403
INTER-SECTORAL LABOUR MOBILITY IN KOREA: ITS ORIGINS AND RELATIONSHIP WITH UNEMPLOYMENT by Fiona Ai Lin Tan Bachelor of Economics (Hons) (UWA) This thesis is presented for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy of The University of Western Australia Business School University of Western Australia September 2008

INTER-SECTORAL LABOUR MOBILITY IN KOREA: ITS ORIGINS …€¦ · the micro policies to control or reduce mobility rates using the relevant variables (to alleviate unemployment) should

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    1

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

INTER-SECTORAL LABOUR MOBILITY IN KOREA:

ITS ORIGINS AND RELATIONSHIP WITH UNEMPLOYMENT

by

Fiona Ai Lin Tan

Bachelor of Economics (Hons) (UWA)

This thesis is presented for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy of

The University of Western Australia

Business School

University of Western Australia

September 2008

i

ABSTRACT

The Asian Financial Crisis was a wake-up call to the South Korean economy that a change

to its economic structure was needed. Prior to the Crisis, South Korea enjoyed healthy

economic growth and low unemployment. With the onset of the Crisis, Korea experienced

severe recession. Unemployment levels soared and turnover in the labour market became

commonplace. The Korean government enacted a series of policies and succeeded in

combating unemployment in the short-term. To the present time, unemployment levels

have been lowered, albeit with job instability and insecurity. A more effective longer-term

solution is needed to increase the resilience of this NIE.

The role of inter-sector labour mobility as a policy tool to combat unemployment using the

relevant determinants of mobility has not been explored in Korea (Asia), although it has

been debated at length in the West since the 1980s. Part of the reason for this lies in the

lack of longitudinal data to facilitate appropriate research. Recently, such data have been

made available by the Korean Labour Institute (KLI). This thesis extends research into the

labour mobility-unemployment relationship to South Korea. The priority is to establish

whether a mobility-unemployment relationship exists in Korea, and to obtain a thorough

understanding of the factors affecting sectoral mobility in this country in order to facilitate

the crafting of potential tools for addressing the unemployment problem.

The thesis is organised into two parts. Prior to the main study, however, the economic

history of Korea is outlined and sectoral labour reallocation patterns are associated with

economic growth. This preliminary work establishes the potential for the detailed research

for the Korean labour market that follows to make contribution to policy solutions to the

unemployment problem along the lines of the earlier research undertaken in Western

countries. Part I, entitled ‘Sectoral Mobility and Unemployment’, details the theoretical

hypotheses and empirical evidence concerning sectoral mobility and unemployment, and

extends the empirical application to Korea. The general finding is that whilst the

hypotheses [Sectoral Shift Hypothesis (SSH), Aggregate Demand Hypothesis (ADH) and

stage-of-the-business-cycle effect] are not relevant for Korea in the pre-Crisis era (1970-

1997), they have some support in the post-Crisis period (1998-2001). However, data

limitations, in the form of the short time period available for analysis, prevent strong

conclusions from being formed. The tentative conclusion is that a new mobility-

ii

unemployment relationship may exist for Korea in the post-Crisis period, thereby giving

rise to the potential for mobility as a policy tool for controlling unemployment. The in-

depth understanding of the factors of sectoral mobility required to implement such policy

provides the basis for the remainder of the thesis.

Part II, titled ‘The Factors Affecting Mobility’, develops a theoretical model for sectoral

mobility, and provides a literature review on other forms of labour mobility (union/non-

union, public-private and rural-urban mobility) as well as an empirical review of sectoral

mobility. These chapters set the stage for the empirical analysis of the determinants of

sectoral mobility for Korea. For the overall workforce, the main conclusion is that sectoral

mobility is a multi-facetted phenomenon involving a spread of factors. Of significance are

the expected and lifetime incomes, which are the pull factors of mobility, the deterrent

effect of the new sector’s unemployment rate and the direct effects of unanticipated sectoral

shocks. The multi-dimensional nature of these factors is replicated in the separate analyses

undertaken for males and females. The main finding is that whilst the monetary variables

and worker/industry characteristics impact male and female mobility differently, sectoral

unemployment and sectoral shock affect male and female mobility similarly.

The thesis is summarised and some policy measures provided in the sypnosis. It is argued

that the ‘new’ mobility-unemployment phenomenon appears to have emerged in Korea

after the Crisis, whereas it had been a feature of Western economies in much earlier time

periods. Traditional monetary and fiscal policies are inadequate when it comes to

combating unemployment in the presence of this mobility-unemployment phenomenon. A

combination of macro-policies, given the relevance of the ADH, and micro-policies, given

the validity of the SSH, is required. The multi-dimensional nature of mobility implies that

the micro policies to control or reduce mobility rates using the relevant variables (to

alleviate unemployment) should cover measures related to monetary wages, labour market

groups and sector performance. The sypnosis notes a dearth of Asian studies on sectoral

mobility, possibly due to the lack of longitudinal data. The collection of quality

longitudinal data for other Asian countries, so that research along the lines conducted in the

thesis could be undertaken for other NIEs, was seen as being of vital importance. With

such data, the standard of research on Asian economies can be at par with that of the

Western countries, and the apparently considerable potential benefits of microeconomic

policies via sectoral mobility for Asia could be realised.

iii

TABLE OF CONTENTS

Page

Abstract

Table of Contents

List of Tables

List of Figures

List of Common Acronyms

Acknowledgements

i

iii

xi

xii

xiii

xv

Chapter

Description

1

1.1

1.1.1

1.1.2

1.1.3

1.1.4

1.2

1.3

INTRODUCTION

Aims of Thesis

Definition of Sectoral Mobility

The Empirical Studies

Sectoral Mobility vis-à-vis Unemployment

The Factors Motivating Mobility

Organisation of the Thesis

Contributions to Labour Economics

1

1

1

1

2

4

5

7

2

2.1

2.2

2.2.1

2.2.2

2.2.3

2.2.4

2.2.5

2.2.6

2.3

2.3.1

2.3.2

2.3.3

2.4

2.4.1

2.4.2

2.4.3

2.5

ECONOMIC HISTORY OF SOUTH KOREA

Introduction

Korea’s Economic History

The Three Kingdoms

Koryo Dynasty

Choson Dynasty (1392-1910)

Japanese Colonial Rule (1910-1945)

Korean War (1950-1953)

Post-war South Korea

Korea’s Economic History in the Post-War Era

The 1970s

The 1980s

The 1990s

Economic Growth, Sectoral Changes and Labour Mobility

The Three Decades: 1970-2000

The 1998-2001 Period

Possible Structural Break during Asian Financial Crisis

Concluding Remarks

10

10

11

11

12

13

13

14

14

15

15

18

19

20

20

25

28

28

iv

Chapter Description Page

PART I:

SECTORAL MOBILITY AND UNEMPLOYMENT

PREAMBLE

29

29

3

3.1

3.2

3.2.1

3.2.2

3.2.3

3.3

3.3.1

3.3.2

3.4

3.5

3.5.1

3.5.2

3.6

3.6.1

3.6.2

3.6.3

3.7

3.7.1

3.7.2

3.7.3

3.8

3.9

THEORETICAL HYPOTHESES CONCERNING

SECTORAL MOBILITY AND UNEMPLOYMENT

Introduction

The Sectoral Shift Hypothesis

Impact of Sectoral Mobility on Aggregate Unemployment

SSH and Supply Shocks

SSH and the Natural Unemployment Rate

Aggregate Demand Hypothesis

U-V Relationship

The σ-U Co-movement Approach

Predicted and Unpredicted Mobility Indices

The Reallocation Timing Hypothesis and Stage-of-the-

Business-Cycle Effect

The Reallocation Timing Hypothesis

The Stage-of-the-Business-Cycle Effect

Conceptual Differences Between the SSH, ADH and RTH

Source of Sectoral Mobility

Chain of Causation

Nature of Unemployment

Methodological Differences

Methods to Test the SSH

Methods to Test the ADH

Methods to Test the RTH and Stage-of-the-Business-Cycle

Effect

Critique of the Mobility Indices

Summary

31

31

32

32

34

36

38

38

40

42

46

46

48

49

49

49

50

50

50

51

54

54

58

v

Chapter

4

4.1

4.2

4.2.1

4.2.2

4.2.3

4.2.4

4.3

4.3.1

4.3.2

4.4

4.4.1

4.4.2

4.4.3

4.5

4.6

4.6.1

4.6.2

4.6.3

4.6.3.1

4.6.3.2

4.6.3.3

4.6.4

4.6.4.1

4.6.4.2

4.6.5

4.6.6

4.6.7

4.7

4.8

Description

THE IMPACT OF SECTORAL MOBILITY ON

UNEMPLOYMENT: A REVIEW OF THE EMPIRICAL

LITERATURE

Introduction

Empirical Review on the SSH

The Raw Lilien Index

The Index Generated by Supply-side Disturbances

Pure Sectoral Shift Measures

The Natural Unemployment Rate Approach

Empirical Findings on the ADH

The Predicted Mobility Indices

The U-V Relationship

Findings on the RTH and Stage-of-the-Business-Cycle

The Horizon Covariance Index

Interaction Variables

Labour Reallocations and Foregone Production

Summary of Empirical Findings

Empirical Application

Type and Frequency of Data

Time Period

Model Estimation

Single-Equation Models

2-Stage Least Squares (2SLS)

Dual-Equation Models

Model Specification

Dependent Variable

Explanatory Variables

Number of σ’s in the Regression Equation

Natural Unemployment Rate Approach

Sectoral Mobility and Gender Unemployment

Summary of Empirical Application

Links with Research on Determinants of Mobility

Page

60

60

60

61

62

62

65

67

67

68

69

69

70

70

71

72

72

73

73

73

80

80

84

84

84

88

89

92

93

94

vi

Chapter Description

Page

5

5.1

5.2

5.2.1

5.2.2

5.3

5.3.1

5.3.2

5.3.3

5.3.4

5.4

5.4.1

5.4.1.1

5.4.1.2

5.4.2

5.4.2.1

5.4.2.2

5.4.3

5.4.3.1

5.4.3.2

5.4.3.3

5.4.3.4

5.4.3.5

5.4.4

5.5

5.5.1

5.5.2

5.6

5.6.1

5.6.2

5.6.3

5.6.4

5.7

SECTORAL MOBILITY AND UNEMPLOYMENT: AN

EMPIRICAL EXAMINATION FOR KOREA

Introduction

Trends in Aggregate and Sectoral Unemployment

Aggregate and Sectoral Unemployment

Sector-specific Employment and Unemployment

Model Framework

Baseline Model

Methodology

Descriptive Statistics

Stationarity

Dual-Equation Modelling

Estimation of Money Growth Equation

Review of Empirical Studies Estimating DMRt

Application to the Korean Case

Specification of Unemployment Equation

Unrestricted to Restricted Models

Preliminary Model Estimation

Structural Change

Prior Knowledge on Korean Unemployment

Tests for Model Stability

Phase I and Phase II

Phase II and Phase III

Accommodation of Structural Change

Re-specification of Unemployment Models

Final Model Estimation

Treatment for Serial Correlation

Sectoral Mobility during the Pre-Crisis Period (1971-1997)

Validity of the Hypotheses

Validity of the SSH

Relevance of the ADH

Applicability of the RTH

Sectoral Movements and Stage-of-the-Business-Cycle Effect

Concluding Remarks

97

97

98

98

98

100

100

100

101

105

106

106

106

108

111

111

114

116

116

116

120

120

123

125

127

127

129

130

131

134

135

136

138

vii

Chapter Description Page

PART II:

