28
Interlinkages between Growth, Distribution and Re-Distribution in Emerging Market Economies Vandana Bhaskaran* and Manasa Venkatesh** Abstract: We analyse the simultaneous relationship between growth, distribution and re- distribution. Three issues emerge: the difficulty in establishing definitive causation between two sets of variables, the complex linkages between growth, distribution and re-distribution, and identifying the best form of re-distribution. We investigate these issues in Emerging Market Economies during 19802010, and consider the time dimension in our analysis. Keywords: Market income inequality, Net income inequality, Growth, Re-distribution, Emerging Market Economies, System GMM *Final Year Masters student in Economics at the Indian Institute of Technology Madras. The author can be contacted at [email protected] ** Final Year Masters student in Economics at the Indian Institute of Technology Madras. The author can be contacted at [email protected] Acknowledgements: We thank Dr. Suresh Babu for his guidance and useful comments

Interlinkages between Growth, Distribution and Re-Distribution in … · 2014-10-23 · Interlinkages between Growth, Distribution and Re-Distribution in Emerging Market Economies

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    3

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Interlinkages between Growth, Distribution and Re-Distribution in … · 2014-10-23 · Interlinkages between Growth, Distribution and Re-Distribution in Emerging Market Economies

Interlinkages between Growth, Distribution and Re-Distribution

in Emerging Market Economies

Vandana Bhaskaran* and Manasa Venkatesh**

Abstract: We analyse the simultaneous relationship between growth, distribution and re-

distribution. Three issues emerge: the difficulty in establishing definitive causation between two

sets of variables, the complex linkages between growth, distribution and re-distribution, and

identifying the best form of re-distribution. We investigate these issues in Emerging Market

Economies during 1980–2010, and consider the time dimension in our analysis.

Keywords: Market income inequality, Net income inequality, Growth, Re-distribution, Emerging

Market Economies, System GMM

*Final Year Masters student in Economics at the Indian Institute of Technology Madras. The

author can be contacted at [email protected]

** Final Year Masters student in Economics at the Indian Institute of Technology Madras. The

author can be contacted at [email protected]

Acknowledgements: We thank Dr. Suresh Babu for his guidance and useful comments

Page 2: Interlinkages between Growth, Distribution and Re-Distribution in … · 2014-10-23 · Interlinkages between Growth, Distribution and Re-Distribution in Emerging Market Economies

1

1. INTRODUCTION

Economists and political leaders alike have been sounding alarm bells over rising income

inequality across economies, their fear only worsened by the 2008 financial crisis. While many

analysts still hold that economic weakness caused by income inequality led to the crisis, the issue

of the relationship between economic growth and inequality has been heavily discussed and

severely contested. Although the crisis saw the return of the questions of distribution at the centre

of economic discussion and analysis, a large portion of this discussion has been marred by

polemical arguments. Empirical evidence has not been so divisive and has mostly been

ambiguous, panel specific and inconclusive.

While the concern about distribution was principal in the analysis of classical economists,

early modern economic theory was preoccupied with growth and the factors contributing to it.

The distributional aspects of economic prosperity came into prominence in modern economic

thought with Kuznets (1955) and Kaldor (1955). It is with Kuznets’ seminal work that we see the

distributional question being looked into with more rigour. Kuznets analysed the distribution of

income among different social groups and hypothesised that in an economy, in the early stages of

development, the income inequality first increases and then decreases as the economy grows

further. This relationship was stylised as the ‘inverted U-shape’. The influence of Kuznets and of

the growth–inequality literature grew in the 1980s and 1990s with most theoretical works

emphasizing growth as ‘a rising tide that lifts all boats’.

Our interest in inequality is not just moral. At an intrinsic level, it is possible that

inequality of income and wealth have possibilities of reducing economic growth. This involves

looking at inequality at a functional level. At the level of simple correlation, more inequality

seems to be associated with less sustained growth (Berg & Ostry, 2011b). Higher inequality might

cause social and political instability, discouraging investments and leading to lower growth. Most

empirical studies estimating the growth–inequality relationship looked into this functional aspect

and these results, at best, have been mixed. Studies have estimated positive, negative and

insignificant relations between the two.

The addition of the re-distribution variable to the above relationship complicates the issue

further. This has been a fairly recent addition in the empirical literature. Empirical arguments

have swung both ways with regards to re-distribution as well. While some re-distribution policies

are growth enhancing, most seem to impact growth negatively. This strand of thought has its roots

in Okun’s (1975) leaky bucket concept which indicated that re-distribution undermined growth

because of the transactions costs involved in the process of re-distribution.

Our preliminary understanding of the literature brought up three issues that need further

examination in the growth–inequality–re-distribution relationship. First, there is a difficulty in

establishing causality between any two sets of variables. Second, the interlinkages between the

variables seem to be bi-directional, calling for joint empirical estimation of the variables. Lastly,

while studies have recognised normatively the type of re-distribution that works best, positive

recognition seems lacking. This paper looks to address the above highlighted issues in the context

of Emerging Market Economies (EMEs) over the 1980–2010 period.

The rest of the paper is organised as follows: Section two examines and summarises the

existing theoretical and empirical literature. Section three looks at the Emerging Market

Page 3: Interlinkages between Growth, Distribution and Re-Distribution in … · 2014-10-23 · Interlinkages between Growth, Distribution and Re-Distribution in Emerging Market Economies

2

economies (EMEs) in particular by mapping growth trends amongst the EMEs onto the inequality

patterns using the Gini coefficient. It also derives some stylised facts about re-distribution trends

in the EMEs. Section four discusses data and methodology while section five elaborates on the

results and empirical estimation. We take the empirical results forward in section six by looking

at policy evidence and outlining effective policy options. Section seven concludes.

2. LITERATURE REVIEW

2.1 Growth and Inequality

There has been some consensus among the theoretical works that look to examine the

growth–inequality relationship. The first formalised relationship between inequality and growth

dates back to 1955, when Kuznets popularised the inverted U-shaped model, by drawing on three

developed nations: the United States, England and Germany. He writes that his observations,

‘justify a tentative impression of constancy in the relative distribution of income before taxes,

followed by some narrowing of relative income inequality after the First World War, or earlier’

(Kuznets, 1955). Kuznets himself acknowledges that the relationship is ‘tentative’, thus

prompting a number of subsequent studies which test for the relationship empirically using

different structural models. While the general stance in theoretical literature has been that

inequality hurts growth, the empirical evidence since Kuznets (1955) has mostly been mixed and

not conclusive of a trade-off between growth and inequality.

To understand historically the nature of inequality over the stages of economic growth, it is

important to look at the development trajectory of an economy. As the economy moves from

agriculture to industry to services, the incomes of the households involved increase steadily.

Those who move linearly across the sectors experience an increase in their income which gives

rise to an increase in the economy’s overall level of inequality. The relationship is thus positive

at the earlier stages of development. As the economy continues to transition, the relationship

becomes negative, as iconized in the Kuznets curve. Early studies such as those by Perotti

(Alesina & Perotti, 1996) and Barro (2000) empirically validate this proposition with their cross-

country studies. However, the non-linear structure of the model was lost as papers in the 1990s

estimated a one-way monotonic effect of inequality on growth.

Alesina and Rodrick (1994) document a negative impact of income and wealth inequality

on subsequent growth. Persson and Tabellini (1994) use a measure of equality instead and arrive

at the same result for nine developed nations. Perotti’s (1996) work also substantiates this

negative effect argument. Ostry et al (2014) examine the inequality–growth relation in a historical

context by looking at cross-country data. Their empirical findings point to a linear negative

relationship between inequality and growth. Banerjee and Duflo (2003), however, contest the

imposed linear structure and reinstate the non-linear form of Kuznets. Changes in inequality (in

any direction) are associated with lower future growth rates (Duflo & Banerjee, 2003). But,

Deninger and Squire (1998) use longitudinal data to disprove Kuznets curve. ‘The work on this

issue is flawed not only because it relies on questionable data but, more importantly, because this

intrinsically inter-temporal relationship has usually been tested using cross-country data’

(Deininger & Squire, 1998). Hence, the Kuznets hypothesis remains a fairly contested one.

Page 4: Interlinkages between Growth, Distribution and Re-Distribution in … · 2014-10-23 · Interlinkages between Growth, Distribution and Re-Distribution in Emerging Market Economies

3

The diverse results emerge from the fact that inequality affects growth via different

channels, both economic and political. We identify five main channels in the literature: savings

rate channel, the credit market channel, human capital channel, macroeconomic balances and

social and political channel.

