilateral financial institutions and forestrymismanagement, there has been little attention given to theenvironmental impact of peaceful interaction between two states.Small portions of this chapter are from Peter Dauvergne, “Patronclient Politics and Natural Resource Allocation and Management inthe Third World: A Case Study of the Timber Industry In TheMalaysian States of Sabah and Sarawak,” Unpublished Course Paper,Department of Political Science, University of British Columbia,1992.

2Environmentalists sometimes point to political corruption asa key factor in resource mismanagement. But this has generallytaken the form of accusations, without any reference to concretepolitical conditions or societal arrangements in these countries.Until recently, politics has been ignored in much of the academicanalysis on environmental change. This is discussed by MichaelRedclift, Sustainable Development: Exploring the Contradictions(London: Methuen, 1987); and Adams, Green Development. One

65

Page 76: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

By paying more attention to the nature of the state and to

policy implementation, this chapter builds on the patron-client

model to understand links between Southern politics and resource

management. I argue that ‘modern’ patron-client networks interact

with political executives, bureaucracies, courts, and militaries to

lower Southeast Asian state capacity to enforce resource

regulations. The first part of this chapter sketches the main

features and analytical advantages of a patron-client framework.

Then, after outlining the evolution of patron-client ties in

Southeast Asia, I borrow ideas from Joel Migdal’s work on state

society relations to explain how these modern relations undermine

state capacity. This creates a model of resource management in

clientelist states.

PATRON-CLIENT MODEL OF ASSOCIATION

The patron-client model was initially developed by

anthropologists to explain traditional village-level, dyadic power

relations. The anthropological patron-client model is a personal

exchange relationship between two persons with unequal status,

power or resources. The higher ranked person provides protection

and benefits (often material) to a lower ranked person in exchange

for loyalty and assistance, including personal services. Although

the client usually benefits less than the patron, this reciprocity

distinguishes patron-client relations from relations of pure

exception is Piers Blaikie, The Political Economy of Soil Erosionin Developing Countries (New York: Longrnan, 1985).

66

Page 77: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

PL

IJH

H—

:‘tI

rtU

I-C)

I-ci

UH

Cl)

dQ

C)W

ct

CD

OH

QP

JO

CDCD

H-

-QCD

CDCl)

H-

0‘D

HrtQ

1Cl)

C)CD

Cl)H

(QC

1ci

frhCD

H-

i—

JCi

)H

-t-

’CD

H-

hCl)

Cl)CD

H-

Fd

Cl)

(IO

C)

‘.D

(D

QI-

H-

-Cl)

ciCD

c-FH

0CD

C)Q

C)

H-H

CD

Hj

pj

0H

-C)

IIC)

H-

H-

CDh

HO

HH

-SC

)

H-

ciH

Cl)

Cl0

ci

0I.<

lH

-p

1C

DH

JI

Cl)

‘-<

H-

U)ci

C)H

ci

CDCD

ci

C-F

H-

HCl)

H-

CDi-P

)H

CD

Cl)l-

Fd

CDCl

)H

-CD

Ct

C)Ci

)0

Ct

‘ti

(1)0

H-

CDCD

H-

ci

Hd

3ciC

DH

p)

CDCl

)-

IIci

C)0

Cl)

Cl)

H-

CDH

-Cl)

CD

ciP

)H

-Cl

)H

-<LQ

CDC

D.

<C

lCD

H-

iCD

C)CD

U)H

U)H

HH

-C

DC)

CDw

Cl)

-U

)•

ciCD

U)C

DU

)H

CDM

iH

ici

—C

DQ

H‘-

HCl

CFH

-H

MM

CD

CD

-H

-U

)ci

H-

ci

I-li

‘<CD

0O

CI)

ct(0

0H

-CD

i-c-F

Cl)C)

H-j

CD

ic-t

CF

H-

c-II

i<h

HCD

F-h

P)

U)0

CD

U)

<CD

-Cl)

HCD

,U)

H-c

-FH

-•

•H

<H

-C)

C)CD

Clci

_

CDç-t•

Cl)

ciH

-c-F

pc-F

cici

1H

CD

’<0(D

c-H

p.

HC

D(C

ll-,

0-

ci

CD

PH

-0

Ht

;:,i

•jp

.0

ci

CDH

U)0

Cl)p

.I

ClJ

CD

p.H

HH

I1

CD0

H-

HI

HH

Ct

HCl)

C)(.Q

H-

Cl)p

.H

H

H-

wU

)C

J)

p)ci

CDC

DU)

.

p.

HC

lCD

p.

Cl)CD

HP

).

()

Cli

icH

-<

H

cF:

ci

g)

HH

U)

dM

iCD

ci

Cl’ci

ClCD

CDCl)

CD(Q

HC

lii

Cl)

C)H

8Cl1

CDC

lH

--r

CD

Hi

ici

Cp

.Cli

Cl)CD

CDCD

HH

Cl)

C1(

1)1

HM

iCD

-CD

p.

CDCD

0d

CD -.

Cl)1-t

iH

-H

-(1

)H

-CD

c-FCD

Cl)P)

N-P

c-FU)

H-

iC)

p)

Ctp

)H

n‘-

:3b

CP

H-

H<

:3C

DC

lc-

P)ci

CDci

Cl)

Cl)

Irj

H H-

H()

C1

c-C

DH

-Cl)

0CD

i.<1C

l)

brr

Cl)0

Cl

Cl)Cl)

CDp

.

CD

H-

11

P)H

HH

CDH

FlH

i

:3Fl

U)P

)C)H

-ciql

HH

CDH

-CD

bci

CDH

HC

DC

lH

r-C

l)H

-CCD

Cl)CD

CDH

-H

-ci

Cl)H

-H-s

H-ci

C)ci

0CD

I.Q

Cl

CD

iM

i0Fl

Cl)0

ciCD

ciH

cii

Cl)

fl0:3

HCl)

Fl

HU)

ciCD

Cl)ci

CD-

Cl)<

FlI

Cl)

H-

H-C

Dd

H-

-0

Cl)Fl

FlFl

3H

H-

H-

Cl

CD

IH-H

HH

-(l)b

0CD

CD

:3(0

(0

<0

CDci

U)ci

Hp

.Cl)

Hi

c-FH

-HciC

D-

•U)

Flci

Hi

H-

ciCD

HFl

HH

-CD

-CD

H-

Hi

H-

Cl)

iU

)C

Dci

FlC

DC

DCl)

ciH

-H

--

H-

U)H

-w

CD

II-

HH

-C

DC

l)M

,•

i—]

CDCD

H-

0C

l0

ci1<

1Cl)

H-@

iC)

Cl)

ClM

iF

lCl)

3F-

hCl)

H-C

rci

ci

H(.Q

ICD

U)0

iCl)

U)(

DC

D<

CD

Cl)C)

ciU)

H-

Cl)

00

0-

M-C

l’-<

HU)

CD0

p.

-IQ

CDCD

H0

Mi

Hi

Page 78: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

way of understanding client action is to view their strategies as

“interest-maximizing rather than risk-minimizing.”7 In other

words, clients enter into patron-client relationships because it is

the most efficient and effective means to improve their socio

economic position.

Building dyadic alliances is relatively easy since “it

involves the simple trading of favours and not the more difficult

task of furthering collective goals.”8 With clients eager to

improve their lifestyle, patrons eager to increase their power, and

alliances fairly easy to form, large groups develop based on dyadic

patron-client exchange (sometimes called clientelism) . Political

scientists in the 1960s and l970s extrapolated the anthropological

model to understand these groups. A patron-client cluster is a

patron’s immediate following, perhaps twenty to thirty people. A

patron-client pyramid comprises not only a patron’s direct clients

but as well the immediate following of these clients. (It is

assumed that one person can be both a client and a patron.) A

patron-client network is a web of patron-client pyramids linked

together by a common patron. Alliances of patron-client clusters,

pyramids, or networks can create factions.9

“Political Clientelism In Japan: The Case of “S”, Asian Survey 28(April 1988), pp.471-483. Cheng argues that the Japanesebureaucracy contains significant patron-client relations despitethe security and prosperity of Japanese bureaucrats.

7jean C. 0±, “Communism and Clientelism: Rural Politics inChina,” World Politics 37, no. 2 (January 1985), p.263.

8Landé, “The Dyadic Basis of Clientelism,” p.xv.

9j. Scott, “Patron-Client Politics,” pp.96-97.

68

Page 79: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

Extrapolating dyadic patron-client relations to these larger

concepts has been criticized for over-stretching a micro-level

model to understand macro-level phenomena.’0 It is in fact quite

difficult, if not impossible, to ‘find’ and accurately describe the

dyadic components of patron-client political structures. To

overcome this problem, rather than taking on the laborious task of

determining the specific composition of patron-client clusters,

pyramids, and networks, it is more useful to focus on informal,

personal, reciprocal, and asymmetrical “patterns of interaction and

exchange.” Emphasizing a specific type of exchange relationship

rather than structure accepts that these ties can vary in their

intensity, duration, and type of resources involved. Although

expanding a micro-level model has unavoidable risks, there are a

number of advantages, especially for understanding political forces

that shape natural resource management in the South.

ADVANTAGES OF PATRON-CLIENT ANALYSIS

The patron-client model is not a grand theory capable of

explaining everything -- rather, as a middle-range perspective, it

‘°See Robert Kaufman, “The Patron-Client Concept and Macro-Politics: Prospects and Problems,” Comparative Studies in Societyand History 16, no. 1 (June 1974), pp.284-308.

“S.N. Eisenstadt and Luis Roniger, “The Study of Patron-ClientRelations and Recent Developments in Sociological Theory,” in S.N.Eisenstadt and Rene Lemarchand, eds. Political Clientelism,Patronage and Development (London: Sage Publications, 1981), p.276.Also see Eisenstadt and Lemarchand, “Introduction,” in Ibid., p.2.

69

Page 80: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

is confined to one particular set of political relationships.12

This allows greater detail and nuance for analyzing how domestic

politics shape natural resource use than is possible, for example,

with world system theory or dependency frameworks.’3 According to

Christopher Clapham, it is “one of a number of middle-range

concepts through which the possibility of a comparative social

science may -- however dimly and elusively -- be glimpsed.”4

The patron-client model enables the analyst to move beyond

formal institutions, groups and policies and towards informal power

relations, fluid associations and personal exchange. This helps

account for dynamic and sudden change and for political systems

characterized “by a lack of clear dividing lines between political

groups and a great deal of shifting and switching among peripheral

group members.”5 It also overcomes problems of many economic

studies of natural resource management in the South that stress

impersonal market-based exchange. As well, it helps explain why a

‘2For a discussion of the trend toward, and merits of, middle-range theory, see Howard J. Wiarda, “Toward the Future: Old and NewDirections in Comparative Politics,” in Howard J. Wiarda, ed. NewDirections in Comrarative Politics, revised ed. (Boulder: WestviewPress, 1991), pp.221-250.

‘3The eminent scholar of world system theory is InimanuelWallerstein. See Irnmanuel Wallerstein, The Modern World System (NewYork: Academic Press, 1976). For an overview of the dependencyapproach, see Tony Smith, “The Dependency Approach,” in Wiarda,ed., New Directions, revised ed., pp.118-130.

‘4Christopher Clapham, “Clientelism and the state,” inChristopher Clapham, ed., Private Patronage and Public Power:Political Clientelism in the Modern State (London: Frances Pinter,1982), p.30.

‘5Landé, “The Dyadic Basis of Clientelism,” p.xix.

70

Page 81: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

bureaucrat’s power can be based more on personal connections than

on a formal position or why a political party may resemble an

uncoordinated gathering of powerful leaders and their loyal

followers.’6 Many political models are constrained by their focus

on formal, institutional arrangements, and are unable to explain

processes that occur outside this framework.17 This can be a

serious limitation since, as James Scott notes, “bureaucratic

political parties in Southeast Asia are often thoroughly penetrated

by informal patron-client networks that underlie the formal

structure of authority.”8 By focusing on informal rather than

formal relations, important insights can be gained into

distribution patterns, including appointments to bureaucratic

positions, awarding of government contracts, and allocation of

state revenues. Formal structures, however, cannot be ignored when

examining patron-client relations. At the very least, “formal

structures are relevant to patron-client systems, if only because

they provide the critical resources necessary to build and sustain

such a system.”9

Patron-client analysis accounts for the importance of

traditional relations of power and concepts of legitimacy and

authority. It provides continuity with the past and considers

indigenous values and beliefs as well as contemporary variations.

‘6J. Scott, ItpatronCljent Politics,” p.92.

‘7Structural-functionalism is especially prone to this problem.

‘8J. Scott, “Patron-Client Politics,” p.92.

‘9Kaufman, “The Patron-Client Concept,” p.301.

71

Page 82: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

Rene Lemarchand argues that since the patron-client model “cuts

across both ‘traditional’ and ‘modern’ referents”, it has a

“heuristic value generally missing from the conceptual arsenal of

either ‘modern’ or ‘traditional’ polities, [and] it directs

attention to processes of adjustment between traditional and modern

patterns of behaviour, expectations, and normative orientations to

politics which might otherwise go unnoticed.”2° Traditional power

arrangements and concepts of authority provide ‘modern’ patron-

client links, which would in many countries be viewed as simple

corruption, with a certain degree of legitimacy. Corruption

entails a legal violation which is perceived as illegitimate by the

community and thus contributes to a loss of authority. Patron-

client exchange may sometimes violate formal law, but its roots in

tradition mean that even when it is labelled ‘corruption’, there is

not necessarily any loss of authority. In fact, ignoring patronage

duties may even contribute to a greater loss of legitimacy and

authority than violating formal laws.

Patron-client analysis accounts for vertical links from urban

to rural areas which cut across class, ethnicity, language and

religious differences. Membership is based on ties to the leader

and is specific to each link; it is not based on shared horizontal

ties among followers. Models that isolate ethnic, religious or

class groups have difficulty explaining intra-group politics and

cooperation between segments of different groups. For natural

20Rene Lemarchand, “Political Clientelism and Ethnicity inTropical Africa: Competing Solidarities in Nation Building,”merican Political Science Review 66, no. 1 (March 1972), p.68.

72

Page 83: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

resource issues such as timber, patron-client analysis points to

the important cross-cutting ties between central financing,

ownership and control, and local contractors, managers, and

workers. As well, in countries with competitive elections, a focus

on patron-client politics directs attention to a partial vertical

redistribution of natural resource profits as central party members

‘buy’ rural votes.2’ Of course, not all patterns of political

behaviour are reducible to patron-client relations.22 Ethnicity,

class, religion, language, nationalism, party ideology, and

central-regional relations are just some of the other factors that

exist alongside patron-client links. Depending on the timing,

situation, and specific context, the impact of patron-client

relations will vary. However, focusing on patron-client ties is

particularly useful for understanding logging in Southeast Asia

since these have historically been, and continue to be, the

dominant force shaping timber allocation and management.

Finally, the patron-client model is especially useful for

understanding cooperation between individuals and groups in times

of peace and stability. (In contrast, class or ethnic-based models

have generally been limited to analyzing conflict.) It effectively

explains the emergence, transformation and continuance of groups

whose membership is not based on shared horizontal characteristics

but where people are linked vertically, sharing few common

21Anthony Hall, “Patron-Client Relations: Concepts and Terms,”in Schmidt, et al., eds., Friends, Followers and Factions, p.512.

22Lemarchand rightly stresses this point, Lemarchand,“Political Clientelism,” pp.68-90.

73

Page 84: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

characteristics, often of different status, and perhaps not even

knowing each other since the common link is personal ties to the

leader. The emphasis on cooperation, however, does not preclude an

understanding of conflict. Robert Kaufman notes that while

“patron-client exchange is premised on hierarchical distributions

of power and resources, the concept simultaneously allows for (and

at times suggests) the possibility of intense conflict between

narrowly based, shifting patron-client clusters and pyramids.”23

The concept of factions is particularly valuable for analyzing

conflict between patron-client units, or conflict within, for

example, an ethnic group.

Despite these advantages, for much of the 1980s and early

l990s, relatively little has been written on patron-client

relations.25 As patron-client ties evolve -- and some argue

dissipate -- many comparative politics specialists have turned to

23Kaufman, “The Patron-Client Concept,” p.286.

24Jean-Francois Medard, “The underdeveloped state in tropicalAfrica: Political clientelism or neo-patr±monialism?” in Clapham,ed., Private Patronage, p.168.

25There are a few recent studies. For example, see JonathanFox, “The Difficult Transition From Clientelism To Citizenship,”World Politics 46 (January 1994), pp.151-184; the collection ofarticles in Luis Roniger and Ayse Gunes-Ayata, eds. Democracy.Clientelism and Civil Society (Boulder: Lynne Rienner Publishers,1994), pp.1-18; Carlene J. Edie, Democracy by Default: Dependencyand Clientelism in Jamaica (London: Lynne Rienner Publishers,1991); Robert Gay, “Community Organization and Clientelist Politicsin Contemporary Brazil: A Case Study from Suburban Rio de Janeiro,”International Journal of Urban and Regional Research 14 (December1990), pp.648-666; Eliphas Mukonoweshuro, “Ethnicity, Class andClientelism in Sierra Leone Politics: A Methodological Critique,”Plural Societies 20 (September 1990), pp.65-91; and Cheng,“Political Clientelism in Japan,” pp.471-483.

74

Page 85: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

other analytic tools. Yet, these relations are still a key feature

of many Southern states. Luis Roniger writes: “While it would be

absurd to predict that certain types of relationships --

friendship, for instance -- would disappear following development,

this has been the main argument regarding clientelism (in both

cases, it would seem more reasonable to expect changes in structure

rather than their natural demise) In Southeast Asia, patron-

client ties remain extensive, though there are important structural

differences between ‘traditional’ and ‘modern’ relations.

MODERN PATRON-CLIENT RELATIONS IN SOUTHEAST ASIA

Traditional patron-client relations in Southeast Asia have

been altered by evolving economic, social and political

circumstances, especially during the shift from colonialism to

independence. Traditional relations were generally characterized

by highly affective ties based on kinship, village, or

neighbourhood bonds. A patron typically relied on personal skills,

wealth (largely through private control of local resources), and

sometimes connections to more powerful patrons. Loyalty,

obligation, honour and non-material rewards supplemented material

exchanges. These ties involved face-to-face contact and multiple

kinds of exchange.

Colonialism, the spread of market capitalism in the twentieth

century, urbanization, and the growth of the state over the last

26Lu±s Roniger, Hierarchy and Trust in Modern Mexico and Brazil(New York: Praeger, 1990), p.xiii

75

Page 86: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

fifty years or so have contributed to important changes to patron-

client relations. Exploiting political power to accumulate wealth

has a long tradition in insular Southeast Asia. Monarchs taxed

peasants and controlled commerce, using these funds to reward loyal

followers. Colonialism and global economic links greatly increased

the economic power and scope of the state, making it a key source

of patronage. After independence states continued to expand. In

countries like the Philippines, as the size of the state increased,

“access to the state machinery became more important than ever for

the creation of wealth.”28 As a result, the state became a key

source of material incentives to bind modern patron-client ties,

including funds, licences, and career opportunities. State

officials have also been absorbed by patron-client networks,

ignoring state rules in exchange for presents, bribes, or some

other particularistic concession. This extensive state patronage

has fostered larger and larger patron-client networks in Southeast

Asia. As Gordon Means notes, the state “provides the institutional

framework for the extension of patron-client networks beyond the

immediate circle of individual loyalties and friendships.”29

27James Rush, The Last Tree: Reclaiming the Environment inTropical Asia (New York: The Asia Society, 1991), pp.30-32.

28Paul D. Hutchcroft, “Oligarchs and Cronies in the PhilippineState: The Politics of Patrimonial Plunder,” World Politics 42(April 1991), p.423.

29Gordon P. Means, Malaysian Politics: The Second Generation(Singapore: Oxford University Press, 1991), pp.298-99. In thecontext of Malaysia, Means claims that: “By the time of Dr.Mahathir, the patronage system had not only grown enormously, butit included many intermediate layers of middlemen in a moreextensive and institutional system of rewarding loyalty and

76

Page 87: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

Patron-client exchange is now more specific and less personal.

Patrons are less likely to maintain regular contact with a client

and more likely to exchange tangible goods, such as a licence for

a ‘political contribution.’ As a result, modern patron-client

relations are also based less on loyalty, obligation and honour.3°

Instead, patronage is a crucial means of building ‘loyal’ followers

(at least temporarily). This is reinforced by immigration and

domestic migration to large cities and towns that has produced

large numbers of people who are most efficiently turned into

‘loyal’ followers using material incentives. For this reason

political patrons often need to provide money, gifts, and

government jobs to build power and maintain prestige and

legitimacy. In areas with competitive elections this has been

encouraged further as patron-client relations have become “closely

linked to the national [or state] level with jobs, cash, and petty

favours flowing down the network, and votes or support flowing

upward.”3’ These trends contributed by the 1970s to “a

comparatively large ‘fairweather’ periphery, a comparatively small

core following, and a less ‘constant’ patron as well.”32

political support.” Ibid., p.305.

30Foreign corporations often supply a key ingredient for modernpatron-client ties: money -- but foreign business executives,including the Japanese, are generally not directly involved inpatron-client exchange relations.

3’Scott, “Patron-Client Politics,” p.105. Scott does note,however, that “in the midst of this change, old style patronsthrive.” Ibid.

32Ibid., p.107.

77

Page 88: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

Patron-client connections have become increasingly unstable as

the size of patron-client networks has grown, as personal contact

has decreased, as clients have lost their sense of obligation, and

as the number of ‘fairweather’ followers has increased. This

instability is natural since “those on the periphery of the patron-

client network become alienated and are cross-pressured between

their pursuit of immediate but meagre benefits (in relation to

other more favoured clients) and their aspirations for improved

opportunities with a new winning coalition.”33 Despite these

changes, the personal and asymmetrical nature of exchange, the lack

of formal-legal contracts or institutional ties, and the reciprocal

expectations make modern patron-client exchange significantly

different from market exchange.34 These exchange relations are a

dominant characteristic of the societies of Southeast Asia. As

patron-client structures evolve, and with the increase in the size

and power of Southern states over the last 50 years or so, it is

essential to understand the consequences of these clientelist

societies on the state. Neo-patrimonial studies are one attempt to

33Means, Malaysian Politics, p.317. The inherent instabilityof modern ties makes it virtually impossible to categorize andspecify the membership of different patron-client networks -- amonumental task even in ideal circumstances -- since thesecontinually dissolve and realign as patrons die or lose control ofkey resources.

34mis is a broad generalization. A more detailed descriptionof modern patron-client relations in Indonesia, Malaysia, and thePhilippines is provided in chapters four to six. For background ontraditional patron-client relations in Southeast Asia, see S.N.Eisenstadt and Luis Roniger, Patrons, clients and friends:Interpersonal relations and the structure of trust in society(Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1984), Indonesia, pp.122-127, and the Philippines, pp.127-130.

78

Page 89: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

give more attention to the links between the state, patronage, and

patron- client networks.

NEO- PATRIMONIAL STUDIES

Neo-patrimonial studies are rooted in Max Weber’s analysis of

traditional authority where the distinction between public and

private is obscured -- there is neither one objective law for all

nor a principle of bureaucratic impartiality. Instead, decisions

are based on “personal connections, favours, promises, and

privileges.”35 Jean-Francois Medard bluntly declares, in a

patrimonial state, “politics becomes a kind of business with two

modes of exchange: connections and money. The state is a pie that

every one wants to eat.”36 Although focusing more on a single

ruler, neo-patrimonialism points to many of the same features as

patron-clientelism -- including informal relations, particularism,

and instrumental exchange.37 For example, Paul Hutchcroft’s neo

patrimonial analysis of natural resource exploitation in the

Philippines focuses on changes to patron-client relations as access

35Max Weber, Economy and Society, ed. Guenther Roth and ClausWittich (New York: Bedminster Press, 1968), vol. 3, p.1041, quotedin Hutchcroft, “Oligarchs and Cronies,” p.415.

36Medard, “The underdeveloped state,” p.170.

37See Harold Crouch, “Patrimonialism and Military Rule inIndonesia,” World Politics 31 (July 1979), pp.571-87. Neopatrimonialism is similar to the model of a bureaucratic polity.For example, see F.W. Riggs, Thailand: The Modernization of aBureaucratic Polity (Honolulu: East-West Center Press, 1966); andJ.L.S. Girling, The Bureaucratic Polity in Modernizing Societies,Occasional Paper No. 64 (Singapore: The Institute of SoutheastAsian Studies, 1981)

79

Page 90: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

to the state has become increasingly important for collecting and

distributing patronage. In the Philippines, this has created a

state where key bureaucratic o:fficials and political leaders

(especially Ferdinand Marcos and family) plundered the natural

resources for personal gain.3 Nec—patrimonial analysis is

particularly valuable in pointing to the dominance of intrastate

factional competition over substantive policy debates in

determining the distribution of natural resources. The difference

between the patron-client model and the neo-patrimonial model is

largely a matter of emphasis,39 and patron-client analysis can be

strengthened by the empirical findings and conceptual conclusions

of nec-patrimonial studies.

Yet despite the similarity to patron-clientelism, a neo

patrimonial framework has certain drawbacks for analyzing resource

management in Southeast Asia. The model tends to overestimate the

dominance of the state and neglect significant societal constraints

to state management.4° Nec-patrimonial studies emphasize central

elites, and often point to a ‘super-patron’ as a key source of

mismanagement. Actors further down the causal chain -- such as

38See Hutchcroft, “Oligarchs and Cronies,” pp.414-450.

39Bruce Gale, Politics and Public Enterprise in Malaysia (ICualaLumpur: Eastern Universities Press Sdn. Bhd., 1981), pp.4-10.

40Neo-patrimonial studies have accurately pointed to thepervasive links between political and military patrons and businessclients as a key feature of Southeast Asian politics and animportant means for societal groups to share in the spoils ofoffice. But there have been no major nec-patrimonial studies thatexamine how these links shape state capacity to enforce rules andlaws.

80

Page 91: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

contractors, sub-contractors, and middle-level administrators --

are often neglected. On the other hand, the patron-client model

spotlights multiple levels of interaction yet still places primary

responsibility with the most powerful elites.41 Neo-patrimonial

studies also downplay the role of urban-rural links, instrumental

exchange that occurs outside of the state, and the impact of

societal structure and social resistance on state directives,

policies and goals. As a result, a neo-patrimonial framework has

difficulty explaining the resilience of pervasive patronage in

absence of, or after the fall of, a ‘super-patron’ 42 Neo

patrimonial studies, however, do have the analytical advantage of

close attention to the state as a source of patronage. To shift

the focus of the patron-client model more to the role of state

patronage, and to gain a better understanding of the consequences

of pervasive patron-clientelism on the nature of the state

itself,43 I now turn to the theoretical work of Joel Migdal.

41Michael Dove persuasively argues that elites must be heldresponsible for the destruction of tropical rain forests, even ifmany actors are involved in the actual process. Michael R. Dove,“Marketing the Rainforest: ‘Green’ Panacea or Red Herring?” Hawaii:East-West Center, No. 13, May 1994, pp.1-8.

42To help dodge this problem Hutchcroft uses the term“patrimonial features.” See Hutchcroft, “Oligarchs and Cronies,”pp.414-417.

431t is commonly accepted in the literature on state-societyrelations in Southeast Asia that state patrons channel extensivepatronage to individuals and groups in society. This is seen asthe main route for societal input into otherwise strong states.See Dwight Y. King, “Indonesia’s New Order as a BureaucraticAuthoritarian Regime: What Difference Does It Make? in BenedictAnderson and Audrey Kahin, eds., Interpreting Indonesian Politics:Thirteen Contributions To The Debate. Interim Reports Series,Publication No. 62 (New York: Cornell University, 1982), p.113; and

81

Page 92: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

PiM

iU)

PiP

CDH

-CD

H—

S

0C

DP

)0

ZC

tC

DCD

0(1)

H-

<CD

U)p3

CDCD

00

HC

DC)

CD

P)C

)U)L

HCD

C)C)

2)I-i

Hi

P)H

-H

i2’

Cr2)U

)P)H

-C

rOC

ril

2)U)

H-

Cr

piC

rC

r0

HH

-CD

0C

rU)t

YC

I)U

)CD

hC

DC

rCD

CDH

-J

H-

I-CD

H-

iII

2’

0H

-H

-C

rC

rP

)H

-C

rCD

Cr

CD2)

C)1

Cr

CD0

HrtX

0H

H-i

-JP

)p

,H-F

-’

0H

-k

<CD

CDH

CDU)

2)U)

00

H-

<3

CD

H-

HH

-C

DrtN

H-i

CDH

IIH

iI-

ti:i

U)‘1

<‘-

0IQ

CtC

DIQ

U)D

CrU

)CD

CD

P.,C

D2)P

’U)

C)C

r1

H-

tO

H-

i..C

)H

PiCD

-CD

-‘

2)C

t0

(P)

C)

2J:Q

DC

DH

iC

rU)

HCD

U)CD

0C

rH

HP

)H-

H‘—

U)Q

OH

-2)

CDCD

H-

L’l

—H

U)

2)—

H-•

‘.3CD

CDci

-2)

HC)

t5H

-CD

I-I

Cr

HH

CD

HH

k<

H-

0:

Cr

U)C

tt-

2)[x

jCr

CDCl

)H

--Q

CDH

-CD

‘dci-

H-H

CrC

DH

.H

-C

rC

r0

0H

-t-t

2)U

)j

IC

rH

Cr

00

iC

)HC

DC

)2)

2)CD

-‘1

CD

CD

p,C

rII

CDC

rP

‘P

)U)

Cl)

ICD

C)

HU

)C

rC

)H

Hi

H-

MCD

0pi

U)p)

Cr

Cr

N-.

Cr

CDk<

2)H

-Lx

i2)

CDC)

CD

cCD

dC

DU

)CD

pjCD

2)P

C)C

rC

rC

r-

‘C

rH

-H

-0

HC

rC)

C4

CDCD

HiC

DP

i2)

H-

CD0

Cr

2’D

ii

oC

rCD

2’Cl

)U)

-Q0

-H

HH

-H

cI

CDk

<

Cr

02’

2)p

CrU

)0

rtH

iH

-H

iU)

H-

HC

rC

rCD

H-

CD-

N2’

I2’tY

H0

<C

rH

U)2)

C)C

r2)

HC

D----C

r2)

CD

H-

2)CL

)H

-0

Cr

QH

-C

r0

2)C

rC)

H-

Hi

H-

H-

H-

CDH

Cr

00

HC

D2

)C

)2

)H

f)

Hp

JI.C

)CD

Hi

2’H

-CD

CDIi

Cr

CDH

Cl)

2)IC

rH

0H

-Cr.

U)

CDIH

-C

)C

)C

)H

Cr

2)0

H-

Cr

C)H

-lo

CD

H-0P0.H

-C

tCD

0CD

Cl)

H-

H-

CDC)

U)H

i2)

CrC

DH

-C

rH

-H

iCD

CDC

r—

0D

C)

HCD

U)H

-d

H-

iU)

2)Cl

)“

0C

rCD

0CD

Cr

0C)

pjCD

Cr

Cr

do

CD

U)-

Cr

HH

-2)

Cr

ii0

Ci)

CDH

-C)

Cr

Cr

H-

0CD

0‘

CD

Cr

Cr

CD

iiU)

C)P

)2)

It1diD

H

2’2’

H-

U)H

-ti

2’CD

CDCD

HH

rJ

Cr

Cr

CDC)

2)Ii

-H

-ui

iIi

U)0

Cr

Cr

H-

H-

HCD

U)ii

H-

H-

H-

H-

Cr

0Ii

u,H

CD

HC

rH

-U

)2)

CDC

rC

rH

-C

rH

H-

U)H

-(.Q

H-

2)H

iH

0t-

QCD

Cr°

Cl)

IiC)

01

Cr

Cr

Cr

0H

iP)

.Q

H-

CD0

H-

2)‘-<

CDC

rC

ri

1-CD

Cr

2)U)

HH

-0

CDH

CD

H-

2)C)

2)2)

Cr

Mi

CDN

Crpi

2)

2)C

r2)

H-

U)2)

2)C

DH

dC

rH

-C

rH

-CD

i2)

2)C

rO

Cr

IiIH

-p

2)C

)0

HCD

Cr

Cr

k<

H-

CD2)

HH

-0

Cn<

C)C

DO

CI)

H-

C)C)

piCD

U)2)

Cr

H•

OH

OC

DIto

H-C

D<

CDC

rCD

U)CD

0C

)tiC

I)IC

rU)

H-

Ii0

Cr

IiC

r2)

C)H

CDU)

<Ii

U)H

-U)

Cm

li<

0H

CDi

Cr

HC)

H-

CDC

rH

-H

-H

-CD

CD

H-2

)I0

CrC

D2)

U)(

CDH

-1H

-CD

CrC

rCrI

0H

k<

U)-

CDIi

2)C

rC

rCD

9)2)

2)0

C)C

rU)

Cr

2)•

U)—

HiC

D<

-•

U)-<

0C

r1

CDU)

CDH

Page 93: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

H Cl) 0 CD CD

C)(Q

1H

P1P1

H3

I-P1

f-Ff-

FP1

Ci)

0H

-3

çFCD

0c-

FQ

P1H

-H

HH

•II

CDCD

P1p1

0H

-CD

Ci)H

-f-F

C)f-F

P1(

0H

-C)

HH

-CD

HO

1<

(Ci<

Cl)Ci)

ct

P1CD

Ci)f-F

Hf

H0

CDCD

HC

DCj)

Cl)

[CD

CDH

C’)(

Hpj

p1Cl

)

P1j

H-

H-

f-I

3d

f-F

H-

oc-

C’)

HP1

CDrr

CI)

gH

-f-

I(i)

p1O

CDCl)

f-I

Ci)H

oCi)

CDP1

H-

00

jf-F

C)c-i

-H

tI)CD

(Ciw

iCD

(CiP1

H-

H CDH

P10

H(

CDCD

H-

f-FM

P1°

gCD

w(C

iP1

IQH

-P1

HCD

H-

0pJ

(CiP1

l))II

fr’f-

Ci)

HQ

H-

IH

C)C)

NP1

CDCD

p

oH

-0

P1H

df-

Ii-j

H-

o(Ci

Hf-F

-CD

0f-F

Hf-F

<CD

()CD

P1CD

Cl)0

CI)

OCD

-C)

33

H-

Cl)o

Hf-F

Ci)

CDH

-Ci

)f-F

3H

--

‘-P<

P1p

c-F

(DPj

f-Fj

P1P1

(CiH

CD‘

CD:i

HCI

)H

-P1

pN

H0

ct

P1w

CI)

I-t

f-I

f-FH

-f-F

0P1

P1(Ci

3(C

i-<

Cl)

00

H t3 H 0 H 0 ‘-P CD H-

H-

H-

H ‘-P P1-•

.Q

‘C

•-;

HH

-tT

CJ)

IPH

cF

1191

OH

-

13

-

Cl)

O—

1C

)I

WH

-°C

DC

DH

-H

CD0 C

i)H

P1C

l)13cF

s1p1 f-

IC

DCD P

1c, C)

Cl)

Hf-

ICD

PIc

Ff-

Fk

<

Cl) -CD H

.f-F H

DO

•13 Ci

)

(TI

0,

w

H-

0f-

IH

-H

13.’

13C)

H-

f-F13.

’13

Ci)

f-F

l))çt

13.’

0CD

b.’)

CD0

f-Ff-F

f-F91

13.’

f-F CD H-

H-

‘Cl

) 13

I91

(Ci

CD13

Cl)j

0H

-11

H Hi

H-

Cl)0

Nf-F

P1

CDH

13Il

0 H1

HH

-C

Dr

Ci) 13

P1

P1P

I.”,

13.’

CDF

-H

-CI

)f-F

CI)

•f-F

(Ci13.

’0

;-.‘

0C)

P1P.

,‘1

H-

I-]

13cF

H-

P1CD

’f-F

CDH

H-

HCi

)P1

Cl)H

HCl)

f-F13 LQ

Cl)0

IICD

f-I-

C)p.

’P1

f-Ff-F

HCD

CDH

-f-F

(Ci

13.’

f-FCl

)H

13(Ci

IiCD

Ilf-V

CD13.

’(C

iCi)

H-

0H

-Cl

)Ci)

Hf-F

(Ci

OH

Ci)

13f-F H

-Ci)

‘.1

Q13C

) H

‘1H

-CD

P11—

If-

ICD

H Cl)

CD

p.,

Cl)CD

f-F13

P1f-

I91

-

;-f-F

Hf-F

H-

t

C) f-FCD

H-

‘i”

91<

P113

CDf-

I

Cl)H

--

f-F(Ci

P1CD

C)Ci)

13f-I

-H

-C)

f-F

OH

-0

13CD

l)rtc2.,

P1P

1H

.13

00

I-’-

,

‘-‘1O

OH H

-Ci)

P1C)

13H

-f-

ICl

)CD

13.’

Cl)91

(Ci

•f-F

Il

CD0

h(I

)(C

i1>’l

f-VCD

f-FP1

çF13.

’C)

P1‘-<

f-FCD

CDH

-f-F

Ci)h

1311

Cl)

P1f-F

‘1C)

Ci)0

C)f-F

O0

P1H

C)P1

Cl)

H-

HP1

f-I

(Ci

Cl)C)

11Cl)

0,j

H-

P1 f-F0

(Ci‘1

Ci)Ci)

-

pCD

Hf-

I

C)Q

Ci)P1

H-

CDP

CDP1

13CD

Cl)

H-

C’ oCD

Cl)

MII

H-

•CD

Cl)

(Cii.

<C)

P1P1

f-I

H-

f-FCD

HP1

(Cif-F

CDP1

CDCD

H<

11Ci)

Hd

f-F

P1H

‘-<:

C)CD

CDf-t t-

b.’

CDCD

H-

(Ci11

Ci),-

rCD

Ci)

CD0

f-FCD

0P1

P1CD

Hf-I

-)

CDCD

f-FCi

)P1

P1H

,.CD

CDH

f-Fp.

’(Ci

<‘

(Ci

P1f-

If-F

H-

P1P1

<(C

i0

Iif-F

CD(Ci

.‘

CD HH

(.Qf-

IP1

f-FQ

13CD

13.’

1313

.’CD

f-FCD

PCD

Page 94: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

HU)

‘ti

U)H

-Pi

0II

C)C

)0

—C

tC)

CDH

-0

I-çi

0PJ

0Y

0[-

IIH

-0

H-

I-Q

çt

0C)

00

hH

-II

H-

ci

LC)

IH

CDW

‘-<

CL)

H-

ti‘t

iU)

C)U)

HC

r‘1

CDJ

Cr

CDH

,U

’‘-

“=

HC

rII

CDPi

H-

C)U)

H-

ciC

rH

-C)

H-

U)

—CD

CT)C

tçt

Ct

Cl)

l1H

-(Q

0C)

CDH

p

jP.)

-cC

rC

t0

FlCL)

NCD

HN

CDC)

HtY

•H

-ci

‘<CD

0CD

C)‘.<

P)C

tN

Ct

Cr

CDC

rH

-Fl

FlP

U)H

-W

ciS

ci

Cr

H-

0Fl

0Ci)

Fl0

CD0

H0

9.)‘<

CD5

ciH

-U)

ciH

CDç-

t0

j0

‘-<

MU)

Cr9

Cl)

C)ci

H-

Ci)

Ct

Cr

9)çt

00

N-

-CD

Cr

Hci

C1H

-U)

9)•

Cl)

WC

Fc-

FN

‘-c::

HU)

PC

rCD

cig

riH

H-

dH

H

ci

Cr

Ui

H.

.H

FlC

rC

rC

rCD

H-

CF9)

H0

C)C

rCD

CDH

CD0

C)H

-CD

Iiw

CDO

t—

OCD

CICl)

H-

H-

9)U)

3C

r,

HCD

:iH

-0

Cl)

CD0

CDCD

U)•

Cr‘<

Cl)

ci°

Cl)1

CD

ciCT

U)ci

IQH

FlC

rH

-H

-C

t0

9)F

lC

DH

(H

-Cl)

9)CD

C)Cl

)CD

FlC

rCD

CDCr

Cr9)

U)ç-

tCD

Cr

Fl‘-<

Cr

0H

-CT

CDCD

CDFl

39)

CDU)

H-

ci

Cr (I)

CDQ

I-’-

9C

r•

NCD

CDC)

CDC

rIQ

‘H

-Cl)

U)i

CL)

U’

0Cl)

C)H

-CD

U)C

tII

FlH

-CD

HCI

ICl

)H

-H

9)H

CDCD

0H

Cr

Hci

U)H

OCF

9)0

CDCD

Cl)CD

Cl)-

Cr

Cl)

H-

IiH

Cl)Fl

CDU)

CDI-’

-C

r9)

U)C)

0U)

C)H

FlCD

0I

CL)

(-QI

>‘C

rci

9)9)

LQP

(-I-

C)‘t

iU)

9)H

-0

CD-

H-

0

HCD

CDCD

CDU)

H-

Cr

CD

Cl)

9)9)

C)-

CDC)

NCD

(I)M

‘<9)

C)C

rM

iH

-9)

FlC

rCl

)U)

HU)

HU)

Ct

Li

(H

-CD

H-

FlCD

Cr

H-

H-

FlCD

CD-

CD9)

CD0

H-

‘<o

pCD

Cr

‘ti

Cr

FlC)

0Fl

Cl)

CDI-C

H•

H-

FlCD

Cr

Cl)9)

rtH

iPi

HH

-H

-H

-(1

Hi

ci

Cr

Cr

CDH

-

C)U)

CTC)

H-

HCD

FlCD

<9)

H-C

l)C)

H-

9)H

50

HH

-C

tCD

HC

rC

rC

rH

U)9)

H-

U)H

-1

PJCD

oH

c-t

C))

wFl

Cl)

CDCD

LQI-C

TU)

CDC)

yCD

Fl0

c-t

CDU)

CDC

ro

Ct

H-

0CD

piCL

)(I)

CrU)

-9)

CDci

‘<0

CDFl

0Fl

FlU)

U)‘t

i‘t

iFl

FlCD

tiM

iCD

Ct

FlCD

piCD

H-

CTC))

CDCr

CDH

-0

U)CD

Cr

Cr

t.Q=

CDCr

H-

Cr

CFC

rU)

Cr

Li

U)F

SJ

CDH

ICD

0Fl

9)0

U)11

<C)

ci

iCl)

H-

Cr

Cr

9)ci

0C

tC

ri

H-C

DH

-CD

9)9)

CDC

rH

-CT

U)CD

CDCD

9)Cl

)H

-H

-9)

H-

CDH

3CD

CTCD

CDci

•CD

-U)

HU)

Cl)H

Cr

—ci

Page 95: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

branches, just as one could snip center strands and have the web

continue to exist.” Fragmented social control is the key reason

for this resilience. While the state is the most powerful

organization in these “weblike” societies, the combined influence

and resistance of other social organizations is considerable. For

example, in Sierra Leone, “no single chief can stand up to the

strength of the state’s leaders, but the sum total of all the

chiefs’ quiet control in remote parts of the country can have a

crippling effect on state leaders’ attempts to increase state

capabilities.” It is also important not to equate state capacity

with the ability to remove one “strongman.” According to Migdal,

“individual strongmen may go, but the overall distribution of

social control may remain remarkably constant.”53

Migdal builds from his model and develops a theory to explain

why most Southern states are weak and a few are strong. For

parsimony, his model portrays the state as “a more or less

monolithic organization, a single actor, without significant

differentiation of parts.” As he develops his theory, however, he

refines this view of the state by pointing to “situations of

accommodation between parts of the state and social organizations

with opposing rules of the game.”54 Differentiating the state

makes it clear that executive decisions are distinct from state

output. Internal divisions and interaction with other social

organizations alter the impact of a state so it is often different

53Ibid., p.37, p.138, p.265.

54Ibid., both quotes, p.182.

85

Page 96: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

than the intent of the leaders. As we will see later, this has a

critical impact on state capacity to implement policies.

To facilitate melding Migdal’s ideas with patron-client

analysis, it is useful to narrow some of his core ideas.55 He

argues that most states fall on the weak end of a strong-weak

continuum. My study does not attempt to place the states of

Southeast Asia on this continuum. While factors like poor tax and

royalty collection, minimal reforestation, general disregard for

regulations, widespread illegal logging, and smuggling all indicate

‘weak’ states, they only point to low capacity in one policy

sector. The same states could have much greater control over, for

example, manufacturing. Migdal’s weak-strong continuum can be

refined by developing continuums of individual state capacity

depending on different policy sectors.56 Logically, a weak state

will have the majority of its policy initiatives fall on the weak

end of the continuum. Even here, however, there may be some cases

of high state capacity. This makes sense since, depending on the

policy area and the stakes, societal resistance to state

initiatives and state determination to enforce its rules will vary.

For example, environmental issues are generally a low priority for

55Some interpretation and latitude is necessary when usingMigdal’s ideas, definitions, and concepts since I am studyingSouthern resource management while he focuses on social policy. Itry to maintain the spirit of his work, even though my emphasis issomewhat different.

561n my view, this is a congruous addition to Migdal’s work.He argues states can be both strong and weak, depending on theactivity -- what he calls the “duality of states.” Migdal, StrongSocieties and Weak States, p.9.

86

Page 97: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

states while environmental regulations are often quite threatening

to nonstate organizations, particularly powerful businesses. As a

result, state capacity to enforce environmental regulations is

frequently low. On the other hand, state resolution to tackle

foreign control over natural resources may be strong while

resistance from nonstate organizations may be minimal, or in some

instances, these organizations may even support the state.

Therefore, a state may appear weak when tackling environmental

problems yet seem strong when tackling foreign control.

A second useful modification to Migdal’s model is to highlight

different societal organizations depending on the specific issue,

problem, or state policy. This is logical since nonstate

organizations can pick areas of resistance while states have

diverse, often contradictory goals, and must tackle a plethora of

issues and crises. Undeniably, even in the face of strong

resistance from organizations in society, state actions have

critical consequences, though often these are unintended. This is

hardly surprising. Compared to other social organizations states

have huge budgets, complex bureaucracies, and powerful coercive

tools. Yet societal organizations, while having far fewer

financial and human resources than a state, can concentrate their

opposition, or seek alliances, sometimes even dominating sections

of the state. For example, for a policy like affirmative action,

the business community may be the decisive societal group opposing

the state. For timber in Southeast Asia, patron-client networks

are the most important obstacle to state initiatives and the major

87

Page 98: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

Cl)

CD-3

Ct

CDI

HH

-C

)U)

::y

0IP

)H

H-C

DH

-C

tCD

H-C

L)t.S

HC

tdi<

HP

)H

U)

PJCD

CDCD

HU)

Ip.

-

Cl)

U)H

Q

U)—L

IH

Cr

CCD

1...

Ge•

CD

’1H

O‘t

iH

-I-

•CV

)C

tCD

H Htt

Jpj

@H

-H

C)C

DU

)0-

CDCD

CD0

HO

n C)

P)O

P

CDH rt

P)H

-Q

HO

:rf

lP)

CDO

HH

Pin

HH

-—

HC

D

C)

P1(D

U)

H-

CD HP

)C

D

C)C

HH

-H

-CT

)CD C

tqD

P)

CD

CD

J

Cl)

U)2)

I-ICF

CDH

-C)

P2)

2)CF

CDCF

CDI-

h21

0H

H2

CL)

2)rt

HCl)

HH

-C

tH

CFç

2)H

-C

rh

Ct

0CD

CDH

-CD

0C

tC)

C)H

-0

‘C)

II•

U)i-

H-

FJCD

H-

21H

-H

-21

LQ-

U)0

CDçt

CFpi

Ct

H-

C)U)

H-

Cr

CC)

CDI))

t-çt

<H

Cr

0H

CDH

-CD

02)

2)C

tH

Ct

U)CD

•CD

Ipi

H<

CDo

CD<

U)CD

c—F

00

0‘-

<C

U)H

H-

CDCD

or-

CDCD

C)U)

rF

CD0

0H

C)H

HCD

çrH

C1CD

CDCD

CDH

-CC

)(C

)

H-

orr

CDCD

P1-

I-CD

H-

2)2)

C)C

tH

-

CDi

CD0

0Cl

)N

H21

CL)

U)C)

0CF

U)

I-H

-CD

CDCD

CFC)

(3pi

H‘d

CF

CL)CL

)CD

CF0

0

-C

t0

HH

-CD

iCD

H-

2)U)

H Ct

H2)

H-

CC)

H-

H-

-CF

Hm

H-

U)H

Cl)CD

I-h

CL)

iH

CFH

-C

t3

CL)

H-

0o

rnC

CDU)

U)-

CDQ

Ct

H-

CFCl

)CF

Cr

Cl)

“<pj

-

i-CD

H-

CL)

CDCl)

H-

U)-t

CDCL)

j(j

)M

iCD

hTCl)

H-

00

H-

H-

CFCD

0c°

‘<çr

2)H

-C)

2’CF

Cl)

CDr

jCF

I-U)

CDCF

HH

U)C)

Cl)

CD9)

HU)

CD9)

CFI

•H

--

9’$1

H-

2)-i

H-

H-

H-

IC)

Ct

C)U)

C)C

rC)

CDCF

CFH

CD-

0CD

I-

0H

-U)

H-

CD‘-

crH

-‘

CI)

CDC)

P1P

CD9

jCF

-CF

C-t

C)CD

I-(1

)tI

Ct2)

LCD

HU)

CDCD

I—’

U)H

-CF

C)

CFH

-0

CD2

02)

2)b

CFU)

U)C

rC

rI

CDCD

‘CF

CL)CF

CDCF

CD0

Page 99: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

broadly conceived as clientelist states.59 The following section

looks briefly at policy implementation in the South. Then, by

borrowing and extrapolating Migdal’s key concepts, I build on

patron-client analysis to develop a model of natural resource

management in clientelist states.

CLIENTELIST STATES AND POLICY

When discussing state control over resource policies, it is

important to distinguish clearly between policy formation and

policy implementation. In terms of policy development a state may

dominate -- that is, there is little or minimal societal input.

Yet this same state may be ‘weak’ in the sense of facing formidable

obstacles to implementing state rules. For example, the Indonesian

state dominates policy formation but in some cases has great

difficulty enforcing policy regulations and maintaining societal

compliance.60 The sharp contrast between state power to develop

59Since state capacity and the impact of patron-client networkschanges across different policies, for this work the term‘clientelist state’ only refers to the management of naturalresources. For other policies, clientelist forces may be lesssignificant in shaping state capacity.

60Since the New Order was established by General Suharto in themid-1960s, the state has become increasingly centralized and nowdominates policy formation. For this reason, most academic studiesportray the Indonesian state as dominating society. For a summary,see Maclntyre, Business and Politics, pp.6-21. Specific examplesinclude Benedict Anderson, “Old State, New Society: Indonesia’s NewOrder in Comparative Historical Perspective,” Journal of AsianStudies 42, no. 3 (May 1983), pp.477-496; Donald Emmerson,“Understanding the New Order: Bureaucratic Pluralism in Indonesia,”Asian Survey 23 (November 1983), pp.1220-1241; the bureaucratic-authoritarian model by King, “Indonesia’s New Order,” pp.104-117;and Karl Jackson, “Bureaucratic Polity: A Theoretical Framework forthe Analysis of Power and Communications in Indonesia,” in Karl

89

Page 100: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

policies and the power to enforce policies has contributed to sharp

differences between scholars who see Southern states as irrevocably

weak and those who see these states as strong.6’ It is also

important to distinguish between the content and effects of

policies. Many comparative studies of Southern policies make

direct links between policy substance and the mismanagement of

natural resources. These studies show that many Southern policies

have serious technical flaws that contribute to environmental

degradation. They also demonstrate that the ability of the

bureaucracy to develop policies is weakened by organizational

difficulties and elite attitudes.62 But even though the content of

resource policies is undeniably important, a more immediate factor

Jackson and Lucien Pye, eds., Political Power and Communications inIndonesia (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1978). Thisconventional view has been challenged somewhat by Maclntyre’s 1990study which shows that, since the mid-1980s, business has gainedlimited input into developing legislation, regulations, andspecific policy measures. He does not, however, look closely atenforcement. As we will see in the next chapter, state dominationof the process of forming resource policy does not translate intoeffective implementation.

6mTheoretical models that concentrate on the process of policydevelopment and decision making -- such as corporatism orbureaucratic authoritarianism -- tend to portray a strong state.For overviews, see Douglas A. Chalmers, “Corporatism andComparative Politics,” in Wiarda, ed., New Directions, pp.59-81;and John D. Martz, “Bureaucratic-Authoritarianism, Transitions toDemocracy, and the Political-Culture Dimension,” in Wiarda, ed.,New Directions, pp.199-220. In my view, these studies overestimatethe ability of Southern states to control the distribution andmanagement of natural resources.

62For a discussion of how comparative politics theories couldstrengthen comparative studies of environmental policy making, seeSheldon Kamieniecki and Eliz Sanasarian, “Conducting ComparativeResearch on Environmental Policy,” Natural Resources Journal 30(Spring 1990), pp.321-339.

90

Page 101: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

driving mismanagement is often the willingness and ability of the

state to implement policies.

Northern states also have poor records for environmental

protection and resource management, partially due to corporate

lobbying and partially to the tendency for bureaucracies to be

dominated by economic interests. Yet, unlike in the South, in most

cases, key battles to improve resource management occur within the

state -- battles over legislation, interpretation of policy, and

budget allocations. While Northern policies are certainly watered

down during implementation, societal compliance to state

regulations is much higher than in the South. For this reason, it

is logical to dissect, analyze, and debate the nuances of Northern

policies. But to do the same for Southern policies may simply

divert attention from the more immediate problem: enforcement and

compliance. This does not mean that resource management will be

better in the North than in the South. But the core of the problem

is likely to be different: in the North, policies dominated by

economic concerns with weak environmental regulations; in the

South, policies that are widely ignored.

In the next section, I sketch a model to explain why

clientelist states of Southeast Asia are generally unable to

enforce natural resource management rules. There are three

interrelated reasons: the structure and norms of society support

institutionalized ‘corruption’; in order to survive, state leaders

-- facing a web of patron-client relations -- sacrifice state

capacity to enforce resource regulations; and finally, with minimal

91

Page 102: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

supervision, many middle and lower-level bureaucrats become

involved in patron-client exchange, ignoring state rules in order

to make money, advance their careers, or create small patron-client

units.

PATRON-CLIENT RELATIONS ND SYSTEMIC ‘CORRUPTION’

Like the patron-client model, Migdal provides a nuanced

understanding of corruption. He points to societal structure and

state reactions as keys to understanding flagrant violations of

state laws. He argues that “much of what is commonly called

corruption is. . .behaviour according to dissenting rules,

established by organizations other than the state.”63 Furthermore,

“nepotism, cronyism, corruption, and arrogance” of state leaders is

partially a response to surviving in a setting of fragmented social

control. Seen in this light, “corruption and arrogance are mere

symptoms of a complex relationship between state leaders and local

strongmen.”64 In societies dominated by clientelism, patron-client

ties permeate the state and nonstate organizations. Although

modern patron-client relations differ from older forms in terms of

stability and the nature of exchange, they are nevertheless a

legitimate, accepted, even expected, part of the political process.

While allegations of corruption, and pejorative labels such as

‘crony’ are part of formal debate and are used to justify

63Migdal, “A Model of State-Society Relations,” pp.54-55. Alsosee M±gdal, Strong Societies and Weak States, p.31.

64Migdal, Strong Societies and Weak States, both quotes, p.138.

92

Page 103: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

investigations, these prevalent practices flow from societal

structures and alternative rules of the game. They cannot be

dismissed as simple ‘corruption.’ Focusing on specific cases of

‘corruption’ highlights a symptom rather than the cause of poor

implementation. For this reason, campaigns in the Philippines,

Malaysia, and Indonesia which have tried to stamp out ‘corruption’

with token firings, fines and jail sentences have had little

impact. Of course, not all state officials in clientelist states

are ‘corrupt’. Some bureaucrats, military officers, and

politicians work diligently to enforce laws, improve regulations,

and raise revenue, even without strict supervision.65 For

management of a resource like timber, however, these officials tend

to be either outside patron-client networks or belong to networks

based on material incentives other than timber, though in some

cases they are simply ‘loyal’ to the state.

LEADERS AND LOW STATE CAPACITY

In the clientelist states of Southeast Asia, political

structures concentrate power among a small elite often motivated by

personal gain. Top state leaders, including Presidents, Prime

Ministers, and Chief Ministers, are often powerful patrons. But at

the same time, leaders must manoeuvre in a societal web of patron

client relations. Confronted by strong resistance from nonstate

65According to one critic of the Philippine state, an exampleis General Orlando Soriano. Marites Danguilan Vitug, The Politicsof Logging: Power From the Forest (Manila: Philippine Centre forInvestigative Journalism, 1993), pp.108-110.

93

Page 104: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

organizations, and faced with potential threats from institutions

within the state (often the military), state leaders, in order to

survive, and to maintain societal stability, follow strategies that

undermine state capabilities -- what Migdal calls the ‘politics of

survival’ 66 To weaken challenges from sections of the state, top

leaders remove and shuffle state agency elites. To maintain or

increase power, they appoint loyal followers, close friends, and

family. As well, to preserve stability, they make nonmerit

appointments to coopt powerful patrons, and ethnic, regional, and

business leaders outside the state. They also use nonmerit

appointments to hinder independent power centres from developing

within the state. These coopted elites are often allowed to get

rich through ‘corruption’. This provides a means of control for

state leaders. If these ‘corrupt’ officials step out of line, they

can be charged and legally dismissed or jailed.

These survival strategies by leaders undermine state capacity.

Shuffling administrative heads and making nonmerit appointments

lower morale and loyalty to the state (as opposed to the leader),

and weaken the ability and willingness to oppose local strongmen.67

Surviving as leader involves maintaining an intricate balance

between “restraining agencies sufficiently so they pose no threat

to rulers while allowing sufficient organization so the agencies

66A second characteristic of the ‘politics of survival’ is‘dirty tricks’ such as torture or ‘illegal’ imprisonment. SeeMigdal, Strong Societies and Weak States, pp.223-226.

67Ibid., p.240.

94

Page 105: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

can perform the tasks necessary for state and leader survival.”68

This is often a difficult balance. As state capacity declines and

the state is unable to provide basic services, leaders lose

legitimacy. To maintain control, leaders distribute even more

patronage. This dynamic -- state leaders using patronage to

maintain loyalty and patronage undermining state capacity to keep

citizens loyal -- can eventually spiral into a regime dominated by

‘politics of plunder,’ as in the Philippines under Marcos. While

the survival strategies of leaders weaken state agencies at the

top, these actions also debilitate state implementation.

PATRON-CLIENT TIES AND STATE IMPLEMENTORS

Effective state implementors -- middle and lower-level

bureaucrats responsible for collecting taxes, monitoring projects,

and enforcing rules -- are crucial for “determining whose authority

and rules will take hold in region after region, the state’s or the

strongmen’s.” Migdal hypothesizes that “the politics of survival

lessens backing and threats of sanctions from supervisors, thus

making the implementor more attentive to possible career costs

involving strongmen and peer officials. The result is a further

weakening of the state’s ability to make the rules governing

people’s behaviour.”69 In the weakest states there is almost no

control of implementors; they will follow rules vastly different

from those outlined in laws and policies. With poor supervision of

68Ibid., p.227.

69Ibid., p.238, p.241.

95

Page 106: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

middle and lower-level bureaucrats, implementation is largely

shaped by bargaining and deals between implementors, other state

and party officials, and strongmen outside the state.7° In

clientelist states, bureaucrats who actually attempt to impose

state rules must confront patron-client ties between state

officials, local strongmen, and party officials, usually putting

their career at great risk. These patron-client ties contribute to

severe perversions in the use and distribution of state resources,

and to state resources being used in ways that thwart state laws

and regulations 71

As a result of poor supervision, and close ties between state

implementors and patron-client networks, patrons sometimes capture

segments of clientelist states. These patrons place followers,

friends, or family “in critical state posts to ensure allocation of

resources according to their own rules, rather than the rules

propounded in the official rhetoric, policy statements, and

legislation generated in the capital city or those put forth by a

strong implementor.”72 These patron-client ties -- operating in

the middle and lower-levels of the military, bureaucracy, police,

or courts -- contribute to widespread violations of state laws and

regulations. State implementors such as customs officials,

enforcement officers, concession monitors, permit issuers, ‘look

70Migdal calls this the “Triangle of Accommodation.” Ibid.,p.249.

71For a more general discussion, see Ibid., p.245, and p.141.

72Ibid., p.256. Of course, for Migdal, all nonstateorganizations have the potential to capture a section of the state.

96

Page 107: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

the other way’ in exchange for cash, gifts, career maintenance or

advancement. Combatting illegal or lucrative timber ‘mining’ is

particularly difficult since timber licences, concessions, and

profits have been a key, and in some cases, the main glue for

modern patron-client ties in Southeast Asia. Weak enforcement is

reinforced by attitudes that place little value on natural

resources. As a result, state rhetoric is generally misleading.

Bureaucratic policies or official elite claims often oppose groups

over-exploiting resources. Yet in reality, some state agencies

accommodate, assist, or even strengthen, the practices that destroy

natural resources.

CONCLUSION

In sum, I posit a model of a state battling patron-client

networks for control over the rules of the game for the management

and allocation of natural resources. In the clientelist states of

Southeast Asia, state leaders are confronted with pervasive,

unstable, informal, material-based patron-client ties throughout

society. To survive in this fragmented society, leaders use

patronage to construct large patron-client followings and coopt

other powerful patrons. These vertical links contribute to

stability by extending the influence of state leaders to the

outlying areas, and by cutting across classes and ideologies.

Paradoxically, while distributing patronage is a legitimate, even

expected, part of building and maintaining power in Southeast Asia,

it has disastrous consequences for state capacity. Extensive

97

Page 108: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

nomnerit appointments undermine state morale, lower state

efficiency, contribute to a cynical view of state laws, and perhaps

most importantly, weaken supervision of state implementors.

Implementors become integrated into patron-client units, receiving

money or career advancements in exchange for ignoring management,

tax, or customs regulations. In some cases, societal patrons

manage to capture parts of the state, placing family, friends and

followers in strategic positions. This contributes to state assets

being used in ways inimical to state goals. It also makes it

relatively easy for these patrons to skirt, resist, even ignore

state policies. As a result, state resource management is dismal.

There is little chance of quickly improving resource management in

clientelist states. Pervasive patron-client ties throughout

society lead state leaders to undermine state capacity and

supervision in order to survive and maintain stability. The

alliances and agreements made between iniplementors and regional

patrons and politicians then reinforce these patron-client

networks. This creates a circle which leaves little hope of

breaking the pattern of poor implementation.73

This modified patron-client model of resource management, by

paying close attention to the nature of the state, the power of

patrons at the state helm, and policy implementation, gains

heuristic strength, while maintaining the advantages of focusing on

informal-personal exchange relations, traditional concepts of power

73This argument is the same as Migdal, though he is referringgenerally to social fragmentation rather than to patron-clientrelations. See Ibid.

98

Page 109: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

and legitimacy, cooperation between vertically-linked individuals

at all levels of society, and fluid ad hoc groups. Looking through

this lens in subsequent chapters reveals salient features of the

timber industry in Indonesia, Borneo Malaysia, and the Philippines

including: a distribution of timber profits which mainly benefits

the state political and business elite; unsustainable patterns of

timber extraction and ineffective forestry management; formal

policies and institutions weakened by informal practices and

unstable ‘rules of the game’; feeble state enforcement of timber

regulations; and logging concessions, licences, and profits that

link state leaders and implementors to timber-based patron-client

networks. Each chapter has the same format. For background, I

begin with a sketch of the evolution of patron-client relations.

While emphasizing links between patron-client networks and the

state, I then examine timber policies, practices, and enforcement

of regulations, revealing the key domestic causes of logging

mismanagement. This provides a context for a more accurate

assessment of the environmental impact of evolving Japanese ODA and

loans, corporate investment, technology transfers, and trade on

timber management in Southeast Asia.

99

Page 110: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

Chapter Four

JAPAN, PATRON-CLIENT POLITICS,

AND THE MISMANAGEMENT OF INDONESIAN TIMBER

Indonesia contains 10 percent of the world’s rain forests, and

around half of the remaining tropical forests of Asia. These

remarkable forests contain “more species of plants and birds than

the entire African continent.” The bulk of Indonesia’s

dipterocarp timber is on the outer islands of ICalimantan, Sumatra,

Sulawesi, and Irian Jaya.2 This valuable resource is rapidly

disappearing. Commercial logging is the most important factor

driving deforestation, estimated at about one million hectares per

year.3 I argue that patron-client links between top politicians,

military officers, bureaucrats and timber operators drive

destructive logging and undermine state capacity to manage the

forests.4 Ties at the pinnacle of the state distort policies and

‘Adam Schwarz, “Banking on Diversity,” FEER 28 October 1993,p.58.

2Commercial trees in the Philippines, Sabah, Sarawak andIndonesia are mostly from the family dipterocarpaceae. InIndonesia, the common commercial name for this timber is meranti,and in the Philippines, lauan.

3FAO data (average for 1982-90), in National Science TeachersAssociation, World Resources 1992-93, p.286. The World Bankrecently estimated annual deforestation at 1.1 million hectares.World Bank, Indonesia: Sustainable Development (Washington, 1993),p.7, cited Cohn MacAndrews, “Politics of the Environment inIndonesia, Asian Survey 34 (April 1994) , p.374.

4For a more general analysis of the impact of Indonesianpolitical forces on deforestation, see Peter Dauvergne, “ThePolitics of Deforestation in Indonesia,” Pacific Affairs 66, no. 4(Winter 1993-94), pp.497-518.

100

Page 111: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

weaken supervision of middle and lower-level state implementors.

Many state implementors join or form timber-based patron-client

networks, ignoring timber regulations in exchange for money, gifts,

or career advancements. In some cases, state bureaus are captured

by timber interests; instead of striving to implement state

guidelines, these state tentacles work in the interest of timber

companies, perverting policies and debilitating state capacity to

enforce logging regulations. At present, with timber profits

stoking the top, middle, and lower levels of the Indonesian

clientelist state, timber companies are able to ignore selective

logging rules and reforestation duties, extract enormous amounts of

illegal logs, and evade corporate taxes and royalties.

While patron-client ties are a critical force driving

mismanagement, Northern shadow ecologies -- especially Japan’s --

have accelerated unsustainable logging. With Japanese government

support in the 1960s and 1970s, trading companies provided

technology and funds for logging operations on Indonesia’s outer

islands. To supply Japanese plywood plants, these trading

companies then imported huge quantities of the best logs. Many of

these logs were used to make plywood panels to mould concrete,

known in Japan as kon pane. Although Indonesian state and business

elites made quick money, Japan gained most of the economic

benefits. Meanwhile, Indonesia’s remote islands absorbed

substantial environmental losses. Log prices were far below

replacement or sustainable management costs. This is starkly

revealed by the common Japanese practice of discarding kon pane --

101

Page 112: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

made from Indonesian trees that likely took a century or more to

grow -- after being used only one or two times.

In the early 1980s, the Indonesian govermtlent, angered by the

lack of economic spin-of fs, banned log exports and provided

incentives to develop plywood processing. This has changed Japan’s

shadow ecology of timber in several key ways. Investment is now

much lower as most trading companies sold their shares or simply

withdrew in the late 1970s and early 1980s. There are also fewer

technology transfers since much of the equipment and infrastructure

for logging is in place. As well, ODA is linked less to commercial

logging operations, and now focuses on large-scale timber

plantations, processing technology transfers, and to a lesser

extent conservation and forest regeneration projects. Yet key

characteristics of Japan’s shadow ecology -- low consumer prices,

wasteful consumption, and import tariffs -- have remained

essentially unchanged. Whereas in the 1960s and 1970s Japanese

companies purchased huge quantities of cheap logs and turned them

into disposable kon pane, today, after imposing onerous import

duties, Japan consumes large amounts of cheap Indonesian plywood,

again mostly as kon pane. While kon pane are now reused slightly

more than in the past, they are still a remarkably wasteful drain

on tropical forests. In short, despite a decline in investment and

technology transfers, and limited changes to ODA projects, Japan’s

shadow ecology continues to expedite unsustainable timber

management.

This chapter is divided into three parts. First, I outline

102

Page 113: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

traditional Indonesian patron-client relations, explaining how

these have evolved in the twentieth century, and now shape the New

Order government under President Suharto. Second, I analyze how

extensive ‘modern’ ties between state patrons and business clients

distort state timber policies and undercut state enforcement. I

examine selective logging rules, the distribution of timber

concessions, tax and royalty regulations, reforestation and

conservation policies, foreign investment guidelines, and policies

to promote plywood and pulp and paper mills. In the final section,

I explore the impact of Japan’s shadow ecology on timber management

over the last three decades. I document changes to ODA projects,

corporate investment, technology transfers and wood imports since

the early 1980s. I then analyze the environmental and economic

impact of Indonesia’s log export ban nd the subsequent increase in

Japanese plywood imports.

TRADITIONAL AND MODERN PATRON-CLIENT RELATIONS IN INDONESIA

Traditional Javanese patron-client relations are dyadic,

vertical, personal, unequal, and reciprocal.5 Patrons tend to

inherit clients rather than building these ties based on personal

achievements. These ties involve more than simply “exchanging

rewards for services” and do not “involve calculation of immediate

5Even though most of Indonesia’s commercial timber is on theouter islands, since the Javanese dominate state positions, I focuson Javanese patron-client relations. Due to lack of space andresources, I am forced to assume that patron-client ties are alsoa key feature of other ethnic groups in Indonesia.

103

Page 114: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

personal interests by the follower.”6 Patrons are “expected to

serve as provider, protector, educator, and source of values.. .In

turn, the follower is expected to reciprocate by volunteering his

labour, his vote, and in some cases even his life although these

obligations are seldom explicit either when incurred or called

due.”7 Clients feel a strong sense of loyalty that transcends

monetary debts and specific requests, and that can be passed down

through generations. Patrons also feel a strong moral obligation

to protect and support their clients. Finally, there is an “aura

of absolutism” surrounding a traditional patron which contributes

to reflexive obedience,8making these relations fairly predictable

and stable.

Traditional patron-client ties still exist in Indonesia,

particularly in rural areas. However, colonialism, the gradual

dominance of market exchange, the growth of the state and its

increasing control over economic development, internal upheavals

(such as the fight for independence and the 1965 coup attempt), and

migration from rural villages to large cities have shattered many

traditional ties. In most instances, these have reconfigured to

form ‘modern’ patron-client links. Although both traditional and

6Karl D. Jackson, “Urbanization and the Rise of Patron-ClientRelations: The Changing Quality of Interpersonal Communications inthe Neighbourhoods of Bandung and the Villages of West Java,” inJackson, and Pye, eds., Political Power and Communications, p.346.

7Karl D. Jackson, “The Political Implications of Structure andCulture in Indonesia,” in Jackson and Pye, eds., Political Powerand Communications, p.34.

8Jackson, “Urbanization,” p.349.

104

Page 115: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

modern patron-client relations are known as bapak—anak buah

(literally, father-children), there are important distinctions.

Karl Jackson documents the difference in patron-client ties between

villagers, urbanites born in a village, and urbanites born in a

city. He shows that as people migrate from villages, traditional

patron-client relations dissolve. After relocating, new relations

develop as people struggle to improve their living standard. These

modern ties are rooted in traditional relations but are “more

limited, instrumental, opportunistic, specialized, achievement-

based, and focused on the recent present rather than the distant

past.

Compared to traditional relations, modern ties tend to have

weaker feelings of loyalty and obligation, although there is still

a “debt of moral obligation,” or hutang budi, “extending beyond the

purely monetary aspect of the debt.” In modern relations, however,

“the lengths to which the individual will go to pay back hutang

budi are much more limited.” For modern links, a patron’s power is

closely related to “his own resources, official position, or his

hold over specialized knowledge,” while “noble birth” or “good

family,” though still useful, are less important.1° As well,

modern patron-client ties are far more likely to revolve around

material exchanges. Clients tend to calculate the costs and

9lbid., p.344. My terminology differs slightly from Jackson.He calls ‘traditional patron-client relations,’ ‘traditionalauthority relations,’ and ‘modern patron-client relations,’ either‘patronage’ or simply ‘patron-client relations.’ Our meanings,however, are essentially identical.

‘°Ibid., p.349, and p.350.

105

Page 116: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

benefits of their participation. If better opportunities arise a

client may well abandon their patron and join another patronage

network. In some cases, clients attach themselves to more than one

patron, making it easier to change allegiances as political tides

shift. Patrons are also more willing to dispose of individual

clients, particularly if the behaviour of a client is undermining

the power or prestige of the leader or the group as a whole. For

this reason, modern ties last for shorter periods than traditional

ties, and are unlikely to transfer across generations. Unlike in

traditional villages, shifting patron-client networks create an

uncertain and unpredictable atmosphere. Patrons can never be

assured of a loyal following and clients can never be confident of

their patron’s protection. This uncertainty is aggravated by the

unwieldy size of many modern patron-client networks, by networks

that extend beyond organizational or geographic boundaries, and by

people who migrated to cities as adults and are not well integrated

into patron-client units.”

Despite these contrasts, modern and traditional patron-client

relations have important similarities. In both, links are vertical

and asymmetrical. A patron fuses together a heterogenous group of

individuals with complementary abilities, with divergent

ideological beliefs, and with different ethnic and social

backgrounds. As Jackson notes, a “truly powerful patron is one who

has the capacity to concentrate within his circle clients of

“Jackson, “Urbanization,” passim, although see in particular,p.390.

106

Page 117: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

varying intellectual, social, official, and financial resources,

thus making this person the vital connecting link in the exchange

pattern animating the circle.”2 A patron is clearly more powerful

than any individual client, though successful patrons must

conscientiously maintain their client base. Modern patron-client

ties also remain essentially personal, informal, and

noncontractual. Patrons supply clients with licences, jobs, and

political protection, or allow clients to ignore laws and

regulations, in exchange for immediate or future gifts, money,

loyalty, or support. Modern patrons are also expected to perform

some traditional duties, including advice “on ideological,

personal, religious, and mystical matters.”3

PATRON-CLIENT TIES ND THE INDONESIAN STATE

The use of public office to reward clients has strong cultural

and historical roots in Indonesia. State patronage was pervasive

in the precolonial and colonial era.’4 After independence from the

Dutch, patronage expanded with the growth of the state --

especially under Sukarno’s Guided Democracy (1958-65). As

‘2Jackson, “Bureaucratic Polity,” p.3.

‘3Ibid., p.14. For further details on traditional and modernpatron-client relations in Indonesia, see Karl D. Jackson,Traditional Authority. Islam, and Rebellion: A Study of IndonesianPolitical Behaviour (Berkeley: University of California Press,1980), especially Chapter 8.

‘i assume that the values and customs of precolonial Indonesiahave important implications for current practices. For asupporting view, see Harry J. Benda, “Democracy in Indonesia,” inAnderson and Audrey, eds., Interpreting Indonesian Politics, pp.13-21.

107

Page 118: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

G. McGuire and B. Hering note, “all ruling groups in Indonesia’s

history” have dispensed patronage. “Indeed the ability to do so is

considered an example of one’s status and personal skill.”5

Traditional village values and roles in Java, where leaders

function as community patrons, have had important implications for

the behaviour of state administrators. It has meant that “for the

villager who rises to the level of district or subdistrict officer

today, traditionally accepted behaviour and values suddenly become

legally corrupt behaviour and values.”6 As a result, the legal

definition and cultural understanding of ‘corruption’ differ.’7

Of course, not all political action and inaction in Indonesia

can be explained by the impact of patron-client relations.

Religion can be an important factor. While 90 percent of the

population is officially Muslim, the deep cleavage between orthodox

(santri) and syncretistic (abangan) Muslims can have explosive

implications. There are also sharp differences within the orthodox

Muslim community. The ethnic and regional composition of Indonesia

‘5G. McGuire and B. Hering, “The Indonesian Army: Harbingers ofProgress or Reactionary Predators?” in Christine Doran, ed.,Indonesian Politics: A Reader (North Queensland: James Cookuniversity, 1987), p.211.

‘6Theodore M. Smith, “Corruption, Tradition, and Change,”Indonesia, no. 11 (April, 1971), pp.25-26.

‘7This helps explain why anti-corruption campaigns generallyfail. Of course, as one would expect in any diverse society, someIndonesians - - especially university students - - are quite criticalof rampant legal violations.

108

Page 119: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

is another significant factor that shapes political interaction.’8

In a population of around 180 million, there are more than 300

different ethnic groups and 250 languages spread across a plethora

of islands. Sixty percent of the population lives on Java, which

represents only 7 percent of the land. Yet the Javanese dominate

top political, military, and bureaucratic positions,’9 while

Indonesian-Chinese, who comprise only 5 percent of the population,

control much of the business world.2° Certain cultural norms also

shape political decisions. A respect for age and seniority, an

emphasis on deference and self-control, and a desire for consensual

decision making contribute to policies that reflect elite

preferences. Elite attitudes also have important ramifications.

Western-educated bureaucrats often have a decisive impact on the

content of current policies, and are instrumental in developing the

Five Year Plans (Repelita) . These technocrats tend to support

rapid economic growth at all costs. As a result, policies like

conservation, reforestation and environmental management are low

‘8For a discussion of the impact of cultural cleavages onIndonesian politics, see Donald K. Enimerson, Indonesia’s Elite:Political Culture and Cultural Politics (Ithaca: Cornell UniversityPress, 1976)

‘9For example, around 75 percent of key positions in themilitary are held by Javanese. Leo Suryadinata, MilitaryAscendency And Political Culture: A Study of Indonesia’s Golkar(Ohio: Ohio University Center for International Studies, 1989),p.1.

20A 1989 survey showed that 163 of the top 200 Indonesian firmsare controlled by ethnic Chinese. Maclntyre, Business and Politics,p.263, footnote 19.

109

Page 120: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

priorities 21

Despite the obvious relevance of religion, ethnicity,

language, regional diversity, culture, and attitudes for

understanding Indonesian politics, focusing on patron-client

relations reveals key features of the current Indonesian state.

Patron-client relations permeate and tie together the political

executive, the legislature, the military, the bureaucracy, the

courts, and the business community. At the apex of politics, the

battle for power is largely between “circles of high-ranking

bureaucrats and military officers. . .held together by an elaborate

system of personal ties and mutual obligations.” To some extent

these ‘circles’ are reinforced by family connections, friendships,

ethnic backgrounds, religious views, and ideological positions.

But the crucial glue is “patron-client bonds.”22

The New Order -- established after Sukarno was ousted from

power in the mid-l960s -- is dominated by President Suharto (a

former General), underpinned by the army, and steered by the

bureaucracy.23 The New Order government -- which arose partially

as a reaction to the turmoil of the l950s and 1960s -- has

emphasized stability and national integration. President Suharto

has gradually consolidated and centralized control, by eliminating

21For more detail on the impact of attitudes on forestrymanagement, see Dauvergne, “The Politics of Deforestation inIndonesia,” pp.506-507.

22Jackson, “Bureaucratic Polity,” p.14.

23For a general overview of the New Order, see Michael R.J.Vatikiotis, Indonesian Politics Under Suharto (London: Routledge,1993)

110

Page 121: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

Communist party members, eradicating troublesome factions in the

military, purging and streamlining the bureaucracy, placing strict

controls on political parties, and sponsoring corporatist

structures to organize social and economic groups. Suhart.o’s

control is reinforced by his authority to appoint cabinet members

and regional governors, to proclaim laws, and to control the armed

services. The People’s Consultative Assembly (MPR) -- which under

the 1945 Constitution is the highest authority and elects the

President and Vice-President -- and the legislative House of

Representatives (DPR) provide some legitimacy but no substantive

checks on executive and bureaucratic decisions.24 The ruling

Golkar party -- under the firm grip of Suharto and the military --

controls the national and regional assemblies.25 The two main

opposition political parties -- the Partai Persatuan Pembangunan

and the Partai Demokrasi Indonesia -- do not pose a serious

challenge. The power of regional governments is limited by lack of

revenues and close supervision from Jakarta.26 In the early 1980s,

24See David McKendr±ck, “Indonesia in 1991, Growth, Privilegeand Rules,” Asian Survey 32, no. 2 (February 1992), p.108.According to Maclntyre, DPR committees have some influence.Maclntyre, Business and Politics, pp.31-35. There are some signsthat the DPR is becoming more important. See John McBeth, “LoyalHouse: But Parliament is becoming more animated,” FEER, 8 September1994, pp.32-34.

25For a study of Golkar, see D. Reeve, Golkar of Indonesia: anAlternative to the Party System (Singapore: Oxford UniversityPress, 1985)

26Army personnel have not been placed at the village level.But these officials sometimes receive military training, and theirloyalty is monitored. Donald Enimerson, “The Bureaucracy inPolitical Context: Weakness in Strength,” in Pye and Jackson, eds.,Political Power, pp.103-104.

111

Page 122: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

many provinces received up to 90 percent of their revenue from

central grants. Interest groups, the media, students, NGO5, and

the general public also have little input or influence on policy

formulation.27 With firm control, in 1993, Suharto was easily

elected for a sixth five-year presidential terni.28

Despite Suharto’s undeniable power, Indonesia is not a one-man

state. Suharto needs the support of influential military generals

and top bureaucrats. As Dwight King notes, “most observers would

agree that Suharto’s leadership style has been deliberate,

predictable and, above all, consultative. Key policy decisions

seem far more the product of a military-technocrat oligarchy than

the discretion of a military dictator.”29 Although coercion has

been indisputably important, Suharto has maintained loyalty in part

through judicious distribution of patronage. He has built a

powerful group of followers, including key political, military,

business, bureaucratic, and regional leaders. This patron-client

network is the nucleus of power and the bastion for elite

stability.

Suharto’s family is at the centre of this network. His

relatives -- first his wife and half-brothers and now his six

27Measures have been taken to control the political influenceof these groups. University student organizations were banned inthe late 1970s. The 1985 Law on Social Organizations (Ormas)severely restricts the activities of NGO5. The media is regularlycensored and many newspapers and magazines have been closed forbeing too critical of the government.

28For details, see Henny Sender, “New Boys’ Challenge,” FEER,1 April 1993, pp.72-75.

29King, “Indonesia’s New Order,” p.108.

112

Page 123: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

children and their affiliated companies -- have received key

government licences, monopolistic contracts, and crucial access to

the corridors of power, enabling them to build substantial

fortunes.3° Even state bank loans are often underpinned by

personal connections, not by collateral or persuasive investment

proposals.31 Although President Suharto avoids any direct role in

business, according to one foreign businessman: “You cannot get

involved in an important deal any more if you don’t bring in at

least one of the children.”32 An academic claims: “At least 80

percent of major government projects go in some form to the

President’s children or friends.”33 Suharto has also used

patronage to placate and integrate potential rivals. As Harold

Crouch notes, after gaining control in the mid-1960s, “Suharto

rewarded his key supporters handsomely; but he was careful not to

antagonize unnecessarily those who had lost in the inter-group

struggles: many losers were also compensated with appointments and

opportunities.” As well, he has allowed key military and

bureaucratic leaders to establish their own clientele, and has

30See “In Suharto’s shadow,” Economist, 9 May 1992, pp.33-34;and Adam Schwarz, “All is relative,” FEER, 30 April 1992, pp.54-58.

31lnterview, Environmental consultant, Bogor Indonesia, 24February 1994.

32Adam Schwarz, “All is relative,” FEER, 30 April 1992, p.54.

33Steven Erlanger, “For Suharto, His Heirs are Key to LifeAfter ‘93,” The New York Times International, 11 November 1990,p. Yll.

34Crouch, “Patrimonialism,” p.578. Also see Herbert Feith,“Political Control, Class Formation and Legitimacy in Suharto’sIndonesia,” in Doran, ed., Indonesian Politics, pp.221-234.

113

Page 124: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

permitted pervasive patron-client exchange at the middle and lower

levels of the state. By partially redistributing the benefits of

rapid economic development and oil exports, these extensive patron-

client networks have enhanced stability, created a powerful group

with a vested interest in the status quo, and bolstered Suharto’s

legitimacy

To some extent, the legitimacy of Indonesian state leaders is

not connected to obeying laws and procedures but to using their

position to reward followers. As Jackson points out, “social

injustice and corruption are felt only if a patron fails to

redistribute his bounty among his clients or if the patron in

adapting to market pressures abandons [his] diffuse

responsibilities.”36 For this reason, Suharto’s overt use of

political power to enhance the fortunes of his clients, family and

friends has strengthened his grip rather than undermined his

35Rapid economic growth and oil exports have been vital for thestability of the New Order. Crouch argues that with “huge sumsavailable for patronage distribution, the regime was in a positionto reward its supporters royally; at the same time it could makedissidence very costly for its critics.” Harold Crouch, The Armyand Politics in Indonesia, revised edition (Ithaca: CornellUniversity Press, 1988), p.355. writing in the early 1970s, W.F.Wertheim argued that under Suharto, patron-client relations wereeroding, especially at the lower levels of society. He predictedthat insurgency and revolution similar to China’s would occurunless the government implemented radical land reform. In my view,part of the reason for his inaccurate forecast is that patronclient links which cut across and weaken class ties have notdiminished but have flourished. For a discussion of Wertheim’swork, see Feith, “Political Control,” pp.229-231.

36Jackson, “The Political Implications,” p.36.

114

Page 125: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

legitimacy.37 This helps explain why Suharto is “undefensive about

his position and the activities of his children” and why he “will

easily move from a conversation about macroeconomic policy to one

about a contract or a regulation affecting” one of his followers.38

This also helps explain why Suharto has not become directly

involved in business operations and has avoided lavish displays of

personal wealth. As was evident with Sukarno, this kind of

behaviour is seen as irresponsible and ‘corrupt’ and contributes to

a loss of legitimacy in the eyes of the ruling elite.

CHINESE BUSINESS CLIENTS

Links between powerful state patrons (mainly Javanese) and

Indonesian-Chinese business clients (cukongs) are a dominant

feature of the New Order.39 Compared to ties between Javanese,

these connections are less likely to have strong bonds of loyalty

and honour and more likely to be held together by mutual need and

a mutual desire to make money. Political and military patrons

supply credit, contracts, licences, access, and protection while

37Privately, some officials do criticize the extensive businesslinks to Suharto’s children. Donald IC. Emmerson, “Indonesia in1990: A Foreshadow Play,” Asian Survey 31 (February 1991), p.185.As well, orthodox Muslims have been critical of his close ties toChinese corporations.

38Steven Erlanger, “For Suharto, His Heirs are Key to LifeAfter ‘93,” The New York Times International, 11 November 1990,p.Yll.

39Richard Robison, “Toward A Class Analysis of the IndonesianMilitary Bureaucratic State,” Indonesia, no. 25 (April 1978),pp.17-39. For even greater detail, see Richard Robison, Indonesia:The Rise of Capital (Australia: Allen and Unwin Pty Ltd., 1986).

115

Page 126: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

Chinese clients provide vital expertise and capital to operate a

business.40 Chinese clients also provide crucial access to markets

and funds through Chinese contacts in Singapore and Hong Kong.

Even though both sides clearly benefit, this relationship is not

equal. Indonesian-Chinese are in a subordinate position and are

vulnerable to political shifts and societal backlash. As Ernst

Utrecht explains, “the cukong is a so-called ‘back-door broker,

because often strong anti-Chinese sentiments within society have

prevented even Jakarta generals receiving Chinese business

associates through the front-door of office or home.”4’ Although

most Indonesian-Chinese have been in Indonesia for generations,

speak Indonesian, and even have Indonesian sounding names, there is

strong prejudice against this group. Despite the stability of the

New Order, there are clear signs of hostility and racism,

especially against the increasingly visible and prosperous Chinese

middle-class.42 Due to pervasive racism, according to Go Gien

Tjwan, “today’s Indonesian society is not attractive enough for

many Peranakan Chinese [people of Chinese ancestry born in

40As attitudes change, and business is no longer perceived asa lower class activity, “a number of fairly large pribumi[indigenous or non-Chinese] Indonesian businesses have developed,particularly those with connections to the presidential family.”MacAndrews, “Politics,” p.372.