THE FACTORS AFFECTING SECTORAL MOBILITY

143

PREAMBLE

143

6

6.1

6.2

6.3

6.3.1

6.3.2

6.3.3

6.4

6.5

6.5.1

6.5.2

6.5.3

6.5.4

6.5.5

6.6

THE THEORETICAL AND CONCEPTUAL ISSUES IN

LABOUR/SECTORAL MOBILITY

Introduction

What is Labour Mobility

Theories of Sectoral/Industrial Mobility

Worker-Employer Mismatch Theory

Sectoral Shock Theory

Bridging Theory

Model of Labour Mobility

Empirical Models of Sectoral Mobility

Probability Choice Models

Simultaneous Equation Models

Vector Auto-regression Models

Sectoral Shock Measures

Time Periods

Summary: Model Application for Current Research

145

145

145

149

149

150

151

151

157

158

162

163

163

164

164

7

7.1

7.2

7.3

7.4

7.5

REVIEW OF THE EMPIRICAL LITERATURE ON

OTHER FORMS OF LABOUR MOBILITY

Introduction

Union versus Non-Union Mobility

Public versus Private Sector Mobility

Rural-Urban Mobility

Summary: Salient Points for Empirical Model

166

166

166

173

179

184

viii

Chapter

Description Page

8

8.1

8.2

8.3

8.3.1

8.3.2

8.3.3

8.3.4

8.4

8.5

8.6

8.7

8.8

EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE: FACTORS MOTIVATING

SECTORAL/INDUSTRIAL MOBILITY

Introduction

Sectoral/Industrial Mobility

Determinants under the Mismatch Theory

Monetary Wages

Macroeconomic Factors

Worker Characteristics

Job/Industry Characteristics

Determinants under Sectoral Shock Theory

Determinants under Bridging Theory

Assessment of Empirical Studies of Sectoral Mobility for

Modelling

Summary of Empirical Studies of Sectoral Mobility

Summary of Lessons Drawn from the Literature

186

186

186

188

194

198

203

220

226

230

231

233

237

9

9.1

9.2

9.2.1

9.2.2

9.2.3

9.2.3.1

9.2.3.2

9.2.3.3

9.2.3.4

9.3

9.4

9.4.1

9.4.1.1

9.4.1.2

9.4.1.3

9.4.2

EMPIRICAL STUDY ON THE DETERMINANTS OF

SECTORAL/INDUSTRIAL MOBILITY IN KOREA

Introduction

Data Sources, Concepts and Coverage

KLIPS Data

Korea NSO Data

The Role of Interim State of Unemployment

Sectoral Labour Flows

Missing Industry Information

Missing Survey Information

Interim States of Unemployment

Generic Model of Sectoral/Industrial Mobility

Descriptive Statistics

Survey Weights

Wave 1 Weights and the Population

Weights for Sample Attrition

Weights for New Entrants

Descriptive Statistics: Complex Statistics

240

240

241

241

245

245

245

247

249

250

251

252

253

254

255

255

256

ix

Chapter

9.5

9.5.1

9.5.2

9.5.3

9.6

9.6.1

9.6.2

9.6.3

9.6.4

9.6.5

9.7

9.7.1

9.7.2

9.8

Description

Derivation of Predicted/Recomputed Variables

Predicted Sectoral Wages

Sector-level Variables

Descriptive Statistics of Predicted/Recomputed Variables

Empirical Analysis: Determinants of Sectoral Mobility

Monetary Variables

Macroeconomic Variables

Worker Characteristics

Industry Characteristics

Sectoral Shock

Extensions of the Model

A Focus on the Initial Industry

Empirical Test: Theories of Sectoral Mobility

Summary

Page

261

262

269

274

275

280

282

283

289

290

291

291

292

298

10 10.1 10.2 10.3 10.4 10.5 10.5.1 10.5.2 10.5.3 10.5.4 10.5.5 10.6 10.6.1 10.6.2 10.6.3 10.7 10.7.1 10.7.2 10.7.3 10.7.4 10.8

GENDER DIFFERENCES IN SECTORAL/MOBILITY IN KOREA Introduction Model and Sample Dataset Validity of Pooling the Dataset Descriptive Statistics for Males and Females Gender Differences in the Determinants of Sectoral Mobility Monetary Variables Macroeconomic Variables Worker Characteristics Industry Characteristics Sectoral Shock A Gender Perspective on Theories of Sectoral Mobility Worker-Employer Mismatch Theory Sectoral Shock Theory Bridging Theory Decomposition Analysis An Overview of the Standard Decomposition Technique Application to Logit Models Decomposition Results Explanatory Power of Observed Variables Concluding Remarks

303 303 304 305 307 311 312 315 316 320 322 323 323 323 324 325 326 327 329 331 334

x

Chapter

Description

Page

11 11.1 11.2 11.3 11.4 11.4.1 11.4.2 11.4.3 11.5

THE SYPNOSIS Introduction Part I: Sectoral Mobility and Unemployment Part II: The Factors Affecting Sectoral Mobility The Policy Implications Policy Measures in Post-Crisis Period Assessment of Policy Measures and Current Situation Policy Recommendations Direction for Future Research

337 337 337 342 354 354 355 356 362

REFERENCES

364

LIST OF APPENDICES* 388

* Available on enclosed CD.

xi

LIST OF TABLES

Table Description Page

Table 2.1 Annual % Change in GDP, CPI and Employment (EMP) and 16

Unemployment Rate (UR)

Table 2.2 GDP by Sector, 1970-2000 21

Table 2.3 Employed Persons by Sector, 1970-2000 23

Table 2.4 GDP at Current Prices by Sector, 1998-2001 26

Table 2.5 Employed Persons by Sector, 1998-2001 27

Table 4.1 Studies on the Impact of Sectoral Mobility on Aggregate 63

Unemployment in the U.S.

Table 4.2 R2 between Actual Unemployment Rate and Natural Unemployment 66

Rate

Table 4.3 Contemporaneous Correlations between Labour Reallocation 71

and Average Value Proxies of Foregone Production

Table 4.4 Unemployment and Money Growth Equations used in Selected 74

Studies of Sectoral Mobility

Table 5.1 Employment and Unemployment By Sector 99

Table 5.2 Symbols of Sectoral Mobility 102

Table 5.3 Descriptive Statistics of Ut, DMRt and σ 103

Table 5.4 Initial Parameter Estimates of σ 115

Table 5.5 Phases in the Korean Labour Market from the CUSUMSQ Test 118

Table 5.6 F- and Harvey-Collier Statistics from Tests of Structural Change 122

Table 5.7 Final Model: Parameter Estimates of σ, D and σD and LM statistic 128

Table 5.8 1971-1997: Parameter Estimates of σ 130

Table 5.9 Parameter Estimates of σ, σSt and/or σStD 137

Table 7.1 Selected Studies of Union/Non-Union Mobility 168

Table 7.2 Selected Studies of Public-Private Sector Mobility 175

Table 7.3 Selected Studies of Rural-Urban Sector Mobility 181

Table 8.1 Probability Choice Studies of Sectoral/Industrial Mobility under 190

Worker-Employer Mismatch Theory

Table 8.2 Wages and Sectoral/Industrial Mobility 197

Table 8.3 Unemployment, Employment, GNP and Sectoral/Industrial Mobility 202

Table 8.4 Age and Sectoral/Industrial Mobility 204

Table 8.5 Gender and Sectoral/Industrial Mobility 206

Table 8.6 Marital Status/Head of Household and Sectoral/Industrial Mobility 207

Table 8.7 Education and Sectoral/Industrial Mobility 208

Table 8.8 On-the-job Training and Sectoral/Industrial Mobility 213

Table 8.9 Occupation and Industrial Mobility 217

Table 8.10 Initial Industry and Industrial Mobility 218

Table 8.11 Employment Status and Industrial Mobility 220

Table 8.12 Working Hours, Product Similarity, Work Similarity and Industrial 223

Mobility

Table 8.13 Sectoral Performance Indicators and Sectoral/Industrial Mobility 226

Table 8.14 Sectoral Shocks and Sectoral/Industrial Mobility under Sectoral Shock 229

Theory

Table 8.15 Assessment of the Explanatory Variables 235

xii

Table Description Page

Table 9.1 Gross and Net Labour Flows based on Sample of 29,474 Observations 246

Table 9.2 Gross and Net Labour Flows based on Sample of 29,474 Observations 248

and the Interim State of Unemployment

Table 9.3 Industry Breakdown of 29,474 Sample with/without Survey Information 249

Table 9.4 Gross and Net Labour Flows based on Sample of 10,691 Observations 251

Table 9.5 Wave 1 Weights 254

Table 9.6 Means and Standard Deviations for Korean workers, Aged 20-64 years 258

Table 9.7 Actual versus Predicted Monetary Variables 269

Table 9.8 Means and Standard Deviations for Predicted and Recomputed

Variables 275

Table 9.9 Unrestricted Model: Logit Regression on Probability of

Sectoral/Industrial Mobility 278

Table 9.10 Main Model: Logit Regression on Probability of Sectoral/Industrial

Mobility 281

Table 9.11 Logit Regression on Probability of Sectoral/Industrial Mobility:

A Focus on the Initial Industry, Selected Coefficients 292

Table 9.12 Logistic Regression of Sectoral/Industrial Mobility on Wages and

Alternative Measures of Sectoral Shock, Selected Coefficients 296

Table 10.1 Logistic Regression of ‘Full’ Model 306

Table 10.2 Means and Standard Deviations for Male and Female workers, Aged

20-64 years 308

Table 10.3 Logistic Regression of Sectoral/Industrial Mobility by Gender 314

Table 10.4 Logistic Regression of Sectoral/Industrial Mobility on the Standard

Error of Wage Distribution and Sectoral Shock for Males and Females 324

Table 10.5 Decomposition Results 330

Table 10.6 Explanatory Power of Observed Characteristics in Decomposition 332

Table 11.1 Micro-policy Targets for Korea 360

LIST OF FIGURES

Figure Description Page

Figure 1.1 Lilien Index (σt) and Annual Unemployment Rate (Ut) 3

Figure 2.1 Korea’s Historical Timeline 11

Figure 2.2 Annual % Change in GDP, 1970-2001 17

Figure 2.3 Annual % Change in Employment and Unemployment Rate, 17

1970-2001

Figure 2.4 Annual % Change in CPI, 1970-2001 18

Figure 5.1 DMRt series 110

Figure 9.1 Probability of Sectoral Mobility and Age 284

Figure 9.2 Probability of Sectoral Mobility and Tenure 285

xiii

LIST OF COMMON ACRONYMS

ABS Australian Bureau of Statistics

ACGR Average Annual Compound Growth Rate

AD Aggregate Demand

ADH Aggregate Demand Hypothesis

APEC Asia-Pacific Economic Cooperation

AR Auto-regression

BLS Bureau of Labor Statistics

CILSS Cöte d’Ivoire Living Standards Survey

CO Cochrane-Orcutt

CPI Consumer Price Index

CPS Current Population Survey

CSO Central Statistical Organisation

CSV Cross-Section Volatility

CUSUM Cumulated Sum of Residuals

CUSUMSQ Cumulated Sum of Squared Residuals

DMR Unanticipated Money Growth

DME Anticipated Money Growth

DOLS Dynamic Ordinary Least Squares

DWS Displaced Workers Survey

ECM Error Correction Models

EP Energy Price Index

ESS Error Sum of Squares

GDP Gross Domestic Product

GIC Government Investment Corporation

GNP Gross National Product

HC Harvey-Collier

HILDA Household, Income and Labour Dynamics in Australia

ILO International Labor Organisation

IMF International Monetary Fund

IQ Intelligence Quotient

IT Information Technology

IV Instrumental Variables

KLI Korean Labor Institute

KLIPS Korea Labor Income Panel Study

LM Lagrange Multiplier

LMAS Labour Market Activity Survey

MLE Maximum Likelihood Estimation

NHWI National Help-Wanted Index

NIE Newly Industrialised Economy

NILF Not In Labour Force

NLS National Labor Survey

NSO National Statistical Office

NSW New South Wales

OECD Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development

OLS Ordinary Least Squares

PID Personal Identification

PPI Producer Price Index

PSC Post-School Certificate

PSID Panel Study of Income Dynamics

RTH Reallocation Timing Hypothesis

SA South Australia

xiv

SSH Sectoral Shift Hypothesis

SME Small and Medium-sized Enterprises

TSM Time-Series Models

TQ Trade Qualification

UI Unemployment Insurance

U-V Unemployment-Vacancies

VAR Vector-autoregression

WA Western Australia

2SE 2-Step Estimation

2SLS 2-Stage Least Squares

σ-U Mobility-Unemployment

σ-V Mobility-Vacancies

Note: Excludes annotations for variables and mathematical symbols.

xv

ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS

This thesis has moved with me through three continents, seven houses and varied states of

employment. It’s a wonder it is finished. I have several people to be grateful for.

My principal supervisor, Professor Paul Miller; who was instrumental in the evolution of

this thesis. His expertise on the area of labour economics and excellent supervision

throughout the thesis will be treasured. His suggestions on modelling and empirical issues,

conscientious attention in reviewing the hundreds of drafts and empirical results, and clear

suggestions in the written drafts are valued, considering that the study was done long-

distance with minimal face-to-face contact. He is the ideal supervisor one could have.

My coordinating supervisor in my initial country of residence, Dr Chai Tai Tee, from the

Government of Singapore Investment Corporation, who gave direction on the choice of

topic and data collection. He sketched a realistic picture on the effort involved and was

willing to give the moral backup outside of the university.

The Korea Labor Institute for their assistance in the execution of the KLIPS software and in

explaining the survey questionnaires and data items which initially appeared in the Korean

language onscreen. The UWA Economics Programme for providing me with the necessary

resources during my residency at the university. A note of appreciation to Ms Derby Voon

for going through my list of references.

Special thanks to my family. To my mother who has been there for me these years; her

perfect blend of kindness and wisdom never ceases to amaze me. To my husband whose

job stint in the Middle East made this study possible and who became the IT helpdesk at

home. To my brother who assisted in the merging of several datasets. To ‘Moses’, my

little Maltese, my source of fun and amusement.

I thank God, too, for bringing these people to me, for without them, this thesis would not be

complete.