The savings rate channel, as illustrated by economists since Keynes, hinges on the premise

that higher incomes lead to higher marginal propensities to save thereby leading to higher savings

and investments in an economy. Understood this way, this channel would argue that greater

inequality leads to higher growth levels, i.e. there is a positive effect of inequality on growth. The

high marginal propensity to save of these high-income individuals translates into greater

investments. Additionally, concentration of income becomes important to facilitate bulky

investments. This line of argument, to suggest that more unequal countries grow faster, was

advanced by Kaldor (1955). Banerjee and Duflo (2003) suggest that the relationship between

investments and income is not straightforward. Rather, the cost of inequality will depend on the

mean income of the economy, that is, if everyone has that minimum income level to afford

reasonable investments, inequality will have no consequence on growth.

Under the credit market channel, imperfections in the credit market restrict access to credit

and thereby reduce people’s ability to borrow. ‘It typically reflects asymmetric information and,

in developing countries, it might point to the limitations of existing legal institutions’ (Barro,

2000). Any investment opportunity depends solely on the individual household’s existing and

possible future income. But limited availability of credit to poorer households implies less capital

availability to undertake both entrepreneurial and human capital investments. Perotti (1992) uses

loan-to-value ratio as a proxy for credit availability and proves that greater credit availability has

a significant positive impact on growth rate. Hence, in this particular channel, inequality has a

negative effect on growth.

The human capital investment channel operates alongside physical capital investment.

‘Higher dispersion can incite people to put forth additional effort or to invest in their human

capital, as the rewards of this additional effort are higher compared to the situation in an

egalitarian society’ (Thewissen, 2013). While inequality prompts growth in this channel, the

human capital aspect could also play out as a negative effect. Wilkinson and Pickett (2009) point

out that unequal countries lack good social indicators. This is because, as discussed, a large

section of the population is credit constrained to make investments in education and human

capital formation, which provide high rates of return. A deeper look into these factors suggests an

augmented Solow model, where growth is a function of physical and human capital investments,

wherein the role of human capital investment is quite ambiguous.

The financial crisis of 2008 had an inequality argument as well. High inequality means

high shareholder power and increasing share capital of income. This can lead to structural

imbalances in the economy, prompting a financial crisis and thus, interrupting growth. While the

economic reasons have been elaborated, and shown to be positive and negative, political factors

are at play as well.

Inequality, measured as a ratio of mean to median income, directs votes in favour of re-

distribution through the political process. This has its roots in the famous Median Voter Theorem:

higher the ratio of mean to median income, the more likely a median preference for re-distributive

Page 5: Interlinkages between Growth, Distribution and Re-Distribution in … · 2014-10-23 · Interlinkages between Growth, Distribution and Re-Distribution in Emerging Market Economies

4

policies. As most policies are either transfers or taxes, they tend to distort the economic decision

making. Taken this way, one would assume the relationship between inequality and growth to be

negative, transmitted through the political economy channel. However, developments in recent

literature have taken up government spending on productive processes, like education, health and

insurance, as non-distortionary re-distributive processes that are non-detrimental to growth. The

effects of such re-distributive policies on growth have been examined further in the later sections

of this paper.

An extension of the political economy channel addresses the concerns of social unrest that

may arise in highly unequal societies. Such political instabilities have been witnessed across

continents in the recent past. It is widely acknowledged that political stability is essential for

prolonged economic growth. High levels of inequality lead to instability, which may prove to be a

major hindrance to investment and capital flows, leading to falling output levels. This result holds

regardless of the political nature of a society, across democratic and non-democratic states.

Leaders favour stability as it breeds higher growth. This higher growth in turn has potential to

bring down existing inequality through the trickle-down phenomenon, as illustrated in the

literature (Alesina & Perotti, 1996).

These five channels interact in complex ways at any given point of time and are specific to

countries. Although there exist many theories examining this vital relationship, it is imperative to

understand that the above mentioned channels are not mutually exclusive; they interact and the

net effects of inequality on growth and vice-versa tend to be ambiguous. Consequently, their

theoretical validity has been undercut by empirical irregularities in estimation. Barro (2000)

contends that while inequality has negative impact on growth in poor countries, the savings rate

channel dominates the other channels and inequality has a positive impact on growth in the richer

or more developed countries. However, this finding has since been challenged by Assa (2012)

who finds a negative relationship between inequality and growth for developing countries but

does not find any significant relationship between the two for developed countries. Ostry et al,

meanwhile, find a negative relationship between growth and inequality, independent of the level

of economic development (Ostry, Berg, & Tsangarides, 2014). This paper looks to empirically

establish this relation for the newly christened group of EMEs in the hope to derive new results

for the extensively studied question.

A closer look at these factors provides us with a clear distinction between the nature of

variables engendering a positive relationship between inequality and growth, and those that cause

a reverse effect. Manuel et al (2011) observe that most of the positive variables such as savings

rate and capital investments are economic factors, which materialise in a relatively short-medium

term. On the other side, the negative effects are associated with political factors and change of

institutions. Such changes take a relatively longer time to come into effect. Thus, the time

dimension needs to be factored in while assessing the relationship. However, a few studies

(Perotti, 1996; Alesina and Rodrik 1994) reveal that inequality impedes growth both in the

medium and long run. Thus, our paper tests for this relationship in both the short and long run.

The use of GMM in the bulk of later literature suggests the recognition of simultaneity

between the two variables. Starting with any initial distribution of wealth, both inequality and the

growth rate must, on average, go down over time, with the consequence that in the long run there

is no inequality and no growth (Banerjee & Duflo, 2003). While this explains the association or

Page 6: Interlinkages between Growth, Distribution and Re-Distribution in … · 2014-10-23 · Interlinkages between Growth, Distribution and Re-Distribution in Emerging Market Economies

5

correlation, the literature has been meticulous to identify the reverse linkage, that is, the effect of

growth on inequality. It has been long argued that the benefits of growth will automatically

trickle down to the poor in the form of increased production activities in the economy. The

solution to tackle inequality lies in increasing growth. However, such a model did not hold up to

empirical testing. Alesina and Rodrick (1994) show that there is no normative significance

attached to the process of growth. This led to the distinction between the concepts of growth and

development, what is required to tackle inequality is development and not growth per se.

Most papers have also consciously made the difference between income inequality and

wealth inequality. However, when it comes to empirical testing, income inequality is often used

as a proxy for wealth inequality. But Deininger and Squire (1998) show that this receives little

empirical support since the correlation between the Gini coefficients for initial distribution of land

and income is relatively low at 0.39. Furthermore, the initial income Gini loses significance in the

presence of region dummies. It suggests that region-specific characteristics which may, but need

not, include income inequality, could be at the root of the relationship observed in much of the

literature (Deininger & Squire, 1998). This is not the case with the initial land Gini, which is used

a proxy for wealth inequality. Land Gini is significantly associated with lower growth rate even

when region dummies are added, particularly in developing nations.

While growth has been the standard variable linked to inequality, the persistence of this

growth process is equally important. Berg and Ostry (2011a) capture this aspect of growth and

observe that countries that enjoy longer growth spells are more equal. Ostry et al (2014)

corroborate their earlier findings; they associate lower inequality with faster and longer periods of

growth. This relationship also finds itself working the reverse way, where increased inequality

will shorten the growth rate. Over longer horizons, reduced inequality and sustained growth may

thus be two sides of the same coin (Berg & Ostry, 2011a). Inequality also seems to be associated

with shorter growth spells. Berg and Ostry estimated that a 10 percentile decrease in inequality

increased the expected length of the growth spell by 50 percent (Berg & Ostry, 2011b).

Another term that is to be noted in Kuznets’ remark is ‘inequality before taxes’. The

distinction between gross inequality (also known as market inequality) and net inequality

(inequality after re-distribution efforts) has been neglected until very recently. Market inequality

is understood in terms of pre-tax, pre-transfer disposable income while net inequality is taken as

post-tax, post-transfer disposable income.

Thus, differences in the conclusions are a result of myriad possibilities of structuring the

relationship, in terms of the variables used. The specification of the nature of the relationship,

namely simultaneity and non-linear effects, affects the results. The results are found to be highly

cohort and country dependent.

2.2 Inequality and Re-distribution

As discussed in the previous section, one of the channels through which inequality affects

growth is through the political channel of the median voter theorem. When mean income exceeds

the median income, the majority will favour re-distribution of market allotted outcomes. That is,

by theoretical conventions, there ought to be a strong positive association between inequality and

re-distribution, particularly in a democratic setting. The type of state, thus, determines the extent

of re-distribution policy and hence the net inequality in the economy. Different welfare systems

Page 7: Interlinkages between Growth, Distribution and Re-Distribution in … · 2014-10-23 · Interlinkages between Growth, Distribution and Re-Distribution in Emerging Market Economies

6

and different social policies lead to various outcomes in changes of income inequality (Caminada,

Goudswaard, & Wang , 2012). However, the most common fiscal instruments across all nations

are taxes and subsidies. The tax–subsidy mix is modelled on progressivity1 grounds and hence

automatically counters any rise in market inequality. Empirically, Immervoll and Richardson

(2011) find evidence that tax-benefit system have become less re-distributive among the working

population in OECD countries since the mid-1990s. However, Caminada et al (2012) do not

conform to these findings.