41Ernst tjtrecht, “Indonesia’s Foreign Private Corporate System,Past and Present,” in Doran, ed., Indonesian Politics, p.184.

42r examples are: the anti-Chinese focus of the 1974 riotsfollowing Japanese Prime Minister Tanaka’s visit to Jakarta; andthe Chinese pogroms in Central Java in 1980. Over the past sixyears, the Islamic revivalist movement has rekindled anti-Chinesefeelings. John McBeth, “Challenges of Progress,” FEER, 28 April1994, p.46.

116

Page 127: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

Indonesia) to wholeheartedly become a participant in it.”43 The

subordinate status and vulnerability of Indonesian-Chinese business

leaders is manifested in most wealthy Chinese channelling profits

outside the country, not only to avoid royalties and taxes, but

also for personal security.

Since Suharto consolidated and centralized control, patron-

client networks at the top of the state have been fairly stable.

But there is still a sense of uncertainty. Chinese business

clients are wary of sudden racial backlashes. The fall of Sukarno

and the purge of many of his followers is also an important

reminder of the tenuous nature of these ties. After Suharto steps

down or dies in office, patron-client networks connected to his

reign may well be pushed aside or eliminated. For members of

patron-client groups grazing on state coffers, especially Chinese

clients, this creates a continual sense of unease despite the

stability of the New Order.

MILITARY

The military is the cornerstone of the New Order. The

military establishment maintains it should have a central political

role, and military officers hold key political, bureaucratic and

corporate posts. Yet the military does not dominate political

decisions. Suharto has been careful to appease and coopt powerful

43Go Gien Tjwan, “The Chinese in Indonesia, Past and Present,”in Doran, ed., Indonesian Politics, p.93.

44See Harold Crouch, “Generals and Business in Indonesia,”Pacific Affairs 48, no. 4 (Winter 1975-76), pp.519-540.

117

Page 128: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

military generals. As well, to hinder alternative power centres

from coalescing in the military, he has reorganized the armed

services, rotated regional commanders, and encouraged early

retirements. As Donald Emmerson notes, “the price of outspoken

independence, several generals have discovered, is an

ambassadorship.”45 Suharto has also prevented the emergence of

powerful military successors. Crouch argues that in the 1980s,

“like the traditional Javanese sultans who kept rival groups of

courtiers in balance, Suharto made sure that no single group of

officers gained a position from which they could challenge his rule

and that no single, clear-cut candidate for the succession

emerged. ,,46 As a result of this prudent management of the

military, the New Order government “has become the master rather

than the servant of the military establishment.”47

Military links to local business grew in the early l950s as

civilian cabinets reduced the military budget. According to Ruth

McVey, as the army’s income fell, “regional commanders began to

make deals with local business interests which enabled them to

45Emmerson, “The Bureaucracy,” p.104.

46Crouch, The Army and Politics, p.357.

47jackson, “Bureaucratic Polity,” p.13. Also see UlfSundhaussen, “The Military: Structure, Procedures, and Effects onIndonesian Society,” in Jackson and Pye, eds., Political Power,pp.45-Si. In the last three years, the number of cabinet memberswith military background has declined, and now most of the 27provincial governors are civilians. One study showed that “from apeak of 25,000 in 1967, officers seconded to dwi-fungsi [dualfunction] positions had dropped to 13,000 in 1986 and to about9,500 by 1992.” John McBeth, “Challenges of Progress,” FEER, 28April 1994, p.46.

118

Page 129: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

support their troops and preserve the loyalties of their

subordinates. This gave them a financial base independent of the

centre.”48 Army interference and participation in business

continued to increase during the chaotic years of Guided Democracy.

By the time Suharto and the army secured power in the mid-1960s,

the weak economy and fragmented administration convinced the new

government that “it had little prospect of raising adequate funds

for the armed forces through taxation.”49 To maintain a stable and

loyal military, and to compensate for budget and personnel

cutbacks, the New Order government has allowed, even encouraged,

the old practices of military officers raising revenue through

business connections and patron-client exchange.5° Patron-client

relations within the military also have important consequences.

The army hierarchy is split between managers who occupy key

administrative posts or operate trading companies and field

officers who are responsible for security. These managers often

supply money to field officers for protection, contributing to a

need for managers to become involved in ‘illegal’ activities.5’

48Ruth McVey, “The Post-Revolutionary Transformation of theIndonesian Army Part I, Indonesia 11-12 (1971), pp.152-153, quotedin McGuire and Hering, “The Indonesian Army,” p.209.

49Crouch, “Generals and Business in Indonesia,” p.523.

501b±d., pp.523-524. As a result of this strategy, officershave prospered in the New Order far more than the lower ranks.Ernst Utrecht, The Indonesian Army (Townsv±lle, 1980), pp.100-101.For details on the military’s involvement in business, see Robison,Indonesia: The Rise of Capital, chapter 8.

51Utrecht, The Indonesian Army, p.103.

119

Page 130: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

BUREAUCRACY

Suharto has purged and pared down the bureaucracy, increased

salaries, and made administrators more active. To increase loyalty

and control, he has placed military officers in strategic

positions.52 By the mid-l980s, about sixty percent of senior

bureaucrats in Jakarta had military backgrounds.53 To undermine

competing political allegiances, Suharto used to require

bureaucrats to join Golkar. Despite Suharto’s moves to ‘backbone’

the bureaucracy with loyal military officers and curtail political

activities, civilian bureaucrats have still had significant

influence. Jackson claims that “the ideas of the civilian

technocrats have probably had more impact on policy in Indonesia

than in almost any other country in the Third World.”54

At all levels, the bureaucracy is perforated by patron-client

ties.55 At the top, informal networks connect senior bureaucrats

to powerful military officers, prominent politicians, and wealthy

business leaders. At the middle and lower levels, patron-client

networks also operate within departments, between different

departments, and between departmental officials and powerful

political, military, and business leaders. As a result, a

52Emmerson, “The Bureaucracy,” pp.82-83, pp.90-91, p.100.

53Colin MacAndrews, “The Structure of Government in Indonesia,”in Cohn MacAndrews, ed., Central Government and Local Developmentin Indonesia (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1986), p.33.

54jackson, “Bureaucratic Polity,” p.13.

55See Loekman Soetrisno, “Patron-client relationships,” ReviewIndonesia, no. 98, 26 February 1994, p.18.

120

Page 131: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

bureaucrat’s power and status are often not related to his or her

position, but to connections. According to McVey, “a powerful

patron will have clients in several ministries or armed units; his

true strength as an official will depend on his personal

connections and the access his position provides to wealth.” For

this reason, successful officials use “the economic possibilities

of [their] position to the full.”56

While the principal goal of intrabureaucratic patron-client

clusters and networks is to preserve or enhance power and wealth,

these groups also have organizational and policy aims. Prevalent

patron-client ties do not always prevent organizational

effectiveness. However, particularly when resources are scarce,

personal interests tend to override organizational objectives --

the financial collapse of the national oil company Pertamina and

the failure of the agency for rice stabilization (BULOG) are two

well known cases from the 1970s. In both instances, “the directors

of the agencies and the long chains of clients extending downward

from the directors’ closest confidants.. .prospered while the

organizational objectives.. .faltered.”57 The dominance of

particularistic, rent-seeking aims of patron-client groups over

organizational objectives also contributed to the fall of Sukarno.

56Ruth T. McVey, “The Beamtenstaat in Indonesia,” in Andersonand Kahin, eds., Interpreting Indonesian Politics, p.88.

57jackson, “Bureaucratic Polity,” p.15. For details onPertamina, see Sundhaussen, “The Military,” pp.53-54; and Eirimerson,“The Bureaucracy in Political Context,” pp.112-116. For details onBULOG (Logistics Board), see Bruce Glassburner, “Indonesia’s NewEconomic Policy and Its Sociopolitical Implications,” in Jacksonand Pye, eds., Political Power, pp.147-149.

121

Page 132: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

According to Jackson, “in almost all organizations at the close of

Guided Democracy there were no slack resources whatever, and the

satisfaction of personal or group objectives precluded the

accomplishment of almost all organizational ends.”58 While

Pertamina and the rice agency are exceptions, since the late 1960s,

foreign investment and loans, massive exports of raw materials

(especially oil), and manageable rates of inflation have provided

the “slack that has allowed less than optimally efficient

organizations to perform effectively.”59 Yet the New Order

bureaucracy is clearly more effective in some areas than in others.

As we will see later, in the case of timber management, close ties

between patron-client networks and timber licences, concessions,

and profits has debilitated the state’s ability to monitor and

enforce management regulations.

JAPAN AND PATRON-CLIENT RELATIONS

While Japanese corporate executives sometimes bribe state

officials, this is not in the context of long-term patron-client

exchange relations.6° According to Utrecht, Japanese investors

prefer to use Chinese brokers in Hong Kong and Singapore to avoid

58Jackson, “Bureaucratic Polity, p.15.

59Ibid., p.16. Crouch argues that foreign aid and investmentand rising oil prices have provided critical funding for massivestate patronage and regime stability. Crouch, “Patrimonialism,”pp.178-179.

60For a discussion of Japanese corruption in Indonesia, seeYoko Kitazawa, “Japan-Indonesia Corruption,” AMPO 8, no. 1 (1976),part I and part II.

122

Page 133: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

incredibly ‘corrupt’ Indonesian (especially non-Chinese)

businessmen.61 Nevertheless, Japanese money has had a significant

impact on patron-client ties. Since the late 1960s, aid,

investment, and resource purchases have supplied key funds to fuel

ubiquitous patron-client exchanges. According to a 1980 AMPO

study, “Japanese capital promotes bribery and corruption in

Indonesia and encourages the formation of a comprador bourgeoisie

that is in collusion with high government officials, the military

and overseas Chinese.”62

SOCIETAL STRUCTURE ND POLICY IMPLEMENTATION

Modern and traditional patron-client ties in Indonesia

disperse power; society is not a pyramid where all power flows to

a peak. Instead of a single pyramid, there are separate

hierarchies in regions, provinces, and villages. Even at the

‘bottom’ there are “complex pecking orders” and “a little power

goes a long way.”63 Society can be conceived in Migdal’s terms as

a web of patron-client links or in Jackson’s terms as “an extremely

complex molecule in which the different atoms have their separate

nuclei and their circling electrons, but the bonds between the

atoms can often be very weak and, indeed, many atoms have no bonds

61utrecht, “Indonesia’s Foreign,” p.184.

62MPO: Japan Asia Quarterly Review 12, Special Issue on“Japanese Transnational Enterprises in Indonesia,” no. 4, (1980),p.49.

63Rush, The Last Tree, p.35.

123

Page 134: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

between them at all.”64 This societal structure has important

implications for policy implementation. While policy development

is dominated by a small elite, subsequent rules must be filtered

through multiple layers of patron-client clusters and networks. As

policies are implemented, and work their way from the insulated

departments in Jakarta to the remote outer islands, state patrons

make particularistic concessions to their clients. If these

modifications were isolated, they would have little overall impact.

But taken as a whole they debilitate state capacity, and the actual

effect of policies often bears little resemblance to the original

content outlined in Jakarta.65

In sum, decisions and policies in the New Order are dominated

by the state -- in particular, President Suharto, the military, and

the bureaucracy. Parliament, political parties, interest groups,

the media, students, and academics are peripheral. Business has

more influence, though this is constrained by pervasive anti

64Jackson, “The Political Implications,” p.35.

65Poor policy implementation is reinforced by a culturalsuspicion of action. Jackson argues that “as designing plans isrelatively passive while implementation requires action, attentionand high status go with the former rather than the latter.Progress in bureaucracies is often impressive until the moment whenimplementation is required.” Ibid., p.39. An example is the 1982Environmental Management Act which contains an impressive set ofprinciples. There are, however, still no implementing regulations.According to MacAndrews, “Without these regulations, cases taken tocourt under this Act have often been dismissed for lack of anadequate legal basis.” MacAndrews, “Politics of the Environment,”p.379, footnote 16.

124

Page 135: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

Chinese sentiments.66 Yet, even though the state excludes societal

input into policy formulation, extensive patron-client ties among

the political elite, in the military, in the bureaucracy, and

between members of these institutions and business, regional, and

community leaders have a profound impact on the implementation of

policies. For the management of timber, these ties drive

destructive practices and undermine state capacity to implement

policies.

PATRON-CLIENT POLITICS AND TIMBER MANAGEMENT IN INDONESIA

Background

Under the 1945 Constitution, all primary forests in Indonesia

are owned by the state. The 1967 Basic Forestry Law is the

foundation for forestry regulations. The total land area of

Indonesia is about 190 million hectares. Officially, Indonesia has

143 million hectares of forests, mainly on the outer islands.67

Conservation areas, such as National Parks and Wildlife Reserves,

cover 19 million hectares. Another 30 million hectares are set

aside as Protection Forest, mostly for soil and water conservation.

66See Maclntyre, Business and Politics, p.3. He argues thatbusiness leaders have had greater leverage over policy formulationsince the mid-1980s, partially due to more pribuini Indonesianbusinesses. Maclntyre focuses on legislation - - on the content ofpolicy. He examines how business groups have fought to overturnregulations (e.g., spinning industry), have resisted theintroduction of specific measures (e.g., pharmaceutical industry),and have attempted to convince the state to introduce legislation(e.g., insurance industry). He does not, however, look closely atproblems with enforcement, where businesses simple ignore or skirtregulations and laws.

67Around 82 million hectares are rain forests.

125

Page 136: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

A further 30 million hectares are Conversion Forest, areas

designated for conversion to agriculture, settlements, and

plantations, often after logging. The remaining 64 million

hectares are Production Forest, accounting for about 60 percent of

legal commercial timber in Southeast Asia. Production areas are

supposed to be managed sustainably, mostly by selective cutting in

primary and secondary forests.6 Numerous observers claim official

forestry statistics are inaccurate. A 1990 fine-resolution mapping

project estimated total forest cover at 108 million hectares. A

1990 World Bank study estimated total forest area at 100 million

hectares.69 The radical Indonesian NGO group SKEPHI (Network for

Tropical Forest Conservation) is even more pessimistic, claiming

This data was supplied by a Professor at Bogor AgriculturalUniversity, Faculty of Forestry, Bogor Indonesia, 25 February 1994.These figures are essentially the same as those used by theMinistry of Forestry. For government forestry data, see IndonesianMinistry of Forestry, Indonesia and the Management of its Forests(Jakarta: Republic of Indonesia, 1992); Indonesian Ministry ofForestry, The Timber Industry in Indonesia (Jakarta: Republic ofIndonesia, 1992); Indonesian Ministry of Forestry, The IndonesianTropical Rain Forest Conservation Areas (Jakarta: Republic ofIndonesia, 1990)

69Both these estimates are cited in WALHI (Indonesian Forum forthe Environment) and YLBHI (Indonesian Legal Aid Foundation),Mistaking Plantations For The Indonesia’s Tropical Forest,(Jakarta: Wahana Lingkungan Hidup Indonesia [WALHI], 1992), p.11.Also see Sandra Moniaga, “Status of Forest Resources in Indonesia,in JANNI, Reshaping “Development”: Indonesia-Japan Relation fromGrassroots’ Perspective, Proceedings of the INGI Kanagawa Symposium(Tokyo: Japan NGO Network on Indonesia [JANNI], 1993), pp.39-42.For a range of estimates, see Jill M. Blockhus, Mark R. Dillenbeck,Jeffrey A. Sayer and Per Wegge, eds., “Conserving BiologicalDiversity in Managed Tropical Forests,” Proceedings of a Workshopheld at the IUCN General Assembly Perth, Australia, 1990. (Gland:IUCN/ITTO, 1992), pp.45-46.

126

Page 137: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

only 90 million hectares of forest remain.70 Even a government

economist at the National Planning Agency estimated Indonesia’s

actual production forest area is only 32 million hectares, half the

official figure.7’

Numerous bureaucratic departments shape the environmental

management of timber concessions. The Ministry of Forestry -- with

a staff of 50,000 -- is responsible for collecting taxes and

royalties, setting annual allowable harvests, enforcing cutting and

silvicultural guidelines, and monitoring timber regulations.72 The

Ministry of Industry promotes the economic development of forest

resources. This ministry has been a key force behind the

development of wood processing. In 1978, the government formed the

State Ministry for Development Supervision and Environment, later

renamed the State Ministry for Population and the Environment, and

now called the State Ministry for the Environment. This Ministry

coordinates environmental management across departments, advises

departments on environmental issues, evaluates the environmental

impact of logging proposals, and monitors reforestation sites.

Other departments and ministries also influence forest management,

including Finance, Trade, Agriculture, Transmigration, Public

70SKEPHI, Forest Management Is Inefficient, Position Paper ForAustria Parliament (Jakarta, SKEPHI, 1993), p.2.

71Sunimarized in. Rush, The Last Tree, p.36.

721n 1983, the Directorate-General of Forestry of the Ministryof Agriculture became a ministry and was named the Ministry ofForestry.

127

Page 138: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

Works, and Energy and Mines.73

POLITICIANS, PATRONAGE, AND CHINESE TIMBER CLIENTS

Approximately 500 concessionaires, under the control of about

50 conglomerates, have licences to log more than 60 million

hectares of Production Forests. Between 1989 and 1994, average

annual legal timber production was over 30 million cubic metres.

Concession holders log around 800,000 hectares a year, more than

the rest of Southeast Asia conibined.74 Already by mid-1990, 25

million hectares had been logged.75 About two-thirds of logging

conglomerates are controlled by Chinese-Indonesians. Non-Chinese

timber businesses are limited mainly to local companies. Chinese

companies, however, must rely on politicians for concessions and

licences, on military officers for protection, and on bureaucrats

for ‘flexible’ interpretation of management rules. Among

Indonesian-Chinese timber leaders, Bob Hasan is the most powerful

figure.76 He is the head of four trade associations, including

73See Malcolm Gillis, “Indonesia: public policies, resourcemanagement, and the tropical forest,” in Malcolm Gillis and RobertRepetto, eds., Public Policies and the Misuse of Forest Resources(Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1988), pp.50-51; and

Malcolm Gillis, “Multinational Enterprises and Environmental andResource Management Issues in the Indonesian Tropical ForestSector,” in Charles S. Pearson, ed., Multinational Corporations,Environment, and the Third World (Durham: Duke University Press,1987), pp.76-78.

74Raphael Pura, “Rapid Loss of Forest Worries Indonesia,” TheAsian Wall Street Journal (hereafter AWSJ), 3 February 1990, p.10.

75WALHI and YLBHI, Mistaking, p.12.

76For an interview with Hasan, see John Vidal, “High stakes inthe rainforest,” The Guardian, 19 October 1990.

128

Page 139: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

Apkindo, the Wood Panel Association that controls the plywood

industry. One forestry official aptly declared: “The forestry

department cooperates with Apkindo, but Apkindo really makes

policy.”77 Hasan’s power stems from his direct link to Suharto.78

Hasan -- who has the rights to log 2 million hectares -- and

President Suharto have had close ties since the late 1950s.

According to one insider, Hasan is the de facto Minister of

Forestry -- the formal Minister of Forestry or the State Minister

of the Environment can only challenge him to a limited degree.79

Asia’s largest timber operator is Prajogo Pangestu, a second

generation Indonesian-Chinese from Kalimantan. His main company is

P.T. Barito Pacific Timber.8° Like Hasan, Prajogo has close,

personal ties to Suharto.81 Prajogo’s timber concessions cover 5.5

million hectares -- the size of Switzerland -- and he employs more

77Adam Schwarz, “Timber troubles,” FEER, 6 April 1989, p.86.

78lnterview, Senior official, Bappenas, Ministry of Planning,4 March 1994.

79This official claimed that Hasan is primarily motivated by adesire to build his ‘empire’, and although he sometimes sounds‘green’, he has little concern for environmental issues.Confidential Interview, Senior Indonesian official, Jakarta, 3March 1994.

80For a critical account of Barito Pacific Timber, see SKEPHI,Setiakawan, no. 10, January-June, 1993, pp.53-55.

81A leaked 1991 memo from Prajogo to Suharto illustrates theirclose relationship. In this memo, Prajogo asked Suharto toencourage the Forestry Minister, Hasjrul Harahap, to “facilitatethe paperwork and financing for an industrial-tree plantation inSouth Sumatra.” According to FEER, Suharto responded by jotting anote to Harahap on the memo that “he should fulfil all of Prajogo’srequests.” Jonathan Friedland and Adam Schwarz, “Risks on Paper,”FEER, 12 March 1992, p.44.

129

Page 140: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

than 50,000 people. Prajogo is the world’s largest exporter of

tropical plywood, with annual sales around US$600 million. The

total value of Prajogo’s forest land, logging infrastructure and

plywood mills is US$5-6 billion. His Barito Pacific Group of

companies is also the largest borrower of state funds, with more

than US$1 billion in loans. In 1992, he received “an unusually

attractive. . .debt rescheduling that stretched repayment periods on

about US$460 million in timber industry borrowings into the next

century.”82 He has recently established huge state-subsidized

softwood plantations to supply a US$1 billion pulp and paper mill.

His partner is Siti Hardijanti Rukmana, Suharto’s eldest child.

Not surprisingly, Prajogo has made substantial ‘donations’ to

charities and social programs connected to Suharto’s family.

Prajogo has also reportedly helped rescue poor investments linked

to Suharto and the military.83 Prajogo and his wife also

conscientiously “nurture the relationship [with Suharto] with small

gestures, such as gifts of home-cooked treats from Mrs. Prajogo’s

home province of North Sulawesi.hIM

82Raphael Pura, “Timber Tycoon Confronts His Critics,” AWSJ, 27August 1993, p.8.

83Prajogo’s timber holdings are discussed by Raphael Pura,“Timber Tycoon Confronts His Critics,” AWSJ, 27 August 1993, p.1and p.8; Raphael Pura, Stephen Duthi and Richard Borsuk, “PlywoodTycoon May Purchase Malaysian Firm, AWSJ, 3 February 1994, p.1 andp.4; and Adam Schwarz, “Forest Framework,” FEER, 12 March 1992,p.44.

84Raphael Pura, “Timber Tycoon Confronts His Critics,” AWSJ, 27August 1993, p.8.

130

Page 141: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

MILITARY LEADERS AND TIMBER

In 1967, Suharto distributed timber concessions to reward

loyal generals, appease potential military dissidents, and

supplement the military budget. In 1978, the Department of Defense

(Hankam) business group P.T. Tn Usaha Bhakti, along with regional

military commands, controlled at least fourteen timber companies.85

Today the military is still heavily involved in logging. For

example, in East Kalimantan, the International Timber Corporation

of Indonesia (ITCI), operates a 600,000 hectare concession, the

largest in Indonesia. As well, by the year 2000, ITCI plans to

develop 140,000 hectares of timber plantations. Fifty-one percent

of this company is controlled by the armed forces.86 Of the

remaining shares, P.T. Bimantara Citra -- a conglomerate chaired by

Suharto’s second son, Banibang Trihatmodjo -- holds 34 percent while

Hasan owns 15 percent. According to Hasan, the military uses its

profits to augment its official budget and build houses for

so1diers) P.T. Yamaker -- which logs concessions in East

85Robison, “Toward A Class Analysis,” p.28. These companieswere backed by Chinese and foreign funds.

861n the early 1970s, ITCI’s major shareholders included themost powerful generals of the New Order. According to Hurst,ITCI’s concession was in effect a “pay-off from Suharto for theloyalty of Indonesia’s military elite.” Philip Hurst, RainforestPolitics: Ecological Destruction in South-East Asia (London: ZedBooks, 1990), p.34.

Based on ITCI (International Timber Corporation Indonesia),PT. International Timber Corporation Indonesia (Jakarta: ITCI,1992); Rush, The Last Tree, pp.36-37; Raphael Pura, “Rapid Loss ofForest Worries Indonesia,” AWSJ, 3 February 1990, p.10; and StevenErlanger, “For Suharto, His Heirs are Key to Life After ‘93,” TheNew York Times International, 11 November 1990, p.Y1l.

131

Page 142: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

Kalimantan near the border with Borneo Malaysia - - is another

timber company linked to the army. This is deemed necessary for

security. Not surprisingly, with strong military protection, there

is little bureaucratic supervision of logging in these remote

areas. According to one insider, convoys of trucks smuggle illegal

logs to Sabah.88

Patron-client ties between state leaders and timber operators

weaken state supervision of bureaucratic implementors and distort

state management policies. In the last few years, state leaders

have declared a crackdown on illegal loggers and tax evaders.

Despite the rhetoric, however, the state has had minimal impact on

corporate practices. Instead, top state patrons and powerful

business clients continue to reap huge profits while middle-level

state implementors continue to ignore state rules in exchange for

bribes, gifts, and career stability. As we will see in the next

section, the result is rampant illegal logging, timber smuggling,

tax and royalty evasion, flagrant violations of logging rules, and

avoidance of reforestation duties. As well, these patron-client

ties have contributed to inappropriate and ineffective policies for

plywood processing, foreign investment, conservation, and pulp and

paper plantations.

88Confidential Interview, Senior Indonesian official, Jakarta,3 March 1994.

132

Page 143: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

FORESTRY POLICIES ND PATRON-CLIENT POLITICS

A. Logging Rules and Concession Distribution

Until the late 1980s, Indonesian logging was regulated by the

Selective Cutting System (TPI). This system divided concessions

into 35 areas which were then logged annually on a 35 year cycle.

Loggers were only allowed to cut trees with a diameter of 50

centimetres or more at breast height. As well, if less than 25

trees with a diameter between 25-49 centimetres remained in a

logged hectare, companies had to do enrichment planting.89 In

1989, the government established a new cutting policy -- called the

Indonesian Selective Cutting and Replanting System (TPTI). Logging

guidelines are essentially the same, although now loggers are

required to replant commercial species. This current policy has

made little difference. According to the NGO WALHI (Forum For the

Environment) and the Indonesian Legal Aid Foundation, “it wasn’t

application of a faulty management system, but rather the failure

to apply any management system which resulted in so much

degradation. Although improving management policies is useful, in

reality the key to better forest management is better

implementation and tighter enforcement.”9° There are certainly

problems with timber management rules. For example, while

companies are allowed to log areas on a 35 five year cycle,

licences are only granted for 20 years, with no guarantee of

89For details on TPI, see Hurst, Rainforest, pp.lG-17. For acritique of Indonesian selective logging rules, see Gillis,“Indonesia: public policies,” pp.63-65.

90WALHI and YLEHI, Mistaking, pp.59-60.

133

Page 144: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

renewal. This obviously makes little sense.9’ But in the context

of Indonesian politics this discrepancy is not critical. Even if

concession licences were granted for 100 years, it would make

little difference since it is clear to loggers -- especially ethnic

Chinese -- that a shift in political or military power could change

the rules overnight.

Historical allocation of timber concessions contributes to

current management problems. Starting in the mid-l960s, Suharto

awarded concessions to numerous loyal military and political

clients. In 1970, to quash provincial claims to timber areas

Suharto had awarded as ‘presents’, the authority to distribute

concessions was centralized under the Directorate-General of

Forestry. As a result, small-scale loggers without Jakartan ties

lost their concessions; many resorted to illegal logging. Jakarta-

based concessionaires often had little forestry knowledge or

capital, and turned to Mt\TCs and Indonesian-Chinese companies to

handle logging operations.92 This split between control of

concessions and management of timber operations continues today,

reducing accountability and transparency. According to Mariko

Urano, “the increase in these absentee concessionaires has

91Barbier, Burgess, and Markandya, “The Economics of TropicalDeforestation,” p.57.

92Despite needing sub-contractors, concessions were stillexcellent ‘presents’ since profits were huge and fast. Interview,Bogor Agricultural University, Faculty of Forestry, BogorIndonesia, 28 February 1994.

134

Page 145: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

H w

dcirtL

IJ-J

iIC

!)

t-•

HQ

QQ

H-

CI(

D0

Hrt

H-M

ii<

(vp.

C)p

IC)

H-

i-iC

(DM

iMi

H-H

-Ir

tCD

HC

D(D

U)C

DH

jIo

Mi

U)•0

rt0

DIh

Qrt

IH

-ct

()I

=C

DH

-<

U)C

Drt-

CD

HH

-fl

CDI-

uJ

--P

)U

)t3

Q)<

ç-t

HC

DC

D(D

HrfH

Hp

jH

U)0

U)I-

PiU

)CD

t12

0ç(D

-

--

H-

0C

)•0p

U)

:CD

P)u-

HP

i-::

3U)

IrJ

jZ

0C

DP

iH

C-t

II-H

-P

U)P

iCD

bi

Pix

jçH

-”

ilCD

oH

-cl

N0

C)

-

Ct

HH

-I-

CD

CtF

jO

j.

ljC

)H0L

QH

U)’

rt0

0C

DjC

D3

—t:

-’‘II

HC

tCD

ICD

HCD

Cr

H-C

)tQ

I1

i]

CD

HU

)CD

WC

Dn

[- CD

‘rt

MC

tW

L’i

OH

Mi

CD•E

‘0U

)P)

’t39

)OC

DC

DIj

Mir

tW

CD

c(D

HM

i9)

(tC

lM

iM

iH

-CI

HC

)ItJ

I<

C)

Ct

HH

ij

09)

cl

=rr

1C

DC

flC

D-

‘-

0H-

(DO

•.O

Cr

HrrH

Oç1

tJH

O(D

Hrr9)’

(.Q

CD

rr.

MiH

Pic

u0H

iU)

MiO

Cti

‘rJH

rrW

H-

Oh

IO-

H-

HC

r3C

tC

DC

DC

lW

CD

Cl

0pjP

iH

0H

MiH

’9)

ClC

tI

‘ti

CDrtH

<C

JDQ

U)

CDC1)

hIC

lC

)O

-C

rMiH

-H

CDhIhIC

D(D

U)H

9)j9)

HC

rP)o

ClH

U]P

iC)N

H-h

I’-D

H-3

Ht

1)

CD

xj

‘dcD

-C

lC

)O

-I-j

CD

hIr

tCD

0‘O

CD

U)C

DC

DH

dtI

CD

CD

U)U

)U

)H

-U)U

)CD

H0(l

)P

JP

)CrH

-oU

,C

DH

-rt

t-C)

H-h

Ih

II1

0iH

H9)h

I9)

<hI’

CDH

9)CD

0C)

3CD

HU)

H-

Ct

9)9)

h9)

Mi

9)9)

Mi

0H

-3

C)CD

Mi

rtM

i‘d

U)M

iCl

HC)

0CD

H-

9)H

-0

CDH

H0

CDII

hIC)

O-

C)I-I

Cl)hI

H-

H9)

C)H

-CD

H0

9)CD

<CD

0H

CDH

-CD

9)hI

Cl)C

rC)

U)H

-CD

9)C)

iiH

U)‘-<

H-

U)3

C)CD

9)CD

9)H

-C

rC)

çO-

0CD

-0

0C

rC

jCD

CDM

i(I)

Mi

hIC

lCD

Mi

U)C

rH

--

H-

U)9)

9)0

-CD

CDO

-CD

Mi

U)C

tCD

CDC

rh

hI0

9)H

-)

<C

r

Cl

HW

CDH

CCD

ç-t

rt9)

HC)

Cr

frj)

pc

Ct

.<0

0CD

Cr

Cl)

Ct

CDCl)

0Q

‘1U)

CD-‘

Cl

HH

(Qr

9)H ui

H-

9)H

-0

CDO-

HhI

‘JM

i0

HC

t)

Ct

Hi

CDH

-9)

0H

-C)

Ct

Ct

CD0

CDCD

Mi

CDCD

CD

3Q

CD&

hICD

CDC

rCD

0hI

H-

HH

H-

hIhI

U)

H9)

hC)

ç19)

CD‘<

Ct

tOC

hICD

H-

U)H

-9)

rrM

ihI

LCD

39)

‘(1)

9)C

l(

H<

CDCD

Cl

U)0

9)(.Q

U)H

CDCD

hICD

Cr

HhI

H-

Cr

Cr

CDff

H.o

U)H

9).

rtU

)C

l<

Mi

H(-

t9)

H-

CDC

r0

Cl

CDC

tQ

hIl

H<

CDCD

çt

9)H

-C)

H-

9)9)

jjj

0C

rQ

CC

r9)

U)CD

Cr

CDCD

Ct

HH

-H

CD9)

0CD

‘CD

CDCD

Q(I)

ç-t

Cl

0rr

QCD

O-

Cr

H-

9)U)

HhI

=9)

03

9)0

CDO

-H

CD3 Ci)

CDCD

dCD

U)Cl

1hI

<C

rC

l4

H-

H-

CDCD

CD9)

(H

-

hICD

Cl

O-

Cr

Cl

0H

-H

iCD

CDC)

0rt

Ct

9)hI

H-

C!)

9)C

rC

C)CD

U)C

lH

CI)CD

Cr

CDCD

hI<

9)H

iD

Cl

CDC

r9)

CD0

H-

0U)

CD0

<U)

thI

Cr

0-

H0

CDCD

CDCD

Cr

U)H

-hI

9)U)

O-

ci

(OU)

9)I-

Mi

Mi

Cr

CDCD

Cr

9)9)

CDto

‘-QC

l0

0hI

CDhI

H-

Ct

HCD

U)hI

hI<

3CD

Cl

CD<

Ui

0

Page 146: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

H w 0)

‘0 ‘0

Cl)

H-

(CC

)H

-H

CD

(‘0 00

C)(D

C)

CD1

C)

•0

H-

tfl

1 - ‘-3q

H(D

p)

1 U)H

Cli

CD

.CD -

Cl 1. C

n

0 CtL

ClH

(D<

pi H-

H

‘0 —1

FL

J HO

Cl

C)1

:rC

l0 C

D(D

H ‘0= 0 CD H

•pJ Cl

) H-

Cl) pJ It’ CD pI ‘1 H U.

H CD ‘—3 CD 0 H 0 CD pi

IIC)

C)H

P9)

HH

-G

-9)

HU)

9)9)

if

‘..DCD

I-Cl)

CD<

9)9)

1H

H-

Cl

—]

Cl)

CD‘-C

i0

CDC)

‘-Ci

CD9)

Cl)C

lC

l0

Cl

Cl)(f

(I)H

-H

-Cl)

F-‘-C

i‘-C

i9)

09)

CDH

CDC)

°CD

9)IQ

C)frt

,(.Q

I-CD

0C

DfrC

D(1)

Cl

HCD

H-

9)0

çl

LC

lC

lj

H-

CDh

1H

-CD

Qçt

=•

9)‘<

Cl

H-

CDZ

CD°°C

lC

Drtg

H0

HCD

pi

CD0

CDC)

Hj

Cl)

!E;-‘<

H-

•U)

IIH

-U) C

l0

CDC)

0C

lCD

I-

0CD

CDH

IC)

C)1

$‘C

lU)

ClH

Cl)H

-9)

(.Qpj

CDi

H-

HW

CDH

H-

oQ

H-

DCl)

jCD

H-

DCl)

hC

)W

H-

CDCF

Cl)

Cl)

‘-Ci

-.

9)P

9)U)

çt

CDCD

U)Cl

)C

lH

Cl

IICl

)‘1

-C

lC

lJ

HC

l‘<

H-

CDC)

piCD

CDC

lC

l0

9’Cr

CD‘<

9C

lC)

fr0

Hi

9)CD

Cl

9)P

iU)

-i

CF

CDCD

)-9)

H-

CDC

l9’

I-(D

i-pi

H-

9)Q

CDt

CDH

-C)

)CD

U)

HC

FH

IC

H-

Cl)C

FC

F9)

0H

-9)

U)U)

H-

0LQ

Cl

‘<CD

9’CD

U)H

HCF

H‘1

Cl

H-

0C

lCD

‘-

H-

Cl

H-

CD0

9)H

H-

0C

l1

M-,

CDH

Cl

CD0

Cl

<_C)

Cl)

U)Cl)

0(D

1<

Cl

‘-Ci

QH

HCl

Cl)

‘-Ci

‘-ii

00

0H

CD1

piH

0CD

CDCD

HH

Cl

1tp

CDCl

)i

U)H

-CD

(DH

-II

WC

lC)

CDH

-U)

CD0

‘-Ci

Cl

H-

CD0

piCD

H-

LQH

‘-

CDCD

Cl

C)H

-H

CDCD

H‘1

9)0

Hi

gC

l<

CDH

-CD

CD0

IIH

-C)

HM

iII

‘CD

‘Cl

CD1

Cl

H-

H-

CFCD

U)C

lH

-&

Cl

0H

-C

lb

Cl

CF

CDII

<H

CDJ

CD9)

9)Cl)

CDC

l(.

‘1CD

CDCD

CD‘-<

Cl)CD

IIU)

-II

0

Page 147: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

I-’C

DC

DI-

U))

rtH

xj

‘1 ix

j

CD

CD

QtJ

)rI

xjx

jLi

iLx

iLI

ILi

i

H t.J

Qpi

c)CD

C)0

<C)

1JCD

C)U)

U)CD

c-I-

U)U)

•U)

Cr

H-

H-

0 pi

Hi

O rnCD H H

Hi

—C

rH

iCl)

H (I)

ci H

HH

‘S.D

p) H-

CDH 0

oH

CD:l)

)U)

U)w

pi

HCD

H.:

H- o

U) C)M

iCD

piCD o

c-t

CH

-CD

Pb

iiII

HU)

CD(1)

Cl)CD P3

oc-i

CI)

Hi

0‘<

H-

WH

CDCD

CD0

‘1U)

P.’CC

)U)

tQ

Cr

<c-

rH

-H

-(

QH

-CD

HH

-CD

CDC)

P.’b

P.’C)

U)LQ

Cr

c-I-

CDc-

IC

rH

-CD

CDCD

HP

U)H

-CD

H-

Cr

U)c-

IC

rCl)

Hi

CD0

4-

0P.’

<p.’

jc-

tCD

c-r

CDc-I

-0

Cl)

0‘<

oU)

CD

CrQ

00

CrH

iQO

<•w CD

c-I-

1H

CDH

L’

:iC)

H-

p.’O

CDC

rC)

H(.Q

c-t

0LQ

-h

H-

p.CD

HH

p.,

(X1

t3p.

,CD

Cl)CD

(.Qpj

0Cl)

C)U)

Cr

Cr

0H

-H

ip.

,•

P.’U)

CDH

-U)

‘CD

))C

r

p.’‘1 0 <H

Hi H

CDc-I

-0H

oH

i0

o0

0II

P.’‘1

‘-1o

HCD

oi

CDCD

C)

HU)

II0

(1.,

oCl)

c-C)

CDCD

W(1)

0p.’

‘C)

P.’Cl)

C)c-I

-C

rc-

rc-I

-P.’

Mi

H-

ICl)

HU)

c-I-

CDO

Hp,

C)CD

U)h

p.’Cl

)o

c-t

-H

-0

Qc-I

-M

iCD

Hi

<U)

CD

0 Hi

c-I-

CD,i

Lii

U)m

P.’Cl

)H

c-I-

c-r

H-

0pj

Hi

HH

H-

c-I-

Op.’

CDLQ

Cl)CD

c-I-

CD1:

1P.’

CDCD

p.’c-I

-H

-hI

0CD

P.’H

c-I-

P.’ c-I

H-

CD.‘

0Cl)

Cl)c-I

-Cl

)‘-‘I o

p.’0

‘<Ii

Hi

CDk<

•P.’

L)

Cl)

CD

O.‘ H

CDC

DH

i IICD

Mi

Ho

c-I-

CDhI

Cl)

c-I-

CD-

PJC

D

C)h

I p.’

“op.’

p.’ SC

,)t1

DC

)

H U)

PJ

ci

Pil

l

C)

H c-I-

CD p.,

H 1:11

II U) c-I

p.’ H Hi

0 ‘-I CD Cl)

c-I

H ci

I

tili

IiIi

I-ICD

P.’Lx

iCD

OP

.CD

U)H

C)W

OU

)OH

-<C

DO

U)H

hIH

ic-I--

hIP

.’h

I3H

-H

C)O

CDCD

CDH

CD

c-I

hI0

H3

”O

U)

P.’p.,C

DO

CD

Hh

IH‘L

iic-

IL

OP

.’-

C)P

ip.’

0P’C

DO

pH

Hp.’

c-I-d

0•

H

‘dP

JH

p.,

c-I

,i

IiH

-I

p.’W

H-

CD0

Hj

Cl)

,j

Wp.,O

OuiU

)WU

)C

)Mi

cY

-’<

LII

H-

•P

bp.

’P

)O

i<

Hc-r

I-

(D

0IIJ

‘-‘

U)U

)H

OC

D’-

Pd

CDO

(DCD

P)C

DH

i1,-

HlC

)pl

0H

-CD

pc-

tH

bU

)ll

LJ.U

)c-t

CD

HP

.’0

Lh

iU)P

.’H

:ip

c-I-

OO

HM

-,CD Ci)

;Piq

Iii

Hi(

“-‘

H-

hI

0C

DP.

’o

bU

)CD

CDt1O

i”

bC

Dp.

’llP

H0

H-

CD0

>‘CD

ij

hh

P4

CD0

dp.

’CD

P.,F

lH

Ijll

CD

P0

U)H

iH

-CD

O0

Hc-I

>C

Db

P)

Pc-I

-C

DH

-1c-I

--

I-IU

)<

OH

-’tl

P.’c-I

-(D

C)

P.’P.’

‘-1CD

c-t

oc-tI

lc-I-U

)U

)C

r•

H-O

H-H

-H-

CD0

P0

c-I-

P.’H

-I-I

HP

i:i

U)

CD

p.’II 0 0 O

tt,

II‘t

ip.’

P O= P.’ H p.,

0 U) Cl) 0 Hi

0 II CD U) c-I

0 II II H-

CD U) H p.,

0 CD U) H P.’

Cl)P.’

Cr

p.,

H-

HCl)

HCl

)0 N CD II Cr 0 CD Cr P.’ p.’ C) 0 H

i

C) H “p p.’ II CD Cr

Cr

CD Cl) 0

Page 148: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

tropical forest burned in Kalimantan, an area as large as

Holland.’05 In late 1994, raging fires in Sumatra and Borneo

disrupted airline flights, and polluted the air for thousands of

square kilometres •106

With almost no state control over timber operators, illegal

logging is rampant. Illegal logging is connected to high-ranking

political and military leaders, police, regional administrators,

customs agents, and forestry staff.’°7 In 1993, total timber

production was around 35 million cubic metres. Yet illegal logging

may be equivalent to legal logging, putting total log production at

about 70 million cubic metres,’°8 far above FAQ’s conservative

estimate of sustainable production at 25 million cubic metres per

year.’°9 Logging companies use various techniques to evade timber

‘°5Peyton Johnson, “Fire in the Mother Lung,” CERES FAQ 24,no.3, (May-June, 1992), p.34; SICEPHI, Forest Fire Profile inIndonesia (Jakarta: SKEPHI, 1992). SKEPHI is critical of the lackof Northern assistance in combatting these fires. SKEPHI,Setiakawan, no. 7, January-June, 1992, pp.44-46.

‘°6As of mid-October, around 500,000 hectares had burned and thefires were still out of control. “Burning rainforest spreads pallover Southeast Asia,” The Vancouver Sun, 18 October 1994, p.A17;and S. Jayasan]caran and John McBeth, “Hazy Days,” FEER, 20 October1994, pp.66-67.

‘°7Many senior Indonesian forestry academics are funded bytimber money and therefore are unwilling to document extensiveillegal logging. Interview, WALHI, Jakarta, 3 March 1994.

‘°8lnterview, Bogor Agricultural University, Faculty ofForestry, Bogor Indonesia, 28 February 1994; and Interview, CentreFor International Forestry Research (CIFOR), Bogor Indonesia, 2March 1994.

‘°9Summarized in Adam Schwarz, “Timber is the test,” FEER, 23July 1992, p.36. A World Bank study estimated that Indonesia’sannual sustainable yield is only 22 million cubic metres.Summarized in Gareth Porter, “The Environmental Hazards of Asia

138

Page 149: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

quotas. Loggers over-harvest their concessions and cut trees in

National Parks and conservation areas.

Smuggling rings involving top military, political and business

leaders, as well as local forestry officials, security officers and

foreign business executives (particularly Malaysians) transport

many of these logs outside the country.”° There are strong signs

that Japanese companies are purchasing illegal logs from

Kalimantan, and moving them through Borneo Malaysia.’1’ In 1992,

timber smuggling reportedly cost the state 135 billion rupiah.”2

Domestic processors -- who face a chronic shortage of supply -- are

also deeply involved in illegal logging.”3 This is hardly

surprising since annual capacity of plywood plants and sawmills is

60 million cubic metres, about twice as high as the Forestry

Department’s estimate of sustainable production.”4 As a result,

Pacific Development: The Southeast Asian Rainforests,” CurrentHistory (December 1994), p.431.

“°According to local Forestry service data, loggers smugglebetween 50,000 to 100,000 cubic metres of illegal timber every yearfrom West Kalimantan to Borneo Malaysia. SKEPHI, Setiakawan, no.11, July-September 1993, pp.31-33.

“Interview, Environmental consultant, Bogor Indonesia, 24February 1994; and Nectoux and Kuroda, Timber, p.73.

“2As±an Timber, January 1993, p.9.

“3Debra J. Callister, Illegal Tropical Timber Trade: AsiaPacific (Cambridge, United Kingdom: Traffic International, 1992),p.30.

“4This incongruity is partially a result of poor coordinationbetween the Ministry of Forestry and the Ministry of Industry. TheMinistry of Industry set the capacity of plywood mills, stressingintense production to maintain rapid economic growth. Interview,Bogor Agricultural University, Faculty of Forestry, BogorIndonesia, 28 February 1994.

139

Page 150: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

processors are constantly scrambling for more logs. According to

a concession director, one way concessionaires increase supply is

by hiring local people to cut logs illegally. These logs are

reported ‘stolen’ and then bought back to feed the company’s

processing mill h15

B. Licence Fees, Royalty Policies, and Timber Taxes

Concession holders must pay uniform ad valorem royalties on

the volume of logs extracted. This aggravates logging

mismanagement since loggers face few penalties for damaging timber

stocks and have no incentives to cut defective or low grade timber.

Instead, loggers concentrate on removing the largest and most

valuable species, often creating irreparable ecological harm.”6

Poorly designed and insufficient licence fees, royalties and

export taxes have contributed to Indonesia capturing a low

percentage of timber rents. According to Repetto, from 1979 to

1982, “only $1.6 billion of a potential aggregate rent of $4.4

billion” was collected by the government -- the remainder became

private prof it.”7 In 1992, the World Bank estimated that the

“5lnterview, Indonesian concessionaire, Jakarta, 3 March 1994.

‘16Gillis, “Indonesia: public policies,” pp.59-60; and Barbier,et., al., “The Economics,” pp.56-57.

117Robert Repetto, The Forest For The Trees? Government Policiesand the Misuse of Forest Resources (Washington: World ResourcesInstitute, 1988), p.43. For more details, see Gillis, “Indonesia:public policies,” pp.85-98. “Rent, by definition, is a value inexcess of the total costs of bringing trees to market as logs orwood products, including the cost of attracting necessaryinvestment. That cost may include a risk premium that reflectsuncertainties about future market and political conditions, so

140

Page 151: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

Indonesian government collected only 30 percent of the economic

rent from logging, compared with 85 percent for petroleum.”8 Even

more alarming, a study by WALHI found that the government captured

a mere 8 percent of timber rents in 1989. In 1990, after an

increase in reforestation fees and timber taxes, WALHI calculated

that the government still captured only 17 percent of timber rents.

According to a WALHI representative little has changed since then;

the government now captures around 15 percent of timber rents.”9

Low government rent collection has important implications.

Loggers -- to maximize profits before rules suddenly change --

quickly and recklessly extract logs while ignoring silvicultural

treatments, reforestation and sustainable management. According to

one study, “when rent capture is low, it allows windfall profits to

the concessionaires and/or their logging contractors. Inevitably,

windfalls are perceived as short-term gains, and the beneficiaries

there are inevitably doubts about the exact magnitude of availablerents.” Robert Repetto, “Overview,” in Gillis and Repetto, eds.,Public Policies, p.18.

“8Sunimarized in Adam Schwarz, “Timber is the test,” FEER, 23July 1992, p.36.

“9WALHI and YLBHI, Mistaking, pp.20-21; and Interview, WALHI,Jakarta, 3 March 1994. There is a wide range of estimates oftimber rent captured by the government, from a low of 8-15 percentby WALHI to a high of 83 percent by a government consultant. Moststudies fall in a range between 20 to 30 percent. For a list ofstudies, see Dudung Darusman, “The Economic Rent of Tropical ForestUtilization in Indonesia,” A Paper Presented at the NationalSeminar on the Economic Aspect of the Forestry Business inIndonesia, the Association of Forest Concessioners and the Ministryof Forestry, Jakarta, October 6-7, 1992, p.17.

141

Page 152: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

will maximize them, as long as they last.”2° Low rent capture

also creates a de facto subsidy that supports inefficient wood

processing. As well, it allows exporters to sell high-grade timber

at exceptionally low prices. The state needs to collect economic

rents since private companies cannot be relied on to plough profits

back into forest regeneration. Since reforestation and sustainable

management involve long-term returns and high financial risks, and

require political stability, corporations have a strong inclination

to invest timber profits into other ventures, especially real

estate which does not involve production, reinvestment, government

licences, or concessions.121

Even though low Indonesian forest charges allow companies to

make substantial legal profits, loggers routinely forge export

documents, falsify harvest yields, illegally log inside and outside

concessions, and ignore reforestation fees. According to one

corporation, 19 out of 21 timber companies in South Sumatra

manipulate their export documents to evade taxes.’22 Companies

also elude royalties and distort figures on volume extracted by

reusing timber transportation documents, sometimes as many as 5

times 123

‘20lndonesian Ministry of Forestry and FAQ, Indonesian TropicalForestry Action Programme: Executive Summary (Jakarta, Governmentof Indonesia and the United Nations, 1991), p.44.

‘21Robison, “Toward A Class Analysis,” p.33.

‘22Suirimarized in SKEPHI, Setiakawan, no. 11 (July-September1993), p.31.

‘23SKEPHI, Setiakawan, no. 8 (July-September 1992), p.3.

142

Page 153: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

C. Foreign Investment Policies

Prior to the mid-1960s, logging on the outer islands was

limited. After 1967, government incentives under the new Foreign

Capital Investment Law opened a door to large Northern and smaller

Southern MNC5, triggering a logging boom in the primary forests.’24

From 1968 to 1980, the volume of logs extracted increased on

average 22.5 percent every year. By 1979, 89 percent of production

forest was divided into concessions.’25 During the late 1960s and

early 1970s, foreign timber technology and management advice

accelerated the rate of extraction.’26 Mt\TC5 made enormous profits

by paying little for timber rights, ‘mining’ concessions of the

most valuable trees, ignoring reforestation, refusing to invest

profits in processing or rehabilitation, and avoiding taxes and

‘241n the 1970s, major foreign investors in the Indonesiantimber sector were from the Philippines, Hong Kong, Malaysia, theUnited States, South Korea, and Japan. Before 1980, Southern firmsaccounted for two-thirds of foreign investment in the Indonesiantimber sector. From 1978 to 1981 Japanese investment expanded. Buteven in 1981 Southern firms still comprised over half of foreigntimber investment. Gillis, “Multinational Enterprises,” p.73. Thesignificant impact of Southern investment -- and increasinglytrade -- on Indonesian timber management suggests an important areafor future research: contrasting the impact of Southern andNorthern MNCs on resource management. For a preliminary comparisonof the environmental impact of Northern and Southern MNCs onIndonesian timber management, see Ibid., pp.84-86.

‘25Gillis, “Multinational Enterprises,” p.70.

‘26See Economic and Social Commission For Asia and the Pacific,Transnat±onal Corporations and the Tropical Hardwood Industry ofIndonesia, United Nations, Joint CTC/ESCAP Unit on TransnationalCorporations, Working Paper no. 16, Bangkok, 1981, pp.1-2. WhileSouthern investors accounted for over half of Indonesian timberinvestment, many of these companies used equipment and techniquesabsorbed from earlier contact with Northern companies.

143

Page 154: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

royalties through transfer pricing.127 Many of these giant logging

operations were in Kalimantan. By 1971, 65 percent of timber

produced came from Kalimantan; 75 percent was exported. By 1974,

around 11 million hectares of Kalimantan had been carved into

timber concessions •128

During the 1960s and 1970s, multinational timber profits and

log exports were lightly taxed. From 1967 until major tax reforms

in 1983, foreign timber investors received four to six year income

tax holidays -- which in practice sometimes exempted firms from

paying any income tax.’29 As well, until 1978 log export taxes

were only 10 percent of export value, compared to around 20 percent

in Sabah.’3° As a result, companies made huge profits, nearly

doubling after-tax investment returns. Despite increases in

foreign exchange earnings from timber, in the early 1970s, the

Indonesian government began to restrict foreign investment. The

government was angry over low rates of reforestation, ‘unfair’ and

uncooperative foreign firms, evasion of timber taxes, and, most

importantly, the reluctance of MNCs to invest in processing. In

1975, the government forbid further foreign ownership or joint

ventures in logging, and only allowed equity shares in timber

‘27A.J. Leslie, “The government-TNC relationship in tropicaltimber concession contracts” (Unpublished paper, 1980), summarizedin Ibid., p.5.

‘28Hurst, Rainforest, p.2, and p.10.

‘29Th±s greatly reduced Indonesian state timber revenues.Gulls, “Indonesia: public policies,” pp.67-69.

‘30Gillis, “Multinational Enterprises,” p.68.

144

Page 155: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

processing.13’

D. Processing Policies

The first Five Year Plan, Repelita I (1969/70-1973/4)

emphasized log exports and increasing foreign exchange earnings.

During Repelita II (1974/5-1978/9), the central government pushed

concessionaires to build processing plants. Beginning in 1977, the

government collected a mandatory deposit on log exports to finance

construction of processing plants. To encourage more processing,

the Indonesian government doubled log export taxes in 1978.132

Foreign firms that refused to participate in processing had the

size of their concessions reduced. At the end of the 1970s, MNCs

began to withdraw in anticipation of even greater government

regulations and restrictions. Before leaving, however, many timber

companies mined their concessions. Partially as a result, in 1979

Indonesia accounted for 41 percent of the world market in tropical

logs 133

From 1980 to 1985, the government implemented a ban on log

exports.’34 The World Bank and all major industrialized countries

1311bid., pp.74-76.

‘32Gillis, “Indonesia: public policies,” p.69. To evade exportand income taxes both national and foreign firms were involved inundervaluing timber exports, including those to Japan. Gillis,“Multinational Enterprises,” p.68.

‘33Potter, “Environmental and Social Aspects,” p.186.

‘341n 1992, the ‘ban’ on log exports was lifted and replaced byastronomical taxes on log exports. This in effect maintains theban.

145

Page 156: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

-- including Japan, the U.S., and Canada -- opposed this decision,

based primarily on free-market arguments. Indonesia ignored this

pressure, concluding it was essential to control the market and

develop a timber processing industry. There were three key reasons

for this decision. One, to add value and diversify the economy

away from a heavy emphasis on oil exports. Indonesian planners

believed this would not occur in a free market. Two, to create

jobs. Three, to provide incentives for long-term forestry

investments.’35 While the government had ‘rational’ reasons for

imposing a ban, state capacity to implement this policy was greatly

increased by close cooperation and support from powerful domestic

business leaders who wanted to concentrate and consolidate control.

Hasan has played a crucial role in forming the state-business

alliance that has strictly imposed this ban.’36

With government support, Indonesia’s plywood industry grew

quickly -- from 29 plywood mills in 1980 to 111 mills in 1988, with

Senior official, Bappenas, Ministry of Planning,Jakarta, 4 March 1994. According to this government spokesman,more companies now replant to ensure future supplies for theirmills.

136Part of the reason the government has been able to enforcea ban on log exports is that it has increased, rather thanundermined, financial opportunities for the most powerful timbercompanies. On the other hand, the Indonesian state has not beenable to control over-exploitation and environmental mismanagement.Environmental concerns, as a low profile, low priority issuealigned against strong patron-client networks and businessinterests do not create the internal support necessary to generatestrong state action.

146

Page 157: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

a tenfold rise in production.137 Now there are over 130 plywood

mills. In 1991 Indonesia controlled 85 percent of world trade in

tropical plywood.138 In 1992, Indonesia exported 9.2 million cubic

metres of plywood. By 1993, forest exports earned US$4.5 billion;

plywood accounted for nearly 75 percent of these exports.139

Plywood manufacturing also generates significant employment and

foreign exchange.’4° Indonesia’s plywood export strategy has been

simple: flood the market with cheap plywood and destroy

competitors; once this is accomplished, gradually raise prices and

government taxes. In some ways, this strategy has been successful.

While the ban led to a temporary loss in foreign exchange earnings,

by 1988 -- using equipment supplied by Taiwan, South Korea, and

Japan -- Indonesia had regained its foreign exchange earnings. With

control over the world market in tropical plywood, Indonesia can

‘37William B Wood, “Tropical Deforestation: Balancing Regionaldevelopment demands and global environmental concerns,” GlobalEnvironmental Change 1, no. 1 (December 1990), p.34.

‘38M. Bob Hasan, Keynote Address, “Prospects for Plywood intothe 21st Century,” Proceedings of the World Conference on TropicalPlywood (Jakarta, ITTO, December 1991), p.21.

‘39”Indones±a to reduce tree cutting to help preserverainforests,” The Japan Times, 27 July 1994, p.18.

‘40Around 2.5 million people work directly in the timberindustry and 1.2 million work in related industries such as gluemanufacturing. In 1990, plywood exports accounted for 14 percentof total foreign exchange earnings. Hasan, “Prospects forPlywood,” p.24. It is, however, important to note that governmentand corporate statistics exaggerate the economic benefits of timberprocessing since “primary forest assets are established withoutcost. Harvesting depreciates what is a valuable stock but theeconomic accounting of timber operations does not include thisdepreciation as a cost.” Zerner, Legal Options, p.5.

147

Page 158: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

potentially be a ‘price leader.”4’ But despite these apparent

achievements, there have been major economic and environmental

drawbacks of building a processing industry.

Dated technology, protective state policies and the log export

ban have contributed to large numbers of inefficient processing

mills.’42 Even though many operate far below capacity -- some as

low as 30 percent -- these mills waste valuable wood, putting even

more pressure on forest Besides fostering

inefficiency and over-capacity, the ban on log exports and state

subsidies for processing -- including labour, electricity, and log

costs -- have contributed to enormous state revenue losses. One

study calculated that as a result of the phased log export ban,

between 1981 and 1986 the government lost US$1.9 to US$3.1 billion

‘41lnterview, Senior official, Bappenas, Ministry of Planning,Jakarta, 4 March 1994.

‘421n Japan, processing efficiency is between 55 to 70 percent;in Indonesia it is between 40 to 50 percent. In fairness toIndonesian processors, while this discrepancy is partly a result ofbetter Japanese technology, expertise, and policies, it is alsopartly due to differences in the quality of logs. Japaneseprocessors import high quality logs while local Indonesian millsoften use logs from the surrounding area, naturally decreasingefficiency. Interview, Japan Plywood Inspection Corporation,Tokyo, 8 April 1994.

‘43Carlos Alberto Primo Braga, “Tropical Forests and TradePolicy: The Cases of Indonesia and Brazil,” in Low ed.,International Trade and the Environment, p.190. While I have nosubstantive evidence, a government spokesman claims that manyprocessing mills have become more efficient since the mid-l980s.Interview, Senior Official, Bappenas, Ministry of Planning, 4 March1994.

148

Page 159: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

in export revenues.’44 By eliminating export restrictions, and

improving rent collection, the World Bank estimates that the

Indonesian government could collect another US$2 billion in

forestry fees every year. According to this report, the export ban

has depressed Indonesian log prices to around half the world level.

This has contributed to “over-cutting and over-investment in

processing capacity. “

Besides financial losses, the log export ban has added to

environmental problems. In 1960, log production was only 1.4

million cubic metres. Pushed by foreign investment and technology,

this climbed dramatically in the late 1960s and 1970s, reaching

24.6 million cubic metres in 1978. Between 1981 and 1985 as the

log export ban was gradually imposed, log production dropped by 35

percent.’46 Indonesian government and business leaders sometimes

point to this decrease in logging rates as proof of the

environmental benefits of the ban. But this was a temporary

respite. By 1988 log production was even higher, estimated at 32

million cubic metres.’47 Today, driven by strong demand from

domestic processors, there is even more pressure on the forests

‘Holly Lindsay, “The Indonesian Export Ban: An Estimation ofForegone Export Earnings,” Bulletin of Indonesian Economic Studies25, no. 2, (August 1989), pp.111-123.

145Quoted in Adam Schwarz, “Timber is the test,” FEER, 23 July1992, p.36.

‘46WALHI and YLBHI, Mistaking, p.17.

‘47This data on log production is from Indonesian Ministry ofForestry and FAQ, Indonesian Tropical, p.4.

149

Page 160: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

than at the height of log exports in the 1970s.’48

Many wood processors operate logging concessions. This is

supposed to provide strong incentives for sustainable management

since processors need steady future supplies. According to Hasan,

“when you log, you don’t care if there are any trees left at the

end. But if you invested in a factory, then you must be sure of a

supply of raw material.”’49 In theory, Hasan may be right. But in

practice, processors -- to maximize immediate profits -- mine

their concessions and use illegal logs to feed their mills.

Furthermore, allowing processors to own concessions distorts free

market signals which would raise the price of logs as plywood

prices increase. Partially as a result, log prices are far too low

to support sustainable management.15° To compensate for low log

prices, Indonesia has considered forming a timber cartel to raise

plywood prices. So far there has been little progress. The major

tropical timber producers -- in particular Malaysia, Brazil,

Nigeria, and the Ivory Coast -- have diverse interests and

different markets: Brazil to the U.S.; Africa to Europe; and

Malaysia and Indonesia to Asia. Countries like Malaysia are also

t48Potter, “Environmental and Social Aspects,” p.180. Also seeBraga, “Tropical Forests and Trade Policy,” p.190.

‘49Quoted in “Shades of green,” Economist, 18 April 1992, p.38.

‘50lnterview, Bogor Agricultural University, Faculty ofForestry, Bogor Indonesia, 28 February 1994. Also see WALHI andYLBHI, Mistaking, pp.18-19.

150

Page 161: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

nervous that Apkindo and Hasan would dominate a plywood cartel.’5’

In addition, unlike oil, a tropical plywood cartel would still face

competition from substitute products, such as temperate plywood,

plastics, and metals. For these reasons, an alliance to drive up

plywood prices is unlikely.

E. Conservation, Reforestation, and Tiniber Plantations

There is an important distinction -- often blurred by

government policies and statistics -- between reforestation that

regenerates natural rain forests or replants vital watersheds, and

reforestation that builds huge, fast-growing, single-species timber

plantations. Most reforestation in Indonesia -- and throughout

Southeast Asia -- focuses on single-species plantations. While

these plantations can create employment, squeeze profits from

degraded land, provide valuable timber stocks for pulp and paper

producers, and perhaps even alleviate pressure to extract logs from

natural forests, these cannot replace primary dipterocarp forests.

Plantations cannot restore the bio-diversity, environmental

benefits, or economic rewards of primary forests. Most plantation

logs are also not an adequate substitute to make plywood.

Reforestation -- especially to protect watersheds and revive

natural forests -- has a poor record in Indonesia. Even according

to official figures, Indonesia only replanted 1.35 million hectares

‘51lnterview, Senior Official, Bappenas, Ministry of Planning,4 March 1994; and Interview, Foreign News Correspondent, KualaLumpur, 9 March 1994.

151

Page 162: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

HH

0IIH

HIQ

I-]

CDCl)

l-PJ

0H

ft‘t

IL

i0

0(Q

bI-h

(D

.IH

HZ

Cl)U)

Cl)CD

0H

iCl)

CD0

M0

(1)‘Z

jMQ

IH[‘

H-

ftft

CDI-

tift

Cl)II

Q<

ftW

Qft

H0

1H

-CD

U)P.)

PiP

0H

0çn

‘dH

CDH

-P

)0

ftII

))D

U)CD

HPi

0I-

CDftC

DH

-C

DIH

-1

H(1)

‘-3ft

Cl)H

cXCD

bftH

U)IP

J‘<

p.,H

-U)

0Cl)

HD

P.)ft

HC!

)H

-ft

CD

CD

HH

.IH

HII

U)CD

ft<

-H

HCD

HC

DL

iH

-P

’I

CDCD

ftH

--

CDH

-H

-H

CDq

I-0

H-

:i0

CDQ

I-Q

•xjH

P.)H

2P

H0

(CH

CDft

()co

H-

P-’ft

pjCD

0I-t

iP.)

H0

N:i

0H-

‘gft

CD3

0CD

0H

(I)CD

LO

P.)

CDk

<H

-CD

0‘I

<ft

CDft

PJC

DCD

I-II

Cl)CD

CD0

U)

‘dP

-H-

H-

Li

HU)

CDft

U)‘-

Hp)

13CD

CD0

ftU)

H

P.)13

l)).C

D)

H0•

-ft

CD9)

Li

HM

‘d‘r

jH

ftP.)

CDI-h

P.)CX

)-

ft

k<

LQH

-Ii!

)II

CD

‘<

,o1

Hft

Cl)I.

hH

-L

ift

H-C

D°‘

H-P

.)(D

0<

H-

i.Q0

I.°w0ft

0•

HH

-CD

0Cl)

IC.))C

1)

9)ft

9)CD

H-

CDIiftp)

I59)

CDft

CD

I.<

lCDI

Cl)H

-.<

:iH

-0

ftCD

HH

-0

CDH

0H

-ft

CD3

ft,<

II’

0IL

iU)

H

U,

H-

l.Q

p)-C

I2Jft

I-CD

H-

12Cl)

UCD

HH

bI-

h9)

H-

H.C

lU)

10H

I.i

ftftH

ft9)

HH

t0

10P.)

U)ci

pH

I-I

‘dp.

1c

‘1p

oCD

CD9

)’C

1)

I’-C

CDft

IIU)

iaC

LCDH

H<

ftH

CD

Hci

ft9)

H-

ftCD

jci)

10p

III

.ci

<:

HC

D,-t

,P.)

‘d[tlft

HQ

ft

HH

HH

.U

,O

CDy•

iCD

0Cl)

CDCD

IICl

)Cl)

CDH

‘-

CD0

•Q

Cfl-

CD

frh

CD

3H

H-

0.

ciciH

HH

I-i’

CDd

U)3

CDi

ft-C

flH

ftCD

CDft

H--

J99)

ftIci

<0

ftH

ciI-h

9)•

0H

-L

jCD

H-

H-

ftH

‘tH

CDCl)

QH

-CD

HCl)

Qft

C1ft

-ICD

CDH

ft1<

IH-

II0

H-

ft0

0‘iI

pi

CDCD

ft0

CDU)

CDH

°Q

‘C

DI

011

-.LC

U)ci

i.PCD

ift

CDft

CDft

IIH

H-

HH

-9)

H-

Jb

Ift

QH

ftft

CDO

CD

CD

09)<

bI°

iCD

9)H

‘<0

P.)0

ciH

ICD

<2)

9)ci

hft

I-b

H-

ftCD

bCD

CD

P.J

PH

-P

U)ft

CDCD

IQII

H-

CDU)

HCD

b0

oI”

H-

ftC

DO

ICD

P.)H

-0

CDft

:ift

ft9

)00

I-C

DC

0I

0P.)

-ft

9)U)

CDP.)

ciW

3I

CD-M

I3

I-h

ci

0•

I-QII

ci

ft•

-CD

CD•

CDCD

Page 163: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

plantations.’57 Many environmentalists argue that these timber

plantations are contributing to, rather than alleviating, forestry

mismanagement. There are certainly serious problems. For example,

the government only allows clear-cutting for plantations in non

productive areas. But according to one report, “companies are not

interested in barren land, when they can maximise profits by

logging natural forests and then replant them with timber

estates.”158 A concession holder claims that logging companies

routinely evade the rules for establishing plantations by

encouraging locals to degrade productive forest areas. These

companies then claim that locals are destroying the forest and it

is necessary to develop a plantation to protect the area and make

it productive.159

F. Plantations and the Pulp and Paper Industry

Like the previous Minister of Forestry, the new minister is

committed to developing huge plantations for pulp and paper. The

government promotes pulp and paper plantations as an environmental

and economic solution to depleting timber reserves. In 1991,

Indonesia produced 1.1 million tons of pulp and 1.7 million tons of

paper. Compared to other producers, Indonesia’s output is still

‘57WALHI and YLEHI, Mistaking, p.23.

‘58Pulp±ng The Rainforest: The Rise of Indonesia’s paper andpulp industry, Down To Earth, The International Campaign forEcological Justice in Indonesia, Special Report No. 1, July 1991,p.6.

159lnterview, Indonesian concessionaire, Jakarta, 3 March 1994.

153

Page 164: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

low. But with government support, Indonesia plans to be one of the

world’s top ten pulp and paper producers by the year 2000.160

There are also plans to build or expand more than 50 pulp and paper

mills by 2010. These mills will be supplied by plantations that

will cover 10 percent of total land area.’61 The government is

hoping foreign investment and aid will support these huge

plantations.162 Since private companies are wary of the risks, the

expense, and the long-term commitment, the government -- using the

Reforestation Fund -- generally takes 49 percent equity and

provides soft loans.’63

Many of the new pulp and paper mills are connected to military

and political elite, particularly Suharto’s patron-client network.

Five of Indonesia’s largest conglomerates -- Sinar Mas, Raja Garuda

Mas, Astra, Barito Pacific, and the Kalimanis Group -- are already

involved in pulp and paper operations.’64 The Sinar Mas Group,

with annual revenues of US$1.2 to US$1.3 billion, has close links

‘60Jonathan Friedland, “Aiming for a market,” FEER, 18 April1991, p.50.

161Pulping the Rainforest, p.2; and WALHI and YLBHI, Mistaking,p.3, p.24.

1621n 1990, former Forestry Minister announced: “We’re openingour country. If you want to invest in these man-made forests, youare welcome.” Quoted in Raphael Pura, “Indonesia Sees Tree Estatesas a Cure-All,” AWSJ, 6 February 1990, p.8.

‘63lnterview, Bogor Agricultural University, Faculty ofForestry, Bogor Indonesia, 25 February 1994; and Pulping theRainforest, p.9. The low rate of private investment in plantationsis aggravated by a legitimate fear that a sudden political changecould nullify state licences.

‘64Jonathan Friedland, “Aiming for a market,” FEER, 18 April1991, p.50.

154

Page 165: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

to the children and followers of Suharto. This conglomerate, under

the control of the Chinese-Indonesian Eka Tjipta Widjaja, is the

largest producer of pulp and paper, and a key force pushing further

development. Prajogo’s Barito Group is also deeply involved in

pulp and paper operations. Prajogo, Suharto’s daughter, Rukmana,

and the state forestry company P.T. Inhutani II are now developing

a new pulp and paper mill in South Sumatra, called P.T. Tanjung

Enim Pulp & Kertas. The Reforestation Fund is providing generous

subsidies. Eventually, around US$2.66 billion will be invested in

this project. This mill is expected to produce one million tons of

pulp and 500,000 tons of paper. To maintain log supplies, between

300,000 to 500,000 hectares have been set aside for timber

plantations. Another key force driving pulp and paper development

is Hasan and his Kalimanis Group. Along with Suharto’s son, Sigit

Harjojudanto, Hasan is a major shareholder in Kertas Kraft Aceh,

which operates a pulp and paper plant in Sumatra. As well, he

controls P.T. Aspex Paper, a joint venture with a South Korean

company. Even more important than these current operations, Hasan

has ambitious plans to expand his control over the pulp and paper

industry. 165

‘65See Pulping The Rainforest, pp.22-25, pp.29-32.

155

Page 166: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

STATE ATTEMPTS TO IMPROVE TIMBER MANAGEMENT

Since Jamaluddin was appointed Minister of Forestry, the

enforcement of logging guidelines has improved marginally.’66 As

of December 1993, the government had rescinded 60 timber licences.

Many concession holders have reacted by simply abandoning their

site. Instead of fining or forcing these companies to replant, the

government appointed the state forestry companies -- P.T. Inhutani

I, P.T. Inhutani III, and P.T. Inhutani V -- to rehabilitate these

degraded areas.’67 In some cases, the government has taken over

shares of timber companies with poor management records and then

appointed a state official to the board of directors. By early

1994, the state had assumed control of 20 percent of the shares of

12 concession holders and 100 percent of the shares of another

dozen.’68 As well, the Forestry Ministry has announced an

“intelligence operation” to catch illegal loggers “in the act.”69

‘66Based on numerous interviews: Environmental Research Centre,Bogor Agricultural University, Bogor Indonesia, 25 February 1994;Environmental consultant, Bogor Indonesia, 24 February 1994;Sumitomo Forestry Co., Ltd., Tokyo, 20 April 1994. According toone optimistic source, he is open-minded, clean, powerful, aneffective manager, and knowledgeable about forestry issues.Interview, Bogor Agricultural University, Faculty of Forestry,Bogor Indonesia, 28 February 1994. Another source claimed that heis honest and independent, and unlike almost everyone else, he hasnot been ‘bought’ by Hasan. Interview, Senior Official, Bappenas,Ministry of Planning, 4 March 1994. He also appears more willingto work with NGO5. Interview, WALHI, Jakarta, 3 March 1994.

‘67Her Suharyanto, “HPH [Concession] Holders Take Money andRun,” Indonesian Business Weekly 1, no. 51, 3 December 1993, p.16.

168”The price of non-Compliance,” Review Indonesia: Economic andBusiness, no. 98, 26 February 1994, p.8.

169”Indonesia will send spies to hunt down illegal loggers,”Japan Times, 18 November 1992, p.21.

156

Page 167: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

As a result, the government fined several major companies for

breaching logging rules. However, while these efforts are

laudable, this campaign has done little to slow the rate of

destructive extraction. So far the state ‘crackdown’ has produced

stern rhetoric but few concrete moves against major timber

operators. This is hardly surprising. With powerful political and

military ties, and with cooperation from key forestry officials,

these companies are largely immune to pressure from the Forestry

Department. For example, in 1991 Barito Pacific Timber was fined

11.1 billion rupiah (US$5.4 million) for cutting nearly 100,000

cubic metres of logs outside their concession. The company,

however, refused to comply and it appears the fine will never be

paid.’7°

Besides these attempts to improve enforcement and compliance,

the government is also developing a timber certification program to

boost state control of the timber industry. Indonesia’s timber

certification program will create an environmental label for timber

from sustainable sources. The labelling criteria are still being

hammered out. Apparently, the labelling process will work on a

cradle-to-grave principle, accounting for all stages of production,

including cutting techniques, concession management, and

processing. Ideally, at each stage there will be guarantees that

the product is produced in a sustainable way.17’ The program will

‘70Adam Schwarz, “Forest Framework,” FEER, 12 March 1992, p.45.

‘71lnterview, Environmental consultant, Bogor, Indonesia, 24February 1994.

157

Page 168: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

create local criteria for sustainable management -- a practical

check-list for loggers, processors, and government managers. Eco

labels for wood products will start from the year 2000,172 then

hopefully spread to all products. According to an NGO

representative, developing an eco-labelling program has provided a

window of opportunity to discuss with the Ministry of Forestry and

concessionaires the criteria for sustainable forestry management.

This program also intrigues concession holders and Apkindo who see

eco-labelling as a possible marketing tool.’73 There has been

little foreign pressure for eco-labelling. Proponents of eco

labelling are aware that Indonesia’s major wood markets -- Japan,

Taiwan, South Korea, and China -- are indifferent to eco-labels.

Advocates hope, however, that countries like Japan can be pressured

or embarrassed into only importing wood with eco-labels.’74

The main force behind eco-labelling is the former State

Minister of the Environment, Emil Salim. He has a direct

connection to the President, and is quite influential, although

Hasan, who has a strained relationship with Salim, is more

powerful. Fortunately for the program, Salim has a close

relationship with the new Minister of Forestry, and has a

‘72This promise was made by Forestry Minister Jamaluddin.“Indonesia to reduce tree cutting to help preserve rainforests,”The Japan Times, 27 July 1994, p.18.

‘73lnterview, WALHI, Jakarta, 3 March 1994. For a critique ofeco-labelling, see SKEPHI, Setiakawan, no. 11, July-September,1993, pp.44-46.

‘74lnterview, WALHI, Jakarta, 3 March 1994; and Interview, EcoLabelling Program, Jakarta, 4 March 1994.

158

Page 169: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

‘gentleman’s agreement’ with the President to establish the

program.175 However, despite Salim’s influence and the optimism of

the NGO5 involved, it is unlikely this program will succeed in the

context of extensive military and political ties to timber

operations. Furthermore, there is no reason to believe state

implementation of certification guidelines will suddenly be better

than the supervision and enforcement of current logging rules.

Instead, it is more likely this program will be captured by

business interests and used to expand markets and divert attention

from unsustainable management. Hasan is already rumoured to be

excited by the potential benefits of timber certification, and he

is eager to start stamping plywood with an attractive logo that

declares, ‘from a sustainable source.’

Keeping in mind the importance of patron-client relations,

distorted management policies, low state capacity, and efforts to

tackle omnipresent problems, I now turn to assess the impact of

Japan’s shadow ecology on timber management. I argue that in the

late 1960s and l970s, Japanese investment, technology, and trade,

often supported by ODA, accelerated unsustainable timber

management. Despite important changes to Japan’s shadow ecology

since the mid-1980s -- including a decrease in investment and

technology transfers, an end to log purchases, a rise in plywood

imports, and marginal improvements to ODA -- three key elements

continue to drive destructive logging in Indonesia: low consumer

and export prices for tropical wood, wasteful consumption, and high

‘75Ibid.

159

Page 170: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

import tariffs.

JAPANESE INVESTMENT AND TECHNOLOGY TRANSFERS

The first Japanese link to large-scale commercial logging on

Indonesia’s outer islands was the Kalimantan Forest Development

Corporation. Japanese trading and wood-based industries

established this company in 1963 to supply the Indonesian state

timber company Perhutani with equipment and technical support on

credit. In exchange, Perhutani agreed to export at least 70

percent of its production to Japan. The Japanese government

cooperated closely with the Forest Development Corporation. The

President of the company was the former head of the Japanese

Forestry Agency while the OECF provided 80 percent of all

credit 176

The 1967 Indonesian Foreign Capital Investment Law triggered

a wave of Japanese investment. In 1968, only 9 Japanese companies

had invested in Indonesia; by the late 1970s, there were over 200

companies.’77 From 1967 to 1989, Japan accounted for 24 percent of

total investment in Indonesia. The second largest investor, Hong

‘76Urano, “Commercial Exploitation,” pp. 67-69.

‘77For general background on Japanese economic links withIndonesia in the l970s, see Yoshi Tsurumi, “Japanese Investments inIndonesia: Ownership, Technology Transfer, and Political Conflict,”in Gustav F. Papanek, The Indonesian Economy (New York: PraegerPublishers, 1980), pp.295-323; and J. Panglaykim, Indonesia’sEconomic and Business Relations with ASEAN and Japan (Jakarta:Centre For Strategic and International Studies, 1977). For a studyof Japanese MNCs in Indonesia during this period, see PO: JapanAsia Quarterly Review, Special Issue on “Japanese Transnational,”pp.3-54.

160

Page 171: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

Kong, was far behind at almost 9 percent of the total.178 Although

to a lesser extent than in other sectors, almost all major Japanese

trading companies -- including Mitsubishi, Marubeni, Itochu,

Nissho-Iwai, Mitsui, and Sumitomo -- invested in timber ventures in

Indonesia.’79 For joint timber ventures, the majority of Japanese

corporations chose Indonesian partners based on their political,

military, or bureaucratic connections, not their expertise or

financial resources. For this reason, the Japanese company often

supplied the equity of local partners.’8° As well, Japanese

ventures tended to be smaller than 1merican and British logging

‘78Hiroyoshi Kano, “The Structure of Japan-Indonesia Relationsand the Relations of NGOs of Both Countries,” in Reshaping“Development”, p. 13.

‘79At the end of 1978, total Japanese investment in theIndonesian timber sector was US$46.2 million, compared to US$48.7million from the United States, US$49.1 million from Malaysia,US$53.0 million from Hong Kong, and US$72.6 million from thePhilippines. Directorat Jenderal Kehutanan, Kehutanan Indonesia1978 (Bogor: October 1979), cited in Gillis, “MultinationalEnterprises,” p.73. Some of the Philippine companies wereapparently backed by Japanese interests. Interview, SeniorProfessor, University of the Philippines at Los Banos, 1 February1994.

‘80Yoshi Tsurumi, A Report Submitted to the Harvard AdvisoryGroup (Jakarta: Bappenas, October 1973), pp.13-14, in Robison,“Toward A Class Analysis,” p.29. For a list of Japaneseinvestments prior to the log export ban, see Urano, “CoirercialExploitation,” see Table 5, pp.72-73. The following are a fewexamples of Japanese timber investments: until 1986, Mitsubishicontrolled 80 percent of P.T. Balikpapan Forest Industries Ltd;until 1978, Tomen owned 49 percent of P.T. East Kalimantan TimberIndustries; until their licence was cancelled in 1978, Mitsui held45.5 percent of P.T. Kalimantan Forest and controlled P.T.Palembang Timber Development Co. Ltd. until 1985.

161

Page 172: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

operations . 181

Along with other MNCs, Japanese corporations provided

technology that expedited rapid and destructive extraction of huge

quantities of dipterocarp logs. For example, in East Kalimantan

during the 1960s, many companies had limited equipment and tracts

were often logged by hand. This frustrated Japanese buyers who

wanted faster, more efficient extraction. To increase supply in

East Kalimantan, Japanese buyers provided “credit for

mechanization” and “by 1971 refused to accept hand-logged

timber.”82 During this period, it was also common for Japanese

trading companies to provide equipment in exchange for dipterocarp

logs.’83 In addition, in the 1970s Japanese companies supported

large-scale logging of fragile mangrove forests in Kalimantan and

Sumatra. By the mid-l980s, around 4 percent of mangrove trees had

been converted to wood chips, shipped mostly to Japan and Taiwan

and manufactured into high-quality paper.’84 Today, Indonesia’s

mangrove forests are facing extinction.185

181Malcolm Gillis, “The Logging Industry In Tropical Asia,” inJulie Sloan Denslow and Christine Padoch, eds., People of theTropical Rain Forest (Berkeley: University of California Press,1988), p.179.

‘82Potter, “Environmental and Social Aspects,” p.182.

‘83Urano, “Commercial Exploitation,” see Table 5, pp.72-73.

‘84M.D. Fortes, “Mangroves and Seagrass Beds in East Asia:Habitats Under Stress,” I.xnbio 17, no.3 (1988), pp.207-213,summarized in Nectoux and Kuroda, Timber, p.81.

‘851n 1990, then Forestry Minister Harahap announced that,without strong conservation measures, of the remaining 4.3 millionhectares of Indonesian mangrove forests, 1 million hectares wouldsoon disappear. “One million ha of RI’s mangrove forests

162

Page 173: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

The Japanese government encouraged and supported corporate

timber ventures in Indonesia. Both ODA and other official flows

financed preliminary logging surveys and risky timber

investments.’86 According to Nectoux and ICuroda, in the case of

Kalimantan, the logging boom, “which appeared to be. . .provoked by

market conditions, was in fact carefully engineered from Japan by

public and private interests. The feasibility study and much of

the necessary survey work were undertaken by.. .JICA’s

predecessor.”87 The OECF also supported commercial logging in

Indonesia. Although since 1975 the OECF has mainly provided

intergovernmental loans, initially it granted loans to Japanese

firms involved in development projects in the South. From 1963 to

1981, more than 70 percent of OECF general forestry project loans

went to Indonesia (41 of 55 projects), most at the height of the

logging boom, 1969 to 1974. While loan information is

confidential, most trading companies likely received OECF loans

during this period, including Mitsui, Sumitomo Forestry and Nissho

threatened with extinction,” Jakarta Post, 8 October 1990. As withall Forestry Department statistics, environmentalists consider theestimate of 4.3 million hectares of mangrove forests highlyexaggerated. Hurst claims that only 1 million hectares of mangroveforests remain. Hurst, Rainforest, p.3.

‘86Urano, “Commercial Exploitation,” footnote 30, p.74.

‘87Nectoux and Kuroda, Timber, p.79. Of course, other M[\TCs alsoaccelerated logging in East Kalimantan. For a general discussionof the role of multinational corporations in East Kalimantan’stimber industry, see William B. Wood, “Two Boom Cities In TheResource Frontier: An Indonesian Case Study,” Asian Geographer 5,no. 1 (1986), pp.25-41.

163

Page 174: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

Iwai 188

Besides loans to Japanese trading companies, OECF’ loans to the

Indonesian government also expedited the timber boom. According to

Urano, “although these were mainly loans to develop infrastructure

such as electric power plants or transport facilities, there is

little doubt that much of it was granted to promote the timber

trade.”89 Since the content of and rationale for OECF loans are

confidential, it is difficult to document links between general

loans and timber extraction. A few leaks have occurred. A 1970

OECF report on loans for the construction of the Balikpapan

Samarinda road declares: “This area is famous for growing tropical

lauan timber exported to Japan, and there is no doubt that [this

project] will directly and indirectly promote the timber industry

and prove immensely profitable to Japan through Japanese firms that

operate locally. ,,190

MITI also provided money to encourage Japanese corporations to

invest in timber operations and import logs.19’ Meanwhile, JICA’s

predecessor “conducted feasibility studies for infrastructure

development (i.e., harbours, roads, and bridges) that were deemed

‘88Mitsui received loans of 193 million yen for forestrydevelopment in Central Kalimantan and 510 million yen for forestrydevelopment in South Kalimantan. Sumitomo received 1.3 billion yenfor forestry development in East Kalimantan in a series loans from1970 to 1974. tJrano, “Commercial Exploitation,” pp.82-83.

1891bid., p.83.

‘90OECF’, “Report of the Indonesian Project Mission of 1970,”quoted in Ibid., p.83.

‘91For a list of MITI projects, see Ibid., Table 6, pp.76.

164

Page 175: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

important to Japan’s timber trade and surveys to gather information

necessary for timber operations (i.e. aerial photographs,

topographical maps, and forest stock estimates) •u192 Of course,

not all of these projects were designed solely to support timber

extraction. But for many this was a key concern. In the case of

the 1975 Banjarmasin Harbour Project, JICA’s objective was “to

improve harbour facilities in order to develop an area rich in

timber resources into a production and distribution site mainly for

the timber industry.”’93 Besides surveys, JICA’s Development

Cooperation Fund, established in 1974, provided technical

assistance and low interest loans to Japanese timber firms involved

in experimental forestry projects and facility upgrades. Although

JICA does not disclose loan information, according to Urano,

Mitsubishi, Mitsui, and Sumitomo Forestry have all received loans

for timber operations in Indonesia.’94 Finally, the EXIM Bank has

granted loans to Japanese logging enterprises in Indonesia.

Although most of this information is also restricted, between 1974

and 1980 the Bank loaned almost 17 billion for timber related

projects in Indonesia, Malaysia, and Papua New Guinea.195

‘92Ibid., p.75.

‘93JICA, JICA Annual Report, 1976, quoted in Ibid., p.75.

‘94Ibid., pp.75-78.

‘95yoichi Kuroda, “Commercial Exploitation of IndonesianTropical Forests by Japan,” in JANNI, Reshaping “Development”,p.44; and Urano, “Commercial Exploitation,” p.85. According to anEXIM Bank spokesman, the Bank is not funding any current loggingproject in the Philippines, Malaysia, or Indonesia, although theBank is prepared to make loans in this area. Interview, Seniorofficial, EXIM Bank of Japan, Environment Section, 11 April 1994.