1

CHAPTER 1

INTRODUCTION

1.1 AIMS OF THESIS

1.1.1 Definition of Sectoral Mobility

Labour mobility is an area of labour economics that has generated considerable attention in

studies across the world. It involves labour movements across sectors, and can take various

forms, including between union and non-union sectors, public and private sectors, and rural

and urban sectors. This study examines labour mobility across industries or sectors of the

economy. Such labour movements are termed as „industrial‟, „inter-industrial‟, or more

simply „intersectoral‟ or „sectoral‟ mobility.

1.1.2 The Empirical Studies

There has been widespread interest in the study of sectoral mobility, from the perspective

of its causes and consequences. The latter has been particularly popular as a research topic,

with many studies looking at the links between sectoral mobility and employment and

unemployment. These links have been examined for the U.S. [Lilien (1982), Abraham and

Katz (1986), Blanchard and Diamond (1989), Parker (1992), Palley (1992), Brainard and

Cutler (1993), Davis (1987), Mills, Pelloni and Zervoyianni (1995), Loungani (1986),

Murphy and Topel (1987a) and Lu (1996)], Canada [Neelin (1987) and Samson (1985)],

Europe [Saint-Paul (1997) for France, Garonna and Sica (2000) for Italy], and Asia [Prasad

(1997) for Japan]. The seminal paper was Lilien (1982) on the relationship between

sectoral mobility and unemployment1. The subsequent development of this led to several

hypotheses, namely, the Sectoral Shift Hypothesis (SSH), Aggregate Demand Hypothesis

(ADH), Reallocation Timing Hypothesis (RTH) and stage-of-the-business-cycle effect.

This research has policy significance, as if the underlying relationship holds, inter-sector

mobility could be an instrument in combating unemployment via adjustments of its relevant

determinants2. Putting it figuratively, this is analogous to sculpting a new tool to solve an

old problem.

2

Given the links between mobility and unemployment, and the potential of mobility as a

policy tool, the need to understand the factors that motivate it emerges. Interest in these

only followed nearly a decade later, in the late 1980s and 1990s. The studies covering this

topic are for the U.S. [Loungani and Rogerson (1989), Jovanovic and Moffitt (1990),

McLaughlin and Bils (2001), Brainard and Cutler (1993), Fallick (1993), Thomas (1996b),

Neal (1995), Clark (1998) and Kim (1998)], Canada [Osberg (1991), Osberg, Gordon and

Lin (1994), Vanderkamp (1977) and Altonji and Ham (1990)], Europe [Ottersen (1993) for

Sweden and Gulde and Wolf (1998) for the European Union (France, Italy, Germany and

Spain)] and Asia [Prasad (1997) for Japan and Jayadevan (1997) for India]. Though the

number of studies is by no means sparse, given its belated entry into the field of labour

economics, sectoral mobility can be considered to be an infant topic of research.

1.1.3 Sectoral Mobility vis-à-vis Unemployment

The empirical basis for the research into the links between sectoral mobility and

unemployment can be seen for several continents/countries, namely, Oceania (Australia),

North America (U.S. and Canada), Europe (U.K., Sweden and Finland), and Asia (Japan,

South Korea and Singapore). The indicator of unemployment is its rate (Ut). Inter-sector

labour movements can be represented by the raw Lilien index (ζt), the derivation of which

will be outlined in chapter 33. Inter-sector labour movements and the unemployment rate

both fluctuate for each country over the 1970-2001 period4 (see country charts under Figure

1.1). Of relevance is South Korea, where sectoral mobility moved in tandem with

unemployment, especially during the 1998-20015 post-Crisis period where unemployment

reached 7% in 1998, the highest since 1970.

The various empirical investigations into data like that presented in Figure 1.1 suggest that

a mobility-unemployment relationship exists in most Western countries. The first review

of the aggregate-level data in Figure 1.1 suggests that a mobility-unemployment

relationship may also exist for Korea. Given the potential for this relationship to be

exploited in unemployment policy in Korea, it is important to establish more formally its

strength, and to determine how it arises. Part I of this thesis addresses these issues.

3

Figure 1.1 Lilien Index (ζt) and Annual Unemployment Rate (Ut)

Australia U.S.

0.00

2.00

4.00

6.00

8.00

10.00

12.00

1970

1972

1974

1976

1978

1980

1982

1984

1986

1988

1990

1992

1994

1996

1998

2000

0.00

2.00

4.00

6.00

8.00

10.00

12.00

1970

1972

1974

1976

1978

1980

1982

1984

1986

1988

1990

1992

1994

1996

1998

2000

Canada U.K.

0.00

2.00

4.00

6.00

8.00

10.00

12.00

14.00

1970

1972

1974

1976

1978

1980

1982

1984

1986

1988

1990

1992

1994

1996

1998

2000

0.00

2.00

4.00

6.00

8.00

10.00

12.00

14.00

1971

1973

1975

1977

1979

1981

1983

1985

1987

1989

1991

1993

1995

1997

1999

2001

Note: Methodology for 1999 revised; data not strictly comparable.

Finland Sweden

0.00

2.00

4.00

6.00

8.00

10.00

12.00

14.00

16.00

18.00

1971

1973

1975

1977

1979

1981

1983

1985

1987

1989

1991

1993

1995

1997

1999

2001

0.00

1.00

2.00

3.00

4.00

5.00

6.00

7.00

8.00

9.00

1970

1972

1974

1976

1978

1980

1982

1984

1986

1988

1990

1992

1994

1996

1998

2000

Note: Methodology for 1989 revised; data not strictly comparable. Note: Methodology for 1993 revised; data not strictly comparable.

ζt*100

Ut

Ut

ζt*100

Ut

ζt*100

ζt*100

Ut

Ut

ζt*100

ζt*100

Ut

4

Japan Singapore

0.00

1.00

2.00

3.00

4.00

5.00

6.00

1970 1973 1976 1979 1982 1985 1988 1991 1994 1997 2000

0.00

2.00

4.00

6.00

8.00

10.00

12.00

1974

1976

1978

1980

1982

1984

1986

1988

1990

1992

1994

1996

1998

2000

Note: Sector employment data not available for 1971-1973.

South Korea

0.00

1.00

2.00

3.00

4.00

5.00

6.00

7.00

8.00

1970

1972

1974

1976

1978

1980

1982

1984

1986

1988

1990

1992

1994

1996

1998

2000

Note: For all charts, the x-axis is the year. The y-axis either represents the unemployment rate in percent terms or the

value of the Lilien index. The Lilien index is a measure of sectoral mobility, and it is the most commonly-used index in

empirical studies that focus on sectoral mobility.

1.1.4 The Factors Motivating Mobility

Where a mobility-unemployment relation exists and is to be used by policy makers, the

factors that determine this mobility need to be understood. Part II is dedicated to enhancing

such understanding for Korea for the recent 1998-2001 post-Crisis period. A range of

determinants of worker mobility have been identified in the empirical literature, covering

monetary and macroeconomic variables, worker/job characteristics and unanticipated

ζt*100 Ut

Ut

ζt*100

Ut

ζt*100

5

sectoral shocks. Study of the Korean labour market will include these, and there will be

emphasis on measuring these separately for the different sectors.

If these determinants can be identified formally, there arises the potential for policy to

control mobility via the relevant variables to alleviate unemployment. This thesis therefore

aims to: (i) establish the relationship between mobility and unemployment for Korea; and

(ii) enable a thorough understanding of the determinants of sectoral mobility in order to

provide a sound basis for policy in this area.

1.2 ORGANISATION OF THE THESIS

The thesis consists of an introduction (chapter 1), a prelude (chapter 2), the main body of

research (Parts I and II), and a conclusion (chapter 11). Chapter 2, on „The Economic

History of South Korea‟, introduces the lesser-researched country of Korea and

demonstrates the importance of sectoral mobility in relation to economic growth. Part I

focuses on the issue of sectoral mobility vis-a-vis unemployment and Part II concentrates

on the determinants of sectoral mobility.

Part I, entitled „Sectoral Mobility and Unemployment‟, contains 3 chapters. Chapter 3

outlines theoretical perspectives on hypotheses concerning sectoral mobility and

unemployment. Chapter 4 covers empirical evidence on these hypotheses. An empirical

application to Korea is undertaken in the last chapter of Part I.

The theoretical hypotheses on sectoral mobility and unemployment presented in chapter 3

are the SSH, ADH, RTH and stage-of-the-business-cycle. The chapter documents the

different methods of testing these hypotheses. Conceptual differences among the

hypotheses, in terms of the source of sectoral mobility, the chain of causation, and the

nature of the resultant unemployment, are identified.

The empirical review of the impact of sectoral mobility on unemployment in chapter 4

focuses on findings, modelling techniques, model specification and the set of mobility

6

indices and explanatory variables. This is considered to be the preparatory work for the

empirical application carried out in chapter 5.

Chapter 5 estimates the impact of sectoral mobility on aggregate unemployment for Korea

in the context of the hypotheses outlined in chapter 3. The empirical model is subjected to

stringent econometric testing procedures. Two periods are distinguished in the empirical

work, the pre- and post-Crisis periods. For the earlier period, the main findings show a lack

of relevance of the SSH, ADH and stage-of-the-business-cycle effect for Korea. The

relevance of the RTH could not be ascertained owing to measurement issues associated

with the primary variable used, the horizon covariance index. For the post-Crisis period,

the findings favour the SSH, ADH and stage-of-the-business-cycle effect, but the limited

number of observations in the aggregate-level annual data prevents strong conclusions from

being drawn. Nonetheless, as the findings have revealed that the SSH and ADH could

apply to Korea, sectoral mobility could be a potential policy tool for addressing the

unemployment problem. Knowledge of the determinants of sectoral mobility is needed.

Part II is devoted to providing this information.

The second part of the thesis, entitled „The Factors Affecting Sectoral Mobility‟, contains

the literature review on labour/sectoral mobility and an empirical study of sectoral mobility

in the context of the Korean labour market. It contains five chapters, chapter 6 through to

chapter 10. Chapter 6 highlights the theoretical and conceptual issues in the study of

labour mobility and develops the empirical model. Chapter 7 reviews the literature on the

forms other than sectoral mobility, i.e. union/non-union, public-private and rural-urban

mobility, to extract findings useful for the current work in terms of econometric techniques,

data banks and relevant research questions. Finally, chapter 8 reviews the empirical

evidence on the factors associated with sectoral mobility. Together, chapters 6, 7 and 8 set

the stage, in terms of identifying a model, conceptual issues, econometric techniques,

appropriate explanatory variables and data to be used, for the empirical analysis of the

determinants of sectoral mobility for Korea.

The last two chapters in Part II contain the empirical application for Korea. Chapter 9

presents the generic model of sectoral mobility, descriptive statistics of the explanatory

variables, selected predicted/recomputed monetary and sector-level variables, and empirical

7

results of the determinants of sectoral mobility. The conclusion is that sectoral mobility is

a multi-dimensional phenomenon involving a range of factors. Of special interest are the

expected and lifetime incomes, which act as pull factors of mobility, the deterrent effect of

the new sector‟s unemployment rate and the positive impact of the unpredictable sectoral

shock. Having established the findings for the total workforce, separate analyses are

conducted for males and females in chapter 10.

Chapter 10 provides within- and across-gender group comparisons in terms of mobility

behaviour. The conclusion is that whilst the monetary variables and worker/industry

characteristics affect the mobility of males and females differently, sectoral unemployment

and sectoral shocks impact male and female mobility similarly. The multi-dimensional

nature of these determinants established for the workforce as a whole in chapter 9 is

similarly reflected in the separate analyses for men and women.

The synopsis is chapter 11. The key findings of the empirical work are summarized, and

links between Parts I and II of the research are drawn. Some policy implications

concerning labour mobility are provided and possible avenues for further research for

Korea are suggested.

1.3 CONTRIBUTIONS TO LABOUR ECONOMICS

The major contributions to labour economics can be succinctly stated. These cover

conceptual and empirical issues. On the impact of sectoral mobility on unemployment (i.e.

Part I), the contributions are:

a) The consolidation of the extensive information available on hypotheses on the

mobility-unemployment relationship, including the varied indices used in

empirical research and the way the hypotheses are tested;

b) Development of empirical research through the use of a comprehensive

specification, sophisticated econometric testing, and accommodation of

structural changes to the economy; and

8

c) Conducting research for Asia (Korea in this case), which has been

underrepresented in analyses of the sectoral mobility-unemployment

relationship.

The more notable contributions found in Part II on the determinants of sectoral mobility

include:

a) Raising the sophistication of research on the determinants of sectoral mobility.

This is made possible by drawing out lessons from the study of other forms of

labour mobility for empirical modelling, having a pooled, time-series cross-

sectional dataset at the micro-level, developing a conceptually-advanced model

and having a comprehensive list of variables in the estimating equation.

b) Filling the gap in the research into the determinants of worker mobility for Asia.