The income dimension of the policy instruments needs attention. Government expenditure

on education and labour force benefit particularly the lower income tail, whereas capital income

tax and other wealth tax are aimed at the top tail. In empirical studies, such policy instruments are

captured through variables such as government transfers, social policy expenditures and more

recently, the difference between market and net inequality. While the most direct way of testing

the theory would be to relate income (wealth) inequality to measures of re-distributive policies,

such a line of attack is problematic due to different countries pursuing different re-distributive

policies in different periods of time (Alesina & Rodrick , 1994).

Thus, as with growth and inequality, empirical results on the effect of re-distributive

taxation on the long-run distribution of income have been mixed. Empirical studies challenging

the conventional theory have emerged. Benabou (2000) does not agree with the median voter

theorem and takes countries like the United States and the Scandinavian countries as evidence.

The United States is the most unequal but less re-distributive, whereas Scandinavian countries are

most equal and most re-distributive. He finds a similar contrast among the developing nations as

well, wherein public education and health are more egalitarian in Asia than in Latin American

countries. Thus, he contests that economies eventually reach two steady state equilibriums,

namely high inequality–low re-distribution and low inequality–high re-distribution. This negative

correlation again has its roots in political argument. Efficient re-distributions meet with a wide

consensus in a fairly homogenous society but face strong opposition in an unequal one (Benabou,

2000). Similarly, Kenworthy and McCall (2008) study eight countries over the 1980s and 1990s

and conclude that countries with high market inequality are less re-distributive.

However, Ferreira (1999) normatively recognises the necessity of certain kinds of

government-funded social insurances as re-distributive measures. In an economy where the

distribution of households tilts towards poorer ones, the aggregate production potential would be

highly under-utilised. This would call for re-distribution of income-generating opportunities.

Benabou (2000) concurs with this argument by stating that state expenditures play an important

role in re-distribution. He maintains that government intervention in such cases will be positive

and not distortionary.

The literature also hints at reverse causality. Becker and Tomes (1979) with their

exclusive focus on returns to education in a multi-period model conclude that re-distributive

policies, particularly taxes, reduce investment on children and therefore increase inequality in

subsequent periods. Hence, re-distribution in the ‘n’th

period will affect the inequality dynamics in

the (n+1)th

and subsequent periods. Unemployment allowances, while reducing income inequality

1 Progressivity is measured using the Kakwani Index (1977). Progressivity is the measure of distribution of tax and

benefit. A tax or benefit which distributes more to the poor is more progressive. However, if it is distributed in proportion to pre-tax/benefit income, such a system has zero progressivity.

Page 8: Interlinkages between Growth, Distribution and Re-Distribution in … · 2014-10-23 · Interlinkages between Growth, Distribution and Re-Distribution in Emerging Market Economies

7

in the current period, will influence behaviours in the labour market, which will have a long-term

effect. One possibility is dis-incentivising people from actively looking for jobs. Thus, similar to

the growth–inequality relationship, the sign and direction of causation between these two

variables are quite ambiguous in empirical literature. This is because, over longer time periods,

trends in inequality and re-distribution result from a complex pattern of income and policy

changes affecting all income groups (Immervoll, 2011).

2.3 Re-distribution and Growth

The notion of growth can be equated to efficiency and that of re-distribution to equity.

Okun (1975) articulated the relationship between the two as essentially one of a trade-off. The

money must be carried from the rich to the poor in a leaky bucket. ‘Some of it will simply

disappear in the transit; the poor will not receive all the money that is taken from the rich’ (Okun,

1975). This ‘leaky bucket’ captures the transaction cost involved in re-distribution which reduces

the overall size of the pie while restructuring it. Okun’s ‘leaky bucket’ concept looked at a

negative relation between re-distribution and growth. Okun and subsequent literature postulated

that re-distributive efforts like transfers decreased the incentives to work and invest thereby

altering the decision-making process and reducing growth and increasing deadweight losses. For

Rodrik (1997), higher levels of inequality divert resources away from productive purposes to

bargaining over ‘distribution of rents’ or ‘burdens of negative shock’. This decreases efficiency in

an economy. Rodrik refers to it as negative re-distributive effects of inequality, i.e. distribution of

resources from productive to unproductive sectors.

Apart from this indirect consequence, re-distribution also has a direct negative effect on

growth by distorting investment initiatives and altering agent behaviours. Alesina and Rodrick

(1994) bring out the policy choices the government faces. To benefit the capitalists, the

government should maximise its growth rate. However, to cater to the worker section of the

society, the government must choose a growth rate that falls short of the maximum attainable

since taxes are set above the optimal rate in this case. Similarly, the case of unemployment

benefits inhibiting tendencies to actively look for a job was discussed in the previous section.

The literature identifies two categories of re-distribution measures – some that are pro-

equality and pro-growth (like fiscal spending on health, education and social insurance) and some

that may lead to a fall in efficiency in the economy (like taxes and transfers). Arguments that

point to the negative relation between growth and inequality usually offer, as explanations, the

possible distortionary effects of re-distributive policies to explain causation. Most studies look at

the effect of the re-distribution policy, whether distortionary or productive, to ultimately establish

a normative judgement. If the effect is distortionary, then the net effect on growth is negative but

if the effect is productive, that is if re-distributive policies allow accumulation of human capital

and productive resources, then the net effect on growth is positive.

Romer and Romer (2010) verify the negative effect of re-distribution on growth through

tax policy changes. A tax increase of one percent of GDP lowers GDP by about three percent. An

important part of that effect appears to be due to the pro-cyclical behaviour of investment (Romer

& Romer , 2010). But not all empirical testing supports this theoretical convention. Lindert (2004)

shows that growth in strongly re-distributive states has been relatively high. The positive

association may arise from provision of social securities and insurance, which provide a risk-free

Page 9: Interlinkages between Growth, Distribution and Re-Distribution in … · 2014-10-23 · Interlinkages between Growth, Distribution and Re-Distribution in Emerging Market Economies

8

environment to develop. Some studies have also looked at drawing distinctions between wealth

and income taxes. They estimate that while wealth tax increases growth in the long run, income

tax is damaging and reduces growth in the same time horizon (Gruener, 1995).

The divergences in empirics could be largely attributed to the different re-distribution

mechanisms taken in such studies. Literature has popularly focussed on human capital

investments, commonly primary school education. Other indicators have been urbanisation and

infant mortality rates, and credit market imperfections (Galor and Zeira, 1989). Under the credit

market imperfections channel, re-distribution of assets from the rich to the poor, if non-

distortionary, has the capacity to raise average return on investment across the economy (Barro,

2000). Deininger and Squire (1998) emphasise on initial wealth endowments for investments to

have a positive impact through their inclusion of land inequality as one of their regressors. ‘A

policy conclusion that emerges directly from this discussion is that accumulation of new assets is

likely to be a more effective way of reducing poverty than efforts to re-distribute existing assets’

(Deininger & Squire, 1998). But they caution that such attempts at asset re-distribution should not

lead to lower levels of investments. Thus, certain re-distribution efforts could be more successful

in countering inequality while sustaining growth. For example, Caminada et al (2012) identify

cash transfers to have twice the re-distributive effect vis-à-vis household taxes in their study of 20

Luxembourg Income Study (LIS) countries.

However, one cannot ignore the simultaneity in this relationship as well. Similar to re-

distribution impacting economic growth, economic growth also influences the need and demand

for re-distribution. We allude to Wagner’s hypothesis of ‘increasing state activity’ to justify this

converse relationship. In a loose sense, Wagner’s law points to a positive long run co-movement

between government expenditures and economic growth (Zaghini & Lamartina, 2008). One,

higher growth rates warrant increased government intervention to ensure political stability and

develop infrastructure. Two, growth, by enhancing the reserve pool, creates possibilities for

government transfers and provisions. The focus of this paper is on the latter aspect where growth

facilitates the process of development through re-distribution.

The scan of literature shows that considerable number of studies has focused on growth–

inequality and growth–re-distribution relationship. The relationship between inequality and re-

distribution has seldom received the same attention.

3. INEQUALITY TRENDS IN EMERGING MARKET ECONOMIES

The EMEs have been gaining prominence because of their growing role in the world

economy. They have also been involved in the shaping of post-crisis global governance and the

global economic growth is being strongly influenced by them. With their role expected to increase

further in the future, it is important to understand the socio-economic dynamic at play here.