165

Page 176: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

Like other MNC5, Japanese trading companies largely pulled out

of Indonesia after the log export ban.’96 According to the Japan

Indonesian Entrepreneurs’ Association, in 1988 only 9 timber and

woodworking joint ventures remained.’97 Prajogo, Indonesia’s

largest timber operator, assumed control of several Japanese

concessions, including ones held by Marubeni and Mitsubishi. Even

though these companies no longer participate directly in

operations, close ties have remained. As Raphael Pura notes, “the

Japanese, in effect, left the job of operating their remote

concessions to Mr. Prajogo, while continuing to market his timber

and help finance expansions.”98

In 1989, Indonesia removed many restrictions on foreign

investment.’99 This has led to increases in overall investment,

but only a small amount has gone to timber enterprises. Today,

there is little foreign investment in Indonesia’s plywood mills --

only five are joint ventures and all are controlled by Indonesians.

Of these five, two are Japanese -- one in East Java, and one in

‘96Sumitomo was one of the few Japanese trading companies toremain in Indonesia after the log export ban, although on a muchsmaller scale than in the 1970s when it controlled over 20 firmsconnected to the timber industry. Nectoux and Kuroda, Timber,p.79. For a list of remaining Japanese timber investments, seeIbid., Appendix C, pp.120-121.

‘97Sunirnarized in SKEPHI, Setiakawan, A Special Edition onJapan’s Role in the Timber Industry, no. 3, November-December 1989,p.18.

198Raphael Pura, “Timber Tycoon Confronts HIS Critics,” AWSJ,27 August 1993, p.8.

‘99”Suharto and the reins of power,” The Economist, 17 November1990, p.38. In June 1994, the government lifted even morerestrictions.

166

Page 177: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

Southern Sulawesi -- and three are Korean.20° There is more

foreign participation in the pulp and paper industry. In 1990,

foreign investment in pulp and paper was US$730 million out of a

total of US$8.75 billion. In 1991, there were five major pulp and

paper joint ventures, accounting for 24 percent of production (42

percent of pulp and 17 percent of paper) •201

While Japanese companies have only invested limited amounts in

pulp and paper operations, these have been linked to environmental

problems. For example, Marubeni invested US$3 million in a

mangrove chipping mill in Irian Jaya operated by P.T. Bintuni Utama

Murni. In return, Marubeni has a ten year contract to buy 300,000

tons of wood chips annually. Environmentalists have strongly

attacked this project, situated in an area that was once a National

Park. Even the Indonesian government has criticized P.T. Bintuni

for poor management. In 1990, the government fined P.T. Bintuni

US$590,000 and temporarily suspended their licence for illegal

logging. Apparently, however, this fine has not yet been paid.202

In recent years, Japanese corporations have made minor

contributions to conservation projects in Indonesia. For example,

the Keidanren Nature Conservation Fund provided 110 million to the

200lnterview, Asosiasi, Panel Kayu Indonesia, Apkindo, Jakarta,1 March 1994.

201WALHI and YLBHI, Mistaking, p.27, and p.6.

202Pulping The Rainforest, p.35. Five Japanese companies havealso invested in Chipdeco, a mangrove chipping plant in EastKal imantan.

167

Page 178: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

Sulawesi Nature Conservation project.203 In 1991, Sumitomo, along

with RETROF, the University of Tokyo, and the Indonesian Ministry

of Forestry, established an experimental reforestation program in

East Kalimantan. In the first five years, Sumitomo will spend

about 150 million. The 100 hectare site is developing new

techniques for planting indigenous dipterocarp in open spaces.

While this decreases survival rates, trees grow much faster,

reaching cutting maturity in perhaps as little as 30 years. In the

first year, the survival rate was only 30 percent, partly because

of light rainfall. In the second year, with improved weather

conditions, and better planting techniques, the survival rate rose

to 70-80 percent. This project is also trying to include local

people, create employment and reduce shifting cultivation.204

While commendable, compared to the lingering impact of past

practices, and the current rates of destructive logging, these

efforts are inconsequential.205

203Keidanren, “Keidanren Nature Conservation Fund.”

204lnterviews, Senior officials, Sumitomo Forestry Co., Ltd.,Tokyo, 20 April 1994; Sumitomo Forestry, Ministry of Forestry(Republic of Indonesia), PT. Kutai Timber Indonesia, and theUniversity of Tokyo, Research Report on the Sebulu ExperimentalForest: 1992, July 1993; and Sumitomo Forestry, “Tropical RainForest Regeneration Project Gets Under Way in Indonesia,”Greengraph: Sumitomo Forestry Newsletter 1 (March 1992), pp.1-2.

205Japanese corporations have provided no assistance for largescale Ministry of Environment programs. Interview, State Ministryof Environment, Jakarta, 3 March 1994.

168

Page 179: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

JAPANESE ODA AND TIMBER MANAGEMENT

Japan is the largest bilateral ODA donor to Indonesia,

accounting for over 60 percent of aid received in 1991. In 1992,

Indonesia received nearly 16 percent of Japanese bilateral ODA, the

biggest share of any country.206 Almost 38 percent of Indonesia’s

foreign loans are owed to Japan, compared to nearly 32 percent to

multilateral institutions and a little more than 6 percent to the

United States.207 Unlike in the 1960s and 19705, today there is

little evidence Japanese ODA is tied to commercial logging

operations or securing timber supplies. Japanese aid now primarily

supports commercial timber plantations and transferring processing

technology and expertise. Though limited, JICA has also provided

technical and financial support for natural forest regeneration,

harvesting of less utilized species, and prevention of forest

fires. As of early 1994, there are nine on-going Japanese ODA

projects in Indonesia -- most are linked to plantations.208

206Japanese Ministry of Foreign Affairs, Japan’s ODA 1993,pp.45-46. For a study of Japanese ODA in Indonesia, see HadiSoesastro, Japan’s ODA and Indonesia: Resource Security Aid?(Jakarta: Centre for Strategic and International Studies, 1991).

207Arief Budiman, “Human Rights, Foreign Aid and People toPeople Cooperation,” in JANNI, Reshaping Development, p.28.

208Sevën are grants for a total of approximately US$15 million.Two are loans for a total of about US$22 million. For a list, seeIndonesian Ministry of Forestry, “Daf tar Proyek Bantuan Luar Negeri(On-going Projects), Departemen Kehutanan (Tahun Anggaran1993/1994), and the Evaluation of CGIF Questionnaire Proyek of OnGoing Forestry Foreign Cooperation Project as of October 1993,”supplied by an official at the Indonesian Ministry of Forestry,Jakarta, 1 March 1994. For more details on JICA forestry projectsin Indonesia, see JICA, Environment (Jakarta: Indonesia Office,1993), pp.12-19.

169

Page 180: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

Compared to the severe problems facing Indonesia’s timber industry,

Japanese aid has had little impact on environmental protection or

improving forestry management.209 Even though Japan is the largest

contributor to Indonesian forestry ODA, accounting for around 35-40

percent of technical assistance, the total is still quite small.

If timber prices incorporated environmental costs, it would far

surpass the financial contribution of ODA.21°

Besides inadequate forestry aid, general Japanese loan and

technical cooperation projects in Indonesia do not adequately

incorporate environmental objectives. Japanese aid still supports

high-tech equipment purchases, with little regard for environmental

implications and with little institutional support. As well,

Japanese aid officials in Indonesia have little environmental

expertise or ground-level knowledge and are reluctant to work with

foreign environmental consultants.21’ Aid staff also apparently

hesitate to work far away from amenities, and avoid places like

Irian Jaya.212 Many of these aid officials insulate themselves,

course, there have been some positive contributions -- forexample, a 1991 OECF loan to upgrade 18 environmental researchfacilities. The money was used to improve facilities, buy booksand equipment, and educate staff. Interview, EnvironmentalResearch Centre, Bogor Agricultural University, Bogor Indonesia, 25February 1994.

210lnterview, Centre For International Forestry Research(CIFOR), Bogor Indonesia, 2 March 1994.

211lnterviews, Environmental consultants, Bogor Indonesia, 24February 1994.

212lnterview, Indonesian Ministry of Forestry, Bureau ofInternational Cooperation and Investment, Jakarta, March 1, 1994.In contrast, a Japanese official claimed that JICA has difficultyconvincing senior Indonesians to study in the field. Interview,

170

Page 181: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

stay a short time, and learn little about Indonesia. R. Forrest

notes that even though “Japan is the leading provider of ODA to

Indonesia, providing 12 times as much aid as the US, Japan has only

20 field staff there, less than one-fifth the total USAID staff;

in-country Japanese staff are responsible for 70 times as much aid

money per person as USAID staff.”213 These problems are compounded

by senior Tokyo administrators who dictate key decisions with

minimal understanding of Indonesia’s diverse cultures and eco

systems.214 One NGO activist claims that JICA -- in terms of

environmental awareness -- is one of the worst aid agencies in

Indonesia 215

TRADE: APKINDO, NIPPINDO, AND THE BATTLE FOR JAPAN’S PLYWOOD MARKET

Japan and Indonesia have extensive trade links. Throughout

the 1970s and 1980s, between 40 to 50 percent of Indonesian exports

went to Japan while generally 20 to 30 percent of Indonesia’s

imports came from Japan. Indonesia primarily imports manufactured

Coordinator of JICA Indonesia, Jakarta, 1 March 1994.

213Forrest, “Japanese Aid,” p.29.

214lnterviews, Environmental consultants, Bogor Indonesia, 24February 1994.

215lnterview, Asian Wetlands Bureau, Bogor, Indonesia, 2 March1994. A Indonesian Ministry of Environment official is less harsh,claiming some improvements have been made to JICA projects inrecent years. Interview, State Ministry of Environment, Jakarta,3 March 1994.

171

Page 182: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

products from Japan and exports natural resources to Japan.216 In

the 1960s and 1970s, Indonesia was a crucial source of logs for

Japanese plywood processors. In 1971, Indonesia replaced the

Philippines as the main source of Japanese log imports. In 1974,

Indonesian log exports to Japan peaked at almost 11.5 million cubic

metres, accounting for 47 percent of total Japanese imports. In

the early 1980s, as the Indonesian government implemented the log

export ban, Japanese log imports from Indonesia fell sharply until

ending in 1986.217 Since then Indonesian plywood exports to Japan

have steadily increased. In 1993, Indonesia exported 9.6 million

cubic metres of plywood -- 3.7 million cubic metres went to Japan,

by far Indonesia’s largest market.218

Apkindo has flooded the Japanese market with cheap plywood.

To expand market shares, Indonesian processors produce plywood from

high quality logs. A Japanese trading company official claims that

“[for plywood] Indonesia is stripping vast amounts of logs [of such

high quality] that we in Japan can only dream of laying our hands

on nowadays.”219 According to a representative from the Japan

216Kano, “The Structure of Japan-Indonesia Relations,” see Table2 and Table 4, pp.6-8 (This data is from various issues of theStatistical Yearbook of Indonesia).

217Nectoux and Kuroda, Timber, p.36. For data on the quantityof Indonesian logs imported by specific Japanese companies, seeUrano, “Commercial Exploitation,” Table 4, p.71.

2181n 1989, Indonesia exported about 3.2 million cubic metresof plywood to Japan. From 1990 to 1992 this dropped to just below3 million cubic metres before surging in 1993. This data wassupplied by an official at Apkindo, Jakarta, 1 March 1994.

219Quoted in Urano, “Commercial Exploitation,” p.92.

172

Page 183: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

Plywood Manufacturers’ Association, Ap]cindo is a monopolistic,

undemocratic organization ruled by Hasan, which has a clear

strategy to destroy Japan’s plywood industry.220 Apkindo has

unwritten rules to force private companies to sell below

international market prices. This is possible since Indonesian

labour and log costs are much lower than for international

competitors.22’ Under Apkindo, Indonesian plywood processors must

export 40 percent of their total plywood production to Japan, 20

percent of which must be as kon pane. This is sold at extremely

low prices to undercut Japanese processors.222 Obviously, in the

immediate term, it would be more profitable for individual firms to

export to markets other than Japan. Yet there is little choice.

If the quota to Japan is ignored, Apkindo can decimate a company by

refusing to allow future exports.223

Besides quotas to keep prices low and quality high, Apkindo

established Nippindo to market Indonesian plywood in Japan. By

using Indonesian ships, and in conjunction with strict quotas and

controls by Apkindo, Nippindo sells high-quality plywood at very

220lnterview, Senior official, Japan Plywood Manufacturers’Association, 8 April 1994.

221lnterview, Bogor Agricultural University, Faculty ofForestry, Bogor Indonesia, 28 February 1994.

222Numerous knowledgeable sources in and outside Indonesiaconfirmed that Apkindo is suppressing prices to bankrupt Japaneseplywood competitors and capture this lucrative market.

223lnterview, Senior official, Bappenas, Ministry of Planning,Jakarta, 4 March 1994. In response to a question on how hemaintains discipline, Hasan remarked: “I sign the approval forrevoking a company’s export licence.” “Shades of green,”Economist, 18 April 1992, p.34, and p.38.

173

Page 184: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

low prices. So far, Nippindo has been remarkably successful. In

1993, total Japanese plywood consumption was 9.2 million cubic

metres -- 4 million from imports, and the remainder from domestic

production.224 Indonesian plywood accounts for over 40 percent of

total Japanese consumption, and around 70 percent of kon pane.225

Part of the reason for Nippindo’s remarkable success is the general

Japanese perception that Indonesia is not an economic threat

(unlike the U.S.) and the tendency of the Japanese government to

stress protecting high-tech industries.226

Apkindo’ s and Nippindo’ s tactics demonstrate the vulnerability

of Japanese processors who rely on overseas logs. As Apkindo

undercuts plywood prices, as log prices rise, and as supplies

fluctuate, many Japanese plywood processors have been driven out of

business. Between 1987 and 1992, domestic plywood production

dropped 20 percent.227 On average 5 plywood factories have been

closing every year in Japan. As of April 1994, there were only 100

members of the Japan Plywood Manufacturers’ Association (JPMAj. By

2Interv±ew, Senior official, Japan Lumber Importer’sAssociation, Tokyo, 4 April 1994.

225lnterview, Asosiasi, Panel Icayu Indonesia, Apk±ndo, Jakarta,1 March 1994; and Interview, Senior official, Japan PlywoodManufacturers’ Association, 8 April 1994. In 1993, even thoughIndonesian plywood exports to Japan increased, as a percentage oftotal plywood imports, Indonesia’s portion declined as moresoftwood plywood was imported. See the Japan PlywoodManufacturers’ Association, Plywood Industry in Japan (Tokyo: JapanPlywood Manufacturers’ Association, April 1994), p.6, Table 7.

226lnterview, Senior official at Bappenas, Ministry of Planning,Jakarta, 4 March 1994.

2Japanese Lumber Journal, 31 December 1993, p.4.

174

Page 185: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

the year 2000, the JPMA predicts that only 60 factories will

remain.228 Spurred by the success of Apkindo and Nippindo, there

are signs Indonesia will use similar tactics to dominate the world

pulp and paper industry. For now, pulp and paper projects are

expanding quickly with few controls. However, once economic

momentum develops, there are plans to establish an over-arching

organization to control and guide the industry (perhaps modelled

after Apkindo, perhaps even headed by Hasan) •229

Japanese officials argue that Apkindo practices unfair trade.

In the late l980s, the JPMA persuaded the Japanese government to

hold a bilateral conference to discuss Apkindo’s export strategy.

This conference produced no results. The JPMA has also appealed to

the Fair Trade Commission of GATT but Apkindo is technically a non

governmental organization and GATT has no jurisdiction.230 Despite

the growing power of Apkindo and Nippindo, the financial crisis of

many Japanese processors, and the inability of the processing

industry to push back the assault, Japanese plywood officials

remain optimistic. According to several spokesmen, Apkindo’s

strategy of flooding Japan with cheap imports cannot continue,

especially It Indonesia keeps the recent promise by Forestry

Minister Jamaluddin to slash annual timber production from over 30

228Senior Executive, Japan Plywood Manufacturers’ Association,Tokyo, 8 April 1994.

229lnterview, Senior official, Bappenas, Ministry of Planning,4 March 1994.

230lnterview, Senior official, Japan Plywood Manufacturers’Association, 8 April 1994.

175

Page 186: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

million cubic metres to 22 million cubic metres.23’ Despite the

rapid loss of valuable commercial timber, Apkindo remains equally

optimistic. According to a spokesman, high labour and tropical log

costs and the inability of temperate plywood to satisfy consumers

will eventually lead to the collapse of Japan’s plywood industry.

Apkindo can then increase profit margins in Japan, which are now

fairly low, especially for kon pane.232 While it is uncertain who

will be victorious in this plywood war, it seems clear that

Indonesia’s forest will sustain heavy casualties.

In the late 1970s, Taiwan and Korea, realising that plywood

processing was a sunset industry, dismantled plywood mills, and

exported used equipment to Indonesia)3 But Japanese processors

have stubbornly persevered. To protect and prolong the industry,

the Japanese government and the private sector have tried to thwart

Indonesia’s plywood industry. For example, after the log export

ban was announced, the Japanese Ambassador, Japanese companies,

JICA, and the QECF all lobbied to lift the ban. While these

tactics failed, the Japanese government has also maintained stiff

tariff and non-tariff barriers to block plywood imports.

231lnterviews, Japan Lumber Importer’s Association, Tokyo, 4April 1994; Japan Plywood Manufacturers’ Association, Tokyo, 8April 1994; Japan Plywood Inspection Corporation, Tokyo, 8 April1994.

232lnterview, Asosiasi, Panel Kayu Indonesia, Apkindo, Jakarta,1 March 1994.

3Interview, Centre For International Forestry Research(CIFOR), Bogor Indonesia, 2 March 1994.

176

Page 187: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

JAPANESE TARIFF BARRIERS

Japan imposes a 15 percent tariff on plywood imports.234 The

Japanese government calculates the tariff based on a price that

includes shipping and insurance costs. This makes Japan’s import

tariff higher than the more usual calculation based on a FOB (free

on board) price (such as in the U.S. which has an 8 percent FOB

tariff on plywood imports). Northern tariffs on plywood reduce the

profits of Indonesian exporters and the revenues of the Indonesian

government. An official at the Indonesian Ministry of Planning

claims that Apkindo exports high-quality plywood to Japan at prices

5 to 10 percent lower than to other countries to overcome tariff

and non-tariff barriers.235 According to Hasan, “in many cases,

the consuming country’s tax revenue on a sheet of plywood is

greater than the total growth of value in producing countries.”236

In 1991, Indonesia paid Japan US$125 million in import duties on

processed timber. These import charges deplete Indonesian revenue

essential for sustainable management. In theory, as former

Forestry Minister Harahap argued, “if the import duties are

lowered, the deductions from paying import duties can be allocated

4Logs are not charged any import duties. Adam Schwarz, “Tradefor trees,” FEER, 4 June 1992, p.60. The 15 percent tariff is forplywood that is less than 6 millimetres thick. If the thickness ismore than 6 millimetres then the import duty is 10 percent. AsianTimber, October 1994, p.9.

235lnterview, Senior official, Bappenas, Ministry of Planning,Jakarta, 4 March 1994.

236Hasan, “Prospects for Plywood,” p.16.

177

Page 188: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

for the conservation of our tropical forests.”237 Besides the 15

percent tariff, Japan also has non-tariff import barriers. The

most important is the regulation that government projects must use

Japanese Agricultural Standard (JAS) certified timber. The Japan

Plywood Inspectors Corporation issues these certificates based on

quality. Indonesia has largely managed to overcome this non-tariff

barrier: 50 plywood mills now qualify for JAS certificates.238

CONCLUS ION

Modern patron-client relations are a dominant feature of the

New Order Government. Like traditional ties, these are vertical,

asymmetrical, reciprocal, personal, instrumental, and non-

contractual; but modern links tend to be more opportunistic, fluid,

and materialistic, and have weaker feelings of loyalty. These

patron-client ties bind together powerful political, military,

bureaucratic, and corporate elites. Links between pribumi

(indigenous or non-Chinese) state patrons and ethnic Chinese

business clients are particularly important. Societal prejudice

and regular backlashes against Chinese businesses create even

weaker feelings of loyalty between ethnic Chinese and state elite

than among pribumi Indonesians. While these ties have been quite

stable during the New Order, there is a sense of apprehension and

237Quoted in “Jakarta receives US$1.9 b in new loans from Japanfor development,” Star, 15 September 1992, p.16.

238lnterview, Asosiasi, Panel Kayu Indonesia, Apkindo, Jakarta,1 March 1994; and Interview, Senior official, Japan PlywoodInspection Corporation, Tokyo, 8 April 1994.

178

Page 189: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

uncertainty which encourages ethnic Chinese business leaders to

channel profits overseas.

President Suharto leads the largest and most powerful patron-

client network with his family, friends, and key followers at the

core. He provides protection, state funds, licences, concessions,

and access to the corridors of power in exchange for political

loyalty, financial support, legitimacy, and stability. He has been

especially careful to coopt or appease influential military

generals, appointing officers to key state positions, awarding

lucrative concessions and licences, and supporting the business

interests of military patron-client networks. Many of Suharto’s

clients also function as political, military, or bureaucratic

patrons, building a base of power using their state position,

wealth, and connections to Suharto. This process of clients acting

as patrons contributes to patron-client ties pervading all levels

‘of the state and society. This does not, however, translate into

power flowing upward to a single summit; power is more diffuse,

resting in pockets of patron-client clusters, pyramids, and

networks -- creating what Migdal calls a weblike society. For this

reason, while Suharto is clearly the most powerful state patron, he

must judiciously cultivate and maintain support from key military,

political, and bureaucratic leaders.

While all political interaction cannot be explained by patron

client relations, these ties at the state helm impair state

policies and dilute control of state implementors. With little

supervision, many state implementors are absorbed by patron-client

179

Page 190: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

clusters, ignoring state rules in exchange for material or

professional support. For logging, distorted state forestry

policies and the inability of the state to monitor and enforce

timber regulations drive destructive extraction and unsustainable

management.

At least two conditions are essential for sustainable logging:

the price must be high, reflecting the long-term costs of

regeneration and management; and log extraction must be kept at a

sustainable level. Indonesia has met neither condition. In the

1960s and 1970s, concessions were granted as gifts to appease or

reward political and military elites -- with little capital or

knowledge, ethnic Chinese and multinational companies were hired to

log these concessions. With almost no state supervision, these

areas were mined and logs were exported in huge quantities,

especially to Japan. While the Indonesian state received a small

portion of timber revenues, MNCs and Indonesian military,

political, and bureaucratic elite made quick, easy money. At the

same time, almost no effort was made to log areas on a sustainable

basis or to regenerate devastated areas.

The ban on log exports and the push to process plywood in the

1980s, and the moves to develop pulp and paper plantations in the

1990s, have done little to improve timber management. Today, there

is tremendous pressure on the commercial forests. There are few

signs of improvement despite a more assertive Minister of Forestry,

and government moves to improve logging management, establish an

eco-label for sustainable timber, increase collection of timber

180

Page 191: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

taxes and royalties, and crack down on illegal logging and

smuggling. The government is also providing subsidies and

pressuring companies to replant; not to regenerate commercial

dipterocarp stands, but to build huge timber plantations to supply

an expanding pulp and paper industry. Instead of ‘reforestation,’

this policy contributes to ‘deforestation’ as areas are cleared to

establish plantations.

Concession operators -- especially ethnic Chinese -- wary of

a sudden political upheaval and new leaders revoking concession

rights, have few incentives for long-term management; instead,

timber operators invest in real estate and stash money overseas.

In addition, there is little state control over timber operations.

As a result, legal concessions are badly managed, enrichment

planting is limited, and illegal logging is rampant. Illegal

logging is likely equivalent to legal logging, placing annual log

production at around 70 million cubic metres, well above even the

most optimistic estimates of sustainable production. Along with

smuggling and schemes to evade timber taxes and royalties, illegal

logging syphons state timber revenues. Forest charges are also

remarkably low and the state is now estimated to capture only 15 to

30 percent of timber rents. As long as powerful state patrons like

Suharto protect timber clients like Hasan (APKINDO and the

Kalimanis Group) and Prajogo (Barito Pacific Timber), and as long

as state implementors follow the rules of patron-client networks,

the state will be too weak to improve logging management,

regardless of the content of actual policies or the rhetoric of

181

Page 192: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

state leaders.

While domestic political forces distort policies, undermine

state revenue and drive unsustainable extraction, the North,

especially Japan, has bolstered and accelerated this process. In

the l960s and 1970s, Japanese ODA, technology, investment and log

purchases had a catalytic impact on unsustainable logging. ODA

funds supported commercial timber surveys, feasibility studies,

logging infrastructure projects, and corporate timber investments.

Although Japan was not the largest investor in the Indonesian

timber sector in the l970s, Japanese corporate credit, joint

ventures, logging equipment and technical advice were key forces

that drove reckless logging. Huge amounts of logs were then

shipped to Japan to feed domestic plywood processors, often leaving

behind widespread damage. As well as expediting destructive

logging, Japanese money -- which deluged Indonesia after the 1967

Foreign Capital Investment Law -- also provided critical financial

slack to allow extensive patronage.

After log exports were banned in the mid-1980s, the key

features of Japan’s shadow ecology changed. Most Japanese trading

companies withdrew or sold their shares in joint timber ventures.

Today, there are few investments in Indonesian plywood or pulp and

paper operations. Logging equipment is no longer shipped in

substantial amounts, although there has been some technological

support for processing. ODA has also changed. Since the early

1980s, few JICA forestry projects or OECF loans have been connected

to corporate logging ventures. Instead, ODA tends to emphasize

182

Page 193: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

commercial timber plantations. While these are positive trends,

Japanese ODA projects in Indonesia still have serious environmental

problems. There are few environmental experts, staff members have

little field experience, and funds often support inappropriate

technology purchases. These problems are aggravated by decisions

made in Tokyo with little understanding of Indonesia’s delicate

outer island eco-systems. In fairness, there is limited Japanese

government and corporate support for forestry conservation and

regeneration, but not nearly enough to dent deforestation rates.

Finally, since 1985, Japanese log imports have ceased while

plywood imports have soared. For both logs and plywood, prices

have been far below the cost of sustainable management, feeding

voracious Japanese consumption habits. During the era of log

exports, Japanese trading companies played a pivotal role in

depressing prices and promoting rapid, destructive logging. Today,

these companies have been usurped by Apkindo. Under Hasan, and

with Suharto’s support, Apkindo has flooded the Japanese market

with cheap, high-quality plywood. This strategy -- designed to

destroy Japanese competitors -- has been successful in bankrupting

many Japanese processors. But it has also lowered prices,

encouraged wasteful consumption, and fostered unsustainable timber

management. At the same time, Japanese plywood tariffs have

undercut Indonesian state and corporate revenue, further reducing

potential funds for forestry management and regeneration. In

short, while some aspects of Japan’s shadow ecology have changed

over the last 30 years, three critical components -- low prices,

183

Page 194: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

wasteful consumption, and import tariffs on processed wood -- have

remained constant. As a result, Japan’s shadow ecology continues

to provoke and support unsustainable timber extraction. This in

turn fuels pervasive patron-client relations.

184

Page 195: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

Chapter Five

JAPAN, CLIENTELISM AND DEFORESTATION IN BORNEO MALAYSIA

Over the last three decades -- as in Indonesia --

unsustainable logging has been a key cause of deforestation in

Borneo Malaysia. Wide areas are degraded and commercial timber

stocks are now perilously low. The environmental group Sahabat

Alam Malaysia maintains that: “Nowhere in the world are the forests

being chopped with such ferocity and speed as in Sarawak.”1 Sabah

has extracted timber with equal intensity. A 1990 ITTO report on

Sarawak’s timber industry claimed that if the “frenetic pace of

logging continues at [the rate] of recent years, all primary

forests will have been harvested in 11 years.”2 Even more dire

predictions have been made for Sabah.

Links between top state patrons and timber operators in Borneo

Malaysia -- similar to those in Indonesia -- distort state

policies, weaken state enforcement, and drive unsustainable

logging. Top political patrons, to maintain loyalty and support in

fragmented societies, grant timber concessions to key political and

business clients. Many concession holders then hire contractors to

manage logging operations; contractors often use subcontractors to

‘Quoted in Hurst, Rainforest, p.102. Parts of this chapter arefrom Dauvergne, “Patron-client Politics,” unpublished, 1992.

2Summarized by Anthony Rowley, “Logged Out,” FEER, 13 December1990, p.72. For the ITTO report, see ITTO, “The Promotion ofSustainable Forest Management: A Case Study in Sarawak, Malaysia,”Report Submitted to the International Tropical Timber Council, ITTC(VIII)/7 7 May 1990.

185

Page 196: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

extract or process the timber. These multiple layers of

responsibility reduce accountability and transparency, increasing

the difficulty of enforcement and effective management. Timber

profits fuel powerful patron-client networks. These networks are

highly unstable, rupturing as political parties vie for power in

Borneo Malaysia’s ethnically diverse landscape. As a result,

concessions are frequently annulled as competing patron-client

networks rise and fall. In this setting, there are no incentives

for long-term management or conservation. Instead, concessionaires

and timber companies race to extract as much timber as possible

before tenuous political alliances and patron-client networks

crumble. Timber mismanagement is further aggravated by poor

supervision of middle and lower level state implementors.

Enforcement officers -- in exchange for money, gifts, and career

opportunities -- disregard concession rules, forge customs

declarations, and ignore illegal logging and smuggling.

Unlike in Indonesia, Japanese aid and investment have not had

a major impact on timber management in Borneo Malaysia. Japanese

ODA has been limited to a few infrastructure projects and minor

technical assistance projects to support plantations (Sabah) and

processing (Sarawak). There have been few major investments in

logging or timber processing. Yet despite limited investment and

aid, Japan’s shadow ecology has accelerated logging rates and

bolstered unsustainable timber management. Japanese trading

companies have purchased huge quantities of logs, shipped them to

Japan, and as in Indonesia, manufactured plywood, especially kon

186

Page 197: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

pane. Purchase and consumer prices have been far below replacement

or sustainable management costs. So far, unlike in Indonesia,

Japanese tariffs on processed wood imports have not significantly

reduced state revenues necessary for effective timber management - -

although, as Sabah and Sarawak reduce log exports and increase

processed wood exports, import barriers have become relatively more

important.

The first section of this chapter sketches the evolution from

traditional to ‘modern’ patron-client relations in Borneo Malaysia.

The second section documents the extensive ties between political

patrons and timber clients in Sabah and Sarawak. The third part

analyzes how pervasive patron-client ties thwart logging rules;

foster illegal cutting, smuggling, and corporate tax and royalty

evasion; and distort the allocation of concessions, policies to

encourage processing, and efforts to promote reforestation,

conservation and sustainable timber management. The final part

assesses the impact of Japan’s shadow ecology on timber management

in Borneo Malaysia.

PATRON-CLIENT RELATIONS IN BORNEO MALAYSIA

It is quite difficult to ascertain the nature of patron-client

relations in Sarawak and Sabah before 1963, when the two states

joined Malaya, forming Malaysia. R. S. Mime claims that “Native

chiefs and headmen, who existed in Sarawak and Sabah before the

British came and who were institutionalized by them, sometimes

functioned as patrons.” In addition, he reasons that “where

187

Page 198: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

communications were good and the population was relatively dense

and well-organized (as among the coastal Malays in Sarawak), or

where the degree of hierarchy was great, as among the

‘aristocratic’ Sarawak Kenyahs, patronage was probably fairly

common.”3 Patron-client relationships also existed among the

Chinese with wealthy businessmen in the role of patrons. The Ibans

of Sarawak probably had less pervasive patron-client links since

their society was relatively egalitarian.4

Near the end of North Borneo Company rule in Sabah and Brooke

rule in Sarawak, and throughout direct British colonial rule from

1946-1963, the populations of both states were “relatively

unmobilized, the functions of government quite limited, and

administrators in the field efficient and helpful, if

paternalistic, within the restricted scope of operations.” Milne

notes further that “life was not particularly unpredictable nor

personal security particularly tenuous.”5 Patron-client relations

developed and flourished due more to a desire to obtain

opportunities and benefits than a need for protection. The

British, in the latter part of their colonial rule, reshaped

patron-client relations by appointing indigenous people to

administrative positions, thus encouraging new patron-client links

to form on a state rather than local scale. At the same time,

indigenous people increasingly entered business, especially the

3Milne, “Patrons, Clients and Ethnicity,” p.898.

4lbid., pp.898-899.

5Ibid., p.896.

188

Page 199: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

timber industry, later becoming prominent state politicians.6

When Sabah and Sarawak joined Malaya in 1963, patterns of

patron-client links were again altered as British colonial

administrators were replaced by state and federal officials. New

patron-client clusters and networks formed around state leaders

while many old clientelist ties reshaped or dissolved. Patron-

client networks also expanded as government institutions provided

the resources to sustain large groups without deep loyalties or

strong friendships.7 Patron-client relations underwent further

changes with the start of directly elected state legislatures in

1967 in Sabah and 1969-1970 in Sarawak. Patron-client networks

became even larger, vertically linking urban areas to more remote

rural areas. Mime claims that “dyadic patron-client relations now

extended, in chain fashion, right to the top of state politics.”8

Large ‘peripheral’ client followings became important during

elections. Paying headmen to influence the voting of their

clientele, buying votes, and swaying the allegiance of politicians

with instrumental rewards were all evident by the 1967 election in

Sabah and the 1969-1970 election in Sarawak.9

Ethnicity (often distinguished by religion) and patron

6These included Fuad Stephens and Tun Mustapha Harun in Sabahand Datuk Amar James Wong Kim Mm in Sarawak. R.S. Milne and K.J.Ratnam, Malaysia - New States in a New Nation (London: Frank Cass,1974) , pp.316-318.

7Means, Malaysian Politics, pp.298-299.

8Milne, “Patrons, Clients and Ethnicity,” p.899.

9See Milne and Ratnam, Malaysia - New States in a New Nation,for a discussion of these practices.

189

Page 200: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

client relations are closely linked in Sabah and Sarawak. Ethnic

groups are generally divided into three categories: indigenous

Muslims, indigenous non-Muslims, and non-indigenous. In Sarawak,

indigenous Muslims (Malays and Melanaus) constitute 26 percent of

the population; about 44 percent are indigenous non-Muslims

(including Iban, Bidayuh, Orang Ulu, Kenyahs, and Kayans) ;‘° and 30

percent are non-indigenous (mostly Chinese) Around 49 percent

of Sabah’s population are indigenous Muslims (Bajaus, Malays, and

immigrants), 34 percent are indigenous non-Muslims (Kadazans and

Muruts), and 16 percent are non-indigenous (primarily Chinese).

The Kadazans are the largest ethnic group in Sabah, comprising 30

percent of the population. In total, just over half of the people

in Sabah and a little more than a quarter in Sarawak are Muslims.

Although some ethnic Chinese have converted to Islam in Sabah, most

Chinese in Borneo Malaysia follow a mixture of Confucianism,

Christianity, and Buddhism. Indigenous non-Muslims are generally

Christians or animists.’2

Today, Sarawak and Sabah are ruled by multi-ethnic coalitions

with some ethnically mixed political parties. In Sarawak, Malay

‘°The Bidayuh and Orang Ulu are sometimes grouped with the Ibanand called Dayaks.

‘1The role of Sarawak’s ethnic groups in politics is discussedin Jayum A. Jawan, The Ethnic Factor in Modern Politics: The Caseof Sarawak, East Malaysia, Occasional Paper, no. 20 (University ofHull: Centre For South-East Asian Studies, 1991). For a specificdiscussion of the Sarawak Chinese, see John M. Chin, The SarawakChinese (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1981).

‘2Diane K. Mauzy and R.S. Milne, Malaysia: Tradition, Modernityand Islam (Boulder: Westv±ew Press, 1986), p.68.

190

Page 201: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

and Melanau Muslims are the most powerful political and

bureaucratic force. In Sabah, Christian Kadazans dominated from

1985 until early 1994. In the new coalition government, Malays and

Muslims are pivotal forces. Since no single ethnic or religious

group can dominate politics in Borneo Malaysia, patron-client

networks that integrate elites from different ethnic groups and

different religious backgrounds, and which often cross-cut official

party lines, are crucial for maintaining power. This is

particularly relevant in Sarawak since many of the ethnic groups

have regional divisions. Michael Leigh notes that the “peculiar

ethnic complex, with three major groups, not one of which

approaches a majority of the population, has facilitated

accommodation in Sarawak.” Political divisions within ethnic

groups have encouraged compromise, “forcing the factions to seek

allies outside their group in the quest for political power.”13

The situation in Sabah is quite similar. Bruce Gale argues that

“questions of race, religion and class, relevant to the study of

West Malaysian politics, are less important in Sabah than the

existence of strong clientelist networks.”4

Some of the most important patron-client links are between

powerful indigenous politicians and Chinese business leaders.

After Sarawak and Sabah joined Malaya, the general mainland pattern

13Michael B. Leigh, The Rising Moon: Political Change inSarawak (Sydney: Sydney University Press, 1974), p.162, p.161.

‘4Bruce Gale, “Politics at the Periphery: A Study of the 1981and 1982 Election Campaigns in Sabah,” in Bruce Gale, ed., Readingsin Malaysian Politics (Selangor Malaysia: Pelanduk Publications,1986), p.25.

191

Page 202: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

of Malay political power and Chinese economic influence was

encouraged in the two new states. In most instances, indigenous

political leaders assumed the role of patrons and the Chinese

assumed the role of clients. Indigenous political patrons provided

political protection and access to resources, licences, or

contracts in exchange for financial and electoral support from

Chinese clients.

Patron-client ties in Borneo Malaysia have been highly

unstable since the first elections. One sign of this instability

is frequent crossovers from one political party to another. For

example, less than a year after the 1987 state election in Sarawak,

six members of the Parti Bangsa Dayak Sarawak (PBDS), which lost

the election, were ‘bought over’ by the ruling Barisan Nasional

(BN) Changing alliances and party cross-overs were such a

problem in Sabah in the mid-l980s that an ‘anti-hop’ law was passed

which forbid politicians from switching parties without losing

their seats.’6 This law was later struck down by a High Court, and

shifting party allegiances dominated the 1994 election.’7 The

Parti Bersatu Sabah under incumbent Chief Minister Pairin won this

election by a slim margin. But defections -- including his

brother, Jeffrey Kitingan -- toppled the government. According to

‘5Marcus Colchester, Pirates, Squatters and Poachers: ThePolitical Ecology of Dispossession of the Native People of Sarawak(London: Survival International, INSAN, 1989), p.32.

16Michael Vatikiotis, “Disarray in the ranks,” FEER, 10September 1992, pp.24-26.

17See “PBS wins by two seats,t’ Borneo Post, 20 February 1994,p.’.

192

Page 203: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

some sources, “many of the defectors”.. .were. . .“enticed to change

sides with money and promises of position.”8 Chinese business-

clients are particularly prone to change alliances. One author

noted that the Chinese in Sarawak “go with whoever is the stronger,

demanding more timber concessions in return for their support.”9

Relations between the federal and state governments have

further contributed to unstable and fluid patron-client clusters in

Borneo Malaysia. Francois Loh and Kok Wah write, “it is

clear. . . that whoever wishes to govern in Sarawak must receive the

blessings of Kuala Lumpur.”2° In both states, federal pressure has

contributed to political realignment. One example occurred in 1976

when the federal government engineered the downfall of Tun

Mustapha’s government in Sabah and helped establish a new multi

ethnic coalition.2’

In sum, compared to traditional ties, modern patron-client

networks in Sabah and Sarawak are more unstable, particularly since

the start of competitive elections. With the influx of immigrants,

especially into Sabah, unstable ‘peripheries’ have grown

‘8M±chael Vatikiotis, “Dominant Front,” FEER, 31 March 1994,18. Also see Michael Vatikiotis, “Settling Scores,” FEER, 24 March1994, p.23.

‘9Suhaini Aznam, “Murmurs in the forest,” FEER, 27 July 1989,p.30.

20Francis Loh and Kok Wah, “Early Elections In Sarawak?:Understanding Electoral Politics in Sarawak,” Aliran 11, no 7(1990), p.5.

21Mauzy and Milne, Malaysia, p.117.

193

Page 204: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

considerably in recent years.22 Political relations with Kuala

Lumpur have also contributed to fluid patron-client clusters --

federal pressure can cause clusters to rupture and realign in an

attempt to placate or gain support from Kuala Lumpur. Patron-

client ties are now based less on loyalty, obligation and honour

and more on material benefits. A common feature of elections in

Borneo Malaysia is the downward flow of jobs and cash from patrons

and the upward flow of votes from clientele. As Michael Vatikiotis

notes, “winning votes in Sabah is an expensive exercise; state

politics is notoriously unpredictable and plagued by shifting

loyalties and an appetite for cash.”23 Finally, a key

characteristic of patron-client links in Borneo Malaysia is the

exchange of political favours by indigenous elite for financial and

electoral support from Chinese business clients.

Political power, patronage and timber are inseparable in

Borneo Malaysia. Timber is more important to the economies of

Sabah and Sarawak than to Indonesia or the Philippines. For this

reason, virtually all political leaders have had extensive ties to

timber operators, and profits from illegal and legal logging fund

22Many of these immigrants, both legal and illegal, manage toget on the electoral rolls, often assisted by political partiestrying to expand their support base. From 1986 to 1989, the numberof new voters in Sabah increased by more than 25 percent, many ofwhom appear to be illegal immigrants. Michael Vatikiotis, “FloatingVoters,” FEER, 18 June 1992, p.30.

23Michael Vatikiotis, “Disarray in the ranks,” FEER, 10September 1992, p.26. For example, during the Usukan by-electionin Sabah on May 11, 1991, all parties reputedly used money toinfluence voters. Suhaini Aznam, “Double Blow: Sabah party losesby-election and a leader,” FEER, 23 May 1991, pp.11-12.

194

Page 205: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

political parties and powerful patron-client networks. The next

section provides background on the timber industries of Sabah and

Sarawak. I then document links between key political patrons and

timber clients, before briefly examining domestic and international

opposition to elite control over Borneo Malaysian timber resources.

PATRON-CLIENT POLITICS ND TIMBER IN BORNEO MALAYSIA

Background

From 1919 to 1952, the timber industry in Sabah was

monopolized by the British North Borneo Timber Company. During

this period, the Company logged limited quantities of high quality

hardwoods. In 1952, logging rates increased after three large

foreign firms and eight local companies began operations)4 Log

extraction accelerated in the 1970s and early l980s. From 1971 to

1989, Sabah exported on average 11.7 million cubic metres of timber

every year.25 In 1973, primary forests covered 55 percent of

Sabah; by 1983 this had dropped to 25 percent.26 Large-scale

24Malcolm Gillis, “Malaysia: public policies and tropicalforest,” in Gillis and Repetto, eds., Public Policies, p.123. Forhistorical background on forestry management in Sabah, see A.J.Fyfe, “Forestry in Sabah,” Malayan Forester 27 (1964), pp.82-95.For a description of timber extraction methods in Borneo Malaysiain the first decade after WWII, see G.S. Brown, “Timber ExtractionMethods in N. Borneo,” The Malayan Forester 18 (July 1955), pp.121-132; and Kadir Mohd. Nastan, “A Note on Logging Methods Used By ALarge Timber Company On The East Coast of Sabah,” Malayan Forester29, no. 4 (1966), pp.303-306.

25Michael Vatikiotis, “Malaysia’s war,” FEER, 4 June 1992,p.65.

26Repetto, The Forest For The Trees?, p.56; and Gillis,“Malaysia: public policies” p.141.

195

Page 206: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

0 1-fl 0 C)

H II CD CD II CD U) P

00 C)

0 H 0 CD U) c-I- CD 1- H II c-I CD U) w

H U) U) CD

:zi

CD

H-

Hc-

I-p) H

pi :i. I.”

(f)0

CD

CD

c-I-

U)

CD

c-I

H ‘-0(l

)H

Hc-

wH

—0 H

p3

(I) t3 Ii CD CD H 0 CD c-I

-

-flI

.JJ

Cu,.

IL

iH

-CD

I--.

).U

)U)o

.’c-t

U)

H-

U)-

I-i

3H

’<

0‘-o

rIl

HH

-‘‘j

iCD

Ho

U)U)

I-

‘JH

-IIH

oH

-fl

U)pi

CD

i.c-

I-H

U)1-J

Oc-I

-w

1b

U)b

t<

)•.

‘<0

1-J

o;

-C

ñi-

IjO

CD“-I

Lj6’C

D0

_)

c-I-

c

CD

Oc-i

-lJ

)H

-C

DH

P)

C)3

II

CDP

P

IU

)U

)P

Jp

)0

pj

ii

U)p

..U

)H

-H

-U)

=c-i

-H

-H

-C)

0CD

O°J1-

HH

-Pi

H

pic

.pJ

U)

Jljo1-

Ht<

I-’-

<)

Cl)U)

CD

H-

H-

U)U

)(X

Pir-

U)

H-J

CDCD

J-

U)C

D

zc-i

-U)

0)

9)I-

flc-

i-‘-c

i0

9)U)

‘-d0

HH

CD0

c-I-

09)

00

0CD

II0

00

CDC)

c-I-

0U)

CDH

-I-

I-c-i

-0

LQLQ

c-I-

9)0

c-I-

IIc-

tH

‘-

CDc-I

-i)

I-Q

,LQ

(.Qi-f)

9)j

CDH

-C

CD‘-I

Zc-I

-CD

CDH

-H

-c-i

-I-j

i-f)Cl)

><‘t

IIpi

I-fl

CD9)

U)0

I-3

9)CD

H9)

H-

9)1-

ic-I

.0

(P(.Q

c-I-

U)H

-CD

U)H

H-

c-I-

‘-<H

c-I-

H-

H-

H3

IIc-

i-9)

<3

CDH

-0

9)CD

c-t

CDCl)

Hc-

c-i-

9)3

HCD

H-

1-fl

ci)

CD‘-

<H

HCD

Hc-i

.U)

HQ

9)0

H-

HU)

9)c-I

-1-

fl9)

H-

k<

HCD

0i

pip

c0

H-

c-CD

3CD

CDpi

c-‘

U)U)

9)H

°:

-U)

0CD

c-i-

c-i

g9)

CDH

CD‘<

CD0

CDpj

‘0

CD9)

CI)

Ic-I

-<

CD‘

U)H

’U)

‘-dI

0—

]9)

c-i-

0CD

C)

CDH

-w

‘•

II9)

CDCD

U)H

-W

H-

9)j

CD:

0c-I

-‘—I

piH

0C)

H9)

0c-I

.1-I

C.

-CD

HH

-9)

jt

HH

-I-

flCD

1U)

U)H

CD9)

CDH

CD

‘-

‘CS

9’9)

Hq

C)

9)CD

9),-

t.H

H-

H1-5 c-I

-c-

I‘

0H

-CD

H-

HH

-H

0c-i

-9)

(X)

1-s

HCD

HCD

HH

-H

CDp-

c-I-

U).?

i-s9)

<o

c-I-

0CD

H-

0H

U)H

-00

Hc-i

-1-

flr-

c-I-

wc-i

-‘

H-

9)9)

09-

Ci)

‘‘-C

S CDCD

H-1

)H

0,

CD0

c-I-

HH

-H

CDCD

Hi-.

9’H

-U)

1-fl

H-

CDCD

9)0

00

CDCD

0

jo

CDP

CD0

CS.

Hc-I

-0

c-i-

H‘C

S9)

U)1

1-fl

CD0

‘CS

c-I-

‘H

9’CD

U)Q

00

0c-I

-CD

1-

CDH

c-i-

H9)

1-5CD

0Q

H0

c-I-

9’CD

pi9)

CDr

1-

j9)

3H

U)CD

c-c-i

-0

H0

I

U)U)

00

0

HCD

H-

0H

-H

-H

-‘-

<9)

H0

0H

0H

-1

CD1-

Hp

H9)

0CD

CDH

PH

-H

-0

k<

H‘-5

U)q

CDH

-0

pc-I

-c-I

-9’

°(I)

1-59)

H-

c-I-

‘CS

H-

jc-I

-U

)CD

IIP

H-

H-

‘-CS

c-i-

S9)

1-5U)

H-

CDp

9)CD

Hc-

t1-

flH

U)9)

9)1-5

09)

H-

1-5H

-9)

c-i-

CD‘CS

U)tJ

HU

i9)

0CD

0CD

H-

U)H

-U)

c-I-

c-I-

H-

0r’

JC

)U)

9)-5

CDCD

CDP.

.-

00

LQU)

-

Page 207: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

permanent forest cover. Under Sabah’s forest policy, 3.35 million

hectares of forests -- or 45.4 percent of the land area -- are

classified as Forest Reserves and under the control of the Forestry

Department. Stateland Forests -- set aside for agricultural

conversion or development projects -- cover 1.14 million hectarés,

and are not controlled by the Forestry Department. Around 30

percent of Sabah’s land is cultivated or urbanized.3° The Forest

Reserves contain around 850,000 hectares of protection forests, and

about 2.5 million hectares of Commercial Forests -- mostly lowland

and hill dipterocarp forest set aside for sustainable timber

production. Most Commercial Forests have already been logged. By

1993, loggers had harvested over 2 million hectares; only 413,000

hectares of primary forests remained in the Commercial Forests.3’

The populations of Sarawak and Sabah are almost identical (1.7

million). However, Sarawak is 60 percent larger than Sabah and is

nearly as large as Peninsular Malaysia. Sarawak has 8.7 million

hectares of forest, covering almost 71 percent of the total land

area of 12.3 million hectares. The dominant forest type is mixed

dipterocarp hill forest. There are three million hectares of

30Sabah Forestry Department, Forestry in Sabah (Sandakan: SabahForestry Department, 1989), p.51, pp.53-54, p.58. This chapterrelies mostly on government or corporate data. Unlike in Indonesiaand the Philippines, there are few NGOs to provide alternativeestimates. As would be expected with government and businessstatistics, these figures tend to represent the most optimisticscenario.

31Sulaiman, “Forest Plantation in Sabah,” p.14.

197

Page 208: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

9)0

0H

-H

C)U)

9)9)

1CD

<0

9)I-

Hi

Mi

H-

093

HH

Cl)IQ

Cl)H

0(

c-I-

9)U)

CDCD

LQC)

III-

CI)

CI)

Cl)

(H

-U)

c-I-

9)I—

iI-0

9)9)

HCl)

c-I-

I9)

9)CL)

0I-I

)9)

.CD

H-

iII

H-

H-

HQ

9’_J_

(.

9)H

ij

CDI

CDH

C()

OC

DH

H9

)F-

CD9’

9’9)

HH

-p

U)CD

Cl)(.

Q9

)M

$JH

c-I-

Hi

H-

CD9)

c-I-

9)••

MH

-CD

IIM

2)9’

CI)

3CD

CDCD

39)

HH

09)

c-t

c-t-

9)Q

iM

U)C

H-

H-

HH

iCD

<0

c-I-

<-

9)9

)•$

)‘-)

CDH

iU)

9)0

H-

t-

-0

9’0

CDI

9)O

H0

CDCD

MH

ii

CD

CD b9)

H-(

DCD

Hi

(1)II

Cl)

FlCD

c-I-

Ci)

H9)

pJC

)t1)

‘1i

0H

9’H

-CD

QC)

•0

CD0

r-t

CD9)

CDC

DP

)MCD

9)H

9)Fl

U)9’

FlCD

HC)

I_1C

i)c-I

-CD

CD0

CD9)

FlCD

CDH

o‘i

IpiM

c-I-

FlH

Cl)

‘1<

c-I-

FlI

CDc-I

-C)

C-I-

9’2)

CDc-

tFl

(0I

0I-H

(1)Fl

H-

9)Ci

)9)

I’zi

c-I-C

D<1

“<

c-I-

HIc

H0

ga

‘ii

1H

-H

9)IH

9’

CDc-I

-CD

c-g

c-r

jk<

IH-

CD

FlCD

9)H

0CD

0CD

H-

c(p

oti)

Ic-I-

dc-I

-H

-9)

9)Fl

H-

IH-

9’

CD9’

1)M

Ci)

‘1(1)

09)

0CD

Cii

CI)

c-I

-H

-CD

CD9)

HH

Fl<

Hc-

rFl

H-

PFl

CD-

Hi

0C)

CDFl

OCD

‘dCD

9’9’

H-

Pc-I

-0

-]c-I

-c-

I

CD

HD

°M

MD

&c-I-H

FlC

DC

DFl

9)H

09’

Fl9’

9)c-I

-9’

c-r

2)(0

H-

oF

l(I)

Fl H-

frU)

H-

Fl(I)

3-‘

HFl

HLi

iN

CD9)

C)M

H-.-

i9)

CD<

C)0

;ia

q‘-

C)Fl

FlH

H9)

I9’

Fl

HH

-9)

U’

9)d

H-

c-I-

9)-

9’0

p.,

c-I-

I

•0

-H

H-

Hi

CDH

CD

•U)

CD-

H0

CDH

-H

-Fl

c-I-

(I)CI

)H

HU

’9’

Flp

M0

Cl)

CI)

Hi

CDH

i0

U’

HCD

9)Cl)

H

C)

C)H

-cQ

<9)

H-

‘rJ

Cl)H

CDH

Q9’

Ci)H

HFl

9’Fl

9)H

H-

p.

CDH

CDH

iFl

H-

C)•

IU)j

L’j

Cl)

c-i-

<ID

—0

02)

c-I-CD

0CD

Mi

wb

HFl

HFl

(1)3

Cl)CD

cFl

2)c-I

-i-

CDc-I

-CD

CDU

.H

-Fl

p.

iD0

HIC

DC

ICD

00

C)CD

c-I-

CDC)

CDCD

C)H

i2)

ICi)P

)9’

c-I-

c-I-

FlH

-C)

CD

Hi

c-I-

0c-I

-H

00

2)C)

(I-

9)H

U)

(i’M

H-

‘-Dc-I

-Fl

CI)

U)9)

9)M

iFl

2)H

-H

p.Q

H-

2)CD

9)H

-CD

CDFl

0CD

39)

UIc-I

-Lx

)H

C)Ci

)c-I

-Fl

CDp

.CD

FlU)

p.

Page 209: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

the highest in Southeast Asia.38 Like Sabah, log exports have

underpinned Sarawak’s economy in the 1980s and early 1990s.39 In

1991 and 1992, total timber production declined somewhat in Sabah,

to around 11 million cubic metres. In Sarawak, log production

climbed to 24 million cubic metres in the late 1980s and still

stood at 18 million cubic metres in 1992. Despite a log export ban

in Sabah and greater export restrictions in Sarawak in 1993, Borneo

Malaysia continues to harvest huge quantities of tropical logs. In

1993, Sabah set log production at 7.9 million cubic metres; Sarawak

established a target of 16.5 million cubic metres (9.5 million

cubic metres from the Permanent Forest Estate and the rest from

State Land Forest) •40 In 1993, Sabah’s Chief Minister announced

that annual log production would be reduced to 6 million cubic

metres over the next few years.41 While the Sabah government

considers 6 million cubic metres sustainable, according to the

38James Clad, “Boom and bust leave Sabah’s vault empty,” FEER,6 February 1986, p.64. More recently, Sabah’s economy has faredpoorly. In 1992-93, GDP only grew by 3 percent, compared with a 9percent national average. Michael Vatikiotis, “Slap On The Wrist,”FEER, 27 January 1994, p.14.

39Sarawak’s GDP growth slipped from over 8 percent at the startof the 1990s, to 5 percent in 1992, and 3.7 percent in 1993. DougTsuruoka, “Awakening Giant,” FEER, 21 July 1994, p.68.

40For Sabah, see “Sabah slaps immediate ban on log exports,”The Straits Times, 30 April 1993, p.23. For Sarawak, see “Loggersturn to copters as prices rise,” The Borneo Post, 19 November 1993;Syed Abu Bakar and Pang Hin Yue, “Taib: Pay attention to theseareas,” New Straits Times, 13 May 1993, p.5; Fadzil Ghazali,“Transparency in forest policy urged,” The Borneo Post, 13 May1993; and “CM: We’ll fully practise sustainable devt by 1995,” TheBorneo Post, 28 January 1993.

41”Logging in Sabah reduced substantially, Chief Minister,”Asian Timber, January 1993, p.4.

199

Page 210: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

Malaysian Primary Industries Minister, Sabah’s annual sustainable

yield may be as low as 3 million cubic metres.42 Until 1995, the

Sarawak Forest Department plans to maintain timber production at

the 1993 level. From 1995 to 2000, the Department will hold

production in the Permanent Forest Estate at about 9.5 million

cubic metres and decrease extraction from State Land Forest to

between 5 and 6 million cubic metres.43 Sarawak maintains log

production is now sustainable, a claim emphatically denied by

environmentalists.

While logging is the economic backbone of Sabah, and a key

resource in Sarawak, timber profits mainly benefit a small

political, bureaucratic, and corporate elite. Only marginal

amounts seep to outlying areas, mostly during elections as patron-

client networks mobilize peripheral supporters. Cash payments by

the state just before elections and straightforward ‘vote-buying’

redistribute a tiny portion of timber wealth in Sabah. In Sarawak,

loggers sometimes put local leaders on a retainer in exchange for

support and an informal agreement to suppress complaints about

environmental degradation. Few native people, however, have

benefitted from logging. For example, even though much of

42The Minister’s figures are based on data from the SabahForestry Department and assume production from the Permanent ForestReserves, Stateland forests, and primary forests. “Figures onlogging provided by Sabah Forest Dept: Lim,” Borneo Post, 28February 1993.

43Sarawak Forest Department, Forestry in Sarawak, p.37.

Stan Sesser, “A Reporter At Large: Logging the Rain Forest,”The New Yorker, 27 May 1991, p.56.

200

Page 211: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

Sarawak’s logging is on traditional Iban land, Ibans have not

prospered. According to Malaysian government figures, almost half

of Iban households fall below the poverty line.45 One reason is

that Ibans, who are 95 percent rural, are not well integrated into

patron-client clusters or networks, perhaps partially due to their

historically egalitarian society. Although an awakening of Dayak

(Iban and Bidayuh) consciousness, similar to Kadazan-Dusun in

Sabah, may eventually bring the Dayak into the patron-client fold,

to date these aspirations have been unsuccessful.46

STATE PATRONAGE AND TIMBER IN SABAH

From 1967 to 1974, the United Sabah National Organization

(USNO), under the firm grip of Tun Mustapha Harun, dominated Sabah

politics. Based mainly on timber, Mustapha built an extensive

patron-client network that superseded all others, allowing him to

rule in an autocratic way. He controlled the state legislative

assembly and the bureaucracy. Mustapha was also head of the Sabah

Foundation. Under his leadership, the Foundation -- established in

1966 to support education and social projects --“was rapidly

transformed to become a prime vehicle for administering state

45james Clad, “Slow the hill rises,” FEER, 30 May 1985, p.36.

Some Ibans do receive a small portion of timber profits. Theanthropologist V.H. Sutlive reported that when a timber companylogged communal forests, money was paid out to the district leader,the longhouse headman, and the Ibans living in the longhouse. Hefound that for every 10 dollars, 6 went to the district head, 2 tothe longhouse leader and the rest was divided among the longhouseresidents. V.H. Sutlive’s work is discussed in Peter Searle,Politics in Sarawak 1970-76: The Iban Perspective (Singapore:Oxford University Press, 1983), p.110.

201

Page 212: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

exploitation and development of timber resources, with the benefits

being distributed on a patronage basis to political supporters.”47

To help win the 1974 election, Mustapha used his control over the

Foundation’s timber profits to award all adult Sabah citizens M$60.

He also used timber profits and concession licences to appease and

mute potential adversaries. According to Means, “patronage and the

‘irregular’ rewards of office were so great that the visible

opposition to Mustapha’s policies had been reduced to

insignificance.”48 During this period, Mustapha’s hold on Sabah

was so tight, he was able to spend 9 or 10 months a year abroad,

ruling through key clients such as Syed Kechik, Director of the

Sabah Foundation. The dominance of Mustapha’s patron-client

network allowed him to funnel a major portion of timber profits to

his own pocket, supporting extravagant personal comforts and

opulent homes in Australia and England. State funds also provided

a luxurious official residence, a Boeing 707, and two executive

jets .‘

After the 1974 election, Mustapha’s control began to erode, in

part due to an escalating dispute with the federal government over

oil revenues. In 1975, under federal pressure, Mustapha ‘retired’

and was replaced by his loyal follower, Said Keruak. From behind

47Means, Malaysian Politics, p.42. For background on the SabahFoundation (Yayasan Sabah), see Yayasan Sabab, Yayasan Sabah: 1966-1991 (Kota Kinabalu: Yayasan Sabah, 1992). For more details onMustapha’s early years in power, see Milne and Ratnam, Malaysia -

New States in a New Nation.

48Means, Malaysian Politics, pp.42.

49Ib±d.

202

Page 213: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

the scenes, Mustapha maintained power until April 1976, when USNO

lost the election to Fuad Stephens’ Bersatu Rakyat Jelata Sabah

(Berjaya) party. In June, Fuad Stephens’ reign ended abruptly when

he died in a plane crash. He was replaced by Harris Salleh who

ruled a multi-ethnic coalition until 1985. Compared to the

Mustapha years, Harris Salleh’s government reduced extravagant

waste and flagrant displays of personal wealth. Yet, patron-client

networks and state patronage were still central features of Harris

Salleh’s reign. Timber concessions and profits were at the core of

many patron-client networks. By the early l980s, Berjaya

“perfected its techniques of retaining power through an emphasis on

development projects, which tended to be distributed by political

patriarchs and through patronage systems linked to the government.”

Berjaya easily won the 1981 election, in part “by a judicious

distribution of projects and other benefits just prior to the

election.”5° Foreign assistance provided crucial support for this

extensive state patronage; by 1985 Sabah’s foreign debt was M$2.7

billion.5’

The Sabah Foundation has dominated Sabah’s logging industry.

In 1970, the Foundation was granted a hundred year licence to

855,000 hectares of forest, “to be developed on behalf of all

citizens of the state.” The Foundation gained even more control in

the late 1970s when it became “a statutory body of the state

50Both quotes are from Ibid., p.154.

51Ibid., p.155.

203

Page 214: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

government.”52 In 1984, the Foundation was awarded another large

concession and now controls close to 1 million hectares of forest,

one seventh of Sabah’s land area.53 The Sabah Foundation has had

close ties to Japanese trading companies. In 1986, the Foundation

extracted 1.2 million cubic metres of logs; 72 percent went to

Japan.54 Besides the Sabah Foundation, there are also some

powerful private timber companies. Aokam Perdana Bhd, under the

control of Teh Soon Seng, operates Sabah’s largest timber

processing plant. Aokam Perdama receives logs at preferential

prices from Idris Hydraulic Bhd which controls a 190,000 hectare

concession in Sabah. Idris Hydraulic has close connections to the

United Malays National Organization.55

Not. surprisingly, top politicians have maintained tight

control of the Sabah Foundation. From 1985 until March 1994, Sabah

was ruled by the Parti Bersatu Sabah (PBS), a multi-ethnic party

led by Datuk Sen Joseph Pairin Kitingan, and dominated by Catholic

Kadazans.56 Even though Chief Minister Pairin was chairman of the

52Both quotes are from Gillis, “Malaysia: public policies,”p.123.

53Yayasan Sabah, Yayasan Sabah and Innoprise Corporation SdnBhd (Kota Kinabalu: Yayasan Sabah, 1993), p.1.

54Sabah Forestry Department, Forestry in Sabah, p.85.

55Raphael Pura, “Timber Companies Blossom On Malaysian StockMarket,” AWSJ, 30 November 1993, p.12.

56The new Chief Minister of Sabah is Tan Sri Sakaran Dandai,leader of the Sabah wing of the United Malays National Organization(UMNO), a key party in the Barisan Nasional (BN) coalition which isaffiliated with the federal government. For background on the BNcoalition and the lead up to the February 1994 election, see“Pairin: I’m not ashamed,” Sabah Times, 3 February 1994, p.1; “Why

204

Page 215: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

CD1x

jC

)U)

ti[-

h’t

i‘-<

‘zI

==

0JQ

C)W

WO

HO

•tiC

DCD

ip

.t-.

H-p

.H-.

pp.

U)O

rt

uJH

OC

D(H

NH

.U

)C

FH

)L

ij

HU

)iJ

)C

DH

jCF

H-i

-H

rF

CD

OU

)H

-U

)JO

rt

U)H

--

C)H

k<C

D—

I-IU

)IC

)<

U)C

D-

<pi

bCD

H-

JU

)D

bIo

HlZ

1C

Dp.o

IJiI

Ij

<1H

-p

içr

Q1i

b’IH

-hi

CD

U)C

FU

)U)

CFC

t-Ii-

<LQ

IIIC

DIF

-]

wh

II]

kDIC

‘H-

CF(D

H-

IH-IU

)IIp

iii0

I-I

H-lC

DU

)U)

‘U)

I-

H-U

)lCD

PIH

lU)

--

CDIcu

p.

1Ff)

IH-k

-=

rt=

H-

HIU

)Q

U)Q

IpiH

‘1IPJ

‘°(7

1j

H6

1:3.I

-1

L-It

’pi

IbH

CD

’II1jI

ILJ-

IP’“Jb

IC

DC

DI

lH

-H

CDtU

)IH

H-

-

HC

D1CD

I’-]

0‘

pit’

CDIH

-CD

IPi

1wIH

-QCD

c-t

‘JQ

PJ’

tiP

Ji.<

-kD

CD

IP’I

PJ0

lCDp.

CDI

IPJ

W1w

I3Ib

ui1w

brt

H-

<II

011

P)

Zk-

H-

H-

U)H

i-<

xj

0<

CD

H0C

D’J

LJ

-“°t5

qiU

)-

HO

P)C

Dpi

HC

D[b

1iP’

HjC

DH

D<

..C

Dpi

pH

PH

°H

H0

U)‘,o

ICD

‘.D

o-

pipi

4.D

HIU

)C

DX

i0Q

:ip.

CD“°

<H

-i

HP

)-:

:H

Hg

HH

ic

H-

..-C

i2-j

-W

CFU

)H

MH

OH

CFH

O<

HiO

0d

HCF

P’IH

-H

-O

H-H

•W

Iw

oC

FC

FH

-H

p.H

Hi

CD

OC

DH

U)

U)CF

CDO

Cl)W

piU)

CDCF

U)CF

ijpi

CDM

i)

CDC)

p.

00

HCD

Mi

CF‘ti

IIH

-Cl)

‘dCD

CD‘—

‘-0

C)p

0C)

C)P)

Pipi

Hp)

p.

H-

p.

CFrt

(I)‘<

HP

)CF

H-G

PP)

CDU

)H

-•

H-

PiI-I

H-

U)3

0c-

FC

rc-

Fp

.U)

C)(1)

0‘tS

tH

-H

p)0

-0

0H

CDCD

H0

PH

-CD

H-

H-

‘j

PJCD

U)

‘tiU)

U)C)

p.

CrH

PiPi

CDP)

HII

CFH

Pii

U)H

H0

CDCD

0H

PC

DU)

CFZ

HCF

PiCF

Mi

0H

‘<H

0‘

o0

H-j

H-

ip

iPi

HH

-:;-

Ct

?U)

CDCF

0CD

H-

•M

icF

pU)

U):3

.tY

p.

piPi

piCF

qH

-CD

II0

HH

-CD

0‘tJ

CDII

U)CD

HH

CDM

iW

Mi

U)CF

0p

.Pi

‘M

iC

H-

0C)

C)b

(.QCF

LQp

.CF

CD)

C)CF

H-

HP’

CF0

.<(j

)H

-h

-CF

CD0

i-CD

H-

-p.

CD‘-P

i—np

.N

P’0

=H

-CD

CFU)

1H

-U)

CFI-

CFCF

H-

U)CD

U)CD

IIP)

u-o

bCD

•p

.0

CL)

PiCD

t.H

-M

iCF

CF0

‘U)

oH

-<

0p.

CFpj

CFj-

.0

CDCD

P’:i

pW

CDFt

l-

Mi

b.-i

pjCD

CDCF

l-CF

P-

0

H-

Li

Mi

CF

Mi

o0

IICD

LJ

0H

Cl)CD

p.p.

p.k<

P)P)

Mi

PJCF

CFH

Hp)

3p

.CD

0U)

CDII

H-

CFH

IM

iCD

H-

30

CFC)

0H

H0

CFH

H-

Mi

H-

:ii-.

iCD

CFCD

-,C

CDCF

IH

k<

6CD

C)CD

-‘

U)0

CFC

DM

i

HCF

CFCD

CF0

3.1

i0

CDCF

IQCF

<11

1)U)

pii

0H

,CD

H-

0p

.CD

HCD

I-iPJ

U)

Pip

.p

.p)

U)CD

II(D

p.H

-H

-H

-p

.b

CF0

PJP)

Cl)CD

H0

H)

CFCF

0M

iU)

HU)

CD(.P

(.QCD

3.0

Page 216: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

Datuk Lim Guan Sing argues that the PBS uses Innoprise and the

Sabah Foundation “for political patronage among its supporters.”6°

POLITICAL LEADERS, PATRONAGE, AND TIMBER IN SARAWAK

Since 1966, the state Ministers of Forestry in Sarawak have

all been from the Malay-Melanau elite and have been members of the

Parti Bumiputra Bersatu (PBB), the most powerful member of the

current Barisan Nasional coalition government. Since the state

Minister of Forestry has the exclusive power to grant or deny

timber concessions, “both between 1970-81 and ever since 1985, the

Chief Ministers have jealously kept this portfolio in their own

office; for it is a portfolio of extreme power.”6’ State leaders

have also maintained close links to lucrative log exports.

According to Colchester, “all whole logs are exported through the

company, Archipelago Shipping, an import-export company part-owned

by the state and part-owned by a relative of the Chief Minister

[Taib] ,,62

The most powerful patron in Sarawak is Chief Minister Datuk

Tan Sri Abdul Taib Mahmud. The Asian Wall Street Journal describes

him as one of Malaysia’s most “flamboyant” politicians. He has a

60A statement by Lim Guan Sing, “Allegations substantiated,”Sabah Times, 11 July 1990, p.2.

61Colchester, Pirates, p.35. For a summary of Sarawak politicsfrom 1983 to 1987, see Means, Malaysian Politics, pp.165-172.There have been five Forestry Ministers: Hj Abdul Taib Mahmud(1966-67); Datuk Tajang Laing (1967-70); Chief Minister Datuk AbdulRahman Yaakub (1970-81); Datuk Haji Noor Tahir (1981-85); ChiefMinister Datuk Abdul Taib Mahmud (1985-to present).

62Colchester, Pirates, p.36.

206

Page 217: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

penchant for extravagant purchases, and owns a vintage Rolls-Royce,

a mansion in Kuching, and the late Liberace’s grand piano.63

Timber underpins Taib’s personal wealth and political power. The

1987 election in Sarawak provided a rare glimpse into his links to

logging. During this campaign, former Chief Minister Tun Abdul

Rabman Yakub and his nephew, incumbent Chief Minister Taib, openly

accused each other of using timber concessions and money to

strengthen their political positions.TM Their dispute was largely

personal and factional -- Rahman Yakub was angry with Taib for not

following his ‘advice’ even though Rahman Yakub had personally

supported Taib’s ascent to the Chief Ministership in 1981. Chief

Minister Taib, in an attempt to weaken the political position of

his increasingly critical uncle, froze 25 timber concessions worth

about M$22.5 billion (US$9 billion) which were linked to Rahman

Yakub’s clientele. This sparked a public war to expose each

others’ links to timber money.65 Taib’s group provided documents

indicating that Rabman Yakub, during his tenure as Chief Minister,

had “set up a very complex web using nominees and shell companies

to cover up ownership of large tracts of the best timber in

63Raphael Pura and Stephen Duthie, “How Ekran Bhd. OutfoxedRival For Power Deal,” AWSJ, 2 February 1994, p.12.

TMChief Minister Taib and the Barisan Nasional coalitiongovernment has ruled Sarawak since 1981. For a pro-governmentaccount of Taib’s reign, see James Ritchie, A Political Saga:Sarawak 1981-1993 (Singapore: Summer Times, 1993)

65Zainon Ahmad, “Timber freeze sparks ‘war’,” New StraitsTimes, 10 April 1987, in Yu Loon Ching, Sarawak: The Plot ThatFailed 10 march 87 - 17 april 87 [A collection of newspaperarticles] (Singapore: Summer Times, 1987), p.66.

207

Page 218: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

Sarawak.”66 It was divulged that all eight of Rahman Yakub’s

daughters, many other family members, friends, associates and his

office staff had large timber holdings. Documents were also

released that showed Chief Minister Taib had distributed similar

amounts of timber concessions to his close family, friends and

clients.67 In total, it was revealed that Taib and his clients

controlled approximately 1.6 million hectares of timber while

Rahman Yakub and his clients controlled around 1.25 million

hectares, which together comprise over 30 percent of the total

forest area of Sarawak.68

Chief Minister Taib’s repeal of timber concessions held by

Rabman Yakub’s group was an important reason behind Taib’s

subsequent landslide election victory. Rahman Yakub’s patron-

client network lost its main source of patronage and many members

defected, especially Chinese ones. Chief Minister Taib reportedly

gained the support of many Chinese politicians by offering timber

concessions to leaders of the Chinese-based Sarawak United People’s

Party.69

Other influential ministers in Sarawak also have direct links

to timber concessions. For example, Datuk mar James Wong Kim Mm,

66”More of timber licences ‘kept’ in Rahman’s circle exposed,”People’s Mirror, 13 April 1987, in Ching, Sarawak, p.69.

67For a list of political connections to timber companies, seeLogging in Sarawak (Selangor, Malaysia: INSAN, 1989), pp.73-74.

68Nick Seaward, “At loggerheads with power,” FEER, 2 June 1987,p.32.

695ee Suhaini Aznam, “Wood for the trees,” FEER, 5 December1991, pp.55-57.

208

Page 219: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

who is President of the Sarawak National Party (SNAP) -- a key

member of the Barisan Nasional government -- and Minister of the

Environment and Tourism, is head of Limbang Trading. This company

controls about 300,000 hectares of timber concessions in Sarawak.

As Minister of the Environment, Datuk Wong has a well—known

reputation for supporting logging and dismissing environmental

degradation. In 1988, he explained that five years after logging

primary forests, “all the animals are back. .with more fruits and

nuts than before.. .logging is good for the forest.”7° In the same

interview, when the President of Survival International asked if he

was concerned with the effect of deforestation on weather patterns,

he relied: “We get too much rain in Sarawak; it stops me playing

golf.”7’ Limbang Trading has reportedly sold timber on the

government’s protected species list; a list established by the

Select Committee on Fauna and Flora, chaired by Datuk Wong.72

In Sarawak, around half a dozen Malaysian-Chinese companies

control timber extraction.73 These corporations are linked to top

70Quoted in “International experts say Sarawak natives badlyaffected by logging,” Utusan Konsumer, (March 1988), in WorldRainforest Movement and Sahabat Alam Malaysia, The Battle ForSarawak’s Forests, second edition, (Penang, Malaysia: WorldRainforest Movement and Sahabat Alam Malaysia, 1990), p.54.

71Robin Hanbury-Tenison, [President of Survival International],“No Surrender in Sarawak,” New Scientist, 1 December 1990, p.29.

72”International Experts,” Utusan Konsumer, in World RainforestMovement and Sahabat Alam Malaysia, The Battle, p.54.

73Doug Tsuruoka, “Awakening Giant,” FEER, 21 July 1994, p.70.According to the Star, 90 percent of Sarawak’s timber industry iscontrolled by Foo Chow Chinese. “The pioneers of timber industry,”The Star, 19 September 1991, p.11.

209

Page 220: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

state leaders, supplying financial and electoral support in

exchange for concession licences and contracts, political

protection and bureaucratic exemptions. Malaysia’s largest timber

operator is Datuk Tiong Hiew King. He heads the Rimbunan Hijau

Group of companies which controls 800,000 hectares of timber

concessions and logging contracts in Sarawak. Rimbunan Hijau also

operates huge logging ventures in Papua New Guinea, accounting for

60 to 80 percent of timber exports. The 1993 Chinese edition of

Forbes magazine estimated his net worth at M$2 billion.74 Datuk

Tiong has powerful political ties. He is an appointed federal

Senator. He is also a key figure in the Sarawak United People’s

Party, and a close friend of Sarawak Deputy Chief Minister Wong

Soon Kai. He strongly backs Chief Minister Taib and the Barisan

Nasional coalition government, and has secure links to local

politicians. Taib’s sister, Aisah Zainab Mahrnud, and the Sarawak

government are partners in one of his logging and plywood

operations. In another logging venture, Datuk James Wong and Datuk

Tiong are partners in a 180,000 hectare site near Limbang.75 Datuk

Tiong has also worked closely with Japanese companies. Japanese

technical advisors have influenced the management of his plywood

mills; through a Hong Kong affiliate, two of these advisors are

74Summarized in Raphael Pura, “Timber Baron Emerges From theWoods,” AWSJ, 15 February 1994, p.1.

75Raphael Pura, “Deal Moves Berjaya Into Timber,” AWSJ, 7December 1993, p.1, p.4; Raphael Pura, “In Sarawak, a Clash OverLand and Power,” AWSJ, 7 February 1990, p.1; and Raphael Pura,“Timber Baron Emerges From the Woods,” AWSJ, 15 February 1994, p.1,p.4.

210

Page 221: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

minority shareholders in Tiong’s timber empire. According to one

source, Datuk Tiong’s companies are “almost Japanese in their

operations. ,,76

Datuk Ting Pek Khiing is another powerful ethnic Chinese

businessman in Sarawak. He is Chairman of the Ekran Company which

controls 600,000 hectares of timber concessions in Sarawak. In

early 1994, this company was awarded a contract to build the huge

Bakun hydroelectric dam. This is the most expensive infrastructure

project in Malaysian history. The dam will create a lake about the

size of Singapore. Before flooding the area, Ekran will clear

80,000 hectares of forest which should produce three to six million

tons of timber. Ekran officials estimate that timber profits from

log exports and a planned wood chip plant could exceed M$2 billion.

Moreover, according to Datuk Ting, due to the “pioneer status” of

the project, “there will be tax exemptions for quite some time.”77

Datuk Ting has close ties to Chief Minister Taib and Prime Minister

Datuk Sen Mahathir Mohamad. Taib’s Sons are minority shareholders

in Ekran and in Pacific Chemicals Bhd, another Ting company.78

These political ties were a critical factor behind the choice of

Ekran to build the Bakun Dam. According to the Asian Wall Street

Journal, the deal was “negotiated privately in just a few weeks by

76Raphael Pura, “Timber Baron Emerges From the Woods,” AWSJ, 15February 1994, p.4.

77Quoted in Raphael Pura, “Ekran Is Tapped To ConstructMalaysian Dam,” AWSJ, 31 January 1994, p.4. Pura provides detailson the Bakun Dam, Ibid., p.1, p.4.

78Raphael Pura and Stephen Duthie, “How Ekran Bhd. OutfoxedRival For Power Deal,” AWSJ, 2 February 1994, p.12.

211

Page 222: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

Datuk Ting and powerful Sarawak Chief Minister Tan Sri Abdul Taib

Mahmud, then approved by Dr. Mahathir and awarded without

competitive bidding.”79 Prime Minister Mahathir confirmed this

deal “a day after he attended a wedding dinner for Chairman Ting’s

son. 8O

PUBLIC OPPOSITION AND PATRON-CLIENT POLITICS IN BORNEO MALAYSIA

The link between politics and timber profits is widely known

among the people of Sabah and Sarawak, yet there is little public

opposition to political control over this valuable resource.81

While discussing the allegations and counter-allegations of

‘corrupt’ timber management during the 1987 election in Sarawak,

Marcus Colchester ponders:

For the foreign visitor, the most extraordinary aspect ofthis affair was that these revelations went undisputedand were accepted by the general public. Neither were

79Raphael Pura, “Ekran Is Tapped To Construct Malaysian Dam,”AWSJ, 31 January 1994, p.4. Two other major timber operators inSarawak are Hiew Teck Seng and Wong Tuong Kwang. Wong’s son, WongKie Yik, is a federal senator. Raphael Pura, “In Sarawak, a ClashOver Land and Power,” AWSJ, 7 February 1990, p.1.

8O5 Jayasankaran, “Onward March,” FEER, 24 November 1994,p.140.

81One notable exception is the Penans of Sarawak who activelyoppose logging. But they constitute a small percentage of thepopulation and are divided on the issue since many work for timbercompanies. I. Rajeswary, “Profits vs. Preservation,” in DwindlingForests: Diminishing Returns (New York: UNOP, 1991), p.17. It ispossible that local and tribal people privately dislike statemanagement of timber since ‘acquiescence’ does not necessarily mean‘acceptance’. See James C. Scott, Weapons of the Weak: EverydayForms of Peasant Resistance (New Haven: Yale University Press,1985). To confidently determine whether local and tribal people inBorneo Malaysia ‘accept’ state management and allocation of timberresources would necessitate direct and extensive field research.

212

Page 223: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

there calls for a public enquiry into the issuing oflogging licences, nor attempts to impeach the politicianson charges of corruption.82

Although this lack of open opposition may partially be a result of

the difficulty of collective action in multi-ethnic and religious

states, and partially due to the political and economic dominance

of a small elite, its roots in traditional power relations and

patron-client exchange help mute public opposition.

While domestic criticism is muffled, there has been strong

international condemnation of ‘corrupt’ Borneo Malaysian

politicians and timber tycoons. For this reason, state leaders --

especially Sarawak’s Chief Minister Taib -- are sensitive to any

international or domestic probes of Malaysian forestry management.

The Sarawak government closely supervises NGOs (including tapping

phones), and monitors foreign visitors, especially journalists and

researchers. For the last 20 years, Sarawak has blacklisted

journalists, academics, and NGO leaders, using the power over

immigration to bar unwanted visitors.83 Despite these measures,

criticism of Borneo Malaysian forestry management mounted in the

late 1980s and early 1990s. In 1992, the federal and state

governments launched a campaign to suppress domestic environmental

critics -- in particular the Penan of Sarawak -- and flood the

world media with positive images of Malaysia environmental

82Colchester, Pirates, p.31. Revealingly, the environmentalcandidates all lost in the 1987 Sarawak election, even though theyhad won several seats in the federal election the previous year.Suhaini Aznam, “The Quiet Drums,” FEER, 10 October 1991, p.19.

83lnterview, Foreign correspondent, Kuala Lumpur, 10 March1994.

213

Page 224: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

management. When announcing the campaign, the federal Primary

Industries Minister declared: “If the reputation of Malaysia is not

protected by giving the right information and counter arguing

against eco-colonialistic attitude Es], such misinformation will in

the end affect the country’s economy.”84

The next section analyzes timber policies in Borneo Malaysia.

Pervasive clientelist ties between top state patrons and timber

operators weaken supervision of state implementors, distort, formal

policies, and undermine state capacity to enforce regulations.

This does not mean that formal institutions and policies can be

ignored. Despite dismal enforcement, public policies have

important consequences, often providing incentives to mine the

forests.85 But they must be seen as existing alongside informal,

unstable, instrumental arrangements that drive destructive logging,

protect illegal loggers and smugglers, undercut tax and royalty

collection, place concessions in the hands of a small,

unaccountable elite, and distort policies to encourage processing,

reforestation, plantations, and concession management.

84Toh Lye Huat, “Plan to counter anti-tropical timbercampaign,” New Straits Times, 11 March 1992, p.10. This campaignhas further clouded the line between propaganda and reality. Ithas also increased the difficulty of conducting primary research inMalaysia. For further details on the campaign, see “Govt tocounter foreign ‘green’ smear campaigns,” The Straits Times, 11March 1992, p.15; and “Help sought to monitor group,” New StraitsTimes, 11 March 1992, p.10.

85For an excellent set of articles on the links between poorlydesigned public policies and tropical deforestation, see Gillis andRepetto, eds., Public Policies. These findings are summarized in“Conclusions: findings and policy implications,” in Ibid., pp.385-410.

214

Page 225: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

ROLE OF FORMAL INSTITUTIONS, REGULATIONS, ND POLICIES

A. Background

Sabah and Sarawak both have exclusive jurisdiction over

forestry management. The federal government is restricted to

financing research and development, providing technical assistance

and training, issuing export licences,86 and approving large

foreign investments.87 As well, under the federal Environment

Quality Act, state logging companies are required to conduct

environmental impact assessments. State governments are

responsible for compliance, however, and so far no logging company

has ever bothered to submit a report.88

Under the 1957 Land Code and the 1954 Forest Ordinance, all

forested areas in Sarawak are owned by the state.89 Responsibility

for forestry policy and enforcement, and issuing and cancelling

timber concessions, rests primarily with the Sarawak Forest

Department, while timber tax and royalty policies are formulated by

the Chief Minister’s Off ice.9° The Sarawak Timber Industry

86Rajeswary, “Profits vs. Preservation,” p.15.

87The federal government also has some indirect influencethrough its control of areas like the national budget and manpower.Interviews, Universiti Pertanian Malaysia (UPM), Faculty ofForestry, Malaysia, 8 March 1994.

88M±chael Vatikiotis, “Clearcut Mandate,” FEER, 28 October1993, p.54.

89Sarawak Forest Department, Forestry in Sarawak, p.7, p.13.

90Gillis, “Malaysia: public policies,” pp.149-153. Forbackground on forest legislation and policy in Sarawak, seeMalaysian Forester, “Forest Resource Base, Policy and Legislationof Sarawak,” The Malaysian Forester 42, no.4 (1979), pp.311-327.

215

Page 226: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

Development Corporation (STIDC) negotiates with foreign investors.

Harwood, a subsidiary of STIDC, monitors log export quotas and

timber concessions. Since the beginning of 1993, STIDC has taken

charge of approving timber export licences from the Ministry of

International Trade and Industry.9’

In Sabah, responsibility for timber management is divided

between the Sabah Foundation (through Innoprise), the Forestry

Department, and the Chief Minister’s Office. The exact duties of

each institution are unclear, although generally both the Sabah

Foundation and the Chief Minister’s Office grant and revoke

concessions, the Chief Minister’s Office determines royalty policy,

and the Forestry Department controls and enforces harvest

regulations outlined in specific licences, the 1968 Forest

Enactment (and 1984 and 1992 mendments), and the 1969 Forest

Rules.92 The Forestry Department is only involved in minor

reforestation projects, primarily for research.93

91”Timber exporters must register with STIDC,” The Borneo Post,1 January 1993.

92Gillis, “Malaysia: public policies,” pp.l27-128.

93lnterview, Sabah Forestry Department (Jabatan PerhutananSabah), Kota Kinabalu Branch, 16 February 1994. For background onthe basic goals and policies of the Sabah Forestry Department, seeSabah Forestry Department, Goals (Sandakan: Sabah State Government,undated); and Malaysian Forester, “The Forest Resource Base, Policyand Legislation of Sabah,” The Malaysian Forester 42, no. 4 (1979),pp. 286 -310.

216

Page 227: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

B. Logging Guidelines in Borneo Malaysia

In Sabah, 2 million hectares have been carved into timber

concessions.94 There are three main kinds of licences for logging:

concessions, special licences and annual licences. The Sabah

Foundation grants concessions, usually from 21 to 25 years and

between 20,000 and 80,000 hectares. In 1989, there were 11

concession holders. Special licences are for 5 years and can be

renewed for another 1 to 5 years. There were 93 special licences

in 1989. Annual licences are renewable 1 year agreements. There

were 500 in 1986.96 In theory, Sabah timber operators -- including

the Sabah Foundation - - use the Malayan Uniform System.97 All

commercial trees above a 45 centimetre diameter are cut in one

logging operation. The stand is then left to regenerate naturally

-- usually 60 to 80 years -- before the next harvest. To

facilitate natural replacement, climbers and seedlings which

94Rush, The Last Tree, p.42.

