10
GOVERNMENT BONDS AND EUROPEAN DEBT MARKETS Jan Toporowski ‘The international financial system is already in such a state in which as soon as the holes in one place start to be patched up, new ones appear in a different place.’ Kalecki 1932. Introduction Just as mainstream economics discovers how to model financial crisis actual events reveal that the crisis is much deeper and this greater depth is expressed in the serial character of the crisis. Current models show crisis as a shock in a dynamic stochastic general equilibrium, with contagion effects arising because heterogeneous agents hold as assets each others’ liabilities (see, for example, Goodhart, Sunirand and Tsocomos 2004). However, the actual course of events since the 2007 financial crisis emerged seems to suggest that, far from a resumption of general equilibrium after the ‘shock’ of that crisis, financial systems have succumbed to a series of shocks. The discussion of financial crisis has moved from modelling the resumption of general equilibrium among agents abstracted from the real world, or empirical data, to a rather more practical discussion of policies and institutional mechanisms for stabilising financial systems. This paper discusses the role of Government debt markets in managing such crises. The first section of the paper discusses the mechanisms by which a well-managed Government bond market may stabilise capital markets in nominal, or cash-flow, terms. The second section looks at the crisis in European government bond markets and suggests ways in which those markets may be converted into stabilising mechanisms 1

J. Toporowski - EURO Government Bonds

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: J. Toporowski - EURO Government Bonds

GOVERNMENT BONDS AND EUROPEAN DEBT MARKETS

Jan Toporowski

‘The international financial system is already in such a state in which as soon as the holes in one place start to be patched up, new ones appear in a different place.’ Kalecki 1932.

Introduction

Just as mainstream economics discovers how to model financial crisis actual events reveal that the crisis is much deeper and this greater depth is expressed in the serial character of the crisis. Current models show crisis as a shock in a dynamic stochastic general equilibrium, with contagion effects arising because heterogeneous agents hold as assets each others’ liabilities (see, for example, Goodhart, Sunirand and Tsocomos 2004). However, the actual course of events since the 2007 financial crisis emerged seems to suggest that, far from a resumption of general equilibrium after the ‘shock’ of that crisis, financial systems have succumbed to a series of shocks. The discussion of financial crisis has moved from modelling the resumption of general equilibrium among agents abstracted from the real world, or empirical data, to a rather more practical discussion of policies and institutional mechanisms for stabilising financial systems.

This paper discusses the role of Government debt markets in managing such crises. The first section of the paper discusses the mechanisms by which a well-managed Government bond market may stabilise capital markets in nominal, or cash-flow, terms. The second section looks at the crisis in European government bond markets and suggests ways in which those markets may be converted into stabilising mechanisms for European capital markets. The conclusion outlines some implications of the analysis for an ‘optimal’ government bond issue.

1. Bonds and capital market stability

Since the Modigliani-Miller studies of the late 1950s it has been widely assumed that the composition of financial instruments in capital markets is merely the aggregation of individual agents’ financing and saving preferences and has no serious implications for the functioning or liquidity of those markets. This is usually because finance theory largely omits considerations of liquidity: The standard definition of financial equilibrium, a situation in which no further arbitrage is possible implicitly assumes that market liquidity is available on demand. As recent events have demonstrated, such liquidity has a disturbing tendency to disappear when it is most urgently required (See Nesvetailova 2010).

1

Page 2: J. Toporowski - EURO Government Bonds

In the paper that follows financial stability refers to the maintenance of the money price of financial assets. These money values are the key parameters for maintaining payments on banking and financial commitments. This is for two reasons. First of all, with the exception of inflation-related derivative instruments, or index-linked bonds (see below), the cash payments that issuers of financial instruments make are related to the nominal value, and not the value of such instruments in relation to goods and services. Secondly, and perhaps even more importantly, payments on financial obligations are money commitments. They cannot be replaced by delivery of goods and services. Where payments on financial obligations are hedged by other assets, those assets have to be sold to raise money in order to meet those payments, or money borrowed against their nominal value. In other words, financial instability is a default on money obligations, and not on real ones.

This does not mean that inflation in markets for goods and services may not threaten the stability of banking and financial markets. It may do so as part of a general debt deflation problem, or a devaluation of money contracts. But the result is a macroeconomic problem, rather than strictly a default on payments commitments arising out of the operations of banking and financial markets.

In an earlier study, I argued that, in a capital market with debt and equity, a high proportion of bonds in the portfolios of market participants tends to stabilise the market. This is because bonds have an ‘assured residual liquidity’, which anchors prices and expectations in the market for those bonds. Financial intermediaries’ balance sheets can be constructed in such a way that future payment commitments may be matched with assured future payment receipts. By contrast, shares or common stock have no ‘assured residual liquidity’. The wider dispersion of possible future values makes these stocks preferred vehicles for speculation, i.e., purchase for capital gain rather than income. An extended period of capital market inflation boosts equity prices and this distorts the preferences of investors towards equity, and encourages equity financing without stable market values (Toporowski 2000, pp. 23-24). Index-linked bonds, or hybrid bonds currently recommended as a source of bank capital, are clearly in between the equity/bond distinction, having the appearance of bonds, but without the assured residual liquidity of equity. Index-linked bonds invite potentially destabilising speculation against future inflation, and hybrid bonds may arouse similar speculation against bank insolvency.