The existing studies for Asia are inadequate in quantity (i.e. conducted only for

Japan and India) and quality (i.e. conducted using aggregate-level datasets with

few explanatory variables). The new research in this area applies the lessons

learnt from the West to Korea. The availability of the micro-level dataset

ensures that the research can be carried out to the desired level of sophistication,

comparable with that of recent studies of the developed countries.

c) Extending the coverage of the research by conducting separate analyses for

males and females. This is an important contribution as there are only a few

gender studies, and these only cover the developed countries (e.g. Osberg (1991)

and Osberg, Gordon and Lin (1994) for Canada, and Jovanovic and Moffitt

(1990), Neal (1995) and Thomas (1996b) for the U.S.).

These contributions make the current study a pioneering effort in terms of coverage (to

Asia and the separate male and female labour markets) and the quality of research. It sets

the research on sectoral mobility for South Korea on par with that of the developed

countries.

9

Endnotes:

1. An earlier paper by Vanderkamp (1977) focused on the factors that determine sectoral mobility. Since this

paper did not generate much interest until the late 1980s/early 1990s, the Lilien (1982) paper on the impact of

sectoral mobility is considered to be the origin of the debate.

2. There are many economic, social and political problems associated with unemployment, including loss of

national output and personal hardship. These have been documented elsewhere and will not be discussed here.

3. Aggregate-level employment statistics sourced from the International Labour Organisation (ILO) are used

to compute the raw Lilien index. The Lilien index has been scaled up 100 times to make it comparable to the

unemployment rate in value terms. For all countries except Singapore, the Lilien index has been estimated

over the same nine major industries as that for Korea. The index for Singapore was estimated over 7

industries, with agriculture, mining and utilities being grouped together since 2000-2001 sector employment

data are not available for these industries.

4. The data period is chosen to synchronise with that for the empirical work undertaken in chapter 5.

5. This data period is consistent with that used in the empirical work undertaken on the impact and

determinants of sectoral mobility.

10

CHAPTER 2

THE ECONOMIC HISTORY OF SOUTH KOREA

2.1 INTRODUCTION

South Korea is classified as a Newly Industrialised Economy (NIE), alongside the

economies of Japan, Singapore, Hong Kong and Taiwan. It has experienced phenomenal

economic growth during the post war era, emerging from humble beginnings as a

developing country with a low per capita Gross Domestic Product (GDP) of U.S.$279 in

1970 to attaining developed country status in 1996, with a per capita GDP of U.S.$14,265

in 2004. Its spectacular growth did not come without obstacles, as it had to encounter the

global oil and food crises in the 1970s and it was one of the hardest-hit Asian countries

when the Asian Financial Crisis occurred in the last decade. The country‟s adeptness in

responding to changing economic conditions through industrialisation, protectionism,

financial reform, globalisation and seeking emergency assistance from international bodies

has contributed to its reputation as a dynamic and growing economy. As of 2004, it was

ranked as the world‟s tenth largest economy in gross domestic product1.

This chapter describes the economy of South Korea and traces its economic history. It also

demonstrates the importance of sectoral mobility in relation to economic growth. Whilst the

first aim is for the benefit of readers in providing background information on Korea‟s

economic history and labour market situation, which is imperative for this lesser-researched

Asian country, the second aligns the significance of the study of sectoral mobility itself to

the South Korean economy. The approach is chronological, with the period 1970-2000

categorised into decades, followed by a year-by-year analysis in the more recent period

covering 1998-2001. The purpose of this more detailed coverage of 1998-2001 is to provide

a better understanding of the data period used in the empirical study in chapters 5, 9 and 10.

The chapter is structured as follows. Section 2.2 sketches the history and economy of

Korea up to around 1970. The economic history post-1970 is presented in section 2.3, with

a separate account for each decade. Finally, in section 2.4, it is demonstrated that economic

growth not only depends on the changes in importance of the various sectors of the

11

economy but also on inter-sectoral labour mobility. Hence, labour movements between the

various sectors are tracked together with sectoral economic growth.

2.2 KOREA’S ECONOMIC HISTORY

Korea has an ancient history which dates the nation‟s birth at 2333 B.C., although its

history of humanization is believed to be traceable back to the Paleolithic period. The

oldest kingdom of Korea is known as the Ko Choson. Ancient Korea was inhabited by clan

communities which combined to form small town-states. By the first century, three

kingdoms: Kogurko (37 B.C. – A.D. 688), Paekche (18 B.C. – A.D. 660) and Shilla (57

B.C. – A.D. 935), had emerged on the Korean Peninsula (now known as Manchuria). This

section traces Korea‟s historical timeline (Figure 2.1) from the Three Kingdoms to present-

day Korea.

Figure 2.1 Korea‟s Historical Timeline

Ancient Kogurko

(37 B.C. –

A.D 668)

Shilla

(57 B.C. –

A.D. 668)

Koryo

(918 – 1392)

Japanese

Colonialism (1910 – 1945)

South

Korea

(1953-)

Ko Choson

(2333 B.C.)

Paekche (18 B.C. – A.D. 660)

Unified Shilla

(668 – 935)

Choson

(1392-1910)

Korean War

(1950-1953)

2.2.1 The Three Kingdoms

Over the period from 37 B.C. to A.D. 935, Korea was ruled by three kingdoms: Kogurko,

Paekche and Shilla. Whilst Koguryo was prominent in the north, Paekche and Shilla were

located in the south. All Kingdoms developed sophisticated state organizations on the

Korean Peninsula, adopting Confucian and Buddhist hierarchical structures with the king at

the pinnacle. State codes were introduced to initiate a legal system. Education of the

nobility and compilation of state histories were undertaken during this period.

The Three Kingdoms competed in the effort toward territorial expansion. Koguryo was the

first kingdom established as a state power. In 342, the capital of Koguryo fell to the

12

Chinese. After this Paekche amassed power and came into conflict with Koguryo in the

late fourth century. Subsequently Shilla managed to defeat the other two kingdoms, but

was initially unable to control the entire territories of Koguryo and Paekche, which were

under Chinese rule. Eventually Shilla defeated the Chinese in A.D. 676, and became a

unified state covering most of the Korean Peninsula.

The Unified Shilla kingdom (668-935) reached its peak of power and prosperity in the

middle of the eighth century. Education flourished in the government service, the equitable

distribution of land for peasants was put into practice in 722, reservoirs were erected for

rice field irrigation and taxation in kind was collected. Learning was encouraged, resulting

in a new transcription system of Korean words by the use of Chinese characters. However,

in the ninth century, Shilla was troubled by intra-clan conflict around the throne and in

district administration.

2.2.2 Koryo Dynasty

Shilla was destroyed by rebel leaders: Kyon Hwon in 900, Kung Ye in 901 and Wang Kon,

the last rebel of Shilla and founder of the Koryo Dynasty (918-1392). During the Koryo

dynasty, diplomatic relations with the former Shilla aristocracy were maintained, state

defence was strengthened, internal conflicts among royalties were discouraged, the

emancipation of slaves in 956 was instituted, a civil service examination system to recruit

officials by merit was enforced and land allocation to officials was put into practice. These

policies enabled the Dynasty to become a centralized government with the power to make

admonitions to the throne on the part of officials and censorship of royal decisions. With

such internal order, Koryo was long able to withstand frequent invasions by the Liaos (old

tribal league) in the 900s. However, in 1238 the Mongolians invaded Korea. When the

Mongol Empire collapsed in the middle of the 14th

century, the Koryo dynasty was faced

with internal problems, e.g. animosity between Buddhism and Confucianism, opposition to

land reform by land owners and raiding by Japanese pirates in the country.

13

2.2.3 Choson Dynasty (1392-1910)

In 1392, King Kongyang (of the Koryo Dynasty) was forced to abdicate his throne and

General Yi took over. This marked the start of the Choson dynasty (1392-1910). During

the early Choson period (till the 17th century), Confucian ethics were promoted. The early

Choson era was noted for progressive ideas in administration, phonetics, national script,

economics, science, music, medical science and humanistic studies, historical geography,

increases in learning and writing of books, an increasing number of schools as well as the

introduction of the Korean alphabet.

The Choson maintained its political independence and cultural and ethnic identity in spite

of a number of foreign invasions. However, these invasions brought about destruction of

government records, cultural objects and historical documents, the devastation of land,

decrease in population, and the loss of artisans and technicians. The late Choson period

witnessed much social and economic upheaval. Following a particularly destructive war

with Japan in 1592, there were activities to reconstruct, provide medical relief and print

books destroyed during the war. The era also saw the rise of mercantilism, upward social

mobility, introduction of agro-managerial production methods, privatized factories, higher

production of goods for trade and a rise in commercial farming.

2.2.4 Japanese Colonial Rule (1910-1945)

Towards the late 19th

century, Korea became the focus of intense competition among

imperialist nations: China, Japan and Russia. In 1910, Japan annexed Korea. The Japanese

remained in the peninsula until the end of World War II and instituted militarized colonial

rule. Anti-Japanese resistance was evident. These sentiments came to the fore on March 1

1919 with a nationwide demonstration declaring Independence for Korea in the face of

intolerable aggression and oppression by the Japanese colonialists. The demonstration was

forcefully suppressed by the Japanese occupiers.

At the height of the independence movement, a provisional government of Korea was

established in Vladivostok on March 21, in Shanghai on April 11, and in Seoul on April 21.

The provisional government in Seoul proclaimed Korean independence, asking Japan to

withdraw its occupation forces from Korea. It called upon the Korean people to refuse

14

payment of taxes to the Japanese government, reject trials by Japanese courts, and avoid

employment at colonial offices. The Vladivostok, Shanghai and Seoul groups attempted to

integrate and form the Provisional Government on November 4. The Provisional

Government, despite financial difficulties, attempted to fulfill the international obligations

of the Korean people for 27 years until World War II. It declared war on Japan and

cooperated with the Allied Powers during war.

2.2.5 Korean War (1950-1953)

The Japanese surrender in 1945 brought many challenges in Korea. Korea was then faced

with a conflict in ideology. Korea was divided by the U.S. and U.S.S.R., which occupied

the north and south of the 38th

parallel, respectively. The ideological confrontation

inevitably gave rise to a tense military confrontation. North Korean troops invaded and

defeated the unprepared South across the 38th parallel in 1950. South Korea appealed to the

U.N. In response, the Security Council passed a resolution ordering North Korea to

withdraw to the 38th parallel and encouraged all member countries to give military and

medical support to the Republic. This was provided by the U.S. and 15 other nations.

Although the Allied forces initially pushed the North Koreans out of South Korea and

advanced into the north, they were soon forced to retreat by the Communist Chinese in

January 1951. The U.N. forces mounted a counterattack, retaking Seoul on March 12. A

stalemate was reached in the area along the 38th parallel, where the conflict had begun. At

this point, the Soviet Union called for truce negotiations, which began in July 1951, and

dragged on for two years before an agreement was reached on July 27, 1953.

2.2.6 Post-war South Korea

By the time the war ended, two million people had died and the country had been officially

divided between the north and the south. The Republic of Korea in the south has a

democratic government, whilst the Democratic People‟s Republic of Korea in the north is

ruled by a Communist regime. From this point, the research focuses on the Republic of

Korea.

The start of the Republic of Korea‟s growth began in the early 1960s with the introduction

of the First Five-Year Economic Development Plan. A conscious effort was made to turn

15

from inward-looking import substitution to an outward-looking strategy of export

promotion. South Korea exported light manufactured goods, in which the country had a

comparative advantage owing to its low labour costs. Other measures included maintaining

high interest rates to increase domestic savings and encouraging the inflow of foreign

investment. Thus, Korea was a growing economy when it entered the 1970s.

2.3 KOREA’S ECONOMIC HISTORY IN THE POST-WAR ERA

The Korean economy has experienced astounding growth in the past three decades. Owing

to its sophisticated industrial structure and globalisation efforts, it was admitted into the

Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) in 1996, signaling the

country‟s entry into the rank of advanced economies. Double-digit growth has been

consistently recorded: 30% in 1970-1980, 17% in 1980-1990 and 11% in 1990-2000.

Corresponding to high economic growth, employment has been rising steadily, by 4%, 3%

and 2%, over the same periods.

2.3.1 The 1970s

Korea‟s economic performance in the 1970s can be described as phenomenal, with high

economic growth and inflation but stable unemployment. There was an economic boom in

this decade, with GDP increasing at astounding rates of between 24% and 41% (see Table

2.1 and Figure 2.2). This boom in fact started in the mid-1960s when Korea made policy

changes to promote a free trade regime for exports and combined this with selective

protection in the import competing sectors. As a result of the food shortage of 1973 and oil

price shock in 1974, Korea‟s balance of payments deteriorated and she responded by

restructuring exports to higher value-added sophisticated products and diversifying her

trading partners. Moreover, industrial restructuring towards heavy and chemical products

led to a rising demand for investment by firms as well as increased demand for skilled

workers in the urban areas. There was consequently a transfer of labour from agriculture to

industry. Employment grew rapidly from 3.6% in 1970 to 6.2% in 1976, although the

growth slowed to 1% by the end of the decade (Figure 2.3). With the growth in

16

employment, the unemployment rate was kept at reasonably stable levels, and actually

decreased slightly, from 5% in 1970 to 4% in 1979.