While the sustained and strong economic growth in emerging economies has helped to counter

absolute poverty, relative poverty levels continue to remain high, and have in fact shown an

upward trend with a few exceptions like Brazil and Peru. We observe the correlation between

market and net inequality to be close to 0.8 in our overall sample. This is consistent with Solt’s

(2009) remark about developing countries having very low re-distribution levels. There has,

however, been a gap in assessing these issues in the empirical literature.

Page 10: Interlinkages between Growth, Distribution and Re-Distribution in … · 2014-10-23 · Interlinkages between Growth, Distribution and Re-Distribution in Emerging Market Economies

9

Table 1: Decadal trends in market and net inequality and relative re-distribution in the EME panel

Source: Authors’ calculations based on SWIID database

The table (Table 1) tabulates changes in mean market inequality, net inequality and

relative re-distribution between 1980 and 2010. In Asia, we see inconsistent trends among the

countries, with market inequality rising in a few countries and falling in some others. China

experiences the highest change in market inequality over the two decades. Most studies point to

rising regional inequality linked to increasing globalisation and integration of its urban areas.

‘Uneven distribution of domestic capital, FDI and trade account for almost 50 percent of the total

regional inequality’ (Wan, 2007). India also observes strong inequality trends arising from spatial

factors. Like China, India is witnessing rising inequality between its urban and rural incomes.

Datt and Ravallion (2002) cite India’s lagging agricultural sector, inflation and education as

possible reasons for higher inequality. In both these countries, re-distribution efforts have not

matched rising market inequality. Relative re-distribution has, in fact, reduced over the years,

placing the net inequality on the same level as market inequality. These trends can be seen in

figure 1. Sri Lanka, Singapore and Malaysia exhibit a constant trend in their inequality values.

However, Sri Lanka’s net inequality is higher than market inequality in the 1990s and 2000s. The

experience of Thailand and Philippines has been the same. In Russia, the market and net

inequality move together while re-distribution has been stable over the period.

1985 1995 2005 % Change 1985 1995 2005 % Change 1985 1995 2005 % change

China 32.14438 41.49858 49.81767 54.98098 27.11935 40.93068 49.31079 81.82878 15.63267 1.368481 1.017474 -93.49136

Indonesia 52.6867 72.08476 57.9182 9.929448 38.57069 46.33251 52.93949 37.25314 26.79235 35.72497 8.596104 -67.91583

India 47.81893 50.61657 49.96781 4.493787 47.52211 50.32106 49.33821 3.8216 4.147774 0.583819 1.260003 -69.62218

Malaysia 50.60266 48.86698 50.14609 -0.902256 48.79143 46.46028 47.1876 -3.287101 3.579326 4.924998 5.899745 64.8284

Philippines 54.85576 52.24481 49.02141 -10.63581 47.13076 47.97787 50.64748 7.461621 14.08238 8.167218 -3.317075 -123.5548

Russia 26.79766 44.85794 48.06327 79.35624 22.87644 38.46317 41.12357 79.76385 14.63269 14.2556 14.43868 -1.325867

Singapore 43.43512 44.04957 42.31578 -2.577038 40.5212 41.04251 40.86192 0.840841 6.708655 6.826534 3.435725 -48.78668

Thailand 55.78826 50.07322 48.80146 -12.52378 54.74971 60.67517 51.80508 -5.378345 1.8616 -21.1729 -6.154771 -430.6174

Turkey 54.81611 48.08705 46.54956 -15.08052 51.86775 46.49364 44.12898 -14.9202 5.378636 3.313599 5.199997 -3.32127

Srilanka 43.90325 41.44741 43.06209 -1.915953 41.77795 43.10284 46.70348 11.78978 4.840883 -3.994045 -8.456133 -274.6816

Pakistan 35.11723 41.49088 44.16637 25.76838 32.95884 40.88086 44.06342 33.69227 6.146243 1.470251 0.233096 -96.20751

Argentina 42.7503 44.73841 44.98963 5.23815 40.22464 43.32096 43.91739 9.180306 5.907937 3.168313 2.383307 -59.65924

Brazil 56.35445 56.09085 53.26287 -5.485955 51.71463 52.10211 49.23182 -4.800986 8.233274 7.111208 7.568215 -8.0777

Chile 51.39601 51.63856 50.08922 -2.542587 49.65599 50.27586 48.666 -1.993692 3.385514 2.638929 2.841366 -16.07282

Colombia 52.93122 50.24972 51.16141 -3.343601 49.35327 49.48624 50.49713 2.317716 6.759624 1.519366 1.298388 -80.79201

Ecuador 45.63401 50.77369 49.93905 9.433846 44.88771 48.96075 49.09079 9.363549 1.635408 3.570629 1.698594 3.863667

Mexico 46.29375 49.07821 48.17646 4.066871 44.71236 47.59202 46.02081 2.926368 3.415999 3.028191 4.474494 30.9864

Panama 50.09767 52.25449 50.44473 0.692772 46.74719 50.75689 49.12176 5.0796 6.6879 2.865978 2.622622 -60.78557

Peru 58.96486 52.00716 51.05519 -13.41421 56.10587 52.15572 50.43813 -10.10186 4.848646 -0.285651 1.208628 -75.07288

Venezuela 43.68849 42.66989 41.64335 -4.681172 42.14678 41.23357 39.87384 -5.392928 3.528859 3.366105 4.249219 20.4134

Bulgaria 24.49099 29.28996 32.43057 32.41837 20.34982 26.77681 28.90618 42.04636 16.90893 8.580255 10.86747 -35.72938

Czech Rep 28.52422 36.07225 38.87033 36.27133 19.99282 23.25906 25.99878 30.04063 29.90934 35.52092 33.11407 10.71484

Poland 29.50551 40.14778 42.48744 43.99836 25.99518 28.31808 29.64626 14.04524 11.8972 29.4654 30.22347 154.0386

Hungary 32.25562 45.1156 41.54138 28.78803 22.17787 30.15887 27.25365 22.88672 31.2434 33.15203 34.39396 10.08391

Egypt 35.38181 34.63161 34.31466 -3.016094 34.87304 36.70036 33.18794 -4.832109 1.437928 -5.973598 3.283495 128.349

Jordon 50.92313 46.01992 47.99558 -5.748964 49.58502 43.44884 47.43387 -4.338302 2.627719 5.586887 1.170341 -55.46172

Morocco 45.556 39.67899 41.43057 -9.055734 42.51394 37.01989 38.70284 -8.964342 6.677632 6.701532 6.583849 -1.40443

Nigeria 46.17098 51.16749 46.33655 0.358597 44.79916 50.12056 42.50862 -5.1129 2.971178 2.046092 8.261138 178.0425

South Africa 53.70662 55.24856 61.54904 14.60235 53.71029 53.91211 58.18109 8.323922 -0.006841 2.418993 5.471978 -

Europe

Africa & Middle East

Net InequalityMarket Inequality Relative Redistribution

Asia

Latin America

Page 11: Interlinkages between Growth, Distribution and Re-Distribution in … · 2014-10-23 · Interlinkages between Growth, Distribution and Re-Distribution in Emerging Market Economies

10

Latin America also displays heterogeneity in its inequality and re-distribution trends

across its countries. Brazil and Peru have reduced their relative inequality levels, even as absolute

inequality levels continue to remain high. Ferreira et al (2006) identify four structural and policy

changes which have been the reason for reducing inequality in Brazil. These are declining returns

to education, urban–rural income convergence, social assistance transfers and declining racial

inequality. Among all these countries, the difference between net and market inequality has been

insignificant. The re-distribution has also been at a relatively low level in relation to other country

groups.

Africa has been recognised as the world’s most inequitable region. In 2010, six of the 10

countries with the most unequal income distribution in the world were in sub-Saharan

Africa, specifically in Southern Africa (African Development Bank, 2012). Africa, however, is

not highly represented in our sample. South Africa2 has been historically characterised by high

levels of income inequality. Its inequality values are the highest recorded in our sample but it has

shown increasing absolute levels, albeit, at low levels since 2007. Re-distributive efforts have

also been increasing in Nigeria since the 2000s. Meanwhile, relative re-distributive trends in

Morocco have been at constant levels and this is reflected by the near overlap of market and net

inequality trends in figure 4.

Emerging Europe provides an interesting contrast to the trends observed in the other three

region cohorts. The absolute values of inequality, both market and net, are among the lowest

while the re-distribution values are much higher. However, these countries have also been facing

increasing inequality levels.

2 The change in relative redistribution for Africa has not been calculated since its initial redistributive value is

negative.