95Domingo N.P. Chai and Yahya Awang, “Current Forest ResourceScenario in Sabah,” in Ti Teow Chuan, ed., Opportunities andIncentives for Wood Processing in Sabah. Proceedings of a seminarorganised by Timber Association of Sabah held at Kota Kinabalu, 22-23 August, 1989. (Kota Kinabalu: Timber Association of Sabah,1989), p.25.

96Sabah Forestry Department, Forestry in Sabah, pp.63-64.

97According- to a spokesman, since 1993 Innoprise has improvedtimber management. While still in the early stages, this involvestwo key changes: leaving some areas undisturbed and planting moreindigenous trees. Japan has shown no interest in supporting theseefforts. Interview, Senior manager, Innoprise Corporation, 9February 1994.

217

Page 228: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

Cl)

c-FQ

c-tpi

PiI

JCD

H,

H,

CDH

,Cl)

H0

c-F0

iH

--

CL)

0Cl

)L

0c-F

0

Cl)

CD Pii

Cl)

H i;JCD CD

CL)

Hi

Cl)

It

-H

c-tP

iCD

H-

JP)

C)[‘

s)

iCD

CD0

Cl)

ItCD

CDCD

I- C) CDII CD

c-f

P)I-h 0

IIt

IIH

-h

CDCl

)CD

Cl)CD

)c-

fc-

fII

H-

CD I-

<‘-

0P

<H

-H

,0

HH

H-

HPi

HCD

H-

C):i

pitj

C);

CDH

-fH

-H

HPi

H-

Pik<

H-

C)0

H-

HCl

)CD

Cl)CD

Cl)

H,

H-

‘dL

Hj

0Cl)

Hcf

CDpi

CD•

çt

QH

,C)

H-

c-Fc-

FH

,0

.•

•3

Cl)

CDCl

)

0H

,Cl

)Cl

)0

k<

c-CD

‘1P-’

0It

F-Cl

)H

U)

HCD

CDCl)

‘<Cl

)It

p,j

c-f

CDo

‘-1

HH

-I-

<CD

pj

H Cl)

H-

(Cl

H-

H-

CDH

,

It

CDH

-Pi

H-

ICD

c-FC)

0c-

f‘-Q

bH

HP)

H‘•

0

Cl)

c-FH

LQ

Pi

H-

‘1-

0CD

CL)

I-P’

II0

CDH

,LQ

oLQ

Cl)

H,

IIH

Cl)

PiH

-0

Pi:1

tLQ

bPi

jpi

c-F0

H-

H,

HZ

CL)

I-0

CD-

QCD

(.QCl)

HC)

F—’

00

H-

0It

HP)

PJCL

)Ii

HCl)

H-

PJ$T

hH

-H

-CD

HJ

Cl)1

H,

CD0

pJI-

Cl)I

CDcf

c-CD

Cl)

Cl)pj

c-f

CDCl)

Cl)I-

H-

CDc-

fP-’

Cl)

IICD

CDCL

)i—

piH CD

Cl)Cl

)C)

0cF

Cl)

C)C

DH

c-F

CD

c-f

HH

H-

CD

cFP)

CDH

-q

ItIt

CDH

II“•

Cl)CD

0H

c-Fi

Cl)

CDCD

Hc-

fCl)

CDCD

Cl)p)

Cl)CD

ItQ

Cl)

I-H

,H

-0

I:SH

,H

H-

0c-

M::

Cl)

01

CD

HCD

DCl

)0

P-’c-F

II‘-

0Cl

)pi

c-FH

H8

CDCD

HPi

0o

0i—

i‘-

PiCD

(QCD

H-

PiH

-r

c-f

-0

I-<

C)CD

0Pi

It

Cl)CD

-c-

fCD

Cl)

Pi bH

pic-F

Cl)

Hpi Pi

b-•

HCD

CD

CDl) It

c-Cl) C)

ItH

-CD Cl)

Hp-I

CDIi CL

)Cl

)

0 H,

p-Ic-F CD

CD t3It

CD0

CDH

C)CD

It 0 CDH II

Cl)

CL)

H-

C) CDC)

iCD

c-F

“j

Cl)Ii

-CD

CDCD

IH-

PJ0

bCD

III

IIICL

)P

)Cl)

Cl)

Cl)Cl)

F-Z

t-

H-c

-Fx

jP

JP-I

pJc-F

Cl)

H

f.J

Dc-ffr

t;•‘

P),

fJpi

HP

)PiO

OH

I-

H-

CD

CD

--

Cn

ICl)

HIt)c-F

H(D

C)

Itc-F

HC

l)

U)

c-fH

-D

QCD

It‘D

0j

C)c-t

O(.

QIC

l)

H-

iCD

H-

f’)

Qi-’

ItO

HII

•H

-.

IIH

-c-t

OU

)CD

HH

,0

F’-

Cl)

HCD

QC

)CD

CDP)

.Qc-F

H-

IIP.’-

C)H

P.’‘r

JM

IJ

U)U

)H

CDH

00

I-- i

Hc-F

Qc-F

H,

H-

0

Cl)

H-

-CD

‘-

c-Fj)

XC

I)

ItC)

U)

U)j

Hoc-F

CDP.’

P.’P.’

‘- c-r

H-

c-f

0P.’

lCD•(

.Q0

-

L-

C) H-

MC

DH

HH

jID)

—)H

P.’P.’

tPIc-

tH

-lU

)-

Ip.’C

l)F

IjCL

)I

H-C

D’l

lM

HCl)

‘P.’

P.’

QC

I)H

MIt5

-0

Page 229: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

liiiZ

ctI

—ID

CD

IHIti

iU

)C

)JI

Ift

CD

H-

rtrt

lcD

-.

U)U

0II))

ft0-

u1

CFCD

I1

pji

1M

CD0J

CD

rt

H-

11

CD

.3

CD

H-Q

CftH

iH-

(H

-CD

j‘H

-Ct-

CDIh=

ICD

)CD

LII-

0H

i-C

)

CDF

3.C

)(D

0U

)C

DFs

)H

i3

j.(D0C

l)

-

H-

Q

CiD

Cr

IpjH

-HH-

I3

0pi

1J0

I lCDU

)CD

CD.

ftH

-H

HC

Dft

-

Hw

OC

DH

i<

‘dU

)C

DC

Dh

‘dH

-H

H-

0 P-

CF

HH

H-

CD

-iD D

-CD

wP

U)

.0ct

dW

00

CID

I-

.L

1JC

DH

-PuP

)tY

U)

ftIt

5’

CDP

urr

(.Q

CD

IPJ

Cl)

d0

tTU)

CDCl

)CD

d<

HH

PuPu

00

Hi

CDC

<Pu

PuCD

0i

0b

dH

-H

iPi

Pub

ftci

I-cH

(QPu

purt

0H

ftCl

)pu

i-C)

IQPu

(ft

0I-

HH

-Pu

CDCD

H-

H-

CD<

ftCD

U)0

-C)

I-CD

iCl)

Cl)M

ipu

Hi

CD(

Qft

CD0

0CD

0H

ftII

Cl)

i-CD

PuCD

C)P

CDC)

pCD

0M

iCD

puH

pCl

)0

H-

0ft

rtft

i-’

t1CD

H-

HH

U)Cl

)ft

CDCD

H-

xQ

0P

u0

Cl)U

)8

k<

PuCD

CD‘r

j<

Hi

Pu<

0Ii

H-

(-<

CD0

•H

-‘1

0CD

CDp

0ft

Mi

Q3

ciPu

Ppu

II CD1

dCl)

CP

—cn

Cl)

HC

rtJ

H-

puCD

Pu‘‘

CI-

3I-

Hi

‘CD

puft

1‘

HH

-ft

0Pu

ç.

CDft

-CD

ft•

I-cCD

C)‘-

CDF-

CDW

CDci

-

CDH

-Pu

Cl)CD

C)I

C)C)

PuPu

U)ft

U)i-

’H

ftII

ftb

00

ci

CDH

-Cl)

0CD

CD3

<H

iCD

ci

CDH

-0

CDH

i:

U)i)

H-

3PJ

0pu

Hi

U)Cl)

H-

HC)

p-

CDH

HH

-Pu

HC

CDH

iH

-CD

WU)

HH

-u

i0

CD0

Hpu

H-

CDft

Pub

CDU)

CDCD

dW Q

U)‘-

<i

HH

--

pjH

U)-c

CDH

§.

HH

-CD

CDpu

puC)

H-

CDC)

Cl)pu

CDH

-CD

U)ci

p,

QCl)

•U)

It

C)H

H-

H-

C)i.

<H

Hi

PuH

iCD

H-

pH

-0

CDH

-p

cic

‘IH

-H

iH

-ft

‘.i

fti-c

ft

uCD

puPu

i-0

-0

Cl)

I-f)

•ft

H

0U)

Hi

CD

QH

-C

PuH

-CD

puCD

-H

0pu

H-

ftPu

CDM

iH

CDpu

FdH

-P)

-CD

U)-j

H-

j)0

C)H

LI-I

H-

U)Pu

ftI1

CDCD

HCD

CDH

..

<J

Pu:3

.(-C

U)•

ci0

ft i—c

CDH

-H

-Pu

CDH

-o

0H

-1

C)H

-H

iM

iH

H-

H-

CDPu

3CD

CD0

wp

U)H

i0

Pu-

H-

ftI-c

H-

I-Ift

Hft

C)H

-CD

HH

CDCD

HCD

0H

0U)

H-

LOPu

LQ0

LOCD

CD0

<0

CDU)

U)p)

LQi-J

I-Ii-

CDft

.<Pu

i-U)

ftCD

CDC)

(.QPu

P-IPu

-H

iPu

ftCD

CDU)

ftH

HI-

Puft

PuH

-J

PuH

-H

-S

I-CD

ftH

HCD

F-J

I-ICD

H3

CDft

Cl)

ftft

-Pu

ci‘-

<Pu

0CD

t-CD

ci

Page 230: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

Japan. 107

C. Tax and Royalty Policies

Royalty policies in Borneo Malaysia have been more effective

than environmental protection policies. State governments keep all

timber royalties, export taxes, and licence fees, a sharp contrast

to the five percent of oil revenues allotted to Malaysian states.

Over the last two decades, timber charges --- especially on log

exports -- have generated substantial revenues in Sabah and

Sarawak)°8 From 1980 to 1989, the forestry sector accounted for

about 60 percent of Sabah’s revenue; 95 percent came from royalties

and taxes on log exports.’°9 In the early 1990s, the forestry

sector accounted for more than half of Sabah’s revenue and around

one-third of Sarawak’s.

Sabah -- through aggressive royalties and export taxes -- has

‘°7joniston Bangkua±, “Illegal export of timber exposed,”Straits Times, 23 April 1992, p.1. It is difficult to document thepath of illegal logs. Small signs do emerge. During one of myinterviews in Sabah, a Japanese corporate executive telephoned andinquired into the possibility of a sawmill doing minor alterationsto some ‘foreign’ logs before exporting this timber to Japan. TheSabah official refused to disclose the source of the logs, althoughthey hinted it was Indonesia. Confidential Interview, KotaKinabalu, February, 1994.

1081n June 1993, royalties on key tree species in Sarawakincreased by 50 percent. James Wong, “New rates for timberroyalties,” The Borneo Post, 8 June 1993.

109Murtedza Mohamed and Ti Teow Chuan, “Effects ofDeforestation: with Special Reference to East Malaysia,” BorneoReview 2, no. 2 (December 1991), p.127.

220

Page 231: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

captured a significant portion of timber fl5•W Nevertheless,

informal agreements between politicians, bureaucrats, and timber

operators have syphoned substantial amounts of potential state

revenues. To lower forest charges, logging companies -- often in

collusion with customs officials and enforcement officers -- forge

species types, under-declare the value and volume of exports, and

falsify the degree of processing.” In many cases, timber

executives simply report to customs a price or quantity lower than

the one agreed on with the importer. In exchange for accepting

these forged declarations, customs officials receive ‘kickbacks.’

Importers -- generally Japanese trading companies -- ignore these

irregularities as long as “their supplies reach them at the agreed

prices and quantities.”2 Besides these ‘sophisticated’ schemes,

companies sometimes dodge customs, and covertly deliver logs to

“°See Gillis, “Malaysia: public policies,” pp.139-143. WhileSabah’s timber charges have generated substantial state revenue, advalorem royalties on logs and export taxes on sawn timber haveencouraged loggers to mine concessions and disregard damage toresidual stands. Ibid., p.130. In Sarawak, timber royalties arevolume-based (which are reduced for lower grade species), andexport taxes are value-based. While Sarawak has capturedremarkably little timber rent, lower forest fees -- especially onesdifferentiated by species -- have provided fewer incentives topractice high-grade mining. For this reason, loggers apparentlydamage less residual stocks in Sarawak than in Sabah. Ibid.,p.131, pp.149-151.

“1Sabah timber exporters -- including the Sabah Foundation --

have reportedly under-declared the value of log exports by as muchas 40 percent. Openg Onn, “Sabah losing millions in timber scam,”New Straits Times, 15 May 1993, p.6; “Putting Sabah’s logging backon the track,” Borneo Post, 1 February 1993; and “Forestry Deptseizes undervalued sawn timber,” Borneo Post, 19 August 1993.

“2Openg Onn, “Sabah losing millions in timber scam,” NewStraits Times, 15 May 1993, p.6.

221

Page 232: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

offshore ships.’13 As a result of these practices, one Sabah

‘insider’ claims that “two out of every five ships leaving here

have not paid duty.”4 According to some sources, 30 to 40

percent of Sabah log exports were improperly documented in the

early 1990s, contributing to substantial losses of royalties for

the state government. In 1991, one Sabah logging group alone was

alleged to be slipping out the equivalent of 10 to 15 vessels a

month during busy periods, with an annual market value estimated by

the Far Eastern Economic Review at US$100 million. The same

article estimated that in Sarawak these practices may be even more

widespread. 115

Under Malaysian law, federal timber revenue -- collected by

the Inland Revenue Department -- is limited to corporate and

personal income tax on timber profits. Borneo Malaysian companies

routinely practice transfer pricing to evade these taxes. Ethnic

Chinese corporations in both Sarawak and Sabah sell logs to ‘home’

companies, usually in Hong Kong. These logs are priced at the cost

of extraction. As a result, the local company’s books show no

profits, and the company pays no taxes. The Hong Kong company then

sells the logs at market prices, in most cases to a Japanese

trading company (the logs generally ‘leave’ Borneo Malaysia only on

paper). Profits appear in the Hong Kong books, where taxes are

“3Doug Tsuruoka, “Cutting down to size,” FEER, 4 July 1991,p.45.

“4Quoted in Hurst, Rainforest, p.109.

“5Doug Tsuruoka, “Cutting down to size,” FEER, 4 July 1991,p.46.

222

Page 233: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

low. These profits are placed in a Hong Kong bank; the Borneo

Malaysian company then borrows an equivalent amount with interest

payments equal to the interest earned in Hong Kong. Since the

money ‘returns’ as a loan, it is tax exempt.”6

D. Political Concessionaires, Chinese Clients, and Sub-contracting

In Sarawak, all uncultivated land -- except designated Forest

Reserves, Communal Forests and National Parks -- can be licensed by

the state government as logging concessions.”7 Control over

concession licences is a critical source of power for patron-client

networks. According to Philip Hurst, “it is an open secret that

timber concessions are handed out in East Malaysia as a means of

strengthening political allegiances or as rewards for favours.”18

One study declared that in Sarawak, “political elites’ control over

awarding [logging] licences gives them the means to maintain and

tighten their grip on state power -- by alternately rewarding their

cronies and followers, and buying off their political rivals and

opponents.”9 Powerful political concession holders rely on

ethnic Chinese contractors with the equipment and expertise to

“6lnterview, Foreign correspondent, Kuala Lumpur, 9 March 1994.

“7Sarawak Study Group, “Logging in Sarawak: The BelagaExperience,” in Logging Against the Natives of Sarawak (Selangor,Malaysia: INSAN, 1989), p.5.

“8Hurst, Rainforest, p.103.

“9Sarawak Study Group, “Logging in Sarawak,” p.3.

223

Page 234: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

manage the timber site.’2° These ties are at the core of many

patron-client clusters. Political patrons gain financial,

political and electoral support while Chinese business-clients reap

huge profits.

The central role of concessions in binding together patron-

client clusters has contributed to over-exploitation. In Sarawak,

60 percent of all land has been granted as timber concessions --

“on a scale which has no relation to the sustainable capacity of

[timber] resources and with little regard for management

prescriptions on the number and size of trees cut.”121 As well,

patron-client links contribute to contracting arrangements in

Borneo Malaysia that reduce accountability and transparency,

especially when concessions are granted to nominees.’22 In

Sarawak, Chinese contractors often make sub-contracting

arrangements. Sub-contractors, many of whom are directly connected

to local leaders, provide employees and some equipment. To appease

local opposition to destructive logging practices and the poor

treatment of many native loggers, “there is evidence of some native

leaders and even communities being paid off for making deals with

‘20Concessionaires receive either a fixed sum or a percentageof the profits from the contractor -- generally between 5-10percent of the value. Hurst notes that “this may seem a low returnbut revenues build up and involve the concessionaires in almost nofinancial risk.” Besides, “the concession holder frequently doesnothing.” Hurst, Rainforest, p.105.

‘21Anthony Rowley, “Logged Out,” FEER, 13 December 1990, p.74.

‘22The use of nominees makes it difficult to determine whocontrols timber companies. For a discussion of this problem inSabah, see Doug Tsuruoka, “Cutting down to size,” FEER, 4 July1991, p.44-45.

224

Page 235: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

timber concessionaires and especially with logging operators.”’23

These complex contracting arrangements obscure lines of

responsibility and make the enforcement of timber management rules

much harder.’24 In 1993, Kuala Lumpur pushed state governments to

stop awarding timber concessions to companies or individuals with

no logging expertise.’25 According to foresters, this would “help

eliminate unnecessary sub-contracting, reduce corruption and

payment of under-counter money, control illegal logging. . .ensure

higher efficiency... [and] in the long term, generate higher

revenues for the state governments.”26

Unstable patron-client ties contribute to a sense of

uncertainty, providing strong incentives to mine timber concessions

quickly. It is fairly common for powerful leaders in Borneo

Malaysia to revoke concessions and licences as political winds

shift. For example, when Datuk Harris Salleh became Chief Minister

‘23K.S. Jomo, “Logging, Politics, Business and the IndigenousPeople of Sarawak,” Paper presented at the 5th Annual Conference ofNortheast Regional Consortium for Southeast Asian Studies,University of British Columbia, October 16-18, 1992, p.6. For adescription of the harsh conditions for native loggers, seeJeyakumar Devaraj, “Logging Accidents in Sarawak,” in LoggingAgainst the Natives of Sarawak (Selangor, Malaysia: INSAN, 1989).

‘The Director General of the Forest Research Institute ofMalaysia argues: “What happens is that at each stage the individualtries to maximise profit [s]. The responsibility and accountabilityis fragmented and this does not lead to good forestry practices.”Azam Aris, “State govts urged to change timber concessionpolicies,” Business Times, 10 February 1993.

‘25”Don’t give timber concessions to middlemen, state toldagain,” Borneo Post, 20 September 1993.

‘26Azam Aris, “‘Overhaul timber concession system’,” BusinessTimes, 1 February 1993.

225

Page 236: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

of Sabah in 1976, he “cancelled concessions granted by his

predecessor, covering 12 percent of the total forest area under

licence.”27 After Pairin’s PBS party ousted the ruling Berjaya

party under Harris Salleh in the 1985 Sabah election, timber

patronage was again redistributed. The constant threat for

concessionaires and contractors of being labelled ‘corrupt’ further

increases uncertainty. The overlap of ‘modern’ legal institutions

and ‘traditional’ relations of power has created a situation where

timber patronage is an ‘open secret’, yet the threat of being

labelled ‘corrupt’ constantly exists. Charges of corruption

clearly do not undermine authority in Borneo Malaysia in the same

way as in many ‘Western’ democracies. For example, even after

Chief Minister Taib was linked to widespread corruption and

nepotism during the 1987 election in Sarawak, he still won easily.

Nevertheless, corruption charges can undermine the stability of

patron-client clusters and networks, especially when used as a

tactic by the federal government to undermine state leaders or when

used as a strategy by state politicians to ‘embarrass’ their

opponents. 128

Unpredictable political settings and unstable patron-client

networks contribute to a serious problem of ‘capital flight’.

127Gillis, “Malaysia: public policies,” p.127.

128To undermine the PBS, the federal government charged ChiefMinister Pairin, and his brother Jeffrey Icitingan with corruption.For details, see Michael Vatikiotis, “Glacial Justice,” FEER, 27May 1993, p.27. In early 1994, Pairin was found guilty. His fine,however, was low enough that he still qualified for office.Although this verdict eroded some of his legitimacy and authority,he still managed to win the ensuing election.

226

Page 237: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

Chinese timber clients -- concerned about future economic trends,

the fall of their patron, and racial backlashes -- stash a

significant portion of timber proceeds overseas, especially in Hong

Kong. In addition, while there is some investment in wood

processing, there is almost no Chinese investment in long-term

timber management. Loggers perceive the industry as too volatile,

perhaps even doomed.’29

E. Log Export Restrictions and Processing Policies

In 1979, to reduce log exports and encourage domestic

processing of sawn timber and plywood, Sabah imposed export quotas

and increased taxes. But compared to Indonesia these were lenient

and not well enforced.’3° This changed suddenly at the start of

1993 when Kuala Lumpur used its power over export licences to

prevent logs from leaving Sabah.’3’ Officially, the federal

government claimed that the ban was necessary to enhance

‘29lnterview, Foreign correspondent, Kuala Lumpur, 10 March1994.

‘30Repetto, The Forest For The Trees?, p.54; and Kenji Takeuchi,“Market Prospects for Tropical Hardwoods from Southeast Asia,” inJames S. Bethel, World Trade in Forest Products (Seattle:University of Washington Press, 1983), p.437.

‘31’rhe Malaysian Timber Industry Board issues export licencesto Sabah. However in Sarawak, the state government issues theselicences. Interview, Malaysian Timber Industry Board, Ministry ofPrimary Industries, Kuala Lumpur, 9 March 1994. Although theMalaysian constitution clearly gives the federal government controlover exports and imports, Sabah argued that the log export ban wasunconstitutional -- that precedents had been set after Sabah joinedthe federation for state control of timber exports. Interview,Senior official, Ministry of Primary Industries, Kuala Lumpur, 8March 1994.

227

Page 238: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

environmental protection and promote domestic wood processing. It

appears, however, to have been primarily motivated by Prime

Minister Mahathir’s desire to undermine Chief Minister Pairin’s key

source of patronage, topple his power base, and establish a more

cooperative state government.’32 Before the ban, Japan had

imported 70 percent of Sabah log exports.’33 The move surprised

Japanese plywood processors, spinning many into a financial

crisis.’34 Kuala Lumpur lifted the ban in April 1993, after

escalating log prices began to hamper wood processing in Peninsular

Malaysia, and after complaints and pressure from Japan’s wood

processing industry and the Japanese government.’35 The Sabah

government, however, then struck back at Kuala Lumpur and imposed

their own ban on log exports.’36 The Japanese government and

‘32Prime Minister Mahathir was also angry that Sabah’s logexport charges to places like Japan, Taiwan and Korea were the sameas to Peninsular Malaysia. At the time, mainland processors --

facing a serious shortage of logs -- wanted Sabah to decreaseexport charges to the Peninsular. Confidential Interview, SabahIndustry Representative, Kota Kinabalu, February, 1994; and seeMichael Vatikiotis, “Local Hero: Drive to topple Sabah leaderstalls,” FEER, 27 May 1993, pp.26-27.

‘33JATAN, “Asia-Pacific Forests,” November 1993, Presented atthe World Rainforest Movement Meeting, New Delhi, India, April1994, p.2.

‘34P.K. Katharason, “Logs meant for Japan stuck in KotaKinabalu,” The Star, 9 May 1993, p.7; and “Tokyo protests to KLover Sabah’s ban on log exports,” Straits Times, 8 May 1993, p.22.

‘35lnterview, Timber Association of Sabah, Kota Kinabalu, 8February 1994; and “Log ban to remain - CM,” Sabah Times, 21 May1993, p.1

‘36Michael Vatikiotis, “Tables turned: Sabah timber-export banriles Kuala Lumpur,” FEER, 3 June 1993, pp.66-67; and Asian Timber,June 1993, p.8. Although the federal government has theconstitutional power to control exports, the Sabah Forestry

228

Page 239: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

corporations tried to convince Sabah to lift this ban but the

Pairin government stood firm.’37

Sabah state revenues have remained stable since the ban on log

exports. To offset lost export charges on logs, the government

increased local processing fees.’38 The government and companies

have also benefitted from an increase in the price of sawn timber

which doubled in the first four months of the ban.’39 The ban on

log exports has provided a crucial boost to Sabah wood processors.

Before the ban, only 105 out of 164 sawmills were operating; many

were functioning at half of their production capacity. Plywood and

veneer mills were also operating well below capiy4O After the

ban, Sabah plywood, veneer, and saw mills all increased output,

absorbing logs once destined for export.’4’ As a result, there has

been little change in total log production.

Despite stable government revenues and an increase in

Department simply refused to assess royalties on log exports, ineffect creating a log export ban. Fadzil Ghazali, “Sabah timberfirms get go-ahead on exports,” Business Times, 19 May 1993.

Angkie, “Japanese sceptical on Sabah,” Daily Express,17 November 1993, pp.1-2.

‘38Official, Timber Association of Sabah, Kota Kinabalu, 8February 1994.

‘39Official, Timber Association of Sabah, Kota Kinabalu, 8February 1994.

‘40John Lim, “Temporary log export ban in Sabah: no pain, nogain,” Asian Timber, December 1992, p.3.

‘41lnterviews, Timber Association of Sabah, Kota Kinabalu, 8February 1994; Innoprise Corporation, Kota Kinabalu, 9 February1994; Institute for Development Studies, Kota Kinabalu, 12 February1994; and Ministry of Tourism and Environmental Development, KotaKinabalu, 15 February 1994.

229

Page 240: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

processing output, Sabah’s ban on log exports has had few economic

or environmental benefits. Log production is still tar above

sustainable levels, and there has been little improvement in the

management of concessions. The total capacity of Sabah’s plywood

and veneer mills is 11.4 million cubic metres. With production set

at 8 million cubic metres there is a chronic shortage of logs,142

creating strong incentives to process illegal logs. As well, in

the absence of international competitors, the Sabah Sawmillers

Industries Association (SSIA) appears to be suppressing log

prices.’43 In addition, as in Indonesia, the ban will likely

protect and foster inefficient processors, putting even more

pressure on commercial timber stocks.’ Finally, much of Sabah’s

sawn timber is little more than logs with their corners shaved,

providing almost no value-added economic benefits. This ‘sawn’

timber is then exported overseas and processed again.’45 In many

ways, Sarawak has been the main beneficiary of Sabah’s log export

ban. In 1993 and the first quarter of 1994, Sarawak’s logging

142”Log ban to remain - CM,” Sabah Times, 21 May 1993, p.1

‘43The SSIA denies these charges. Interview, Sabah SawmillersIndustries Association, Kota Kinabalu, 16 February 1994. Tostabilize log prices, in mid-1994 the government was contemplatingsetting a minimum and maximum price on logs.

‘Senior Researcher, Institute for Development Studies, KotaKinabalu, 12 February 1994.

‘45lnterview, Ministry of Tourism and Environmental Development,Kota Kinabalu, 15 February 1994.

230

Page 241: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

industry thrived as log prices increased.’46

Unlike in Indonesia since 1985 and Sabah since 1993, Sarawak

has tried to balance log exports with incentives and restrictions

to promote wood processing. Beginning in 1988, the government set

aside 10 percent of logs for processing; in 1992, this was

increased to 17 percent. Despite higher prices for log exports,

since the beginning of 1993, Sarawak has made even more aggressive

moves to promote processing.’47 To guarantee logs and stable

prices for local processors, in early 1994 the state-controlled

Harwood Company was made the sole distributor of local logs.’48 As

well, in 1993 the government gave generous royalty rebates on logs

manufactured in Sarawak,” and reserved around 36 percent of logs

for local processors.’5° By the year 2000, the government intends

to set aside 50 percent of logs for local processors.15’ There

‘46lnterview, Sabah timber executive, Kota Kinabalu, 9 February1994. Although Sarawak log exporters made substantial profits, therapid rise in prices hurt local processors as log prices climbedmuch faster than processed wood prices.

‘47”S’wak aggressive in going downstream,” The Borneo Post, 16September 1993.

‘48”Harwood takes charge from February 1,” Sarawak Tribune, 26January 1994, p.1.

149Sarawak Forest Department, Forestry in Sarawak, p.33; “EnoughSupply of Logs, Says STA Chairman, Peoples Mirror, 9 February 1993;and James Wong, “Cheaper logs for local processing, The BorneoPost, 9 February 1993.

‘5°Interview, Sarawak Timber Industry Development Corporation,Kuching, 17 February 1994. In 1993, the government planned to setaside 6.0 million cubic metres for local plywood and saw mills. “6Mu cu m Of Logs reserved For Local Industry,” Peoples Mirror, 17January 1993.

‘51Sarawak Forest Department, Forestry in Sarawak, p.33.

231

Page 242: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

are, however, no plans to ban log exports.’52 According to a

government spokesman, foreign demand keeps log prices high, and log

exports generate critical foreign exchange. Furthermore, around 60

percent workers who manufacture wood are already Indonesian;

creating more processing jobs would not boost Sarawak’s economy.’53

So far, unlike in Sabah, Japan has not overtly pressured the

Sarawak government to reduce log export restrictions. However,

local loggers -- perhaps backed by Japanese companies -- have

lobbied to reduce export restrictions.’54

With the help of government subsidies and protection, Sarawak

now has 15 plywood mills, 10 veneer mills, and 213 sawmills with a

total capacity of 7 million cubic metres.’55 Processed timber

production is steadily rising. For example, total plywood

production in 1992 was one million cubic metres and was expected to

rise to 1.5 million cubic metres in 1993.156 Like in Sabah and

Indonesia, however, many processing plants operate below capacity.

For example, in early 1993, plywood mills were functioning at 60 to

‘52Tan Chin Siang, “Taib: Sarawak will adopt flexible timbertrade policy,” New Straits Times, 19 October 1993, p.10.

‘53interview, Senior official, Forest Department, Kuching, 17February 1994.

‘54lnterview, Sarawak Timber Industry Development Corporation,Kuching, 17 February 1994.

‘55Asian Timber, February 1993, p.5.

‘56Jack Wong, “Plywood prices revised upwards,” Borneo Post, 10February 1993.

232

Page 243: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

‘.iJ

t!)

C)H

iH

-(1

)9)

(IDCD

U)

c-I-

c-I-

HM

iCD

9)0

tij

•I-0

0I

9)0

H9)

b2)

c-I-

0H

-0

0tY

Hi

•o

U)9)

IIH

0c-F

9)CD

CD‘1

H-M

ic-t

c-FC)

CDCl)

9)CD

l-c-I

-c-I

-<

CDCD

U)H

H-

•C

)H

c-I-

cI-

9)CD

U)CD

H-

C)0

CDH

-(D

ç-I-

c-I-9)

C)CD

c-F

U)c-I

-II

c-I-

H-

Ho

U)9)’

H-

H9)

c-I-

Hi

CDII

k<

9)C)

CD-

II<

9)H

Mi

(DCD

CD

U)H

‘H

-U)

c-F0

U)0

CD0

CDC)

0H

-M

i-

Ic-

IC)

Hi

9)9)

Mi

9)0

0H

i0

01M

iH

CDd

H-

C)H

i-’-

Hi

CD‘-

U)‘-<

CD9)

()CD

0o

9)N

c-I-

CDCD

C)H

-L

CDH

iCD

H-

CDH

-rj

)9)

U)

H-

U)9)

H-

9)$1

Hi

C)H

9)H

CDH

H-

9)c-

c-t

piCD

H0

CDH

(I)9)

o‘-

<U)

U)i

tY9)

c-t

<(I)

CD

H-H

-c-

U)9)

c-I-

CD-

CDC)

H-

CD0

CD0

9)CD

CDU)

c-H

iH

-U)

Hi

H-

c-I-

Mi

I-H

--

Hi

C)•

c-I-

c-I-

0c-

I

CD9)0

C)C)

9)=

CDCD

CDCD

9)9)

c-I-

Mi

c-c-I

-CD

H-

°H

CD9)

0c-I

-H

-c-I

-c-I

-CD

II0

9)9)

Hc-I

-H

01c-I

-0

U)

‘U)HH

CD1

<1

9)c-I

-H

H-

rrIU

)c-

cc-

H-

HCD

CDCD

Ic-

cc-

ck<

CDCD

U)9)

H9)

c-I-

0c-I

-

-U)

c-I-

9)F

d-

0L\

.)P.

.c-I

-I-

HW

0H

-U)

Hc-I

-‘

CDH

010C

DH

-9)

Hi

Hi

H(Q

H-C

H-

iic-

IH

-H

-’l

9)H

i9)

CDU)

-y()

H-

Hc-I

-0

--0

9)CD

C)<

C-

H-

P..

HC

)9)

HH

9)H

IItY

0I-’

CD

CDCl

)H

9)H

-p)

U)

9)(P

(D9)

Hi(P

•U

)h<

NM

HCD

Hi

CDC

DCD

H9)

CD:

H(P H

-

C)3

CDC)

9)‘

U)H

-H

(Pc-I

-

CDH

-H

-(P

CDg

‘tI

1H

jc-I

-c-

fCD

9)U

)0

1I’i

,j

HH

-H

Q9)

P..

CDU)

J9)

U)

c-r

I..9)

9H

iCD

HH

i9)

9)9)

0tY

01un

•CD

c-H

0II

CD0

c-I-

(P•

0U)

H-

-CD

CDCD

Hp.

CDc-I

-H

-CD

‘-:I

b-

tY9)

CD0

9)c;I-

0CD

CDCD

)c-I

-0

9)CD

WC

Dc-I

-c-I

-CD

H-

p3

CD0

CDCD

9)II

H-

I-’l

c.p

c-I

c-

CDH

ic-I

-CD

jCD

c-I-

0H

Q0

H-

Hi

0CD

CDCD

U)H

iCD

CDCD

-H

-9)

fCD

9)CD

9)0

9)H

ik

<C)

H-

HH

CDCD

U)

Hc-I

-d

‘1H

CDc-I

-c-I

-Q

0(P

c-C)

..

9)c-I

--‘

Hi

CDI-

0H

-<c-I

-Q

U)(0

U)U

)H

I-I9)

h0

<H

-U)

2)c-I

-9-’

IIc-I

-c-I

-H

9).

09)

9)<

U)0

CDH

iH

-0

33

C)3-

(PH

HCD

CDCD

Hi

IICD

9)H

iU)

P..

CD‘-

<CD

CD‘<

Page 244: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

forests, illegal logging in conservation areas, and ineffective

reforestation projects.

In Sabah, there is little corporate investment in natural

forest regeneration or timber plantations. Since timber land and

concessions rights are linked to unstable patron-client networks,

both domestic and foreign investors are wary of long-term

commitments. As a timber exporter succinctly explained, companies

“want to be sure that after investing. . .huge sums of money, the

timber will be theirs. There is still much uncertainty over this

aspect.”6’ For this reason, most reforestation is conducted by

the state government -- especially the Sabah Foundation (through

Sabah Softwoods Sdn Bhd) and the Sabah Forestry Development

Authority.’62 There are now 300,000 hectares of state timber

plantations in Sabah, mostly fast-growing acacia mangium.163

Unlike Indonesia and Sabah, Sarawak has no plans to reforest

concession sites or develop commercial timber plantations. Only

about 10,000 hectares of degraded land have been replanted in the

Permanent Forest Estate, mainly for conservation. According to the

‘61Quoted in “The private sector and reafforestation,” The Star,21 September 1991, pp.8-9.

‘62lnterview, Timber Association of Sabah (TAS), Kota Kinabalu,8 February 1994. TAS is a private organization. It works toprotect its members from detrimental government policies. Forexample, TAS advises and negotiates with the state government onlicensing and royalty fees. It is the main organization for logproducers (in the past exporters).

‘63lnterview, Institute for Development Studies, Kota Kinabalu,12 February 1994. For background on Sabah’s forest plantations,see “Four fast growing species in Sabah forest plantations,” TheStar, 17 September 1991, pp.8-9.

234

Page 245: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

government, slash-and-burn farmers destroyed most of these

areas*M In the Forest Department’s view, plantations or

reforestation are inherently unnecessary since areas are logged

selectively. Instead, it is more important to improve

silvicultural techniques 165

G. Recent Attempts To Improve Tiitiber Management

Over the last couple of years, the federal and state

governments have introduced policies to tackle illegal logging and

smuggling, destructive timber extraction, and tax and royalty

evasion. In 1993 the federal government amended its National

Forestry Act to improve enforcement of timber management rules and

curb illegal logging. The revised law increases fines for logging

violations, stipulates mandatory jail sentences of up to 20 years

for illegal loggers, and permits the armed forces to be deployed in

the forests. However, although this law provides important signals

to Borneo Malaysia, as one opposition member of Sarawak’s

legislature noted: “No federal forestry ordinance is strictly

enforceable in Sarawak.”66

‘64See Forestry Department Sarawak, Forestry in Sarawak, passim.

‘65lnterview, Senior researcher, Forest Department, Kuching, 21February 1994; Interview, Senior official, Forest Department,Kuching, 17 February 1994; “Reforestation does not cover loggedareas,” The Borneo Post, 20 November 1993; and “Reforestation OnlyIn Deforested Permanent Estates,” Peoyles Mirror, 20 November 1993.

‘66Quoted in Michael Vatikiotis, “Clearcut Mandate,” FEER, 28October 1993, p.55. For background on the federal initiatives tocombat illegal logging, see Abu Yamin Salam, “Army can nab illegalloggers,” New Straits Times, 25 April 1993, p.2; “Copters to combatillegal logging,” The Star, 25 April 1993, p.3; and “New law to

235

Page 246: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

Iw

HI

IC/)

IJ‘d

Pi

nbCD

HIH

-IP

Jfl)

HC

r111

H1Ib

bP

HH

-Ii

Ii(D

ICD

Iiii

OIC

D•

Il)2

II0

1);

pi-

Ip)

4I]11

Cr

=C

i<

Hp

jIH

<‘1 0

iwC

tH

0gi

U) Cr

CO

IC)

(l)

CD

jH

,0

I(!)

5C

I)

(l)

U)

Cr

CD

H-

piC

DH

-00h

pi

U)H

iC

)H

CD

Lp(

0i

0<

HtY

CDC

DO

(D

H.Q

H-

U)

0‘.

OU

)P)

PH

Wçt

p.1

1c3

.1

-=

k<

pi

p 0ti°

HC

DW

)I(D

.Ii

CD

[rj’

M1

HC

DQ

LQM

PH

-CD

WC

D11

Hp

Ct)

11C

D0

I(p

HC

rU

)U)

(QItn

PH

(CD

CDI

CDI1

Cl)

H(Q

PJ

LI11

CD

HIc-I

Ii1

t-ti

<hi Ip IH

wL

QIc

-I.C

D-

jH

1

U)

CD

Cr

0—1.F

rj

:iIH

110°

IU

)H0

11

HIW

CD

<‘-

<c-

I-fri

Ji

CDU)

p1W

-

piC

DI

CD

III

p,ICD

ItI

) ‘U)

IH

OIh3

DI-

]I0

HH

iI

CD

fr

H-

Hfrj

w11

Ic-r

f):

ICr

I[’l

CDIC

Dp

Cr

-I

illU

)C

DII

-]‘X

jIH

-U)

‘ib

‘—‘

cit-

t-

ICD

‘lID

)=

U1

-

0f-I

-H

CI-

p1U)

QC)

U)H

ci

Cr

‘dM

iH

-ZY

Hi

Cl)H

-0

Cr

P1CD

0CD

Mi

‘ZI

CDC

rU)

iiii

(1)

(.C1<

H-

CD0

CDCD

<CD

CFc).

H-

Cl)C

rpJ

C)-

IiIi

IiCD

C)J

Cl)P1

U)P1

pCl)

Cr

pi<

Cl)

‘-<

CFCI

-ff2

CI-

HIi

CDC

rH

IiCl

)CD

iC

rCD

p1U

)0

0P1

U)

H-

U)p1

Iipi

P‘1

Ii-

IiC

r“i

CD.

IU)

CDp1

Hp1

k<

P10

U)C

rH

i0

IiIi

1-

p10

HCD

HCD

CDC

rCD

11H

P1CD

U)Q

Cr

Cr

Hi

c-FU)

0CD

H-

P1H

H<

Ci)0

U)b

HCl)

P1Lx

iCD

,C)

CDC)

U)CD

3rI

Cl)çu

CDP1

HC

rCD

1H

Ii0

H-

0H

‘i0

CDC

rII

U)p

0rr

Hi

(1)H

-CD

Cr

CDp

Cr

Hi

H-

HU)

b.

IH

-c

CDH

-H

0C

rC

rp1

C)II

CDCD

-C’

Cr

CD°

C)CF

CDH

0H

—LQ

)rr

H-

U)(1

•U)

C)

H-

H0

pj‘

U)

‘1H

-H

0I

0‘

HU)

Cl)

3P1

0H

HP1

0CF

(I)P1

(QH

-H

HCi)

CD0

‘YJ

‘C)

Cr

(DC

p1CD

CDU)

p10

CD3

IIH

-:i

p1C

rH

CD IiP1

‘C

rC

r‘t

CDH

-CD

U)3

CD‘1

H0

‘1H

CDC)

Hb

CDCD

(QCD

H0

C)H

-CD

CDp

CDC

lpi

P11

(.

‘1CD

CDp

C)H

Hi

1p

‘1Ii

iCD

Cl)

U)Q

Cr

U)s1

(Q‘1

HH

P1C

rII

CDH

--<

H-

bCD

3M

iII

piH

-H

Cr

P‘1

P1p

0P1

IIH

-CI

-p

p10

Cr

pH

i3

CDH

DC)

Cl)

w0

CI-

Cr

HCD

P1H

3H

-C

rIi

CDW

WL

i.U)

0(-Q

Cr

0CD

0H

-p

Cr

CDCi)

•H

QU)

H-

Cr

H-

H-

-

U)o

IIII

‘-

U)C

rCD

H-

‘1P

H-

IICD

(U)

Cr

PCl

)CD

‘-C)

Cr

CDri

C)H

i‘-<

1CC

rii

o0

CP.)

CDH

CDCl)

H-

CDC

r-

(I)U)

H-

i-M

U)p1

U)CD

=CD

Hi

Cr

H-

LCCD

CDCF

U)p1

0CD

-P1

0 Hi

CDU)

H-

C)0

P1°

CI-

13CF

‘CD

IIH

iP1

11H

-H

-‘I

CDCD

CDC

rC

rU)

1H

-CF

U)H

PJH

II13

Cr

13M

iP1

CDP1

0U)

0H

-CD

0P1

CDM

i13

13CD

‘OCD

p113

Cr

Cr

CI-

Cr

13CD

CDC

rCD

‘1bi

U)H

Cr

013

p1CD

0C

r11

Page 247: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

round-the-clock checking of all log export points, regular patrols

in the jungle, mount raids and ambushes where necessary and make

regular checks on logging camps, rafts and barges in transit and

log ponds.htl7i The State Enforcement Unit of the Sarawak Forest

Department also established floating check points at all export

locations. Ships or barges transporting logs are now inspected

just before leaving. In addition, the Enforcement Unit plans on

surprise checks of ships loading logs offshore.’72 As an incentive

to boost enforcement, Sarawak forestry officers now receive 50

percent of the total value of confiscated illegal logs.173 To

further hinder illegal loggers, in early 1994, Sarawak banned

transporting logs on some rivers at night.’74

While monetary incentives, more enforcement officers, stiffer

penalties, and tighter regulations appear to be important steps to

improve timber management, in the setting of pervasive state links

to timber operators, these moves are likely to have little impact

on large companies. When announcing plans to combat illegal

logging, the Sarawak forestry director Datuk Leo Chai argued that

most illegal loggers were local people, not major companies. As he

171”Training for Sarawak forestry officers to curb illegallogging,” New Straits Times, 23 April 1993, p.7.

‘72Bob Kedeni, “Move to curb log smuggling,” Sarawak Tribune,21 July 1993; and Magdelene Rogers, “Checking stations to curb logsmuggling,” The Borneo Post, 21 July 1993.

‘73”Sarawak sets up an anti-smuggling team,” New Straits Times,6 February 1993.

on moving logs at night to be enforced soon,” The BorneoPost, 1 February 1994, p.2.

237

Page 248: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

explained, “there are few organised illegal logging groups in the

state because they cannot bring their logging machinery into the

forest without being detected.”175 The failure of past campaigns

to tackle illegal logging and tax evasion demonstrates the impunity

of commercial timber companies in Borneo Malaysia. In 1991, a

former manager of a major Sabah timber group publicly alleged that

his company had extracted logs from restricted areas, forged

species types, and distorted log measurements, costing the state

millions of Malaysian dollars. He claimed that Sabah Forestry

officials were part of these illegal activities. In response,

Chief Minister Pairin announced a low-key campaign to halt illegal

logging and royalty evasion. These efforts, however, had little

impact on major timber firms. Instead, “small operators served as

the scapegoats.” These “small operators were mostly businessmen

believed to be unable to pay customary gratuities to forestry

officials. ,,176

To increase state capacity to monitor exports and improve

royalty collection rates, Sabah officials are now considering a

proposal to hire a British firm -- Inchcape -- to check timber

175Quoted in Seman Endawie, “Cash-for-logs scheme soon,” SarawakTribune, 2 February 1993. The Sarawak Forest Department alsoclaims that efforts to capture illegal loggers are frustrated bylocal residents who work for loggers and refuse to provideinformation on illegal activities. “Locals collude with illegalloggers,” The Borneo Post, 10 June 1994; and “Soon Kai WarnsAccomplices,” Peoples Mirror, 14 June 1993. The village singledout by the Forest Department in the above articles denied thesecharges. “We have nothing to do with illegal logging,” The BorneoPost, 23 June 1993.

‘76Doug Tsuruoka, “Cutting down to size,” FEER, 4 July 1991,p.44.

238

Page 249: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

export and import documents. Inside Sabah, Inchcape would replace

forestry and customs officials who verify volumes, tree diameters,

species type, and tax and royalty assessments. Inchcape would also

place inspectors in key importing countries, including Japan.

According to Sabah forestry director Miller Munang, “the global

approach -- checking shipments at both ends -- is the best way to

plug the leak in the state coffers.”77 If, as Munang hopes,

Inchcape inspections begin at the end of 1994, this could

significantly increase state capacity to control illegal logging

and tax evasion. Since foreigners are not linked to patron-client

networks and are not involved in political struggles, in theory

Inchcape inspectors could be far more effective than current state

officials. But state leaders and implementors who feed on timber

profits are unlikely to allow this to occur. It is more likely

that Inchcape’s proposal will be scuttled or that Inchcape

inspectors will become pawns of the ruling elite to legitimize

current practices.

In the early 1990s, the federal Inland Revenue Department

began a campaign to stop transfer pricing by Borneo Malaysian

timber firms. According to federal Primary Industries Minister

Datuk Lim Keng Yaik, even though transfer pricing is exceedingly

difficult to prove, in 1992 Inland Revenue forced numerous Sarawak

timber companies to pay outstanding taxes, including one large

‘77Th1s quote is a summary of Munang’s comments by DougTsuruoka, “Tree Cover: Malaysian state may hire Inchcape unit totrack timber,” FEER, 20 January 1994, p.54. This article describesInchcape’ s proposal.

239

Page 250: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

conglomerate which had to pay M$100 million. As a result, he

claims that transfer pricing has dropped to a “bearable

minimum.”78 In late 1993, the federal police and Inland Revenue

authorities searched Sarawak’s Rimbunan Hijau Group (led by Datuk

Tiong) for evidence of tax evasion. While the results of the

investigation have not been disclosed, there is ample reason to be

suspicious of Tiong. According to the financial records of Tiong’s

major company -- Rimbunan Hijau Sdn Bhd -- from 1976 to 1991 the

company made a mere after-tax profit of M$9.68 million on total

revenues of M$3.2 billion. As a result, Rimbunan Hijau Sdn Bhd

only paid M$20 million in federal corporate taxes.’79 Compared to

state initiatives, the Inland Revenue Department has had a far

greater impact on large companies, perhaps because Borneo Malaysian

corporate links to federal authorities are often weaker than those

to state leaders.

In the midst of Malaysia’s vigorous campaign to reduce

international criticism of its environmental practices, it is

difficult to wade through the rhetoric and document concrete

changes to timber management. Overall, there do seem to be

marginal improvements, especially in hindering transfer pricing.

But Borneo Malaysia is still far from reaching sustainable timber

management. Harvesting rates are falling but this appears to be a

response to declining timber stocks rather than better management.

‘78Quoted in Raphael Pura, “Timber Baron Emerges From theWoods,” AWSJ, 15 February 1994, p.4.

‘791b±d.

240

Page 251: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

With powerful political patrons protecting major loggers, and with

customs and forestry enforcement officers integrated into timber-

based networks, large timber companies have largely escaped the

‘crackdown.’ When illegal loggers or smugglers are nabbed, they

tend to be small-time operators or local swidden farmers. Sim

Kwang Yang, an opposition member of parliament from Sarawak,

succinctly summarized the current campaign to improve timber

management: “On paper, there is a sluggish move in the direction of

reduced logging under international pressure.”8°

Keeping in mind domestic patron-client politics and timber

policies in Borneo Malaysia, I now turn to assess Japan’s

ecological shadow of timber. I argue that the effects of Japanese

investment, ODA, and conservation projects in Borneo Malaysia have

been swamped by the impact of Japanese log purchases. Japanese

trading companies have bought huge quantities of logs at prices far

below the costs of regeneration and sustainable management. These

logs -- rapidly extracted using Northern bulldozers and chain saws

-- have stoked Japanese mills that churn out cheap, disposable

plywood. Since the log export ban in Sabah, and the gradual log

export restrictions in Sarawak, Japanese companies now import

slightly more processed wood from Borneo Malaysia. As a result,

Japanese consumption of sawn timber, plywood and veneer, and import

barriers to manufactured timber are relatively more important

factors shaping Borneo Malaysian timber management. However, the

180Quoted in Michael Vatikiotis, “Clearcut Mandate,” FEER, 28October 1993, p.54.

241

Page 252: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

residue of Japan’s past log consumption, and lingering log

purchases in Sarawak, have left the deepest scars on Borneo

Malaysia’s forests.

JAPANESE ODA IN BORNEO MALAYSIA

JICA and the OECF have only channelled a small amount of

technical assistance and loans to Sabah forestry projects.181 The

OECF has not provided any concessional loans to help finance

plantation schemes.’82 JICA currently has no projects in Sabah and

there are no plans for future assistance.’83 JICA’s last major

forestry aid project in Sabah -- the Re-afforestation Technical

Development and Training Project -- began in 1987 and expired in

March 1994. This project was operated jointly by JICA and the

state-controlled Sabah Forestry Development Authority (SAFODA).

The state government provided funding, while JICA supplied experts

on reforestation, equipment (such as bulldozers, front-end loaders,

and fire-fighting equipment), and training in Japan. The main

purpose of the project was to enhance planting techniques and train

forestry personnel in silvicultural methods for timber plantations.

The research concentrated on acacia mangium -- a fast-growing

‘81lnterviews, Timber Association of Sabah, Kota Kinabalu, 8February 1994; Institute for Development Studies, Kota Kinabalu, 12February 1994; and Ministry of Tourism and EnvironmentalDevelopment, Kota Kinabalu, 15 February 1994.

‘82lnterview, Institute for Development Studies, Kota Kinabalu,12 February 1994.

‘83lnterview, Senior JICA official, Sabah Re-afforestationTechnical Development and Training Project, Kinarut, Sabah, 14February 1994.

242

Page 253: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

Australian hardwood imported to Sabah in the 1960s -- although

there was some preliminary research on dipterocarp. Today, SAFODA

controls this project, training new recruits using the knowledge

and equipment supplied by JICA.’’

According to SAFODA and JICA officials, the SAFODA-JICA

project was a resounding success.’85 SAFODA -- created in 1976 --

had made minimal headway in replanting in its first decade. But

with JICA’s advice and equipment, by 1993 SAFODA had planted 25,000

hectares of acacia mangium, and 8,000 hectares of rattan.186

SAFODA has no ambitious plans to expand and only expects to plant

around 2000 hectares every year.’87 To date, only a few thousand

hectares of acacia mangium have been harvested. Most plantation

logs have been sold to South Korea.188

Interview, Consulate of Japan, Kota Kinabalu, 9 February1994; Interview, Senior manager, SAFODA, Kota Kinabalu, 12 February1994; and Interviews, Senior officials, Sabah Re-af forestationTechnical Development and Training Project, from JICA and SAFODA,Kinarut, Sabah, 14 February 1994. For background, see “Japanhelping in development of the forest plantations,” The Star, 20September 1991, pp.8-9; and JICA and SAFODA, Official Opening ofthe SAFODA-JICA Reafforestation Technical Development and TrainingCentre (Kota Kinabalu, Sabah: JICA-SAFODA, 1989).

‘85lnterview, Senior manager, SAFODA, Kota Kinabalu, 12 February1994; and Interviews, Senior officials, Sabah Re-afforestationTechnical Development and Training Project, from JICA and SAFODA,Kinarut, Sabah, 14 February 1994.

‘86lnterview, Senior manager, SAFODA, Kota Kinabalu, 12 February1994.

‘87lnterview, SAFODA official, Sabah Re-af forestation TechnicalDevelopment and Training Project, Kinarut, Sabah, 14 February 1994.

188Plantations in Sabah are classified as agriculturalenterprises and are exempt from the log export ban. Interview,Institute for Development Studies, Kota Kinabalu, 12 February 1994;and Interview, Senior manager, SAFODA, 12 February 1994.

243

Page 254: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

JICA-SAFODA research on cross-breeding and silvicultural

techniques improved the quality of acacia mangium plantations in

Sabah. Trees are taller, straighter, grow faster, and have fewer

blemishes. But compared to the problems confronting Sabah forestry

managers, these efforts are minor. The project itself was quite

small; only four, and sometimes five, JICA researchers worked at

the project. Moreover, even if acacia mangium becomes an important

‘agricultural commodity’ able to thrive in degraded areas, it

cannot replace the biodiversity and environmental benefits of

natural forests or sufficiently substitute for the commercial value

of dipterocarp logs. It is also unclear whether these plantations

will actually reduce pressure on natural forests. In theory,

plantations can create employment and provide an alternative wood

source in severely degraded areas. But in practice, as in

Indonesia, timber companies often maximize profits by clearing

natural forests before establishing plantations.189

Japan has provided no major loans or grants for Sarawak

forestry projects.’9° There is now one major technical assistance

project. In April 1993, JICA launched the Effective Wood

Utilization Research Project and Timber Research and Technical

Training Centre. There are four long-term Japanese experts

189This evaluation of the JICA-SAFODA project is not a criticismof individual researchers. I was impressed by the competence andenthusiasm of JICA-SAFODA staff in Sabah, and within their mandate,these scientists made notable strides. But these were narrow,technical solutions with little impact on the sweepingenvironmental and management problems facing Sabah foresters.

‘90lnterview, Senior researcher, Forest Department, Kuching, 21February 1994.

244

Page 255: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

advising S Sarawak counterparts. As well, some Japanese

specialists visit for one or two months. As part of this project,

two or three researchers from Sarawak will study in Japan every

year. In its first year, JICA spent 1150 million. JICA’s budget

for 1994-95 is just over 167 million. This project is designed to

provide equipment, technology, and advice to improve the efficiency

of domestic processing. At present, Sarawak processors discard or

burn 40 to 50 percent of logs. JICA’s project is also supposed to

encourage loggers to extract lesser quality, lesser known species.

Better wood utilization coupled with improved efficiency will waste

less wood and presumably reduce pressure on commercial species in

the natural forests.’9’ While these efforts are laudable, as in

Sabah, compared to the problems of timber management, JICA’s

overall financial and technical contribution has been

inconsequential 192

JAPANESE CORPORATE INVESTMENT IN BORNEO MALAYSIA’ S TIMBER INDUSTRY

In Sabah, Japanese trading companies have invested minimal

amounts in logging and processing.’93 As of December 1993, there

‘91lnterview, Senior JICA official, Effective Wood UtilizationResearch Project and Timber Research and Training Centre, Kuching,21 February 1994; also see JICA and Timber Research and TechnicalTraining Centre, Sarawak Forest Department, “The Effective WoodUtilization Research Project in Sarawak, From April 1993 to March1998,” JICA and the Sarawak Forest Department, July 1993.

‘92lnterview, Foreign correspondent, Kuala Lumpur, 7 March 1994;and Interviews, WWF Malaysia, Petaling Jaya, 10 March 1994.

193lnterviews, Timber Association of Sabah, Kota Kinabalu, 8February 1994; Institute for Development Studies, Kota Kinabalu, 12February 1994; and Ministry of Tourism and Environmental

245

Page 256: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

were 11 wood processing companies in Sabah with Japanese equity.

These mills include veneer, plywood, sawn timber, and moulding.194

Japanese investment is not likely to increase in the near future.

Since the log export ban and the reduction in log output to 8

million cubic metres, Japanese investors have become even more

reluctant to invest in Sabah forestry projects.’95 Furthermore,

Sabah timber operators have become disillusioned with joint

ventures. According to a Sabah business executive, local companies

are wary of joint ventures with Japan since many lost money in the

past. He argues there are two key reasons for this poor track

record. First, some Japanese partners manipulated timber prices

and undercut profit margins of joint ventures. In these cases, the

Japanese joint venture partner, after consulting with their ‘home’

company, sold logs below the international market price to enhance

the profits and economic stability of the company as a whole.

Second, joint ventures often have lower production efficiency.

Japanese (as well as U.S. companies) have a tendency to manage

workers within their own cultural prism. As a result, Sabah

Development, Kota Kinabalu, 15 February 1994.

194From the data bank of the Department of IndustrialDevelopment and Research, Sabah, Malaysia, supplied February 1994.Small foreign investments only require state approval while largeones necessitate federal permission. Of the 11 Japanese projectsin Sabah, 7 were large enough to require federal endorsement.

‘95joehann Angkie, “Japanese sceptical on Sabah,” Daily Exress,17 November 1993, pp.1-2; and Joehann Angkie, “Come, talk to us:TAS,” Daily Express, 19 November 1993, p.1. The political strugglebetween Prime Minister Mahathir and Chief Minister Pairin furtherincreased the reluctance of investors. See “No trade zone underPBS: KL,” Daily Express, 15 February 1994.

246

Page 257: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

workers -- who may, for example, respond poorly to anger -- are

less productive.’96 Sabah’s dominant timber operator -- the Sabah

Foundation -- has moved away from joint ventures. For example,

Sinoru Sdn Bhd -- a wood processing plant in Sandakan -- was

originally a joint venture with Japan’s Yuasa Trading Company.

However, in 1989 after 15 years as a joint venture, the Foundation

gained full control.’97

Most Japanese trading companies have avoided direct

investments in logging in Sarawak. The few Japanese-Sarawak

logging joint ventures have not been particularly successful. For

example, Itochu’s joint logging venture with Limbang Trading

Company (owned by James Wong) was a public relations fiasco. A

scandal erupted after it was disclosed that the company’s logging

roads had been funded by JICA and the EXIM bank.’98 Itochu

withdrew in 1987 after intense public criticism, including a debate

in the Japanese Diet. There have also been few Japanese wood

‘96lnterview, Sabah timber executive, Kota Kinabalu, 9 February1994.

‘97The Foundation’s only remaining joint venture is SabahSoftwoods, an agro-forest plantation with the British company,North Borneo Timber (which holds a 40 percent share). TheFoundation offered to buy these shares but North Borneo Timberrefused. Interview, Senior executive, Yayasan Sabah [SabahFoundation], Kota Kinabalu, 14 February 1994. For background onSabah Softwoods, see Raymund G.S. Tan, “Tree Plantation -- TheSabah Softwoods Sdn Bhd Experience,” in Ti Teow Chuan, ed.Opportunities and Incentives, pp.37-50.

198Yo±chi Kuroda, “Historical Overview of the Timber Trade andForestry Development in East and Tropical Asia and the PacificNations,” A Paper Presented at the International Workshop forForest and Environmental Preservation in Asia-Pacific, Seoul, SouthKorea, February 1994, p.3.

247

Page 258: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

processing joint ventures in Sarawak. In total, there have been

about half a dozen, all with guarantees of access to the Japanese

market.’99 Sarawak’s Ministry of Resource Planning and the Sarawak

Timber Industry Development Corporation have both urged Japanese

companies to invest in processing.20° But these firms have shown

little interest.20’ Rather than participate directly, trading

companies prefer to purchase logs, and when necessary provide

credit, equipment, and technical advice to facilitate logging.202

‘99lnterview, Senior official, Sarawak Timber Association,Kuching, 20 February 1994; [STA represents nearly 500 privatelogging and timber processing companies in Sarawak. Sarawak TimberAssociation Brochure, Kuching, undated); and Interview, Seniorofficial, Forest Department, Kuching, 17 February 1994.

200James Ritchie, “Sarawak to cut log production within twoyears,” New Straits Times, 30 March 1992, p.3.

201Taiwan is the most important investor in Borneo Malaysianwood manufacturing. Interviews, Department of IndustrialDevelopment and Research, Kota Kinabalu, 16 February 1994; andSarawak Timber Industry Development Corporation, STIDC, Kuching, 17February 1994.

202Japanese funds and equipment helped companies log Sarawak’shill forests during the l980s. Kuroda, “Historical Overview,” p.2.In 1987, Datuk Leo Moggie claimed that “the marketing of Sarawaktimber is still very much controlled by the Japanese trading housesas Sarawak timber companies are largely dependent on these tradinghouses for their intricate line of credit.” Quoted in Nigel Dudleywith Sue Stolton, The East Asian Timber Trade and Its EnvironmentalImplications (Surrey, UK: WWF UK, 1994), p.9, first quoted in E.Hong, Natives of Sarawak (Penang, Malaysia: Institute Masyarakat,1987)

248

Page 259: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

JAPANESE COMPANIES AND CONSERVATION IN BORNEO MALAYSIA

Japanese companies have not participated in conservation, or

improving forestry management in Sabah.203 In the last few years,

Sabah officials have tried to prompt major log buyers from Japan --

companies like Sumitomo, Itochu, and Marubeni -- to provide

assistance for forestry management and conservation. But so far

there has been no response.204 The Sabah Foundation -- which is

now developing techniques and training personnel for enrichment

planting in logged areas -- has received some support from two

utility companies, the New England Power Service and the Dutch

Electricity Generating Board, but nothing from Japan.205 According

to a Sabah forestry official, Japanese companies seem far more

concerned with developing new techniques to make temperate plywood

than with ensuring a sustainable yield of tropical timber.206

Japanese trading companies have also not invested in timber

203lnterview, World Wildlife Fund Malaysia, Kota Kinabalu, 15February 1994.

204lnterviews, Senior manager, Innoprise Corporation, 9 February1994; and Sabah Forestry Department (Jabatan Perhutanan Sabah),Kota Kinabalu Branch, 16 February 1994.

205lnterviews, Institute for Development Studies, Kota Kinabalu,12 February 1994; and Senior executive, Yayasan Sabah [SabahFoundation], Kota Kinabalu, 14 February 1994. Utility companiesfund tropical forest plantations and rehabilitation to ‘off-set’carbon dioxide emissions (utility companies discharge carbondioxide while forests absorb it). This will presumably improvecorporate image and perhaps reduce future ‘carbon-taxes.’ Fordetails on the merican and Dutch projects, see Michael Vatikiotis,“For Profit’s Sake,” FEER, 14 April 1994, p.68; “A Better Way toCut Trees,” Asiaweek, 28 April 1993, p.50; and M. Hamzah, “Down thebeautiful green Danum, Sabah Times, 2 February 1994, p.4.

206lnterview, Sabah Forestry Department (Jabatan PerhutananSabah), Kota Kinabalu Branch, 16 February 1994.

249

Page 260: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

plantations in Sabah. In 1993, Sumitomo -- acting as a broker for

two paper companies in Japan -- began negotiations for a large,

joint venture plantation project. These companies, however,

eventually lost interest.207 Japanese corporate executives are

wary of the long-term commitments, financial risks, unclear land

tenure, sudden political or policy changes, and world fluctuations

in pulp and paper prices.20S

Poor harvesting techniques and inefficient processors waste

valuable wood and increase the pressure on commercial timber

stocks. Although Japanese corporations have provided some

equipment and technical advice for Sabah loggers and processors,

there has been no systematic effort to enhance processing

efficiency, recover timber waste, or improve cutting methods.209

Instead, Japanese trading companies have sent technicians to Sabah

to guarantee that logs and sawn timber meet Japan’s rigid cutting

and manufacturing stipulations. These technicians ensure that the

best timber reaches the Japanese market; they are not concerned

207lnterview, Senior manager, SAFODA, Kota Kinabalu, 12 February1994.

208To offset some of these concerns, in mid-1994 the Sabahgovernment started drafting comprehensive investment guidelines.Interview, Institute for Development Studies, Kota Kinabalu, 12February 1994.

209lnterview, Institute for Development Studies, Kota Kinabalu,12 February 1994. Some Sabah students have gone to Japan to trainon high-tech forestry equipment. Quite naturally, these studentsbecome more comfortable with Japanese machines, and are more likelyto purchase Japanese equipment in the future. Interview, TimberAssociation of Sabah, ICota Icinabalu, 8 February 1994.

250

Page 261: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

with the process, only the end result.21° In Sarawak, -- where

processors waste as much as 50 percent of logs -- Japanese

companies have also done little to improve efficiency. One

exception is a Japan-Sarawak joint venture to produce Sarawak’s

first Medium Density Fibreboard (MDF) plant. Construction began in

1994 and production is expected to begin in 1996. There are five

partners: Dai]cen Corporation of Japan holds 50 percent equity,

Itochu (20 percent), the Sarawak Timber Industry Development

Corporation (15 percent), the Sarawak company Proexcel (10

percent), and Datuk Wong’s Limbang Trading Company (5 percent).

The joint venture company -- Daiken Sarawak Sdn Bhd -- received a

US$50 million loan from the EXIM Bank of Japan. To make F, this

plant will use wood scraps from plywood and saw mills. The company

hopes by the end of this century to export 80,000 to 100,000 cubic

metres of NDF.21’

Sarawak has been attacked by environmentalists around the

world for its forestry management and treatment of aboriginal

peoples. Japanese companies have also been strongly criticized.

Some of the harshest criticism has been levelled at Mitsubishi,

even though, in terms of log purchases, other Japanese companies

have a greater impact. To counteract these critics, Japanese

companies have increased funding for public relations and made

210lnterview, Senior Sabah timber executive, ICota Kinabalu, 9February 1994.

211Aden Nagrace Timor, “S’wak’s first MDF plant to startconstruction April,” The Borneo Post, 20 February 1994, p.6;Interview, Sarawak Timber Industry Development Corporation,Kuching, 17 February 1994; and Asian Timber, June 1994, p.7.

251

Page 262: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

token contributions to forestry management in Sarawak, but there

have been few serious efforts to improve timber management.212 For

example, Mitsubishi partially funds the Bintulu project, a research

experiment to recreate a natural rain forest.213 According to a

professor at the University of Tokyo, of all the recent corporate

‘conservation’ projects, the Bintulu project is designed the most

for “show. ,,214

JAPANESE TIMBER PURCHASES FROM BORNEO MALAYSIA

Japan’s primary impact on Borneo Malaysia’s timber industry

has been as a buyer of logs. Most of these logs have been used to

make cheap plywood. Since the quality of wood in Sabah is higher

that in Sarawak, after commercial timber stocks collapsed in the

Philippines, Japanese companies turned first to Sabah.215 In 1970,

out of a total of 20.2 million cubic metres of Southeast Asian log

imports, Japan imported 4.0 million cubic metres from Sabah and 1.9

212lnterviews, Senior official, Forest Department, Kuching, 17February 1994; and Senior executive, Sarawak Timber Association,Kuching, 20 February 1994.

2135ee Yusuf Hadi and Abas Said, “Planting Indigenous TreeSpecies To Rehabilitate Degraded Forest Lands: The BintuluProject,” in Ahmad Said Sajap et. al., eds., Indigenous Species forForest Plantations, Proceedings of a national seminar, Faculty ofForestry, Universiti Pertanian Malaysia, Serdang, Malaysia, 23-24April 1992, pp.36-44.

214Confidential Interview, University of Tokyo, Tokyo, 17 May1994.

215The major Japanese companies in Sabah are Mitsui, Itochu,Iwai, Sumitomo, and to a lesser extent Mitsubishi. Interview,Sabah Sawmillers Industries Association, Kota Kinabalu, 16 February1994.

252

Page 263: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

million cubic metres from Sarawak. In 1978, Japan imported around

21.8 million cubic metres of Southeast Asian logs; 9.2 million

cubic metres came from Sabah, and only 1.5 million cubic metres

came from Sarawak. As Sabah logs became less abundant in the

l980s, and after Indonesia’s log export ban, Japanese log purchases

from Sarawak increased substantially. By 1987, Japan’s total log

imports had dropped to 13.7 million cubic metres. Sabah accounted

for 7.0 million cubic metres, and Sarawak for 5.5 million cubic

metres, together representing over 90 percent of all Japanese

tropical log imports.216

From 1979 to 1988, Sabah exported an annual average of around

9 million cubic metres of logs, worth more than US$5.5 billion.

Jbout 80 percent was exported to Japan.217 After 1987 Japanese log

imports from Sabah steadily declined. In 1988, Japan imported 5.4

million cubic metres of Sabah logs. By 1991, Japanese log imports

from Sabah had dropped to around 2.6 million cubic metres, although

this still accounted for over 70 percent of Sabah’s total log

exports.218 In 1992, Japan imported 2.1 million cubic metres of

logs from Sabah. In 1993, as a result of the log export ban,

216All figures are rounded to the first decimal point. Kurodaand Nectoux, Timber, Figure B7, p.118. Based on data from theJapanese Plywood Manufacturers’ Association and the Japan TariffAssociation. Also see Sarawak Timber Industry DevelopmentCorporation (Perbadanan Kemajuan Perusahaan Kayu Sarawak), (STIDC),Statistics of Timber and Timber Products. Sarawak 1993 (Kuching:STIDC, 1993), p.3.

217Raphael Pura and Steven Jones, “Sabah Log-Shipping CartelDefeats Rivals,” AWSJ, 14 March 1989.

218”Tokyo protests to KL over Sabah’s ban on log exports,”Straits Times, 8 May 1993, p.22.

253

Page 264: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

Japanese log imports from Sabah plummeted to less than 300,000

cubic metres.219 From 1987 to 1993, there were only marginal

increases to Japanese plywood, sawn timber, and veneer imports from

Sabah. In 1988, Japan imported 213,700 cubic metres of sawn

timber, 200 cubic metres of plywood, and 80,200 cubic metres of

veneer. In 1992, Japan imported 444,496 cubic metres of sawn

timber, 14,965 cubic metres of plywood, and 201,616 cubic metres of

veneer. After the log export ban, sawn timber and veneer imports

did not change significantly, although plywood imports increased to

over 120,000 cubic metres.22° As a result of these changes, total

Japanese timber imports from Sabah (in roundwood equivalent), fell

from nearly 7.5 million cubic metres in 1987, to 2.9 million cubic

metres in 1992, to well below 1 million cubic metres in 1993.221

As Sabah’s log exports decreased from 9.4 million cubic metres

in 1987 to 3.4 million cubic metres in 1991, Sarawak increased log

219These figures are from the Japan Plywood Manufacturers’Association, Plywood Industry in Japan (Tokyo: Japan PlywoodManufacturers’ Association, 1993), pp.24-25; the Japan PlywoodManufacturers’ Association, Plywood Industry in Japan (April 1994),p.8; and data from the Japan Lumber Importers’ Association,received by the author, 4 April 1994.

220From January to July 1993, China was the main market of Sabahplywood, accounting for 35 percent of total exports (Japan imported20 percent). Korea was the major market for sawn timber,accounting for 34 percent of total exports (Japan imported 16percent). Japan is the largest market for Sabah veneer, accountingfor 42 percent of total veneer exports. This data was supplied bythe Sabah Sawmilling Industries Association, February 1994.

221This data was supplied by the Malaysian Timber IndustryBoard, Kuala Lumpur, March 9, 1994, and is based on data from theStatistics Department of Sabah. Except where noted, the figuresfor 1993 are based on data from January to October and extrapolatedfor the entire year.

254

Page 265: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

exports, from 12.6 million cubic metres in 1987 to 15.9 million

cubic metres in 1990 and 15.8 million cubic metres in 1991.222 As

logs became less accessible in Sabah, Japanese corporate purchases

were a key force behind faster extraction in Sarawak. In 1988,

Japan imported 5.3 million cubic metres of logs from Sarawak.

Japanese log imports from Sarawak climbed to 6.7 million cubic

metres in 1990 and then dropped slightly in 1991 and 1992 to around

6.5 million cubic metres. In 1993, after Sarawak increased its

restrictions on log exports, Japanese log imports decreased to 4.9

million cubic metres.223 Over the same period, Japan imported more

sawn timber and plywood, although veneer imports declined. In

1987, Japan imported 10,723 cubic metres of sawn timber, 2 cubic

metres of plywood and 47,848 cubic metres of veneer. In 1992,

Japan imported 54,668 cubic metres of sawn timber, 45,300 cubic

metres of plywood and 18,449 cubic metres of veneer.224 As a

result of these changes, total Japanese timber imports from Sarawak

(in roundwood equivalent) increased from almost 6 million cubic

222Sarawak Timber Industry Development Corporation, Statisticsof Timber and Timber Products. Sarawak 1993, p.3. Also see“Loggers’ Lament,” Asiaweek, 28 April 1993, p.49.

223These figures are from the Japan Plywood Manufacturers’Association, Plywood Industry in Japan (1993), pp.24-25; the JapanPlywood Manufacturers’ Association, Plywood Industry in Japan(April 1994), p.8; and data from the Japan Lumber Importers’Association, received by the author, 4 April 1994.

2241n 1992, Sarawak exported 10.5 million cubic metres oftimber. Japan purchased 45 percent of this total; Taiwan, thesecond largest consumer of Sarawak timber bought 20 percent. In1992, log exports provided the key source of forest revenue,earning M$3.1 billion, compared to M$385 million for sawn timber,and M$255 million for veneer and plywood. Sarawak ForestDepartment, Forestry in Sarawak, p.34.

255

Page 266: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

metres in 1987 to around 6.5 million cubic metres in 1992. In

1993, however, export restrictions reduced total Japanese timber

imports to around 5.5 million cubic metres.225

JAPAN, TARIFF BARRIERS, LOG PRICES, AND SUSTAINABLE MANAGEMENT

As Borneo Malaysian processed timber imports to Japan

increase, Japanese import tariffs on processed wood reduce timber

revenues and, in theory, as in Indonesia, syphon money that could

support sustainable management.226 Also as in Indonesia, the

prices Japanese companies pay for Borneo Malaysian logs and

processed timber are far below the cost of sustainable management.

One angry Malaysian columnist writes: “Japan is gobbling our trees

because they are dirt cheap. A jungle tree which took hundreds of

years to grow is cheaper in Japan than a softwood pine that took

only 20 years to grow. That’s why Japan is using Malaysian timber

for junk furniture and throw-away construction frames.”227 Without

prices that reflect environmental costs, there is little chance of

225These statistics were supplied by the Malaysian TimberIndustry Board, Kuala Lumpur, March 9, 1994, and are based on datafrom the Statistics Department of Sarawak. The figures for 1993are based on data from January to October and extrapolated for theentire year. Also see Sarawak Timber Industry DevelopmentCorporation, Statistics of Timber and Timber Products. Sarawak1993, p.3.

226At an International Tropical Timber Council Meeting in May1993, Chief Minister Taib called for unimpeded market access toallow Sarawak to reduce timber production yet still maintainsufficient funds for sustainable management. “Taib calls forunimpeded markets,” Sarawak Tribune, 13 May 1993.

227Halinah Todd, “Japan Rubbishes Malaysian Timber,” UtusanKonsumer, (May 1989), in World Rainforest Movement and Sahabat AlamMalaysia, The Battle, p.502.

256

Page 267: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

sustainable management. Barney Chan, spokesman for the Sarawak

Timber Association, argues: “If you give tropical timber a higher

value, it allows us to harvest it in a fashion more friendly to the

environment. We have all along been saying to the West: put your

money where your mouth is. If you want to save the rainforest,

give us a better price for timber.”228 In theory, Chan is correct.

Japan’s extensive log purchases have played a key role in driving

unsustainable timber management. But increasing prices is not an

automatic solution. In a setting where particularistic, rent-

seeking patron-client networks undermine state capacity to enforce

rules and distort state policies, higher prices may simply add

incentives to extract logs recklessly and make quick money.229

CONCLUS ION

Patron-client politics and timber in Borneo Malaysia are

intricately connected -- patron-client relations shape timber

resource distribution and management while timber binds many of

these links together. Like traditional patron-client relations,

modern ties are vertical, instrumental, informal, reciprocal, and

asymmetrical. Modern patron-client networks, however, have large,

fluid peripheries, and are based less on loyalty and honour and

more on self-interested material exchange, contributing to highly

unstable ties which frequently rupture as political parties contest

228Quoted in “Loggers turn to copters as prices rise,” TheBorneo Post, 19 November 1993.

229The final chapter discusses this point further.

257

Page 268: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

elections and jockey for control. This creates an unpredictable

atmosphere that encourages fast, destructive logging. Political

leaders have used timber concessions and profits to build and hold

together multi-ethnic patron-client networks, and appease and coopt

potential adversaries. As a result, patron-client ties strongly

influence the allocation of concessions, licences and contracts,

determining who primarily benefits from logging profits, and

contributing to a complex distribution system that decreases

transparency and accountability necessary for environmental

management. Patron-client ties to timber operators at the top of

the state also dilute political will and weaken state supervision

of forestry and enforcement officers. In this context, timber-

based patron-client networks are able to capture or coopt bureaus

of the state. This contributes to many state implementors ignoring

customs and management regulations in exchange for gifts, money,

and career opportunities. In short, informal, particularistic

relations are a critical force shaping formal timber institutions,

policies and regulations in the clientelist states of Borneo

Malaysia.

Sabah, which began large-scale logging before Sarawak, now has

grave forestry problems. Poor management, weak enforcement,

political links to logging concessions, unstable patron-client

ties, and constant disputes with the federal government have

contributed to over-logging and forest degradation. The dominance

of the state-controlled Sabah Foundation -- rather than enabling

the state to tackle unsustainable logging -- has contributed to

258

Page 269: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

mismanagement as timber profits have been channelled to powerful

political patrons such as Chief Ministers Mustapha, Harris Salleh,

and Pairin. The 1993 ban on log exports, and the moves to tackle

poor harvesting practices and illegal logging have done little to

improve timber management. Annual log production has dropped; but

this is more a result of declining stocks of commercial timber than

better forestry management.

Sarawak has similar problems, but with a later start and more

forest resources, there are still considerable areas of valuable

commercial timber. Based on timber concessions and profits, top

politicians such as Chief Minister Taib and Environment and Tourism

Minister James Wong have built personal fortunes and powerful

patron-client networks. These networks have distorted state

policies and undermined state capacity to enforce timber

regulations. Private-sector timber companies -- such as the

Rimbunan Hijau Group (Datuk Tiong) and the Ekran Company (Datuk

Ting) -- are protected by political patrons and assisted by

forestry and enforcement officers. As a result, these corporations

continue to extract unsustainable timber yields, ignore logging

rules, conduct illegal logging and smuggling, elude state royalties

and federal income taxes, and disregard conservation and

silvicultural treatments. In the short-term, since Sabah’s log

export ban, Sarawak has benefitted from higher log prices. But

these prices still fall far short of the costs of sustainable

management. In addition, as in Indonesia and Sabah, government

moves to build a domestic processing industry are unlikely to

259

Page 270: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

promote sustainable logging. With similar political forces driving

mismanagement, and Japanese corporate purchases expediting over

cutting, Sarawak appears headed down the same trail as Sabah, with

Indonesia not far behind.

Unlike in Indonesia, Japanese ODA and investment have had

minor implications for Borneo Malaysian timber management.

Japanese tariff barriers have also had little impact on state and

corporate revenues, although since 1993 this has become relatively

more important. Nevertheless, Japan’s shadow ecology has expedited

the process of Borneo Malaysian deforestation. Japanese log

purchases have provided incentives for destructive logging and

crucial funds for patron-client networks. In many cases, Japanese

equipment and advice also facilitated unsustainable logging. As

Japanese imports of logs from Sabah increased in the 1970s and

early 1980s, Sabah’s primary forest cover fell sharply, from 55

percent of the total land area in 1973 to 25 percent in 1983.

Today, only 413,000 hectares of Sabah’s Commercial Forests are

undisturbed. While Japan now has less impact on timber management

in Sabah, massive log purchases in the 1970s and 1980s -- at prices

far below the costs of sustainable management -- have left Sabah

scrambling to find the funds and timber resources to save what

remains of their commercial timber industry.

After exhausting much of Sabah’s valuable commercial timber,

Japanese corporations turned to Sarawak. Log imports from Sarawak

grew from about 1.5 million cubic metres in 1978 to 2.3 million

cubic metres in 1980 to 5.6 million cubic metres in 1988. By 1990,

260

Page 271: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

Japanese log imports from Sarawak surpassed 7 million cubic metres.

Today, even with restrictions on log exports, Japan imports around

5 million cubic metres of logs from Sarawak. Rather than encourage

sustainable timber management, Japanese trading companies have been

remarkably consistent: simply move to a new area as commercial log

stocks fade or after governments impose log export restrictions.

Predictably, these companies are now purchasing more tropical logs

from Papua New Guinea and the Solomon Islands. As well, in

preparation for the collapse of tropical log stocks, Japanese

companies are developing new techniques to make temperate plywood

and are importing more softwood from around the world.

Having analyzed the implications of patron-client relations

for timber management, it is interesting to speculate on the

possible impact of declining timber resources on patron-client

relations since in Sabah and Sarawak these two issues are virtually

inseparable -- a change in one will certainly result in a change in

the other. Since patron-client clusters are largely bound together

by timber profits, at the very least, depletion of timber resources

will force patron-client clusters to reshape and realign, and

perhaps more ominously, could destabilize the political system.

Patron-client links now provide an essential source of stability

and means of cooperation between the diverse ethnic and religious

groups. If timber revenues evaporate, many patron-client links

will dissolve, quite possibly realigning along religious or ethnic

lines, especially since an economic crisis will likely accompany

the collapse of the timber industry. Another result of the loss of

261

Page 272: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

timber revenue could be increased calls from Sabah and Sarawak for

greater autonomy from the federal government in Kuala Lumpur,

especially control over oil revenues. ICuala Lumpur is, however,

unlikely to concede control over this key resource and serious

disputes could arise.230

230For a discussion of the tense relations between Kuala Lumpurand Sabah, see Audrey R. Kahin, “Crisis on the Periphery: The RiftBetween Kuala Lumpur and Sabah,” Pacific Affairs 65 (Spring 1992),pp. 30-49.

262

Page 273: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

CID

-JP

)i

IJO

çt

U)o

rtH

--I:-

’w H

-C

)j

C)

Wrr

o HCD

CDC

)U

)H (VIl

CDCD

H-I

lH

- C)

Hpj

HiC

DH

çt

H lCD

‘IIlL

CDH

-C

D

pil

l<

0 Hi

ig<

CrC

tr-

,j0

-‘Il

CD.

CD‘-

JU) C

rCD

<Il-<

H-

0°t5

-

oH

-P1

Ilc H

CD

EI’

:i

Mip

i(V

Cr

H-

CDH

(VC

rC

<

Cr

dP

Mi

(f)C

)H

-C

tCt

I1H jH

CD

H-

HH

ii

)CD

HIl

CDp,

U)H

0U)

Il...‘

ld

H-

H-C

rHo

ç-t3

U)H

-’<

P.)CD

-:i-

:jU

)

‘I‘H

M-I

CD

CDO

H-U

)H

iHi

tJ’F

-’O

C)

0P

H-

IlIl

CD

’tH

-CD

CD

-

°U

)U)

U)H

-CD

Cr

Cr

CD

PPi

PJC

D0C

rct

U)

H-H

‘•‘;I

H-C

D

rr

-H

Il

PC)

CD

YCD

‘.o(

DU)

H?U

)-3

::--‘U

Ho

O0

CD0

U)‘I

CD0C

D-

“‘dP

JC

FC

DIl

i-j

HjJ

H1

tJH

CDC

r11

H

0H

H-

0C

tq

Cr

I-’H

ZCD

CD‘-<

HH

(Dd,m

U)

P-h

U)

CD‘dH

-U

)H

CD

q‘i-

HU

)p

i0•

CDCD

Hi

0’;7

-

P1:i3.C

DO

(Vfr

-i0C

D

CD

CD

Hi

H-

CDrt

0çt-

Cr4

Pl

C-]

H• C)

‘•z:

I:j

CI)

HH

-H

-o

HH

-C)

UIC

DiQ

H-.

.‘1

1CD

PU

)C

tH

c-F

0H

-CD

P.)k

<C

t0C

tIl

-U

)CD

’“<

-

I.<

P.)CD

IICD

<1C)

H-

IIP.)

CDCF

H-

‘III

pjp.)

-P.)

II1

((-Q

CDk<

c-FCD

CFH

ii-

Mo

CDCD

Mi

‘ICD

U’

CDC

Fd

‘ICF

H-

CDU)

-‘I

CDC)

U)U)

CD

P.)C

rC

I

pH

-i

H-

U)1

CD0

It

Hi

CFCD

p‘1

Cl)P.)

‘ICX

)C

ro

oCD

H-

C)H

P.)-

HII

,-H

i-‘

ItIt

Q,

0H

<k<

CD2

CDCl

‘IH

CDM

iU)

Cr

0C

t0

H-

IIU)

CDCD

CDIt

CDC

FCD

U)C

FH

C)1

Hi

‘ICD

0CD

C)

Cr

H-

o0

C)).Q

P.)t

HO

HH

-H

iH U) P.)

P.)C

rCD

It:

Hi

oCD

0CD

)-.)

CF‘I

IIH

-CD

CDco 0

P.)CD

0H

-CD

0H

--

CDp.)

0‘-

‘‘I

Cr

0LQ

U)Q

p-’U)

Cr

CDCD

C)P.)

CD‘I

(<

C)<1

HH

-II

P.)CD

CDCD

ItP.)

U)U)

C)F

dC

rU)

C)C

rCD

CDP.)

H-

HH

CCl

.Cr

CD<

H-

HP.)

CDi

CD‘I CD

C)P.) U)

Hi

Cr

Cr

-)

CFH

-0

P.)CF

‘1H

-o

CDH

i‘

U)U)

‘I•

HC

l.—

I-CD

P.)CD

CF

P.)U)

CD-,

U)H

IIC)

Ip.)

bC

F

HU)

bIt

CDH

CDi

U)H

<.

ClH

--

It H-

r.P.)

H-

HCD

Hi

HU)

Cr

‘P.)

CD‘I

r‘I

Mi

-H

-0

P.)CD

ClH

IICD

oCD

U)U)

H-

-P.)

p.)C

lC)

CF

CF

HC

F

Hr

QQ

H-

H)Q

IIi

-

P.)It

CDII

CDC

r

C)U)

U)C

lM

U)U)

H0

pI

C)CD

0<

CDCl)

ItP.)

(.Qft

\C

rC

r11

H(•

IIH

-CD

I-CP.)