Table 2.1 Annual % Change in GDP, CPI and Employment (EMP)

and Unemployment Rates (UR) GDP CPI EMP UR

1970 27.9 16.0 3.6 4.5

1971 24.0 13.5 3.4 4.5

1972 23.5 11.7 4.4 4.5

1973 28.9 3.2 5.4 4.0

1974 41.2 24.3 4.4 4.1

1975 34.6 25.2 2.4 4.1

1976 36.9 15.3 6.2 3.9

1977 28.2 10.1 3.2 3.8

1978 35.0 14.5 4.7 3.2

1979 28.1 18.3 1.4 3.8

1980 21.8 28.7 0.6 5.2

1981 25.4 21.4 2.5 4.5

1982 14.9 7.2 2.5 4.4

1983 17.3 3.4 0.9 4.1

1984 14.3 2.3 -0.5 3.8

1985 11.4 2.5 3.7 4.0

1986 16.7 2.8 3.6 3.8

1987 17.2 3.1 5.5 3.1

1988 18.8 7.1 3.1 2.5

1989 12.2 5.7 4.1 2.6

1990 20.6 8.6 3.0 2.4

1991 21.1 9.3 3.1 2.3

1992 13.5 6.2 1.9 2.4

1993 12.9 4.8 1.2 2.8

1994 16.5 6.3 3.2 2.4

1995 16.7 4.5 2.9 2.0

1996 10.9 4.9 2.2 2.0

1997 8.3 4.4 1.7 2.6

1998 -2.0 7.5 -6.0 6.8

1999 8.6 0.8 1.8 6.3

2000 8.1 2.3 4.3 4.1

2001 5.7 4.1 2.0 3.0 Source: Data on CPI, Employment and UR are from the ILO LaborStat database.

Data on GDP are from the Korea National Statistical Office.

17

Figure 2.2 Annual % Change in GDP, 1970-2001

-8

-4

0

4

8

12

16

20

24

28

32

36

40

44

1970

1972

1974

1976

1978

1980

1982

1984

1986

1988

1990

1992

1994

1996

1998

2000

Figure 2.3 Annual % Change in Employment and Unemployment Rates, 1970-2001

-8

-4

0

4

8

1970

1972

1974

1976

1978

1980

1982

1984

1986

1988

1990

1992

1994

1996

1998

2000

EMPG

UR

Annotation: EMPG: Annual % Employment Growth Rate

UR: Unemployment Rate

%

%

year

year

18

Figure 2.4 Annual % Change in CPI, 1970-2001

0

4

8

12

16

20

24

28

32

1970

1972

1974

1976

1978

1980

1982

1984

1986

1988

1990

1992

1994

1996

1998

2000

This economic progress came at the cost of high inflation (Figure 2.4). Moreover, the

industrial structure was distorted by over-investment in heavy industries and under-

investment in light industries. There was also a high degree of government control which

distorted prices and stifled competition.

2.3.2 The 1980s

Compared to the previous decade, the 1980s was a decade with lower growth, less inflation

and reduced unemployment. The growth in GDP slowed, from 22% in 1980 to 12% in

1989. Inflation rates dropped significantly, from 29% to 6%, over the same period. These

changes were the result of active steps undertaken to reduce inflation, rectify the structural

imbalance in the economy and to promote competition in the 1970s. Many restructured

industrial firms (power-generating, automobile, electrical, electronics, shipping, overseas

construction industries) were forced to merge to reduce excess capacity. There was also a

financial restructuring in the 1980s, as many commercial banks privatized, barriers to entry

into the financial sector were reduced, and financial services were diversified and

streamlined. On the labour front, employment levels rose, with about 2.8 million new jobs

being created during the decade. The rate of unemployment sank to the unprecedented

level of 2.6% by 1989.

%

year

19

2.3.3 The 1990s

The third decade can be categorized into two phases, with the first (1990-1997)

characterized by high growth, high inflation and low unemployment, and the second (1998-

1999) by low growth, inflation and high unemployment. In the first phase, GDP continued

to grow at double-digit rates and unemployment was at relatively low rates of 2-3%. This

was attributed to Korea‟s regionalization and globalization policy, i.e. “segyehwa policy”,

in which the country reformed its financial sector and participated in international activities

through trade talks in the Uruguay Round, membership in the Asia-Pacific Economic

Cooperation (APEC) and accession to the OECD in 1996. The rising income levels that

followed from the robust economy induced excessive private spending and speculation, and

caused inflation rates to escalate again in the first half of the 1990s.

The Asian Financial Crisis was a turning point for the otherwise healthy Korean economy.

The export success of Korea from the late 1980s led Japanese firms to withdraw key inputs

from the top financial conglomerates „chaebol‟, which eroded Korea‟s export drive. There

was overdependence on the chaebol which were using their profits for speculative rather

than productive investments. By 1998, the chaebol recorded drastically reduced profits and

several went into bankruptcy. By this time South Korea had accumulated foreign debt of

billions of dollars2. GDP and employment growth rates plunged, to negative 2% and 6%,

respectively. The rate of unemployment registered an all-time high of 7%. To prevent the

total collapse of the economy, the government sought an emergency loan from the

International Monetary Fund (IMF). Following the Crisis, there was a series of reforms in

the financial, corporate and labour sectors aimed at promoting sustainable growth, reducing

debt and increasing labour market flexibility. By 1999, the Korean economy had recovered

from the Crisis. GDP rebounded to 9% growth and employment started to show signs of

growth. However, unemployment rates were still relatively high and this presented a

challenge for the government which wanted to reduce unemployment in order to maintain

social stability.

20

2.4 ECONOMIC GROWTH, SECTORAL CHANGES

AND LABOUR MOBILITY

The previous section highlighted that Korea has undergone several phases of boom and

recession in recent times. These have been associated with changes in the importance of

various sectors of the economy. This section illustrates the associations between economic

growth, sectoral changes and labour mobility on a decade-by-decade basis, from 1970 to

2000, with special attention on 1998-2001 to coincide with the period of data collection for

the dataset used in the study of worker mobility in Part II of this thesis. The major

sectors/industries comprise agriculture, mining, manufacturing, utilities, construction,

commerce, transport, storage and communications, financial, business services and real

estate, and community, social and personal services. The classification of these nine

sectors/industries follows that of the empirical study to be undertaken in Part II of this

thesis.

2.4.1 The Three Decades: 1970-2000

The Korean economy at the start of the 1970s was dominated by three sectors: agriculture,

manufacturing and commerce. Together, these sectors contributed more than three-fifths of

total GDP in 1970, with the share of total output for agriculture, manufacturing and

commerce at 29%, 18% and 17%, respectively. At the end of the first decade, as a

consequence of the 1970s oil and food crises, the share of output due to agriculture and

commerce had declined considerably, to 16% and 14%, respectively. Corresponding to

their lower share in total output, the average annual GDP growths of agriculture and

commerce over the first decade were lower, at 22% and 28%, respectively. In comparison,

the share of manufacturing output rose to 24% and the sector experienced a strong average

annual growth of 34% over the decade. The services sector‟s contribution to GDP rose,

especially due to growth in the transport, storage and communications industry (share rose

from 7% to 8%), and the financial, business services and real estate industry (share rose

from 7% to 12%), with the average annual growths at 32% and 36%, respectively. These

high growth rates are reflective of the success of Korea‟s export-oriented policy and the

protectionism in the import sector. Thus, Korea‟s economic growth in the first decade was

associated mainly with strong growth in the manufacturing and services sectors.

21

Table 2.2 GDP by Sector, 1970-2000 1970 1980 1990 2000 1970-1980 1980-1990 1990-2000

% Distribution by Sector Average Annual Growth (%)

Total Gross Value-

Added at Basic Prices1 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 29.9 17.1 11.9 Agriculture 29.2 16.2 8.9 4.9 22.4 10.4 5.3 Mining 1.8 1.9 0.8 0.4 31.2 7.6 3.8 Manufacturing 17.8 24.4 27.3 29.4 34.1 18.4 12.7 Utilities 1.4 2.2 2.1 2.6 36.1 17.0 13.9 Construction 5.1 8.0 11.3 8.4 35.9 21.3 8.5 Commerce 16.8 14.2 13.0 10.8 27.7 16.1 9.8 Transport, Storage &

Communications 6.7 8.0 6.8 7.0 32.2 15.3 12.2 Financial, Business

Services & Real Estate 7.3 11.5 14.9 20.1 35.9 20.3 15.3 Community, Social &

Personal Services 13.9 13.7 14.8 16.5 29.7 18.1 13.1

Source: Korea NSO.

1. Whilst overall GDP comprises gross value-added at basic prices plus taxes less subsidies on products, the

latter does not have a sectoral breakdown. As such, „Total‟ refers to total gross value-added at basic prices. This

facilitates the computation of sectoral contributions.

By the second decade, the adverse effects of the global oil and food crises spilled over to

the agricultural and commerce sector where their shares of output declined to 9% and 13%,

respectively. Reflecting the diversification towards heavy and chemical industries during

the post-Crisis period, manufacturing‟s share of output continued to grow steadily, to 27%.

In the services sector, the contribution to GDP was the result of the increases in the

financial, business services and real estate industry (share rose from 12% to 15%) and

community, social and personal services industry (share rose from 14% to 15%). For the

financial industry, the availability of investment funds made the growth in the industry

possible.

In the third decade, the rising importance of services, particularly financial, business

services and real estate, and community, social and personal services industries, was

evident. The share of GDP increased from 15% to 20% for the former and from 15% to

17% for the latter. The success in the financial, business services and real estate industry

was attributed to financial restructuring and globalization efforts. The manufacturing sector

managed to sustain its high share of 29%, and this was probably due to lower costs

associated with the amalgamation of manufacturing industries in the late 1980s. In

contrast, agriculture‟s share of total output continued to fall, to a meager 5%. The

22

commerce sector also registered a declining share of GDP over the decade, although its

drop in relative importance was not as pronounced as the drop in the rural sector.

In terms of sectoral labour shifts, Korea‟s labour force moved from the rural and services

sectors to the manufacturing, construction and commerce sectors over the first decade. The

share of agricultural employment declined from 50% to 34%, whilst notable increases

occurred in manufacturing (13% to 22%), construction (3% to 6%) and commerce (12% to

19%). The proportion of employment remained fairly stable in the other sectors/industries

over the first decade.

Between 1980 and 1990, the composition of the labour force shifted from agriculture to the

manufacturing, commerce and services sectors. Whilst the employment share continued to

drop in agriculture (34% to 18%), it rose in the manufacturing sector, from 22% to 27%,

and from 19% to 22% in the commerce sector. Each of the services industries also

recorded rising shares of employment during the decade.

By the third decade, the sectoral shifts were mainly in the form of movements from the

agricultural and manufacturing sectors towards the commerce and services sectors. The

first two sectors witnessed proportionate declines in the employment whilst the latter two

experienced increases in their relative employment.

Table 2.3 Employed Persons by Sector, 1970-2000

1970 1980 1990 2000 000s % 000s % 1970-1980 growth 000s % 1980-1990 growth 000s % 1990-2000 growth

Total 9,745 100.0 13,683 100.0 3.5 18,085 100.0 2.8 21,156 100.0 1.6

Agriculture 4,916 50.4 4,654 34.0 -0.5 3,237 17.9 -3.6 2,243 10.6 -3.6

Mining 111 1.1 124 0.9 1.1 79 0.4 -4.4 17 0.1 -14.2

Manufacturing 1,284 13.2 2,955 21.6 8.7 4,911 27.2 5.2 4,293 20.3 -1.3

Utilities 25 0.3 44 0.3 5.8 70 0.4 4.8 64 0.3 -0.9

Construction 284 2.9 843 6.2 11.5 1,346 7.4 4.8 1,580 7.5 1.6

Commerce 1,213 12.4 2,625 19.2 8.0 3,945 21.8 4.2 5,752 27.2 3.8

Transport, Storage &

Communications 350 3.6 619 4.5 5.9 923 5.1 4.1 1,260 6.0 3.2

Financial, Business Services &

Real Estate 0.0 332 2.4 945 5.2 11.0 2,113 10.0 8.4

Community, Social & Personal

Services 1,562 16.0 1,489 10.9 -0.5 2,638 14.6 5.9 3,814 18.0 3.8

Source: ILO LaborStat database. No employment data are available for financial, business services and real estate in 1970.