A high proportion of bonds in the capital market therefore makes those markets more stable and less speculative, because of the limited scope for capital gains. In turn, such reduced variability would make for more consistent portfolio and financing choices, and a sounder basis for the expectations of market participants. The greater stability of the market should be reflected in the stability of an ‘average’ portfolio of financial assets. However, once portfolios become heterogeneous the ‘average’ portfolio becomes less representative. Two recent trends in particular have increased the heterogeneity of portfolios. The first is the rise of specialist funds, such as private equity funds, or hedge funds, with much less diverse portfolios. The second is the absorption of large quantities of government bonds by central banks: For example, some two thirds of U.S. government

2

Page 3: J. Toporowski - EURO Government Bonds

bond issues are held as long-term investments by central banks and their associated sovereign wealth funds. This greater heterogeneity therefore makes for less stability in the market if the full variety of portfolio holders is not present in the market at any one time.

While corporate bonds could in theory provide stability for the capital market, in practice they are less efficient stabilisers than government bonds for two reasons. First of all, corporate bonds still have some element of risk associated with them. It is therefore imprudent for central banks to guarantee the market for corporate bonds, in the same way that central banks can guarantee the market for government bonds. Secondly, most issues of equity are to repay corporate debt. This means that, in a phase of capital market inflation, corporate bond issues are more likely to be reduced, rather than increasing pari passu with the increased value of equity. An overinflated equity market may end up on a very thin foundation of corporate bonds.

It is true that government bonds too are not perfect stabilisers of the capital market: The government’s fiscal balance tends to vary in a counter-cyclical way, while the stock market moves with the business cycle, or slightly ahead of it. The result is that the issue of government securities varies inversely with stock prices. However, this is in any case complicated by institutional factors, such as the absorption by central banks and sovereign wealth funds of government securities, due to chronic international trade imbalances. The capital market may still be efficiently stabilised if there is a permanent stock of government debt outstanding that can be converted into long term bonds during the boom, taking liquidity out an inflating capital market, and then converted into shorter-term securities to provide stable liquid assets for the banking system in the recession.

The banking system too benefits from holding large quantities of government bonds which, contrary to the view of fiscal conservatives, do not squeeze out lending to the private sector. They may do so in a commodity money setting. But in a credit economy, credit is enhanced, rather than restricted, by the availability of larger quantities of readily realisable government bonds. The stabilising influence of government securities in bank portfolios is well illustrated in the case of U.S. banks. In 2006 their holdings of U.S. Treasury securities in nominal terms were more or less the same as they were twenty years before. On the eve of their biggest banking crisis since the Great Depression, U.S. banks held negligible amounts of Treasury securities.

Therefore, as Minsky argued, a government bond market embracing all financial intermediaries and managed by central bank is essential for stabilising investment portfolios (Minsky 1986, 33-37). The alternative is more extreme financial cycles and, with the build-up of debt in the economy, an eventual condition of ‘serial’ crises preventing economic recovery. It should also be pointed out that the above remarks apply to Government borrowing in its domestic currency. The fears of Government default, that were so widespread in European financial markets, have a rational foundation in the case of borrowing in foreign currency. In the case of domestic currency, default does not arise because the government always has two options available to manage its internal borrowing. First of all, a Government can increase taxes (for example on holders of

3

Page 4: J. Toporowski - EURO Government Bonds

government bonds) in order to service its debts. Secondly, the Government can always refinance along the yield curve, e.g., reducing short-term interest rates and issuing short-term bills, the proceeds of which can be used to buy in long-term government bonds. Such short-term bills are usually readily held by banks because of their liquidity: on maturity, the Government can usually repay the bills through a new issue of bills. Only in extreme cases, such as in conditions of hyperinflation, would such debt management be impossible.

2. Stabilising European capital markets

Within the Eurozone the cyclical issue of government securities that was mentioned above as an impediment to efficient capital market stabilisation has, in practice, turned out to be less of a factor in the issue of government securities because, contrary to their best intentions, the founding fathers of the European Monetary Union have failed to harmonise the respective national business cycles of member countries. Harmonisation was supposed to be a condition for joining the monetary union. However, when harmonisation failed, the effect of the common monetary policy should, if monetary policy works as intended, make business cycles diverge even more: The common monetary policy set by ‘average’ conditions in the Eurozone would tend to be too inflationary for the countries in a boom, and too deflationary for those countries experiencing recession.