0b•

P.)LQ

Cr

Cr

HU)

CD‘I

-0

00

9.)o

p.)H

cr

1C

lU)

‘-<0

CDU)

CD CD P.)

H-

CD

HH

i0

Cl

‘0

CDCD U) H

-(V

p.)

H-

p.)

Cl

Cl

Cl

WCD

0H

i‘I

0i

‘ICD

CD0

U) CF P.)P.)

CFH

H-

.)o

k<

-U) H

-H Ii C

r8

CD

CD Cl C)H

-H

-H

P.)H

-H

It It

HH C

CD ‘1 U)

op.)

0 ClCD

L’i

1:1

H P It It w

M 0 w

ti:

Cr ‘I P.) H

P.)

H-

H

U)

Hi

MC

DG

-.I

pJ II

U)

II H-

PC

)C

.09j

0 ItC

r

It C

rCD C) C

F Cl H-

C) Cr)

H-

C) Hi

0 II CD U) Cr z CD

Page 274: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

Qctflrr

I1C

)C

)0

H-C

DC

Dcu

çt

QH

(D

HC

Dfr

rt-

(D

‘<

.rt

H-

Hi

i-S.

‘ii

CD

f-t

(DH

QC

DH

,LT

j1j:i

,m

rt°

--

CI)

H-

(.Qpi

HU)

HIIF

]L

J.

H-p

i.

‘ocui

‘t-rC

DW

Cr

CD

H-

CD—

‘HH

-C

J)<

j..

-0

U)C

DC

DC

rCD

cu-’

Cr

•CD

“U

•C

D

U1

C)

Cçt

•H C

D‘1

CD0

QID

Hi

0p)

p-IH

iCr

C)l

i

jC

t(D

H —1;

DC

DC

rF

1U

)P-I U

)LJ

Cr0

3iCD

0

<C

rrt

CDU)

rr

t-tH

Chip

)H

-h0

p-IH

H-

hC

thO

PJI

hH

CD

p-IH

U)p-I

CDCD

Ct

<C

DI-h

Mi

CD0

IIH

Hp-I

I(_c

oçt

Q-

HH

-H

iH

-C)

CDC

rPJ

hi

I-hC

td

CDC

rP-I

HC)

U)C)

CDC

tCD

p-IH

Cr-

Cr

P-ICD

oH

-H

-‘

0pj

U)U

)IC

t

H0

I-h

CI)

CDC)

HCD

Hp

c-t

CD1

çt

0C

t‘d

Ct

0C

tC

tII

C)0

HU)

H CD

CDp

Crçt

iC)

2)H hi

CrH

CDU)

(hi

0-

CDC

tCD

II‘

CDCD

CDH

H H-

C)CD

HCD <

Ct

0<

HI-h

II“<

CDC

DC

DH

Cr

rtU)

H-

U)CD

C)P

-H

‘<&

‘CLi

HCD

CD‘C

I-hI-h

CD

Ci)H

H-

tH

-H

-hi

Ct

<12)

U)CD

ç2)

U)CD

p-IC

rCD

P..

hiC

tP-I

HCD

ci.

-p

U)Cl

-H

H-

.b

iCD C)

HC

rH

Hhi

Cr

CD U)H

0P-I

C)I-h

H-

p-It

CDIi

CDçt

Ct

P-IH

-P-I

Hp

)hi

HP

0H

-M

ihi

Pi hiC

)C

r

CDP-I

hi•

çt

Ct

IICD

i0

U)C) H H

I-hC)

CD0

hiH

U)C

r

Ct

Cr

.

rnH

0CD

I-h- h

Cr

CD0

CD U)Ii

dH

CDCD

H

hiH H

U)k<

I-h‘t

S2)

CDti

Hi

iCD

Cr

Cr

hiCD

ICD

I-h

Cr

Ct

CDCD

hiC)

I-]

CD h4I-h

H-

rtI-h

U)CD

P..

hiC)

CDC

rhi

C) p-It-

ppi

Ct

CDC

tCD

•CD

I-h-

- p-ICD

H hiH

-0

hiU)

U) çt

p HCD

H

P-I0

U)H

iC) CD

çt

hi Cr

CD U)C

tCD

0H

iC

t0 I-h

CDCD U)

C)C

r0

U)hi C) H

Hhi

HU)

HH 0

ci.

hiH

-•

U) P-I

U)

H-

CDhi

P-IC)

I-hCD

0 CDCD

I-h

P.O

‘dCD

dH

hihi

hi0

Hhi

IlCD

ci.

p-Ihi

CDH

çt

I-hH

-CD

NP

.CD

HP

.H

-hi

Mip

CDçt

Cr

çt

CDCD

H

U)

C)H

HC

t0

0P-I

H-

hi1

Jb

Hi

Mi

hihi

C)CD

H-

HCl)

çt

HF

dF

ihi

2)H

-H

-C)

CDC

rH

-P

.Ci)

t3LQ

CD2)

Ct

0C

t

Hrt

0hi

H-

U)‘.o

CDCD

U,

U)U)

CDC

r,,

p,

H-

P.0

U)CD

cu-I

CDH

-0

P.

HP-’

IC

rC

rhi

CD‘D

Cr

P.

o-CD

Cr

CDH

CP.

-Ii

U)CD

C)—

U)H

-H

Cr

çt

pH

-Ci)

rt-

CD0

Ct

hiCD

CDp

U)C

rL

Cr<

CD

C)U)

CD

CDCD

P-IH

-P

.U)

U)1t5

H-

U)H

P..

51H

-P-I

P-IH

CQH

CDC

r,r

Ct

Hi

.k<

Pc-

t0

H-

CTC

rI-h

I-h

Ct

q0

0CD

hihi

CDCD

C)CD

Ct

Cr

Hi

CDhi

hiQ

Ct

hiU)

I-h-r

hiCD

CD0

•hiCD

P.

u-Cr

1

P.

Cr2

H-

CDp.

,-h

0C)

<ha

Hi

-CD

CDH

hCD

hC

rP-I

I-h

HH

Mi

0CD

‘-.0

CDH

-H

<H

ihi

C)C

rH

-CD

2)0

2)01

Cr

U)C)

H-

I-H

IQ

H-

U)CD

<h

P-ICD

HU)

U)P-I

iU)

0H

Cr

H—

HP

.•

Hi

U)U)

Page 275: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

c-F9) C.)

CDC) CD

HH

9)CD

c-FII

CD

CD9) ‘1

c-C) C

D

-<‘1

CD0

9) I-’l

CDU)

U)•

U) c-F

0c-F H CD

c-c-F

J0

CD I-c-

CD- CD

9) i-CD :- CD qCD

9)c-F 9)

(I) CDpj U)

C)c-F

oCD

IIH

d9)

o CDH

i

C)0

9)(.Q

‘tJ0

Hi

H-

I-i

H9)

9)CD

CDH

i1x

jc-F

HH

-II

U)H

-‘d

CD0

IIH

-U)

9)h

CDH

CDU)

CDc-F

-

I9)

C)I

CD0

PC)

HII

CD0

H-

CDCD

.QH

CDb

9)H

i9)

1c-

9)CD

c-t

U)c-

FC)

CDCL

)c-F

HCD

H-

C)c-F

U)0

9)c-F

CDU)

k<

U)U)

CDCD

Cl)

Cl)

9)c-F

c-9)

CD

‘1c-F

c).,

H-

9)CD

H-

0I-

‘1H

CDc-F

9)H

iH

-C)

Cl)0

CDI-I

CD[1

-?CD

CD9)

0Cl) c-

frJ

Mi

9)CD

c-F

CDH

-<

9)0

CD0

9)-

c-F

9)H

-H

iH

-3

H0

:iH

i-CD

C)U)

1(.C

CDU)

bCD

9)c-F

-<LQ

HC)

CD0

CDq

H3

j9)

CD0

C)c-F

hLQ

CDU)

9)9)

LU)

c-FH

-U)

CDH

-H

IU)

0LC

0I

CD

c-FQ

c-FC)

0H

i0

CDH

CDF’l

H-

c-Fc-F

CDC)

:-H

iI

H-

CD0

H--

Cl)

‘-U)

CDc-F

U)c-F

CD9)

9)c-F

CDc-F

U)

c-FCD

0CD

c-FCD

rJI-

CDH

9)C)

CD:i

H-

H 9)<

H-

CDH

9)CD

H9)

U)H

-CD

I-’

c-F 9)H

-CD

c-FH

-c-F

9)CD

H‘1

9)[

CDCD

c-FH

-0

3LQ

II<1

Hi

H-

0C)

CD0

0II

t-i

ICD

CDC)

9)C)

9)CD

HH

U)c-F

H-

CDCl)

Cl)9,

CDi-

jH

-H

-c-F

CDc-F

i•

c-FU)

-H

-c-F

Cl)CD

9)c-F

Cl)c-F

9)

_

CDc-F

H-

CD

MH

c-’CD U)

:iCD

C)‘—

jH

-H

-9)

HU)

c-c-F

c-FH

-1<

CD-

0 ‘-‘I

Qc-F

CD9)

c-FH

0H

CDc-F

c-Fc-F H

-H

9)0

CD3

c-F9)

LCD

CD(.

CDII

HCD

CDC)

)H

hP

c-FH

c-F‘-D

H-

-D0

H-

3H

-0

Ui

P-’

0i

U)Q

CDc-F

C)0

0c-

F1

IICD

U)H

U)I

HCD

Cl)U)

CDCD

9)9)

19)

I

c-t

IH

C)CD

CDk<

CD0

<H

Cl)

9)CD

H0

c-t

QH

Hi

HU

)H

HCD

H0

H-

c-F

Hi

c-FCD

0

Hi

IH

-CD

C)C)

Cl)H

HH

-U)

9)CD

H-

9)9)

c-F

CDU)

CDCD

Ii<

CD:i

<

CDh

c-CD

CDCD

-I

-9)

CD9)

c-F

CD9’

c-U)

Hc-F

q)H

cO

I-CD

iH

-c-

F3

CDCD

IIO

I0

I

C)9)

C)H

iH

h0

c-F

H-

CDc-

tH

-CD

CD

°d

c-

HH

io

CDCD c-F

Qc-

F3

c-F9

H-

CDCD

0CD

:i‘1

‘1II

Cl)9)

rc-

FU)

Q0

-U)

CDH

iH

Hi

U)9)

Hi

•H

-

HCD

•H

-H

Cl)H

c-FH

H0

c-F

HH

H-

Ui

1<

c-f

9)Cl

)H

-CD

U)c-

Fc-

F9)

9)c-F

H-

9)-<

c-F

9)c-F

CDCD

U)U)

CDII

CDU)

-CD

c-F

CDCD

U)H

-c-

FH

c-F

IIH

-0

Cil Hi

C)d

c-F

c-F

HCD

H-

Hi

<CD

c-CD

-•

c-F

C)CD

Hp

CD0

H-

U)L

CDc-F

Hi

L9)

9)H

-c-F

c-F

HCD

CDH

tCl

H HII

U)H

ic-

F

U)U)

09)

c-F

H9)

C)c-

FCD

CDU) H

09)

c-F

HCD C) c-

FII

øCD

CD-

9) H;7c

-9)

H-

CD

CDd

Hi

9)9)

-c-

FC)

IlH

I-,

QH

--

Ic-

FcC

)9)

‘H

c-F

CDH

-CD

‘-CCD

- 9)c-F

I-C 9)

c-FCD

0U)

9)9)

9)k<

c-F

Ui

H c-F CD ‘-C CD U) c-F U) 9) c-F CD c-F 9) CD Hi

0 C) H LQ 9) CD CD c-F ‘-‘C H C) H It H CD U) c-F CD

Page 276: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

investments or timber purchases. Nevertheless, the residue of

Japan’s ecological shadow of timber compounds the problems facing

Filipino managers. Filipinos are now absorbing the costs of

substantial profits reaped by Japanese companies in the past.

State managers must cope with and pay for the consequences of

extensive deforestation, including soil erosion, river siltation,

flash floods, climatic instability, and inadequate timber stocks.5

Burdened by past environmental abuse by Filipino elites and their

Northern allies, it is hardly surprising that current managers are

struggling to find the funds and means to preserve the scattered

primary forests, and reforest the swaths of degraded areas. One

obvious place to look is Japan. But current Japanese ODA does not

compensate for past practices. At present, there are no JICA

technical cooperation projects or grants. Instead, the Japanese

government has emphasized ‘environmental loans’. But these have

major flaws. In the case of the Forestry Sector Program Loan

(US$120 million from 1988-1992), rather than reviving the

environment, this loan will eventually add even more pressure to

extract and export natural resources to acquire foreign exchange

5The Philippines has one of the world’s highest rates of soilerosion. Debora MacKenzie, “Uphill battle to save Filipino trees,”New Scientist, 30 June 1988, p.42. One study estimated that soilerosion -- which reduces agricultural productivity and potentialhydro-electric power, and disrupts irrigation and fisheries --

costs the Philippines over half a billion U.S. dollars every year.Summarized in Frances F. Korten, “Environmental Loans: More HarmThan Good?” Paper Presented at the Fifth Annual Conference of theNorthwest Consortium for Southeast Asian Studies, Vancouver,British Columbia, October 1992, p.5. For more details on theenvironmental, economic, and social costs of deforestation in thePhilippines, see Hurst, Rainforest, pp.165-171.

266

Page 277: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

and repay the national debt.

This chapter is divided into four parts. I begin by

explaining key changes to Filipino patron-client relations. I

concentrate on shifts prior to 1972, changes after Marcos declared

martial law in 1972, and realignments after Corazon Aquino became

president in 1986. In the second section, I document links between

state patrons and timber operations, emphasizing the continuity of

patron-client ties across the regimes of Marcos, Aquino, and Fidel

Ramos. In the third part, I examine the impact of pervasive

patron-clientelism on Philippine timber management, including the

effect on the Department of Environment and Natural Resources

(DENR), legal concessionaires, illegal loggers and smugglers, log

export bans and restrictions, processing policies, local forest

management, and conservation and reforestation. In the final

section, I outline the historical impact of Japanese investment,

trade, and development assistance on Philippine timber management.

I then discuss the residual effect of Japan’s shadow ecology of

timber, and the current influence of environmental loans.

‘TRADITIONAL’ AND ‘MODERN’ PATRON-CLIENT RELATIONS

Traditional patron-client relations in the Philippines are

multifarious, asymmetrical, personal, non-contractual, and grounded

in a strong cultural norm of reciprocal obligation (utang na bob).

As in most of rural Southeast Asia, these ties initially developed

between land owners and tenant farmers. Land owners provided

agricultural fields, credit, security, and prestige in exchange for

267

Page 278: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

loyalty, obedience, labour, and collective power. These ties

persisted for decades, often crossing generations of both patron

and client families. After the Second World War, with the

onslaught of ‘modernization’ -- urbanization, a market economy, a

larger middle-class, more educational opportunities, social

upheavals, changes to agricultural production, and an expanding

bureaucracy -- patron-client networks became larger and more

complex. These networks integrated people with diverse

occupational backgrounds and from all levels of society.6

Shopkeepers, rice dealers, employers, labour leaders, bureaucrats,

and local politicians became patrons. As the bureaucracy expanded,

patrons increasingly relied on the state as a source of patronage.

In this new setting, patron-client ties -- while still personal,

informal, and asymmetrical -- became based more on direct exchange

of state resources and less on loyalty, reciprocal obligation,

family wealth, and feelings of shame. These large, material-based

patron-client networks are more unstable than traditional ties as

6Benedict Kerkvliet documents the decline of traditionalpatron-client relations in Central Luzon in the 1950s. BenedictICerkvliet, The Huk Rebellion: A Study of Peasant Revolt in thePhilippines (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1977) . Fora description of changes to traditional patron-client relations inother local areas, see the collection of essays in Benedict J.Kerkvliet and Resil B. Moj ares, eds., From Marcos To Aguino: LocalPerspectives On Political Transition in the Philippines (Manila:Ateneo de Manila University Press, 1991), especially Alfred W.McCoy, “The Restoration of Planter Power in La Carlota City,”pp.105-142; Cristina Blanc-Szanton, “Change and Politics in aWestern Visayan Municipality,” pp.82-104; Fernando N. Zialcita,“Perspectives on Legitimacy in Ilocos Norte,” in Kerkvliet andMojares, eds., From Marcos To Aguino, pp.26G-285; James F. Eder,Political Transition in a Palawan Farming Community,” pp.143-165;and Resil B. Mojares, “Political Change in a Rural District in CebuProvince,” pp.82-104.

268

Page 279: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

patrons and clients switch allegiances to maximize opportunities.

Modern networks often dissolve when a patron dies or loses

political or economic clout. Today, modern networks are pervasive,

although some traditional ties still remain, mostly in outlying

areas. Alliances between these modern patron-client networks

create factions, often generating strong cleavages among Filipino

elite .

Political and corporate activities are often organized around

families. Some families even maintain their own bank. In the

1960s, about 400 families dominated the Philippines. By the end of

the 1970s, this had dropped to around 60 families.8 Filipino

families are built on both real and ritual kinship ties.

Compadrazgo, or ritual kinship, joins families of similar socio

economic rank as well as poor families to wealthier ones. These

ties are often cemented by a member of an influential family acting

7For a discussion of traditional and modern patron-clientnetworks in the Philippines, see K.G. Machado, “Continuity andChange in Philippine Factionalism,” in Frank P. Belloni and DennisC. Beller, eds. Faction Politics: Political Parties andFactionalism In Comparative Perspective (Santa Barbara, California:ABC-Clio, Inc., 1978), pp.193-217; K.G. Machado, “From TraditionalFaction to Machine: Changing Patterns of Political Leadership andOrganization in Rural Philippines,” Journal of Asian Studies 33,no. 4 (August 1974), pp.523-547; Thomas C. Nowak and Kay A. Snyder,“Clientelist Politics in the Philippines: Integration orInstability?” The American Political Science Review 68 (1974),pp.1147-1170; and Thomas Nowak and Kay Snyder, ‘Urbanization andClientelist Systems in the Philippines,” Philippine Journal ofPublic Administration, 14-15 (July 1970), pp.259-275. For acritique of patron-client analysis in the context of thePhilippines, see Willem Wolters, Politics, Patronage, and ClassConflict in Central Luzon (The Hague: Institute of Social Studies,1983)

8David G. Timberman, A Changeless Land: Continuity and Changein Philippine Politics (New York: M.E. Sharpe, 1991), p.17.

269

Page 280: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

1:0 —1

C

-3o

0<

çtØ

5Cl)

9)H

CD

CD9)

I—CD

0<

CD9)

II0

H-

h0

CDW

rtH

-1C

DH

-H-

0Cl)

H-

Cl)CD

09)

HiC

D0

H-F

tH

-I-]

HC

DF

rH

-H

-CD

CDC

DF

t-,-

-

9)9)

CDF

r0

-QH

-F

t

000

H-

FtL

)H

-p

j9)

0F

t‘

H-I

HP

CD

0

H-

I

Cl)

0,-

Cl)

P1fJ

CDH

-CD

CD

j0

Ft

op.

II U)

0L-

CD

-‘ o

HF

t.

Cl)Cl)

CDH

-H H

(Cl

Hçt C

CDH

(t

H-

Fr•

FtC

J)CD

Cl)

H•

00

b‘

3d

rto

•C

DC

DP

)°9)0P

J000H

-F

tF

rF

tH

Hi

HH

Ct

dD

IH

Ft9

)P

)C

DH

9)

009)

CDCl)

‘ICD

CDCD

<H

-9)

jC

l)U

)-

CD

IH

p.

‘—3

II CD Cl)

Cl)

—‘0

C Lt

H-

ei

U)—

.

CDcx

Cl) Ft

-

0p

.‘r Cl

)9)

)0

p.

0:;d

H-’

0çt-

CD

CD

H-

p.

rJ

CDH

Hi

It’

H-

pj9)

çt ‘IC

D0

‘1

0-fl

H0

H-

CD j Ft

U)9

CD

9)-

CD

p.

HC

DC

DH

iCl)

IIC

l)<

H-

0CD

l:-

jp

i;

p.

U)p

.-

-H

i

CD

HH

’i

1:s)

a-,

i-M

•CD

•CD

0‘-

Cl)CD

I-QH

iCl

)H

-II

‘-‘J

J9)

09)

H-

H-

09)

9)0

H-

H-

9)9)

Cl)II

Ft

N0

Ft

HCl

)CD

IICD

0Cl

)CD

H-

CDF

tH

H-

H-

9)0

IIH

DH

-2)

Cl

H0

0H

-‘-

<U)

CD0

HH

-H

-H

iI

Hi

‘ti

rt9)

9)CD

0(-Q

CDII

Cl)F

tF

t0

U)p

.9)

HCD

CD0

Ft

H-

H-

CDH

iI

U)H

iH

Cl)H

-F

tCl)

9)F

tF

tF

tLQ

CDi

CD

CD

ClU

)‘I

iH

-H

2)H

iM

HL

I

CD0

H-

c-i-

(1).

p.0

H

c-i

Hi

U)U)

H-

0H

-0

0-.

.0

U)H

H0

H0

HH

-U)

H-

IH

-CD

H<

Ft

00

CD‘-t

it

Irj

LQ0

9)H

-9)

‘rj

Ct)ft

c-i-

2)CD

C!)

0CD

p.

pCD

Ft

Mi

CD

CD

p.

CD-

CD(1)

Ft

Ft

Ft

Hi

2-

c-i-

CD

P0

Hi

9)0

CDF

tM

HH

-CD

0

09)

H0

U)H

-Q

HH

-CD

iH

iF

tH

HF

tj

iCD

09)

H-

0H

FlCD

-<

H2)

0U)

p.

9)CD

H-

9)0

H-

c-i-

p,

(QD

pH

H-

CDH

H-

Ft

0F

t<

HH

iH

Hi

Ft

9)H

-F

tH

Ft

Ft

CDCD

c-i-

H(Q

0i

CDH

9)0

QM

itQ

0I—

iM

ip.

HCD

0F

t0

Mi

9).<

Ft

iF

t0

FlH

Cc-i

--

Mi

Ft

H

U)p.

0-

CDC

CDU)

9)0

9)i

gH

-•

Ft

DCD

CDH

-‘-

H-

Hi

CFl

U)U)

H-

HF

tC

)

Ft<

9)H

-

Ft°

CD‘-r

j8

Ft

piU)

0H

i‘-<

CDp.

lCD

‘-d0

CDU)

H‘I

<Fl

p.Cl)

CDH

Iji

H.

:9)

CD•

CDH

0F

tH

-U)

‘o•

H

<CD

Ft

0H

iH

-CD

‘1F

tH

-CD

0CD

9)U)

Ft

HH

-CD

U)9)

Ft

Ft

oH

Cl)

9)p

.F

tF

tH

H-

IIH

-F

tCD

I-I9)

9)9)

9)i

0H

CD‘-P

9)i

iFt

CD9)

00

‘-<

CDi

CDp.

Hp.

Ft

0-1

Ft

U)CD

U)

Page 281: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

PATRON-CLIENT RELATIONS (1898- 1972)

After the U.S. colonized the Philippines in 1898, more and

more patrons exploited bureaucratic connections and resources to

obtain benefits for their clientele. As the bureaucracy grew,

especially after independence in 1946, “congressmen and senators,

the president and close associates, influential businessmen,

members of the press, bureau directors and office chiefs all made

telephone calls, wrote letters of recommendation or personally

accompanied their protégés to agencies where vacancies and new

positions were available.”’3 As more patrons relied on state

resources to sustain their networks, bureaucratic appointments,

licences and funds were increasingly allocated based on personal

contacts rather than on competitive bids or exams.’4 In the 1950s

and 1960s, loyal Congress members -- especially from the government

party -- gained informal powers to appoint followers to

bureaucratic positions. Through this clientele and their control

over the budget, political leaders dominated the bureaucracy.

Instead of functioning on principles of merit and efficiency,

bureaucratic decisions and policies were overwhelmed by

particularistic, opportunistic patron-client interaction. In this

1990), p.244.

‘3Eisenstadt and Roniger, Patrons, clients and friends, p.128.For background on the Philippine bureaucracy, see Raul P. DeGuzman, Alex B. Brillantes, Jr., and Arturo G. Pacho, “TheBureaucracy,” in Raul P. De Guzman and Mila A. Reforma, eds.,Government and Politics of the Philippines (Singapore: OxfordUniversity Press, 1988), pp.180-206.

‘4Hutchcroft, “Oligarchs and Cronies,” p.422.

271

Page 282: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

CQ

HU)

IIC)

0C)

Cr

Hi

Mi

1U)

CDH

iJ

)CD

CD.)

Pi1)

H-

Cl)CD

0<

CD1)

H-

PiH

-CD

HC

rC

rC

rH

9)C

rI-

Cr

HI

(-QH

CDtY

‘ti

CDH

-<

Cr

H-

CD‘1

t-H

-P

hCr

H<

HII

H-

H-

9)C

rH

-c-

tCD

00

<CD

0H

-I-

-H

-H

CDH

Cr

U)H

Hi

CDI-

Cl)9)

C)9)

C)C

rH

-9)

0C)

Mi

H-

LII

,LI

IU)

I9)

IIU)

9)U)

Cl)

HCD

Ct

Cr

Cr

H1

H-

0LQ

H-

H-

CDC)

(QH

iCD

U)CD

CD9)

H-

Cl)9)

H3

-U)

IIU)

HH

Cl)-

CD‘

0F-

Cr

NH

Mi

CDH

iCD

H-

9)I-

CDQ

IH

-H

-‘Z

ICD

Cl)CD

Cr

‘CD

H-

a’II

0C)

HU)

HU)

Cr

Cl)U)

9)9)

CD1

Cr

Zh

Cr

Ct

0CD

CDti

Cr

-C

rH

CFH

H-

CDCD

H-H

-C

D

3H

iP

sIi

frxj

CD0

HCD

gi

Mi

CF

U)IH

-C

rIH

-C

rC

rCD

HH

0CT

)-

Cr

Cr

H-

HH

iH

9)j-

CDC

rH

-H

-9)

U)U)

0I’

-‘1

c-r

iC)

9)9)

tiC

r9)

II

IC

FCD

Cr

ci

I

‘ti

0CD

Cr

U)0

Cr

ii

U)C

r3

U)CD

Cr

Qc-I

-0

‘<H

‘1H

-C

(pH

H0

CDIt

ICD

C):i

U)U)

9)9)

Cr

Cr

H-

H-

HU)

CDU)

ICH

-10

H:i

C)H

CDH

-H

HCl

)C)

U)Cl)

IHIH

CDI

cpIH

CD1H

CDC

FI-

Hi

CDH

Cr

(-P

Cl)

Cr

9)H

1HF-’

-U)

CDU)

H9)

CDH

9)9)

CDC

r

Cr

ICr0

H-C

DH

H-

9)H

<CD

L‘

L‘

IH

H:i

3-

‘1-

9)H

C)‘

HCD

‘ti

Cr

Cr

CDH

-C

ri

HH

I-H

-C

rC

r(.

H-

0H

-H

H-

00

CDCD

H-

HCD

CDCD

CDCl)

CDCD

Cl)i

C)H

H-

Cr

U)Q

9)pj

-U

)P

Cr

CD9’

‘-PH

-C

rC

rC

rCD

Cl)

Cr

U)U)

H-

9’H

-CD

9’0

Cr

CDC

rH

-CD

U)C)

9’C

rC

rH

iCD

Cr

cj

Cr

CDCF

U)9’

Cr

CDH

iCD

H-

CDi-

HH

C)•

<CD

Cl)

.C

rH

-•

H-

0CD

CDCD

CDP

CDU)

H-

H-

Hi

00

HH

-9)

CDU)

CDCD

Hi

0H

iCD

HC

rH

-H

i9)

Cr

Cr

C)0

HC

rH

C)0

C)

H9)

9’9)

C)C

rCD

C)C

rC

rC

rH

-9)

0P

‘I-i)

I-C

rH

C0

Hpi

CDH

-<

Cr

Cr

Hi

Hi

H-

Cr

CDCD

CDCl)

CD0

H-

00

HH

-H

-H

-H

CDH

-C

rC

rCD

Cr

Cr

i-CD

0(P

C))

Cr

1CD

H-

Hi

CDCD

H-

1CD

HH

-P

CDCD

Hi

U)H

-C

r9)

9)C

rH

i0

Cr

U)H

U)U)

CDC)

HCl)

0CD

U)‘t

iC

rC

rrj

Cr

Hi

Ii0

CDp.

--

CDH

-‘<

HH

-H

HCD

CDC)

9)C)

I0

U)C)

H-

t5H

-•

•‘d

c..pW

CDC)

Cr

Cr

9)H

-U)

Cr

b0

U)C

r‘

0C

r0

H-

HC

r0

U)9)

Mi

HH

9)H

-U)

0H

-C

rH

-H

-C)

<CD

Cr

9)H

iCD

IH

its

)10

I-IC)

CDC)

H-

C)9)

C)H

-CD

I-C

rC

r9)

9)C

rH

-(0

WC

r9)

hI0

0H

9)9)

(P9)

9)H

Cr0

CDCD

<k<

C)•

•‘<

HCD

Hi

Hi

HIQ

HCD

HI-

’‘-<

0H

P‘-

<I

CD

Page 283: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

switching, by rebels who contested the official party candidates,

and by independent candidates.”9 In this setting, many clients

exchanged their votes for money, gifts, and jobs. As well,

financial backers of victorious politicians often received senior

administrative posts. Elections were expensive and political power

was often limited to wealthy families.20 The 1969 election

apparently cost 1 billion pesos, nearly one-quarter of that year’s

national budget. By this time elections were so expensive, they

“trigger[edl massive government deficits and ultimately the

devaluation of the peso.”21

MARCOS AS SUPREME PATRON (1972-1986)

After Marcos declared martial law in 1972, his family and

clients (cronies) -- especially from his home province of Ilocos

Norte - - consolidated control over the distribution of patronage.22

Rather than dispersing “the national network of patron-client

‘9jose V. Abueva, “Philippine Ideologies and NationalDevelopment,” in De Guzman and Reforma, eds., Government andPolitics, p.52.

21Wurfel, Filipino Politics, p.329 (quote), and p.100 for thedata. As traditional patron-client relations evolved in the 1950sand 1960s, it was increasingly common for voters to accept moneyfrom several candidates or accept money from one candidate and votefor another. This further increased election expenses. See Ibid.,pp. 99 - 10 0.

22For Ilocanos, Marcos was their apo, or supreme patron.According to McDougald, “all his trusted generals in the military,and many of his trusted advisors, were Ilocano.” Charles C.McDougald, The Marcos File: Was he a Philippine Hero or CorruptTyrant? (San Francisco: San Francisco Publishers, 1987), p.114.

273

Page 284: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

relations,” Marcos manoeuvred to centralize control over these

networks. To increase his power, he decided “to become ‘supreme

godfather’ and acquire the personal wealth that would reinforce

that role. He eliminated his competitors at the national level and

strengthened his own position in regions and provinces by dealing

more directly with the barangay” [the smallest unit of local

government] 23

Friends, followers, and relatives of Ferdinand and Imelda

Marcos received government credit, licences, tax exemptions,

monopolistic contracts, classified government information, and

privileged access to foreign aid and joint ventures. Funds from

the World Bank, the International Monetary Fund, and Northern

bilateral donors and commercial banks -- especially the U.S. and

Japan -- fuelled pervasive patronage. In 1991, the Philippine

Solicitor General alleged that Japanese firms -- including Mitsui,

Nissho Iwai, Marubeni and Sumitomo -- channelled US$55 million of

aid money to Marcos’s bank accounts in Hongkong and Switzerland.24

In this setting, Marcos and his clients -- such as Herrninio Disini

and Ricardo Silverio (manufacturing), Eduardo Cojuangco (coconuts),

Antonio Floirendo (bananas), and Roberto Benedicto (sugar) -- built

23Wurfel, Filipino Politics, p.152-l53. There are five levelsof local government: regions; provinces; cities; municipalities;and barangays. In 1986, there were 42,000 barangays. Forbackground, see Raul P. De Guzman, Mila A. Reforma, and Elena M.Panganiban, “Local Government,” in Guzman and Reforma, eds.,Government and Politics.

24”Japanese envoy and Manila legal chief in row over ‘bribes’’to Marcos,” Straits Times, 14 December 1991, p.16.

274

Page 285: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

3”

—rtO

p-

CD

CD

CD

H-I

C)

H-C

-pIo

L)

oo-

HIU

)‘

CDU)

wO

pjH

-)

C-F

CDhC

-F

iii

frH

rtC

)H

FM

UJçjj

H-

••1C

DM

1CD

C-F

j1C

DU

)H

I)H

-H

al

HC

-0F

—H

H-

frij

Fx

j

H-

Cl)

•C

DIH

IH0

HCl)

CD

IH]H

-H

-C

DC

DCD

Cl’

IH ni‘

H-

tj::iIj

Q-

iC

Dpi

1

ICD

I’d

dW

HU

),C

)I’t

lIC

Cl)

0IH

HO

0.

IH-

9)F

1j

1(1

1IH

-çt

•H

-CD

CD

IHIC

)CD

0H

-IC

)1W

I-i-

]H-

PiU

)iW

r.JC

)U

)H-3

—J

F-

9JW

-U

)M

)

01

‘dt

.9)

hH w

ci)

U)H

W

ci0

HH

C-F

’.<

ci

.C-

Fi

CD II U)

‘tl

C)9

)

Cl) CD CDH

9JH

-C-t

O’d

H0

P)

i—<01H

H-

HH

-Q

HH

9’C

DH

0O

CD

‘dL

QH

C-

CD9’

9)C

DCD ‘-I

0H-

C-F

Q9

)U)C

D

Mi

CD

P”d

—U)

HCD

‘-I9)

C)0

‘ti

C-F

C-t-

H‘-‘I .

t3

HIC

I)

çFH

CD

H-I

0C

-FH

-H

-CD

CD

U)IJ0

C)I

1IC

DC

D3

H-

C)H

-H

-C)

l-9J

9)0

Cl)

‘U)

H-

CDCD

2)H

-3

0CD

bM

2)C-

F<

ii3

9)C)

U)9)

MH

-H

-C-

F9)

CDCD

Mi

pH

Hh

CDC-

FH

-C-

FU)

I-(

CDH

0(Q

Hco

I9)

CDC)

CDU)

0(Q

U)C-

FCD

CDci

‘dH

i‘1

H-

CDU)

YU)

IH

-U

iC-

F9)

CD2)

9)I

‘ICD

00

0H

3H

-C)

HI-

C!)

)C)

H<

:U)

CD2)

CD0

CDj

U)C)

Fj

Ht-Q

CDCD

CDQ

LJ

‘-•

Q9’

U)C-

FCD

<9)

QC-

Fç)

09)

H

CDU)

CD0

H-

C-F

C-

Cl)

Q-(1

2•C-

FH

9)CD

C)u,

pC-

F-

CD0

c-F

C)rF

U)CD

CDc-I

-C-

FCD

HC-

I-H

-CD

HH

-0

CDH

-j

C-F

0CD

CD2)

I9)

t-i

09

0CD

-cc

U)9i

HH

-U)

0-t

H-

C)-

‘t3H

CD

‘1CJ

)0

U)‘-

9)C)

U)I-

U),

9)9)

P0

CDCD

CDC1

H-Q

CD9)

3H

CD:i

-C)

3<

H-

Cl)‘-‘I

iiti

9)pi

C

CDCD

CDC)

‘-<-

z9’

CDCD

3Q

C-F

HC)

h

CD-

H-

H1:5

CDCD

tCD

0F

H-

00

CDCD

CDH

<H

CD9)

CD9)

CDCD

CD0

U)H

-H

<9)

QH

t-C)

)C)

9)C-

FCD

U)3

H-

-CD

CDCD

H-

CD0

a’CD

CD9’

CDI

P-H

-w

0H

HCD

i-C-

F0

C-F

9CD

C-I-

0C-

F‘r

J‘<

U)9)

0‘

CDJ

ci

HII

CD9)

9)H

C)CD

‘ci

CD‘

C-I-

CDi

H-

CDU)

CD0

(1)CD

HC)

I-i)H

-C

C-F

H9)

c-F

2’w

H-

9’0

:iCD

Hc-i

-CD

C-F

1H

iH

-i

H-

1C!)

i-fD

.C)

U)9’

1U)

CDH

-CD

CDCD

U)-

CDU)

rFCD

C-F

CDH

-9)

CD3

9)

00

9’C)

C!)H

dU)

‘1‘1

-CD

0‘1

9)<

0Q

‘1H

iCD

C)CD

II3

-H

HCD

9’C-

FCD

<çF

9)pj

3-

C-F

U)CD

CD9)

C-F

CDU)

U)0

‘ci

II9’

CDU)

H9)

9)H

-H

CDH

CDU)

CF‘<

‘dCD

‘C)

CDH

H-

$1H

9)3

-H

-9)

9)U)

C-F

Mi

‘<Q

IQ

CDH

0CD

CDJ

CDg

Hi

10

‘-i5

CDH

Hi

U)CD

H-

9)-

H-,

CDH

-9’

‘<0

0C-

FU)

CDH

-9)

CDt

Mi

9)9)

H-

0CD

C)9)

i-0

H-

C-F

H-

-H

-9)

CDi-

01

IiCD

9)CD

U)b

c-F

9)3

fr3

QCD

C-F

U)CD

2)9)

HH

C-F

H9)

C-F

U)CD

9)CD

CD9)

U)CD

H-

9)CD

(P‘c

iH

--

H3

-<C-

F1

--

IP

U)CD

C-F

CD3

U)9)

Page 286: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

that bribes accounted for 10 percent of GNP between 1975 and

1980 29

The military was the backbone of martial law, providing Marcos

with an effective tool to suppress dissent. Marcos promoted loyal

generals, retired reluctant followers, and judiciously distributed

patronage to senior officers -- including top positions in state

corporations.3° In addition, many military officers became middle-

level patrons, and “speeding applications and cutting red tape

often became a colonel’s rather than a congressman’s function.”3’

As a result, the military establishment developed a vested interest

in preserving the status quo. As David Wurfel notes, “whether

profiting or sacrificing, all officers were becoming enmeshed more

deeply in increasingly centralized patronage networks. School ties

and ethnicity created factions, but ultimately it was the

superpatron who provided material benefits, and so even factions

were organized by patronage.”32 By linking key generals to his

patron-client network, and allowing middle-level officers to skim

personal benefits, Marcos maintained solid control over the

military, although there were certainly rumblings from some junior

29Kunimer, Deforestation, p.71.

30Alex B. Brillantes, Jr. “The Executive,” in De Guzman andReforma, eds., Government and Politics, p.125. Through loyalclients and prudent appointments, Marcos also kept firm controlover the judiciary. See Froilan M. Bacungan and Alf redo Tadiar,“The Judiciary,” in De Guzman and Reforma, eds., Government andPolitics, pp.164-179.

31Wurfel, Filipino Politics, p.144.

32Ibid., pp.150-151.

276

Page 287: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

officers who advocated greater efficiency and less corruption.

Under Marcos, the bureaucracy was emasculated by rent-seeking

patron-client networks. Martial law undercut legislative patrons,

increasing the scope and power of local and intermediate

bureaucratic patrons and intrabureaucratic patron-client units.33

Bureaucratic patron-client networks proliferated as Marcos placed

clients in strategic positions, rewarded loyal followers, and

punished dissidents.34 By the mid-1970s, competitive exams were

used to fill only 35 percent of government positions. Political

manipulation of bureaucrats and flagrant accumulation of personal

profits by state leaders lowered bureaucratic morale and justified

similar activities among state implementors. As a result, instead

of working to promote state objectives, bureaucrats from top to

bottom worked to maximize particularistic goals and personal

profits.35

,Marcos used patronage and loyal clients to control outlying

regions. By 1979, Marcos had appointed 26 percent of the country’s

mayors. In 1981, Imelda Marcos introduced the Movement for

Livelihood and Progress to provide interest-free ‘loans’ to the

33Eisenstadt and Roniger, Patrons, clients and friends, p.130.For background on the legislature and bureaucracy, see De Guzman,Brillantes Jr., and Pacho, “The Bureaucracy,” pp.180-206; andAurora C. Catilo and Proserpina D. Tapales, “The Legislature,” inDe Guzman and Reforma, eds., Government and Politics, pp.132-163.

34Marcos required bureaucrats to file letters of resignation,leaving everyone vulnerable to being suddenly dismissed.Brillantes, Jr., “The Executive,” p.125.

350f course, not all bureaucrats were absorbed by patron-clientnetworks. Some technocrats had clear policy goals or had acombination of policy and particularistic objectives.

277

Page 288: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

‘poor’. In effect, this program provided cash to loyal local

leaders and their clients. Loan procedures were ignored and few

were repaid. According to Wurfel, “the style of the program

created the impression of a patroness distributing largesse; few

perceived the money as repayable.”36 While Marcos extended his

patron-client network down to the villages, this did not increase

the total amount of patronage distributed to rural areas. With

fewer elections -- and with few restrictions on the manipulation of

election results -- rural areas actually received less patronage.37

PATRON-CLIENTELISM AND THE FALL OF MARCOS

In the twentieth century, Filipino government leaders have

faced two contradictory pressures that shape their legitimate right

to rule: traditional demands by clients for particularistic

benefits; and a legal regime that precludes the use of public

office for private profit. Politicians must manoeuvre in a mine

field between ‘acceptable legal bounds’ and ‘acceptable levels of

patronage.’ In this setting, too much patronage can undermine

legitimacy, as can too little. When the interest of one network

supersedes all else, material exchanges, rather than supporting

stability and legitimacy, can spiral ‘out of control’ and corrode

elite support. Throughout the l970s, as a result of reasonable

economic growth and substantial international funding, most

Filipino economic elites supported Marcos. But increasingly

36wurfel, Filipino Politics, p.257.

37Ibid., p.131.

278

Page 289: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

blatant patronage by state-owned firms and the personal

extravagance of key allies -- including Imelda Marcos38 -- began to

undermine the economy in the early 1980s. International creditors

lost confidence in Marcos, the economy stagnated, and opposition

from Filipino economic elites mounted.39 As his legitimacy eroded,

Marcos responded with “massive outlays to insure the loyalty of

local elites.”40 But without international support or a vibrant

economy, Marcos could no longer sustain his vast network and still

appease state and societal dissidents. By the time ‘People Power’

vaulted Corazon Aquino to the presidency in 1986, Marcos and his

clients -- in their desperate bid to hold together their unwieldy

patron-client network -- had plundered and decapitated the state.

PATRON-CLIENT NETWORKS ND PATRONAGE SINCE 1986

The Aquino government restored key features of pre-martial law

politics, including the pre-1973 constitution, many former

politicians, and pervasive, decentralized state patronage.4’ After

38lmelda Marcos had her own followers and in many ways had aconfrontational relationship with her husband. Yet her actionsstill undermined President Marcos’s legitimacy.

39Hutchcroft, “Oligarchs and Cronies,” pp.445-446. Martial lawwas ostensibly lifted in 1981 but Marcos still maintained the samelevel of control. Brillantes, Jr., “The Executive,” p.126.

40Wurfel, Filipino Politics, p.274. Unlike in most of thecountry, the people of Ilocos Norte backed Marcos to the bitterend. To Ilocanos he was an effective patron and therefore alegitimate ruler. See Zialcita, “Perspectives on Legitimacy,”pp . 266 -285.

41Timberman, A Changeless Land, p.3; Wurfel, Filipino Politics,p.326; and Hutchcroft, “Oligarchs and Cronies,” pp.447-448.

279

Page 290: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

Marcos fell, his network fragmented. But instead of dissipating,

these ties realigned and power dispersed among rival networks.

While Aquino was not personally ‘corrupt’, and despite public anti-

corruption campaigns, she was not able to undercut systemic state

patronage. She could not even purge the bureaucracy; instead, “it

was filled to overflowing by some of her less respected allies.”42

Ramos has also encased his reign in flamboyant campaigns to

eradicate state patronage.43 But like Aquino, he has had little

success. Today, patron-client networks permeate the state and

weaken state capacity to develop and implement policies. Informal

material exchanges persist; personal links to political and

bureaucratic patrons remain a decisive factor in obtaining state

licences, contracts, and tax breaks; and personal contacts --

rather than objective judicial or police procedures -- continue to

shape the interpretation and enforcement of laws. Not

surprisingly, patron-client relations still dominate resource

management. As Paul Hutchcroft vividly explains, “once again, as

in the pre-martial law years, a decentralized polity simply gives

more oligarchs a chance to claw for the booty of state.” Along

similar lines, David Kunimer argues that Filipino politics remains

42Wurfel, Filipino Politics, p.324.

43See Bobby Capco, “Ramos: Anti-graft drive real, plunderers tohang,” The Philippine Star, 22 January 1994, p.1.

44Hutchcroft, “Oligarchs and Cronies,” p.447. Post-MarcosPhilippines confirms the persistence and resilience of patronclient networks. It also supports the picture of the Philippinesas a clientelist state rather than a neo-patrimonial one whichemphasizes one dominant patron.

280

Page 291: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

“basically a form of ‘institutionalized looting,’ with the main

purpose of public office being to enrich oneself and one’s

followers.

Voter attitudes, a cultural proclivity to view transactions as

personal and to feel obligated to reciprocate, cynical views of

politicians and state laws, low bureaucratic salaries, and general

poverty contribute to the persistence of patron-client ties and

state patronage. Many Filipinos “expect their votes to be rewarded

concretely with better roads and schools, with government jobs, and

with ‘a little help’ when confronting stubborn officials or

unreasonable regulations. Politicians who do not comply or who,

for lack of influence in the right places, cannot comply, soon find

themselves of fice1ess.” As a result, members of Congress often

focus on securing ‘pork barrel’ projects for their constituencies

rather than debating and drafting national or regional socio

economic development policies.

The clash between traditional values and modern (American)

legal and political norms contributes to flagrant violations of

laws and to a cynical public view of the state. According to David

Timberman, “the conflict between traditional and modern values is

exemplified by the contradictory tendency of Filipinos to pass laws

and regulations against corruption and nepotism (in a desire to be

45Kummer, Deforestation, p.71. Kuinmer borrows the term‘institutionalized looting’ from Warden Bello, “From Dictatorshipto Elite Populism: The United States and the Philippines Crisis,”in Morris H. Motley, ed., Crisis and Confrontation: Ronald Reagan’sForeign Policy (Teethe: Roman and Littlefield, 1988).

46Rush, The Last Tree, p.33.

281

Page 292: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

‘modern’), even though the norms of traditional society, which

emphasize kinship ties, reciprocity, and personal loyalty, compel

almost everyone to ignore or violate these laws.”47 This has

contributed to government campaigns to purge corrupt officials, and

to incessant charges of corruption by opposition parties, NGOs and

the media. However, although token scapegoats are sometimes

punished, only marginal progress has been made in curbing the use

of public office for private gain. As Timberman notes, “it is a

paradox of Philippine politics that corruption is assumed to be

endemic to politics and government, but at the same time ‘exposing’

corruption is a time-tested political tactic and guaranteed vote-

getter.”48 This has undermined public faith in legal institutions

and government regulations.

A cultural tendency to perceive transactions as personal

reinforces patron-client ties between state officials and societal

members. In this cultural prism, “routine political, bureaucratic,

or business transactions considered in the West to be impersonal

(such as voting, applying for a permit or licence, or entering into

a business contract) are instead considered to be personal

interactions involving favours or other unspecified obligations.”49

According to Carle Land, “when a congressman proudly ‘gives’ a

town a new chapel or bridge, few may know or care whether the money

47Timberman, A Changeless Land, p.14. Filipino cynicism isfortified by the memory of Marcos who coated most of his actions ina constitutional veneer.

481b±d., p.25.

491bid., p.22.

282

Page 293: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

came from his own pocket or from the government.”50 As a result,

patron-client links flourish as people feel obliged to individual

state representatives rather than to the state itself. Low state

salaries -- undercut by inflation and general poverty -- further

strengthen patron-client ties. Rush argues that in poor countries

like the Philippines, almost everyone searches vigilantly for ways

of “getting a little more.” For this reason, “from top to bottom,

civil servants are often entangled in relationships of mutual

assistance with others outside government.” There are few working

for the “common good,” and state laws are often sacrificed for

personal profit.5’

In sum, there is surprising continuity across post-war

political regimes in the Philippines. In the 1950s and 1960s,

particularistic, rent-seeking patron-client networks -- often

centred in Congress -- battled for votes and control of state

levers to distribute patronage. During this period, power was

dispersed among central, regional, and local patrons. Using the

tools of martial law, Marcos centralized the allocation of

patronage in the 1970s. Although he relied heavily on support from

international financiers, the military, and less powerful patrons

throughout the country, Marcos managed to eliminate or appease many

competing patron-client units. He was deposed in 1986 after

50Carle Landé, Leaders, Factions, and Parties; The Structure ofPhilippine Politics (New Haven: Yale University Southeast AsiaStudies Program, 1965), p.80, quoted in Timberman, A ChangelessLand, p.22.

5’Rush, The Last Tree, p.34.

283

Page 294: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

resources grew scarce and he could no longer sustain his unwieldy

patron-client network. Today, power is again dispersed among rival

patron-client units -- many with a powerful economic ‘family’ at

the core. These have ties to the president, members of Congress,

key corporate leaders, military officers, bureaucrats, and leaders

in the outlying provinces. While these three periods have obvious

distinctions, all are characterized by one dominant feature:

patron-client units battling for access to and control over state

patronage.

PATRONS ND TIMBER

From the l950s to the mid-1980s, extensive ties between senior

state officials and timber operators distorted management policies

and drove destructive and excessive logging. During the Marcos

years, top political and military leaders -- including Defence

Secretary Juan Ponce Enrile, and Armed Forces Chief of Staff

General Fabian Ver -- were involved in illegal logging and

smuggling.52 Powerful timber operators -- such as Alfonso Lim and

521n 1985, a Presidential Task Force claimed that three timbercompanies owned by Enrile -- Dolores Timber, San Jose Corporation,and JJ Tirador Lumber Corporation (Cresta Monte) -- and hisshipping company, Cresta Monte Shipping, were involved in logsmuggling. Marit.es Danguilan Vitug, The Politics of Logging: PowerFrom the Forest (Manila: Philippine Center For InvestigativeJournalism, 1993), p.29. Also see Marites Danguilan Vitug, “Isthere a Logger in the House?” in Eric Gamalinda and Sheila Coronel,eds., Saving the Earth: The Philippine Experience, 3rd edition,(Manila: Philippine Center for Investigative Journalism, 1993),p.68; and Criselda Yabes, “Boon or Ban?” in Gamalinda and Coronel,eds., Saving the Earth, p.28. The Philippine Veterans Investmentand Development Corporation (Phividec) -- through its subsidiary,the Construction and Development Corporation (Phicondec) - - wasalso involved in destructive logging and smuggling. See Vitug, Th

284

Page 295: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

Herminio Disini -- were key Marcos clients.53 These clientelist

ties at the top of the state weakened supervision of state

implementors, undermining state capacity to enforce timber

regulations and collect forest charges. The state was not able to

protect and rehabilitate the forests, and deforestation was

rampant.

After the fall of Marcos, patrons and clients scrambled to

form new alliances. A remarkable number survived. A University of

the Philippines resource specialist lamented: “With the change of

government [in 1986], many of us were hopeful that things would

change -- only to find out that a new group of politicians close to

Malacanang [the presidential palace] has again served as

sponsor. . . showing that the control of natural resources is power

and that the game goes on.”54 Today, numerous Congress members,

provincial governors, and local mayors have past or present links

Politics of Logging, p.31; for Phividec’s logging activities, seeIbid., pp.30-32.

53Lim’s timber empire was impressive. He effectivelycontrolled about 600,000 hectares of logging concessions. Vitug,The Politics of Logging, p.16. Disini -- who married ImeldaMarcos’s cousin --controlled almost 200,000 hectares of timber innorthern Luzon. James K. Boyce, The Philippines: The PoliticalEconomy of Growth and Impoverishment in the Marcos Era (London: TheMacMillan Press Ltd., 1993), p.233. Vitug provides extensivedetails on the links between Marcos, his clients, and timberoperators. I will not reiterate her work. See Vitug, The Politicsof Logging, especially, pp.16-24, and p.44. In chapter five(pp.85-101), Vitug documents the extensive past and present links-

- both clear and tenuous - - between Congress members and thetimber industry.

54Quoted in James Clad and Marites D. Vitug, “Words, words,everywhere and not a thing is done,” FEER, 24 November 1988, p.52.

285

Page 296: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

to timber companies.55 The career of Palawan timber magnate Jose

‘Pepito’ Alvarez illustrates how many timber operators linked to

Marcos survived the transition to Aquino. After working for about

ten years for a Japanese timber company in Indonesia, Alvarez moved

to the heavily forested province of Palawan. Alvarez developed

close ties to Teodoro Pena, the Minister of Natural Resources and

Marcos’s key Palawan client. Pena arranged for Alvarez to obtain

two concessions covering 168,000 hectares, 61 percent of Palawan’s

productive forest. In exchange, Alvarez supported Pena’s bid for

a seat in the legislature. Alvarez’s links to Marcos were

reinforced by his father-in-law, a key Marcos client in Mindanao.

According to photos taken by former workers, Alvarez’s main

company -- Pagdanan -- has logged illegally, clear-cut forest

areas, and limited reforestation “to the sides of roads.”56 But by

adroitly switching patrons after Marcos fell, and judiciously

distributing patronage, Alvarez has remained largely immune from

state sanctions. In the 1987 congressional election Alvarez

abandoned Pena and backed Ramon Mitra, who later became a

presidential candidate and Speaker of the House. Alvarez financed

Mitra’s political party and reportedly gave him a ranch house in

Palawan. Besides cultivating close ties to Mitra, Alvarez has

prudently maintained links to Palawan’s other Congressman (David

555ee Vitug, “Is there a Logger in the House?” pp.62-68. As of1993, nine Congress members have significant past or present linksto the timber industry. Vitug, The Politics of Logging, p.92.

56Robin Broad and John Cavanagh, “Marcos’s Ghost,” AmicusJournal (Fall 1989), p.26.

286

Page 297: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

Ponce de Leon), provincial military officers, business leaders who

control the two newspapers and one radio station in Palawan, local

government officials, and even Palawan’s Catholic bishop.57

According to Robin Broad and John Cavanagh, Alvarez is typical of

many powerful loggers in the post-Marcos era: they simply “shifted

their allegiance and economic backing from Marcos to politicians in

Aquino’s camp. “

As a result of these realignments, loggers still have leverage

over political decisions and policies, especially in the outer

regions and among state enforcement officers. But at the highest

levels their power has diminished. Aquino had no apparent ties to

loggers and pushed for better environmental management.59 Changes

to the political positions and the timber interests of the three

main candidates in the 1992 presidential election -- Mitra, Eduardo

Cojuangco, and Ramos -- demonstrate the waning influence of loggers

57Rush, The Last Tree, p.43; Horacio Severino, “The ChallengeAhead,” in Gamalinda and Coronel, eds., Saving the Earth, p.9;Broad and Cavanagh, “Marcos’s Ghost,” p.20; and Robin Broad withJohn Cavanagh, Plundering Paradise: The Struggle for theEnvironment in the Philippines (Berkeley: University of CaliforniaPress, 1993), pp.39-55. Besides Alvarez, other concession holdersin Palawan in 1988 included “the wife of the provincial governor,a former governor, a member of the provincial board and former townmayor, and other members of influential families, includingAlvarez’s.” Rush, The Last Tree, p.43

58Broad and Cavanagh, “Marcos’s Ghost,” p.20.

59Former DENR Secretary Fulgencio Factoran stated that: “Thepolitical pressure I experienced was not from a higher-up asking meto do something against my will. President Cory never intervened.It was the two houses of Congress.” Quoted in Vitug, The Politicsof Logging, p.50. Aquino once inquired about the suspension of thetimber concession operated by Greenbelt Wood Products (linked toFidel Ramos) but, according to Factoran, “she did not make mechange anything.” Ibid., p.51.

287

Page 298: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

at the top of the state. During the 1992 presidential campaign,

Mitra, who in the past had been a staunch supporter of logging,

publicly condemned destructive and illegal loggers, and -- although

he still defended Alvarez -- called for a total logging ban. This

sharp reversal of his previous environmental views likely reflected

the growing concern among Filipino voters with floods, soil

erosion, and environmental degradation. While Mitra has indirect

ties to the timber industry, Cojuangco -- a former Marcos client --

has direct links. He is president of International Hardwood and

Veneer Corporation (Interwood) and director of Eastern Plywood

Company and Santa Clara Plywood Company. In 1992, after DENR found

evidence of illegal logging, Cojuangco -- despite controlling a

corporate empire -- was unable to prevent the suspension of

Interwood’ s licence.60

Ramos has also had direct ties to destructive logging. He

held shares in Greenbelt Wood Products, a company chaired by his

father until he died in 1986. Greenbelt violated numerous timber

regulations, even after March 1991, when its concession licence

officially expired. According to one report for the government,

Greenbelt has an “image of invincibility. . .with apparent blessings

of. . .some patrons in Manila. With its vast resources and

influence, it was able to put up its own security force.. i,61

Before the 1992 presidential election, Ramos severed his direct

60Vitug, “Is there a Logger in the House?” pp.60-61. Interwoodhas also been connected to processing under-sized logs, andinadequate reforestation.

61Quoted in Ibid., p.61.

288

Page 299: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

ties to the timber industry and divested his shares in Greenbelt.

He then made environmental protection a key part of his 1992

presidential platform. Since winning this election, Ramos has

responded to some environmental concerns. At the start of his

term, under intense media and Congressional pressure, he replaced

his political ally Edelmiro Arnante as Secretary-designate of DENR

after the media publicized Amante’s close links to Mindanao timber

companies. Ramos then accepted a recommendation by a coalition of

environmental groups and appointed Angel C. Alcala as the new DENR

Secretary. In his first two years as president, Ramos has

supported moves to curb illegal logging and smuggling, increase

reforestation, and improve forestry management.

The weakening of ties between loggers and top state leaders

does not signal a fundamental change to Filipino patron-client

politics. Rather, it reflects the collapse of the timber industry:

with fewer valuable logs, there is simply less patronage to sustain

powerful timber-based patron-client networks. As Horac±o Severino

aptly notes, although it would be gratifying to perceive the

changing balance of power as a victory for NGOs and environmental

groups, “just as likely, the diminished influence of the loggers in

our society has simply coincided with the disappearance of much of

our country’s forests.”62

As timber-based patron-client ties to top politicians erode,

as potential profits decline, and as attitudes supporting

environmental protection strengthen, there has been a marginal

62Severino, “The Challenge Ahead,” p.10.

289

Page 300: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

increase in state capacity to manage the forests. As we will see

in the next section, since 1986 the state has slashed the number of

logging licences, gathered more accurate data and information, and

made notable strides in reforestation. But pervasive patron-client

links between politicians, military officials, and bureaucratic

implementors still distort policies and thwart enforcement. As a

result, illegal logging is common, companies evade taxes and timber

royalties, numerous reforestation sites have failed, timber

processors are inefficient, and selective logging bans -- including

one to protect the last primary forests -- are almost meaningless.

Even the laudable move to allow communities to manage forest areas

is undermined by local patron-client networks that struggle to

promote particularistic goals.

FORESTRY POLICIES AND PATRON-CLIENT POLITICS

A. Background

The Philippines has around 7,000 islands and a total land area

of 30 million hectares. The state owns all land classified as

forests. After independence in 1946, forests covered about three-

quarters of the Philippines.63 Partly driven by Northern trade and

technology, and partly by government incentives, large logging

operations began in the Philippines in the 1950s. By the 1960s, as

log purchases from Japan soared, annual deforestation climbed to

300,000 hectares. In 1969, timber output peaked at over 11 million

6300± Jin Bee, Depletion of Forest Resources in the Philippines(Singapore: ASEAN Economic Research Unit, Institute of SoutheastAsian Studies, 1987), p.14.

290

Page 301: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

cubic metres, and log exports accounted for one-third of total

Philippine export earnings. In the early 1970s, timber production

held steady at about 10 million cubic metres. As valuable timber

stocks grew scarce, and as demand from Japan dropped sharply, log

extraction declined in the 1970s, and by the early 1980s annual

deforestation had fallen to 150,000 hectares. By 1990, annual

deforestation was less than 100,000 hectares due in part to fewer

logging concessions, more reforestation, selective logging bans,

and most importantly, the depletion of commercial forests.

The government classifies 15.88 million hectares -- or 53

percent of total land area -- as forest lands. But there are

actually only 5.9 million hectares and it “is going down as fast as

fire, axe and chainsaw allow.”64 Of this, 3.91 million hectares

are dipterocarp forests; about 800,000 hectares of these forests

are undisturbed.65 According to an ecologist with the Institute of

Church and Social Issues, every year another 50,000 hectares of

primary forests disappears.66 At the beginning of 1992, the

government banned logging in all primary forests to slow the rapid

loss of old-growth forests. Logging is now only allowed in

Johnson, “Fire in the Mother Lung,” p.34.

65Philippine Department of Environment and Natural Resources,Forest Management Bureau, Republic of the Philippines, 1992Philippine Forestry Statistics (Manila: Republic of thePhilippines, annual publication, 1993), p.xi.

66Summarized in Alan Robles, “An Ecological Crisis,” inGamalinda and Coronel, eds., Saving The Earth, p.15.

291

Page 302: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

“adequately stocked residual forests.”67

In 1986, the duties of the Ministry of Natural Resources were

expanded to include environmental protection and the ministry was

renamed the Department of Environment and Natural Resources (DENR)

DENR is responsible for regulating, monitoring, and protecting

forest land, issuing timber licence agreements (TLAs), enforcing

selective logging guidelines, and ensuring adequate

reforestation.68 The Aquino government also restructured forest

management within the Department, curtailing the powers of the

Bureau of Forest Development (BFD) , the core of many patron-client

networks linked to poor enforcement in the past. The BFD was

renamed the Forest Management Bureau. It was given “support rather

than operational functions,” and field officials were integrated

into DENR’s “line structure.”69 In addition, the government pushed

forestry staff into the field, decentralized some power to lower

levels of the Department and regional offices, and put more

emphasis on social and community forestry programs.

67Philippine Department of Environment and Natural Resources,1992 Philippine Forestry Statistics, p.xi. Rapid policy changes --

coupled with a plethora of legislative proposals since 1986 -- makeit difficult to unravel environmental and timber policies in thePhilippines. This problem is aggravated by ambitious governmentofficials and overly zealous reporters and NGO activists whodistort statistics. Many articles are inconsistent, ambiguous,vague, and based on rumour and accusation rather than concreteevidence. As a result, there is substantial confusion -- bothinside and outside the Philippines -- over current forestry dataand policies. Numerous authors note this frustrating problem. Forexample, see Callister, Illegal Tropical Timber Trade, pp.59-60.

68Belcher and Gennino, eds, Southeast Asia Rainforests, p.36.

69Korten, “Environmental Loans,” p.6.

292

Page 303: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

Aquino appointed Ernesto Maceda DENR Secretary in 1986,

despite previous allegations of corruption. According to Marites

Danguilan Vitug, “the DENR post was Cory Aquino’s ‘thank you’ gift

to Maceda for his big role in her victory.”70 Maceda’s tenure only

lasted 9 months, ending after the November 1986 attempted coup.

Maceda was replaced by human rights lawyer, Fulgencio Factoran,

following interim Secretary Carlos Dominguez. Factoran had a

profound impact on the Department and -- until his term ended in

June 1992 -- was a key force behind efforts to improve state timber

management. After Factoran stepped aside, DENR Undersecretary

Ricardo Umali acted briefly as interim Secretary until Ramos

appointed Angel Alcala. Alcala has continued in the tradition of

Factoran and pressed hard for better enforcement and forestry

management. But like Factoran he has faced formidable obstacles,

including his own recalcitrant Department.

B. Timber Concessionaires and Legal Logging

As in Indonesia and Sarawak, in theory, Philippine companies

are supposed to follow selective logging rules and conduct

appropriate enrichment planting and silvicultural treatments. But

in practice, loggers -- with protection from political,

bureaucratic, and military officials -- have rarely adhered to

these rules and many timber concessions have been devastated.7’ In

70vitug, The Politics of Logging, p.40.

71See Hurst, Rainforest, p.188; “Philippines,” (Based on thework of Cesar Nuevo), in Blockhus, Dillenbeck, Sayer and Wegge,eds., Conserving Biological Diversity in Managed Tropical Forests,

293

Page 304: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

CDU)

Hçu

p.H

Cd

oCD

cid

CD0

(-QCD

(h

H-

H-

CDcJ

)H

c-I-

C.)w

H-

HLQ

CCD

LU) CD

HU)

CH

-o

CD4

-

Mi

CDo

H-

HCD

CDc-

IH

U)H

-c-

I-

c-c

H-

CDCD

HCD

)c-

Hj)

Q

HH

-ci

hc-I

-P

iH

-CD

U)—

ciU)

tOH

-c-I

-c

ciCD

oH

U)

c-t

c-I

H-

U)M

iH

c-I-

CDCD

ci

HH

-H

-U)

H-

HIQ

U)H

HH ci

oCD

o0

H-

CCD

Mi

CDU

)ci

c-I

CDM

iCD

i-h

H-

H-

H-

Cl)0

H-

oU)

bCD

0i-

cic-I

-1

U)—

.H

-CD

2)-

cici

HU

)

Ccik<

Mi

ccCD

0H

2)0

Hp

<H

IIH

-<

CDt)

2)c-

I--

-cc

H-

U)c-

I-0

H-

02)

CD0

<J

3ci

CD0

Cl)

Hci

2)

2)i 0

H-

CDCl

)II

U)c-

I

9)CD

0j

Iib

U0

CDM

i

U)9)

U)CD

H-

IiH

-ci

ciN

0H

-CD

CDI-

0H

-CD

c-

Cl)0

0U)

IiC

Mi

c-c

Mi

Hii

c-c‘<

?o

c-I

CD‘-d

lZ5

Mi

ci9)

CDc-I

-CD

H-

c-I-

0ci

H-

0‘1

52’

FlcI

-C

-2)

13(S

Ii

,CD

HH

0U)

CDH

CDCD

ci13 0 CD

H-

$j

CD c-c

c-c

H

c-t

CDo-

CDc-I

-0

CDC

c-c

0H

9)Cl)

FlI

H-

c-I-

Ic-c

H-

U)H

<M

i2)

0CD

CI

139)

-II

I5

I-13

CDCD

130

CDc-

c2) II CD U) 0 CD I- 0 CD

c-I

CD H ‘0 cD U) 2)P

13o

ci

oH

U,

0•

U)U-

I13

-H

-H

H-

H-

ciH

OH

CDH

-13

Mi

DC

013

CD U)c-

cH

CDCD 0

CDc-

rH

c-cii

o0

2)CD

c-I-

i.QCD

HCD

U)U)

FlH

U)M

iH

2)H

0M

i<

ci

00

13I

U(1

CDFl

FlFl

U)2)

CDQ

c-I-

c-I-

9)p

H•H

CDCD

ciCD

ciCD

FlFl

Mi

CD0

00

Flo

H-

•0

13a-

OM

ib

-

CDH

c-I-

<CD

U)2’

13CD

U)CD

H-

H-

cic-I

-H

-13

13H

oc-

tH

H13

H-

2’H

-13

c-I

U)2)

130

c-cCD

Pci

130

13

H‘-<

CCD 2)

(Fl

H-

U)13

H0

U)o

0t.

q13

HtQ

c-I-

Mi

CDII

c-I

I-H

-U)

U)b

•H c-1

oc-I

-CD

U)0

c-I-

0 C C U) H-

c-I-

H 0

dH

2)H

-C

c-c

0H

IICD

H-

oc-c

130

H-

U)CD

0•

U)H 9) 13

I-]

2)U)

13C

Dci

CDc-

cH CD

CD0

H FlFl 9)

QH

9) Flc-

cU)

HC

Dl:3

H-ci

13

H•

H-

U)

ci1

3O

cib

•CD

CD

-•

(01

31

dc-I

H-

1-H

-C

DH

dc-I

-c-c-I-

c-I-

<•

•i

c-I-C

DP

LQ

0W ‘

U)tO

CD

HrJ

13ciH

-’-

CDU

)013

CD•H

-CD

U)-C

Dlt

H-s

HH

-H

Hci

00j

U)M

iO

Fl

13

FlM1

OC

D(0

Hi

CDH

U)U

)U

)1—1

c-c0

U)

H-c

0-

U)C

D•

HH

-H

-W13

‘w-

c-I

•cY

’ICD

•9

)5

Ui

ci•

P13

.IH

-LX

if-IW

os

CD

•H

-Mi

0HdF

lij

c-c

e -.

H-U

)Fl

1AFl

rci

2)-

CD9)

13c-I

-ci

9)H

H-

13H

CD

WQ

Fl

-H

-CO

H-

H$

)U)

ci13

Pci

CD9

)0H

-CCD

-

H H-

00 CD

00

CDCD U)

U)-

H CH

IO

c-I•

(-p H 13 (-p

0 C 13 c-I

2) 0 c-c U)

0 C 13 c-I

Fl H c-c H 13 (-

p c-I

C H 0 9) 13 ci ci CD U) c-I

ll 0 c-I-

H CD 13.

2) CD U) c-I-

H 13 (-p c-I

-CD 0 13 H CD U)

ID II H 13 (-p II c-I

-H 2) H H 9) 2) 0 C U) H

-U) U) CD ci cc

H 2) 0 CD ci

Page 305: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

subcontractors, especially ethnic Chinese companies.74 A typical

concession was 40,000 to 60,000 hectares, although key Marcos

clients controlled areas larger than 100,000 hectares, the nominal

constitutional limit.75 These loggers made enormous profits. The

Haribon environmental group estimates that from 1972 to 1988,

Filipino companies logged 8.57 million hectares, for a total profit

of US$42.85 billion; 3.88 million hectares were primary forests.76

Extensive links between top state leaders and timber operators

weakened supervision of state enforcement officers and lowered

state morale in the Marcos years. Instead of working for the

state, many middle and lower-level officials worked to promote

their own interests. According to a former Bureau of Forest

Development bureaucrat, “because the leadership was corrupt, the

rank and file employees were not afraid to be corrupt.”77 In

exchange for money, gifts, and job opportunities, enforcement

officers often ignored blatant violations of selective logging

rules. Former DENR Secretary Maceda claimed that 90 percent of

forestry bureaucrats in the Marcos era were corrupt.78 In this

setting, the few state officials who tried to uphold the law

74Nectoux and Kuroda, Timber, p.68.

75vitug, The Politics of Logging, p.14.

76Robles, “An Ecological Crisis,” p.18.

77Quoted in Vitug, The Politics of Logging, p.28.

78Summarized in Hurst, Rainforest, p.164. In the Marcos era,the Bureau of Forest Development had a reputation as the most‘corrupt’ government agency. Sajise, et al., State of the NationReports. Saving the Present For The Future, p.19.

295

Page 306: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

confronted formidable systemic barriers.

In the 1970s, Marcos extended the time limit for timber

concession licences to twenty-five years. But at the same time, he

fostered an unpredictable setting by threatening to cancel licences

to control his timber clients. The tenuous position of loggers was

aggravated by the arbitrary power of Marcos’s top client in the

forest bureaucracy, Edmundo Cortes, director of the Bureau of

Forest Development from 1975 to 1986. As a result, longer

concession licences had little practical impact since loggers

realized their licence depended on the grace of Marcos and Cortes.

Few bothered with long-term management.79 According to Vitug, if

loggers “were out of favour with Cortes and Malacanang [the

presidential palace], their TLA would surely be cancelled. The

application of the law was subjective.”80

Since 1986, DENR has suspended, cancelled, and refused to

renew numerous timber licences. At the end of 1992, 61 timber

licence agreements and 10 other kinds of licences provided loggers

with access to 2.3 million hectares with a total allowable yield of

79Boyce, The Philippines, p.226; and Broado, “Incentivepolicies,” p.177.

80Vitug, The Politics of Logging, p.36. Vitug argues thatCortes ruled the Bureau of Forest Development like a ‘godfather.’“The powers of Cortes were enormous. He could suspend licences oftimber concessions. He recommended export quotas of loggingcompanies. At his disposal was 50 percent of the Ministry’sbudget.. . .He could assign his personnel to premier positions inManila and take them out of the hinterlands. He dangled foreigntrips and honoraria.” Ibid., p.34.

296

Page 307: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

1.94 million cubic metres.8’ As a result of these changes,

official log production in 1992 was 1.4 million cubic metres, 26

percent lower than 1991; total government timber revenue in 1992

was 467 million pesos, a 42 percent drop from 1991.82 Since 1987

DENR has not granted any new logging licences,83 and there are

apparently no plans to issue licences in the future. Instead, DENR

is promoting community-based industrial forest plantations “to

maintain wood supply and to provide alternative livelihood for wood

dependent communities.”84 As of December 1993, DENR had awarded

176 industrial forest management agreements.85

As a result of DENR’s moves to reduce legal logging, timber

operators face the constant possibility that the government will

revoke or cancel their licence with no concrete explanation. As

81Philippine Department of Environment and Natural Resources,1992 Philippine Forestry Statistics, p.xi. My sources on thenumber of timber licences and total allowable cut are somewhatinconsistent. According to Vitug, between 1987 and June 1992, DENRreduced the number of timber licence agreements from 143 to 32 andthe annual allowable cut from 6.03 million cubic metres to justover 1 million cubic metres. Vitug, The Politics of Logging,pp.59-60. Another study claims that in 1993, there were 33 timberconcessionaires with logging rights to 1.6 million hectares.Beicher and Gennino, eds, Southeast Asia Rainforests, p.37.

82Philippine Department of Environment and Natural Resources,1992 Philippine Forestry Statistics, p.xii.

83”RP losing race to save forests,” The Manila Times, 31January 1994, p.A6.

84Philippine Department of Environment and Natural Resources,State of the Philippine Environment and Natural Resources,Executive Summary Press Release, received by the author, February1994, p.9.

85Priscila R. Arias, “P4.7 B for forests,” Manila Bulletin, 13January 1994, p.7.

297

Page 308: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

one study notes: “The national government.. .has the tendency to

cancel leases on areas peremptorily, sometimes without due process.

Many TLA holders continually fear the cancellation of their leases

as political circumstances change, with the consequent loss of

their fixed investments in processing plants, infrastructure, and

forest development in their areas.”86 As in the past, this induces

timber operators to extract logs as fast as possible. In this

context, loggers routinely ignore silvicultural treatments,

enrichment planting, and selective logging rules.87 While poor

management of legal concessions is certainly a problem, as the

government cuts the number of licences, illegal logging is an even

greater factor driving contemporary deforestation.

C. Illegal Logging

Illegal loggers -- in cahoots with politicians, military

leaders, police officers, and bureaucrats -- are chopping down the

few remaining primary forests and destroying the National Parks and

wildlife sanctuaries.88 Although illegal logging is often blamed

86Garrity, ICummer, and Guiang, “The Philippines,” p. 608.

87Cancelling concession licences does not automatically improvetimber management. It is also crucial for the state to protectabandoned concessions. A recent study found that many cancelledconcessions in the Philippines were destroyed by small-scaleillegal loggers and slash-and-burn farmers. Rudy A. Fernandez,“Total log ban cannot stop forest denudation,” The Philippine Star,10 January 1994, p.1, p.5.

88lnterview, College of Forestry, University of the Philippinesat Los Banos, 1 February 1994; Interview, Program Director, DENR,Quezon City, 3 February 1994; and Belcher and Gennino, eds,Southeast Asia Rainforests, p.36. In some cases -- such as inQuezon -- the military simply extracts logs. See Rita Villadiego,

298

Page 309: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

on destitute villagers, in many cases influential officials and

timber company executives -- who skim most of the profits on

lucrative illegal log sales -- protect and encourage these

people.89 In Samar, even though logging was banned in 1989, timber

companies extract logs “through a web of allies ranging from

politicians to local officials and even communist rebels.”9° In

1989, a World Bank report estimated that illegal logging may be

roughly equivalent to legal logging.9’ In the same year, a Senate

committee claimed that destructive and illegal logging cost the

Philippines US$5 million every day.92 In 1991, the Economist

Intelligence Unit estimated that the Filipino illegal timber trade

was worth US$800 million a year.93 More recently, Congressman

Renato Yap claimed that illegal logs account for about half of

annual Philippine timber consumption -- estimated at 2.5 million

“Last Days of the Sierra Madre,” in Gamalinda and Coronel, eds.,Saving the Earth, pp.41-47.

89lnterview, Program Director, DENR, Quezon City, 3 February1994.

90Yabes, “Boon or Ban?” p.28. For more examples of governmentand military involvement in illegal logging, see Callister, IllegalTropical Timber Trade, pp.62-64.

9tSunimarized in Boyce, The Philippines, p.234. Also see RhonaMahony, “Debt-for-Nature Swaps: Who Really Benefits?” Ecologist 22(May/June 1992), p.101.

92Summarized in Callister, Illegal Tropical Timber Trade, p.58.

93Summarized in Dudley with Stolton, The East Asian TimberTrade, p.29.

299

Page 310: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

I-SI

H CD U) -0

0

C

HO rt I—

I

Hz 0 pi H

irt CD

o

H 0 tQ CD ‘1 U) H w U) H-

H pJ HI

CD H-

H 2)

CD

H-H

CD

rtrq

CD

HO

<9J

OC

D2)

<‘t5

H9

)U

)çt 2)o

H-H

CD

CH

HP

JII

P)

H-e

db

OP

)H

QC

tH(-

QC

DC

FH

U)

HH

-<H

-CD

CD

CD

--

H-

CDU

)H

IiH0 C

t0C

t0

Ho

HH

l(C

DH

HC

t0C

DH

-rt

HL

QU

)C

DH

.0

CD

Q-

PJ•U

)C

D’

CDH

-2)

30<

0

IH-H

iH-

0JI-jC

D

IH

OH

H-C

DH

IP

)hH

-L

H-

H-

zC

tI

CD

Ct2

)c-t

Ct

CD

OIU

)p)C

DU

)Ct

‘U)

IC

t0

IH

-0

IH<

-IH

O0CD

0I(

p)[1H

i

IrtC

DCD

Hi

IHIH

CD

CD

IH-C

DC

DU

)çtH

i0

-IH

.HC

tb

iU)

zH

i-

U)C

DU

)CD

CD

0I(Q

.11

0’

ICD

PJ’

<Ii

to<

2)

Ct

H-

HH

CD0

(D

3U

)U

)H

HC

t

CD

CtH

3Li

U)jJQ

:x”o

°U)

0P

)yC

tCD

H-

CDC

tp.

HH

H-

NU)

ICD

CDU

)9

Jh

çt

h

•C

t0

H-

Hçil

pj

CDI

‘..O

HH

H2)

WH

CD

Hd

U)I

HC

DC

t2)

-H

IH1-P

tcz,C

tIP

)

CtC

DCD

H2

)0CD

CDU

)IHI

-II

HII

CD

CiH

-CtH

-0

0frt

11

HF—

iW

(PH

•(P

HH

-I

O12)<

CD

Ct

HC

t.

‘dH

CD

L‘1

2)

[0-U

)i)Q

h’

WO

CD

WU

)0

CtH

<H

i•H

HH

HL

iQ

)C

-H

‘d()

1xj

H0

U)0

02)

03

0I-

H-

00

cuLQ

(QU)

-U)

(Q0

U)<1

[1(.Q

t-QH

-(.1

Ct

(-Q<

H-

H-

0L

H-

CDH

-CD

HCD

C)H

-CD

H-

3H

CDH

-C)

HI-

9)U)

j0

C)‘1

CDH

-U

)9)

1U)

9)t-

CDU)

C)U)

9)(.Q

H-

--

H-

U)h

•H

-U)

QH

CDHI

2)U)

CDH

-C

tH

ici

j9)

HCD

0C

t0

0H

-CD

ç-t

-C

9)CD

H-

0H

3ii

IIU)

LiC

tCD

dH

Ct

<Z

0H

ci

00

Ct

QH

-0

CDLC

)H

CDH

-CD

Hi

C)H

Hi

0CD

H-

0o

0i-

9)H

H<

U)rt

Hi

CD0

U)9)

0<

CD

Cr

CDH

i0

H-

0

CH

-h

1H

-H

H-

Ct

Hçt

U)U)

‘1H

-c

-<CD

Ct

U)0tI)°.

HC

tCD

09)

CDH

-H

-I

U)CD

HC

tCD

<I

CDCD

H<

H-

H-

H-

Ct

9)0

CD0

U)9)

0H

-II

HH

-H

9)j

CDJ

CD9)

0tj

U)o

9U)

CC

tL

3tS

pCD

H-

Ct

LCCD

U)H

-:i

HCD

Li k<

Hi

Ct

9jCD

:0

CD‘1

Ct

CDH

-h(

(Pci

2)H

CD<

0U)

0C

tU)

00

LJ

k<CD

9’CD

9’II

0CD

‘1II

00

:iCD

CD(I)

<CD

CDci

iH

iH

t(0

<U)

ciCD

-0

H-

CDi

U)

Hi

Ct

Ct

U)C

tCD

Hi

0

9)H

iC

t:J

0ci

0H

i‘1

CD9)

‘10

CD-

ci

U)I-

HH

0C

tH

iC

t

Ct

9)U)

-C

tU)

0i.

<CD

H-

CD0

9)9)

0CD

Ct

0U)

H-

CDH

U)0

Hi

Qci

U)CD

HH

H0

Hi

CDH

-°‘

H-

9)<

Hi

9)1

0CD

Ct

bH

-0

0CD

iP

HH

-0

H0

U)0

Hci

0C

HIr

jH

-C

t2)

0(1)

HH

-CD

2)H

-U)

=H

-0

CDH

CD0

CDH

ciH

HH

CDH

CDU)

U]

,‘

HC

tCD

1H

(C

tCD

hII

CDF-

’-H

i9)

<CD

IQ9)

9)0

(QCD

H9)

CH

H-

I-’0

9)H

0CD

9)U)

HH

U)H

iH

-ci

0ci

H

Page 311: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

to logging companies -- candidly admits that “there are violations

which could not be avoided because regulations of the Department of

Environment and Natural Resources are difficult to comply with.

Sawmill operators may lose money if they follow DENR rules to the

letter. 1199

Since 1986 the government has tried to curb illegal logging.

DENR has cancelled concessions, confiscated illegal logs,

strengthened laws, and prosecuted cases. In 1987, to increase

state capacity to monitor illegal logging, the government began

rewarding informers 30 percent of the value of seized logs.100 In

early 1994, the Presidential Anti-Crime Commission and DENR

established a special task force to tackle “big-time” illegal

loggers.’0’ Before 1987, no one had been convicted of illegal

logging; yet by the middle of 1991, 28 people had been convicted,

including city councillors, and the wife of a senior military

officer. 102

Despite these moderate results, pervasive links between local

DENR officers and timber operators continue to undermine the

state’s ability to halt illegal logging. From 1987 to 1992, the

99Quoted in Red Batario, “The Pillage of Isabela,” in Gamalindaand Coronel, eds., Saving the Earth, pp.37-38. For a descriptionof links between loggers and local politicians in Isabela, seeIbid., pp.37-40.

‘°°Debora MacKenzie, lluphjll battle to save Filipino trees,”Scientist, 30 June 1988, p.43.

‘°‘Rey Arquiza, “PACC forms task force to go after illegalloggers,” The Philiptine Star, 2 January 1994, p.1, p.5.

‘°2For more details, see Callister, Illegal Tropical TimberTrade, pp.66-67.

301

Page 312: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

government investigated 443 cases of improprieties at DENR -- 50

officials were disciplined; six were fired.’°3 Local enforcement

officers routinely ignore and even assist illegal logging..’04 In

Cagayan, the former regional director of DENR, Rogelio Bagayan,

concedes that: “We have problems of collusion [between government

officials and loggers]; we have to transfer staff or force them

out.”°5 In 1990, DENR punished or relocated local forestry

officers in Isabela after an undercover team found strong evidence

of collaboration between illegal loggers and provincial DENR

officials. After this crackdown, illegal logging was temporarily

reduced -- but by early 1991, “illegal logging activities [had]

resumed with a vengeance.”06 According to Senator Heherson

Alvarez, “it is very difficult to enforce [laws in Isabela] because

everybody is involved.”07 Local DENR officials -- linked to

timber-based patron-client networks -- have also undercut central

DENR investigations. For example, in 1992, after a successful

government raid of Super Mahogany Plywood Corporation, local DENR

‘°3v±tug, The Politics of Logging, pp.48-49. According to onereport, in 1993 alone, there were around 1,800 corruption casesfiled against DENR officials. “RP losing race to save forests,” TheManila Times, 31 January 1994, p.A6.

‘°4”PNP to go after loggers in Basilan,” The Manila Times, 31January 1994.

‘°5Quoted in Robles, “Logging and Political Power,” p.22.

106Batario, “The Pillage of Isabela,” p.35. Batario -- a memberof this undercover team -- claims that loggers harassed and triedto bribe the team. After menacing threats, the team leader --

Francis Altarejos -- sought refuge in the United States in 1990.Ibid.

‘°7lbid., p.36.

302

Page 313: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

allies apparently tampered with crucial evidence.’08 Of course,

not all DENR officials are ‘corrupt’ or members of patron-client

networks. Some are competent, idealistic and work hard for the

state (which presumably supports better timber management). These

officials, however, face grave dangers from other state officials

as well as powerful economic elites. In 1993 alone, 10 DENR

officials and employees were apparently killed by illegal

loggers 109

To sever links between local DENR officials and timber

operators, DENP. Secretary Alcala has suspended and reshuff led

personnel. This has created a backlash from recalcitrant

departmental staff. In late 1993, the Ombudsman began

investigating graft and corruption charges against Alcala and

Undersecretary Ben Malayang III. These charges -- levelled by a

former DENR assistant Secretary who Alcala fired for anomalies in

the campaign to halt illegal logging -- are apparently part of a

campaign to topple Alcala.”° In February 1994, the DENR Employees

Union called for Alcala’s resignation, arguing he had destroyed

morale and abused his authority.” As a result of this internal

‘°8Vitug, The Politics of Logging, pp.117-118.

‘°9”RP losing race to save forests,” The Manila Times, 31January 1994, p.A6.

‘10According to these charges, Alcala appointed his daughter,a son-in-law, and a brother-in-law to DENR positions. BobbyTimonera, “Alcala, DENR exec face graft charges,” The PhilippineInquirer, 23 October 1993, p.1, p.11.

“DENR men seek ouster of Alcala,” The Manila Bulletin, 5February 1994, p.12.

303

Page 314: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

resistance, Alcala has made only incremental progress in weakening

links between timber operators and DENR staff.

Besides ties between forestry officials and timber operators,

remote concessions and a lack of institutional resources further

hampers DENR’s ability to curb illegal logging. Monitoring illegal

logging is exceedingly difficult. The Philippines has only 4000

forest guards.”2 Palawan -- which contains one-third of the

remaining primary forests -- has just 135 guards. Enforcement

problems have increased even more since the closure of U.S.

military bases.”3 The navy is unable to patrol the jagged

coastline. Even when surveillance units pinpoint smugglers, by the

time the navy reaches the site it is often too In

Cagayan, DENR has “neither the helicopters nor boats to conduct

patrols with and soldiers who are supposed to enforce the law often

connive with loggers.”5 In Samar, DENR has “no guns, no radios,

no boats, and only 250 guards to roam the jungles, where they are

usually terrorized by armed men or rebels.” In Bukidnon, DENR

officials confessed in 1989: “We are unable to control the illegal

112Vitug, The Politics of Logging, p.67.

“3The 10,000 hectare primary forest at the former Americannaval base in Subic Bay, Luzon, has been one of the best protectedareas in the Philippines. But since the withdrawal of U.S. forces,it is unclear whether the Philippine state can keep illegal loggersout of this forest. “Manila fears it cannot protect rich Subicforest,” New Straits Times, 26 April 1992, p.14.