24

It should be noted that the Table 2.3 data illustrate the net mobility across sectors, and

include the impact of individuals moving from outside the labour market into employment,

and of individuals leaving employment for non-labour market activities. For example,

between 1970 and 1980, there was an increase in employment of 1,671,000 in Korea‟s

manufacturing sector. This is accompanied by employment growth in the mining, utilities,

construction, commerce and services sectors, and a decline in employment in the

agricultural sector. The 1,671,000 people who, on net, joined the manufacturing sector

over this period will generally comprise:

(i) inflows into manufacturing from outside the labour market, Iolm, and from

agriculture (Ia), mining (Im), utilities (Iu), construction (Ict), commerce (Ic) or

services (Is)3;

(ii) outflows from manufacturing to either non-labour market activities, Oolm, or to

work in either agriculture (Oa), mining (Om), utilities (Ou), construction (Oct),

commerce (Oc) or services (Os).

These individual inflows and outflows are the gross flows that combine to generate the net

flows illustrated in Table 2.3.

Hence,

1,671,000 = Inflows – Outflows

= (Iolm + Ia + Im + Iu + Ict + Ic + Is)

- (Oolm + Oa + Om + Ou + Oct + Oc + Os)

Clearly, inflows exceed outflows, and the number of employed persons in the

manufacturing sector has risen. While knowledge of the individual flows would assist

understanding the dynamics of the Korean labour market, the net movements provide a

useful measure of the relative strengths of the various economic sectors.

It can be seen that the growth in the Korean economy not only depends on changes in the

significance of the various sectors but on labour movements between sectors. The data

reveals that the sectoral flows of workers occur in the same direction as that of economic

growth. In the first decade, there was a net movement of labour from the agriculture and

services sectors to the manufacturing4, construction and commerce sectors. The net labour

25

flows were from agriculture to the manufacturing, commerce and services sectors in the

second decade. In the third decade net labour flows occurred mainly from the agricultural

and manufacturing sectors to the commerce and services sectors.

2.4.2 The 1998-2001 period

Throughout 1998-2001, the sectoral shares of GDP (at current prices) and employment

have remained fairly stable. The major contributors to overall GDP have been the

manufacturing sector and financial services industry, with a combined contribution of about

half of the total. In contrast, the mining and utilities sectors contributed a meager share of

less than 5%. In terms of overall employment, whilst the manufacturing remained one of

the largest contributors, and the mining and utilities sectors the lowest, the commerce sector

emerged to have the largest share, displacing the financial industry in this regard.

As compositional changes are not usually obvious within a short span of 4 years, sectoral

changes for 1998-2001 will also be examined using growth data. The earlier section

revealed that the Asian Financial Crisis was associated with a deterioration in both

economic and employment growth, to negative 2% and 6%, respectively, in 1998. Many

sectors recorded declines in GDP, including agriculture, mining, construction and

commerce. Correspondingly, three out of these four sectors with adverse economic

performance experienced declining employment5.

The series of reforms after the Crisis led to rises of 9% in GDP and 2% in employment. All

sectors except mining and construction experienced improvements in economic

performance. In the labour market, it was these two same two sectors, along with the

agricultural sector, where employment failed to recover. The situation in the agricultural

sector probably reflects the continued outflow of surplus labour from the rural to urban

sectors.

Economic recovery continued in 2000, and GDP rose by 8% and employment by 4%. The

growth in performance was seen in all sectors other than construction. Even in the

construction sector, the magnitude of decline slowed considerably, from 7% in 1999 to less

26

than 1% in 2000. Correspondingly, nearly all of the sectors, including construction, had an

increased intake of workers in 2000.

Sustained economic growth was witnessed in 2001, with GDP growing by 6% and

employment by 2%. All sectors other than agriculture and mining displayed positive GDP

growth in 2001. Employment levels increased in all sectors except agriculture,

manufacturing and utilities. The drop in employment in the manufacturing sector reflected

a slowdown in sectoral GDP growth.

In general, a sector‟s significance in employment coincides with its importance in terms of

its value-added contribution. In 1998, many sectors experienced declines in both GDP and

employment. During 1999-2001, with a few exceptions, sectors that had a higher (lower)

GDP growth also had larger (smaller) employment intake for the same year.

Table 2.4 GDP at Current Prices by Sector, 1998-2001 1998 1999 2000 2001 1998 1999 2000 2001

% Distribution by Sector Annual % Growth Total GDP -2.0 8.7 7.6 5.8 Total Gross Value-

Added at Basic Prices 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 0.0 7.8 8.7 7.0 Agriculture 5.1 5.2 4.9 4.5 -6.4 11.0 0.9 -0.9 Mining 0.5 0.4 0.4 0.4 -10.6 -0.8 2.8 -0.8 Manufacturing 27.3 28.1 29.4 27.6 3.9 10.9 13.7 0.3 Utilities 2.3 2.5 2.6 2.7 12.0 19.6 10.6 10.9 Construction 10.6 9.2 8.4 8.6 -13.5 -6.9 -1.0 9.9 Commerce 9.2 10.0 10.8 10.8 -7.4 17.7 17.4 6.5 Transport, Storage &

Communications 7.1 7.0 7.0 7.5 6.1 7.5 8.6 14.0 Financial, Business

Services & Real Estate 21.1 20.8 20.1 20.4 3.2 6.2 5.3 8.9 Community, Social &

Personal Services 16.9 16.7 16.5 17.6 3.0 6.3 7.2 14.3

Source: Korea NSO.

1. Total GDP comprises gross value-added at basic prices plus taxes less subsidies on products.

Table 2.5 Employed Persons by Sector, 1998-2001 1998 1999 2000 2001

000s % Annual

growth

000s % Annual

growth

000s % Annual

growth

000s % Annual

growth

Total 19,938 100.0 -6.0 20,291 100.0 1.8 21,156 100.0 4.3 21,572 100.0 2.0

Agriculture 2,397 12.0 4.9 2,302 11.3 -4.0 2,243 10.6 -2.6 2,148 10.0 -4.2

Mining 20 0.1 -23.1 19 0.1 -5.0 17 0.1 -10.5 18 0.1 5.9

Manufacturing 3,917 19.6 -13.7 4,027 19.8 2.8 4,293 20.3 6.6 4,267 19.8 -0.6

Utilities 61 0.3 -21.8 62 0.3 1.6 64 0.3 3.2 58 0.3 -9.4

Construction 1,580 7.9 -22.1 1,475 7.3 -6.6 1,580 7.5 7.1 1,585 7.3 0.3

Commerce 5,570 27.9 -5.1 5,739 28.3 3.0 5,752 27.2 0.2 5,874 27.2 2.1

Transport, Storage

& Communications 1,162 5.8 -1.0 1,200 5.9 3.3 1,260 6.0 5.0 1,322 6.1 4.9

Financial, Business

Services & Real

Estate 1,864 9.3 -2.9 1,933 9.5 3.7 2,113 10.0 9.3 2,290 10.6 8.4

Community, Social

& Personal

Services 3,347 16.8 1.9 3,520 17.3 5.2 3,814 18.0 8.4 3,995 18.5 4.7

Source: ILO LaborStat database.

28

2.4.3 Possible Structural Break during Asian Financial Crisis

At this stage, it is worth mentioning that the Asian Financial Crisis could give rise to a

structural change in the Korean economy and labour market. Looking at the data trends,

there are reasons to suspect that a structural change occurred around 1998. The Korean

economy had been experiencing double-digit growth in GDP throughout the pre-Crisis

period, but the GDP growth rate suddenly dipped to negative 2% in 1998 immediately after

the Crisis occurred. In the Korean labour market, employment had been growing by about

2-3% since the late 1980s but in 1998, the employment growth rate plunged to negative

6%. Unemployment, which had been at a general low of 2-3% since the late 1980s,

suddenly increased to 7% in 1998, the highest in the past 30 years. These trends provide a

priori justification for tests of a structural break in chapter 5.

2.5 CONCLUDING REMARKS

This chapter has traced the economic history of Korea and illustrated how the success of

this Asian country has been associated with the growth of the various economic sectors and

also how it has been associated with inter-sectoral reallocations of labour. The patterns for

the decades covering 1970-2000, as well as for the more specific 1998-2001 period, were

reviewed. It is concluded that labour (and sectoral) mobility should not be ignored in the

analysis of the different phases of the macroeconomy. Labour market flexibility among

various sectors has emerged as a challenging issue, particularly in explaining the rising

unemployment experienced towards the end of the last decade. This has implications for

labour and macro policy. The following chapters introduce and review the recent research

undertaken in several countries on the relationship between sectoral mobility and

unemployment, and the corresponding factors that affect labour (and sectoral) mobility.

Endnotes:

1. See www.korea.net, the official homepage of the Korean government operated by the Korean Information

Service.

2. Prior to 1997, Korea‟s exchange rate regime was managed or pseudo-fixed [Park, Chung and Wang

(2001)].

3. In this section, the three services industries, as distinguished in Table 2.3, namely Transport, Storage &

Communications, Financial, Business Services & Real Estate, and Community, Social & Personal Services

are treated as a single „services‟ sector.

4. This follows the Lewis surplus model of labour transfer from rural areas to the industrialized sector.

5. The exception is agriculture, which experienced higher employment in 1998.

29

PART I: SECTORAL MOBILITY AND UNEMPLOYMENT

PREAMBLE

Part I, entitled „Sectoral Mobility and Unemployment‟, is about the relationship between

inter-sectoral mobility and aggregate unemployment. It introduces the macroeconomic

problem of unemployment and links it to sectoral labour movements. The discovery of the

mobility-unemployment relationship in the late 1980s led to extensive debate, resulting in

the formation of four hypotheses: sectoral shift hypothesis (SSH), aggregate demand

hypothesis (ADH), reallocation timing hypothesis and stage-of-the-business cycle effect.

Part I contains three chapters. The theoretical exposition of the hypotheses on sectoral

mobility and unemployment is found in chapter 3, which includes discussion of the

methods of hypotheses testing and conceptual differences in terms of the source of

mobility, chain of causation, and nature of the resultant unemployment. The empirical

evidence on the hypotheses in chapter 4 focuses on modelling techniques and specification,

the set of mobility indices and findings from studies across the U.S., Europe and Japan.

Chapters 3 and 4 provide the theoretical and empirical foundation from which empirical

work for Korea can be carried out.

The empirical work is presented in chapter 5, where the model is first constructed and then

used to test the four hypotheses in the Korean labour market. The model is subjected to

rigorous econometric procedures involving tests of structural change, collinearity and serial

correlation. The tests for structural change reveal a structural break between the pre- and

post-Crisis (1998-2001) periods. The key findings show a lack of support for the SSH,

ADH and stage-of-the-business-cycle effect for Korea in the pre-Crisis period. For the

post-Crisis period, the empirical results favour the SSH, ADH and stage-of-the-business-

cycle effect, but data limitations prevent the formation of firm conclusions. Nonetheless,

the tentative support for the hypotheses reveals the potential for mobility to be used as a

tool for reducing unemployment, giving rise to the need for an in-depth study of the

determinants of sectoral mobility for Korea. Part I concludes by linking the research on the

impact of mobility with work undertaken on the determinants of sectoral mobility in Part II.

30

31

CHAPTER 3

THEORETICAL HYPOTHESES CONCERNING

SECTORAL MOBILITY AND UNEMPLOYMENT

3.1 INTRODUCTION

Sectoral mobility is an important feature of labour markets across the world. It is also a

phenomenon that has entered most major macroeconomic debates on unemployment, with

numerous studies having examined or questioned its influence on this economic outcome1.

This chapter presents a review of the ways that sectoral mobility has been advanced as a

potential contributor to unemployment.

In a seminal paper, Lilien (1982) introduced the importance of sectoral mobility in

explaining unemployment for the U.S. economy. Using a sectoral shift measure of

employment dispersion, it was shown that nearly half of the rise in aggregate

unemployment during 1948-1980 was attributable to sectoral mobility. This association of

sectoral mobility with unemployment formed the basis for the Sectoral Shift Hypothesis

(SSH). The Aggregate Demand Hypothesis (ADH), introduced by Abraham and Katz

(1986), challenges the SSH, and associates unemployment with aggregate demand

fluctuations, claiming that the sectoral shift measure picks up effects of aggregate demand

rather than inter-industry disturbances. In comparison, the Reallocation Timing Hypothesis

(RTH), mooted by Davis (1987), acknowledges the role of sectoral shifts in explaining

fluctuations in unemployment but argues that sectoral movements are reinforced by past

patterns of labour reallocation and their impact influenced by the stages of the business

cycle (termed as stage-of-the-business-cycle effect). Whilst the SSH and ADH have

triggered a series of debates, the RTH and stage-of-the-business-cycle effect have not

warranted much attention in the literature, apart from the sporadic work of Davis (1987) for

the former and Mills, Pelloni and Zervoyianni (1995) for the latter.