Page 12: Interlinkages between Growth, Distribution and Re-Distribution in … · 2014-10-23 · Interlinkages between Growth, Distribution and Re-Distribution in Emerging Market Economies

11

TRENDS IN MARKET INEQUALITY AND NET INEQUALITY

ASIA

(Figure 1)

15253545556575

19

80

19

83

19

86

19

89

19

92

19

95

19

98

20

01

20

04

20

07

20

10

CHINA

15

25

35

45

55

65

75

19

80

19

83

19

86

19

89

19

92

19

95

19

98

20

01

20

04

20

07

20

10

INDIA

15

25

35

45

55

65

75

19

80

19

83

19

86

19

89

19

92

19

95

19

98

20

01

20

04

20

07

20

10

SRILANKA

15253545556575

19

80

19

83

19

86

19

89

19

92

19

95

19

98

20

01

20

04

20

07

20

10

INDONESIA

15

25

35

4555

6575

19

80

19

83

19

86

19

89

19

92

19

95

19

98

20

01

20

04

20

07

20

10

MALAYSIA

15

25

35

45

55

65

75

19

80

19

83

19

86

19

89

19

92

19

95

19

98

20

01

20

04

20

07

20

10

SINGAPORE

15253545556575

19

80

19

83

19

86

19

89

19

92

19

95

19

98

20

01

20

04

20

07

20

10

PAKISTAN

15253545556575

19

80

19

83

19

86

19

89

19

92

19

95

19

98

20

01

20

04

20

07

20

10

THAILAND

15

25

35

45

55

65

75

19

80

19

83

19

86

19

89

19

92

19

95

19

98

20

01

20

04

20

07

20

10

TURKEY

15

25

35

45

55

65

75

19

80

19

83

19

86

19

89

19

92

19

95

19

98

20

01

20

04

20

07

20

10

PHILIPPINES

15

25

35

45

55

65

75

19

80

19

83

19

86

19

89

19

92

19

95

19

98

20

01

20

04

20

07

20

10

RUSSIA

Page 13: Interlinkages between Growth, Distribution and Re-Distribution in … · 2014-10-23 · Interlinkages between Growth, Distribution and Re-Distribution in Emerging Market Economies

12

15

25

35

45

55

65

75

19

80

19

83

19

86

19

89

19

92

19

95

19

98

20

01

20

04

20

07

20

10

BRAZIL

15

25

35

45

55

65

75

19

80

19

83

19

86

19

89

19

92

19

95

19

98

20

01

20

04

20

07

20

10

CHILE

15253545556575

19

80

19

83

19

86

19

89

19

92

19

95

19

98

20

01

20

04

20

07

20

10

COLOMBIA

15

25

35

45

55

65

75

19

80

19

83

19

86

19

89

19

92

19

95

19

98

20

01

20

04

20

07

20

10

ECUADOR

15

25

35

45

55

65

75

19

80

19

83

19

86

19

89

19

92

19

95

19

98

20

01

20

04

20

07

20

10

VENEZUELA

15

25

35

45

55

65

75

19

80

19

83

19

86

19

89

19

92

19

95

19

98

20

01

20

04

20

07

20

10

PANAMA

15

25

35

45

55

65

75

19

80

19

83

19

86

19

89

19

92

19

95

19

98

20

01

20

04

20

07

20

10

PERU

15

25

35

45

55

65

75

19

80

19

83

19

86

19

89

19

92

19

95

19

98

20

01

20

04

20

07

20

10

ARGENTINA

LATIN AMERICA

(Figure 2)

15

25

35

45

55

65

751

98

0

19

83

19

86

19

89

19

92

19

95

19

98

20

01

20

04

20

07

20

10

MEXICO

Page 14: Interlinkages between Growth, Distribution and Re-Distribution in … · 2014-10-23 · Interlinkages between Growth, Distribution and Re-Distribution in Emerging Market Economies

13

15253545556575

19

80

19

83

19

86

19

89

19

92

19

95

19

98

20

01

20

04

20

07

20

10

POLAND

15

25

35

45

55

65

75

19

80

19

83

19

86

19

89

19

92

19

95

19

98

20

01

20

04

20

07

20

10

CZECH REPUBLIC

15

25

35

45

55

65

75

19

80

19

83

19

86

19

89

19

92

19

95

19

98

20

01

20

04

20

07

20

10

EGYPT

15

25

35

45

55

65

75

19

80

19

83

19

86

19

89

19

92

19

95

19

98

20

01

20

04

20

07

20

10

HUNGARY

15

25

35

45

55

65

75

19

80

19

83

19

86

19

89

19

92

19

95

19

98

20

01

20

04

20

07

20

10

JORDAN

15

25

35

45

55

65

75

19

80

19

83

19

86

19

89

19

92

19

95

19

98

20

01

20

04

20

07

20

10

MOROCCO

15

25

35

45

55

65

75

19

80

19

83

19

86

19

89

19

92

19

95

19

98

20

01

20

04

20

07

20

10

BULGARIA

EUROPE

(Figure 3)

15253545556575

19

80

19

83

19

86

19

89

19

92

19

95

19

98

20

01

20

04

20

07

20

10

NIGERIA

15253545556575

19

80

19

83

19

86

19

89

19

92

19

95

19

98

20

01

20

04

20

07

20

10

SOUTH AFRICA

AFRICA & MIDDLE EAST

(Figure 4)

Page 15: Interlinkages between Growth, Distribution and Re-Distribution in … · 2014-10-23 · Interlinkages between Growth, Distribution and Re-Distribution in Emerging Market Economies

14

4. DATA AND METHODOLOGY

The empirical verification of this model has been largely fixated on OECD nations. This has

been motivated by the fact that these countries have well documented datasets. But the need for a

similar analysis in the context of developing nations was emphasised in the previous section.

This paper, being one such attempt, looks at a panel of 29 EMEs as listed by the IMF.

An important improvement in this field has been the launching of the SWIID database. The

database provides Gini indices of gross income inequality and net income inequality on a

comparable and wider scale3. The gross income inequality is the distribution of income from

market outcome, while the net income inequality is the inequality post-government intervention in

the form of taxes and subsidies4. A progressive tax-subsidy mix ought to reduce the value of the

net inequality Gini vis-à-vis the market inequality Gini. The Gini index ranges from 0 to 100,

where 100 refers to a point where a single unit is the recipient of all incomes. We use income

Ginis from the SWIID database since the separation of gross and net inequality, based on taxes

and subsidies, allows us to capture the re-distribution value in these economies, in addition to

inequality values. Re-distribution is calculated as the difference between market inequality and

net inequality. This gives us the absolute measure of re-distribution. In our analysis, we use the

relative measure of re-distribution which calculates the value in relation to corresponding market

inequality.

Another important variable required to estimate the simultaneity is the growth of an economy.

The relationship between growth and inequality is analysed via the economic channels of savings

rate and human capital investment. The savings rate channel is proxied by investments, and

education is used for human capital investment. The education variable is captured by primary

and tertiary enrollment ratios separately. Secondary education could not be added due to lack of

sufficient data points. Population has been an important factor in growth models since Solow, and

hence our model factors in this variable. Other macroeconomic variables include inflation and

trade openness. The sources for all these variables are World Development Index and Penn table

7.1 and table 8.0

To look at how the dynamics of the relationship change over time, we consider a long and a

short panel. Long panel includes data points from 1980 to 2010. Short panel is taken from 1999 to

2008. This is to avoid the years of Asian Financial Crisis in 1997–1998 and the Global Financial

Crisis post-2008. We choose annual data in case of both the datasets. The number of countries

reduces to 20 when we include the control variables due to scarcity of data with respect to these

variables. Our baseline models, nevertheless, use 29 countries.

Our analysis extends further to look at the effective re-distributive policies to counter

inequality. Here, the impact of tax-subsidy mix, government expenditure on health and education

and inflation are assessed on net inequality. The tax-subsidy mix is denoted by the re-distribution

variable. Hence, we don’t add income tax or any subsidy variable in the model. The fact that re-

distribution does not capture in-kind provisioning justifies the discrete inclusion of government

3 We use the SWIID 4.0.

4 It is to be noted that the net inequality in the SWIID database does not include indirect taxes or in-kind government

provision.

Page 16: Interlinkages between Growth, Distribution and Re-Distribution in … · 2014-10-23 · Interlinkages between Growth, Distribution and Re-Distribution in Emerging Market Economies

15

expenditure on health and education5. Inflation is added since it acts as a regressive tax and thus

erodes the purchasing power. Our re-distributive model has been limited by lack of data.

Insufficient data points for government agricultural expenditure and other taxes such as capital

gain or indirect taxes do not allow us to look at these re-distributive aspects. These countries also

lack data on the sources of household income ruling out an assessment of cash transfers and

allowances.