In principle, such a situation should keep a stable supply of government bonds in the Eurozone capital market. However, the institutional rules of the Eurozone are resolutely hostile to government bond stabilisation of the capital market. The fact that there has not been a major capital market crisis (notwithstanding the current serial government bond crises) says rather more about the immaturity of the Eurozone capital market than about any natural equilibrium properties that it may have. The hostility to government bond stabilisation arises out of the view prevalent in the most powerful country of the zone, Germany, that central banks should not in principle hold government bonds in their portfolios, other than for repurchase purposes, because to do so would be to monetise government deficits. This, it is believed, is inflationary. This principle is incorporated in the rules that are supposed to make the Eurozone central banks ‘independent’ of governments. The result of this reluctance to hold government debt is that the ECB instead monetises private debt or issues its own paper. Such private debt, issued and monetised to excess, is causing serial crises.

The outbreak of the crisis in 2008 placed different financial pressures on different governments. Without central bank management of the government bond market, premiums emerged on bonds issued by different governments. As the table shows, these premiums are unrelated to the actual debt/GDP ratios, but are largely influenced by perception of banking crises in different countries. Yet in Greece, which set off the Eurozone crisis in 2010, there has been no bank crisis.

4

Page 5: J. Toporowski - EURO Government Bonds

Government Debt and Bond Yields

Government Debt as % of GDP Spread of 10-yearGovernment bonds

2010 2013 over German bunds(basis points) (Jan.11)

Greece 130 144 880

Italy 118 120 196

Belgium 100 106 134

Ireland 94 105 625

Portugal 83 92 423

France 84 90 47

Hungary 78 80 522

UK 77 86 63

Germany 75 77 0

Austria 70 75 58

Netherlands 66 74 23

Spain 63 79 270

Source: International Monetary Fund, Financial Times (11 January 2011) and author’s calculations.

Germany itself, whose government issues the benchmark bonds for the Eurozone, owes the stability of its government bond market less to the prudence of its government, and more to its pension system which is obliged to hold large quantities of government bonds, with maturities matched to pension liabilities. The German pension system therefore not only stabilises itself against the problems of pension fund maturity that have wrecked equity-dependent American and British funded pension schemes. By buying in large quantities of government bonds, the German pension system also helps to stabilise the market for such bonds and keeping the yield on 10-year bonds at a low of 3.26%.

5

Page 6: J. Toporowski - EURO Government Bonds

However, in general institutional investors’ holding of government bonds cannot be an effective stabiliser for the market in such bonds. It works in Germany because the distribution of income and wealth is relatively equal, and pension funds there have a correspondingly greater influence over the capital markets. Most other countries in the Eurozone have a more unequal distribution of income and wealth. This gives their pension funds less influence over their capital markets. The institution that is, most generally, best placed to maintain a liquid market in government securities is the central bank, in particular because it has the capacity to expand and keep its balance sheet liquid in a way that other institutions cannot.

Conclusion: An ‘Optimal’ Government Bond Issue?

The above analysis suggests that three conditions must be in place to avoid serial crises of financial systems. First of all, the supply of government bonds in private portfolios should be sufficient to maintain the liquidity of private capital markets. Secondly, participants in banking and capital markets should be obliged to hold government paper in some proportion of their portfolios (as German institutions are obliged to hold government securities). Thirdly, central banks should maintain a liquid market in government securities. Only in such conditions can capital markets maintain the stable liquidity necessary to price assets in accordance with their assessment of the economic prospects of the issuer of financial paper.

Thus the determination of the ‘optimal’ govt bond issue should not start with some arbitrary ratio of government debt to GDP, or fiscal deficit, let alone some nebulous Ricardian prospect of being able to repay all the debt in the future, as Barro and some New Classical theorists have suggested. In a capitalist system with sophisticated financial markets, the starting point has to be the size and value of the capital market that needs to be stabilised. This determines the issue of risk-free government paper that must be held in private portfolios. Only the government and its central bank can do this because only the government can operate along the whole yield curve all the time, and such policy must be integrated with monetary policy and, as recent events have shown, with the function of a lender of last resort.

References

Goodhart, C.A.E., Sunirand, P., and Tsocomos, D.P. (2004) ‘A model to analyse financial fragility: applications’ Journal of Financial Stability vol. I no. 1, pp. 1-30.

Kalecki, M. (1932) ‘Czy możliwe jest „kapitalistyczne” wyjscie z kryzysu’ (Is a „capitalist” way out of the crisis possible) Przegląd Socjalistyczny 2/10, pp. 1-2.

6

Page 7: J. Toporowski - EURO Government Bonds

Minsky, H.P. (1986) Stabilizing an Unstable Economy New Haven: Yale University Press.

Nesvetailova, A. (2010) Financial Alchemy in Crisis: The Great liquidity Illusion London: Pluto Press.

Toporowski, J. (2000) The End of Finance: The Theory of Capital Market Inflation, Financial Derivatives and Pension Fund Capitalism London: Routledge.

7