This chapter forms the start of Part I of this thesis, which analyses the relationship between

sectoral mobility and unemployment. It provides a theoretical exposition of the hypotheses

introduced above. The following chapter, chapter 4, supplements this theory with empirical

evidence. Chapter 5 then extends the application to Korea. Chapter 3 proceeds in the

32

following manner. Sections 3.2 to 3.5 outline, in some detail, each hypothesis. The

conceptual and methodological differences between the hypotheses are presented in

sections 3.6 and 3.7. It is shown that there is an array of mobility indices that can be used

to test each hypothesis. Consequently, an attempt is made in section 3.8 to narrow the

range of suitable indices. A summary of these issues is given in section 3.9.

3.2 THE SECTORAL SHIFT HYPOTHESIS

3.2.1 Impact of Sectoral Mobility on Aggregate Unemployment

The SSH asserts a causal role for sectoral mobility in accounting for variations in aggregate

unemployment. This form of mobility can represent pure sectoral shifts and/or sectoral

reallocations arising from a supply-side disturbance that results in more labour being

allocated to some sectors and less to others [Parker (1992)].

Pure sectoral shifts originate from changes in individuals‟ tastes/preferences, desire for

higher wages, non-pecuniary benefits etc., and can occur during periods of stable aggregate

conditions. Frictional unemployment results from pure sectoral shifts as labour markets are

imperfect and labour is not instantaneously responsive [Lilien (1982) and Parker (1992)],

i.e. it takes time for workers to find suitable jobs and employers to find the right employees.

Supply disturbances to the economy can also induce sectoral mobility [Prasad (1997)].

These include changes in technology, oil prices, import competition and war, where

declining sectors reduce their employment requirements and expanding ones increase their

employment intake. Workers from declining sectors may be slow in responding to the

shifts in employment demand owing to industrial attachments, and this can result in higher

aggregate unemployment. At some point, the rise in employment in expanding sectors may

not offset the falling levels in declining sectors. At the aggregate-level, unemployment

increases. The resultant unemployment is regarded as structural.

A proxy statistic to represent the magnitude of sectoral movements was devised by Lilien

(1982), and has been labelled the „raw Lilien index‟ by subsequent authors. It is the

33

weighted standard deviation of the cross-sectoral employment growth rates, expressed

mathematically in the following equation:

N

ζt = [ ∑ (eit / Et)(Δ log (eit ) - Δ log (Et ))2]

½ (3.1)

i =1

where eit is employment in sector i, i = 1,.. , N, in period t and Et is aggregate employment

in period t. The term (eit/Et) is the ith

sector‟s share of total employment at time t, while Δ

log (eit ) and Δ log (Et) represent the rates of growth of employment in sector i and in the

aggregate economy, respectively.

Lilien (1982) computed the raw index over 11 sectors in the U.S., and used this as an

explanatory variable in the following model of the aggregate rate of unemployment in

period t, Ut:

J

Ut = βo + β1 ζt - ∑ β2j DMRt-j + β3 Ut-1 + β4 T + εt (3.2) j =0

where DMRt-j is unanticipated money growth, Ut-1 is the unemployment rate in the

preceding period, T is a time trend variable, εt is the stochastic disturbance term and J

denotes the number of lags for the unanticipated money growth term. The unanticipated

money growth term (DMR) was introduced by Barro (1977), and is the residual of the

following money growth equation:

DMt = α0 + α1DMt-1 + α2DMt-2 + α3FEDVt + α4UNt-1 + DMRt (3.3)

where DMt = log Mt - log Mt-1 is the annual average money growth (of M1) and

UNt-1 = log [U/(1-U)]t-1, where U is the average annual unemployment rate. FEDVt is the

difference between real and normal government expenditure. FEDVt ≡ log (FED)t – [log

(FED)]*t where FED is real government expenditure and [log (FED)]*t refers to the normal

value of this expenditure. Empirically, [log (FED)]*t can be generated from the adaptive

formula: [log (FED)]*t = ρ [log (FED)]t + (1-ρ) [log (FED)]*t-1 with ρ being the adaptive

coefficient. DMR is the difference between the observed DM and the DM predicted from

the regression equation.

34

The results from estimating equation (3.2) showed that nearly half of the unemployment in

the U.S. during the post-war 1948-1980 period was accounted for by sectoral mobility.

This effect was more substantial than that of the unanticipated monetary growth. Lilien

(1982) interpreted the positive ζ-U correlation as evidence that much of aggregate

unemployment is attributed to the process of sectoral labour reallocation.

3.2.2 SSH and Supply Shocks

Supply shocks are argued to lead to sectoral mobility in the SSH and this argument has

been formalized by Loungani (1986) and Mills, Pelloni and Zervoyianni (1995). Loungani

(1986) suggests that it was dramatic oil price shocks requiring an unusually high amount of

labour to be reallocated across industries that increased the unemployment rate in the

1970s. The point of departure for this theory is the representation of sectoral employment

growth. Sectoral employment growth (eit) was decomposed by Loungani (1986) as:

eit = β0Xt + β1Zt + Sit (3.4)

where Xt is a matrix of current and lagged aggregate-level variables, Zt is an unobserved

aggregate shock orthogonal to X and Sit is the residual sectoral component of employment

growth. The residual sectoral components were assumed to have an AR structure:

Sit = ρ1Sit-1 + ρ2Sit-2 + … ρjSit-j + εit (3.5)

The raw Lilien index computed across N sectors was altered to:

N

ζt = [ ∑ (ei /E) (εit)2 / ωt ]

½ (3.6)

i =1

where εit is the residual for each industry i obtained from the regression of equation (3.5).

Each industry‟s residual is weighted by (ei/E), the industry i‟s share of total employment.

Note that there is no time subscript for the term (ei/E) as it refers to a specific time period,

i.e. 1969 in Loungani‟s (1986) case. The denominator, ωt, is the variance over time of an

T

industry‟s residual and can be written as: ωt = ∑ (εit)2 / T where T is the length of the

t =1

35

sample period. Compared to the raw Lilien index in equation (3.1), the difference lies

in this denominator, which denotes the variance over time of an industry‟s residual.

This representation of sectoral employment growth has been modified to reflect the

characteristics of specific supply-side shocks. For example, to construct the Lilien index

generated by oil price shocks, the sectoral employment growth in equation (3.4) can be re-

written as:

eit = β0Xt + β1Pt + β2Zt + Rit (3.7)

where Pt is a matrix of current and lagged changes in oil prices and Rit is the residual

component of sectoral employment growth which is assumed to have an AR structure:

Rit = ρ*1Rit-1 + ρ*2Rit-2 + … ρ*jRit-j + εit (3.8)

for j number of lags. Whilst equation (3.5) captures the residual sectoral component of

employment growth which can include oil price shocks, equation (3.8) is the residual

component of sectoral employment growth that is independent of aggregate demand and oil

price shocks.

Equations (3.7) and (3.8) can then be used to construct the mobility index brought about by

oil price shocks:

N ζt(s) = { ∑ (ei /E) / [(βi – β) Pt ]

2 }

½ (3.9)

i =1

N

where β = ∑ (ei /E) βi with βi being the estimated coefficient of the oil price variable from i =1

the ith

sector‟s regression. The mobility index capturing the effects of the residual (r)

reallocative shocks in period t, ζt(r), that is purged of aggregate demand and supply

influences, is expressed as:

N

ζt(r) = [ ∑ (ei /E) (εit)2 / σt ]

½ (3.10)

i =1

T

where σt = ∑ (εit)2 / T.

i =1

36

Mills, Pelloni and Zervoyianni (1995) purged the raw Lilien index of aggregate supply

influences [change in the logarithm of energy prices (ΔEP) ] by regressing (Δeit - ΔEt ) on

the current and four-period lagged values of ΔEP and (ΔEP)2, respectively, to obtain the

residual series εp1

it and εp2

it. The pure indices purged of ΔEP and (ΔEP)2

can be expressed

as:

N

ζp1

t(up) = [ ∑ (eit / Et) (εp1

it )2]

½ (3.11a)

i =1

N

ζp2

t(up) = [ ∑ (eit / Et) (εp2

it )2]

½ (3.11b)

i =1

The index caused by supply shocks as per equation (3.9), that which is purged of demand

and supply influences as per equation (3.10), and the indices purged of supply influences

from equations (3.11a) and (3.11b) are alternatives to the raw index. Evidence for the SSH

requires these indices to have a positive and significant effect on aggregate unemployment.

3.2.3 SSH and the Natural Unemployment Rate

The SSH emphasizes the role of natural unemployment, which consists of frictional and

structural unemployment. It can be affected by a structural change, e.g. supply shock

where sectoral labour reallocations impact the structural rate, or via pure sectoral shifts

resulting in frictional unemployment2.

The logic of the links between the SSH and the natural rate stems from the view that

aggregate unemployment in the current period t evolves from Ut-1 and the differential

between separations (St) and hires (Ht) in the current period [Palley (1992)]. The

assumptions are that separations depend on the extent of demand shifts between sectors: St

= S(ζt), whilst hires are a constant proportion (k > 0) of Ut-1. The natural (or equilibrium)

unemployment rate is therefore U* = S(ζe)/k, where ζ

e is the expected dispersion of

sectoral demand shocks. If actual ζ exceeds ζe, then an increase in sectoral demand

dispersion arising from a supply shock can cause an increase in the natural unemployment

rate above the expected U*.

37

Lilien (1982) estimated the natural unemployment rate from the results of the regression of

aggregate unemployment as per equation (3.2). The natural unemployment rate in the

current period t, U*t, was expressed as a function of sectoral movements in the preceding

periods and a time trend variable, T:

U*t = ∑ βj2 (β0 + β1ζt-j + β3Tt-j) (3.12)

j=0

where β0, β1, β2 and β3 are the parameter estimates for the constant term, ζt-j, Ut-1 and Tt-j,

respectively.

The U* series is not time invariant and it has changed considerably over 1949-1980. The

correlation coefficient between actual U and U* for this period was 0.74. Since Ut and U*t

both trended upwards during the post-war period, U* might be detrended by replacing T in

equation (3.12) with its average value over the period. Since the trend term is assumed to

capture demographic components of the labour market, the detrended measure would

probably more closely reflect changes owing to pure sectoral movements. The correlation

coefficient between U and the detrended U* was 0.60.

As the unemployment rate (U) is quite highly correlated with the natural rate, and given

that U is influenced by sectoral mobility (ζ), it is expected that sectoral mobility would be a

significant explanatory variable for U*t as well. This provides the foundations of the

SSH‟s recognition of the role of the natural unemployment rate. Several studies have

examined the role of the natural unemployment rate from unemployment models, including

Loungani (1986), Mills, Pelloni and Zervoyianni (1995), Parker (1992) and Samson (1985).

There have been numerous studies examining the credibility of the SSH across a range of

countries. These include Parker (1992), Palley (1992), Brainard and Cutler (1993),

Loungani and Rogerson (1989), Davis (1987), Mills, Pelloni and Zervoyianni (1995),

Loungani (1986), Murphy and Topel (1987a) and Lu (1996) for the U.S., Neelin (1987) and

Samson (1985) for Canada, Saint-Paul (1997) for France, Garonna and Sica (1997, 2000)

for Italy and Prasad (1997) for Japan. The majority of these studies focus on the impact of

sectoral mobility on aggregate unemployment, using unemployment models along the lines

of equation (3.2).

38

However, there appears to be a dearth of studies analyzing the origins of mobility,

particularly supply-side shocks generating sectoral mobility. Davis (1987) used a dummy

variable for periods before and after 1974 to capture the effects of the oil price shock on

unemployment. Brainard and Cutler (1993) regressed oil prices on unemployment. The

coefficient of the dummy variable was significant and positive in Davis (1987), but oil

prices were insignificant in Brainard and Cutler (1993). Although both studies analysed the

effects of a supply-side shock, their limitation is that the impact of a supply-side shock on

mobility is not captured. The exceptions are the unpredicted indices constructed by

Loungani (1986) in equations (3.9) and by Mills, Pelloni and Zervoyianni (1995) in

equations (3.11a) and (3.11b) which cater to analyzing the influence of supply shocks on

mobility.

3.3 AGGREGATE DEMAND HYPOTHESIS

The ADH, advanced by Abraham and Katz (1986), presents a case for aggregate demand

disturbances in explaining unemployment and questions the causal role of sectoral mobility.

Two lines of argument against the SSH were presented, the first being based on the

unemployment and vacancies (U-V) relationship and the second involving the ζ-U co-

movement approach.

3.3.1 U-V Relationship

The central piece of evidence against the SSH involved the U-V relationship. Under pure

sectoral shifts (independent of aggregate disturbances), sectoral mobility produces a

positive ζ-U correlation. This is because such changes to the structural economy will cause

the U-V curve to shift inwards (outwards) and thereby increase (decrease) the job matching

rate. The declining (increasing) inter-sector labour movements are a likely reason for the

inward (outward) shift of the U-V curve. The result is that a decline (rise) in

unemployment caused purely by sectoral labour shifts will be accompanied by a drop (rise)

in job vacancies. In other words, the measured relationship between U and V will be

positive. If the SSH correctly reflects why ζ and U are positively related, then ζ and V

should be positively related as well.