The simultaneity among growth, inequality and re-distribution, and the interdependence

across years requires a dynamic panel modelling. Hence, we use the system GMM method to

estimate the equations, where the instruments for the endogenous variables are derived from

within the model itself. The variables are instrumented using their first differences and lags.

While papers in this area have looked at both the difference and system GMM, we rely on

system GMM. The specification of the model becomes extremely important because different

estimation techniques yield different results. Manuel et al (2011) find a positive relationship

between growth and inequality using first difference; the same relationship turns negative in

middle and low income countries when system GMM is applied. Our reasons for using system

GMM over difference GMM are as follows. First, system GMM, by introducing more instruments

in its system of equations, has higher efficiency compared to the difference GMM model

(Roodman, 2009). Second, first difference GMM exploits only within-country variation and does

not account for cross-country variations. System GMM, on the other hand, exploits both time-

series and cross-country variation in data.

5. ESTIMATION AND RESULTS6

The objective of our empirical research is threefold. One, to model the relationship between

the three variables simultaneously. Two, to factor in the time dimension by looking at the

relationship in the long run and short run. Three, to identify effective re-distributive policies.

We consider three baseline models, each taking the variables of interest as the dependent

variable. We extend two of these baseline models, by including controls, to consider the

relationship among the variables simultaneously and to estimate effective re-distributive policies.

Table 2 shows that higher market inequality has led to greater re-distribution in these EMEs

both in the short and long run. While growth and re-distribution exhibit a positive relationship in

the long panel, it is negative in the short run, implying that the idea of growth dominates in the

short run and that development (brought about by re-distribution) is a long run objective. Alesina

and Rodrick (1994) allude to this by stating that re-distribution could lead to less-than-optimal

growth rate. But the short-run results could be purely indicative of the decade under

consideration. Considering these countries have experienced high growth rates in 1999–2008, the

negative relationship points to the low or reduced re-distribution efforts during this phase. In both

cases, high levels of initial income lead to high levels of re-distribution.

5 We have included input variables to assess the impact of re-distributive efforts on inequality. A better way would be

to look at the output variables since huge inefficiencies in transferring resources would mean that the actual benefit

(output) could be less than the intended benefit (input). 6 For all results presented, standard tests for the validity of the instruments and AR (1) and AR (2) are satisfied.

Hansen J test and Sargan test provide favourable results.

Page 17: Interlinkages between Growth, Distribution and Re-Distribution in … · 2014-10-23 · Interlinkages between Growth, Distribution and Re-Distribution in Emerging Market Economies

16

Table 2: Baseline regression 1: Re-distribution on market inequality and GDP growth rate

The following table (Table 3) looks at the relationship between growth rate and inequality

and re-distribution. We find that market inequality is insignificant in the long run but has a high

negative impact on growth in the short run. On the other hand, re-distribution exhibits an exact

opposite behaviour. It is positive and significant in the short run and insignificant in the long run.

A combined analysis of these two variables helps us explain this behaviour. A deeper look into

the inequality–re-distribution data (Table 1) across the sample reveals that re-distribution efforts

were relatively high in the 1980s and early 1990s. This led to lower market inequality in

subsequent years in these two decades. This effect dominates the long panel results where re-

distribution is seen to be significant and market inequality is insignificant. However, there is a

marked decline in the relative re-distribution in the 2000s, leading to higher market inequality

levels. This is reflected in the short sample.

Dependent Variable :Re-distribution

Variables Long Panel

(1980–2010)

Short Panel

(1999–2008)

Market inequality 0.036***

(0.0083)

0.537**

(0.0220)

GDP growth rate 0.106***

(0.0153)

–0.062**

(0.0275)

Log(Initial per capita GDP) 1.774***

(0.0679)

4.978***

(0.1013)

Constant –10.204***

(0.6362)

–35.412***

(1.3720)

Number of Observations

787 289

Note: System GMM estimation where robust standard errors are in the bracket. *, **

and *** indicate statistical significance at the 10, 5 and 1 percent levels respectively.

Page 18: Interlinkages between Growth, Distribution and Re-Distribution in … · 2014-10-23 · Interlinkages between Growth, Distribution and Re-Distribution in Emerging Market Economies

17

Table 3: Baseline regression 2: GDP growth rate on Market Inequality and Re-distribution

Dependent Variable : Per Capita GDP Growth Rate

Variables Long Panel

(1980–2010)

Short Panel

(1999–2008)

Market inequality –0.019

(0.0160)

–0.101***

(0.0320)

Re-distribution 0.260*

(0.0138)

0.032

(0.0203)

Log(Initial per capita GDP) –1.014***

(0.1287)

–0.715***

(0.2145)

Constant 10.838***

(1.183)

13.879***

(2.1238)

Number of Observations 787 289

Table 4: Baseline regression 3: Market inequality on GDP growth rate and re-distribution

Dependent Variable : Market Income Inequality

Variables Long Panel

(1980–2010)

Short Panel

(1999–2008)

Per capita GDP growth rate –0.716***

(0.0107)

–0.155***

(0.0241)

Re-distribution 0.027***

(0.0005)

–0.033**

(0.0149)

Log(Initial per capita GDP) 0.552***

(0.0480)

–0.151

(0.1159)

Constant 43.128***

(0.0368)

49.157***

(0.8740)

Number of Observations 787 289

Note: System GMM estimation where robust standard errors are in the bracket. *, ** and ***

indicate statistical significance at the 10, 5 and 1 percent levels respectively.

Note: System GMM estimation where robust standard errors are in the bracket. *, ** and

*** indicate statistical significance at the 10, 5 and 1 percent levels respectively.

Page 19: Interlinkages between Growth, Distribution and Re-Distribution in … · 2014-10-23 · Interlinkages between Growth, Distribution and Re-Distribution in Emerging Market Economies

18

Our last baseline (Table 4) estimates the effect of growth and re-distribution on market

inequality. The impact of growth on inequality is consistent across time horizons. Higher growth

rate implies lower inequality. Meanwhile, the effect of re-distribution is ambiguous. While re-

distribution lowers income inequality in the short run, the effect is inconclusive in the long run.

The long-run relationship could merely be a reflection of the sample characteristic. Re-

distribution values have been observed to be negative in certain Latin American and Asian

economies in late 1990s; implying regressive re-distribution. In this case, re-distribution leads to

higher market inequality in subsequent periods.

5.1 Growth–Distribution–Re-distribution

This section empirically verifies the simultaneity among all three variables. The variables

are standard in accordance with the existing literature and the model specification follows Ostry et

al (2014). However, we have used market inequality instead of net inequality.

We observe that market inequality has a significant negative impact on growth in the long

run (Table 5.1) but it is insignificant in the short run (Table 5.2). Our model finds no trade-off

between re-distribution and growth. One unit increase in re-distribution, in fact, increases growth

by 0.04 percent. This implication is time invariant. This is in contrast to Ostry et al (2014) who

find the re-distribution variable to be insignificant. We reason that the use of net inequality in

their model could have subsumed the effect of re-distribution, thereby rendering it insignificant.

Furthermore, we find evidence to support the savings rate and human capital channels

outlined in the literature. Investment and returns to education, both primary and tertiary, are

significant and positive in the long run. The relationship extends to the short run as well with the

exception of returns to primary education. Investment in physical capital seems to have a

dominant effect on growth vis-à-vis human capital. Inflation as a regressive tax has a significantly

detrimental effect on growth.

We also tested for the non-linear relationship as hypothesised by Kuznets by adding a

higher-order market inequality term. However, the second-order market inequality variable

proved to be insignificant7.

7 The non-linear relationship was tested out only for the long sample. The short sample is too small a size to account

for the structural changes underlying the Kuznets hypothesis.

Page 20: Interlinkages between Growth, Distribution and Re-Distribution in … · 2014-10-23 · Interlinkages between Growth, Distribution and Re-Distribution in Emerging Market Economies

19

Table 5.1: The effect of inequality and re-distribution on growth from 1980–2010: Extending the

second baseline

Note: System GMM estimation where robust standard errors are in the bracket. *, ** and ***

indicate statistical significance at the 10, 5 and 1 percent levels respectively.