“4lnterv±ew, Consultant to DENR and World Bank, Quezon City,3 February 1994.

115Quoted in Robles, “Logging and Political Power,” p.24.

“6Yabes, “Boon or Ban?” p.29.

304

Page 315: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

loggers. i,117

DENR is also unable to trace the volume of logs extracted and

compare this with allowable cuts. To monitor harvests, DENR issues

a Certificate of Timber Origin. There are two serious problems

with these Certificates. One, companies bribe officials to ignore

or alter certificates. Two, companies duplicate certificates which

are then stamped by local DENR officials. Without a computerized

system, DENR cannot trace these documents.”8 An additional

problem is DENR’s reliance on timber companies to provide

transportation, and accommodation, and in some cases, protection

from surprise attacks by the communist New People’s Army (NPA) h19

These close ties to timber companies subvert the independence and

objectivity of DENR inspectors.

D. Smuggling

Under Marcos, domestic companies -- often with the

participation or knowledge of customs officials and foreign firms

-- smuggled huge quantities of logs to the North. Former DENR

Secretary Maceda “estimated that between 1974 and 1980, US$960

117Quoted in Joy Hofer, “Up in ArmS in Bukidnon,” in Gamalindaand Coronel, eds., Saving the Earth, p.34.

“8lnterview, Consultant to DENR and World Bank, Quezon City,3 February 1994. In Isabela, to increase profits and evade forestroyalties, “loggers use fake.. .invoices.” Batario, “The Pillage ofIsabela,” p.37.

“9This is a serious problem in Isabela. Batario, “The Pillageof Isabela,” pp.36-37. In most cases, the NPA does not directlyparticipate in illegal logging, but some units do protect or taxillegal operations. See Vitug, The Politics of Logging, p.134.

305

Page 316: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

million worth of timber was smuggled out of the country by friends

and associates of President Marcos.”’2° Many illegal logs landed

in Japan. Official Japanese customs records show that in 1981

Japan imported 1.4 million cubic metres of Filipino logs; but for

the same period, according to Philippine records, only 365,441

million cubic metres were shipped to Japan.121 In 1984, Japanese

companies imported 938,000 cubic metres of Philippine logs, over

400,000 cubic metres higher than the official export quota. In

1985, 257,000 cubic metres of undocumented Filipino logs were

imported into Japan. In 1986, under the new government, the

discrepancy between Japanese import and Filipino export figures

dropped to 85,000 cubic metres. But even in 1987, after the total

ban on log exports, “35,000 cubic metres of ‘unexplained’ logs left

the Philippines for export to Japan.”22 Although it is difficult

to prove, Japanese companies likely colluded with Filipino loggers

to smuggle logs and falsify export documents.’23 Through these

practices timber operators exceeded their allowable cut, evaded

export and corporate taxes, and stashed foreign exchange earnings

‘20Summar±zed in Boyce, The Philippines, p.234.

121Norman Myers, The Primary Source: Tropical Forests & OurFuture [Updated for the l990s] (New York: W.W. Norton & Company,1992), p.109.

‘22Nectoux and Kuroda, Timber, p.72.

‘23Telephone Interview, Centre For Investigative Journalism,Manila, 31 January 1994; and Interview, College of Forestry,University of the Philippines at Los Banos, 1 February 1994.

306

Page 317: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

overseas. Today, most illegal logs are consumed in the country.124

Although some timber is smuggled overseas, especially to Taiwan,

there do not appear to be substantial shipments. It is unlikely

that Japanese trading companies are still involved in smuggling

syndicates. Potential profits are now too low to risk sabotaging

newly crafted corporate images.’25

E. Tax and Royalty Evasion

Marcos provided timber licences to key clients for a paltry

fee of one peso. For a long time, the main source of government

logging revenue from forest exploitation was based on remarkably

low royalties based on the volume extracted. In 1983, this was

only 20 pesos per cubic metre.’26 Between 1979 and 1982, the

government only collected US$170 million in export taxes and timber

royalties, a mere 11.4 percent of potential timber rents.127 The

excess profits flowed to a small elite, often linked to Marcos. In

the late 1980s, Haribon president Junie Kalaw vividly explained:

In the past 15 years we have had only 470 loggingconcessionaires. . .The average profit on logging is100,000 pesos per hectare after you’ve paid all expenses.When you total this, it would amount to about US$42billion, more than our foreign debt, that came from theforest and this money went to 470 people. The processcreated poverty for 17 million people around the forest

‘24lnterview, Program Director, DENR, Quezon City, 3 February1994.

‘25Telephone Interviews, Centre For Investigative Journalism,Manila, 31 January 1994.

‘26Nectoux and Kuroda, Timber, pp.68-69.

‘27Broado, “Incentive Policies, p.184.

307

Page 318: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

areas 128

Despite negligible forest charges, during the heyday of log

exports, Filipino companies used elaborate schemes to conceal over-

cutting and evade royalties and taxes. With the help of forestry

and customs officials, companies forged export documents, preparing

one for the foreign port (often in Japan) which stated the true

volume of timber, and one for Filipino authorities which

underdeclared the volume (often the allowable cut). The foreign

company paid a front company in Hong Kong the full value of the

timber. The Hong Kong company then paid the Filipino company the

value of the underdeclared shipment. The difference was generally

diverted to a foreign bank or used to finance overseas

operations •129

A 1989 World Bank report estimated that the Philippine

government -- through royalties and taxes -- collected only 9 to 14

percent of potential timber rent in the late i98O.’° In 1991,

forest fees were increased substantially and are now 25 percent of

market price (this includes an environmental fee of 500 pesos per

cubic metre of logs extracted, first imposed in 1990) 131 But

without better collection these higher charges will make little

‘28Quoted in Broad with Cavanagh, Plundering Paradise, p.46.

‘29Nectoux and Kuroda, Timber, p.72.

‘30Summarized in Rigoberto D. Tiglao, “Forest Fires,” FEER, 23March 1989, p.13.

‘31Ph±lippine Department of Environment and Natural Resources,State of the Philippine Environment and Natural Resources,Executive Summary Press Release, p.6.

308

Page 319: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

difference. Since 1986, tax evasion has continued to be an acute

problem. According to Antonio Carpio, a key anti-corruption

activist in the Ramos government, tax evaders are disabling

economic development and driving the deficit. One company alone --

Fortune Tobacco under the control of beer and tobacco billionaire

Lucio Tan -- avoided paying 7 billion pesos in taxes from 1986 to

1993 132

F. Log Export Restrictions, Logging Bans, and Processing Policies

Unlike in Indonesia, where strong political will and business

cooperation created a stringent log export ban, in the Philippines,

strong societal resistance, weak state capacity, and diluted and

inconsistent direction from top state leaders have distorted and

delayed policies to restrict log exports, ban logging, and promote

domestic processing. In 1973, the Marcos government announced a

log export ban to be phased in over three years. This was never

enforced and in 1975 Marcos proclaimed a selective log export ban.

This selective ban enabled Marcos to award timber clients with

export quotas and deny smaller and recalcitrant companies log

export profits. It also fostered widespread illegal logging and

smuggling as companies skirted these new regulations.’33

In 1986, log exports were finally banned. In 1987, the

government announced it would not issue any new timber licences.

‘32Rigoberto Tiglao, “Crusader or Crook?” FEER, 12 August 1993,p.15.

‘33Hurst, Rainforest, p.l’75; and Vitug, The Politics of Logging,p.35.

309

Page 320: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

In 1989, sawn timber exports were banned; in the same year, logging

was banned in provinces with less than 40 percent tree cover, in

theory, stopping logging in 65 of 73 provinces. But as one report

bluntly stated: “None of these bans have been enforced.”34 In

1992, the government banned logging in all remaining primary

forests. But like so many government initiatives, the state has

been unable to enforce this law. Since 1986, there have also been

numerous unsuccessful Congressional attempts to pass a total ban on

logging. Yet even if a total ban is eventually passed -- if

previous selective bans are any indication -- this will have little

impact on the rate of destructive logging.

The Marcos administration provided incentives to process logs.

Although processed wood production increased, these policies

protected small, inefficient plywood, veneer, and saw mills.’35

The value of processed wood exports (mainly sawn timber and

plywood) reached $317 million in 1979. However, by 1982 exports

had dropped and the number of plants had decreased -- sawmills from

325 to 190, plywood mills from 209 to 35, and veneer mills from 23

to 11.136 At the end of the Marcos era, processed wood exports

were still quite low. In 1986, the Philippines exported 495,000

cubic metres of sawn timber, 256,000 cubic metres of plywood, and

‘34Belcher and Gennino, eds, Southeast Asia Rainforests, p.37.

135Plywood and veneer mills were particularly inefficient.Broado, “Incentive policies,” p.195.

‘36Repetto, The Forest For the Trees?, p.64.

310

Page 321: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

50,000 cubic metres of veneer.’37 Today, the Philippines does not

have a major wood processing industry. In 1992, total sawn timber

production was 647,000 cubic metres, an 11 percent decrease from

1991. Of this, companies exported around 56,000 cubic meters,

worth US$14.5 million. In the same year, 42 plywood mills produced

331,000 cubic metres and 13 veneer plants manufactured 79,700 cubic

metres 138

G. Local Power and Forest Management

In 1992, local governments were allocated more powers,

including powers to manage forests. Since forest degradation

directly affects villagers, decentralized control could potentially

improve management. The author of the new Local Government Code,

Aquilino Pimentel, argues that “resistance from local environmental

groups will make local officials think twice. This will affect

their votes.. .It is easier to monitor corruption on a local level.

In the national office, the official hides in the bowels of the

bureaucracy.”39 But Pimentel may be overly optimistic. Already

there are signs that local leaders are using their new powers to

distribute patronage. Vitug claims that “among some NGO5,

especially those that work with community-managed forests, there is

a downcast feeling. They are apprehensive that some politicians

‘37FA0 data, in Nectoux and Kuroda, Timber, p.115.

‘38Phil±ppine Department of Environment and Natural Resources,1992 Philippine Forestry Statistics, p.xii.

‘39vitug, The Politics of Logging, p.189.

311

Page 322: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

will recklessly issue stewardship contracts and permits to cut

trees to favoured supporters. The field is wide open to abuse.lh4O

Community involvement is clearly vital for effective management.

But it is equally apparent that effective checks must be placed on

self-interested local patrons and clients.

H. Conservation, Reforestation, and Tiniber Plantations

Until 1986, conservation and reforestation policies were

largely ineffective. A 1988 study showed that the Bureau of Forest

Development -- which claimed that it had reforested 272,000

hectares -- only successfully replanted 70,000 hectares)4’ In

1986, the Philippines began a National Forestation Program (NFP) to

replant 1.4 million hectares by the end of the year 2000. The goal

is to reforest an annual average of about 100,000 hectares.

Initial progress was slow: in 1986, 33,000 hectares were

reforested; in 1987, 40,000 hectares; in 1988, 64,000 hectares. In

September 1988, DENR began implementing the ADB-OECF First Forestry

Sector Program Loan and reforestation accelerated.142 According to

DENR, 190,000 hectares were reforested in 1990, dropping to around

‘40Ibid.

‘41Philippine German Forest Resources Inventory Project, Surveyof Government Reforestation Proiects (Quezon City: ForestManagement Bureau, Department of Environment and Natural Resources,1988), summarized in Korten, “Environmental Loans,” pp.8-9.

‘42Tolentino, Dionisio S. Jr., Philippine National ForestProgram Steering Committee Chairman, Presented, “The NationalForestation Program: A review of Lessons and Experiences andFormulation of Action Plans,” PENRO/CENRO Convention, Quezon City,November 26 1992, (revised to include data as of December 1992),p.1.

312

Page 323: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

93,000 hectares in 1991, and about 40,000 hectares in 1992. As of

1992, in total just over 1,350,000 hectares had been replanted.

The government reforested almost 950,000 hectares, timber

concessionaires accounted for just over 310,000 hectares, and

private sector organizations planted the rest.’43

Since the late 1980s, DENR has promoted forestry management at

the local level -- to encourage communities and NGOs to participate

as managers as well as to monitor and enforce rules. There have

been, however, serious difficulties. The government has had

problems persuading local people -- especially marginal forest

dwellers -- to participate since ‘results’ are often far in the

future. As well, leases have been too short and there has been

little long-term money to maintain and protect reforested areas.

Even more troublesome, reforestation has been undercut by patron

clientelism. While discussing DENR’s reforestation efforts during

his term, former DENR Secretary Factoran admitted that: “We had to

make a political decision. We chose to distribute reforestation

funds to congressional districts to make congressmen cooperate.”

As well, NGOs and ‘community groups’ have formed spontaneously to

take advantage of the funding; there has been wide evidence of

abuse.’45 DENR officials and local politicians who syphon funds

‘43Philippine Department of Environment and Natural Resources,1992 Philippine Forestry Statistics, Table 1.07, p.26.

‘Quoted in Vitug, The Politics of Logging, p.61.

‘45lnterviews, Department of Forest Resources, University of thePhilippines at Los Banos, 2 February 1994; Program Director, DENR,Quezon City, 3 February 1994; and DENR National ForestationDevelopment Office, Quezon City, 3 February 1994.

313

Page 324: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

have also undermined reforestation. DENR officials have been

linked to ‘ghost’ reforestation sites, accepting bribes and gifts

from contractors, and demanding a percentage of profits from

reforestation contractors.’46 During Factoran’s term as DENR

Secretary (1986-1992), “about 15 percent of the funds spent [on

reforestation] may have gone to the pockets of some DENR officials,

politicians and parties contracted to reforest.”47

DENR is now trying to improve reforestation. The most

important initiative is the Second Forestry Sector Program (1993-

1995) which attempts to build on the lessons and successes of the

First Forestry Sector Program (1988-1992) 148 The Second Forestry

Sector Program is funded by an ADB US$100 million project loan and

US$29 million from the Philippine government. Since this is a

project loan, the ADB approves all sub-projects.’49 By 1995, this

program aims to develop 93,000 hectares of community forests,

55,000 hectares of integrated reforestation sites, and 22,000

hectares of critical watershed restoration. Under this program,

DENR only grants reforestation contracts to local residents. These

‘46Priscila R. Arias, “DENR officials suspended,” ManilaBulletin, 21 January 1994, p.1, p.8.

147Vitug, The Politics of Logging, pp.60-61.

‘48For details on the new policy guidelines, see Tolentino, “TheNational Forestation Program, pp.7-12.

‘49Rosario N. Banzon, “Loan II For The Forestry Sector,” NEBulletin: The Official Newsletter of the National ProgramCoordinating Office 3, no. 2 (November 1992), p.7. The ADB’s othermajor reforestation initiative -- the First Forestry Sector ProgramLoan -- was policy based, dispersing funds when the government metcertain policy conditions. Interview, Senior officer, AsianDevelopment Bank, Manila, 4 February 1994.

314

Page 325: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

are long-term agreements designed to encourage villagers to plant

various indigenous species. To discourage fraudulent NGOs from

taking advantage of reforestation contracts, NGO5 are compensated

for services to local contractors. The fund is also designed to

protect 800,000 hectares of primary forests.’5°

THE PHILIPPINES AND JAPAN’S SHADOW ECOLOGY

The North has expedited large-scale logging in the Philippines

since the Spanish colonial period. During the 17th and 18th

centuries, Cebu was logged extensively to build Spanish galleons.

During the 2merican colonial period log extraction increased,

driven in part by mer±can technology, advice, financing and market

demand. After WWII, Northern investment, technology, and trade

further facilitated and accelerated destructive logging.15’

Japanese log purchases were a particularly virulent force, although

‘50Besides improving community reforestation and protection forprimary forests, DENR is also working on a new forestry code,better NGO participation, incentives for private forest managers,implementing the Master Plan For Forestry Development, improvingwatershed management, increasing interagency coordination, andenhancing information flows and forestry education. See Ito N.Banzon, “What Loan II holds in store,” NFP Bulletin: The OfficialNewsletter of the National Program Coordinating Office 3, no. 2(November 1992), p.11; and Philippine Department of Environment andNatural Resources, National Forestation Office, A Primer On TheCommunity-Based Forest Management Proiect (Manila: DENR, undated).(Somewhat confusingly, the Community-Based Forest ManagementProject is a second name for the Forestry Sector Program). Fordetails on the Master Plan For Forestry Development, see PhilippineDepartment of Environment and Natural Resources, Asian DevelopmentBank and Finnish International Development Agency, Caring for theForest to Safeguard the Future: Master Plan For ForestryDevelopment (Pasay City: RIVELISA Publishing House, August 1992).

‘51Broado, “Incentive policies,” p.174.

315

Page 326: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

Japanese money and technology were also important.

A. Japanese Investment and Technology

Japanese investment surged during martial law. In December

1973, Japan and the Philippines signed the Treaty of Amity,

Commerce and Navigation. From almost no investment prior to 1972,

by 1978 Japan accounted for 21 percent of all Philippine

investments approved by the Central Bank.’52 After the rapid

appreciation of the yen following the Plaza Agreement in 1985,

Japanese investment soared worldwide. In the Philippines, from

1985 to 1990 Japanese investment increased 891 percent, from

US$25.9 million to US$256.7 million.’53 Despite these substantial

increases, in the early 1990s, the Philippines still accounted for

less than 1 percent of total Japanese investment.154 Japanese

investors are wary of political instability, unreliable power

supplies, inadequate infrastructure, and rampant crime. In 1991,

Japanese companies invested US$203 million in the Philippines,

compared to US$1.19 billion in Indonesia, US$925 million in Hong

‘52Wurfel, Filipino Politics, p.200; also see Edberto M.Villegas, Japanese Economic Presence in Southeast Asia (Manila:IBON Philippines, Databank and Research Center, 1993), p.59. Fora critical study of Japan’s economic impact in the Philippines, seeRenato Constantino, The Second Invasion: Japan in the Philippines(Quezon City: Karrel, Inc., 1989). For a critique of Japan’scorporate environmental practices in the Philippines, see MasakiYokoyama, “Not in Our Backyard: Exporting Pollution to thePhilippines,” AMPO Japan-Asia Quarterly Review 23, no. 3 (1992),pp.24-27.

‘53villegas, Japanese Economic Presence, pp.61-62.

‘54Reg±nald Chua, “Philippine uncertainties keep Tokyo investorson the sidelines,” Straits Times, 18 October 1992, p.5.

316

Page 327: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

Kong, US$880 million in Malaysia, and US$807 million in

Thailand.’55

Direct Japanese investment was less important in triggering

the Filipino logging boom in the 1960s than the Indonesian boom in

the 1970s. In the case of the Philippines, American companies --

such as Weyerhauser and Georgia-Pacific -- provided much of the

advice and equipment necessary for large-scale logging during the

1950s.’56 Nevertheless, Japanese companies were still a key force

driving extraction. To guarantee log supplies -- yet minimize

risks and maintain a low profile -- many Japanese companies

provided credit in exchange for logs or held minority shares in

local Philippine companies.’57 These arrangements accelerated

destructive logging. According to Suzuki,

In cases where the Philippine side could not supplyenough capital to make up 60 percent, the Japanese sidewould provide the difference through the back-door...These back-door funds often accounting for as much as 30percent of the total, could not be insured. As a resultthe Japanese side endeavoured to recover the uninsuredamount as quickly as possible, contributing to the

155Meriain 0. Dacara, “Hiked Japanese aid to Manila seen,”Times Journal, 17 December 1993, p.1.

‘56R. Ludwig, “Cable Crane Yarding, An Economical andEcologically Suitable System For Commercial Timber Harvesting InLogged-Over Rainforests of the Philippines,” Philippine-GermanIntegrated Rainforest Management Project, PN 88.2047.4-01.100,Technical Report no. 2, 1992, p.1; Eduardo Tadem. “Conflict overtLand-based Natural Resources in the ASEAN Countries,” in Lim TeckGhee and Mark J. Valencia, eds., Conflict over Natural Resources inSouth-East Asia and the Pacific (Singapore: United NationsUniversity Press, 1990), p.15; and Gillis, “The Logging Industry InTropical Asia,” p.179.

‘57Nectoux and Kuroda, Timber, p.62, p.79, p.86. Also seechapters three and four.

317

Page 328: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

extremely rapid exploitation of concession areas.158

Through minority shares, Japanese investors had significant

influence over the sale and price of logs. As Nectoux and Kuroda

note, in many cases, “Japanese control of logging interests [was]

obtained not through corporate ownership, but by financing an

operation, supplying equipment, purchasing logs and controlling

export operations.”59 As with almost all timber companies in the

Philippines prior to 1986, companies with Japanese shareholders

logged areas illegally, forged export documents, ignored

silvicultural and reforestation duties, evaded royalties and taxes,

and were protected by powerful political elites.’60 Today, major

Japanese trading companies have little interest in the sparse,

inaccessible stands of commercial timber. There are some small

Japanese investors with minority shares in lumber processing,

rattan furniture, and chopstick mills.16’ But unlike in the past

-- when Japanese trading companies facilitated rapid, large-scale,

and often destructive logging in primary forests -- these investors

do not have a major impact on the overall structure or sustainable

management of the timber industry.

‘58M. Suzuki, “Notes for Tropical Rainforest Log Export SystemReport,” Tokyo, 1986, unpublished, quoted in Nectoux and Kuroda,Timber, p.68.

‘59Nectoux and Kuroda, Timber, p.86.

‘60For example, see the history of Cellophil (1972-1986), acompany which was part owned by Mitsubishi Rayon (6%), Daicel (3%)and Marcos’s client Herminio Disini. Ibid., pp.84-85.

‘61Ibid., p.86.

318

Page 329: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

B. Japanese Trade

Japan’s greatest impact on Filipino timber management has been

massive purchases of logs far below replacement or sustainable

management costs. In the 1950s and 1960s, the Philippines was the

primary source of Japanese tropical log imports. Over this period

-- as Japan used more and more dipterocarp logs to make cheap

plywood and kon pane -- wasteful Japanese consumption propelled

destructive, rapid harvests.162 In 1950, the Philippines accounted

for 93.3 percent of Japanese timber imports from Southeast Asia,

although the total volume was only 119,000 cubic metres. In 1961,

Japan imported 3.8 million cubic metres of Philippine timber,

accounting for 68.7 percent of all Southeast Asian timber imports.

In 1965, Japan imported 5.62 million cubic metres of Philippine

timber. By 1969, Japanese timber imports from the Philippines had

soared to 8.32 million cubic metres, although this now only

comprised 46.7 percent of total timber imported from Southeast

Asia. In that year, Filipino timber exports peaked at more than 11

million cubic metres.

In the early 1970s, as accessible, high-quality Filipino logs

became increasingly scarce, Japanese companies shifted to Sabah and

Indonesia. Many Filipino loggers -- in some cases financed by

Japanese companies -- also moved to Indonesia.’63 In 1971,

162Starting in 1966, Philippine mangroves -- especially fromMindanao and Palawan -- were also chipped and exported to Japan.Ibid., p.80.

163lnterview, Professor, University of the Philippines at LosBanos, 1 February 1994. From 1970 to 1990, 17 Filipino loggingcompanies invested US$279.5 million in Indonesia. For a

319

Page 330: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

Indonesia surpassed the Philippines as Japan’s key source of

tropical timber. By 1973, Indonesia and Sabah supplied almost 70

percent of Japanese timber imports from Southeast Asia. In that

year, Japan imported 6.24 million cubic metres of Philippine

timber. In 1976, Japan only imported 1.95 million cubic metres of

Philippine timber, a mere 8.7 percent of total Southeast Asian

imports. Over the next ten years, Japanese companies -- including

Nissho Iwai, Sumitomo, Marubeni, Mitsui, Mitsubishi, and Itochu --

continued to purchase Philippine timber, although far less then

during the logging boom in the 1960s.164 In 1983, Japan only

imported around 900,000 cubic metres of Philippine timber. After

the log export ban in 1986, Japanese legal imports were reduced to

small amounts of processed wood.’65

From the l950s to the mid-1980s, processed wood accounted for

a minor portion of total Japanese timber imports from Southeast

Asia. For example, in 1984 Japan only imported 151 cubic metres of

plywood from the Philippines.’66 Even after the ban on log

description of Philippine investments in Indonesia’s timberindustry, see Vitug, The Politics of Logging, pp.26-28.

164In the l960s, about 60 percent of Philippine timber exportswent to Japan; by the early 1980s, Japan only accounted for around30 percent. Boyce, The Philippines, footnote 4, p.241.

‘65unless otherwise noted, the Japan-Philippine trade data forthis section is from Isamu Nomura, “Japan: The timber trade and itsproblems,” in Andras Nagy, ed., International Trade in ForestProducts (IIASA, AB Academic Publishers, 1988), cited in Dudleywith Stolton, The East Asian Timber Trade, p.8. These figuresinclude sawnwood and logs, although the bulk of Philippine timberexports were in the form of logs.

‘66Hurst, Rainforest, p.191.

320

Page 331: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

exports, in 1990 Filipino plywood exports to Japan were still

inconsequential: 2,842 cubic metres, 0.1 percent of Japan’s total

plywood imports. By 1993, Japan imported even less, a mere 723

cubic metres of plywood, a negligible portion of Japan’s total

plywood imports of just over 4 million cubic metres (both softwood

and hardwood) •167 As a result, unlike in Indonesia, Japanese

tariff barriers on plywood have not had a major impact on Filipino

timber management.

Even though Japan no longer imports Philippine logs and only

buys a small amount of processed wood, past timber purchases far

below the costs of regeneration or sustainable management have left

deep scars that entail significant economic, social, and

environmental costs. The Philippines is now struggling to

regenerate swaths of degraded forests, and tackle concomitant

environmental disasters, including floods, soil erosion, siltation,

and rural poverty. Filipino managers cannot find the funds to

absorb all these costs and still protect the remaining primary and

secondary forests. One logical source of funds is Japanese

development assistance.

‘67Japan Plywood Manufacturers’ Association, Plywood Industryin Japan, Table 7, p..6.

321

Page 332: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

C. Japanese Forestry and ‘Environmental Aid’

Japanese aid to the Philippines increased substantially in the

1970s, providing an important financial pillar for Marcos’s

patronage network. From 1970 to 1976, Japanese development loans

swelled from 7 percent to 19 percent of total Philippine loan

assistance, rising in absolute terms from US$23.5 million to

US$308.4 million. Japan is now the largest aid donor to the

Philippines, accounting for 53.5 percent of total Philippine aid in

1991. In 1992, around 12 percent of bilateral Japanese ODA went to

the Philippines.’68 In the early 1990s, annual Japanese aid to the

Philippines was around US$1 billion.’69 Until recent OECF loans

for reforestation, Japan had made only modest contributions to the

forestry sector. From 1976 to 1992, a JICA technical cooperation

project -- the Forestry Development Project Watershed Management in

the Pantabangan area -- provided assistance with Philippine

reforestation techniques. As well, from 1985 to 1988, JICA

conducted a development study of the Cagayan River watershed to

help formulate a forest management plan. JICA also provided one

grant in 1978 (11.05 billion) and two in 1984 (11.07 billion and

1103 million) to construct forestry buildings and fight forest

fires.’7° Today, there are no JICA technical cooperation forestry

‘68Japanese Ministry of Foreign Affairs, Japan’s ODA 1993,pp.45-46.

169Meriam 0. Dacara, “Hiked Japanese aid to Manila seen,” ThTimes Journal, 17 December 1993, p.1.

‘70JICA, For Our Green Earth: Outline of JICA’s Cooperation inForestry (Tokyo: JICA, Forestry and Fisheries DevelopmentCooperation Department, July 1993), pp.21-26.

322

Page 333: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

projects in the Philippines, although a coordinator is examining

possibilities. 171

During the Aquino administration, international donors loaned

substantial sums for DENR projects to protect the environment and

rehabilitate and reforest degraded areas. Between 1979 and 1988,

the Bureau of Forest Development was the primary recipient of only

one loan and had a secondary role in eight others, in total

implementing about US$60 million. In contrast, between 1988 and

1992, DENR received loans worth over US$500 million, accounting for

a major portion of Philippine development assistance. The OECF

provided a large share of these loans. The two largest loans were

the 1988-92 Forestry Sector Program Loan from the ADB (US$120

million) and the OECF (US$120 million) and the 1991 Environment and

Natural Resources Sector Adjustment Loan (ENR-SECAL) from the World

Bank (US$224 million) and the OECF (US$100 million) •172 DENR also

implemented grants and grant-funded projects from USAID, several UN

organizations, and numerous Northern governments. To understand

‘71lnterview, Coordinator of JICA Indonesia, Jakarta, 1 March1994.

‘72Korten, “Environmental Loans,” pp.6-7, including footnote 13and footnote 53, p.27. The ENR-SECAL program has six mainobjectives: “a) design an integrated Protected Areas System; b)provide program support for management of ten priority protectedareas; c) improve the monitoring of logging operations andenforcement of forestry laws and regulations through the provisionof equipment, training and technical assistance to DENR offices...;and d) develop the capacity of LGUs [local government units) andline agencies to generate community-based resource management andlivelihood projects in watershed areas. .“ Philippine Departmentof Environment and Natural Resources, “Highlights of the ENR-SECALProgram,” DENR Policy Bulletin (February 1993), p.9. For moredetails, see Ibid., pp.9-li.

323

Page 334: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

the environmental impact of Japanese development assistance, the

next section evaluates the 1988-92 Forestry Sector Program Loan.

The Philippines now has more than 10 million hectares of

degraded forest land. To reforest this area would cost about

US$7.8 billion. The ADB/OECF Forestry Sector Program Loan was

intended to reforest 358,000 hectares over five years, “a first

step on a long and expensive journey toward restoring the nation’s

wealth.”73 The OECF accepted 1-UDB guidelines and procedures for

this loan, remaining in the background and providing yen credit.’74

Yet the OECF is still responsible for any repercussions, even if by

default. Although many of the principles and concepts behind this

loan were laudable, and while some areas were reforested, there

were significant drawbacks.

Prior to 1988, the Bureau of Forest Development had conducted

most reforestation, often hiring local residents to plant and

nurture the trees. The 1988-92 Forestry Sector Program Loan took

a different tack, using contracts to include corporate, community,

non-governmental, and family groups in managing forest areas. In

theory, contractors were paid based on the survival of their trees

-- if 80 percent of the trees survived after 3 years, then the

‘73Korten, “Environmental Loans,” p.8.

‘74lnterview, Senior officer, Asian Development Bank, Manila,4 February 1994. As noted earlier, building on lessons learnedfrom this project, the DB provided another US$100 million for theSecond Forestry Sector Program Loan (1993-1995). As of February1994, negotiations were still being conducted with the OECF tomatch this loan. Interviews, DENR, National ForestationDevelopment Office, Quezon City, 3 February 1994.

324

Page 335: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

contractor would be fully paid.175 In some cases, contractors

established effective forest plantations. Successful contractors

tended to be family contractors, genuine ‘community contractors’ (a

group of residents), or committed NGOs that worked closely with

locals 176

Despite these scattered accomplishments, numerous

reforestation sites failed. Sometimes trees died, sometimes

contractors never planted trees, and sometimes local residents

burned the area. In some cases, contractors reached less than 20

percent of their target.’77 Several studies have estimated that

after three years less than 40 percent of trees had survived. The

scope and speed of reforestation under the Forestry Sector Loan

contributed to problems, including poor supervision by DENR (which

tended to involve paperwork rather than on-site inspections),

misunderstandings, and insufficient training for contractors.178

Patron-clientelism further distorted the potential benefits of this

loan. Contractors often had few connections to the community and

local inhabitants were hired as low-wage planters instead of being

active participants. Many contractors lived in the provincial

capital; instead of links to the community, they had personal ties

175Korten, “Environmental Loans,” p.9.

‘76Ibid., p.14.

‘77lnterview, College of Forestry, University of the Philippinesat Los Banos, 1 February 1994.

‘78Contractors mostly planted a single species -- gmelinaarborea. This reduced the environmental benefits of manyplantations and made them more susceptible to disease and pests.Korten, “Environmental Loans,” pp.16-17.

325

Page 336: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

to DENR officials. Reforestation funds were used for bureaucratic

patronage and ‘corruption’ was common. DENR officials syphoned

funds by awarding reforestation contracts to ‘fictitious’

people.’79 Although perhaps somewhat exaggerated, one scholar

estimated that 60 percent of the Forestry Sector Loan was ‘lost’

and only 40 percent went into reforestation.’8°

Besides mixed environmental results, the Forestry Sector

Program Loan has major economic drawbacks. The agreement

stipulated that the loan be placed in the Central Bank to establish

a ‘peso account’ to fund DENR’s contract reforestation program.

Foreign exchange was supposed to be used to purchase essential

foreign products. However, according to Frances Korten, many

“items eligible for financing were for the use of loggers and wood

industry enterprises, some of which were the cause of the

deforestation that the loan was presumably trying to reverse.”18’

The annual interest rate for the OECF loan -- after an initial

seven year grace period -- is 2.7 percent. This must be repaid in

yen after 25 years. While on the surface these are soft terms, as

the yen appreciates, repayment will become increasingly onerous.’82

‘79lnterv±ew, College of Forestry, University of the Philippinesat Los Banos, 1 February 1994; and Sajise, et al., State of theNation Reports. Saving the Present For The Future, p.19. The‘disappearance’ of funds is not unique to the Forestry SectorProgram Loan. As noted earlier, reforestation money and contractshave become a key tool of state forestry patrons.

‘80lnterview, Department of Forest Resources, University of thePhilippines at Los Banos, 2 February 1994.

‘81Korten, “Environmental Loans,” p.24.

‘82Ibid., footnote 46, p.24.

326

Page 337: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

This expands the Filipino debt, adding even more pressure to

generate foreign exchange by exporting natural resources.’83 As

Korten notes, “lending that couples the environmental agenda with

foreign exchange. . . is likely to accelerate the very damage it is

intended to reverse.”’ While Japan considers this loan part of

its environmental aid, the concept ‘environmental loan’ is an

oxymoron.

CONCLUSION: A LOOK TO THE YEAR 2000

Politics since Marcos is remarkably similar to previous

political regimes as tenacious patron-client networks battle for

access to and control over state resources. Many timber-based

patron-client networks that dissolved in the wake of Marcos,

realigned in the Aquino years. But with less valuable commercial

timber, fewer quick profits, and greater voter concern with

environmental degradation, ties between top state leaders and

timber operators are now more tenuous and brittle. In this

setting, the state has pushed harder to tackle timber mismanagement

and rein in ‘corrupt’ state implementors. The state has cancelled,

suspended, or refused to renew many timber licences; made scattered

attempts to punish illegal loggers and their state allies; and --

with support from international donors -- increased reforestation

‘31n May 1993, the Philippine debt was US$34.3 billion.Philippine Department of Environment and Natural Resources, Stateof the Philippine Environment and Natural Resources, (Manila:Republic of the Philippines, received by author February 1994),p.2.

‘84Korten, “Environmental Loans,” p.30.

327

Page 338: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

of degraded land. Yet there are still intrinsic problems. As in

the past, as state leaders fight to maintain stability and control,

they are unable or unwilling to break pervasive clientelist ties

between local political and military leaders, middle-level state

officials, enforcement officers, and timber operators. These links

distort state policies and allow timber-based patron-client

networks to capture state bureaus, crippling state capacity to

enforce rules and collect taxes. As a result, poor logging

techniques, inadequate silvicultural treatments, extensive illegal

logging in primary forests and national parks (estimated to be

equivalent to legal production), insufficient reforestation, and

low state timber revenues continue to drive deforestation.

Post-Marcos Philippines also highlights the potent residue of

ecological shadows. Japanese trade, technology, and investment now

have little direct impact on timber management. But past Japanese

log purchases at prices far below the cost of sustainable

management have left deep scars that impair current efforts to

manage timber. Rebuilding a viable commercial timber industry will

necessitate finding the funds and means to replace lost forests

while still paying for concomitant environmental damage, including

extensive soil erosion and climate changes that reduce agricultural

productivity and produce calamitous floods. Considering the

environmental impact of Japan’s past practices, Japanese aid is a

logical source of funds. Yet there are currently no technical

cooperation projects or grants in forestry. Instead, Japan has

provided ‘environmental loans’. While these yen loans have

328

Page 339: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

supplied foreign exchange and financed a few successful

reforestation and conservation sites, there are severe problems.

In the case of the ADB-OECF First Forestry Sector Program Loan, a

large portion of the money was wasted by administrators and

contractors, or syphoned by bogus NGOs, local political and

military leaders, and DENP. officials. Moreover, the concept

‘environmental loan’ is flawed; rather than offsetting Japanese

past practices, these loans will eventually create even more

pressure to extract and export natural resources to service the

accompanying debt.

Over the last century, commercial loggers -- protected by

state patrons and driven by Japan’s shadow ecology -- have ravaged

Southeast Asia’s primary forests. In 1900, primary rain forests

covered 250 million hectares of Southeast Asia; by 1989, only 60

million hectares remained.’85 The history of timber mismanagement

in the Philippines suggests a bleak forecast for the rest of

Southeast Asia’s primary forests.’86 Japan’s shadow ecology is

‘85Mark Poffenberger, “Introduction: The Forest ManagementCrisis,” in Potfenberger, ed., Keepers of the Forest, p.xix.

‘86 is already too late for Thailand. Thai commercial loggers-- protected by state patrons and driven by Northern markets andfunding -- cleared and degraded much of the country over the lastfour decades. Largely as a result, forest cover declined from 70percent after the Second World War to 19 percent at the end of thel980s. In 1989 when logging was banned most of the best timbertracts were already exhausted. Today, timber companies survive byimporting logs from Cambodia, Burma, Laos, and Vietnam, and byextensive illegal logging in Thailand, estimated at 2.5 millioncubic metres a year. Peter Dauvergne, “The Failure of ForestryManagement in Thailand: Politics Behind Deforestation,” 1993, anunpublished paper presented at a SEADOC Seminar, Centre forSoutheast Asian Research, University of British Columbia, 27January 1993.

329

Page 340: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

pushing Borneo Malaysia and Indonesia down the Philippine path of

widespread deforestation. Poorly designed Japanese aid programs

often tied to corporate motives, inappropriate technology

transfers, short-sighted purchasing practices, and voracious

consumption have facilitated and accelerated destructive timber

extraction. As well, low purchase prices and tariff barriers to

processed wood (especially Indonesian plywood) have reduced

Southern state revenue essential for sustainable management. These

practices have left deep environmental and economic scars that

impede current efforts to fund and manage sustainable timber

operations. Problems are reinforced and exacerbated by elite

attitudes, a need to service foreign debt, and international

incentives to ‘develop’.

Besides Northern pressures, clientelist forces are also

driving Borneo Malaysia and Indonesia toward a future similar to

the Philippines. As leaders battle to survive in societal webs of

patron-client ties, clientelist networks flourish at all levels of

the state and society. These pervasive links distort state

policies, contribute to a small elite prospering from timber

profits, create complex and murky layers of subcontractors,

generate an unpredictable atmosphere that encourages quick and

destructive extraction, subvert supervision of state implementors,

and thwart state enforcement of timber regulations. Protected by

state patrons, Southeast Asian loggers damage one-third to two

thirds of the trees left after legal harvesting. Illegal logging

-- often in parks, wildlife sanctuaries and watersheds -- is an

330

Page 341: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

even greater problem. In Indonesia alone, as much as 35 million

cubic metres of illegal logs -- equivalent to the legal harvest --

are cut each year. Many of these logs are then smuggled overseas

or used by inefficient local processors. Extensive illegal logging

and smuggling decrease state revenue necessary for sustainable

management. State coffers are further plundered by timber

companies that evade remarkably low royalties and taxes. In Borneo

Malaysia and Indonesia, the state only collects a small fraction of

potential timber revenues. In addition, clientelist states and

private companies have neglected conservation and reforestation or,

as in Indonesia, the government has used ‘reforestation’ to build

immense fast-growing timber plantations.

Without radical changes to the clientelist states of Southeast

Asia or to Japan’s shadow ecology, there is no chance that

Indonesia, Sabah, Sarawak, or the Philippines will reach the ITTO

goal of sustainable timber management by the year 2000. Reforming

Southeast Asian political and social interaction is obviously a.

difficult task. As the Philippines shows, patron-client relations

are resilient; even breaking these ties at the top of the state

will not guarantee significant improvements to timber management.

Rather than navigate the treacherous shoals of possible Southern

political reforms -- a route that I believe is especially

precarious for cultural outsiders -- it is more productive, and

perhaps more feasible, if still arduous, to manipulate Northern

shadow ecologies. In theory, Northern resources can promote

sustainable management, and perhaps even undercut particularistic

331

Page 342: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

0h

PiI-

hCD

uJ(Q

cI

L(I

H0

CDH

-p.)

jc-I

-I

CDb

H-

C)i

CD0

Hc-I

-II

H-

U)CD

p.)H CD Pj

H-

0

U)z

HU)

c-I

0C)

p.)CD

c-I-

CDc-

w wH

[\)

c-I-

L

0

Hfr-

hCD

Ci)

U)0

H-

qc-

IH

P)

P.)c-I

-H

-d

çI

c-I-

P)CD

CD)

jp.)

c-I-

-C)

CDU)

p.)

CDpj

tC)

C)U)

Cl)0

H-

H-

c-I-

Hc-

I)

c-I-

QI.

<CD

LQ

I-hH

0CD

I-CU)

CDI-h

U)PJ

0c-I

-I-C

I-C0

C) CD

Page 343: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

Conclusion

JAPAN’S ECOLOGICAL SHADOW OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA

This chapter evaluates the impact of Japan’s shadow ecology of

timber in the clientelist states of Southeast Asia. I examine the

three core elements of Japan’s shadow ecology: government technical

assistance, grants, and loans; corporate investment, and technology

transfers; and trade, including corporate purchasing practices,

export and consumer prices, wasteful consumption, and import

tariffs. I outline the main trends from the 1950s to the mid

1990s, assess the repercussions of post-1990 Japanese corporate and

government overseas environmental policies, and discuss possible

reforms to encourage sustainable timber management in the South.

I argue that recent Japanese corporate and government moves to

address the environmental impact of overseas activities have not

altered the fundamental impact of Japan’s ecological shadow of

timber. Even though Japanese investment, technology, and aid now

have fewer detrimental effects on Southeast Asian timber

management, the residual and proximate repercussions of Japanese

trade continue to accelerate deforestation. Fundamental reforms to

Japan’s timber trade are essential.

The Japanese government has focused on reshaping the least

potent element of Japan’s shadow ecology -- ODA. This has

contributed to marginal improvements to ODA forestry initiatives in

Southeast Asia, particularly JICA technical cooperation projects.

Aid now concentrates less on facilitating commercial logging, and

333

Page 344: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

more on conservation, large-scale reforestation, and improving

Southern processing efficiency. But there are still serious

deficiencies. JICA and OECF environmental guidelines are vague and

non-binding. There are few JICA or QECF environmental experts, and

most aid staff have little field experience in tropical forests.

Poor coordination between Japanese ministries, aid distribution

based on Southern elite requests, informal ties to Japanese

companies, poor cooperation with NGOs, and inadequate supervision

of aid money compounds these problems. Partially as a result,

environmental reviews of forestry projects are often ineffective,

and Japanese aid -- under the guise of ‘reforestation’ -- has

supported inappropriate technology transfers and fast-growing

timber plantations. Finally, the forestry sector receives only a

small portion of environmental aid, much of which has been

misguided -- such as environmental loans to the Philippines.

While the government tinkers with aid projects, new Japanese

corporate environmental departments and guidelines, and revised

rules to integrate environmental factors into corporate decisions

have produced more sophisticated rhetoric and token forestry

conservation projects, but few concrete changes to business

practices. Both Japanese companies and powerful government

departments ignore or superficially address the critical factors

driving Southeast Asian deforestation: wasteful consumption of

tropical timber from unsustainable sources; timber prices far below

replacement or sustainable management costs; import tariffs that

syphon Southern revenues essential for sustainable management; and

334

Page 345: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

residual effects that leave Southern governments struggling to find

the funds to cope with a plethora of environmental and economic

problems.

Japan has the potential to facilitate sustainable management

rather than accelerate destructive logging. But considerable

reforms are necessary. The Japanese government must accept

responsibility for past environmental practices, and restructure

and increase the amount of environmental aid. Japanese consumers

must use less and pay more for tropical timber. These additional

revenues must be transferred to sustainable Southern timber

concessions. Japanese companies and the Japanese government must

avoid intentional or inadvertent policies and practices that

undercut Southern state capacity to collect revenues, enforce

regulations, and manage environmental problems. And once bilateral

or multilateral mechanisms are built to determine ‘sustainable’ and

‘unsustainable’ timber, Japanese companies must limit timber

purchases, investments, credit lines, and technology transfers to

sustainable concessions.

JAPANESE TECHNICAL ASSISTANCE, GRANTS, LOANS AND TROPICAL FORESTS

Under pressure from the international community, Japan rapidly

increased the quantity of ODA in the l970s and 1980s. Today, Japan

is the world’s largest bilateral aid donor and the major

contributor to the Asian Development Bank. This aid has provided

vital scientific and technical assistance to many Southern

countries. But while Japanese aid has certainly provided benefits,

335

Page 346: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

bH

ci

HLi

MCD

CUCD

MM

icc

H-

piU)

PH

U)O

CDc

Li0

CU0

0U)

I-’

<Pi

00

LiLi

CDCl)

3o

cc()

Hc-

ti-

‘-rJ

U)c-

IIM

iQ

C)M

ifJ)

LiCU

0Cl)

Cl)C)

Cl)0

0CD

Mi

1Li

H-

LiH

-0

U)C

DI-I

CT)C)

hH

-U)

QP

LiLi

IIu

CDCD

H-

CLi

Ct

U)CD

CDH

CDU)

CC

UC

UC

UU)

U)H

Hi

CL)

U)CD

çU)

H-

U)-

H H-

I-

H-

00

CDH

U)-

U)U)

CUCD

P-’ii

piq

H’

OH

-U

c-I.

H’

cc

U)C

DO

QCD

H-

HH

-U)

LiLi

0c-

HC

U,

LiCD

-4H

-(I)

P1P

CDLi

cH

ccU)

CU-

CUCD

Li0

Li0C

DG

’Cl)

-c-i

-CU

,CU

LiH

-i

DH

-H

Hcc

CDLi

U)CU

U)CD

ciH

-0

CDCU

CDLi

U)U)

cc

Li

CDLi

LiCD

CUH

-

LiU)

0U)

ci HH

-Li

H0

CDpi

C)CU

CU HH

U)C

t0

CDCt

-

CDCU

Lipi

0L

iL

CDCD

LiH

’CD

8P11

LQc-

cCU

LU)

CDLi

piCD

CD

LiCU

piH

110

•H

CUCD

Do

LQU)

H-

H-

OLi

Hi

LQCD

PCD

Licc

LQCD

CDU)

QP1

LiO

Mi

H’

EDLi

ID0

cc

CUU)

11cc

0CD

CUH

-H

HCD

CUCU

HU)

P1CD

CL)0

Cl)

o

c-V CU

11

(CD

CULi

CD

CD

H-

Li

CDLi

CD-I

CDLi

H-

Lip

UL

iCI

011

H-

H-

CULi

C)CU

H’

lji

0IQ

0.Q

LiP

Hi

c-cP1

Hi

Lio

Li11

U)11

0Li

H-

U)P1

CDCD

0U)

Hç-

tc-c H

’M

iLi

cLi

LiCU

CDH

iC)

,Li

aCU

H-

HCU

HCU

LiH

-H

-H

H0

p111

Licc

I-ti H-

CD0

0CD

C<

CD0

Liii

H-

tc-

H-

CU0

ccLi

U)H

-CD

HC)1C

DH

Mi

CDH

CUc-c

c’C)

Cl)-

CDC

tH

-0

CDII

I-’-

0H

Cl)c

IICD

CDLi

U)CU

CD

Li

OH

Hcc

HCD

CD0

c-t

CUI-I

HI-I

ci

H-

Mi

Mi

ID0

CD1L

i3

CDLi

(1)CU

ciLi

Lij

c‘tS

P1M

i0

cic1

CDCD

t-U)

Qp1

CDCD

I-Io

U)CD

Mi

oH

i11

H-

U)cc

CU<

&0L

i•

Mi

ccLi

I-I

HH

CDi-

CD0

CDLi

CUCD

Ip

LiCD

CU11

U)ID

U)CD

CDc-V

CDCD

CDC

CDLi

H-

Lio

LiH

P1CD

U)<

U)P1

LCCD

HH

-Li

cc

U)I))

CD‘-‘i

ccCU

c-c

U)CD

JD

cc

LiU)

LiH

pC

DH

-H

-Li

LiU)

U)CU

<H

c-c

ICH

LiU)

011

CDH

-M

iH

U)CD

,q

H-

CU HIL

ici

HQ

H-ID0

ciU)

CDt--

Nc-

CUCU

0Li

LiLi

Licc

CDC)

IH

-•C

DL

iU)

U)II

CUP1

Hi

C)CU

CUci

CDj

CU)

z<

U)—

.)H

C)

c-VCD

0C

U)Li

1111

<cc

HO

CLi

iH

CDCD

110

Li’

110

I-’-

0CD

CU•ciL

ici,

CDp

U)

P1P1

CDII

II

i.

CDH

-Li

CH

-—

.p1

I-IU)

C)b’

H-

LiCD

Ci)U)

LiC)

CD

CDct

cc0

Ct

Mi

p1c-

cLi

’II

LiC)

ccCU

C)H

-CD

CDCD

LiH

-U)

U)CD

0(.Q

CDU)

CU0

IICU

CDLi

c-ci

C)CU

P1-

ccC

)-•

0CD

-P

IIC

-<-

U)1d

LiH

U)0

Li’

LiU)

Li

Page 347: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

intergovernmental OECF loans funded infrastructural projects

essential for logging and massive log exports; and OECF loans to

Japanese companies offset risky timber investments.

Since the early 1990s, fewer JICA intergovernmental forestry

cooperation projects are linked to commercial loggers or securing

wood imports. More projects now stress regenerating degraded

forests, conserving rain forests, and developing social and

community forestry.4 JICA has also changed the emphasis of

forestry loans to Japanese corporations. From 1974 to 1994, JICA

provided 144 soft loans to Japanese companies investing in the

South. Of these, 51 were forestry projects: 15 in Indonesia; 1 in

Limbang, Sarawak; and 6 in the Philippines.5 In the past, many of

these loans funded fast-growing monoculture tree plantations. NGOs

and environmentalists criticized these projects for ignoring

indigenous people’s rights, clearing natural forests, and providing

minimal environmental benefits. According to a senior JICA

official, in an effort to appease these critics, JICA now ensures

that concessional loans only fund plantations in degraded areas.

JICA also encourages companies to plant a variety of endemic

4lnterviews, Senior official, Forestry Cooperation Division,JICA, Tokyo, 12 April 1994; and Senior official, InternationalForestry Cooperation Centre, Forestry Agency, Ministry ofAgriculture, Forestry and Fisheries, Tokyo, 19 April 1994. Socialforestry projects emphasize broad social aspects, while communityforestry projects tend to be small, community-based projects.

5This data was provided by an official at the ForestryCooperation Division, JICA, Tokyo, 12 April 1994.

337

Page 348: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

species to foster bio-diversity.6 In addition, to facilitate

corporate participation in forestry conservation, JICA recently

established an Environmental Protection Credit Line. Loans will

supposedly reforest degraded areas; protect watersheds and primary

forests; and support social and community forestry projects.7

Despite these apparent improvements, JICA’s forestry and

environmental projects still have significant problems. JICA’s

guidelines and procedures for pre-and-post-project environmental

reviews are vague and inconsistent. Projects still fund technology

transfers with little institutional support - - in some cases, the

equipment never leaves the box.8 As Forrest notes, instead of

promoting conservation, Japan “transfers high-technology equipment,

ensuring lucrative profits for Japanese companies.”9 As well, JICA

still supports dubious reforestation techniques in Southeast Asia,

particularly fast-growing eucalyptus and acacia mangium

plantations.’° In Indonesia, JICA emphasizes large-scale

industrial timber estates. JICA’s last project in Sabah -- the

JICA-SAFODA Re-afforestation Technical Development and Training

Project which ended in 1994 -- provided technical support for fast

6lnterview, Senior official, Forestry Cooperation Division,JICA, Tokyo, 12 April 1994.

7Ibid.

8lnterviews, Environmental consultants, Bogor Indonesia, 24February 1994.

9Forrest, “Japanese Aid and the Environment,” pp.31-32.

‘°See Kanda, “A Big Lie: Japan’s ODA and Environmental Policy,”p.44; and Forrest, “Japanese Aid and the Environment,” p.31.

338

Page 349: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

growing acacia-mangium plantations. At present, there are no JICA

forestry projects in Sabah or the Philippines, and only one in

Sarawak, designed to improve domestic processing efficiency.

Despite the new policies, it is clear that only a negligible

portion of JICA technical cooperation actually supports social and

community forestry projects, natural forest regeneration, and

primary rain forest conservation.

Along similar lines as JICA, the OECF and the EXIM Bank have

also expanded their environmental departments and developed

procedures to consider environmental factors when evaluating loan

applications. This has contributed to more refined rhetoric, but

no obvious changes to forestry loans. Although it is difficult to

be certain since OECF and EXIM Bank environmental procedures and

evaluations are shrouded in secrecy, few loan requests seem to be

rejected for environmental reasons.’1 OECF and EXIM Bank

environmental departments appear more concerned with avoiding

scandals than promoting environmental management in the South.

General problems with Japanese ODA hinder attempts to

incorporate environmental and social factors into grants, technical

cooperation, and loans. Despite some commendable principles,

Japan’s new Environment Law and ODA guidelines are ineffective.

Numerous clauses are ambiguous and there are no concrete

enforcement mechanisms or penalties. There is also little

“At present, the EXIM Bank is not financing any loggingprojects in the Philippines, Malaysia, or Indonesia, althoughunlike the World Bank, the EXIM Bank is prepared to provide loansto tropical loggers. Interview, Senior official, EnvironmentSection, Export-Import Bank of Japan, Tokyo, 11 April 1994.

339

Page 350: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

coordination or cooperation between key ministries -- MITI, the

Ministry of Foreign Affairs, the Ministry of Finance, the Economic

Planning Agency, the Environment Agency and the Forestry Agency --

or the two implementing agencies, JICA and the OECF. Convoluted

guidelines and a fragmented aid structure impede environmental

reviews and obscure accountability. Environmental miscalculations

are further aggravated by a lack of aid staff with environmental

expertise, field experience, or in-depth knowledge of the diverse

cultures and eco-systems of insular Southeast Asia. The emphasis

on concessional loans -- which comprise over half of Japan’s ODA,

more than any other donor’s -- also thwart environmental

objectives. As the yen appreciates, repaying these loans has

become increasingly onerous. Rather than promoting environmental

protection, Southern states -- in search of foreign exchange --

turn to unsustainable natural resource exports. Japan’s request-

based aid further undermines moves to integrate environmental

objectives. Recipient countries are often ambivalent or apathetic

about environmental protection, and tend to request aid for high-

tech infrastructure projects with immediate economic returns. The

allotment of ODA funds is also poorly supervised and large chunks

have been syphoned by Southern patron-client networks.12 Finally,

effective Japanese aid projects are undermined by continuing links

to Japanese trading companies, and poor cooperation with NGOs,

‘2For example, Japanese ODA funds were apparently channelled toRamon Mitra’s 1992 Philippine presidential campaign. TakashiSadahiro, “ODA allegedly used in Manila election,” Daily Yomiuri,16 May 1994, p.1.

340

Page 351: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

environmental groups and communities.

JAPANESE ENVIRONMENTAL AID AND TROPICAL FORESTS

In FY1992, almost 17 percent of Japanese ODA was allocated as

‘environmental aid’. There are clear problems with this aid. The

definition of environmental aid is ambiguous; this total was in

part derived by simply reclassifying traditional projects.

Moreover, ‘environmental loans’ have accounted for about 70 percent

of this aid. Under MITI guidance, environmental aid has focused on

exporting environmental technology to tackle industrial pollution,

especially urban water and sewage management. As a result, except

in the Philippines, only a small portion has funded conservation,

reforestation, or tropical forestry management.’3

The Philippines is now struggling to cope with the

environmental repercussions of deforestation, including soil

erosion and siltation, devastating floods, and rural poverty.

Japanese aid -- which can be seen as partially derived from

economic growth propelled by unsustainable resource imports -- is

a logical source of funds to tackle environmental and forestry

problems in the Philippines. But Japan’s response -- environmental

loans like the 1988-92 Forestry Sector Program Loan -- have had

marginal environmental rewards and considerable economic penalties.

In the case of the Forestry Sector Program Loan, the economic

‘3According to forest managers in Indonesia and Malaysia,environmental aid has had little impact on timber management.Based on more than 50 interviews in Sabah, Sarawak, Kuala Lumpur,and Indonesia, from late January to late March 1994.

341

Page 352: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

burden is compounded by the failure of many reforestation sites, by

contractors and government officials who wasted funds, by patron-

client networks that syphoned substantial portions (perhaps as much

as 60 percent), and by the steady appreciation of the yen.

JAPANESE CORPOPATE INVESTMENT AND TECHNOLOGY TRANSFERS

To increase the speed and volume of log extraction in

Southeast Asia, Japanese trading companies have supplied capital,

equipment (chain saws, bull dozers, and road machinery), and

technical advice, often in exchange for logs. Through credit,

equipment, and minority shares Japanese traders have influenced

prices and export volumes. However, except in Indonesia in the

late 1960s and 1970s, Japanese companies have avoided major direct

investments in logging operations or timber processing, and instead

have emphasized securing and buying large amounts of high-quality

logs at the lowest possible price.’4 Most Japanese investors

pulled out of Indonesia after the gradual log export ban in the

first half of the l980s. Today, as accessible and valuable

tropical timber becomes increasingly scarce, as Japan’s plywood

industry fades, and as environmental criticism mounts, Japanese

companies have even less interest in lengthy commitments to

‘4Prior to the late 1960s, Indonesia had little logginginfrastructure. Risky investments enabled Japanese traders tosecure access to Indonesia’s vast primary forests. Theseinvestments were facilitated by MITI, strategic ODA disbursements,and Indonesian foreign investment laws.

342

/

Page 353: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

Southeast Asia’s logging sector.15 Trading companies now provide

few technical advisors or long-term lines of credit.’6 Even with

the rapid appreciation of the yen since the mid-1980s, there is

almost no Japanese investment in the timber industries in Borneo

Malaysia and the Philippines, and only a small amount in wood

processing and pulp and paper in Indonesia.’7 Japanese plywood

processors also have no plans to relocate to Southeast Asia,

despite the financial struggles of many mills in Japan.’8

Despite abundant profits from the tropical timber trade,

Japanese companies have been even more reluctant to finance or

participate in major conservation or reforestation projects.

Several factors inhibit Japanese investment in forestry

conservation and timber processing. Trading companies are

structured to maintain stable resource supplies, and preserve

corporate equilibrium. These companies generally purchase large

volumes with low profit margins, and avoid long-term commitments

essential for effective reforestation or sustainable timber

operations. According to Yuta Harago of the WWF Japan: “They are

‘5JATAN, Tropical Forest Destruction and Japan’s Timber Trade,Summary of the Revised Version of Timber from the South Seas (WWFReport, 28 February 1994), p.1.

‘6lnterviews, Senior officials, Green Environmental R&DDivision, Sumitomo Forestry Co., Ltd., Tokyo, 20 April 1994.

17Other Northern MNC5 have also avoided timber investments, andmost timber operations in the Philippines, Borneo Malaysia, andIndonesia are now controlled by domestic interests. Gulls, “TheLogging Industry In Tropical Asia,” p.179.

‘8lntervlew, Executive Director, Japan Plywood Manufacturers’Association, Tokyo, 8 April 1994.

343

Page 354: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

basically traders, not investors. So they aren’t obliged to think

in terms of 30-year projects.”19 In addition, environmentalists

and the media tend to scrutinize and fervently criticize timber

joint ventures. On the other hand, even though the economic and

environmental consequences may be far greater, it is more difficult

to develop sensational stories about purchasing practices and

import prices. Southeast Asian politics also curb Japanese

corporate investment. While clientelist states are natural prey to

feed voracious Northern processors and consumers, they provide

little security for investors. Japanese companies are wary of

sudden political shifts that could undercut concession licences or

change informal rules that allow quick, profitable logging.

Finally, quite naturally firms do not want to sink money into

poorly managed, likely doomed timber operations.

JAPAN’ S TIMBER TRADE IN SOUTHEAST AS IA

A. Japanese Corporate Purchasing Practices

The timber trade has been a key force accelerating

deforestation in Southeast Asia. Southeast Asia accounts for two-

thirds of the tropical timber products on the world market.2°

Japanese companies have dominated this trade. At no time have

Japanese traders considered the source or long-term environmental

implications of wood imports. Instead, as supplies have dwindled,

19Kathryn Graven, “Japan’s Timber Consumption Draws Fire,”AWSJ, 8 February 1990.

20Nectoux and Kuroda, Timber, p.18.

344

Page 355: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

or after Southern governments have restricted exports, Japanese

firms have simply moved to new sources. In the 1950s and 1960s,

the Philippines was the main source of Japanese tropical logs. In

the early 1960s, Philippine logs accounted for around two-thirds --

and Sabah for around one-third -- of Japanese log imports from

Southeast Asia. Japanese log imports from the Philippines

continued to rise throughout the l960s, peaking at the end the

decade. However, as accessible Philippine primary forests were

depleted, and as Japanese consumption of tropical logs surged,

Japanese companies increasingly turned to Sabah, Indonesia, and to

a lesser extent Sarawak.

In 1970, the Philippines was still Japan’s largest source of

tropical logs. Japan imported 7.5 million cubic metres of

Philippine logs, 6.1 million cubic metres from Indonesia, 4.0

million cubic metres from Sabah, and 1.9 million cubic metres from

Sarawak. In 1971, Indonesia replaced the Philippines as Japan’s

key source of logs. In that year, Japan imported 8.2 million cubic

metres of logs from Indonesia, 5.7 million cubic metres from the

Philippines, 4.1 million cubic metres from Sabah, and 1.5 million

cubic metres from Sarawak. In 1974, Japanese tropical log imports

from Southeast Asia peaked at 26.8 million cubic metres. In that

year, Japan imported nearly 11.5 million cubic metres of logs from

Indonesia, over 7 million cubic metres from Sabah, 3.9 million

cubic metres from the Philippines, and 950,000 cubic metres from

Sarawak. After the mid-1970s, Japanese log imports gradually

declined as accessible, cheap log stocks dwindled and as Japan’s

345

Page 356: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

plywood industry contracted. In 1976, Japan imported 22.2 million

cubic metres of Southeast Asian logs: 9.7 million cubic metres from

Indonesia, 8.5 million cubic metres from Sabah, 1.7 million cubic

metres from Sarawak, and 1.7 million cubic metres from the

Philippines. By 1980, total Japanese log imports from Southeast

Asia had dropped to 19.0 million cubic metres: 8.6 million cubic

metres of logs from Indonesia, 6.3 million cubic metres from Sabah,

2.3 million cubic metres from Sarawak, and 1.1 million cubic metres

from the Philippines.

As Indonesia slashed log exports in the early 1980s, Japanese

traders maintained a steady supply from Sabah, and boosted log

imports from the lower-grade forests of Sarawak. In 1982, Japan

imported 15.1 million cubic metres of logs from Southeast Asia: 6.4

million cubic metres from Sabah, 4.0 million cubic metres from

Sarawak, 2.5 million cubic metres from Indonesia, and 1.3 million

cubic metres from the Philippines. In 1987, after the complete ban

on Indonesian and Philippine log exports, Borneo Malaysia accounted

for over 90 percent of Japan’s total log imports from Southeast

Asia: 7.0 million cubic metres from Sabah and 5.5 million cubic

metres from Sarawak. Without access to the vast tracts of

Indonesian old-growth forests, in that year Japanese log imports

from Southeast Asia dropped to 13.7 million cubic metres.

In the late 1980s, as accessible, high-quality commercial

forests became increasingly scarce in Sabah, Japanese companies

turned even more to Sarawak. In 1988, Japan imported 5.4 million

cubic metres of logs from Sabah and 5.3 million cubic metres from

346

Page 357: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

Sarawak. Japanese log imports from Sabah then fell sharply, from

4.6 million cubic metres in 1989 to 3.4 million cubic metres in

1990, to 2.1 million cubic metres in 1992, to less than 300,000

cubic metres after the log export ban in 1993. Sarawak is now

Japan’s most important source of logs. Japanese log imports from

Sarawak climbed to around 6.7 million cubic metres in 1989 and

1990, then fell slightly to 6.5 million cubic metres in 1991 and

6.4 million cubic metres in 1992. After the Sarawak government

imposed greater log export restrictions in 1993, Japanese log

imports dropped to 4.9 million cubic metres. To partially replace

tropical logs from Borneo Malaysia, Japan has increased log imports

from Papua New Guinea, the Solomon Islands, Burma, and Africa.2’

Nevertheless, tropical log imports continue to fall as hardwood

supplies diminish throughout the Asia-Pacific region, as Japan’s

recession impedes builders, as Japan imports more tropical plywood,

and as plywood processors refine techniques to make softwood

plywood,22 using temperate logs from the U.S., Canada, New Zealand,

China, and Russia. As a result of all these changes, in 1993 Japan

211n 1990, Japan imported 608,000 cubic metres of logs fromPapua New Guinea, 254,000 cubic metres from the Solomon islands,29,000 cubic metres from Burma, and 126,000 cubic metres fromAfrica. By 1993, Japan imported 1,662,000 cubic metres from PapuaNew Guinea, 335,000 cubic metres from the Solomon Islands, 85,000cubic metres from Burma, and 507,000 cubic metres from Africa.JATAN, “Asia-Pacific Forests,” Table I, based on data from theJapan Tariff Association.

221n 1993, more than 40 Japanese mills manufactured softwood ormixed (softwood and hardwood) plywood, accounting for 14.6 percentof total production. “Wholly or partly softwood plywood is 15% oftotal plywood production last year,” Japan Lumber Reports,published by Japan Forest Products Journal, no. 198, 9 September1994, p.1.

347

Page 358: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

imported only 7.4 million cubic metres of Southeast Asian logs.23

Besides these legal log purchases, Japanese timber traders in

Southeast Asia have cooperated with -- and perhaps participated in

-- smuggling syndicates, transfer pricing, and schemes to alter

volumes, species, extent of processing, and log diameters on

Southern customs documents. In Borneo Malaysia, loggers and

customs officials have routinely forged legal log export documents.

The bulk of these logs have been shipped to Japan. In 1981 alone,

over one million cubic metres more Philippine logs entered Japan

than were recorded by Filipino customs officials. More recently,

Mitsui was caught smuggling logs out of Cambodia after the 1993 UN

embargo 24

235ee Chart I on the next page. The category ‘other’ includesthe Solomon Islands, Papua New Guinea, Vietnam, Burma, Laos,Cambodia, and other less important exporters in the region. Thesestatistics are from the Japan Plywood Manufacturers’ Association,Plywood Industry in Japan, 1993, pp.24-25; the Japan PlywoodManufacturers’ Association, Plywood Industry in Japan, April 1994,p.8; and data from the Japan Lumber Importers’ Association,received by the author, 4 April 1994. Also see Nectoux and Kuroda,Timber, Figure B7, p.118.

“UNTAC accuses Mitsui of violating ban on log exports fromCambodia,” The Japan Times, 18 February 1993, p.2.

348

Page 359: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

30

252015105

Chart

I

Japan

eseL

ogIm

portsFrom

Million

Cubic

Metres

SE

Asia

0)

C’)

019701972

19741976

19781980

19821984

19861988

19901992

Year

Philip

pin

esS

ab

ah

[JJlS

arawak

____

Indonesia

lllllllO

ther

Page 360: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

B. Export and Consumer Prices, Consumption, and Low State Revenue

Japan’s share of global tropical wood consumption soared from

4 percent in 1950 to about 50 percent in the 1980s.25 Today, Japan

is the world’s largest importer of tropical logs and plywood.26

Since the 1950s, Japanese traders have paid remarkably low prices

for Southeast Asian logs, sawn timber, veneer, and plywood. These

prices have assumed that primary forests are essentially free,

reflecting extraction and transportation costs, and ignoring the

investment, manpower, and time it will take to regrow a tree, and

the social and environmental costs of degrading the forest eco

system. This fosters two bizarre consumption patterns in Japan.

It is cheaper to import primary dipterocarp logs than to harvest

domestic plantations to manufacture plywood;27 and it is more

economical to burn hardwood furniture and kon pane than to reuse or

recycle them. As a result, Japanese consumers have ‘wasted’

enormous amounts of tropical timber.28 Cheap timber imports have

also enabled Japan to protect its own forests. In 1991, the OECD

estimated that Japan extracted only 53 percent of their annual

25Boyce, The Philippines, p.227.

26JATJ “Asia-Pacific Forests,” p.1.

27Japanese plywood processors import 92 percent of their logsupply. Japan Plywood Manufacturers’ Association, Plywood Industryin Japan, 1994, p.5.

281n 1987, about one-third of Japanese plywood was used as konpane. Sandra Postel and John C. Ryan, “Reforming Forestry,” Stateof the World 1991. A Report on Progress Toward a SustainableSociety. (New York: W.W. Norten & Company, 1991), p.85. Japanesebuilders now use more coated kon pane, which can be reused three toten times. But this is still an incredibly wasteful drain ontropical timber.

350

Page 361: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

growth, allowing a significant net increase in forest cover.29

Today, around two-thirds of Japan is covered in forests; about 41

percent of these forests are planted. As a result, Japan is one of

“the most heavily forested countries in the world.”30

While Japanese timber traders and processors have made

substantial profits, and while Japan has judiciously protected its

own forests, low log export prices -- coupled with illegal logging,

smuggling, low Southern timber fees, and the inability of

clientelist states to collect domestic taxes and royalties -- have

left Southern states without enough revenue for sustainable

management. A 1991 ITTO study showed that “producer countries

captured only 9 percent of the final product price (comprising

production costs, government revenues and profits) .. .when exporting

raw logs.. .The remaining 91 percent went to consumer countries.”

For some Southern states, forest charges to assess the value of the

standing tree were less than 1 percent of the final price.3’

C. Indonesian Plywood Exports and Japanese Import Barriers

Bob Hasan and Apkindo have exploited wasteful consumption

habits to break into Japan’s plywood market. Since the mid-l980s,

Apkindo has flooded Japan with cheap plywood. Indonesia now

supplies around 40 percent of total Japanese plywood consumption

29Summarized in Boyce, The Philipiines, pp.227-228.

30Japanese Forestry Agency, Forestry White Paper: Fiscal Year1992, Summary (Tokyo: Government of Japan, 1993), p.2.

31Surnmarized in Arden-Clarke, “South-North Terms of Trade,”p.127.

351

Page 362: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

and about 70 percent of kon pane. To capture Japan’s plywood

market and destroy Japanese processors, Apkindo has suppressed the

price of plywood and forced manufacturers to export 40 percent of

production to Japan.32 Apkindo also established Nippindo to import

plywood directly, bypassing Japanese overseas trading and shipping

companies.33 As a result, Indonesian plywood prices not only

ignore environmental and social costs but also underestimate the

full economic costs of extraction and transportation. Moreover,

Japanese import charges on plywood further decrease Indonesian

state and corporate revenue. The result is proliferate and

wasteful Japanese consumption of Indonesian plywood, a large

percentage of timber revenues accruing to the Japanese state,

insufficient Indonesian revenue for sustainable timber management,

and few economic incentives for efficient processing and effective

use of wood waste.

32Japan’s plywood industry has had severe economic problems asApkindo bombards the market with cheap plywood, as tropical logstocks disappear, and as Southern states restrict log exports,sometimes, as in Sabah, with no warning. In 1987, Japan processed7.34 million cubic metres of plywood. By 1992, plywood productionhad dropped to 5.95 million cubic metres. Japan Lumber Journal, 31December 1993, p.4. This points to a neglected area of research:the impact of environmental change and political responses in theSouth for economic and social change in the North. This suggestsa mutual interdependence and vulnerability of South-North resourceextraction and consumption. Some authors have started to explorethese issues. For an analysis of the social consequences ofinternational timber markets on Japan, see Patricia M. Marchak,“Global Markets in Forest Products,” in Peter N. Nemetz, ed.,Emerging Issues in Forest Policy (Vancouver: UBC Press, 1992),pp. 339 -369.

33Nippindo still uses conventional distribution channels inJapan. Plywood is sold to Japanese trading companies which thensell to wholesalers and processors. Urano, “CommercialExploitation,” footnote 70, p.93.

352

Page 363: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

JAPANESE ENVIRONMENTAL GUIDELINES AND THE TIMBER TRADE

The current campaign by the Japanese government, Keidanren,

and the major trading companies to improve Japan’s international

environmental image has contributed to more sophisticated

environmental rhetoric and perfunctory corporate and government

efforts to support better timber management. Corporate brochures

now call for advice and equipment to improve the efficiency of

Southern wood processors34 -- a move that would presumably reduce

wood waste and decrease some of the pressure on tropical forests.

There are also scattered corporate calls to reduce wasteful

tropical timber consumption and buy timber from sustainable

sources. Marubeni claims that it “will only purchase timber from

such logging companies who strictly follow laws and regulations on

logging and adhere to environmentally sound management.”35 The

Japanese Building Contractors Society -- comprising 81 key

companies -- announced in 1992 a non-binding target to reduce

tropical plywood consumption by 35 percent over the next five

years, “in order to help protect the world’s tropical rain

34For example, see Marubeni, “Friendly To Forests And To OurMother Planet,” Internal document (Tokyo: Marubeni, undated);Marubeni, Earth Conscious (Tokyo: Marubeni, March 1994); andSumitomo Forestry, Sumitomo Forestry: Annual Report 1993 (Tokyo:Sumitomo Forestry, 1993) , p.4..

35Marubeni, Earth Conscious, p.7. Also see Marubeni, “FriendlyTo Forests.” At the same time as publicly declaring ‘new’purchasing practices, Japanese trading companies downplay theirrole, claiming local slash-and-burn farmers are the key cause ofdeforestation while the timber trade has little global impact.Makoto Inoue, “Who’s Killing the Rain Forests?” Jaian ViewsQuarterly (Autumn/Winter 1992), p.12. This view was confirmedduring interviews at Keidanren, Mitsubishi, Itochu, Nissho Iwai,Sumitomo, and Marubeni, Tokyo, April-June 1994.

353

Page 364: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

forests.”36 On a voluntary basis, in the early l990s the Japanese

Lumber Importers’ Association (JLIA) -- comprising 131 companies,

including the major trading companies -- developed importing

guidelines to improve forestry management. Companies agreed to

import in “an orderly manner,” follow ITTO’s ‘Guidelines for

Continued Management of Tropical Natural Forest’, and urge “timber

suppliers of long term contract to abide by the ITTO guidelines.”

These companies also agreed to buy and use scrap wood, provide

information to local cutters to encourage better cutting practices,

and promote value added processing in the South.37 Meanwhile, the

Japan Plywood Manufacturers’ Association -- with technological

support from the Japanese government -- also plans to lower

tropical wood consumption and use softwood logs for 30 percent of

plywood production by 1996.

The Japanese government has also made sporadic calls to lower

tropical timber imports, improve corporate purchasing practices,

36Japanese Building Contractors Society, “Methods To Reduce TheConsumption of Plywood Forms Which Use Tropical Timber,” Internaldocument (Tokyo, Building Contractors Society, Board of Directors,19 February 1992).

37Government of Japan, “Japan’s Paper For Proposed ProgressTowards The Year 2000 Target,” Presented at the InternationalTropical Timber Council, November 1991, pp.3-5. Also see “LumberImporters Issue Rain Forest Guidelines,” The Daily Yomiuri, 5December 1991.

38”Wholly or partly softwood plywood is 15% of total plywoodproduction last year,” Japan Lumber Reports. Published by JapanForest Products Journal,- no. 198, 9 September 1994, p.1; andGovernment of Japan, “Japan’s Paper,” p.5. Japanese plywood makersclaim that the move to softwood logs is motivated by environmentalconcerns. But it is far more likely an attempt to survive theonslaught of cheap Indonesian plywood and more expensive hardwoodlogs, and prepare for the future collapse of tropical log stocks.

354

Page 365: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

and internalize environmental costs into timber prices. The

Construction Ministry’s new industry guidelines call for builders

to reduce practices that waste tropical timber.39 The Forestry

Agency has also announced plans to encourage companies to limit

timber purchases to sustainable sources and lower tropical timber

imports by 20 percent over five years.4° At a 1991 International

Tropical Timber Council session, Japan declared that it “intends to

make active contributions to a series of ITTO meetings which will

estimate and examine the costs of sustainable management, aiming

that prices of tropical timber cover the costs of sustainable

management.”4’ At the same meeting, the Japanese government

announced a program for “rational utilization” to reduce tropical

timber consumption. Japan agreed to support measures to use less

and reuse more kon pane, substitute non-tropical logs to make

plywood, and educate the Japanese public on the inherent value of

tropical rain forests. Japan also agreed to promote research,

39lnterview, JATAN, Tokyo, 26 May 1994.

40Sunimarized in Yoichi Kuroda, “The Tropical Forest Crisis andthe Future Course of Japanese Society,” Research on EnvironmentalDisruption toward Interdisciplinary Cooperation (Special Edition,Global/International Environmental Problems 2, Iwanami Shoten, July1991), p.6.

41Government of Japan, “Japan’s Paper,” p.6. Not surprisingly,Japanese corporations are extremely hesitant to connect low priceswith environmental mismanagement. Keidanren’s EnvironmentalCharter does not address incorporating environmental costs intoprice. Interview, Global Environment Department, Keidanren, Tokyo,7 April 1994. In the case of Sumitomo, officials argued that theprice of tropical timber has actually been quite high --

particularly in 1993 -- and there is no evidence of insufficientfunds for reforestation or sustainable management. Interviews,Green Environmental Research R&D Division, Sumitomo Forestry,Tokyo, 20 April 1994.

355

Page 366: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

training, and technology for value-added Southern processing, and

to “study the utilization of non-wood forest products and the

commercially less accepted species.”42 Since then, several local

Japanese governments -- including Tokyo, Osaka, Kanegawa, Kyoto,

Nagoya, and Sapporo -- have also announced plans to reduce the

amount of tropical kon pane used in public projects.43 More

recently, the central government reiterated its support for the

ITTO objective to limit trade to timber produced from sustainable

sources by the year 2000, and agreed to “contribute to discussions

to establish rules of timber trade, with a view to conserving the

world’ s forests.

Despite a profusion of glossy corporate environmental

brochures and more refined government environmental rhetoric since

the early l990s, there is little evidence of concrete changes to

Japanese trade practices or to the attitudes of decision makers.

This public relations campaign has contributed to a few token

forestry conservation projects -- such as Sumitomo’s experimental

project to replant an indigenous forest in East Kalimantan and

Mitsubishi’s project to recreate a natural rain forest in Sarawak

-- and to modest funding for reforestation, especially research at

42Government of Japan, “Japan’s Paper,” pp.5-6.

43For example, the Tokyo Metropolitan government announced in1992 that it would reduce tropical timber use by 50 percent by 1995and 70 percent by 1997. However, it is not mandatory and there areno implementing measures. Interview, JATAN, Tokyo, 26 May 1994.

Government of Japan, National Action Plan for Agenda 21(Tokyo: The Government of Japan, January 1994), p.62, internaldocument supplied by an official at MITI.

356

Page 367: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

Japanese universities.45 But the new Environment Law, Keidanren’s

Environmental Charter, revised corporate environmental

guidelines,46 and new corporate environmental departments appear

designed more to deflect environmental critics than to improve

overseas environmental management.47 During 1994 discussions, most

government and business leaders ignored, disputed, or dismissed as

irrelevant the environmental impact of wasteful consumption, low

resource prices, unsustainable purchasing practices, import

tariffs, and past environmental practices. There are also no signs

of specific government measures to eliminate import charges on

processed wood, introduce environmental surcharges, raise consumer

prices, provide ‘environmental reparation payments’, regulate

corporate purchasing practices and technology transfers, or ensure

funds are ploughed into sustainable Southern timber operations.

Instead, in the last few years, as timber prices increase and

imports decrease,48 the Japanese government and companies have

45There are no plans to increase the scope of reforestation orconservation in Southeast Asia. Interviews at Mitsubishi,Sumitomo, Marubeni, Nissho Iwai, Itochu, and Keidanren, Tokyo,April to July, 1994.

46According to a Keidanren survey, over 70 percent of Keidanrenmembers now have internal structures to integrate environmentalconcerns. “Global attention turns to industry,” The Japan Times,12 June 1992, p.3.

470f course, some individuals at corporate environmentdepartments are concerned, keen, and want to make a difference; butlittle change has occurred to corporate mentality or practices.Interview, Professor, University of Tokyo, 17 May 1994.

48From 1991 to 1994, prices for tropical timber have risenwhile prices of other commodities have remained level or fallenslightly. The Economist, “Chainsaw massacres,” 25 June 1994, p.39.However, since Japanese traders purchase timber with merican

357

Page 368: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

opportunistically announced policies to reduce tropical timber

imports for ‘environmental reasons’. But these trends are driven

by less abundant tropical timber stocks and a shrinking Japanese

plywood industry, not by greater concern for tropical forests.

JAPAN AND SOUTHEAST ASIAN TIMBER MANAGEMENT: RECONMENDATIONS

It is tempting to remain in an analytical cocoon and predict

-- based on the potent Northern and Southern political and economic

forces driving deforestation -- the extinction of Southeast Asia’s

primary forests. Even though my analysis leaves little room for

optimism, and despite the danger of sounding naive or ethnocentric,

I feel compelled to provide some concrete recommendations to

improve tropical timber management. These are preliminary

suggestions, in no way provide a comprehensive solution, and are

not presented in any order of priority, although trade reforms will

certainly have more impact than changes to ODA. My hope is merely

to spark constructive and relevant South-North discussions.

A. Reform Japanese Aid

JICA and the QECF should be more transparent and

accountable.49 The government should increase public access to ODA

feasibility studies and project assessments, and provide Southern

dollars, the appreciation of the yen has largely offset thesehigher prices.

49While I propose numerous reforms to Japanese aid -- in partbecause it is easier to find specific problems and specificsolutions -- it is crucial not to overestimate the potential foraid to improve commercial timber management.

358

Page 369: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

and Northern environmental groups and NGOs with more input into aid

projects. JICA executives and field staff should also receive

better environmental training and more experience in the South. As

well, JICA and the OECF should cooperate more with other Northern

donors and hire more foreign consultants, especially environmental

experts. Japan should also accept responsibility for the final

results of aid. Allowing or ignoring the ‘disappearance’ of large

chunks of aid bolsters patron-client networks, undermines state

capacity, and burdens Southern states with loans syphoned by

private actors.

Japan should overhaul its environmental aid program. The

Japanese government should develop a coherent definition of

environmental aid, clear and binding environmental guidelines, and

effective social and environmental impact assessments. As well,

Japan should restructure the administration of ervironmental aid to

improve distribution, implementation, and supervision. The

Environment Agency should have more input while MITI and its

corporate partners should be relegated to a peripheral role. Japan

should also change the tenets of environmental aid. At present,

the focus is on procuring ‘environmental profits.’ Considering

Japan’s role in driving over-logging and deforestation, Japan

should lead a financial wave to support better timber management,

rather than repeating historical patterns, sweeping profits back to

Japan. Instead of environmental loans, Japan should increase the

amount of grants, on the principle of returning past ‘environmental

profits’. The South needs compensation for the immediate and

359

Page 370: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

residual environmental effects of unsustainable timber purchases,

timber prices that have ignored social and environmental costs, and

import tariffs that have syphoned revenue. Japanese ‘environmental

reparation payments’ should target long-term, risky, low-profit

forestry conservation -- particularly projects to preserve primary

forests and regenerate natural forests. These payments should also

be used to push Japanese companies to invest more in natural forest

conservation and long-term reforestation, and transfer more

technology and knowledge to improve Southern processing efficiency

and silvicultural techniques.5°

B. Trade: Corporate Purchasing Practices

Trade can be reshaped and controlled to support sustainable

timber management.5’ Ideally, Japanese trading companies,

processors, construction firms, government agencies, and the

general public should only purchase timber from sustainable

50Other authors have also recommended extensive reforms toJapanese aid to enhance tropical forestry management. See Forrestand Harago, “Japan’s Official Development Assistance, pp.15-21.

51See Hilary F. French, “Reconciling Trade and theEnvironment,” in State of the World: 1993 Woridwatch Institute (NewYork: W.W. Norton & Company, 1993), pp.l58-179; and Edward B.Barbier, “Policy Issues and Options Concerning Linkages Between theTropical Timber Trade and Sustainable Forest Management,”Economic Linkages Between the International Trade in TropicalTimber and the Sustainable Management of Tropical Forests, ITTOActivity (PCM(XI)/4), 14th Session of the International TropicalTimber Council in Kuala Lumpur, 12-13 May 1993. For an overview ofthe links between trade and tropical deforestation, see June D.Hall and Arthur J. Hanson, A New Kind of Sharing: Why We Can’tIgnore Global Environmental Change (Ottawa: InternationalDevelopment Research Centre, 1992), chapter five, “Choices in theHarsh World of Trade,” pp.116-150.

360

Page 371: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

sources. Strict purchasing practices -- where timber from

unsustainable sources has no market and timber from sustainable

concessions receives reasonable prices -- can potentially dissolve,

or at least weaken, patron-client ties based on timber (or, perhaps

optimistically, force these informal ‘partners’ to reorganize and

better manage their concessions) . At the moment, there are no

comprehensive criteria or effective tools to certify timber from

sustainable sources. Japan should participate in international

efforts to move in this direction. An international timber

certification program has the potential to increase consumer

prices, force companies to purchase sustainable timber, and boost

Southern state capacity to enforce tougher regulations.52 While

there are formidable political and technical obstacles -- including

the endorsement of GATT, acceptable criteria for sustainable

management, and South-North cooperation -- and although there is a

definite danger that Southern and Northern political and corporate

interests will hijack certification programs, effective

certification would provide an important tool to regulate

corporate, consumer, and state behaviour.53

52To help undercut patron-client networks in the South,international inspectors must work closely with Southern stateofficials who are trying to combat destructive and illegal loggers.While expensive, it is essential that international inspectorsmonitor check points, evaluate concession sites, and verify customsdocuments. Otherwise, certification will become an internationalstamp of approval for current mismanagement.

53For background on timber certification, see Salahudin Yaacobet., al., Forest Stewardship Council (FSC) Malaysian ConsultativeStudy, Malaysian FSC Consultative Study Working Group (SelangorMalaysia: WWF Malaysia, August 1993); Baharuddin Haji Ghazali andMarkku Simula, Certification Schemes For All Timber and Timber

361

Page 372: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

C. Trade: Import Restrictions

Another possible option to reshape trade is to impose

unilateral restrictions on tropical timber imports. But import

restrictions have severe drawbacks.54 JATAN -- the most important

Japanese NGO tackling tropical forestry issues -- is now pressing

local Japanese governments, business organizations, construction

firms, and trading companies to restrict timber purchases.55 This

strategy is flawed. Although import restrictions may temporarily

reduce Southern logging rates, repressing demand, without

compensation or higher prices, will undercut the economies of

Southeast Asia, provide incentives to convert forests to more

profitable fiinctions,56 encourage companies to extract higher

volumes to offset lower prices, and leave even fewer funds for

sustainable management.57 Import bans could even increase

Products, Report for the ITTO (Yokohama: ITTO, 15 April 1994); andBarbier, “Policy Issues and Options,” pp.22-26.

54For a critique of complete trade bans, see Barbier, “PolicyIssues and Options,” pp.7-B. For selective bans, see Ibid., pp.9-10; quantitative restrictions, pp.lO-1l.

55For a description of JAPAN’s approach, see JANNI, “Reshaping‘Development’,” p.45 and Kuroda, “The Tropical Forest Crisis,”pp.6-7. There is also a growing movement in Europe to ban orrestrict tropical timber imports.