Dependent Variable: Per Capita GDP growth

Variables (1) (2) (3)

Log(Initial per capita

GDP)

–1.310***

(0.1809)

–0.881***

(0.3059)

–0.713**

(0.3219)

Market Inequality –0.049**

(0.0230)

–0.687**

(0.0268)

–0.067**

(0.0271)

Re-distribution 0.036**

(0.0149)

0.052***

(0.0161)

0.047***

(0.0162)

Investment 0.105***

(0.0199)

0.133***

(0.0235)

0.116***

(0.0253)

Log(Population) 0.629***

(0.1878)

0.745***

(0.2270)

Primary Education 0.017

(0.01744)

0.031*

(0.0177)

Tertiary Education 0.044***

(0.0143)

0.033**

(0.0156)

Inflation –0.002***

(0.0005)

Trade Openness 0.006

(0.0059)

Constant 11.839***

(2.1107)

–5.362

(5.3331)

–9.822

(6.1726)

Number of Observations 504 430 430

Page 21: Interlinkages between Growth, Distribution and Re-Distribution in … · 2014-10-23 · Interlinkages between Growth, Distribution and Re-Distribution in Emerging Market Economies

20

Table 5.2: The effect of inequality and re-distribution on growth from 1999–2008: Extending the

second baseline8

Dependent Variable: GDP growth rate

Variables

(1) (2) (3)

Log(Initial per capita

GDP)

–1.036***

(0.3393)

–0.817*

(0.4312)

–0.773*

(0.4352)

Market Inequality –0.029

(0.0378)

0.030

(0.0462)

0.030

(0.0490)

Re-distribution 0.061***

(0.0197)

0.051**

(0.0208)

0.050**

(0.0211)

Investment 0.175***

(0.0320)

0.243***

(0.0366)

0.232***

(0.0435)

Log(Population)

0.645***

(0.1768)

0.720***

(0.2114)

Primary Education 0.006

(0.02134)

0.007

(0.0243)

Tertiary Education 0.090***

(0.01455)

0.087***

(0.0154)

Inflation –0.003

(0.0228)

Trade Openness 0.004

(0.0072)

Constant 8.7651**

(4.1113)

–12.7432*

(6.5477)

–14.50**

(6.970)

Number of Observations 199 170 168

Note: System GMM estimation where robust standard errors are in the bracket. *, ** and ***

indicate statistical significance at the 10, 5 and 1 percent levels respectively.

8 The shorter panel suffered from auto-correlation due to persistence in trends. We have used higher-order lags to

correct for AR (1).

Page 22: Interlinkages between Growth, Distribution and Re-Distribution in … · 2014-10-23 · Interlinkages between Growth, Distribution and Re-Distribution in Emerging Market Economies

21

5.2. Re-distribution mechanisms

Table 6: Effective re-distribution policies: Extending the third baseline.

Dependent Variable: Net Income Inequality

Variables Short Panel

((1999–2008)

Re-distribution

–0.565***

(0.0153)

Log(Initial per capita GDP)

2.991

(0.2227)

Per capita GDP growth

–0.240***

(0.0458)

Government Expenditure on education

(% of GDP)

0.110

(0.1332)

Government Expenditure on health

(% of GDP)

–1.322***

(0.0991)

Log(population)

2.002***

(0.1366)

Lag(Inflation)

–0.059***

(0.0136)

Democracy

8.179**

(0.3895)

Unemployment

0.376***

(0.0278)

Constant

–13.209***

(3.6038)

Number of observations

181

Note: System GMM estimation where robust standard errors are in the bracket. *, ** and ***

indicate statistical significance at the 10, 5 and 1 percent levels respectively.

Page 23: Interlinkages between Growth, Distribution and Re-Distribution in … · 2014-10-23 · Interlinkages between Growth, Distribution and Re-Distribution in Emerging Market Economies

22

Table 6 shows the differential impact of various re-distributive measures on inequality.

We have taken government expenditure on health and education, re-distribution and inflation as

re-distributive measures. Re-distribution variable, as defined by Frederick Solt (2009), captures

the tax-subsidy mix. This justifies the inclusion of government health and education expenditures

as discrete variables. Demographic and economic factors are controlled by inclusion of growth

rates, population, unemployment rates and a democracy dummy. The lack of availability of data

severely hindered our focus on other re-distributive variables like government agriculture

expenditure, direct cash transfers and wealth taxes, and restricted our analysis on different

components of household income.

Our analysis reveals that a one unit increase in a progressive tax-subsidy mix decreases

inequality by 0.5 units. Other government re-distributive policies like human capital investment

seem to be more efficient. We observe this empirically from the effect of government expenditure

on health. A one unit increase in government spending on health decreases inequality by 1.3 units,

which is almost double the impact of tax-based re-distribution.

We cannot, however, infer the same for government spending on education, which is seen to

be insignificant. This could be due to the larger gestation period associated with returns on

education which cannot be analysed within our small time frame. Returns to education could

prove to be significant in the long run. Our study presently does not account for that. We can

nonetheless extend the argument to contest that certain re-distributive policies could indeed be

both pro-growth and pro-equity.

6. POLICY EVIDENCE

This section takes our empirical results forward by deriving insights from existing

successful policies.

Measuring the impact of fiscal policies on re-distribution involves comparing the incomes

before and after the taxes and transfers. That is, the vertical distance between market income

inequality and net income inequality shows the extent of fiscal re-distributive measures. Among

the emerging market economies, the role of fiscal policy has not been very assertive with the

exception of the European countries. ‘While average tax ratios for advanced economies exceed 30

percent of GDP, tax ratios in developing economies (excluding emerging Europe) generally fall in

the range of 15–20 percent of GDP’ (IMF, 2014). Lower tax receipts translate to lower welfare

and social security spending across countries. The re-distribution trends as observed in our panel

(Figure 5) concur with the existing evidence.

The emerging European nations have consistently shown positive and high re-distributive

efforts. Simpler tax codes with fewer exemptions and tax brackets have worked in favour of these

economies. These economies also emphasise social sector contributions with greater incidence on

employers. Data suggests that there are no uniform policies that these four countries9 have

adopted, however they have each independently succeeded in reaching an optimal tax-subsidy-

transfer mix10

. Moreover, we can extend the argument to contest a neighbourhood effect. The

9 Bulgaria, Czech Republic, Hungary and Poland

10 The European Commission (2009) states that while Hungary, Bulgaria and Czech Republic have reduced their

marginal income tax rates, Poland is the only country to have increased it. It also reports the introduction of a flat 10 percent personal income tax (PIT) rate in Bulgaria and a flat 15 percent PIT in Czech Republic. However, Hungary

Page 24: Interlinkages between Growth, Distribution and Re-Distribution in … · 2014-10-23 · Interlinkages between Growth, Distribution and Re-Distribution in Emerging Market Economies

23

countries have gained from the positive externality arising from proximity to high-income

developed countries, in addition to being part of the European Union.

A closer look at the social protection and welfare spending policies of the panel also

reveals vast divergences between the different sub-groups11

. Increased spending on education and

health boosts social mobility. Our results about effective re-distributive policies (Table 6)

correspond with this theory. While we find both re-distribution (tax and subsidies) and spending

on health to be highly significant, the health coefficient is twice that of re-distribution.

Amongst the other emerging nations, we see Brazil steadily displaying substantial re-

distribution efforts. The Bolsa Família federal assistance program launched in 2006 employed

conditional cash transfers to improve education outcomes. Incremental transfers are made per

child based on the level of education attained by the child. The scheme covers approximately 2.5

percent of government expenditure in Brazil. The success of Brazil’s inequality reduction lies in

its social security system, which is the second-highest component of household income. In fact,

among the Latin American countries, the highest transfer of income to the elderly is in Brazil.

‘One key policy variable is the progressive differentiation of social security adjustments, which

means that higher income groups receive lower income gains’ (Neri, 2012).

Figure 5: Composition of tax revenue and social spending (as a percentage of GDP in 2011)

Afr

Source: IMF (2014), EUROSTAT and authors’ calculations

Progressivity of tax indices also contributes considerably towards proportionality of re-

distribution. Using Kakwani index as a measure of progressivity and including it in the re-

distribution equation to look at tax progressivity and its impact on income inequality could be an

extension of this paper.

There has been an increased burden on fiscal policy to reorient towards re-distribution. It is

important to remember that re-distribution has a critical effect on growth (Table 5.1 and 5.2). It

becomes essential then that re-distributive policies are consistent with the overall macroeconomic

policy objectives of the economy. Likewise, effective re-distributive policy needs complementary

mix of direct and indirect instruments. The success of re-distributive policies in Europe can be

attributed to this. Institutional factors also play a vital role. Reducing the ineffectiveness of re-

distribution hinges on the ability to make transfers with fewer leakages; increases in tax revenues

and Poland continue to maintain two tax brackets. Hungary follows 18 percent and 36 percent tax rates whereas Poland has 18 percent and 32 percent with the incomes brackets being significantly different. 11

Asia-Pacific, Latin America, Europe, Middle-East and Africa.