56Former Indonesian Forestry Minister Harahap warned: Ifconsumer countries “impose a boycott, the wood will have noeconomic value for us. We may turn the forests to things that areuseful to us.” “Jakarta may turn forests into farms over timberboycott,” Straits Times, 14 October 1992, p.12.

57Following similar reasoning, former Indonesian Minister ofState For Population and Environment Emil Salim has criticizedunilateral Northern moves to boycott tropical timber. Third WorldNetwork, “South-North development monitor,” no. 2591, 24 April1991, in World Rainforest Movement, The Endangered Rainforests and

362

Page 373: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

management problems as prices fall and the demand short-fall is

filled by domestic or other foreign consumers. Import restrictions

also discriminate against Southeast Asian producers in favour of

softwood exporters like Russia, Canada, New Zealand, and the United

States.58 The South will likely perceive unilateral Northern

import bans as environmental imperialism,59 reducing the capacity

of the North to influence Southern forestry policies and practices.

Even though there are clear problems with Southern state capacity

to enforce regulations, and despite substantial evidence of

straightforward corruption, it is still imperative to reach

solutions through North-South cooperation and dialogue.60

The Fight for Survival, volume 1 (Penan, Malaysia: World RainforestMovement, 1992), p.520. In theory, selective import restrictionson timber produced from unsustainable sources and open markets fortimber from sustainable sources could improve management in theSouth. But first it will be necessary to establish internationalsustainable management criteria and a means to certify sustainabletimber.

58Many Southern leaders are concerned that temperate timberexporters will use restrictions on tropical timber imports toincrease their market share. For example, Sabah Timber Associationpresident Datuk Andrew Tham argues that New Zealand has lobbiedJapan to restrict tropical timber imports “in their attempt toboost their export of softwood.” Quoted in Mark Kong, “Sabah,S’wak condemn NZ’s timber boycott,” The Star, 8 April 1992, p.6.

59For example, the South reacted strongly to Austria’sunilateral legislation to require labels -- such as ‘sustainableforest management’ -- on tropical timber imports. After harshcriticism, especially from Malaysia and Indonesia, Austria withdrewthis proposal. See Jeffrey Ramayah, “Austria warned of likelyASEAN boycott,” New Straits Times, 27 October 1992, p.7; “For thechop,” The Economist, 30 January 1993, p.63; and “Malaysia’s NewJungle War,” Asiaweek, 10 February 1993, p.47.

605ee Hall and Hanson, A New Kind of Sharing, especially theconclusion, “The New Dialogue,” pp.297-311. Southern log exportrestrictions are also not an effective tool to promote sustainabletimber management. To increase economic benefits of timber exports

363

Page 374: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

D. Trade: Purchases, Import Volumes, Prices, and Consumption

Japanese tropical timber consumption must not exceed

sustainable yields of Southeast Asian producers. While a Japanese

ban on tropical timber imports could quickly reduce consumption, a

more constructive way to lower timber consumption is to internalize

environmental and social costs into consumer prices.6’ If prices

are high enough, strong incentives can be created for

‘conscientious consumption’ and recycling. While public campaigns

that explain the causes and effects of tropical deforestation, or

pressure on construction and trading companies to treat tropical

timber as a limited and valuable resource may help reshape wasteful

consumption patterns, it is vital that consumer prices reflect

-- and presumably raise revenue and increase incentives foreffective management -- the Philippines, Indonesia, Sabah, and toa lesser extent Sarawak, have all placed constraints on log exportsand provided processing incentives. Even though this has createdsome jobs, there are severe problems: domestic processors areinefficient and waste wood; there are now far too many domesticprocessors -- often with close links to state patrons -- who firmlyresist moves to lower log production to sustainable levels; andsevering foreign demand has suppressed log prices. Despite theseproblems, however, dismantling export barriers could make thesituation even worse as processors scramble to survive and loggersexploit new markets. For now, it is more productive to reshapeNorthern shadow ecologies and improve Southern enforcement andsustainable management.

611n 1990, tropical timber producers issued a joint call on theNorth to adjust timber prices “so that the costs of forestmanagement and reforestation can be considered.” Quoted in ThirdWorld Network, “South-North development monitor,” no. 2591, 24April 1991, in World Rainforest Movement, The EndangeredRainforest, p.521. But many Southeast Asian leaders are nervousthat temperate wood will substitute for more expensive tropicaltimber. For this reason, many Southern managers insist thattemperate and boreal timber also internalize environmental andsocial costs. Interviews, the Philippines, Sabah, Sarawak,Indonesia, and Peninsular Malaysia, January to March 1994.

364

Page 375: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

these attitudes.62

In theory, export prices that internalize environmental and

social costs would increase Southern state revenues and foster

sustainable management. But in Southeast Asia, clientelist states

are too weak to collect timber royalties, control illegal loggers,

or impede destructive concessionaires. Without first gaining

control of particularistic, rent-seeking patron-client networks,

higher export prices will create even stronger incentives to

extract illegal logs or mine legal concessions as timber operators

make even more money.63 This presents a practical logjam. It is

unreasonable to expect the South to strengthen state controls and

implement sustainable policies without adequate funds. But it is

equally unreasonable for the North to pay higher prices only to

bolster greedy elites and fuel patron-client networks. To overcome

this problem, Japan -- in conjunction with Southeast Asian

exporters -- could create a sustainable management fund by imposing

an environmental surcharge on Southeast Asian timber imports. This

surcharge -- which should absorb processed wood import tariffs --

62Presuntably, if consumer prices for products like kon panereflected environmental and social costs then Japanese builderswould either find cheaper substitutes or change their constructiontechniques.

63This has occurred in the Philippines where higher log pricesin the 1990s have stimulated illegal logging rather than bettermanagement. Interview, Senior official, ENR-SECAL Program,Department of Environment and Natural Resources, Manila, 3 February1994.

64Numerous Southern officials argue that the North shouldremove import barriers on processed tropical wood. Interviews, thePhilippines, Sabah, Sarawak, Indonesia, and Peninsular Malaysia,January to March 1994.

365

Page 376: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

could partially internalize environmental and social costs into

consumer prices and still keep export prices at a moderate level.

By placing higher surcharges on timber from primary forests, and

lower surcharges on timber from secondary forests, Japan-Southeast

Asian management teams could lower consumption of primary forest

timber and maintain sustainable yields in secondary forests. This

sustainable management fund could be used to support Southern

conservation, protect primary forests, regenerate natural forests,

manage sustainable logging, and bolster Southern state capacity to

enforce regulations. Great care would be required to ensure that

these funds were not syphoned by the Japanese state, Japanese

corporations, Southern firms, or Southern patron-client networks.

Environmental import surcharges could also help control

consumer prices. Prices must be high enough to reduce excessive

consumption but not so high they destroy demand. Quite naturally,

as timber prices rise, consumers will substitute other products --

like plastics, metals, and temperate timber. If consumption falls

too far, timber concessions would lose economic value, state timber

revenue would erode, and state and private managers would have

fewer incentives to manage and regenerate secondary forests.65

Using environmental import surcharges, prices could be manipulated

to maintain sufficient demand for a viable commercial industry and

maximize Southern revenue. A sustainable management fund is only

a partial solution, and will involve considerable political

65This point was emphasized by numerous Southeast Asianbusiness and state officials during interviews, late January tolate March, 1994.

366

Page 377: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

cooperation and transaction costs. But until Southern states

internalize environmental and social costs into timber prices, and

until Southern timber operators strictly obey management policies,

Northern import surcharges -- coupled with Northern environmental

reparation payments -- are reasonable ways to offset some of the

environmental costs of trade.66

LESSONS FOR NORTH-SOUTH INTERACTION AND ENVIRONMENTAL MANAGEMENT

The inability of Southern clientelist states to impede

destructive loggers, collect timber revenues, and enforce

regulations, and the current and residual impact of Japan’s

ecological shadow of timber cast an ominous darkness over the

forests of Southeast Asia. Other Northern shadow ecologies -- with

patterns similar to Japan -- add to the pall over these forests.67

661n 1992, a World Bank report recommended that the Northestablish a one to two U.S. billion dollar a year fund -- separatefrom development aid -- to conserve biodiversity in primary rainforests. The report argues that rich states must compensate poorertropical countries for sacrificing short-term economic gains andpreserving global biodiversity. Summarized in Cherian George,“Rich nations urged to pay for preserving forests,” Straits Times,17 May 1992, p.4. Numerous Southern leaders -- including MalaysianPrimary Industries Minister Datuk Sen Dr Lim Keng Yaik and formerSabah Chief Minister Pairin Kitingan -- support environmentalpremiums. Unlike my proposal, however, most Southern elites demandthat proceeds are transferred to Southern managers with few stringsattached. See A. Rachel, “Sustaining tropical timber,” New StraitsTimes, 12 May 1993; “Lim: ITTO membership needs a look,” and “M’siaseeks perks for timber products,” The Star, 12 May 1993, p.3; andThird World Network, “South-North development monitor,” no. 2591,24 April 1991, in World Rainforest Movement, The EndangeredRainforest, p.519.

67Comparative studies of the impact of Northern shadowecologies on Southern resource management is an important area forfuture research.

367

Page 378: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

Effective solutions to global deforestation will have to tackle

powerful political forces in the South, and broad environmental

effects of South-North interaction.68 Extrapolating from an

analysis of Japan’s shadow ecology in Southeast Asia, it is clear

that breaking South-North trade ties -- while perhaps temporarily

slowing deforestation -- will entail long-term economic, social,

and environmental costs. It is more productive to manipulate

Northern shadow ecologies to ensure that sufficient profits are

ploughed into forestry management. Aid, investment, and technology

transfers must target sustainable timber operations. Northern

consumers must use timber more efficiently and pay for the costs of

sustainable management. Ideally, multinational companies should

buy timber from sustainable sources and Northern governments should

dismantle trade barriers to timber from sustainable concessions.

To move in this direction, Northern states should cooperate with

Southern producers to create international mechanisms to verify

‘sustainable’ timber.

Until sustainable timber can be certified, and until Southern

states can enforce sustainable management policies and collect

68The process of deforestation is exceedingly complicated.While Northern shadow ecologies and Southern clientelist states arecritical factors driving deforestation, comprehensive solutionswill also have to consider the impact of Southern debt,international financial organizations, land use rights, indigenousrights, federal-provincial relations, apathetic and uninformedpolitical and bureaucratic leaders, the content of forestry andnon-forestry policies (e.g. resettlement and exchange ratepolicies), population growth, poverty, and world attitudes thatpromote industrialization at all costs. Gillis and Repetto providea valuable outline of possible Southern public policy reforms toimprove tropical forest management, in Gillis and Repetto,“Conclusion: findings and policy implications,” pp.396-407.

368

Page 379: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

sufficient timber revenues, Northern states -- in cooperation with

Southern producers -- should impose environmental surcharges on

tropical timber imports to create sustainable management funds.69

These environmental surcharges can help internalize some

environmental and social costs into timber prices. Bilateral -- or

perhaps multilateral -- South-North teams can use these funds to

support sustainable Southern timber operators. Sustainable

management funds are only a partial solution. The North must also

provide environmental reparation payments. This money -- perhaps

channelled as aid grants - - is essential to compensate for the

residual and immediate effects of Northern shadow ecologies. The

South cannot absorb the concomitant costs of deforestation --

including soil erosion, flooding, and rural poverty -- and still

find sufficient funds for sustainable management.

Northern shadow ecologies must also be manipulated to push

Southern states to tackle management problems. Aid, investment,

and environmental funds must not fuel patron-client timber

networks. Instead, South-North teams need to establish mechanisms

to bypass patron-client networks and enhance Southern state

capacity. Transforming Northern shadow ecologies and Southern

clientelist states will require the North to sacrifice money, the

South to sacrifice some sovereignty, extensive South-North

dialogue, and a plethora of innovative international and domestic

policies and structures. It will also require the international

69There is a strong Southern argument for imposing similarenvironmental standards and surcharges on temperate and borealtimber.

369

Page 380: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

community to confront Southern political forces driving

deforestation. This may well be impractical in a world that

jealously guards artificial borders, relentlessly pursues economic

growth and higher consumption, and invariably protects powerful

political patrons. If so, the world’s primary rain forests will

soon disappear.

370

Page 381: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

ACRONYMS AND INDIGENOUS TERMS

ADB: Asian Development Bank.

Apkindo: [Asosiasi Panel Kayu Indonesia], Indonesian Wood PanelAssociation.

Berjaya: Bersatu Rakyat Jelata Sabah (political party).

BFD: Philippine Bureau of Forest Development.

BN: Malaysian Barisan Nasional (political party).

BULOG: Indonesian Agency for Rice Stabilization.

DAC: QECD Development Assistance Committee.

DENR: Philippine Department of Environment and Natural Resources.

DPR: Indonesian House of Representatives.

EIA: Environmental Impact Assessment.

ENR-SECAL: World Bank and QECF Environment and Natural ResourcesSector Adjustment Loan for the Philippines.

EPA: Japanese Economic Planning Agency.

EXIM Bank of Japan: Export-Import Bank of Japan.

FAQ: Food and Agriculture Qrganization.

Hankam: Indonesian Department of Defense.

ICETT: International Centre For Environmental Technology Transfer.

ITCI: International Timber Corporation of Indonesia.

ITTQ: International Tropical Timber Qrganization.

JAS: Japanese Agricultural Standard.

JICA: Japanese International Cooperation Agency.

JLIA: Japanese Lumber Importers’ Association.

JPMA: Japan Plywood Manufacturers’ Association.

Keidanren: Japanese Federation of Economic Qrganizations.

Kon pane: disposable Japanese construction panels for moulding

371

Page 382: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

concrete.

MDF: Medium Density Fibreboard.

MITI: Japanese Ministry of International Trade and Industry.

MNCs: Multinational Corporations.

MPR: Indonesian People’s Consultative Assembly.

NFP: Philippine National Forestation Program.

NGOs: Nongovernmental Organizations.

Nippindo: a branch of Apkindo designed to import and market plywoodin Japan.

NPA: Philippine Communist New People’s Army.

ODA: Overseas Development Assistance.

OECF: Japanese Overseas Economic Cooperation Fund.

PBB: Parti Bumiputra Bersatu, the most powerful member in thecurrent Sarawak Barisan Nasional coalition government.

PBDS: Parti Bangsa Dayak Sarawak (political party).

PBS: Parti Bersatu Sabah (political party).

Repelita: Indonesian Five Year Plans.

RETROF: Japanese Research Association for Reforestation of TropicalForest.

RITE: Japanese Research Institute of Innovative Technology for theEarth.

SAFODA: Sabah Forestry Development Authority.

SKEPHI: Indonesian NGO Network for Tropical Forest Conservation.

SNAP: Sarawak National Party.

Sogo Shosha: Japanese Trading Company.

SSIA: Sabah Sawmillers Industries Association.

STIDC: Sarawak Timber Industry Development Corporation.

TLAs: Philippine Timber Licence Agreements.

372

Page 383: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

TPI: Indonesian Selective Cutting System.

TPTI: Indonesian Selective Cutting and Replanting System.

USAID: U.S. Agency for International Development.

USNO: United Sabah National Organization (political party).

WALHI: Indonesian NGO Forum For the Environment.

373

Page 384: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

‘Cl

)Iui

i-H

-H

-IH

-H

IPCD

CDH

-CD

CD0

CDCD

HH

-H

I<0

Lx

idi

fl(tI

LO

ItoH

-Cl)

C1dW

U-]

Ph

i-

IH”-

Hi—

aH

-P)

ooo

CD

OO

oI

MH

.Ic

-rH

-pup.

Tjc

.rr<

H-r

tP)

HM

iH

-0

1-

<O

H-

(X)

CT)

‘°IT

1H

i<

OH

CD

Hic

iH

-d

Hi

.PJpj

‘Do(f

)I

‘DH

-’ij

CD

I-

frç(

DF

-rC

D,I

11110

(D

c-t

0Q

c-t

(T)Q

CO

PIC

T1

O0

H-W

(DO

W[rtH

-W

(T)H

‘-TCl)

010

rt(D

-C

DC

DCl

)U

)CD

WC

flC

)CD

Ji

H-Q

OH

-‘H

-0(T

)H

-C

l)C

tI

(DO

00

r-r

“C

DH

-jC

DH

-N

L’JP

i‘<

to)

Or-

’-H

HH

-IP

H-

CD

()

<c-F

t5c-ti

-H

--C

DH

-c-i

-I-

I°(D

oH

-H-

-F

-Q

Cl)C

HI

HI-

IIO

c-F

HH

-’C

1-

H

H-

-CJ

DCD

LT

J1

)i

Iii

CD

PJ

IOCD

3H-

HCl

)IC

D<

01

HW

Cl)

•H0

wO

H-

H-

H-

0<

HH

H-

JJJ

jcr

‘--‘

H-.

Cl)

Z1’d

H-C

ID=

c1,<

CD

HH

-o

(D

CiiF

144

H-H

Hoc

CD

-C

J)C

l)O

0C

fli

rt

QO

HC

)H

--

QC

D(D

bC

DC

DC

DH

0(j)

jH

W I-I

H--

HH

-)H

0(1

)pC

tH

-1O

-.(i

)P

JH

CD

CD

OLI

Io

icx)

0-

HW

oO

t’JbQ

-H

-•.

CD

HC

DO

HO

CD

HO

(DO

OH

O1

H0

l))—

HI-

H<H

O-

CD

c1-

CDH

-’<

11

o••

H-

00(0

HC

C’)

H-O

o OC

D0

(0<

<(T

)CD

H-

CD

-]c-r

c-r

Cl)

I’J.

C’2

(fl

3H

H-

h(T

)“

IH

-i.

<H

-o

H-

Hi

HO

c-Cl)

H-

o..O

H0

H0

CD

H—

c-t

HiH

HC

DH

-H

Oj

1ic-’

•c-

Fc-t

ç-t

OH

CD

,

OH

,c-r

‘uq

CD0

0CD

CD

c-F.C

l)

OH

-C

iCD

0P

HO

H-

HC

DC

DCD

([)to

)c-F

H‘d

H-

IHLI

IH

-i’

HH

-hi

:i-

iic-

rC

Cioc

--jc

-’o

CD-I-

HO

IJ

Cl)

H-

HC

DC

D0

c-100

H-<

rr<0C

DH

(QH

CD

Pip

CD

H‘<

CD

H-

<H

-C

DH

CD

H-

0O

Io

i0

:C

D(D

HH

-HIC

F‘<

i-tr

.jH

iCD

.—C

_I00

c-f

liH

-0

OH

OPi

c-Fp

i()

pi

Cfl

’rJ

Pi

Wc-

rH

-b

IH-C

D:c’C

DI0

c-F

CD

‘tIP

)-“

H-

CDP

Jh

c-F0

IO

CDH

-Hi

bI

ICfl

I-(

CD

C1)

‘d

CDH

CDII

IrF

CO

HIH

-PC

Dh

H-

•CD

)H]

H-

c-t

CD

PiP

)H

-i

H-C

DP)

CD

HH

-P)

WC

I2C

l)c-F

P)

-

Cl)

“P

HC

’)

0‘C

D-

CD-

CD

Page 385: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

ww

ww

ww

CD)

IJI)

I)U)

Hrt

I-iI-

C)CD

H-

C)H

NN

IIP)

0H

-H

-H

-0

0C

DH

-I1i

HL

’J

1H

HrrW

CD

‘dH

CV

P111(1

)IQ

F-

IO

Q0

LP

F-e

qCl

)flJh

’1

Q(D

Ifl)

CD

HM

C)-

P)C

DQ

J‘O

Ofr

-ntr

-h-n

h,-

pJ

H-H

--U)

U)I

U)h

,0U

)OP

JrtrtC

Drt-

rt-

DQ

-li-

f-CD

fr-n

i-n

N•

(1)1

(1)0

0rt-

HP

)C

1)

PJ

Pil

l)P

IH-

H-H

-HH

-0

0P1

II‘-

Q(D

L’i

-Q

I-j

—‘O

l’l

Io

OIC

)C)-

tP1

I-pj

ICj)

ç2C

)IC

)U)

H-

HP

JH

-P1

H0O

CDI1

iI1C

D(

CtH

Cl)C

D1C

DC

DC

Dc2

.-1

frO

M-U

)IC

DH

-o‘1

H-

CD

CD

P1.

Ic’-

Cr..

U)C

Drt

11

1(D

P1

—C

Drt

pj

t5C

)P)

WH

-’l

WH

PlO

0P1

U)U

)rr

<1I

P1CD

U)1H

-h

H--

U)h’

C)H

H(-tc

-t

IH-

HI

CtC

!)-

‘dH

-rrO

rt0

•H

-CH

P1U

)pj

I-

iIH

-0

00

U1Q

‘z

PJ

CDI”-

-Q

U)I0

HH

PIfr

0p1

:CD

WO

P1

U9H

,iO

H0C

DO

ICD

rrIH

-0

Oh,H

•I

CDC

DC

rCF

Irr

H-I

CC

f)P

-.0

CD

JF

-P1

HP

)O

ICDH

IH

-lj

tOC

)i-

•O

WH

-P1

Id

rF

IH

.-O

Ct

Pd

P’I-

=Q

iI-

L’J

CD

CD

Cr

CDi

Hrt

ICr

P1Cr

‘Cr

CD

QO

P)C

DU

)CD

IH

CD

IH

CDH0C

rH

.H

H-

Cr

Op

)IP

1P1

(DC

DcI

CD

CD

WC

DH

®C

)H-

HH

-CD

C)L

O(O

0CD

O-

(D

Oe

i-ti

iU)<

PJH

--

P)C

)O

C)

J(D

<C

FH

CD

0CD0

tflC

rH0

H-

HU

)C

DC

FH

CDCD

H-

CD

.P1

U)C

DQ

.i-

H-C

)H

H-

HH

HJ-

&IJ

Oi-

nH

U)P

JC

rC

rC

C)

M)O

P1CD

CD

PU

)D

1•

CDCD

0CD

H.

0H

H-

HI1

H-

DQ

-i-

nC-i

H-

IIH

-O

QC

DW

i=

00

rti

JP1

0-

00

U)H

-C

DCD

•C

DO

P1

HH

QQ

ci

H-

P1P

1u

23P1H

-W

rtC

DC

)U

)U

)’t5

CD

‘-D

c-t

‘DC

Dp

0-

H-j

U,

‘oç

HH

(l)

.c-

tH-C

D‘o

CD

‘oCD

CDC

l)P

).O

CrC

)P1

U)C

)C

FCD

tOC

Df-IU

)C

DP1

HC

rIj

Cj)

P1

P1C

DH

-C

)P

).H

,CD

“H

Cr

-iO

CDU

)H

IH- H

-•

H-

•0

.H

HH

-C

)O

CD

H-

P1U)

IIH

wIH

Ct

•Q

Cr

Hrr

(t0

CD

P1CD

H.H

po

CD

QCD

IHC

D0

P1C)

0H

<Il

H-H

-w

CFCD

P1i-

rjJ

DC

Dt-

FI-

HCD

H-I

lIl

Cr

0C

DC

DC

DO

CD

CD

JP

1S

CD

P)C

rP1

•H

-H

Io

°o

0C

rP

H.

pIlH

-H

P1I

FC

)

Cl)

).

)H

H.

CtC

t0o

CDH

.HU)

C)IC

tF‘I

’-’l

H-i

CD

P1Q

jP1

rr

1<

rtP

)C

Dccl

pi=

rr

IH

-H-

HC

DCD

LH

-H

•CD

CDH

CDP1

IZ1W

C)C)

P1CD

P1

P‘d

CI)

0oi

oIH

•pj

clH

-W

HC

rIl

—1)

HC

l)W

-oI

üI

U)H

-C

r0

xjC

DclH

Ci

C)C

Hi

•0

oIH

-

H-0C

DC

DU

)Cr

IlW

IIC

DIl

P1

P1

IQ

U)P

1-C

rC

DU

)Ii

H-

clI

i-

0C

Di>

<P

1U

)H

-C

)P1C

D—

.HH

-IH

H-1

H=

P1’1

01

IlP

1(D

H-

P1C

)HH

-H

-’1

1C

FH

-CD

.IH

Cr0

-

H-I

0C

rU)C

)d

H-

H--i

oO

H-

P1IC

DP1

1”H

-H

-Il

HU

)IH

-U)

00

HP

)IlP

)P

1h=

CrI

Cr

Cr1

OC

C)lU

)CD

0P1

IIi

bCr

CDH

-t

-3H

-H

-IH

-H-

II--3

U)‘—

s2i

OIH

-P

CD

P1H

---F

-Q

U)C

DC

rP

HP

1Cr

tOO

“IP

1-

U)c

lM’

“H

-C

DC

DrtU

)‘<

CD

CD

-Cl)

CDCD

H”

Page 386: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

ww

ww

ww

ww

iw

iiii

iiII

0H

HH

HIH

CDCD

CDo

00

H-

CD0

Pi)

ICrt

Hpi

pi9J

H0)

00

H-

H-

I’H

HCl)

0I

CD0

o—

.-

QH

-C

DPJ

ZP

JH

H-

l:)I

xi

ICID

H-

OH

-H

It’i

HCD

—C

f)’d

-I-

I-,Q

iC

DO

CV

IlC

DQ

CID

IOC

DIO

CD

I’xi

ti—

PiO

HIl

Cl)

rr-

QrtC

DO

CD

)jC

1O

Q0

)IN

10—

IP

OH

-C

l)H

00

0CD

1OCD

PJCl

)Pi

MCD

1HH

P)1H

I0I

<q

Piçt

HF

-Ypit

-tb

WF

<C

1Il(

-)I-

WH

IlH

-CD

I0

ICD

iIrt

•C

Dp

hj

P)rt

1jH

-H

t5H

-Q

QH

CDçn

o-

ICH

-k1

H-

IIH

CDII

HH

H-C

D0

PJ

IiCl

)I—

’P)

-d

01<

CDIH

-CD

Cl)

’tC

flCD

H’<

W0pi

CDC

X)p

i()L

11

<h

rtQ

Hd

P’I

i•Il

ICD

IlH

-Il

Ho

iP

JP

)

H-

(V)

jH

‘tH

—Cl

)IC

l)0

)P

i0fl

CtC

IlH

(D.

Cl)H

-Ii

0<

CD

.•rto

)O

pi

CDCl

)‘I

H-

H-

IlO

HII

(j)

0(1)

0-

0P

iIl

P)O

bH

-Il

H-t

)(V

H0)

(D

(D

o-

H-

CD

Ild

I4O

pi

CD

IlH

‘0

H-

CDC

DC

DH

-P)

‘tI<

‘t<

ii>

I.-]

HPJ

Ilpi

HH

WC

Dk

<C

fl.

OH

HH

CD

CD

azP

)p

jp’

pi

H-

0)

H‘L

QW

Ctt

cCD

‘dH

-0

“H

-Il

H1

CD

0H

0.0

-H

-P

JCD

H-

H-H

-CD

rt

H-

H0H

pC

D

CD.

H‘•tj

tIC

fl

.CH

-O

IQII

<0

H

CD

i-<

rtH

çIl

FIJ

Hq

Dq

QclH

-OCD

HH

H-

p)rt

Hçt

0ttQ

Hrr

H-O

IlH

-CD

CD

CD

--

PJL

i<

CD

9)ct-

0Pi

Il

0)

H“H

-•

(D

0)

CI)

Ci)W

CD.

.H

H-o

Ilp

.H

-0

Cl)3(Q

—1

ijP

PiC

DP

içC

DIl

IlW

CD

H-

HIl-

IlJ

c-FCl

)0H

OH

WH

-0

PiH

-Il

.

-H

-I

H-H

-H

-H

-Il

IlIl°

0(T

)H

°O

0CC

)0

00p,P

)Cl

)H

-H

O•

0P

H0)

HH

-CD

0)

CD

NH

JO

jO

HC

H-

HCD

Cl)

H-I

lCl)

H-

-1-H

-Ij

rt

H

OH

IlH

HH

-H

--

PiH

-0

IlH

-0

Il0

-

Cl)

Cl)’

Cl)H

a=

IlC

D0

H-

CD0)

H0Q

CD

•Cl)

H-

HC

Cl).H

-Il

Cl)-o

-CD

Hci

H-

xj

Ct

CCD

(D

‘1II

1_b

Il

CT)Il

N0

oCD

IlH

1<

pji

0H

CDH

-••O

P)Il

Il

HH

CD

Cl)0

0CD

IH

F-

-3O

‘Ilç

-tH

0O

Il..

I0C

DC

t10

P)CD

IlIIl

ClH

iiI

P’Il

lH

ç?H

-CD

CDI

LI(l)

CDM

H-

CD0

0Il

H-

H-

CD-

CDCD

IHU

)Cl

)Ic

H-t

i)H

Qp)H

Oct

P)

CD

Il0

0—

-CD

Pi

loP

iC

H0

WH

H-I

lH

CD

)0

HC

tc-

tic-

iIl

i-fl

Il0

)H

-H

0H

p1IC

I)pi

c-FH

-IH

c-FH

-C

D0

H-Q

Pi

I-<

H-

HH

-<

1o

IPi(tH

P)r

FO

0(D

I-p

iw

CD(D

ID)

CDIH

-<C

D-

•-••.

-Z

C)1

Io

-.•

-

Page 387: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

C)

C)

C)

C)

C)

C)

C)

C)

C)

WW

WW

1Jl-

H-

CDCD

)Pi

PH

I-0

00

CDH

H-

H-

CH

(.

H-

QQ

HI-

H-

CDC

IDLI

tti

L1

(D

HC

()H

-CIQ

U)p

.fl

U)

IU

)fl

u)

HH

-ct

frij

-L’

itI)

IQL

IJH

i‘d

H-

H-

lU)U)

CDPi

H-

0H

U)Pi

ctIH

-C

Ic0

-H

-IH

-’d

U)<

C!D

ct

P)C

I2IO

CDU

)0

CD

IcL’

C’

DIQ

0IP

JctC

DH

1PiC

DO

CD

rrC

D-

1-

I(D

itj

Pic

t-b

Id

MZJ

I(1)

•IH

Hir

OH

CD

IIP

H-

CD

fl3(

D‘1

-IC

CD

-‘P

IU)c

f)O

.QP

JJ

H-

ICl)

H-

0d

wIi

‘Iii

IH-

qH

-I

ii<

Ict

H-

1(1)

0-‘

oH

Iipi

0IH

-H

-0

0IN

it’

P)H

-H

lCDH

-H

rrtd

liC

Di

rtC

DH

-HI<

0IP

)C

DI

Ct(

T)

5liO

HH

HH

-l)

HO

pi

li1<

0l

-CD

.H

lU)H

-IH

-U)

IiIli

0.

‘H

Hli

CDC

Dli

lid

H-(

Dli

U)p

iC

DICI

)N

p)

IrtP

i(D

CD

bI

H-I

--h

id;:

CX

)i:

U)0U

)1

lCD:

IiH

CñC

D<

.!ic

t-,

Ilirt

ciC

D-

U)Q

H-

-

H-

piP

)H

—ii

liq

IU)r

n‘

—.C

DH

p)•

PW

H-.

H-

HU)

Hli

pj

J0

jC

rP1

H-

(5

-Cr

Ht1

H(H

O

L’i

‘H

-(D

Pip

i1li

CtC

DC

DH

li

HL

’J0p

Cr()

].

-]d

HU

)H

-H

li1

CD

CD

H-

-0

00

H-

H-

C)

=H

piQ

Cr

pi

-00

HH0

lH

HH0

pC

Dli

çt

CD(D

P)

CDH

HH

(T1C

)H

H-

CD

li

liliH

Pi

U)U

lt?

0li

PI

HC

t-

-H

CD

HCD

(D

HC

DCD

Ilir

tH

U)••

CD (i2?

Cfl

j‘D

liI

Hli’

I’dH

CDCD

-(D

ç2

0U

)C

ric

tCD

H-

IcH

Ct

H-

WC

DCr

—‘H

iDC

DP

Ipj

0IH

Jli

I<C

D°C

Dli

CDH

-li

Mi

H-

CDIH

-H

0lCD

ii-

-H

-H

CD

piH

<H

-C

r‘

<C

rH

-CD

CDP1

U)P

ili

<Ii

‘d

H-p

afi

P)

0(D

dli

CD

HIH

-H

U)

Ct

lip

)d

P1

oIi

lo

wI-3

Cr

CD‘H

PH

OiP

)I-

JH-

U‘dj

0H

H-

IH

CD

0li

C)

hC

li‘P

1-

lili

CD

H1

-CD

Hq

U)

“ct

<çi.

.Pi

Hi

Iip

Cr

ij

IiI

)P

1C

Dli

CD

tiH

liLI

crpi

CD

li’

‘-<

li3

H-

Cr

Cr

U)p

ili

H-

0•

..

Cr

H-

Cr

CDi

I-CI”:J

4LQ

IiH

H0

P)’

-0C

Dcoq

ib(j

)CD

:CD

liCD

Cr

H-L

H-

0Ic

rH

-CD

HP1

l-

iHh

pCD

U)‘t

iLI

I1H

H-

H-

=CD

oU)

•H

-P

iH

CD

0H

U)

CDI

H-

FH

-H

-lCD

Cr

HPi

LIl

H-

Pi0 IH

CDI

PC

rH

-C

rU)

‘DC

r0

IC1)

lili

IHri

IIxj

CDH

-ICr

H-

Hli

CDr

piI

qiii

10H

iC

ICI

U)U)

Cr

Cr

•0

HP1

oI

IH

Cr

C0

10

H0

H-C

DO

P)

tIli

C)

-l

C•

IH-

HI-’

-IH

)CD

li(X

IHI

I-CCD

H-

CI)

U)0

10

-l

‘IIC

CM

iH

OC

DIP1

WC

DIli

ID)

H-

IliCD

IPJLI

CDIii

t5H

-P)

liJ

H-

t’H

-IH-

li0

-IP1

Pi0

CDH

LIIPi

IP1CD

010

tQI

CDIH

H•

LICD

k<

P1Iii

•IH

hj

Page 388: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

C)

1)

C)

C)

()C

)C

)C

)C

)C

)C

)C

)C

)C

)()

iiI-

Q0

00

00

0H

HH

HH

HH

0H

-H

IJ)H

C)C)

C)rt

0H

-.-

-

IC

,)-

-Q

F-

KD

PJ

tI)’

-<D

iQ

CD

—0(0

I’E

’iC

D‘tJ

PJ

frU

JJIC

!)H

jh

IIi-

IP’

H-

H-H

i-

-‘d

U)

Ci)

CI)

OC

)CI)

H-C

sIi

-Ic

H-

ktC)

C)0

(Drt

U)•‘-<

ct

(DtQ

rtQ

rt

H—

IH--

rt<

-II

-<(D

Ort

NH

-C

rI)(D

PJ(D

Q.H

(DC

FH

-1<

Ict’

CD

H-

IH

-U

)H

-Q

QO

CD

IC

)IH

FU

)0

H-

P3

-—

H--

H-

0Irt

1(0(

1)I

H-

Cl)

-(D

Ui-

ON

•.

C)

I(D

Ip

i1

)2p

iIc

x-

U)I

H-

1wrt

I—.-’

•=

Ht

rtrt

C!)

0PH

HH

IjU

)fr

iH

-CD

Hpi

PJ’

ctC

DH

P•

H-

‘C)

Cl)

Ipjç

iI(D

z-,j

0—

CD

P3C)

CC

)

IH

-C

)U)

H-

Cr

CD

U)

“C

)H

-CU

)

Cr.

!)Iç

IP3

’IH

-q

.Q0

P3

H-i

-]i

<IH

-H

C!)

IIC

Dr-

rçi

40

H-

H-C

D.

<H

-.

IP)IU

)’tH

-11

P3C)

Cr

J)

piU

)Ii•

tIH

I

c-r

P3(

1)C)

H.

H(-F

CD

JP

)Iii

—H

-LQ

H(D

H.

HO

H-

(1)H

1pH

-C)

(D

-H

•Q

i-Q

-P

)I

H-

P3(

1)L

J-

dU

)P

)H

-CD

HO

HH

.C

DiC

flC

)•.

C)Z

O(D

CI)

CD.

01-C

DC

tU

)-

H-

CD

•.

Li

H(I

)U)C

DH

aU

)CJ)

CDC

I)b

PC

lHH

-C

DP

3C

l)’-

]U

)HH

.IH

-H

CDQ

CD

CH

-C

rH

1(1)

p)

.C

)H-

CD

HH

-H

C)C

)C

Dj

‘DO

(-CD

H11

IU)

WC

r<H

-H

1(1)

OH

HF

1i

—H

-•

H-

O<

HIC

rCD

WH

CD

Cb

cçu

CDH

-Cr

CDC

F(0

H-

CD

DU

):4

U)H

Cm1

Lil

iH

-••

0

U)

L-

U)

‘tC

D(D

p..

•H

-Q

)

H•

IL

’i

$C

D-

CD

çtC

P3

CD0

!•h

H-

(QL

iJ,

Cl)

H-

IC

D•Q

’C

D10<

rn

U)H

M-

CDU)

H-

HIm

1HC

DL

’I’

U)

(DC

D‘-<

ICD

m1

PH

--

H-,

.jH

-H

OC

cP

Cr

CH

-O

CDH

<C

l)<

IC

PiI>

J‘H

P3

(DC

CCD

‘O

(D

-lH

pi•::

m1

CO

CrC

DC

DH

-C)

CCD

(00

m1

P3C

=CD

po

CDC

Dp

3-

CD

C0

U)“°

(DC

Do

CD

iOrr

m1

0C

DC

rL

IJIl

HC

1)

Cl)H

-0

pC

rH

F-]

PJC

D0C

D•0

H..

IICD

m1C

D“J

1(1)

‘SD

,‘S

DC

i0

H-

1i

CX)

Hpj

U)

CD‘S

DH

CC)

l-

H-

H‘t

H-

1IL

XIC

)H

‘SD‘S

D)

-p

.

HCl)

18H

WH

IH‘d

ij

Cfl

4Ct

)C

)H

-Cl)

II(D

ICC

D0

30

HH

H.

Cr

P3

HP

30

‘1-C

l)H

IH-’

-]m

1H

-htJ

(DO

CDp3

H-

HH

-IU

)H-

P3

Cr

P30

U)H

II

P3P3

Irr

H-

CD0

U)CD

H-

U)&

P3C

)C

)CD

p.

P3b

HH

-CD

Cl)C

X)p

.H

-—

0IJ

(DC

Dm

1•

HP

3H

Cr

•‘-<

••••

P3-

0m

1•H

U).

.-

p.H

—J

‘-<

Page 389: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

Cramer, Stephan. “Samar NGOs Position On: Selective or TotalLogging Ban?” Draft. Mimeo. July 1990, pp.1-9.

Cribb, R. “The Politics of Environmental Protection in Indonesia.”Working Paper No. 48. Australia: Monash University, 1988.

Crouch, Harold. The Army and Politics in Indonesia. Revised ed.Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1988.

Crouch, Harold. “Generals and Business in Indonesia.” PacificAffairs 48, no. 4 (Winter 1975-76) , pp.519-540.

Crouch, Harold. “Patrimonialism and Military Rule in Indonesia.”World Politics 31 (July 1979) , pp.571-87.

Darusman, Dudung. “The Economic Rent of Tropical Forest Utilizationin Indonesia.” A Paper Presented at the National Seminar onthe Economic Aspect of the Forestry Business in Indonesia, theAssociation of Forest Concessioners and the Ministry ofForestry. Jakarta, October 6-7, 1992.

Dauvergne, Peter. “Patron-client Politics and Natural ResourceAllocation and Management in the Third World: A Case Study ofthe Timber Industry In The Malaysian States of Sabah andSarawak.” Unpublished Course Paper. Department of PoliticalScience, University of British Columbia, 1992.

Dauvergne, Peter. “The Politics of Deforestation in Indonesia.”Pacific Affairs 66 (Winter 1993-94), pp.497-518.

Dauvergne, Peter. “Japanese Domestic Environmental Policy Making:An Examination of the Role of the Liberal Democratic Party.”M.A. Research Essay. Ottawa: Carleton University, Departmentof Political Science, 1991.

Dauvergne, Peter. “The Failure of Forestry Management in Thailand:Politics Behind Deforestation.” An unpublished paper presentedat a SEADOC Seminar, Centre for Southeast Asian Research,University of British Columbia, January 27, 1993.

De Guzman, Raul P. and Ref orma, Mila A., eds. Government andPolitics of the Philippines. Singapore: Oxford UniversityPress, 1988.

De Guzman, Raul P., Brillantes, Alex B., Jr., and Pacho, Arturo G.“The Bureaucracy,” in Guzman and Reforma, eds., Government andPolitics.

De Guzman, Raul P., Reforma, Mila A., and Panganiban, Elena M.,“Local Government,” in Guzman and Ref orma, eds, Government andPolitics.

379

Page 390: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

1’i

IrJL’

iLi

iLi

iLi

iIi

H-

H-

C)0

00

00

CDCl)

U)U)

H-

CD0

0LQ

t-9)

Cl)Cl)

CDII

H9)

HCD

CD9)

U)U)

--

00

CD-

0H

C)H

U)

U)

II°

H-IO

-]

‘•tS

(.QH

’-<

HIQ

0P

ICiD

$)rt

$Jr

?Q

•-O

DtIM

H-

‘nH

-Q

C-F

-co

tyZ

I(D

CD

Dir

t-frfr

HC

-t$

Jrt$

)1

9)

IC

-9)i9)0

•U

)U)

cx

CD

H-

IH

-CD

‘oIi-

’(D

O-

rt-i

bD

ç‘1

QI-i

PC

-FCD

U’

0Irt0

(DC

)w

ipi

U)C

DF

C-t

Qc1

IP)H

I’—

O•

L’J

H-

—‘d

iCD

H-

•Irt

U)H

-qI

H-

ICD

i0C

DiP

)U

93’-

Cl

‘0$)

i’iP

U)

ICD

(D-

0j

$)H

cIC

D9-’

i9)i

H-U

)$)I$’

I-

H’

(D

PC

i).L

QC

DH

H-

{Q

i$

pc-t

C?

-Q1

Ci)

IH-

CDC-

FC-

FQ

C-F

p.

p<1

C)

H-

HH

-H

P$1

U)IH

-p

.H

HH

(DU

).C

D’

10H

-iH

C-F

3rt

I(D

<‘

CD0

q-

0(V

,H

-0

I-’-

Cp.

H-

lU)’

WCD

.$i

.iU

)o

2‘

‘“

-

CD09)

H-

H$

)H

0H

-’Iir

tC

DC

-tP

HCD

•$)C

i)=

pip

9,p

.H

q-

H-H

F]

HO

‘U

)9)

H-$

lO

H-t1

0(1

)p

.tP

i0

H-I

lL

XJ

$1$

)C

D9)

pit

!)O

CD

Il

CDCD

LQ

$)

IIC

DQ

.Op

QH

U)H

PC

-Fp)

U)p

.$

)C

D(O

HCD

rt

‘d

H-C

-F’

0H

.H

-0H

-O

0U

)H

P0

<-

00

(V

O0

IlC

-9jO

U)H

Ok

<Q

H0

IlH

-U

)p.

OH

C-F

p9)

-

•H

CD••

•C

fl

CDH

-HC-

FH

--0

p.

9)P

H-

3CD

H-

,-H

C-F

0U

)0

CQ

HL

XJ

rF

p.

CL)

:3U

)U

)C

U)

9)C

I)3

$)

C-F

U)

9)

H-

U)H

--

H-C

DU

)(I)

CD0

IH

9)•C

-F

9)0

•<

9)

H-C

DU

)rt

c-t

Il

CD

H-

H-

Irt4U

)0C

D(V

P)

-•‘‘

dQ

00

gC

D9)

L9)

C-F

Cl)

(VU)

Lii

-p

.(i)

HC

-F

IX

J0

H0i)•

PH

-C

-FU

)CD

(1)0

-.

CD

rto

C-F

CD

H-

‘-<

9)0

F]H

-H

-‘O

IlI-

]I-h

rttr

HIl

U)

HH

H

II‘1

-O

0”

H“C

l)H

-C

DIl

OH

U)C

)Il

Ci)

U)

CD

CDC

IF

]0

Il$)

P)

HU)

Q

U)pO

CD

C-F

HP

••

‘.D

C-t

CI)

’—]

HH

CD

U)rF

°U)

OIl

IpIl

CD

’nj

H-

9)C

-t

.C)

0H

--10

$CD

HCD

()‘-d

CH

-Il

U)U)

•U)

rrp.

)C)

Fj

JCl)

p.CD

•O

C-

CIH

•.

3H

-Iii

OH

H-

CD

IlO

H9)

H,C

DC

D9)

CDH

H-

U)-

,HH

-bt

Il0

•F]

.U

)HIl

CD

9)ip

.-

H-

oU)

lCDC-

F0

9)

9)9)

Lii

09)

CI)

U)

9)

PH

-o

’p.

19)

9)CD

U)p

.H

JCD

C-F

HC

CD

-.j

9)H

-Ic

<1H

-fl

?‘nO

H-

?;1•

Il.9

)Id

H-

OH

HO

0CD

HC

)H

-.H

p.c-

t-

L’J

IlU

)CD

H-

iU

)h

-CD

PH

’nI

-to

4P

Il

$)p

j•

Ci)

<H

OIl

C-F

IIli

j9)9)

C-F

H.

D$)

CDU)

C-FC

DH

OH

-H

(Vi9

)H

-0

PU

)0

‘Il

p.r

-FQ

IMH

-Cl)

‘-O

HCD

i°Il

CQ

C-F

HC

DH

-H

U)M

OH

-,‘

(V

0H

-Il

lrtp

.P

U)

H-

IH

-0

C-F

H-

CD9)

(D

iII

CD

CD

IrF

C-F

IF]

OIlO

—U

)OH

-iU

)CD

C-F

U)

H-i

1OL

Q-

‘H

ip

.H

p.

C-r

p.

-C-F

9)1(i)

CD

Page 391: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

rJrJ

Li

L’J

Li

Lii

Li

Lii

Li

Li

Lii

HH

H-

HH

CD9-’

HH

-9)

H-

Ct

0H

HC

tC

tCD

CDCD

CDH

--

Cl)H

-9)

I-II

0dfl0-

H--

HL

i9

)I

IHW

Io--

H-t

flIiw

ICI)

wfl

u)

rt

Ct9)

L’Jw

‘°-

:3I’

-co

9)Ii—

nLi

Q‘d

Ho

Io

Io

-Ij

9)

H-C

Drt

‘-dH

-0Q

0Li

w.Q

i0

I’-o

I3

si:

3Ii-

IF-i

‘iI9

)C)<

u)H

9)

HCD

H-u)-

(ñ(D

CO

CD

ila

IW

Ic

IX)-

H1<

1-fr

-i--

IQW

OH

(-i-

Cl)

H‘—

s.I’i

9)0

Ct

Li9

)CD

HH

-fl

9)C

D-Q

tQ0

Q4

-d

JH

<d

IC

tCt

(I)H

--i-

w•o

pJ(

l)C

[1lc

-t9)

I9)C

tO

H-L

i0

I9)

ri-H

-9)

Ci-

0

CtC

t01

.H

t9

)H

59)

I:3.

w.

HCD

Ci>H

-C

tH

<H

-lw

013

:3U)

0W

150

CDcn

9)cr

,

0H-

IH

‘•-<P

-’ri-

59)

Hfr

d9

IQC

DC

I)C

t9)0

QH

--t,

(l)

‘-

5i-

o•

cd

Hp

9)

w5H

wu,W

CtI

—.

00

9)Q

IH

Ct

9):

3C

DIH

-H

-0

I’

Li

F.<

rtC

tH

-’d

9)

M(0

15

H><

0H

-=

H-

IH

-9)

0J3

09)

9)H

1wH9)

H-

(00

Ct

H-

oi.o

0:35

0(00

9)

Ct

MIQ

HCD

I-

hi<

9)0

cQ

.Ci-

:3_Q

0U

)9)

.CD

9)9)

Lii

rCD

CD0

HH

HH

-5

:3

wH

Ct

Iw

9)•

Ct

HH

-H

-Cl)

1.0

(09)0

9)C

D(0

0N0

0C

D9

)Ct

9)a

)5

5Q

9)

.?0t-t CD

Op

O9

)q9)

9)P

H-

U)9)

Hç)H

(DH-

Ct

I-h

:39)

-9)

-

H-

iH

-H

9)0

•.

Ct

0i-

9)

9)P

9)

flu)

Pfl

CD

’W

aW

H-

dr

H•

0•9

)(000cr

0C

t°r-tN

Li

09)

H-p

I-h

9)

:3

q:3

Ct

0Q

0C

tH

(D

09

)<

U)

CD

CD

Ct

:3tI-<

:

pC

t<

frQ

CD

5D)

9)

I(J)C

D1.0

0p

H-

fr0

H=

H-

iW:3

1.D

:3(l

)C

DI

pCD

9)9

)O

°H

-’

5:3

:30

$)

•0

-‘i

Hoc

-i-

]I

‘ni-]

H-

CD

H-

0Li

jC

tcr

0H

-C

D•Q

0-

-w

9)CD-

Ct

MH

.‘rJ

H-H

oC

DH

-IH

9)

0:3

HI

(0

frti

too

CDl-

9)

H-

H9)

‘-1P

Ct

Cl)1.

00

ww

Qw9)

IIU)

(1)H

-Li

iH

H-

Ct

p

0W

Ifi

1130

i’fl

I’J9<

9)iV

ilH

-fl

CD9)

CtH

9)O

(0

p•

I1DC()

9)

I’i1(0

Ip<

9)

CD

ht1

IoH

-IIU

)9)

wt9)

••H

oi-

--C

D-

‘1Q

H-

CtH

dI

sI

H-l

i13

U)

Ct

(0-

CD9)

—I

Cl)l>

013

‘H

C,)

Ct

HU

)d0Q

HF

-Ct

9)U

)5

H-

$)I

-hC

tH

-13h

sol

9)

NCD

CD<

Ct

Ct

130

‘<0

IIs

H-

Ct

(0i

lCDCD

=H

Cl)-

9)I

•I

HI

9)U)

51(0

IH-

Ct—

.Cl)

‘tj

Ct

I’-9)

H0

0I

1<

flH

U)1

.0I0

ri-H

IH

-1.

0H

-0

19)IH

--

0(1)

•-

I-

HH

9)H

--

Hii

fr

Li

13cD

9)

1wo

9)1.0

:3:3

IU)

-°0

oIP

109)

fr9

)0

(00

9)CD

Wrt

IH-

•9)

0C

DCD

IO

0U

1C

0IU

)0H

-li

U)—

H-

I0

U)0

1I-t

’U)

-U

)•l

•‘<

HC

tri-

U)-0

li••

CD

-C

t

Page 392: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

00

00

C)Ix

j1r

JIi

jiJ

htj

p)pi

cuii

IIH

HH

LJ

III

IIII

PJCT)

CDCl)

CDH

--

III-

H-

H-

--

Cl)

C)C)

Cl)Cl)

CDCD

Qc-tI

H-Iij

cf

MH

-I1

HR

’O

LiH

-C

)C

l)H

Il-C

l)M

CI)

H>

’U1

O<

OCD

IPO

wU

1[-

hIP

)D

)H

-co

bc-t

Hc?

iCD

rtC

DI

H--

llH

-Q

Hll

IH

ll

H-ç

1H

-C

)H

-I<

Q()

Cr°

(IC

DF

HH

Jq

-0rr

HIH

-llQ

H-

CD

X-

CD

HC)

IH

-H

H--

c1<

C)C1

rt

H-

H-I

ll0

NC

llU

)1

[T

)IW

LIJ

CD

CD

CI)

CD

HIO

CD

CD

lCD<

L’J

ciIH

-H.

llC

D‘d

Io

in.

ICDC

)C

DH

-ll

I’C

DH

ili

H-IQ

U)’

rrIP

-Jj

1’J

IC)

0H

j1Q

‘-<

<iI

CD

CD

5I

tij

H-C

)-

rtC

DC

)P

JI

rtj

1D

Q(D

HIj

CD

IOll

HCD

OC

Dll

HlO

CH

HH

IH

-H-

H-

11

)0I’

tJH

-QCD

It

Ti)

HC

DP

JH

CD

CD

H-

IH

Hçl

•H

-‘o

Iiq

H-

CFH

-p.

llC

FIH

-CF

ICD

pjH

-CD

H-

In

H-

CDH

Hll

‘H

H-pj

H-

=H

-C

DH

QI0

wo

°H

C)

CD

H-

ICfl

‘-

Hpi

QH

-pi

pip

,L

!<•C

f)i

DQ

C)Q

<H

-CF

pjH

-O

HpiC

Hll

CD-

llW

0H

HC

DC

DC

Dz

—-<

CD

jC

l)H

-C

Dp

itti

•°

Cfl

0IJ

CD

Hp

jW

.H

XC

I)y

•C

Iiz

CI)

O-

,p

icr

CDP1

H-

3‘

HO

WH

H-(I)

cD

Wp

jC

FH

.Cl

)CD

HC

FC

DCI

)C

)C

all

IpiP1

CD

P1

H-

IHH

H

HC

F

Ij

H-

bd

CD

HCD

CDP1

H)

llL

hJ

P1:J

<(I

)C

OP

)H

CI)

P1°M

H-

CD

CD

IpiH

-(j)

-C

OW

H-

CF-ll

IH

-P

1H

-C

FCF

CD

WC

DW

CD

H-

CFH

-H

-H

-O

COCF

CFCD

COH

-H

-CD

P1Q

FllC

FP

-C

)pj

llC

)P1

llP

)H

-H

-H

-CD

CDc-i

.P

11)

CD

Cn

HC

Di

:jrj)

C)CD

OW

Cl)H

•C

Dq

HC

DH

HP

10

H-C

Dp,

llP

III

(I)H

-H

CDCF

CDC

Dll

çH0

P1

H-

CD

IIC

D<

HP

1C

DtI

JCD

-M

IIW

H-

9‘S

Os-

-H

-II

HH

F-]

H-

P1w

CL

pC

DH

CF

HC

DO

P1o

CI)

-H

’ll

C)

MH

-P1

iH

rr

CD

CDI

HH

‘dl

H-

WC

I)CD

c-r

CF

CD

IC

D•H

LXI

HC

DC

nIH

‘tIi

CD

CD

<iP

1H

(DO

HQ

I1

H-

LXI

T1

C-F

H-W

CD

llP1

P1lH

-0

•H

-CD

lIP

)H

CD

IIC

)pi

CD

CFH

IHO

IInIC

)H

HP1

10

ICIr

JD

T)c

--‘C

!)t3

IHI

CD

••‘-<

.QH

Fri

MiC

FO

ld)

HM

CO

IWH

H-

CF

ICaP

1:

Cl)

IC!)

•P

ill

IIIC

F‘-°

CO

CFH

-CD

H-

P1I

P1CX

)H

-H-

CFI

P1L

DH

PII

P10

IH-

CD

CD

plH

IH-3

[0lC

DO

ICF

MiIO

•F

-]

CFC

FIC!

)•C

FC

D10

••

P1I

COCI

)IC

DC

Cl)IC

FFX

JCF

Page 393: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

00

00

00

00

00

00

00

00

HH

-H

-H

-H

-H

-H

-H

-CD

IIH

HH

HH

H)

0CD

U)H

HH

HH

HH

NI-I

H-

U)H

-H

-H

-H

-H

-H

-H

O(D

IJ)t)

H-U

)fr

dP

)U)

H-r

i)‘d

U)

OU

)U

)CJU

)-<

‘jH

L’i

CI)

HC

IQ

j0

I°o

U)O

I0i-

i-

H-

CD

-C

DC

DO

OH

-H

CP

U)

flU

)<

H0

hD

H-C

DI-

IH

0H

-0IH

U)rr0

0w

H-

•CJ2

—C

Dct(

T)

0P.)

IH-

H-

PP

0IH

0

o(t)

IH

-O

H-•

HH

IH

JH

H-C

DH

OP3

OU

)C

D-t

0H

-P

rt

rtO

CD

U)C

1H

-P)

iOrT

P)

H-P

U)U

)P)

HQ

P.

I1

HF

-M

Q-

100-

U)O

tiH

ICD

(D°

HO

0H

-O

P)

00.

OO

-t

CD

IP)H

rt•

H-Q

lU)

0H

-CH

O0

CD

0P.)

3I

CD

•0

(.(D

-.

IHH

-P

JC

()

U)H

.r-rH

U)H

‘.O

HP

)OH

CD.

I-

qIrtW

H.

HH

-0

&Q

°rtp

j-

frH

-H

p.)

..

p.

P)•

HH

crb

CD

H0

IO

0C

Dt-

0P3

1)1

••

0Z

CD

pH

IP

’0

H-

:i-

‘-j

‘tiP

.)b

H-

HIC

DH

CD

(DC

D0

CD

P3

:(D

t.Q

Q(D

CD

0tIJ

PIII

P3

zJp

)j

P)(D

HH

O0H

-0

CD

HC

DH

QH

HC

P<

jH

‘.0‘d

PJ

CD0

(1)

U)(

Drt

U)=

rt

(DP

3P

IU)•

‘dH

PC

D-t

O(D

rtU

)CD

-çt

Iiç

CD

CI)

H(D

H0

ICD

CD

MC

D<

0H

-iH

-rtN

1’O

IH-

H,

P3rt

ti2

i-M

U)

rtH

-rt

-P3

H-

U)X

ji.

OH

H0

O<

ij

U)P

)..

QQ

(DtI

)H-‘:

°H

-C

DH

-O

P3

rt(D

OH

Ct

Hpi

‘.O

H-’

CD

aI

CDct

CD

rtC

D’O

.H-

Ui

U)P3

CD-‘

iI’d

U)L

P.I

U)0

HH

2,U

)•

•O

Lir

tIO

H-

H.t

i)C

!c-t

3(D

P)

CI)

H-H

-U

)b

0‘d

(•Q

U)H

HC

DH

-U

)-

wk

<fl

) I-L

JIC

tH)U

)H

-H

-•

CD0

HH

-Lxj

i.

i(I

)’‘.0

H-

.H

bCD

J(

H3

()C

Q0

IH-

Pi’

rJ‘1

3cj

pH

‘.00P

3(D

H-

O”<

OQ

io

o-

0H

H-

c-I-

iP

iH

-0’H

0H

U)

IU)o

OH

t3H

-Ib

’13

CD9

c-I

-CD

o,

-U

)0

I0

U)

OH

H

Hj

H-

H0H

OU)

PJI-

(Dc-

I-H

HIH

-HCD

0c1-(

D’t

Lil

U)

0-

HCD

H-

H-

10H

-P

Ml

H-

0U)

U)

CDP3

Lxi

H-

fri

H-

I’t)

H-

c-I-

‘1)H

CD1j3

-IO

3CD

10(1

)P

32C

DP

oCD

IH

U)

IHU

)C

D(D

H-

H0

U)

H-

P3M

lO

‘ii

HIH

-3

I0

lOP

)Q

(DP

)cH

aI-

H1P

3P)

U)

In

P30D

cIH

-0

IiIH

-0

Hh

0U)

3(1)

I(D

CD

(DIC

DP

3H

-O

H-

‘t

0c-I

-3

IU)

‘dU

)lU

)O

P30c-

o0

c-I-

CDH

3•

0C

DQ

•c-

I-H

-O0L

x1

H-

CD

CDH

c-ta

I-d

0II

-

IIii

Nc-I

-i-

0H

-Q

)H

-P3

H-

CDb

U)

QH

H-

Co

P-R

HH

Oc-f

frH

-i—

t,0

qH

-jc

--

(PH

--Q

H-

P3H

-0

Opi

-H

-0

0C

DjH

‘lc-t

H0CD

C)-

c-I-

‘.d

H(D

P3H

-P.)

H-

HH

H0

CDCl

)H

-1

Pi

HC

1(D

H-

U)0

CDC

ñO

0U

)U

)•P

3C

Dc-I

-0

C21c-I

-’CD

-00

P1P3

I-fl

H-

H-

H3

11H

(Q0

P3

jP3

CD

-O

P3(D

c-I

U)in

b1-d

c-I-

c-I-

CDH

-fr

iCD

IICD

0-

I-xj

P30

H-

U)H

-c-I

-rI-

’<O

CDc-t

0CD

I-O

HH

HU

)C

D00

‘1

HC

DH

-3

U)U)

CD‘-

3(D

‘-00

U)P3

U)H

-H

-c-I

-H

-U)

HP3

CDU)

Hc-I

-H

-c-I

-U)

CDP3

‘.0i

P3p

i0

H-

•c-I

-U

)U)

-H

-c-I

--

c-I-

c-I-

H-

U)

OC

DC

U)

0H

-H

H(D

3-

U)c-t

•=

10

-=

‘-<C

D•

3c-t

p•

U)

•U

)U

)

Page 394: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

Government of Japan. Ministry of Foreign Affairs. “The Forefrontof the Environmental Movement in Japan.” Tokyo: Government ofJapan, 1992.

Government of Japan. The Basic Environment Law. Law No. 91, 1993.Effective November 19, 1993.

Government of Japan. National Action Plan for Agenda 21. Internaldocument supplied by a MITI official. Tokyo: Government ofJapan, January 1994.

Government of Japan. Fourteen Proposals for a New Earth -- PolicyTriad for the Environment, Economy and Energy. Report by theSpecial Committees on Energy and the Environment: IndustrialStructure Council, Advisory Committee for Energy, IndustrialTechnology Council, 25 November 1992.

Government of Japan. “Japan’s Paper For Proposed Progress TowardsThe Year 2000 Target.” Presented at the International TropicalTimber Council, November 1991.

Government of Japan. National Action Plan for Agenda 21. Tokyo:The Government of Japan, January 1994. Internal documentsupplied by an official at MITI.

Graziano, Luigi. “Patron-Client Relationships in Southern Italy,”in Schmidt, et al., eds. Friends, Followers and Factions.

Gunes-Ayata, Ayse. “Clientelism: Premodern, Modern, Postmodern,”in Roniger and Gunes-Ayata, eds, Democracy, Clientelism andCivil Society, pp.19-28;

Haas, Peter M., Levy Marc A., Parson, Edward A. “Appraising theEarth Summit.” Environment 34 (October 1992), pp.7-36.

Hadi, Yusuf and Said, .Abas. “Planting Indigenous Tree Species ToRehabilitate Degraded Forest Lands: The Bintulu Project,” inAhmad Said Sajap et. al., eds. Indigenous Species for ForestPlantations. Proceedings of a national seminar, Faculty ofForestry, Universiti Pertanian Malaysia. Serdang, Malaysia,23-24 April 1992.

Hall, Anthony. “Patron-Client Relations: Concepts and Terms,” inSchmidt, Steffen et al., eds. Friends, Followers and Factions.

Hall, June D. and Hanson, Arthur J. A New Kind of Sharing: Why WeCan’t Ignore Global Environmental Change. Ottawa:International Development Research Centre, 1992.

Handa, R., ed. Forest Policy in Japan. Tokyo: Nippon RingyoChosakai (Association for Research and Publishing on JapaneseForestry), 1988.

384

Page 395: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

iii

00

H-

CDCD

CDPi

PiPi

P)Pi

PiH

(pi

pi-<

U)(I)

IIII

HCl)

.<ct

CDCD

P1P)

U)H

-II

0P1

CDU)

U)L

JU

.0

CD

-JH

-ct

tji

icrI-

’-i

i-

wc-

fruJ’

)(,

‘)Q

ixjj

Q(t)Q

iQ

ij

Pl

0ct

CD

rFIO

HC

DC

DO

H0

P1Ic

H-O

ct

HP

H-i

bhi

crC

DII

-hi

<0

I<

U)11<

IH011H

-O

<00

•ct-1-

CDct

P)11

(l)

2)2)

IH-

IH

Irt.

-Q-

IH-b

-Ii.j

II

P1

’rs

CD

°Ic

t2

tflH

-IC

P111

1HC

DC

DIJ

11i-

ICD

q•

CD

H-

iti

11

C)

0i•.

CD

H1n’

-to

pi

CD

I2)1

11

oIH

-C

DN

I°°w

dC

I10(0

U)[

lIpJ

CD

ct11

10Cl

)jH

pl11

I<

H.

U)U)

ID)Q

çt

•I-

iIi

2)1<

CD2)

Cl)H

-CD

Lxi

IIi

H-

lCD-

PLQ

Ip.i

rtH

CM

1p

Hct

po

0’-

]-

oq

••(0

PI(

0

ICctj

U)CD

PP

)H

ctHI

Q<

H1

1.

I-h

CD

‘H

H-

c’.P

I11

tort

CD1tJ

CD‘<

0Irt

H-j

1—F

•H

-C

j)U)

HI

‘1<

Hq

H11

rtH

0HId

CD

2)H

-‘Q

CD

pi

CctH

-0

•.

j:

ICD

CO

P1

-U)

P)°

HL

’l1

11

LQ

HtJ

ri-

HM

11

H

<p

iU)

I.

C-

HC

DtJ2

H-

HH

QQ

2JL

iQ

Cl)

H11

1:J

lCD‘I

toCD

H‘d

oP

iMlH

-bb

Hpi

rtrtH

(011

rtH

-‘i

0P)

ID)0

PJbxj

C)H

Ho(0

I-]

U)o

(0

OC

F<

M-

H-

HH

-‘1

H-

Ij

‘H

CD0

CDart

0M

IO

21

fl)

(D

QIH

CD

a0

I’

tw

g-j

0a-

HMpi

rt..

P1cr

•CD

WlD

rtH

-H

Qb

dC

DH

“ci

HIL

rJ0

art

CD

H-P

1U

)(0

<O

W‘o

frxj°

CD

-b‘-

<U

)O

HC

X)U

)03

H-

0(t

11

(0

M0

1-f

l

QU

i0

0<

11

‘<H

U)H

-0

(0

-U)

•CD

o-

q11

CD

M11

110o

H0

pii

-ci

o11”

0Oi

2)M

(D

(DC

)U)

U)C

DCD

t’ç

U)

PH

-CD

CD

(Dc-

FH

-W

c-C

D‘.O

piH

Hrj

U)U

)C

DoH

’d

•H

-H

-C

)11

c-F

-H

0(0

-H

H<

Mi

tOrt

c-rU

)•

P1

(D

pH

ct

1.Lx

i•

H11

.CD

•U

)C

)Q

CD

rF(0

rF‘2

1pit

t)U

)ji

Hto

I-t,

HCD

DG

)-

]i

j(0

CiH

I)

0Z

QH

OH

ct-C

DoP

)()

pi’

ti0

M:

i-t,

11-

9)U)

CD

HH H

-O

H-’

d‘

U)P

lL

U)

11CD

‘ci

0H

MH

-H

-li

Hct

2) HU

)P

)O

c-Fc-

c-t

i)j

2)9)

CD

VI

Wb

IP

1H

-‘<

OH

-U)

Cl)

(0f-

FP

<0

CDU)

oo

1a

Lii

lCDU)

‘ti

°tO

CD91

2)Lx

iLx

iL

ijL

Q0H

H-{

0U)

UiQ

P11

.Lc-t

CD

(0U)

HO

p<

XH

-•

oP

1<

H-’

<CD

<0H

-0110

12)

CDC

DP)

tJ<

H-

i.]H

-H

-HT

M‘d

c-tI

M•

0H

..P

H-

‘d(D

’‘1

1100

CD

IQ=

0•H

‘H

P)

0II

CDIH

11C

LII

ciH

-°O

11

H!

F]P

)’X

jM

HP

JI

0U

)-

c-F‘<

‘OO

Oog

CD‘D

ctC

f)L

QM

U)

‘1

CD0

CDP

)M

H-

CDW

H-H

-OI

CDP

lO

CD

H-

Iicli

-]‘-

<M

CD

ac-F

pic

-t‘.

Dc-F

O,,-]

P1H

CD0

Cc-F

•C

c-rU

)c-

t•C

DrtI

-••

U)

Mi

Mi

•ct

•••

CD•.

PJc-t

HC

D•

1H

1U

)3iC

D

Page 396: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

HH

HH

HH

HIH 10 IL’

irr

CD0

00

00

00

rr0

toc-i

-to

I’-

CDc-i

-H

-0

IH-(

1)H

Od)

CC

DxiG

)H

xIC

DH

H(D

‘-<

c<

hH

F-()

IC,)

-c-r

Ij

Irtto

ooow

IiCD

ti)Jto

(DO

D)

‘D0U

)Iii

(D

to(D

OJ(D

D:3

’-

IcC

D-

ItOH

-II

‘OI

H-

I1<

H-

H-

(DII

H-

‘0II

H-

I-h

H-

HH

-HII

O(D

0I

i(D

’-<

P-’C

DW

Qt1

PJ

I0C

D’

J)

rt(D

P)

OC

D)

QQ

JI-

i-d

Ii

0—

LIH

’IIi

H-to

•toi

CO

IIi

PJc-i

-(D

CD

ri-

13

HO

Hc-i

ICH

-H

OO

CD

(D0H

-0

H

II-

DH

-It

od

p:

(Q

to

toil

toH

C)h

U)p

HIL

IJH

r-ti

-p

dlCD

H-

<CI

)LQ

oH

-IH

-H

-H

-H

-H

-ci

-0

H-

1H

-d

IpH

-Cl)

C)P-

0H

Ito

IP

(D

0o

P)P

PH

-ri-H

tdrtP

)It

od

IIH

-C

DII

IH

-d

H-

1<

HH

-H

-H

c-i-

H-

1<

c-i-

•H

-Ic-

rH

CDH

1I-I

0H

Ippi-

riti

c-i-

cU)

dc-i

-H

CI

c-i-

PJH

Ito

toqdO

-to

c-i-

H-

(l)t

oC

to

H0H

--

0.

pU

)0

IL

c-i-c

-i--.

IIH

-C

DP

II

iri-

:IIo

c-i-‘-°

•to

H-H

-cl

F.<

CD

to<

HII

<II

PJ

H-H

.O

00

to0

H-

IIjtH

PH

H-C

0H0

ri-

ti-

C))

c”ti

•c-

i-H

-L

i--

Mi

CJ

HP

JO

LIIII

IQH

Hlo

‘Ic-i

-H

-C

-t

Ov

0

HH

-Jti)

HtI

).jj

PJL

tiI]

‘rt

(D

II<

CDH‘

0C

DQ

0O

tOc-i

CD(D

Pi

Cl)CI)

‘li-

IC

IIL

\)c-t

CD

to

PC

H-H

JC

?d

PII

H-t

o0

H-

•Q

IIpiO

CD

II

HC

HP

iN

H<

H-

i-pi.

HII

c-i

-(I)

IIH

’1

CD

H-

Hw

OQ

H-lI

-t31

(ii

•‘tl

prr

HH

H-Q

:H

-<

•H

H-

HC

)‘O

Hp

JQ

_

(D

0(D

Hfr

hW

ijC

DP1

wO

H-

H-

0W

OCl)

(Dc-

i-

_

-ii

--

P)

iII

ow

H-C

DQ

..

CD

0H

CD

rp

iip

i:i

pJH

O<

HH

.d

Ci)

Irt

HH

-H

P)f

—P1

H0.

CD

••H

H-

(Dc-

i-to

C)C

DIc

-ito

H-H

CD

hj

O<

M(l

)H

•.H

CII

pc-

i-<

jII

0C

DII

CD

c-i-

HIH

Hp1

IpiC

DC

DH

Io

HH

O-i

--<

toC

O(D

Hcv

PJC

DH

-H

-c-i-

‘—-

ir-i

-H

P1

too

to

OH

H-

c-i-C

DIi

C) P10c-i-

ct

(DC

DH

P1to

II0

Hc-i

-j

III(

DP

Iti

OH

IIc-

i-s

c-i

-Ic-i

-O

iH

HC

DL

00p1

P)

0CD

HtC

DIH

-(D

•P1

wc-i

-(D

CD

H-C

c-i-

pP1

P1H

-H

-to

0lCD

P1II

lu-

H-

toM

P1

oH

-H

HCl

)C

DIH

(DCD

IoCl

)P1

HC

HH

u-

‘dI

H]

-H

IM

1rj

‘ti

a°td

CD

c-i-I

Cto

CDH

II-

tooII

H0

OII

I0

CDc-i

-oI<

tQZ

P1

bIII

0P

1H

10

W(C

)c-i-

NIH

c-i-

HH

1(1)

P1C)

Ic-C

D1O

pH

-Ij

HIH

—C

l)II

HII

c-i

-(D

tqC

DH

-CD

CDc-

1c-i-

CD

HH

-ic-

i-ic

-i-

Hc-i

-‘-

<C

P1L

QC

toiI

H-

Cl)

IC

DL

IdP

IP1

P1b

II(D

H-

Oil

)H

-I

c-i-

IIP

1III

IIc-

i-IH

0O

CD

0P

1II

OP

1P1

H-1

P1P1

0100

p1—

IP1

H-C

DH

-IO

HH

-M

-IIM

IH

-M

H•

HIP

fr-t

i--t

H.

“IH

H.’

“H

(D

Page 397: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

Indonesian Ministry of Forestry and FAO. Indonesian TropicalForestry Action Programme: Executive Summary. Jakarta,Republic of Indonesia and the United Nations, 1991.

Indonesian Department of Information. Indonesia 1990: An OfficialHandbook. Jakarta: Department of Information, Republic ofIndonesia, 1990.

Innoprise. Innoprise Corporation Sdn Bhd: 1991. Kota Kinabalu:Innoprise, 1992.

Inoue, Makoto. “Who’s Killing the Rain Forests?” Japan ViewsQuarterly (Autumn/Winter 1992), pp.12-13.

INTEP Newsletter. Tokyo, International Environmental PlanningCentre, no. 1 (February, 1993).

International Tropical Timber Council. “The Promotion ofSustainable Forest Management: A Case Study In Sarawak,Malaysia.” ITTC (VIII)/7, May 1990.

International Tropical Timber Council (ITTC) Report. Submitted byMission Established Pursuant to Resolution I (IV). “ThePromotion of Sustainable Forest Management: A Case Study inSarawak, Malaysia.” ITTC (VIII)/7, May 7 1990.

Inyaku, Tomoya. “A Step Forward? Debt-for-Nature Swaps.” l4PO:Japan-Asia quarterly Review 23, no. 3 (1992), pp.46-49.

Islam, Shafiqul, ed. Yen For Development: Japanese Foreign Aid andthe Politics of Burden-Sharing. New York: Council on ForeignRelations Press, 1991.

ITCI (International Timber Corporation Indonesia).International Timber Corporation Indonesia. Jakarta: ITCI,1992.

Itochu. “Global Environment Problem and Itochu Corporation.”Internal document. Tokyo: Department of Global Environment, 30November 1993.

ITTO (International Tropical Timber Organization). “The Promotionof Sustainable Forest Management: A Case Study In Sarawak,Malaysia.” Report Submitted to the International TropicalTimber Council. ITTC (VIII)/7, May 1990.

Ives, J. and Pitt, P.C. Deforestation: Social Dynamics inWatersheds and Mountain Ecosystems. London: Routledge, 1988.

Jackson, Karl D. Traditional Authority. Islam, and Rebellion: AStudy of Indonesian Political Behaviour. Berkeley: Universityof California Press, 1980.

387

Page 398: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

Jackson, Karl D. and Pye, Lucian W., eds. Political Power andCommunications in Indonesia. Berkeley: University ofCalifornia, 1978.

Jackson, Karl D. “Urbanization and the Rise of Patron-ClientRelations: The Changing Quality of InterpersonalCommunications in the Neighbourhoods of Bandung and theVillages of West Java,” in Jackson and Pye, eds., PoliticalPower.

Jackson, Karl D. “Bureaucratic Polity: A Theoretical Framework forthe Analysis of Power and Communications in Indonesia,” inJackson and Pye, eds., Political Power.

Jackson, Karl D. “The Political Implications of Structure andCulture in Indonesia,” in Jackson and Pye, eds., PoliticalPower.

JANNI (Japan NGO Network on Indonesia). Reshaping “Development”:Indonesia-Japan Relation from Grassroots’ Perspective.Proceedings of the INGI Kanagawa Symposium. Tokyo: Japan NGQNetwork on Indonesia, 1993.

Japan Plywood Manufacturers’ Association. Plywood Industry inJapan. Tokyo: Japan Plywood Manufacturers’ Association, 1993.

Japan Plywood Manufacturers’ Association. Plywood Industry inJapan. Tokyo: Japan Plywood Manufacturers’ Association, April1994.

Japanese Forestry Agency. Forestry White Paper: Fiscal Year 1992,Summary. Tokyo: Government of Japan, 1993.

Japanese Ministry of Foreign Affairs. The Forefront of theEnvironmental Movement in Japan. Tokyo: Government of Japan,1992.

Japanese Ministry of Foreign Affairs. Japan’s ODA 1993. Tokyo:Association For Promotion of International Cooperation, 1993.

Japanese Building Contractors Society. “Methods To Reduce TheConsumption of Plywood Forms Which Use Tropical Timber.”Internal document. Tokyo, Building Contractors Society, Boardof Directors, 19 February 1992.

JATAN (Japan Tropical Forest Action Network). “Republic of Korea.”Draft paper presented at the International Workshop for Forestand Environmental Preservation in Asia-Pacific. Seoul,February 18-21, 1994, pp.1-9.

JATAN. “Asia-Pacific Forests.” November 1993. Presented at theWorld Rainforest Movement Meeting, New Delhi, India, April

388

Page 399: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

qq

qq

qq

qq

qq

o0

00

HH

HH

HH

HCD

non

cmcm

cmcm

opi

pi-

U)U)

U)•

dirt

-Q1

j-

flI

IJ

rtdiJpj

n2Q

pi

1(I)-

(I)

H‘d

CD

oIc

11’i

tdo

(1)

ibc

o9J

j.

.çii

çu-

W1H-

P1i

CDO

I’-

‘i<

CD

çL

ICD

pipipi

Hh

qIrj

CC

’)iC

fl-

<D

iP3

1<<

diC

—-C

DO

(D

I‘r

j‘D

H-l

1H

PJP

i•

UlU

){

•I

rtI

IH-

CDC

DIW

CO

CD

U)

dH

H-C

’lix

ip)

<iP

OC

D-C

DIi

(D

-0

I-H

I-Ir

tP

3Q

rt

PO

IP3

U)P

3c

(D

M0

q=

‘H

-<

IOC

D0

0H

‘H

cm

d’-

<P

)iIU

)0

-r

CDH

P3C

DC

Dp)-

çt

CD

CDCD

CDH

CD

-

rtL

’i.

rrhiP

’C

DH

tJ

••

=I

çt

HU

)rr

tflj

=Ii

CD

I.<C

DH

-.<

qH

0d

CD‘1

PC

DC

D0

-

-:i

P3P

3i

CD

3C

0p

OH

-I1

CDp

iI-

pj

P3

H-

cmC

DH

-U

)pir

tP3

“Q

CD

HP3

cL

’1

C)zjH

-C

DC

DCD

CD

Hti

H-

-

•U

)U)

cm

4(D

xi

rt

Ow

CDCD

H-

P3

cm°

(Dj-

5C’

)P3

H--

“U

)-

CDi

)U

)P

30)

-rt

Cl)

rfl

0Q(D

H-

rr()

(-t

<C

-tW

CD

c-t

:i0

<q

CD

•ri-

CDC

DI<

iip

iOH

-C

DU)

HP

30

H-

(D

01I-

H-

H-

CFH

-H

QCF

H-.

<H

CD

_CD

HU

)H

rT

H-

0H

-H

-•

Hrt

H(I)

H-

0CD

iH

-H

-H

CD

QC

J)CF

k<

CD

HC

tC

DH

Cl)

0P3

CD

t?;7

j.‘-

pio

‘-<

w

-H

CDH

H-

P)C

DH

rt°

pi

or’

-.-

Ci)

c—

°a

HC

DH

-H

°<

P)

C)-

H-

U)C

DH

-n•pic

CD<

H-

H-1H

-•

Hip

i

C’-

P)H

HH

Qi-

H

U)

IC)

CD

H

IU

)HH

H-

IH

-H

-•

0U

)H

NC

)H

0ç-

trtH

H-

‘-<

CD

cm

OH

-0

H-C

FL

P3C

D-

-‘-

oCD

I‘-

<C

D‘or’-

P3=

(Di-

’0

-C

_1

I-h::

Iq

•O

P3—

lCDC

i)

H0

‘-<

cmH

CD

=ic

rH

<:

OC

Ddo

cm<

CD

rt

P3-

-r

c-

13C

DIQ

Ii-

ct•C

DCF

CD

H-

HC

DC

I)•.

ofr

-ti

Irt

IL\

)II

HH

--

P3CF

0o

C)

U)P3

IMi

IH

IcH

-P3

HFC

jqiI

H-

P1ZI

-Qc-r

(1)1

1‘H

-C

oC

DU

)H

H-

‘-.0

P3P

3H

H-I

0lCD

CI)$

.C‘-

<CD

(DP

3W

CD

CT

”0

CD

H-

OC

D‘-.

0CD

OO

IH-

IH

•p

JU

)H

H-

0P

3‘P

3IP

3IC

00

U)C

D•

-U

)-

•C

tI

HIH

IM-

1-t

iHi

Page 400: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

Jomo, K.S. “Logging, Politics, Business and the Indigenous Peopleof Sarawak.” Paper presented at the 5th Annual Conference ofNortheast Regional Consortium for Southeast Asian Studies,University of British Columbia, October 16-18, 1992.

Jukofsky, Diane. “Problems & Progress in Tropical Forests.”American Forests 97 (Jul/Aug 1991), pp.48-53.

Kahin, Audrey R. “Crisis on the Periphery: The Rift Between KualaLumpur and Sabah.” Pacific Affairs 65 (Spring 1992), pp.30-49.

Kalimanthu, K. Ramanathan. “The Sabah State Elections of April1985.” Asian Survey 26, no 7-12 (1986), pp.815-837.

Kamieniecki, Sheldon and Sanasarian, Eliz. “Conducting ComparativeResearch on Environmental Policy.” Natural Resources Journal30 (Spring 1990), pp.321-339.

Kanda, Hiroshi. “A Big Lie: Japan’s ODA and Environmental Policy.”ANPO: Japan-Asia Quarterly Review 23, no. 3 (1992), pp.42-45.

Kane, Hal. “Managing Through Prices, Managing Despite Prices,” inZaelke, Orbuch, and Housman, eds., Trade and the Environment.

Kano, Hiroyoshi. “The Structure of Japan-Indonesia Relations andthe Relations of NGOs of Both Countries,” in JANNI, Reshaping“Development”, pp.5-23.

Kartawinata, K. and Vayda A.P. “Forest conversion in EastKalimantan, Indonesia: the activities and impacts of timbercompanies, shifting cultivators, migrant pepper farmers andothers.” Ecology in Practice. Proceedings of the UNESCO - ICSAConference, Paris, September, 1981. Dublin: Tycooly, 1983.

Kaufman, Robert R. “The Patron-Client Concept and Macro-Politics:Prospects and Problems.” Comparative Studies in Society andHistory 16, no 1 (June 1974), pp.284-308.

Keidanren (Japanese Federation of Economic Organizations).Keidanren Global Environment Charter. Tokyo: Keidanren, April1991.

Keidanren. “Keidanren Policy and Activities for 1994.” Internaldocument. Tentative Translation. Tokyo: Keidanren, 4 January1994.

Keidanren. “Keidanren Nature Conservation Fund Makes First Pledgeto Conservation Projects.” Internal document. Tokyo:Keidanren, undated, acquired by the author April 1994.

Keidanren. Towards Preservation of the Global Environment.Tentative Translation. Tokyo: Keidanren, 27 May 1992.

390

Page 401: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

o0

H-

H-

H-

H-

CDCD

CDCD

H-

00

00

IIo

1CD

NN

Cl)

-.

----

H-

IQJ

IH-L

i1p

Jrt

HP

)0

IC,)

CIP

JH

Jt-’H

‘dH

HIH

-H0

)W

H-

ICD

i<H

-CH

jM

iQ0

ki

H-

IP)C

DQ

H-

I5H

lCDI

<IH

H-

IhH

-H

-CD

10H

-CD

CDIH

-CD

—)

ICD

I°t-

’-

CD

CD

HQ

II(P

CDIH

-IH

--

.I

WD

CD

IIQ

LQ

lCDP

J0

H)

IIC

DIj

CD

W1

Opir

tL’

J‘d

L\)

H-

ç-r

CDkm

(QCD

IH-

CDIi

CDC

DF

QM

P0

.H

-H-hI

HCD

rtC

DIC

D0C

DIH

-CD

0C

D0

0•

CDlC

D-.

‘•<

CD

pH

-P.’

lC

D0P

IHP

I;:d•

0H

CDcX

i•.

lCDrt

=W

CD

00

H-

-IH

-H

HO

P)

0M

0o

-.H

-qpH

13

H-r

tçt

P)

Cl-

-f-I

-O

QC

tH

rt

rJrr

IHI

H1C

DP

)p

jp

CD

.H

-Ct

P)

0()

0H

CD

CD

CD

H-

H-

HC

tP

)pi

Iq

H-

CD

CD

H-C

Dj

H-.

CD

çUH

CD

HC

t•H

-H

-CD

.ICD

bCD

p)C

DI-i

1H

-IC

D-I

P)P

HC

DC

DH

CD

P)C

Dpi

-

H-

HH

(.Q

HH

-C

DC

DC

DW

CD

OiQ

H-P

fl-H

-C

DC

0 C1

çt

Ct

•0

CDdC

tC

D(D

CD

CD

u-

03

Hj)

CD

P)C

DC

DH

CD

HC

D..

-P

J(D

CD

p,

-

P)H

CDCD

CD

HM

CD

1CD

P)C

D0C

D

Ctp

jCD

CD•

--

HQ

HC

D0

IIci

piH

OC

DO

CD

Ct

Wq

OH

Cl-

CD

0X

oil

-H

CD

CD

p.

U1P

JP

0B.

:C

D’<

-CD

piC

D..

Pp

LjH

pi

L.

HC

D--

CDII

-H

-iH

0H-

P)P.

’ilC

DC

tO

ilP

.’L

’IQ

.tx

jH=

HW

Hp)

çtH

CD

CD

CD

H-

0C

DN

IIC

1Cf)

“C

D°°

°0C

1-

H-0

pi

H0C

Dt1

PiH

-0

pip

iiq

pio

cCD

H-

CD

CD

HH

CDfli

CD

p,C

D-3

CD-C

tl-

il-

WC

t-

Cl-

H-

CD

ilil

il’-

1H

H-C

tdC

DtL

l=

QIp

iI

H-

oCD

CDIj

H-

10

C1D

’I0

0C

D’

H-

0H

HC

DP

)C

Dil

CD

OH

-H

CD

Lxi

Ip

iIC

tCl-

L’J

I-ti

HC

DO

1°1W

10CD

p3lCD

H-

0CD

HP.

’H

-P)

HH

-‘-

xiC

Drt

I.<

CD

fr]1

H-J

0H

-H

-Ill

M-iC

D0010

I”

HC

tH

°CD

CDH

Ct0

rtI0

IIIC

II

0C

l-C

l-CD

H-

•H

-H

0II

H-I

sii

CDCD

Ill1

ICHI

-C

CDC

ICD

ICD

IH

IP-I

CDC

l)H

CD

IiH

-H

.IT

J0C

DIH

-Ct

100

3’

Ipi

H-

LH

-•

CDCD

CDC

CD11..

-

CD

CtP

)I

CDC

tH

0il

CD

1°0

IC

tl

CDH

H-

H-

HCD

HH

CDil

CDCD

IIrto”

I•

H‘-

CD

Q

‘.0H

-P.

’lCD

IICD

IH-

CC

tI-

P•

H-

PiiH

-CD

P1P1

P-I0

‘.0C

tI

CD0

WP.

’1P

IH-

P-I

-P.

’H

-H

-’--

<1

IP1k<

CDCD

3H

Ii-

CDH

HCD

•I

3-

Ct

P.’