0

5

10

15

20

25

30

35

Property

Corporate

Income

Indirect

Tax Revenue

05

101520253035

Education

Health

SocialProtection

Social Spending

Page 25: Interlinkages between Growth, Distribution and Re-Distribution in … · 2014-10-23 · Interlinkages between Growth, Distribution and Re-Distribution in Emerging Market Economies

24

should be effectually translated into increased spending. Human capital expenditures have shown

to enhance efficiency and therefore, have a greater impact on income inequality in the long run.

Increasing access to education and health care services, as evidenced by our paper, works to

equitise opportunity in an efficient manner.

7. CONCLUSION

Studies on the relationship between growth and inequality have not made the distinction

between gross and net inequality. Gross inequality is the outcome of market distribution and net

inequality is post-government re-distribution efforts. Our paper recognises this difference and

classifies the growth–inequality relationship as a three-variable model: growth, distribution and

re-distribution. We focus on the simultaneous relationship among these variables and their

changing dynamics over time.

Our results show that, controlling for re-distributive transfers, inequality has a significant

detrimental effect on growth in the long run. The strand of literature that adheres to this

standpoint suggests growth in itself as a measure to reduce inequality. Growth acts as ‘a rising

tide that lifts all boats’. However, this idea of trickle down has received very little empirical

support.

This brings in the notion of re-distribution wherein market outcomes need to be reallocated

to reduce the net inequality in the economy. While growth allows for more re-distributive efforts,

the effect of re-distribution on growth is ambiguous. Okun (1975) contests that such interventions

may be distortive and will eventually harm growth. However, our data finds no trade-off between

re-distribution and growth both in the long run and short run. In fact, we show that re-distribution

reduces inequality and accelerates growth, particularly in the long run.

We go beyond the tax-subsidy nature of the re-distribution variable and look at other policy

instruments like government expenditure on health and education, and their impact on reducing

inequality. The government expenditure on health proves to be significant in reducing inequality,

but our model fails to capture the education effect. This is because we have restricted our analysis

to a period of 10 years which is too short to capture the long-run returns to education.

The lack of consensus in empirical literature raises a lot of questions. Empirical estimation

encounters several difficulties. In cross-country regressions, data comparability over time and

countries may be difficult to achieve. Panel data estimations make several assumptions. In this

case, re-distribution policies and social protection spending assume similar design across

countries. Besides, the results and interpretations are panel and data specific, hindered by the

paucity of data for the emerging economies. This paper must be viewed in light of the above

addressed limitations.

We, nonetheless, highlight the rising inequality and falling or near constant re-distribution

levels in most of the EMEs. The net inequality levels in the country closely follow the gross

inequality levels. This warrants a relook at the current re-distribution mechanisms and their

progressivity to counter inequality effectively while not compromising on growth.

Page 26: Interlinkages between Growth, Distribution and Re-Distribution in … · 2014-10-23 · Interlinkages between Growth, Distribution and Re-Distribution in Emerging Market Economies

25

REFERENCES

Alesina, A., & Perotti, R. (1996). Income distribution, political instability and investment.

European Economic Review, 1203-1228.

Alesina, A., & Rodrick , D. (1994). Redistributive Politics and Economic Growth. The Quarterly

Journal of Economics, 109(2), 465-490.

Assa, J. (2012). Inequality and Growth Re-Examined. Technology and Investment, 1-6.

African Development Bank. (2012). Income Inequality in Africa.

Barro, R. J. (2000). Inequality and growth in a panel of Countries. Journal of Economic Growth,

5-32.

Becker, Gary S., and Nigel Tomes. An Equilibrium Theory of the Distribution of Income and

Intergenerational Mobility. Journal of Political Economy. 87 (1979), 1153-1189.

Benabou, R. (2000). Uneqaul Socieites: Income distribution and the Social Contract. The

American Economic Review, 90(1), 96-129.

Berg, A. G., & Ostry, J. D. (2011a). Inequality and Unsustainable Growth: Two Sides of the

Same Coin? IMF Staff Discussion Note.

Berg, A. G., & Ostry, J. D. (2011b). Equity and Efficiency. Finance and Development.

Caminada, K., Goudswaard, K., & Wang , C. (2012). Disentangling Income Inequality and the

Redistributive Effect of Taxes and Transfers in 20 LIS Countries Over Time. LIS Working

Paper Series No 581.

Datt, G., & Ravallion, M. (2002). Is India's Economic Growth Leaving the Poor Behind? Journal

of Economic Perspectives. 16(3).89-108.

Deininger, K., & Squire, L. (1998). New ways of looking at old issues: Inequality and Growth.

Journal of Development Economics, 57, 259–287.

Duflo, E., & Banerjee, A. (2003). Inequality and Growth: What Can the Data Say. Journal of

Economic Growth, 8(3), 267–99.

European Commission. (2009). Taxation trends in the European Union.

Ferreira, F. H. (1999). Inequality and Economic Performance: A Brief Overview to Theories of

Growth and Distribution. Washington, D.C: World Bank.

Francisco H.G. Ferreira, P. G. (2006). The Rise and Fall of Brazilian Inequality: 1981-2004.

World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 3867.

Gruener, H. P. (1995). Redistributive Policy, Inequality and Growth. Journal of Economics, 1-23.

Halter, D., Oechslin, M., and J. Zweimüller. (2010). Inequality and Growth: The Neglected Time

Dimension. CEPR Discussion Paper No. 8033 (Centre for Economic Policy Research).

IMF. (2014). Fiscal Policy and Income Inequality. Washington, D.C: International Monetary

Fund.

Page 27: Interlinkages between Growth, Distribution and Re-Distribution in … · 2014-10-23 · Interlinkages between Growth, Distribution and Re-Distribution in Emerging Market Economies

26

Immervoll, H. & Richardson, L. (2011). Redistribution Policy and Inequality Reduction in OECD

Countries: What Has Changed in Two Decades? OECD Social, Employment and

Migration Working Papers 122.

Kakwani, N. C. (1977). Measurement of Progressivity: An International Comparison.

The Economic Journal. 71-80

Kaldor, N. (1955-56). Alternative Theories of Distribution. The Review of Economic Studies,

23(2), 83-100

Kenworthy, L., & McCall, L. (2008). Inequality, public opinion and redistribution. Socio-

Economic Review, 6(1), 35-68.

Kuznets, S. (1955). Economic Growth and Income Inequality. The American Economic Review,

15.

Lindert, P.H. (2004). Growing Public: Social Spending and Economic Growth Since the

Eighteenth Century. (Cambridge, U.K.: University Press).

Neri, M. (2012). Declining income inequality in Brazil. In R. Traub-Merz (Ed.), Redistribution

for Growth? Income inequality and EconomicRrecovery (pp. 57-65). Shanghai: Friedrich

Ebert Stiftung.

Okun, A. (1975). Equality and Efficiency: The Big Trade-Off. Washington DC: Brookings

Institution Press.

Ostry, J. D., Berg, A., & Tsangarides, C. G. (2014). Redistribution, Inequality, and Growth.

International Monetary Fund.

Perotti, R. (1992). Fiscal Policy, Income Distribution, and Growth. NBER Discussion Paper

Series 636.

Perotti, R., 1996. Growth, Income Distribution, and Democracy: What the Data Say. Journal of

Economic Growth. Vol. 1(2), pp. 149–87.

Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (1994). Is Inequality Harmful for Growth? The American Economic

Review. 84(3), 600-621.

Rodrik, D. (1997). Where did All the Growth Go?: External Shocks, Social Conflict and Growth

Collapses. Cambridge: Kennedy School Harvard University.

Romer, C. D., & Romer , D. H. (2010). The Macroeconomic Effects of Tax Changes:Estimates

Based on a New Measure of Fiscal Shocks. American Economic Review, 100, 763-801.

Roodman, D. (2009). How to do xtabond2: An introduction to difference and system GMM in

Stata. The Stata Journal, 86-136.

Solt, F., (2009).Standardizing the World Income Inequality Database. Social Science Quarterly,

Vol. 90(2), pp. 231–42.

Thewissen, S. (2013). Is it the income distribution or redistribution that affects growth? Socio-

Economic Review, 1-27.

Page 28: Interlinkages between Growth, Distribution and Re-Distribution in … · 2014-10-23 · Interlinkages between Growth, Distribution and Re-Distribution in Emerging Market Economies

27

Wan, G. (2007). Understanding regional poverty and inequality trends in China: Methodological

issues and empirical findings. Review of Income and wealth, 53(1), 25-34.

Zaghini, A., & Lamartina, S. (2008). Increasing Public Expenditures: Wagner's Law in OECD

Countries. Italy: European Central Bank.

Wilkinson, R., and K. Pickett. (2009).The Spirit Level: Why Greater Equality Makes Societies

Stronger (New York: Bloomsbury Press).