P.’

I•.

CDP

.’C

FC

D.

CD

IO-

ci

Page 402: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

00

Ii‘1

II0

00

0ci

CDCD

’CD

\P

-Cl)

I-ICD

CD

qQ

ci0

WZ

HH

CD

CD

o00

H0

CD0

.1H

-Q

H0

CD

CDH

-

ciC

D0

1HH

CD

cici

CD

H-C

DC

Dcic

iCD

HC

D

CD

CE

OH

-

CD

CD

Hcici°

HH

H

°

<

CE

ciC

E1H

-H

H‘

ClCD

0C

E0

H-

1CD

.C

DH

-H

CD

-

-C

DC

DQ

ciC

D

rtw

CD

0(D

CE

0’

‘dC

DC

Dp

j.

1:-I

4tl

CD

CD

CDH

-j

‘<

Hi

tiD

CD

CD

ciC

D‘

CEci

HQ

C

CD

CE

CD

HO

HC

DH

-CD

CD

i<

H

ciC

D0

CD

-ci

tiCD

0C

CD

d-

C)

QC

E

•C

DU)

P)H

3

CEC

DC

E9

JI

CE

CE

wo

ci

PJC

HW

5ç))

OC

D0

ciH

CD

H-

H-c

l

ciW

HL

tH

-O

H-

CD

OQ

MC

D

2)o

H-

°‘C

vP

‘d

jo

CE

0IC

D-

CE

HH

-CD

ci2)

2)C

D2)

ci

02

)H

--a

H<

-C

E0

‘W

x1

p-

>C

D-C

t)L

i0

0(1

ICD

(DO

‘TJ

frhC

E0

‘0ciG

)C

DU

)CD

CD

2)1

1H

II0

WCl)

(DH

-2)

QC

DCD

CD

.C

Dci

O h‘D

t’JCE

ci-

CD

ci

3<(D0C

E

cli

p)

-‘

Oci

çt

CEC

DJC

D

()D

pci

‘tP

)CE

Ct)

CECE

H-

H-H

ci

CDC

Dd

CD

OH

0OH

HH

ci

CED

’CD

-0H

-H

-H

11C

EH

H-C

DY

’O

CE

2)

•“

H0

0ci

H<

H-C

D11

HQ

CDH

-2)

H2)

ci.

.

HCD

CD2)C

DC

E

H-

CD

ciC

E•,jO

11C

1)C

Eci

CE

H

H-

11C

D=

11.

H

CD

ci

H-

I

H

H-

CDC

DH

-2)

H-

CECD

CD

CE

11H

-CD

110

CEH

-p

jJ

CD2

)C

D9

H.

CD

CD0

<C

Dfr

ci

ci

0CE

ciH

CDj•

-t,O

ci

2)CD

H-1

1C

D

OH

-0

CD

2)

HC

E0

CD

11

H-1

1

rO

HC

E2)0

Oci

ci

-CE

2)C

EC

DC

E11

•H

-

CD-

HCE

ci

H-

00

0

1111

H-

ciCD

00

ci0

ICE

0

CEci

CD0

H-

0H

-ci

H-

ciH

-2)

0

2)0

CEci1

1C

DC

D0H

11

CEH

-02)

CD

ciQ

CDH

-0‘ci

H0

HQ

CE

H-

0

CD

ci-110

--C

D2)

H•‘

-C

D

Page 403: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

-1:_

I0

00

010

H-

H-

H-

CDCD

CDCD

H-

H-

H-

00

WW

rrH

-IH

-H

WII

Cl)Cl

)IH

HO

CID

LI-<

0-‘

IIC

Iifr

’IC

DIC

IJp

Jc1C

D‘-d0

Li-

0-

C1-

Wfl

CD

‘b

<op

Icn

iIQ

lo-

IrtO

’<(D0

QM

Cl)

M<

H-(

DH

CDIC

DO

rt(D

H-

I--

(D

)--

Iu-P

III-L

H-C

I)

HP

JH

-ID

JCD

IIC

tC

F--

-Ip

iII

IuCD

qIP

Cl)

CF0

H-

H-

Cl)

H-

H-

H-

Cl)

13W

:3IQ

c.

‘1H

-IC

DI

Iwpi

IH-

rt0

Cl)

HO

H(D

oP

i-

hi)-

H-

hb

H-

H-

CDI

IIC

rCD

0II

H-l

--

HH

‘<l-

i-

IC,)

ICfl(

1)W

1WO

P)H

•‘H

Ipi

CD

HZ

(DC

D0

”H

-O

H-

“i

0O

H-f

l2

JrF

PiC

1)

-0

2)C

D2i

CDO

1210

HC

DH

-‘1

-.

H21

H2

1W

CD

HO

CD

gD

HCl

)Ip

)—

.)F

u1

LIJ

<C

FH

•H

‘b

CD

‘CD

21I

21H

-21

C,C

DH

-H

-C

IDC

DO

’P

H-

=It

-Ipi

QH

j0’d

Lxi

‘d

-H

LiC

tL21

Cl)

H-

HW

•H

-d

tiC

DI

C1ç-t

Q3L

H-C

D0

CDCD

-

OH

CD

CD

2’II

•210

OF

(I)

CD

t?-

0

Cr

1O

CD

IpiM

CCD

Q2)

°H

-W

CD0

3CD

3H

-—

_H

CDH

-cr

CD—

çt

irF

21

“CD

‘Xi

CD

CD

Cr

21CDi

CD

OH

-<

‘-

021

OC

.1

9)b

Li

—H

<C

r•.

pi

H-

Ipi

H-

H-

<H

°C

D

09)

H-

:i121

H-

H-W

-C

DP

Cl)•

H-

3U)

CF.!

‘-t

o2’

1>

3t

0IH

CD

t?0

H-Q

Cl)

219)

H-H

2’

HW

H

00

IHP

)I-3

CDH

-H

OW

CD

C-F

t-F

Ct

HH

HpiJH

-3

13H

—1-

h(-

I-C

OO

)H

HCD

<O

H0

D11

piIt?

91.

-H

-CD

QH

kD21

rrp

21jt’

2’

octH

CD

‘1‘t

ioCD

H-

Ih1

CD

—•—

‘P

‘o3

H-

oo

U)

CD

tpi

I-j-

21d

CD

WC

DH

CD

HC

rC

D1Ø

OIp

ipi

i--<

.IO

iLJ

U)

9)

H-W

Cl)H

3ç-

FH

-3

Irt

91‘•d

Cl)U

]q

0C

tU)

H-

H

OC

D

H-C

DH

-G

9)

‘H

-

0CD

r-t

21‘

6P

(D

CD0

<

Cl)

PP

oP

U1

1212

1o

‘DC

Dd

H-C

rCD

H9)

IH

‘H

.1-1

•‘-

)CO

CDU)

11H

-pi

HCD

HO

Ct.

)t-F

13

HCD ti

1ZI

H-

CC)

H0W•

H-p

H-

Cl)0

0-<

CF

CO

.Iii

0•

Hp1

(D

-00

H<

ç?12

1Cr

piI

0L

’J

0P

p)

ID

H‘

HW

(FC

D0

<H

CDIC

DCD

P0

i-i,

DC-

F•p

OH

-)H

-H.

CDt-

‘-3H

-tl

)pj

cxij

CD

CO

p(W

91

Li

1:1

C)

9)C

liH

-H-

021

0Q

CFI-

hO

CFH

.jp

H-ç

It,

•H

-L

xi

0H

gCD

iP

(l)

OH

-li

H-

Q0

H-

0‘d

Lc

••

U)H

:i9

1t-

<‘d

-H

-H

-O

CD

—rd

0H

0(3H

HH

O=

liH

-C

iCD

.U)

CD.0

liliH

CFCl)

H-

t1

o-

U)‘C

DU)

‘CD

0CD

CDH

-H

-Cl

)H

-O

’L

i(.Q

00H

--

CD21

21CD

PO

OH

-C

rCD

211

ICD

OCD

02

1-

•CD

IQO

••

-CD

P1‘tj

tO

I1

d--

I-21

H-f

lC

tH

ii1Q

21IH

-0

0•

IH-

H-

-Cl

)M

HO

CD

HZ

CF10

t1I

Ion

H-

21H

-I-h

H-

H-

021

P.

HCD

H-

•12

1H

-0

CD1

121

21H

-CF

0H

IliO

t-h

“I

IliH

‘-<

Page 404: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

pipi

pipJ

cJ2)

2)2)

P)2)

IH

HC)

C)C)

C)C)

C)U)

C)C)

2)2)

)0

P.H

IICD

CD)

2)PJ

PJ

P02)

H—

IjC

fiW

QU

)IL

’I’<

L’J-

ILT

JHH

-IH

-cir

tH

JH

-ni

IJ

HC

D‘D

H‘D

2)c

tH

CD

H-

t’JI-

hH

-IC

)—P

)I2)H

k<

.O

piO

QtI)

DC

1jP

)H

E-

.oo

-D

-QP

J2)

10IrtH

CD

HQ

I1—

.)H

-rt-

-II-

-CD

CX

O-

Cl)H

bP

C)

-]H

-i

CI)

3P

H-

Irt(

D-

k-i-

CD

iIH

rt

WiP

iG

CD

C,-

-2

)O

j‘D

U)

2)I0

H-(l)

I3h

Ii--

CD

-—

H-C

DC

Dfl

3U)

HP

2)

tH

—F

--Ii

0rt

0q.<

H.

I-

0P

-O

C)P

Jxj

2)0

1H

0U

)CD

H.

HO

1(1)

3H

-U

)Q

0.

CDC

tQIw

PH

oC

DH

-‘n

H-I

lP

J(D

cl

2)

(DC

DU

)M

CD

,I

H-

C)0C

DU

)IO

CD0

H-:

U)

C.Q

.C)()IlH

-Q

QjU

)C

tIO

U)i-t

C)

I(D

.CD

H-

CD

pjç,

:(l)

t’)

9)

1C4IH

CD

p-

clC

D2)0

•II’i

Cl)H

pi.

IO

H-

Il:

W:Il

:i

•H

IC

FL

Po

—p

j2)

1rt

WlCD

Cf)

(D

¶<

CD

U)

We-

,-H

U1q

IMH

°W

CD

:pit

TC

D.

..C

D(1)

0C

DH

Hdi

2)

H-

O—

‘P

J2

)C

DQ

H-

H-

U)P

H-

0pjj

-C1

CD

H-

PC

I‘O

HIl

I-’C

DO

CD

QO

H,D

U)

pip

j2)

CD

’-<

IlH

CD

Il0

IIH

-CF

HO

Cl)

çtCD

‘(D

C)C

DIl

CD

MH

H-

- 2)

HH

CDIu

bk<

O2)U

)(D

’tJ

Ilo

CD

U)

0rr

:iC)

CD

IU)2

)U)

H-

H2)

Ctci

“U

)C1)

h3

CD

pU

)H

-ic

y0

:ipi(

1)

‘D

(1)2

)H

-H

CDpj

:iU

)‘°

c’)C

Dr-

’-O

H-C

t2

)W

I)‘D

0L

’J

U)H

-Q

j)

.-O

Hi

--D

cç.

U)C

Dp

2)II

H-

CDCD

çt

Oil

-:

0-

H-i

lIX

j-

2H

-H

Hi

2)

0H

-2)

IC

DO

CDH

-cy

‘1o2)

U)

IP

)CF

Hi

H-

H-

H-’

dhj

IC)C

D‘O

0CF

CD

‘-<a

HJ

CF

W•

-‘O

C)

IH-H

HW

P)C

DC

D2)

‘-DQ

IO

Wil

lH

Il

2)

ilU

)Ci

)H

-H

HC

p)H

-I

CDI

fl-o

w<

CD

<C

DoH

-H

-0H

H-

-H

Otl

CD•p

J‘.

oO

ç1frti

‘H-

0H

tOIl

pi

‘Cl)

CD

W-

IOH

-W

CD‘t

iw

liP

iNU

O•

U)O

rtIH

HQ

00

IJ

[.H

CD0

CD

H-

H-U

)C

Di

ic-t

’o•

IH-H

-O

CD

CD

1xj

<Ht1:T

IIH

-’d

CDO

H-

CD<

-•C

)H

pjU

)L

JI

IC)H

2)Q

)CD

0‘t

iH

HH

PIU

)iC

rCF

H-

U)

(1)1

12)

CD

CDN

O•C

D

‘ti

CDH

CDC

t0

OC

FH

-H

-CD

IIi.

<jj

Qçt

Ct

2)

N.

H-

3C)

‘ti

.il

0Q

H-

CDO

CD

aC

Dil

0C

DW

H-

CFH

H-

2)IH

H-

H-

tOH

-(QCD

120

0U)

H-

H-

3‘1

‘.0•

L-

0H

H0

rt‘-P

2)

ç-F

C)[d

U)

CD‘ti

p2)

lCD2)

Ct

‘OH

Hi

CD•I

hi2)

HCD

•2)

H-

LPPI

CDCF

1Q

i3

H-

U)il

L-’

ICt

:P

Wrt

CFC

DH

IH-

0U)

H-

CD

0C

t3

2)P

H-

U)C

rCfr-

hIl

U)i

lH-

2)U

)C)

tOH

-C

DU

)QH

OW

IH-

CFC

F2

)H

ilC

Di

=•..

CD

I0

-H

t

Page 405: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

(March/April 1991), pp.66-72.

Martens, Todd K. “Ending Tropical Deforestation: What is the ProperRole for the World Bank?” Harvard Environmental Law Review 13(1989), pp.485-515.

Martz, John D. “Bureaucratic-Authoritarianism, Transitions toDemocracy, and the Political-Culture Dimension,” in Wiarda,ed., New Directions. Revised ed.

Marubeni. Marubeni Corporation: Annual Report 1993. Tokyo:Marubeni, 1993.

Marubeni. “Guideline on Global Environmental Issues.” Internaldocument. Tokyo: Marubeni, 1991.

Marubeni. Earth Conscious. Tokyo: Marubeni, March 1994.

Marubeni. “Friendly To Forests And To Our Mother Planet.” Internaldocument. Tokyo: Marubeni, undated.

Mauzy, Diane K. and Mime, R.S. Malaysia: Tradition. Modernity andIslam. Boulder: Westv±ew Press, 1986.

Mauzy, Diane K. and Milne, R.S. Politics and government inMalaysia. Rev. ed. Vancouver: University of British Columbia,1980.

McCoy, Alfred W. “The Restoration of Planter Power in La CarlotaCity,” in Kerkvliet and Mojares, eds., From Marcos To Aguino.

McDougald, Charles C. The Marcos File: Was he a Philippine Hero orCorrupt Tyrant?. San Francisco: San Francisco Publishers,1987.

McGuire, G. and Hering, B. “The Indonesian Army: Harbingers ofProgress or Reactionary Predators?,” in Doran, ed., IndonesianPolitics.

McKendrick, David. “Indonesia in 1991, Growth, Privilege andRules.” Asian Survey 32, no. 2 (February 1992), pp.103-110.

McVey, Ruth T. “The Beamtenstaat in Indonesia,” in Anderson andKahin, eds., Interpreting Indonesian Politics.

Means, Gordon P. Malaysian Politics: The Second Generation.Singapore: Oxford University Press, 1991.

Medard, Jean-Francois. “The underdeveloped state in tropicalAfrica: Political clientelism or neo-patrimonialism?” inClapham, ed., Private Patronage.

395

Page 406: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

0H

-H

HH

HH

-H

-H

-H

-H

-H

-H

-CD

L.J

HH

HH

Ht

H-

HH

HH

HH

HL

JII

CDCD

Cl)Cl)

CD1J

Cl)Id

CD

Ixjjpi

H0

r1lt

f)

‘rJ

Q’r

J-

I-<

I-Iij

Hxj

CD

H‘ijtH

Inor

‘—C

Di

‘dC

Dq

‘t

lJ0

0-

iiIi

-D

O-

Qh

CD

iO

0H

-rt

<C

H1

‘11<

‘.D

•H

-HU)

CDCD

-CI

)H

-CX

)•

Cl)H

-‘-

<IH

-H

CD-

q))

qH

)IH

fr-<

wP

Hf-f-

•CO

CDQ

oct

0D

’<

HH

-i

P’I

OH

c‘C

D(D

H-C

DH

CD

Hf)

3Ic

i’U

)ct

ICD

Hct0H

OH

-H

0 CDH

--

I0

CD

CD

U)ct

IiIC

DC

DD

CtU

)‘-D

PJ

H-

0I

0ct

‘DC

DO

-)H

H-U

)I

ci•

QP

)CD

I.

•0

9H

-I-U

-H

-:H

.0

wo’

-<dP

U)

•H

-C

l)çl

iCD

HH

•CD

HIcl-

I0

H-.

II-0

HU

)H

ct

H-

CD

HH

HC

DIQ

‘-<C

D

o0

I-<CD

0H

-n)

I0

CD

CD

0C

DC

DH

.rt

H1i

IQ

P)C

D•ti

)H

•H

iH

H

H-C

)?O

CD

0H

H-C

D(D

O0’-

<L

rJO

CC)

CD

’H

H0

H,H

iH

-H

iQ(tH

H(-t

HCI

)C

DH

-ct

CD-

Hip

jH

CD

CD

oH

-CD

<1:)Jct

Cl)

Lxi

H-

U](

tCl)

HC

DZ

1O

I1,C

DI-

bw

:iH

1C

Dii

CI)

P’

CDçjh

i’•

U)rJ)

HZ

Hkl

)Q.

H-

1.H

-IL

’JIH

-

:!-.

Irt

‘-<

HH

-id

p,

Cf)

0C

f)P

CD

H-

H-

LC

-H

-

HCD

(D

.

Li.

H-

0H

-C

t

HPC

DH

ct

0:i::

o”

H-

Iiio

Hi

piC

D‘-

<C!

)M

QH

P’

Hi

pC

()

IH

(J)C

.0

CD

HL

xjO

Hi

oH

iP’

Hi

CD

CD

HU

)HC

)P)

OH

o(I

•Ip

iH-

pCD

CDP

tHi

•H

-H

H-H

Cl)

CI)

3Q

CD

H-

CD

Ii

p,

0(D

CI)

H-

01P

)•H

H-

CD

Ioo

frtj

(J)

H-U

)H

P’H

o?

l’Ih

lIr

tQ

PJ

0CD

C)

°U

)‘p

‘]C

IDIC

DG

)C

Dpp.

gC

DH

U)

CD

-(f

lU)

H-p

ictO

HC)

H-

CDH

U)

jCv

<H

iU)

CD

0C

D

IH-

Cl)

=H

i’-<

I-CD

0J

HH

-.H

P’

PiH

-0

0H

-0

WC

()

H-:

H-

CD

H-

HH

-OP

I‘D

Hx

j(t

crH

‘1P1

CC

)-

P1

ICD

CD

H-

OH

H-l

P10

U)0

HC

Di’

0U

)<

-M

‘-]

0D

H-p

iCD

DP

iU

)Pi

P1i0

CD

ctC

D•

H-C

D-

••

HiH

H-

Page 407: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

Mok, S.T. “Strategic Options For Forestry Development in Asian-Pacific Countries.” Energy and Environment 2 (1991), pp.368-379.

Moniaga, Sandra. “Status of Forest Resources in Indonesia,” inJANNI, Reshaping “Development”, pp.39-42.

Morita, Tsuneyuki. “Environmental and Natural Resource Accountingin Japan.” CIDIE Workshop on Environmental and NaturalResource Accounting, UNEP Headquarters, Nairobi, 1992.

Mukonoweshuro, Eliphas. “Ethnicity, Class and Clientelism in SierraLeone Politics: A Methodological Critique.” Plural Societies20 (September 1990), pp.65-91.

Murtedza Mohamed and Ti Teow Chuan. “Effects of Deforestation: withSpecial Reference to East Malaysia.” Borneo Review 2, no. 2(December 1991), pp.122-141.

Myers, Norman. “The Environmental Basis of SustainableDevelopment,” in Schramm, and Warford, eds. EnvironmentalManagement.

Myers, Norman. The Primary Source: Tropical Forests & Our Future(Updated for the 1990s). New York: W.W. Norton & Company,1992.

Myers, Norman. “Whose Hand On The Axe?” in Tropical Deforestation.Hearings before the Subcommittee on InternationalOrganizations of the Committee on Foreign Affairs House ofRepresentatives, Ninety-Sixth Congress, Second Session, 1980,pp.138-143.

Nakamura, Yoichi. “The Ecobusiness Logic.” AMPO: Japan-AsiaQuarterly Review 23, no. 3 (1992), pp.55-57.

Nastan, Kadir Mohd. “A Note on Logging Methods Used By A LargeTimber Company On The East Coast of Sabah.” Malayan Forester29, no. 4 (1966), pp.303-306.

National Science Teachers Association. World Resources 1992-93. AGuide to the Global Environment. Washington: National ScienceTeachers Association, 1992.

Nectoux, Francois, and Kuroda, Yoichi. Timber From The South Seas:An Analysis of Japan’s Tropical Environmental Impact. Gland,Switzerland: World Wildlife Fund International, 1989.

Nemetz, Peter N., ed. Emerging Issues in Forest Policy. Vancouver:UBC Press, 1992.

Nester, William R. Japan’s Growing Power Over East Asia and The

397

Page 408: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

World Economy. London: Macmillan, 1990.

New Sunshine Program. Tokyo: New Sunshine Program PromotionHeadquarters, AIST, MITI, 1993.

NGONET. Computer database of the Alternative Conference at UNCED,Rio de Janerio, 1992. (To request use: ngonetlib@chasque . apc . org).

Nicholson, D.I. “An Analysis of Logging Damage in Tropical RainForest, North Borneo.” Malayan Forester 21 (1958).

Nissho-Iwai. “Environment 21: Nissho-Iwai Corp.” Internal document.Tokyo: Environmental 21 Division, Nissho-Iwai, 12 February1991.

Nowak, Thomas C. and Snyder, Kay A. “Clientelist Politics in thePhilippines: Integration or Instability?” The AmericanPolitical Science Review 68 (1974), pp.1147-ll7O.

Nowak, Thomas and Snyder, Kay. “Urbanization and ClientelistSystems in the Philippines.” Philippine Journal of PublicAdministration, 14-15 (July 1970) , pp.259-275.

O’Loughlin Cohn. “The Influence of Forest Roads on Erosion andStream Sedimentation--Comparisons Between Temperate andTropical Forests.” Working Paper. East-West Centre Honolulu,Hawaii, 1985.

OECF (Japanese Overseas Economic Cooperation Fund). OECF AnnualReport 1993. Tokyo: OECF, 1993.

OECF. OECF and The Environment. Tokyo: OECF, 1993.

OECF. OECF Environmental Guidelines. Tokyo: OECF, 1989.

0±, Jean C. “Communism and Clientelism: Rural Politics in China.”World Politics 37, no 2 (January, 1985), pp.238-266.

Oka, Hiroyasu. “Process of Deforestation in the Philippines,” inThe Current State of Japanese Forestry (VII): Its Problems andFuture.Tokyo: The Japanese Forest Economic Society, 1991,pp. 93 - 98.

Ongkili, James P. Modernization in East Malaysia 1960-1970. KualaLumpur: Oxford University Press, 1972.

00± Jin Bee. Depletion of Forest Resources in the Philippines.Singapore: ASEAN Economic Research Unit, Institute ofSoutheast Asian Studies, 1987.

Orr, Robert M., Jr. The Emergence of Japan’s Foreign Aid Power. New

398

Page 409: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

CDCl)

CDCD

CDIJ

IIH

-CF

H1J

PJU)

C)1

H0

III

C)H

-Pi

CFH

--

H-

C)CI

)U)

U)C)

)3

(1)H

Xd

‘-<

NIJ

LX

jOIc

tU)Q

‘P

)0

IjC

DIb

i-H

H‘r

j(D

CD

ct-

Hi’

P)

frdH

-H

Ct

iq

qi

i-<

P)P

’O

IJH

CD

-0

O-

kI)

’<IP

)C)

J’O

IP)P

)O0

<cF

CD

-C

D-

<U

)C

D’x

lrt

ILx

JIC)

rrC

Db

Id’d

bL-

H-P

Jri

CD

IC

)U)

CD

CDcF

C)

H-

H-

CD

H-

H-

CDCD

ICup

)CD

H(.

QC

D“0

F-P

)11

’JC

DQ

U)C

FQ

Hp)

IU)

H-(

D’<

H-Q

HI-

t-

IIhl

P)C

DQ

C)P

)10<

Ict.

0U

)IQ

-H

-P

)C

FI-ct

L’J

P)ct

31<-

CD

p)t3

H-

lU)Z

U)

ICD

H-H

P)1

‘0CD

(D(D

HH

-C

)1H

—)’

lS

’d

CC

D<

<IM

HD

HCD

0(D

rtIH

0CF

q

U)<

L-

CD

IO•C

DC

D-ñ

P)

IH

-(

H-

H-.

I-i

0c-

Fctw

00

HH

-Ii

-P)

Cr.

.p

<C

DC

DIi

jIi

-H-C

iJ

CD)

qlCD

qI

HH

IH-

H-

‘1P)

ICD

H-C

I)U

)CD

HC

DH

-fl

1i

H-jj

HO

iCD

:.

F:’b

-.o

-tI

CD

.IC

iPkic

,bi

(.c

.0

OH

-0

CD

Hi-

.C

ICD

U)

ixIP

)0

P)

Ii

C)C

DC

tU)

CD

CD

HH

-Q

CD

I<••

pi

td

tJU

)i-

tiU

))

c0P

)U)

flfl

)p)’

-]H

CD

Qh

H-

Q..

CDO

ct

L-hH

-II

ti H-

CDC

Di1

l0-

-c-t

IH

HP

)<

yH

-0

CDC

D“

Lxi

C)

‘CD

‘CD

tiI

U)Z’

ICD

CD

U)C

DH

‘DC

FCD

I-IIi

Lx1

CD(D

(.--

H-

CD1

CD

0’-<

-.

•H

--

2)U

)Hp

’-

IC

DL

\)H

-‘d

U)H

’dH

-0

tOQ

HC

FM

CV

HH

HC

t’U

)H

L’i

CDH

CD

ç?W

HCD

H-

9)•H

.‘O

p)C

)Ct

•‘-

<-

--

CD

3•

-H

9)C

tP

)U

)P)

CD3

3H

-U

)çF

HU

)=

c-to

•P

)‘<

HC

DC

D

PO

C)

H-

‘.ø

CD-

•9)

9)..

OH

a)’

9)0

U)CD

••

H-

HH

CD U)H

HC

FLD

U)H

Lxi

‘i

H-

CD

jH

-O

C))

-..‘

rjC)

U)W

iq

CDCD

c--j

CF

p.

pi

U)U

)

0)()

LxJ

H-

Hr’

)p

HC)

C)1I1

fl

l.tJ.

:4fr

H-

Ht1

H

0rtO

oU

)oçi

‘dt:

:jH

c-C)

-c-F

0H

9)

H-•

O

QP

)H

‘ØH

CD

wo

0CF

tH

°C

D0U

)U

)j

U)<

0U

)9)

tOI-

tW

CDC

DH

-C

DO

H-

HH0

01-.d

0

CF

H-

CD

H-

2)

CF9)

CF

jj

9gtO

’C

Drj

CD

H-

l.D

.0H

-•

‘-<g

C)U

)O

CD

i‘.D

p)

CD••

O9)

U)Q

1H

-CD

CD

uH

1U

)H

——

Lxi

OC

FC

DC

D-

H-

CH

-•

2)0

H-

0II

-U

)p

HC)

H-

U)•

•0

U)

CF

(l)

C)—

.

9)i-

9)‘d

(DL

’I‘o

tx

io

1H

H-

0ctC

)‘H

oC

ii,-

H-c

t9)p

HH

CF

CD

.

9)U

)q

-c-t

cI<

•I

•C

tç-I

H-

lU)“

H-C

12‘x

ic-t

U)

0H-

ICF

H-

CFH

-‘o

19)<

09)

‘lD

p‘-d

H-:

3-

U)9)

CDP

H-

CDH

-CD

0H

CDP

c-t

O•

U)

CD

U)

fliIi-

•P

iH-

9)U

)H-

U)&

(I)

CD

CD

H-

hI•

H-

U)CD

2)IH

-CD

Hp.

c-H

Lxi

‘.D

C)C

D9)9

)IP

H-3

IbIC)

1H

-(.Q

9)H

-U)

IL

.JU

)U)

CD•

ICD

CF

CF

IH19)

CDC

tCF

•Io

•CD

•.

c-F

I$

1‘-<

lCDfli

H--

QI-

•0

=fr

-t-

-

Page 410: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

‘d‘d

oo

00

00

oH

iH

iH

iH

iH

-H

-H

-H

-H

-H

-H

-H

,H

iM

iH

iH

HH

HH

HH

CDH

-Cl)

CDCI

)CD

H-

H-

H-

H-

H-

H-

HH

-ti

H-

1iC

f)i

HH

-1i

d’tj

J0

‘jti

‘i(I

)’T

jC

I)’u

jO

dU)

ob

‘D

HO

“jL

’r5

OH

CD

’d

CD

M,’

dO

pd

‘D

<rr’d

CD

kiJ

d)ç-t9J

CD(D

‘Orr

(DCD

(DH

-H-

PJC

DH

-d

H-

Mrt

H-

‘DC

DP

JH-

U)IH

-H

-ic-tH

rJ

rt

CC

DO

Qrt

CD

H-

4Q

rti

0IH

H-C

DH

-C

DIi

aQ

LQ

Q•L

QL

I-C

DCD

QH

CD

YD

U)O

CD

•C

DC

DciU

H-C

DH

QC

D(h

Ok)

HiC

D(D

CI)

fl)

H,C

DH

F-’C

Drt

CF‘l

iii

HpJ

Hi

Hi

PJh

Hi

P)H

-O

•C

H-

JH

-0t

(D•

H-C

DU

)H

d=

HU

)-ft-

CDC

DO

iCD

XH

Li

<H

iCD

-(D

pi

CD

.’tJ

Irj

rtH

-‘-

<C

DJQ

CD

d::5

Fd-)

CDCD

dU)

U)

CDH

-ci

tYX

XC

FL

Q0P

)pl0H

-P

.)‘J’d

CDC

OP

’H

U)P

JrF

F-

HI1

PJQ

P)

t-I1

U)f

rU)

hI-

QI-

U)H

-C

tH

-rt

HP

)Z

ct

0H

-(-Q

‘-D

rr

rti

--C

D(D

ctC

DCD

PiC

D•

WH

,W

(DCD

CD‘D

H-

HC

Dfr

H—

CDH

PI

H-

(DC

FC

DP

’’ti

HH

H-U

)(]J

(D-

-(-

l-::

IH

i-t

cr

pitj

i-rt.i,

C)CD

HC

tLD

OC

DC

trtc

-t<

HH

(DP

H-

CD

‘C

J0

H-

0H

-H

OH

-çO

CD

Oç-t

‘d(D

Hi

HL

iHi

‘dO

‘dH

HH

iQ

Cl)H

-H

hd

thi

0‘.

.OH

iP

)Lxi

j’i

0H

iCD

H-

oC

DI

HC

DH

--o

U)H

-CD

CD

Ct

Hi°

CD

CI)

CD

HO

H-

CD

Mi

U)i<

piU

)H

(DP

’H

,HPi

(DC

)H

u)L

Xi

OH

-O

HiL

x1

(DH

H-

(D

U)C

DctH

-U)

(I)H

CF

CD

H-

‘‘JO

U)O

•O

<C

DL

IJ°

ctH

H.

yH

-O

H-

iX

-C

D-

(DH

-O

OH

-C

)H

-U

)Qrt(D

pio

PIH

JDr-tri

P10

H-H

i,.

H-i

CDi

U)

CD‘U

IU

)rt

OP

)rt

H-

Mi

CD

CD

H’U

ICD

-pj

o0rj

-C

trt

(DU

)pi

H-pi

P1I-

H-i

0Cl)

CD

Pip

,••H

-rt

op

U)ct

ZC

D<

H,H

PC

DZ

1C

DP

)li

CD

Oç-t

L’J

1(D

I’j

CDp

oX

O(D

CO

Ct

-

zO

Ct

0O

CD

CD

)tT

cp

JZ

H-p-t

I_”J

Hi

frU

)-

Ct

ctH

I(D

pi

frU

)U)

“P

lI

Ht1

Cl)

C-t

(Dç-t

c-t

Xj

ctP

l1

IU)

(api

p’H

CF

HH

pi

rth

tQrr

<O

CD

iDc-r

H-

IPP’

L’JC

D(D

C?

hU

)C

DIH

-‘d

P’C

DO

CD

rtoi-

cIiU

)C

t(D

H-O

U)p

iI

OC

D‘

°P

’H

’JH

U)

CO

OP

’H

lU)

iiI-j

HH

i0

tP

’i

0(D

CDC

tCD

H-

-H1

CtU

)P

)(D

P1CF

t’1

0C)

“°

oH

XCF

I‘t

Ji-

CD

0U

)Q

‘.00

C)(D

’<P1

CDC

D<

CD

P1.

CDH

-CD

(DU

)L

’J

‘.o

<-(D

CDU)

C)

U)

b-.

CD

U)

U)rt

U)

‘‘JU

)M

OP

IU)

U)2’

“IC

t2)

0H

H-

‘-<

X-

0(D

O—

.C

DC

DH

Oc-F

HC)

Oco

‘ci

H-

HH

-X

0P-i

Ipi

0U)

1jçii

‘.0

H-

I-

‘lC

DU)

H’l

U)P

)F

dH

IC

I)

‘l’

lL’i

CF

P1

pi’l

WCD

CD

U)

CD

H-

CD

C)

U)U

)‘.O

H-I

rtP

inrt

C)Cl

WU)

U)U

)CD

U)C

t(D

H-C

FC

DH

-‘.

OH

IPI

U)C

DP

)CD

‘lH

-Ii-

2’P

)(D

•C

tH-

U)

H-U

)C

DP

1ir

PJI

rtC

DU

)‘l

U)—

P’<

I—

<U

)CD

-•

-CF

‘..Q

’lc

-t

•--

1(1)

1-

‘<

-•

HC

DIC

D-

-

Page 411: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

‘tI

‘ii

‘ti

‘ii

2)‘-1

00

00

00

0C

rL

JH

2)c-

FC

tI-

02)

CDCl)

c-FCD

c-F

c-FCF

c-FII

0c-

FH

-c-F

HCD

CDCD

CDCl)

CDH

ICJ)

Lxj

.‘dP

)’I

lIJ

IHH

LjI

H-I

iw

O’-

Hl’

UJ

HL

EJI

-lC

g)I

rtH

Itj

Ii--.

CD

ICc-

FH

-IH

-9)oI

uo

ob-

Ic-

ia-

Ii-

c-F

<I

1Ic-

pH

-‘O

0IQ

CDIC

)‘t

iC)

1(1)

IHCE

)<

ICI

CI)CD

H-

CDH

-”<

Cl)H

HI

-0

q1H

0H

H-I

Ci)

IH-

C)Cl

)H

iti

frH

c-H

-1

Ill0

1W(I)

H-

0I

0l

CDI

9)IC

r0

CDH

0H

-IH

-C

D0

09

)pH

-Ica

OIH

-9)

(DH

-CD

c-F

IIH

-9)

O9)

oIo

9)‘<‘

IWH

9)9

)H

-lh’l

9)L

iIo

wrtW

‘-<

Iiio

9)19

)9)

IH

-H

-9)

H‘H

‘-1D2

CDCD

CDc-F

IHH

.i

2)C

FC

D.C

r(D

Cr

H-1

H-C

Dc-F

(Y

IH-

H-H

OC

DW

HC

r.

IC

Do9)

.M

’t,

09

)H

‘tI

e,M

H.k

<D

I

Lqd

HH

H019)

09)

•w

Ic

HI

IHW

Cr-

CFI

WH

H:

Qh

t)

H-p

)IH

-CD

CF

HIC

rO

(D

H-.

IWW

-01

HH

-(I)

Cl)

CD

ic-rO

CD

L$c-r

9)I

HH

-..

..

..

(1)9)

i-Il

CD

HW

HL

ICDo

Cr

CD

jCD

H-

HhbC

r‘<

H-

H-

H-’t

WH

O.

CrL

i•0

(D

0H

-C

DW

(D<

CDH

-C

)9)9

)H

9)

(39)

H-

9)

0C

)HCD

L’J

P)i

CDd

c-Fç-F

WH

Wo

O9)

H-

°ci

0H

-(3

’LiI

jC

Dc-F

:j

c-tO

c-FH

(Dc-

FIt

jt-

I0

0w

Cc)

U1<

0H9)

0n

0C

Di.

-.Q

WC

DH

W9)

H-O

CDC

t

9)

CD

WC

Dc-

t.C

r

CD

CD

.(D

c-r

CD0

CD

•H

-0

CD

CII

HO

Hd

CD9)

II9)

c-F

9)0

HI-I

H-.

.C

r-

CD

,.<9)D

R’

WH

C)CD

H-H

-C

DW

(DC

D9)

c-F

c-‘t

l:j

9)

ClD

HII

CM0

H-

CD•

CD

-

c-F

H-

LIJ

Pg

CD

!H

9)

H(D

CDH

H-

OM

:jI-

H-

dW

o.

<C

x9)W

-09)

‘-30

‘0H

Hz

c-F

H-

0H

H-

H-

‘CD

C=

CD

CL

)9)

CF

HC

FC

D9)

(DC

DiJj

Cl)

CJD

c-F

(DO

Hc-

HH9

)O

Cr

OH

-H

HC

F(p

9)CD

9)Q

09)

H-9

)M00

IH-

9)U

.H

(H

H-3

c-FO

H9

)H

-H

Hc-F

09

)9)

c-FO

H-

•c-F

°-

H-

ZC

D0

W9)M

0H

‘.<3

WH

1H

.H

HH

9)(

D-

H-

H-

0jW

I9)9

)H

hO

Or_

bCI

)Ic

-t9)

CD

H-

0•H

tiC

rIC

()0

9)Ic

-F3

oH

-

IM-

0H

Cr

HH

-I9)

H-

9)C

rH

-10

0C

DH

-0

c-FCl

)CD

9)lCD

-CF

HH

-H

-H

-3

Ic-FCI)

rnQ

9)Cl)

CDH

Cr

1Wq

hH

-I

C)C)

9)lCD

Ic-t

H-

Ci)

GH

ICr

CDO

Fs)W

CDO

IC

rIo

r-t

OC

r9)0

Ho)

I’H

OH

9)

Ol

.H

ID9)

I1H

--

I‘<

MH

O)

••M

CD

IHH

<0

CD

Page 412: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

00

H-

H-

HH

-H

-H

-LI

ICD

CDCD

CL)

CDCD

CD0

i-]

CI

CDH

-H

--

-LI

I0

CDCD

CDCD

00

U)U)

Cl)0

rtrt

rtrt

CDH

H‘d

0)Q

IC1

IH

I—

Ct)

H-

21

-rr

H:Ij

frtj

rtP

c-t

Hr-nt

Iç-t

(ID

-O

H-

OH

‘d

H-i

1J

ICD

HIH

CD

01J1

Ioo

-Di3

OIo

H-

hM

iIO

hIH

PIp

I’-C

D-

‘l

CD

UntC

DIH

-‘-D

)-

U)C

DkI

D-

Li

ri-

c-t

PH

-icu

I1IL

’lCl)

0CD

U)IH

-Q

ri-

ni-

IL

(Q

-fr-

i--

—ar

t-(i

•C

D.

•CD

CD

qH

I-]

CD

CD

IO

jH

-H

-S)

IIH

--

H-

ntO

r-O

0Q

CD

IH

-Q

U)1W

HC

DO

jt-C

DIC

DJ

iU)b

Ipic

00

CD

H-

iO

I-

Hl

HO

2IC

l)CD

CDCD

rT

CD

HH

-p

i-

H-U

)••

nt

CD

U)

CDC

Drt

CDf-t

-l>

J[1

..P

)pj

‘rt

ap

.PJ

H-

1rr

o.

•a-rt

iiH

IH

-O

HCD

L’I

H-

CD

xjO

r-IC

D’Q

••

U)

PiP

rt.

OU

)H0

M.

0ri-

p10P

iCD

1<

H-H

-Ii

U)-

U)P

)-

U)U

)rt

F]

OIC

I)H

Qi(-t

c-t

_

oO

DY

MI-

IU)H

HH

-H

‘fl

CD

aC

D°H

Li

Oc-t

1”

F]r

-‘o

O..

CDo

‘0O

Lxl

i-oH

CDH

CD

0(1

)<

HC

Dp

•.C

DCD

f-i-

-]

rr

HU)

Ct,.

IH

13

-c-I

-W

H-

U)F

]r-

‘P

)H

-C

Dj

CD0

U)

U),p

HH

-CD

IIH

CD0

r-U

)H

CD

zt

P10

00

U)C

t-i-

-0

hi-

-nP1

CD

•Lx

i‘—

CU)

<•-)

pj

CL)

“d

U)

0H

:io

Drt

CD

,CD

“H

nt

.(t

HrtP

Li

11

OO

ijçii

-3

‘-

tij

U)O

r-P

)•

PH

H-

Cn

CDCD

••1

1Q

U)H

H-

Hpi

iC

Db

H-

CD

Hpj

hh

tH

CD

QCD

‘-D

Oi

H-°

,l••

‘-Q

ç‘D

pi‘-

dH-

P1L

’I(D

-j

‘tI

U)=

Hc

CD

L’J

PI•.

i-]i

-t-,

CD

QCD

CDCL)

pi•rt

(DP

I••--

JQ

MH

-nt

CD

IHC

I)U)

HH

-U

)rt

0110

HO

?-]

WH

-11

r-

CDLI

IP

HU

)H-

Li

xI(

D11

Ho

CD

CDI

0U

)CD

H-

11CD

ri-C

l)U)

H.C

DH

<l

HCD

OP

)rt

-p

‘oC

DLI

IH

IU)

=CD

CD“D

Oor-

Ct-

’pi

0-

.cjO

0O

M-

cri

-H-r

iC

OH

H-Q

o<

3H

•H

-0

Q0

CD-

H-

0P

<O

Cl)11

CDU)

f-I-

HC

DpI H

0H

-0

CLH

11o

CDf-

i-fl

)11

rto

0nt

Hp

U)j

‘ti

0CD

H-

“D

F]F

]C

o“

HCD

0CD

Hpi

gl-

.L:j

U)CD

p,(7

It

O‘-

000

Or

Wl-

‘ijO

H-H

.C

D1

:I-

HP1

I-L

11CD

U)H

-P

Ct)H

rtnt

CD

CD

p1II

1)H

(I)

H-

U)U

)H

pH0

HIC

!)nt

H-

H-

0CD

H-

0U)

ni-

U):i

‘dH

-In

I-’-

HH

P..

-p

1‘x

jxj

U)

CD

01H

U)0

•.

IIP1

LII

00

ni-

CU

)H-

CDCl

)H

-H

Ii-

2)P1

0H

H-

iii

fr,i

H-

0CD

IU)

DC

DP

II‘t

iH

‘D0

CD

CD

Irr

U)

In-

U)H

CDri

-0

H-

cx

iIb

CD

IIIH

HP.

.Ct’

11nt

Co

ni-

nt

IHri

-U)

021

IHi

CDCD

U)H

-—

CD‘H

-•—

IH-

CD

U)

CD

IH-

CD-

P-10

U)1

10•

P..

CD

Page 413: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

(I)

(I)

U)

U)

Cl)

U)

U)

9)9)

9)9)

9)9)

00

00

00

1—

-U)

U)-<

rr9)

9)9)

H-

9)9)

9)U)

-H

-H

-H

-H

-

H-P

JU

)9)

HF

-P

)O

QF

d(D

HH

11j

IjH

ct

HIp

J(D

IU)p

J(1

)-<

fl)

U)U

)9)S

OH

-U

)-t(

Dh-

11

OO

Hk

Ic

J‘D

QIi

I0$)h

Qc

1U)

p0

i-H

-IH

-9)

CD

GH

-Ii

i-IO

1rr-

II-

U)U

)°IH

-O

cr

0•ci—

’-

(DU

)co

t—i-(

DU

)’

lU)

•(D

(D

—g

iO

r-i

lCD‘-

..L

H‘C

H-

CD

(D

c-rr

’H-

(flU

)(l

U)

Ic-tU

)U)

0h

H-ç

-i-

IH-i

IrtQ

(D9)

1U

)rto

-r

1cr

‘-

IU)9

Jk-

ki

H-

rJH

-U

)H

-I.<

U)<

H(D

IU)

HQ

U)

IH-U

)O

U)

frU

)19)

.IijC

lU)

Qxj

9)U

)‘<

9)

=i

IH(D

.9)

k•

‘j

•H

.I

9)U)

‘H-

Hh.

O(f

lU)

CT)H

-H9)

H-

1OiJ

dH

.=

0F

-ui

Icn

U)H

cr9

)U)

9)

crH

9)I-

I7-J

9)

9)

H‘Z

tirr

HP

H-c

rU

(()fl

PI8

U)

U)

U)’i

QU

)HU

)cr

PJH

-o

0Ij

HH

-I-(

0U)

cr

0pic

tcr

9)U

)U

)9)

9)

rr

U)U

)P)

9)

IQ

H-

IpjO

H-

1-rr

IrrH

jHU

)o

U)H

(T)(

P(D

CD

CD

grrC

tH

U)ri

z_

‘J

cr

9)L

OU

)•

9)H

-19)

H-H

--j

Hcr

Q9)

U)H

tI)

H(I)

H-ç

i()

H-H

-ci

-U)

Cl)

HU

)f-t

H-U

)U)

lU)()

çt

HW

U)U

))h

•çuQ

U)(1)

U)

IH

-tO

oQ

U)ç

lU)

9)I-

,-0

O(3

H-

HQ

wC

f)P

•(D

9)r

rH

-U)

H-

Hcr

IH-

0H

U)

0(D

9)

crH

r’H

U)

<H

-U)

c°I-<

-pa

rr-

3(3

U)O

=CD

cr

0

Qc-r

Io

HH

U)

OH

-IH

H.

0U

)

—0

9)H

U)

Pjcr

U)

U)

FAL

:l0

IH

-O

°H

HH

9)ic

roçU

)H

-9)

U)

U)H

-L

OH

O19)

(3I

IId

H0

orr

HH

9)U

)U)

..

Cl)

jO

UH

CDtY

P)

H°H

-0

9)9)

HU

)FIQ

cFU

)H

O°U

)H

OH

-U

)9)

9)9)

01(l

)jU

)9)

hI

CD

0U)

Icr

crH

-9)

H-I

9)

U)H

-

0H

-09)

U)

WH

clr

rC()

i-

0to

HH

-c

U)I-

.19)

cr0

U)U)

H-

9)H

1<CI

)•

HH

-(3

<IH

-(I)

1r-t-

U)—

U)Q

-0)

N0

)ii

Cl

H-

09

)U)

0C

D9

)IU

)L

09)

H09)

H

U)0

H-

H9)

U)H

-IU)

9)IH

H-

(3H

-O

HH

-H

-cr9

)U

)i-

I00

I3

‘DU

).

0

H-

U)H

-H

Icr

19)IH

-0

H-

9)H

-<

(H

-U)

9)-

01

09

)cr

9)I

to

Ici

9)rJ

IO9)

FC

D.U

)H

-CD

U)I-

’-lH

i‘-

<••

ICD

I-t’

-•..

H‘-<

IH

h

Page 414: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

COCI

)CO

COCi

)CO

COCO

COCO

COCO

COCO

COCl)

CT)Cl)

00

C)0

0l

p1Li

iLi

iLi

iH

-cli

COcli

00

COCD

COf

Cr

l-0

CDI-

CDH

rfrf

cli

HH

-CI

)H

IHH

HIC

OH

H-t

i)‘j9i

CD

H-

Cf)

CD

l-

—C

O-

QL

tjQ

(Q

CC

HxjH

-H

•I

liP

)Q

CDH

-ICI

)l0

‘SO

PI

OC

Ocl

irt

liC

Dli

HO

-C

OO

IIC

Oq

(V

qW

ili

CD

CO

H-

H-C

l)H

-‘1

CI)

i10

IH

--

qp

iCD

-I

CI)

LQ

ul

IH-p

1rtp

)‘D

cl)

rth

CO

H-C

D<

‘C

tLii

CD

CO

0C

O1cliH

cli

-C

O‘-

<C

fPJ

CD

ICO

0li

•CD

CF

Mip

iCO

CD

CD

liC

Opi

l-C

D0

‘dIQ

cl’

dC

fIC

l)li

CD

0(D

G)

CD

CD

1rF

i-S

O1

<C

tt-t

CDIC

OH

‘1

Icl

pit

!)C

OIC

!)O

Ihli

OC

I)Ip

1CO

P1CO

dliH

-0C

DC

OO

H-C

OO

COH

-H‘-<

JO

3li

•Cl)

I’

ir•

[1

liH

CO

CD

liO

Oli

liM

iH

-H

MC

D-

H-

Mi

rFclJ

OH

-Hi

fliCD

N)

IH-

0CD

tIH

-.

=li

i<cl

lCDC

D•

0‘-D

ct

0F

(DP)

cliCD

k<

COii

fr

IliH

-Q

CO

lili

1-UJ

COH

-I1

0H

-H

-0

H-

cliP

0CO

MiC

FC

Dli

0II

II

><

HH

-CD

CD

CO

rF=

CDII

i-

cliC

DM

iH-

CDCD

it:J

lCD

0W

CO

Ili

‘<‘d

On

‘p1

°H

CO

OC

Oli

PiC

rj

ICO

CD

Ocli

ICD

0F

IH-

Cf

xj

CO

HO

)CO

IIIC

t0Z

CfH

CD

liI

ri-

po

.-

HC

FC

1H

CD

H0

.Z0C

DR

i—

-1rt

COc-

fH

Hcli

HW

Mi

0H

-CD

In

CDC

<0

)H

li

:i.D

0H

0piri-g

oH

-C1()

<cl)

HIh

1li

HCD

‘CD

‘O

pi

CD

HP

lOC

DH

-11i

rtpi

HH

-li

lio

PC

OC

O--

)Pl•

cr.i

CD0

IliH

SD

<“M

iH

HH

H-M

iH

-H

H-

o

H-

OC

DIO

00

H•p

iCD

0C

DH

-DC

f(D

CO

Cr1

3H

-O

li-

CO

Pl

:i

COH

Q.

COcli

CDpi

H-c

l)H

4H

••C

tMi

IP

HCD

‘•d

iC

fC

DC

D-

H-C

OH

-CD

13C

D0

O1

‘I1

‘<cl

iCD

Hi

CDIj

QC

Oo

013,]

I’P

i•

CDC

1H

OH

-C

D‘1

i-O

H0

CDn

zC

DH

-HH

-O

OCD

L\)

HH

-cl

1C

FH

-0

(T)

HH

H-

clici

CD130

p1I

H-C

fH

-CD

COp

iCD

lCD

F-

Cr1

3P

C3’

QC

OC

D”

OH

-1

3H

-C

Oli

H-

H•

H-

-—

flC

OQ

IIP

inl3

’-<

)c-f

HCD

pj

—S

=•I

Q-

IC

OL

IJH

CO

•CO

‘TJlI

Qq

H-

—)

H-<

HH

-C

Df—

’1

3

qc1P1

13(Q

“0”

‘-<[

‘10

13

wpi

o0Ij

‘C

D

••

dH

CDH

-H

0i

CfC

DC

Opi

CD

OC

‘tcli

c-F

W‘tl

CDp1

Li

HH

CD

pi.0

-H

13

..

H‘-

HCl

)‘1

CD

0“c

cl’

p1CD

CDCD

00

H-

Cf

CO0

0L

C’)C

DC

DP

Cf

cliCD

‘H

-H

CO

H-

cliCO

13

p111

CO

CO‘z

iCO

H-

C)

HCD

0CD

CO

Q.•I

13

CO

”p1

p1H

-0

Lii

H13

13dC

f0

CDU-

iH-

CO.1

3.’

NC

rCD

HW

CD

00L-

.1

3C

D13C

D13

.’

H13.’

i13

HCD

COM

ioC

CDC

Dj

COC

Oc-

rC

D<

‘C

)CO

H1o

C)

p1

H-

H-

p10

Cf

CDp1

CO0

H0

‘—ar

tCO

WO

I-•

0CD

13H

-H

-Cf

—3

QH

-H-

Cf•

0=

Crp1

WC

D013

p10

.‘0

I-I-

’13

H-

CO0C

Dp1

13cl

iP)

‘<Q

0H

-13

H-

(1CD

l,—3

p1•

131c

r(Q

130

0C

D—

CD-

I-’

13.’

CD13

H-

IP

)O

H-

OC

OII

Qp1

Mi

•CO

CO-

CD•

Cf

H13

1H••()

Mi•

•CD

Page 415: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

CDCD

Cl)

CDCD

CDCl

)CD

CDCD

CDCD

CDCD

CDçt

00

H0

CDCD

H-

H-

L’l

Lii

Lii

H-

H-

H-

0I-

c-f

(I)c-

fc-

Fc-

FC

rc-

fC

rH

--

CDP.’

HdO

cO

Ic1O

Ixj

HIL

II-

QC

DIH

H-

C4U

)F

OH

-I-

-H

HH

HC

DH

DC

D’-

ICI)

3IC

DP.’

°C

D‘s

oI>

-It

P)C

rU

1CI)

IH-

0.

.‘.

OU

).IQ

O-

‘-

ic’-

IU)

‘-]

U)Li

iW

(DU

)CD

IU)C

DCD

0t

100

P)O

MIC

D’

c-f

HQ

Q•P

)j

Ii-’i

WH

CD

•H°

H-

Ii-

10°

HC

D‘I

O—

•C

DlCD

0CD

0C

Di

IO

CDc-

tc-f

HO

H-

0•

CDCD

H°c--’-

Ic-’.

‘-iC

r‘1

Ic”

CDP

—.•

IHk

<‘-

CDpi

CDIC

rCD

ICr

CD1H

P)H

-“

P)P

Lii

Ic0

CDH

-H

-H

-P.’

U)CD

P.’U)

Cr

H-

‘CD

0.

IP)c

.o•

III

c..1.

p.p.

c-’.

c-f

<c-f

fr<

c-’

.p

i0q

-O

H-

alU

)-

CD

piC

rp.’

IH

P.’

Cr

CDII

hIC

DCD

CD

.jj=

.-

‘1‘1

.‘h-I

i-]’

.<H

<H

k<

IIH

-O

H-

IH

-H

0H

H-

•H

-•F

p’.’

II0

c-Fq

OH

-H

•H

-0

Cr’

j‘<

PJ

Pj

•P

JN

P.’

ww

•p.’

IP.’

0.1

CD

U)CD

—c-

t<:

H0p.’

HP)

‘-]

P.’‘-

]IhI

‘.0.

hIH

hI

hIH

hI

CDCl

)o

CDH

-j0

—I’

L’i

jo

ç-F

HU

)p!d

p’t

CD

Cr

Irn

U)

0H-

0H-

CDlH

-C

D‘ii

CD•O

H0H0

IP.’

oC

DC

MM

CD

CD

QC

D‘.

0C

D.’

‘.D

CD

P.’

c-F

HIi

H-

bP

),-

CD

c-.‘

Ct

H’i;

lp.’

0‘.H

J)H

CD

P.’

ICD

“H

HC

DF

ir?

p.’t.i•

H-

H)F

ii

MH

-P

-“.

c-..

hI

c-tp

.’‘0

C)‘C

3P

.’H

‘.0

hIH

bU

).[h

bC

rip

00

p)Q

,.RIi

EJh

Ii.

<h

ID)

b..’I

iCD

CD

P.’

iFic

-’.

OU

]CD

‘d[‘

3c-

F-.

CD

rno

H-

H-

H-

c-’.

lH

-H

-W

U)d

Ui

p.’c-F

frh

HP

Jx

j,

H-IC

D‘i

c0H

•c-•

IH

H0

CDU-

iH

OL

t1CD

‘.‘J

HII

Hd

°‘.H

Li1

P)

.Q

J‘.°

U)0’H

-pi

k<

HF

dC

DC

D•‘.c

.’H

-CD

aD

I-•

‘<U

)W

H-

H-

I0

CrL

XI’

.H

-.H

CD

[OC

Df3

CD

0H

Cr

HC

DH

P.’

H-

‘t-

HP

‘.0o

II.<

•tS

cF

CDC

D‘.-

‘.

H-

c-FU)

hIC

DC

DC

DP

.’(D

t5

‘-<

0o

‘hI”

CD

‘tip

.’p

.’:

‘.o

-CD

HH

CD‘-Q

P.’b

•.‘

CDp.’

HC

rP

ii‘-

<O

Cr

CD

CD

HH

-P.’

‘ZiP

CDCD

CD

HC

rC

rC

D“ii

‘.0

HP-

.p.’

H-

Oo

CI)

CD

.-j

o•

0CD

Cr

c-r

CDH

-Ii

Ho

iO

.‘P

)0

HH

-C

r’<

UiH

0

P.’C

rCD

CD

H-

0H

-0

CD‘d

CD

H-

CD

CDC

rCl

)H

0H

U)H

OC

rC

rH

U)

HO

CrC

r’.

00

0.

Po

‘zj

CrC

D]P

.p.’

-

FiP

)H

0C

rH-

(i)C

D..

-

HO

hI

OhI

oH

-C)

.iP.

’C

D1H

.H0

00

CD‘.0

OU

)0

H-I

tli

IHI—

’-I

CD

Fi

ICD

Içu

‘.D

’P)P

.’“1

(1)

‘iiC

DC

rU

iCU

).’

U)H

-I

P.

‘.o

CD

i-q

00

OF

OP

)‘‘

i-C

r10

10CD

W<

H-

P.’.C

DF

ic-’

.h

ICr

HU

1’Z

iI

i,-

I•

‘Cr

OU

)CD

CDU)

•P

.’hI

Cr

CDP

lCDlCD

HC

iP.’

qH

-U

)G)

U)G

)U)

IiCD

<‘.D

1ulU)

‘.0

hI<

P.’C

rCD

Cr

CDCD

U)C

rhI

IH-

‘.0H

-IC

rI

‘iJ‘.0

Cr

H0

—h

ICr

hIC

rCD

U)U

)CD

CDH

CDCD

P.’0

MC

DO

P.’U)

U)U)

CDCD

I•.‘)

hIl

-hI

Page 416: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

(1)

(1)

Cf

U)

H-

9)9)

9)9)

9)9)

9)9)

7j

‘1-3

-CD

CDCl)

9)2)

CD9)

H-

CD9)

0(1)

9)rt

HIH

-O

—J

IHL

xjd

CI)

C)

IQ

‘tH

--

QU

)’C

DIrtp

)0-

‘L

HU

)Q

frd

O9

)(1

)0U

)CD

I42

)0

2)I

CD

‘t3

iC

DH

-IH

-D)

<(I

)02)

c-r-’-

Io

I0’d<

H-

i.Q

H-

-3

IP

CD

CD

L’i

rr

Iw

Q0

ICD

CD

t-

IH

--

Mrt

(flH

-•

H-

CDC

DQ

9)

ICD

HU

H0

IH

0<

CD

hrt

IhC

Drtj

H--

-C

D’

9)pH

•ç

OH

-I2

)IH

CD

H-

2)Q

H’

2)0

--

.Qw

2)

IHC

DP

orrI2

),

rrH

<9)

CD9)

0irt

ir

rtO

PH

0O

CD

rtH

-I

ICD

C)Q

rt

rJ

Hç)

0H

.H•

<CDrt

IWC

D•

Ijh

I-

CDH

‘irt

p‘D

H-

•—

(I)

HH

-C

IW

9)9)

d2)

9)

rt

-H

H-

0j•

0r1-

CD

2)H

H-

i—’1

-2)•

9)H

-0H

-H

-(

HO

:CD

CD

°Q

Q(I)

CDCD

ji

--

U)C

DX

Ctj

29)

H-

-H

9)w

q(1

)C

)C

DC

DC

D(-tt

H-

C)p

hj

(1)I

H-C

DCl)

H-

H-

PH

H-

H-

c-t

9)H

-H

9)U

)H

-C

DH

-C

F•.

pjC

DF

-

CD

9)

CF

HP

jD

HCl)

Cl)C

DjQ

2)H

t2

G)’

‘<

H‘-3

H-

)tJ

9)Cl)

2)

CD

.d

H-<

-CF

CD‘t

I0

Cl-

CFU

-Mi

H-P

iC

Dp

:9)

WC

DH

-H

9)

CD

‘o9)

9)‘.

H-’

<0

Pir

jC

Dd

HCl)

2)H

-••

10

9)-

0W

H-

-l

Ho

2)

9)•

(1)

Cl)

H-

CD•

CD

-H

9Jrj

‘SD

CD

CC

).

0-3C

Dct

wl

Qp

QQ

•(1

)9)

-C

D0j

(1)‘1

cl-f

l)Ji

H-O

CD

H-

r0W

HQ

QC

D9)

CD

Ii“H

-P

CF

CD

9JH

-2

°0h

0C

D9)

Hi-

tH

-ct

0•

0C

DH

-’3

HC

D••

(1)u

9j9)H

-CD

CD

i-30

Cr

H-

CDII

CD

2)H

0-

C’

0(D

CD

WC

Dctc

tQ9)

‘-<C

D9

)C

D<

H-

<p

CD

9)0

CF

‘C

DC

FH

ç-

‘0

Q$)

“H

-’l

cH

tJH

ob.0

wC

D0

9)H

-H-

jI.<

H-

CD

H.

(‘)

wj

CDo

0Cl

-9)

HH

-H‘-

<a

CD

CD

CD0

9)C

D’

crC

DH

2)

<H

--

‘EjH

CD

-CF

H0H

-0H

‘CD

CD

CF

0H

IC

)2)1 CD

CD

IIi-

t0

Iw

9)9)

(1)H

-9)

CD

CFcU

MC

DO

0C

D0

H-

cl-

Hl0

Cr

LO

CF

FJ

i.<

•H

HW

0H-

9)p

Mj

CD

’’J

IH

,i

4H

-iH

<0

cr2

)<

ijC

DI

iIJ

0P

)CF

IH-

IPLI

J0

CrlCD

CD9)

1(1)

0lo

oI

H-

H-M

i‘-3

•H

-F’

ICFM

i0

LH

(1)

ow

00

DC

FH

-I’-

-

lU-C

DW

H-

iW

wM

iCD

CD2)

IH-

H-

CFCD

Hi

lo0

CtM

iO

H-

wIC

DH

H

CF

(DH

O•

0P

H-

—i

1C

FIo

(1)0

0I2

)ct

0-

‘1--li

lP

Q0

-CF

IO

cl-C

D••

Hi

l-IH

W

Page 417: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

<ci

cici

cici

cii—

3p—

]‘-3

-3‘-3

‘-3H

-CD

çtI

U)U)

CH

-H

-H

I-CF

I-H

-H

-H

-II

HH

HCF

H-

CDCD

ct

CFc-

F3

IICD

CUH

-C)

C)C

CDCD

CDCD

CUCD

cltIW

:13

lH-

13J13

xj-

cicl

Hcl

cH

IIç

)Jh

F-3F

-j-.

jj-r

IIh

13

H-

IO

HU

)C

DC

CFC

FC

CD

CD

H-

CC

CD

H-C

QC

FH

-0

CDH

CF

H-C

DC

F-

cl-

H-<

1“D

ZH

-Z1

CD

I)-

0F

fl)1

3IH

-CU

‘-QIC

DC

DC

F13<

CD

H-

CF

CD

IJC

Urt

CU

I13

k<

)C

D’-

<C

DC

DQ

1H13

oIn

H-C

U-

HU

)LI

IU

)CU

CD

HC

U•rt

CD

c-I’

d’H

13<

CU

)IH

-F

13

U)t’

0—

‘1I-

CF

j.clo

t-F

H-

CIH

-I

13

0•‘

CD

Qb

HC

FH

-13

CD

13

U)

H-

00

IC1i

clH

13

CDP

)c1J

13C

FH

’U)

U)U

)13

I0

OQ

H-

OH

-H

--C

DH

-c-

FC

DC

Fy

’9

CU

CD

13U)

CU

IrF

l3(Q

P)

°H

-H-

I13

U)c

-1

CFIH

<Q

CF

13

0•

13’

CF

13U

)C

F’

IH

CD

,C

UC

FCU

H<

OO

ICD

-H

-CU

H-

CD0

CUCF

CFH

-CF

•H

-0

U)U)

H-

flH

Icl

L•

IC)H

rF(1

)CU

Ii-3-

C1:0

’C

1C0

H-’

3M

&Q

0I’d

I°H

-C

UCU

CDC

Ufl

13W

13

-

QI•

CF

13

13H

CDw

clp

H-C

DIH

130

3-

cl

oL

I1U

)’d

1313

13-

CDH

HC

Fofr

hP

)C

It-I

cr)

I:r:tiI

ct,

IC)IC

DIc

lH

-I

tT

HQ

CD

13

(1••

CD

IU)o

CDC

D’

0H-

I1H

pj

cl

13

CD

CD

rn‘H

Q(1

)‘<

c-F

CDIii

hH

-H-

WC

DH

IPH

-11

CD

0U

)1

3’

r1

ICI)

CU13P

)0

‘0C

FI-

‘H

13

Hrty

H’s

O.

CDCU)

U)CU

11cl

I-q

0CU

H•

CD

CD

‘113

CD

LII

,H

Cl)H

-C

DC

1’

-CD

0U)

U)

H-C

FCU

CFH

HCD

H‘ti

1<

HU

)U

)H

-tJ

)H

13

’C

U)

13O

IJ13

H(.Q

11H

H-C

t0C

UC

DH

11U

)CD

CID

CDH

iCU

c-

PSH

CD13

H-

CDCU

H-

CUII

11,.

c-

H-13

1P

b’

Ci)

CD

13 pJ_J

‘.

‘d

-0

13

-H

’t°’

H-

13I°

H-

ciC

DQ

CD

CDCD

IiC

F1

I-

C)Q

13‘1

011cl

LII

°‘

11N

H-

H-

CDC

DC

D13

IU)C

UH

-13

U)H

CFcl

U)

H-

-‘

—._

_U

)i-

jH

-0’

CU

)<1

ICUC

D0

CDCD

H13

13C

FQ

U)C

U13

13‘d

i13n

:CF

Hcl

(9W1

3H

-11

H-

H-

0C

F0

LIJ

CU

cl13

C)0

CF-

CD

CU

CD

13C

D

clc

iH

-0

-11

3C

Fcl

•‘

CDC

‘CD

-H

Hocl

HCF

Ofl

13clC

UH

L1U

1-

IC

Dj<

M13Q

°C

F13

U)U)

H-H

13

H0

CDC

FU)

OH

-13

13.

-C

DC

DQ

CU

CDH

H.

H13

cl<

L’I.

°‘‘

-30C

DU

)H

-<

CDCU

jQ

U)

HC

U‘•

CD

13

H‘•C

JclC

DC

DC

l13

13C

FQ

CD

11‘-

<H

•‘i

iH

-H-

1313

CU

QH

.CU

ICU

0clr

tH

-II

CU

CDC

F13

CD

CF‘—3

HH

CF

(QQ

CF-

‘<C

UC

DC

D”

CD‘‘

--a

CDCD

0CD

H-

1313

CU..

13

Z13

U)

1311

CU13

CDCD

0C

UCU

CCF

CF0

U)

CU

CD

CF

11

13U)

-H

11-

H-

H-

-U)

HH

-U)

H-

0Cl

)0

‘DC

)’‘t

iH

-0

CH

-CU

CDc

CDCF

CUI

.‘D

CD

CU0

11C

U13

I-F-

’(V

H-

CF

”N

CU

1311

CD13

IH-O

H-Q

W11

U)CU

U)CD

cl’z

IO

O1

3C

UC

UH

-‘C

lC

l113

H-1

3’

‘CF

H“C

l•‘

U)•

-•

I’13

U)

Page 418: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

o0

CH

-H

-CD

H-

H-

H-

oH

HS)

H-

Hrt

rrH

Hi

I-III

CDH

Cl)

HCl)

CD-

Cl)II

Cl)H

CD(D

QJ

Ci)

HO

0H

b‘d

HH

C-I

CQ

-qIj-

LQ

()il

)H

-QC

D1

0-

Cl)

-‘D

CO

)w

‘-

do

ii

H-

(5

t3I-

CD

ctçl1

Hct

II-

rn

i-H

H-H

--H

--

-k<

J)C

DO

CP

JP

Pi

I-IC

DpJ

H--

0ctc

tW0

—P

H-

-W

H-

-H

iIw

H-

H-

.H

,C

-C

DC

D0

H-H

.)I

ctH

-L

’i

CDtl

)Cl2

:i:

ç-t

H.ct

HH

Ul

‘rjç

-tH

p.•

CH

H-H

-D

H-

CDCl

)(I)

HC

Dd

H-C

D1

HcvP

HC

l)W

CDCD

.C

DO

ct

P.

•J

iCD

1PO

Cl)

CD

q•q

WC

D

CW

CD

H.

C_)

IIjzj

H-

‘tI’

-o

ct

Hij

0H

CD

H-

H(l

)CD

QO

OJ•

HH

C?H

-C

WH

-H

-i

pH

-ce

rt

Pr1

°•

-H

-H

-(Q

i-nj

•“H

HC

1Ip

()P

JC

D‘H

‘••

pH

C?M

iP)

‘t5

PI

Cl)CD

H-C

H0H

H-i

CDH

’N

Cl)

CD

CD

-It’J

-iC

D(f

lLi

C?

H-

CD

U)

‘(t

CD

CD

HC

DC

Dç--

1-H

-C

l)P

)C

D’

‘C

-lCD

Cr

CDI’

JCD

CDrn

CDC

DC

CQ

Z<

I--

CC?

CCl)

H-

H-

CD

ct

CC

•Q

‘i

CD-t

piH

-CD

CDH

-pj

WH

-H

-:i

CC

C?

Ct

H-

C?

C)

(D

IC

Dçt

.cr

QC

D

C)

CP

)C

DC

DH

()C

DC

(.CC

D-r

CD•

Cl)

o:i

CDtC

l)Cl

)•

H-1

CD10

Cl)CD

-Cl

)pi

Cl)

C•H

H-

L’J

0C

crC

CDcC

Oct

CDIJ

)P)

‘-<C

DH

-Cl

)C

tC

DD

)

Cl)C

Cl)

flC

DH

-Cl)

CDP

)’tJ

CD

oC

nC

D

C•.

jC

Cpi

jH-

CDH

-c-F

CH

-H

Pic

tC

DH

iH

-C

niH

CDpi<

I1

4crL

’“

C)CD

HC

Dpj

çt

PH

H-H

-WP

°•

PH

-C

DC

oC

pi‘d

C-

••

CL

QH

‘.OH

CC

Dct

H-

I0H-

HCD

CDII

cH

Ii

CDH

H-

Q..

HC

DcF

CD

CW

H.

IwCD

•p,

CD

CC

jC

CC

DPI

Cr

oH

-jH

-H

‘-

Nrtxj

EI

CDCD

CD

CH

-C

tC

H-

-c-F

i•.

CDC

Ct

—.H

-C

DCD

H-

CDC

oct

•“

CFH

-WH

-C

ICD

Cl)

)H

Ct

CDH

-Cl)

iCi)

C?‘..

DCI

)1P

JCl)

C)C

Ci)

H-

H-

1-H

-L’

JH

-ct

‘DH

P1O

CD

H-

Cl)

H.

(P

)CD

CH

-P

)JC

?H

-W

PJ

H-

C)‘dC

D•C

CDCD

Page 419: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

pipJ

00

00

00

U)0

0P)

CDC)

Mi

HH

HH

U)U)

rt1Q

U)C

_

Cl)-

1)IflJ

C1QH

-M

CD

IC!)

-H

IfltT

CID

CH

0L

’J

Ci)

HIO

PJ

H-

—a-

wlo

o-

do

rt-

>(

0i

P)I

PJ

oIo

CD

CD

qil-

i0

PJ

I<

Ii

CD

H-C

DH

i°t-

H-I

hP

’<

HF

-PJ

H0-

hIH

-i-

WIU

)O

H<

j0

HU

)iI

c1)H

(DI

H-C

DH

MO

UiO

P0H

-IH

-IH

-H

-QC

DC

DP

I1

1Q

HiI

CD

U1

CD

t•QU

)H

ipj

pH

-o

lpiH

iM

iQ

Qf—

’‘C

DU)

0H

-0

II

HH

-U)

H-

I0

0=

U)H

Hrt

CD

i-3

CD

ct

PJ.

H-Q

.çC

DC

DI-I

ç-t

0F

xj

H?

Ii

Ic-tC

DrF

CD

.H

-U

)CD

U)IU

)(DC

DC

DI•

0H-

U)

CDC

DCD

0IU

)U

)lU

)1C

-r

p<

C1

CtC

tIH

-Cl

)‘-

Ht-.

IL’J

ICD

00o

HP

JIp

jHC

l)pj

CDP

ipi

c1In

’-Id

HO

QH

HP

’H

-H

CDH

-H

-CD

[p<

HCD

ICD

k1

.-

U)H

Li

U)r

r-4

1U)C

DIcj

IC

Dxj

H-

HC

D-

<H

(--

0U

)CD

HC

D‘1

I<U

)Cl

)°13

H-

H-H

-1

ij

U)Q

(t<

rirt

(D

CD

CD

pj H

H-

..C

DCI

)•

0C

DI

H-

P)C

l)pj

CDU

)rt:J

CD

i-3H

WC)

WH

U)H

H-(

DC

DH

pi0P rt

•j’

j()

hIH

-•C

DH

=

4H

‘iO

CD

I1)

>‘•

)CD

rtH

-‘-

<(-

7C

D0

)iC

tH

p)I

1P

)I

‘-<

a‘t

IPi

Ct

‘C

D‘U

)0

H-

U)h

II’i

CFI

Pp

iH

-‘H

‘-<

(D

1W

IipJ

PH0

OH

-Ip

ihI

H.

CD

p.

Mi

Ct

‘H-

IM

iIC

D0-

°“0

H(n

Ctrt

—.

CD

CD0

H‘-<

1<CD

U)<

IC)

F--i,

I-IC

D<

-tlCD

U)U

)CD

‘.oH

pj

CD--

U)CD

HC

DIP)

HH

CD

oH

-H0

lo‘0

L-’

QH

°H

“pi

CD

H.I

O<

‘-<CF

HH

IHp)p)

pj1

CD

hI-

.PC

•U

)0

•U)

‘1H

H-

)P

ICD

<o

•i

1O

U)

IpC

I)

U)(

l)CD

ICp)(

DP

)H

-“

gP

)(j)

I•PC

oi’-

H-

CFC

l)

CDPC

piP

)0

CFpjp

,PJ

p)H

iH

IzI

<IjI

-<

CCl

)Q

piF

jH-Q

HP

l0

U)(

U)

))C

tH

iCD

H-

CI)

IIH

QH

-H

-H

-0Q

HU

i

P1q

PCC

)H

U)hI

0.

P1cn

CD

pi&

HCD

‘IH

I-]

Hoo

t-

piI

ii‘-

<cm

‘Z

hIIj

coP

H-

lU)0

cmI

-‘-

‘IH

-H

-lo

P1P

Ho

U)1P1

‘-<

•I

U)piP

)H

IP

CI

-‘-I

D‘

H-

IH

C)

IH

-CD

hIP1

WO•

0Cl

)IP

CCD

QP

1I

HH

iH

IQ

H

PChI

CDhI

U)CF

H-

I0

•IH

H-

•hI

CDC’

)hI

ICt

(.Q:C

D

U)H

-PC

H-

<U)

H-

CD

HIhI

0hIL

CDhIH

-IC

Cp1

U)lC

D.

U)P

)H

P-’

lCD13

I0

U)1

3IP

iPi

CD13

(1)13

-rt

13’-

<H

..•

••Ih

IC

FC

F-

Page 420: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

NN

NH

-CD

0pi

‘-CD

HH

0C)

CDH

-H-

iJC

HJ(D

—rj

PJ

Cl)

jrr

Qij-.

U)

HS)

)Q

QH

.DH

-PJ

tY-

.piC

)i

kD

H-

Piçt

L’J

H(D

HrtP

i—

It

-C

Dpji-

(D

.çt..H

‘d0

H-C

l)H

0CD-j

‘o(D

dC

DC

DC

DH

-W

-(l

)H-

10rt

0U

)U

)1

0•

•H

-H

-p)U

)C

DH

°)

Zc

ciP

iciO

-Ioo

LJ.

1H

HP

iU)

0’Z

qO

;(DC

D r1

CD

L’i

pj

‘oH

P-’(D

HC

CI)

-oo

Irj

0U)

rt

CD

O HO

(D

H-r

IC

D

0rt

PJU

)iO

rt

H-

0pi

CD

H-C

D0

CD

-•

U)H

J)

0PJ

CD

LQ

Ii-

C?H

-C?

rtli

i9

CDC

DP

JOQ

IP)

C?-

Ht-

ICD

WC

D

Page 421: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

ih

-I

Iqiq

c-q

iqH

IH

H0

10‘-

jL

ii

iij

i’-

ii

ikD

CDI

IC’)C’)

PJIP-’

iI

IHC’i

0Ipi

Ip-’I

w1w

1wIH

IPJCD

<1W

CIII

Ibhi

IHIH

H-

IC’)

IpiIpi

IIIH

-C’)

C’)C’)

C’)i

iIi

I’--

CDI’d

idCD

Li

IC<

<I

1wI

Ipi

10C

C’)IC”

IC’)

C’)ff1I

wIç

Ipiw

IH-

11<1W

1wII

ICD

lCDH

-1W

IH-

H-

IC

tH

-lCD

H-

hihi

çt

1wIC

<tfl

C’)H

-

ICt

piI

lCDlCD

ICC

<iw

i-C

H

rFI

HH

P-

IP-IC

IIIC

IH-

IH-

1wCD

H-

IH-

IH

PH

II

.I’tJ

HI

C’id

Cl)Irt

ICD

H

IH-

1i

Ct

I)H

-I

C’)I

IlCD

C

Ikp

hi

IH-

H-

IHiw

iwCD

CDiw

IHiw

‘-]

lCD‘I

‘I1rt

C’)C

lCDw

iI

III)

IH-

wlCD

Ct

CDH

-ir

tH

ICt

H-

Li

IH-

1wlCD

CI’-

1wI

‘iCt

-Iii

ff2IH

-ICr

wIH

0•

1ww

CDCD

hiC’)

CDCD

C‘-L

CDH

-C

•t

CDH

w•

Ct

CDCD

CII

Ii

•C

t•

H-

CII

IICL

)C

Cr

CH

‘1C’)

‘<—

-w

CD‘-<

çt

C’)H

OH

wH

-0

ti:i

IIC’)

U)H

0II

HH

••

•C

tC’)

iCD

CDC

tL

iC

tII

IICD

CDC’)

H-

dCD

H-

Ho

H-

IIC’)

HH

-Ii

Ct

iC

tCl

)C’)

H-

C’)H

-•

HC

Ct

CD0

•H

-•

CC’) H

C’)H

HL

iH

LiH

-H C

tQ

H-

oCD

•C

t C’) H H C’) H C)

CD Ct

II CD

Page 422: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

II<

IcCl

idh

-Ii—

3ii

-Ii-

]IC

,)Cl

)IC

,)Z

Ii

-]fr

jI

iIc

uIcr

cI

I:5I1

II

PIPJ

a)‘-

ik

1(0lCD

hi)

PIC

I(V

HIC

!)IC’

)I

ICD

0‘d

IHI

kIi-<

IP

‘IH

-ic

rIc

rPi

I-i

IItD

lCDic

rIc

1Z1<

ICl

)0

IIP)

IP)

I’-

Cr

H-

H-

CDIii

iii

IHIC)

1W

Q

IIa)

II

IPJIP)

H-

ttj1w

I

lCD1(1)

ICPi

iI

IH-

HC

l)IE

’H

HI

iIC

RH

-iC

l)IH

-1-3

C)I

—CD

H-

H-

IpiI

IH-

‘Cl]

IP

C)I

icr

IH

-(0

H-

icr

If-]

IhID

)IH

I’-’I

II

lCDlCD

(0I

ib<

0CD

IcI

iI

Ct)

It!)

Hq

ti)IH

-U)

it!)-

iI

FCD

ICI

IbC)

CrH

-H

fliI

Hi

CCD

IC‘-3

(1)lCD

HIH

-P

Cl)

Cl)

CDCD

IH

-Cl]

Ihili

ilCD

C)

H-

IIP)

lCDCl

)H

lCD1H

Cl)II

cr1w

CD•

Cpi

11L’

Jii

oH

-C)

•H

IIC)

0‘1

crH

(0•

CDC H

-C)

CD CDIi

H

wH

Cl)

CDH

-C

CDii ct

wC 0 H ‘1 CD ct U) frb C 1b 0 CD w Cr

Page 423: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

INTERVIEWS

From late January 1994 to the end of July 1994, I conducted morethan 100 in-depth, open-ended, confidential interviews -- generallybetween 1 to 3 hours -- with government officials, businessleaders, academics, private consultants (whose firms remainanonymous), and NGO representatives in the Philippines, theMalaysian states of Sabah and Sarawak, Peninsular Malaysia (KualaLumpur), Indonesia, Singapore, and Japan. I am indebted to numerousindividuals at the following organizations.

A. INDONESIA

APKINDO [Asosiasi Panel Kayu Indonesia], Jakarta.

Asian Wetlands Bureau, Bogor.

Bogor Agricultural University, Faculty of Forestry, Kampus IPBDarmaga, Bogor.

Bogor Agricultural University, Environmental Research Centre,Kampus IPB Darmaga, Bogor.

Centre For International Forestry Research (CIFOR), Bogor.

Centre for Economic and Environmental Studies, EnvironmentalEconomics Studies Foundation, Jakarta.

Indonesian Eco-Labelling Program, Jakarta.

International Tropical Timber Organization (ITTO), IndonesiaOffice, Jakarta.

JICA, Indonesia Office, Jakarta.

Ministry of Forestry, Indonesia, PHPA (Forestry Conservation),Bogor.

Ministry of Forestry, Indonesia, Bureau of InternationalCooperation and Investment, Jakarta.

Ministry of Planning [BAPPENAS], Jakarta.

Ministry of Forestry, Indonesia, Forest Utilization, Jakarta.

Ministry of Forestry, Indonesia, Forest Protection and NatureConservation, Jakarta.

PEL.ANGI INDONESIA (Policy Research for Sustainable Development),Jakarta.

413

Page 424: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

Rimbawan Muda Indonesia (RMI) [Indonesian Institute for Forestryand Environmental Research & Service], Bogor.

SKEPHI [NGO Network For Forest Conservation in Indonesia], Jakarta.

State Ministry for the Environment, Jakarta.

WALHI, (Indonesian Forum for the Environment), Jakarta.

B. JAPAN

Centre for Environmental Policy & Advocacy: Tokyo (CEPAT), Tokyo.

Environment Agency, Office of Overseas Environmental Cooperation,Tokyo.

Environment Agency, Global Environment Department, Tokyo.

EXIM Bank of Japan, Environment Section, Tokyo.

Friends of the Earth Japan, Tokyo.

International Development Centre of Japan, Tokyo.

International Tropical Timber Organization (ITTO), Yokohama.

Itochu Corporation, Department of Global Environment, Tokyo.

Japan Plywood Manufacturers’ Association, Tokyo.

Japan Lumber Importers’ Association, Tokyo.

Japan Plywood Inspection Corporation, Tokyo.

JATAN, [Japan Tropical Forest Action Network], Tokyo.

JICA, Forestry Cooperation Division, Forestry & FisheriesDevelopment Cooperation Department, Tokyo.

JOFCA [Japan Overseas Forestry Consultants Association] , Tokyo.

Keidanren, [Japan Federation of Economic Organizations], GlobalEnvironment Department, Tokyo.

Marubeni, Environmental Protection Department, Tokyo.

Ministry of Agriculture, Forestry, and Fisheries, Forestry Agency,International Forestry Cooperation Centre, Tokyo.

MITI, Environmental Policy Division, Industrial Location andEnvironmental Protection Bureau, Tokyo.

414

Page 425: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

MITI, Global Environment Division, Tokyo.

Mitsubishi Corporation, Environmental Affairs Department, Tokyo.

Nissho Iwai, Environment 21, Tokyo.

OECF, Environment and Social Development Division, Tokyo.

RETROF [Research Association For Reforestation of Tropical Forest],Tokyo.

Sumitomo Forestry Co. Ltd., Green Environmental R&D Division,Tokyo.

University of Tokyo, International Environmental Planning Centre(INTEP), Tokyo.

University of Tokyo, Faculty of Agriculture, Department ofForestry, Tokyo.

WWF [World Wide Fund For Nature] Japan, Tokyo.

C. PENINSULAR MALAYSIA

Asian Wall Street Journal, Kuala Lumpur.

Far Eastern Economic Review, Kuala Lumpur.

Malaysian Timber Industry Board, Ministry of Primary Industries,Kuala Lumpur.

Ministry of Primary Industries, Kuala Lumpur.

Universiti Pertanian Malaysia (UPM), Faculty of Forestry, Serdang,Selangor.

WWF Malaysia, Petaling Jaya.

D. PHILIPPINES

Asian Development Bank, Mandaluyong, Metro Manila.

Centre For Investigative Journalism, Manila.

Department of Environment and Natural Resources (DENR), ENR-SECALProgram (World Bank/DENR), Quezon City.

DENR, National Forestation Development Office, Quezon City.

DENR, ENR-SECAL Program (World Bank/DENR), Monitoring and

415

Page 426: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

Enforcement Office, Quezon City.

DENR, Forest Management Bureau, Forest Economic Division, QuezonCity.

International Rice Research Institute (IRRI), Los Banos, Laguna.

Philippine News and Features.

Philippine Institute for Development Studies (PIDS), Makati, MetroManila.

University of the Philippines, College of Forestry, Los Banos,Laguna.

WWF Philippine Program, San Juan, Metro Manila.

E. SABAH, MALAYSIA

Consulate of Japan, Kota Kinabalu.

Department of Industrial Development and Research (Sabah), KotaKinabalu.

Innoprise Corporation Sdn. Bhd., a subsidiary of Yayasan Sabah[Sabah Foundation], Kota Kinabalu.

Institute For Development Studies, Institut Kajian Pembangunan(Sabah), Kota Kinabalu.

Ministry of Tourism and Environmental Development (Sabah), KotaKinabalu.

Rakyat Berjaya Sdn. Bhd., a subsidiary of Innoprise CorporationSdn. Bhd., Kota Kinabalu.

Sabah Forestry Department [Jabatan Perhutanan Sabah], RegionalOffice, Kota Kinabalu.

Sabah Sawmillers Industries Association, Kota Kinabalu.

Sabah Re-aftorestation Technical Development and Training Project,Kinarut.

Sabah Melale Wood Industries, Sdn. Bhd., Kota Kinabalu.

Sabah Forestry Development Authority (SAFODA), Kota Kinabalu.

Sabah State Library, [Perpustakaan Negeri Sabah], Kota Kinabalu.

Timber Association of Sabah (TAS), Rota Kinabalu.

416

Page 427: JAPAN AND THE POLITICS OF TIMBER IN SOUTHEAST ASIA …

WWF Malaysia, Sabah Office, Kota Kinabalu.

Yayasan Sabah [Sabah Foundation], Kota Kinabalu.

F. SARAWAX, MALAYSIA

JICA’s Effective Wood Utilization research Project, Timber Researchand Technical Training Centre, Kuching.

Sarawak Timber Association [Persatuan Kayu Kayan Sarawak], Kuching.

Sarawak Forest Department (various sections), Kuching.

Sarawak Timber Industry Development Corporation [PerbadananKemajuan Perusahaan Kayu Sarawak] , Kuching.

Universiti Malaysia Sarawak, Kota Samarahan.

417

I-’