39

Abraham and Katz (1986) contended, however, that the positive ζ-U association generates

a negative ζ-V relationship. A positive (negative) AD shock, for example, that leads to

lower (higher) unemployment results in an increase (decrease) in job vacancies. This can

be construed as a movement along the Beveridge curve which posits a negative U-V

relation in response to aggregate shocks [Blanchard and Diamond (1989)].

To test the U-V argument, the Conference Board‟s3 help-wanted index was used as a proxy

for job vacancies. A normalized help-wanted index (NHWI) was constructed using the

employment weighted average of the number of help-wanted advertisements in 51

metropolitan newspapers and dividing the result by total non-agricultural payroll

employment. A negative U-V relationship was plotted for the U.S. for 1949-1980.

Abraham and Katz (1986) regressed unemployment and job vacancies (the NHWI) on ζt in

the equations below.

Ut = αo + α1 ζt + α2 ζt-1 + α3DMRt + α4DMRt-1 + α5DMRt-2 + α6Ut-1 + α7T + ut (3.13)

NHWIt = αo + α1ζt + α2 ζt-1 + α3DMRt + α4DMRt-1 + α5DMRt-2

+ α6NHWIt-1 + α7T + ut (3.14)

It was found that ζt had a positive impact on U for equation (3.13) but a negative effect on

NHWI for equation (3.14). These co-movements of ζt, U and V provided support for the

ADH. To further validate the ADH, the above regressions [equations (3.13) and (3.14)]

were extended to the U.K. using vacancy data over 1961-1981. The resulting positive ζ-U

and negative ζ-V correlations for Britain provided further support for the ADH.

A few studies have validated the ADH from this perspective, but they only focus on the ζ-

V portion of the U-V argument. Among these are Davis (1987), Brainard and Cutler

(1993) and Palley (1992) for U.S., and Edin and Holmlund (1997) for Sweden. The reason

for the limited number of studies is possibly that there is a lack of data available for

vacancies [Garonna and Sica (2000)] and because the suitability of the NHWI as a proxy

for the job vacancy rate has been questioned [Watcher (1987), Shin (1997a) and Zagosky

(1990)].

40

3.3.2 The σ-U Co-movement Approach

The second line of argument against the SSH was that aggregate demand disturbances

alone generate positive ζ-U co-movements. This argument thus suggests that an adverse

(positive) shock would reduce (increase) employment by a larger magnitude in industries

with an already low (higher) employment growth, thereby enlarging the employment gap

across industries and fostering a positive ζ-U relationship. From this perspective,

unemployment fluctuations could be explained by economy-wide fluctuations and a fall in

aggregate demand. The assumption is that sectors have different cyclical sensitivities in

employment growth [Abraham and Katz (1986), Lu (1996) and Garonna and Sica (2000)]

and are negatively correlated in the trend rate of growth and responsiveness of employment

to cyclical fluctuations. Abraham and Katz (1986) argued that, in comparison, with pure

sectoral shifts all sectors were assumed to have the same trend rate of growth and not to

differ in their sensitivity to cyclical fluctuations. To illustrate, let:

ln e1t = δ + η1T + γ1(ln Yt - ln Y*t) (3.15)

ln e2t = δ + η2T + γ2(ln Yt - ln Y*t) (3.16)

where e1t and e2t are employment in sector 1 and sector 2, respectively, T is a time trend, Yt

is actual GNP, and Y*t is trend GNP. Assume η1 > η2 (sector 1‟s employment grows at a

more rapid trend rate than sector 2‟s employment) and γ1 < γ2 (sector 1‟s employment is

less cyclically responsive than sector 2‟s employment). If it is assumed that the two sectors

start out equal in size, Abraham and Katz (1986) show that the sectoral mobility index for

the two sectors can be approximated as:

ζt = ½ | (η1 - η2 ) + ½ (γ 1 - γ 2 ) ( Δ ln Yt - Δ ln Y*t )| (3.17)

If Ut bears an Okun‟s law relationship4 to the percentage deviation of GNP from its trend,

then as shown by the same authors, unemployment can be expressed as:

Ut = ω + ζ (ln Yt - ln Y*t) (3.18)

41

where ζ < 0. From equation (3.18), unemployment rises during a downturn (actual GNP

growth falls below the trend growth) and falls during an upturn. It can be seen from

equation (3.17) that ζt will rise and fall during a downturn and upturn, respectively. It

follows that ζt and ∆Ut can be positively correlated when their movements are induced by

fluctuations in aggregate demand. The existence of a negative correlation between the

industrial trend rates of growth and their cyclical sensitivities is sufficient to produce a

positive correlation between ζt and ∆Ut.

Empirically, Abraham and Katz (1986) showed, using annual data for 11 major sectors for

the same 1949-1980 period as the Lilien (1982) study5, that AD fluctuations appeared to

generate a positive ζ-U correlation in postwar U.S. First, it was shown, using the

estimating equations below, that there was a positive correlation between ζt and ∆Ut.

Δln eit = δ0i +η2iT + δ1i(Δln Yt - Δln Y*t) + δ2i(Δln Yt-1 - Δln Y*t-1) + εit (3.19)

where eit is the employment in sector i at time t, T is a time trend, Yt is the GNPt series6, ln

Y*t is the trend value of ln (GNP) and the η‟s and δ‟s are the parameters to be estimated.

The lagged term (Δln Yt-1 - Δln Y*t-1) was included to assess if deviations from trend GNP

in the past period would have affected sectoral employment growth. The correlation

between d(ln eit)/dt and the sum of the δ coefficients from the above OLS regression was

-0.571. That is, there was a strong negative correlation between the industries‟ trend

growth rates and their responsiveness in employment to cyclical fluctuations. This

satisfies the condition of a positive ζt-∆Ut relationship as outlined in the paragraph above.

Furthermore, using annual U.S. data for 1949-1980, it was found that ∆Ut and Ut were

positively associated. Thus, an aggregate demand-induced positive correlation between ζt

and ∆Ut could, through a positive association between ∆Ut and Ut, produce a positive ζt-Ut

relation.

There are a number of studies testing the validity of the ADH against the SSH using this ζ-

U co-movement approach by purging the raw Lilien index of aggregate demand

disturbances and applying it as a regressor in aggregate unemployment equations. The

studies include Lu (1996), Palley (1992) and Mills, Pelloni and Zervoyianni (1995) for the

42

U.S., Neelin (1987) for Canada and Garonna and Sica (2000) for Italy. Several techniques

of purging the indices are described below.

3.4 PREDICTED AND UNPREDICTED MOBILITY INDICES

The mobility index has been decomposed into two components in some studies that

examine the ADH. These are: (i) the „unpredicted index‟, which is an index that is purged

of aggregate demand disturbances so that it is indicative of pure sectoral shifts; and (ii) the

„predicted index‟, which is an index that accounts for sectoral mobility generated solely by

shocks to aggregate demand. Variations of these predicted and unpredicted indices have

been proposed. Hence DMR has been used as a proxy for aggregate demand to purge the

raw index of AD disturbances and construct the predicted/unpredicted indices by Garonna

and Sica (2000) and Neelin (1987). Aggregate employment has been used for this purpose

by Lu (1996) and Palley (1992), and DME (anticipated money growth), and DMR and the

ratio of the government deficit to nominal GNP (g) by Mills, Pelloni and Zervoyianni

(1995).

Garonna and Sica‟s (2000) method involves the following steps7.

1. The predicted values of the growth rates in sectoral and total employment are estimated

using the regression equations below.

log eit – log eit-1 = β0 + β1DMRt + β2DMRt-1 + β3T + εit (3.20)

log Et – log Et-1 = β0 + β1DMRt + β2DMRt-1 + β3T + εt (3.21)

where DMR, the unanticipated money growth, is a proxy for swings in aggregate

demand and a one period lag is applied for this variable. The time trend (T) captures

demographic and other changes in the labour market. Since DMR may not capture all of

the aggregate influences on the sectoral employment growth rate, Abraham and Katz

(1986) suggested using the employment weighted average residuals as an independent

variable. Thus, the estimated equations are as follows:

43

log eit – log eit-1 = β0 + β1DMRt + β2DMRt-1 + β3T + β4AvgRest + uit (3.22)

log Et – log Et-1 = β0 + β1DMRt + β2DMRt-1 + β3T + β4AvgRest + ut (3.23)

where AvgRest is the weighted average of the residuals from the estimated regressions

for each sector. The shares of each sector in the total employment are utilized as

weights when forming AvgRest.

Neelin (1987) developed the predicted and unpredicted indices along similar lines as

Garonna and Sica (2000)8. Since quarterly data for Canada are used, equations (3.20) and

(3.21), and the subsequent equations (3.22) and (3.23), were estimated using four time lags

of DMR, compared to the one period lag in Garonna and Sica (2000), where annual data

were used for Italy.

2. In the Garonna and Sica (2000) and Neelin (1987) studies, the fitted growth rates in

sectoral and total employment are obtained from the estimated versions of equations

(3.22) and (3.23), along with the residuals where:

(log (eit) – log (eit-1))a = (log (eit) – log (eit-1))

f + uit

(log (Et) – log (Et-1))a = (log (Et) – log (Et-1))

f + ut

where the fitted and actual growth rates are superscripted with „f‟ and „a‟, respectively.

3. Using the fitted employment growth rates, the predicted index is calculated as:

N

ζt(p) = {∑ (eit / Et) [(log (eit) – log (eit-1))f – (log (Et) – log (Et-1))

f]

2 }

½ (3.24)

i =1

and this index captures the effects of swings in aggregate demand on sectoral mobility.

The unpredicted index, which captures the impact of sector-specific shocks on sectoral

mobility, is computed as:

N

ζt(up) = [∑ (eit / Et) (uit – ut )2]

½ (3.25)

i =1

44

Lu (1996) purged the mobility index of aggregate employment growth and estimated it as

follows:

N

ζa1

t(up) = [∑(eit / Et) ( εit - εt )2]

½ (3.26)

i =1

where εit is the residual of the following regression of the ith

sector‟s growth rate:

J

(log eit – log eit-1) = β0 + ∑ βj Et-j,gr + εit

j = 0

where J is the total number of lags, Et-j,gr is the aggregate employment growth rate, and εt is

the employment-weighted sum of all industries‟ residual employment growth.

Palley (1992) introduced two types of indices: one that was attributable to sector-specific

and sectoral shift factors and another attributable to aggregate factors. The methodology

consisted of estimating the ith

sector‟s regression as follows:

J J

ln(eit - eit-1) = β0 + β1T + ∑β2i,t-j ln(eit-j – eit-j-1) + ∑β3,t-j [ln(Et-j – eit-j) – ln(Et-j-1 – eit-j-1)] + εit j=1 j=0

with T as the trend variable, E as the aggregate growth rate in employment of all industries

except sector i, eit as sector i‟s employment growth in period t for a total of j = 0…J lags,

and εit as the residual term.

The next step involved decomposing the above estimated regression as follows:

J

Zit = βo + β1T + ∑ β2i,t-j ln (eit-j – eit-j-1) + εit (3.27) j=1 J

Yit = ∑ β3,t-j [ln (Et-j – eit-j) – ln (Et-j-1 – eit-j-1)] (3.28) j=0

Zit and Yit are computed using estimates from the ith

sector‟s regression above. Zit depicts

changes in employment in sector i between the current and lagged period as well as

changes in sectoral shift factors. Yit represents the difference between the deviation of

sector i‟s employment from aggregate employment in the current period t and the same

deviation in the past period. In other words, Zit is the component attributed to sectoral

disturbances whereas Yit is that which is attributed to aggregate influences.

45

The mobility index depicting the dispersion in sectoral employment growth attributable to

sectoral factors was estimated as9:

N

ζa2

t(up) = [∑ (eit / Et) (Zit - Zt )2]

½ (3.29)

i=1

N

where Zt = ∑ Zit. i=1

The predicted index which reflected the dispersion in sectoral employment growth rates

attributable to aggregate influences, was computed as:

N

ζa2

t(p) = [∑ ( eit / Et ) ( Yit - Yt )2]

½ (3.30)

i =1

N

where Yt = ∑ ( eit / Et ) Yit. i =1

Mills, Pelloni and Zervoyianni (1995) purged the index separately of DME, DMR and g by

regressing Δeit - ΔEt on the current and four-period lagged values of:

a) DMEt and DMRt to obtain the residual series εm

it, and

b) g to obtain the residual series εgit.

The unpredicted indices purged of monetary shocks and government deficits were then

each constructed as follows:

N

ζm

t(up) = [ ∑ (eit / Et)(εm

it )2]

½ (3.31)

i =1

N

ζgt(up) = [ ∑ (eit / Et)(ε

git )

2] ½

(3.32) i =1

The unpredicted and predicted indices are used to test the SSH and ADH, respectively. A

positive predicted ζ-U correlation renders support for the ADH. A positive relationship

between the unpredicted indices and unemployment provides evidence for the SSH10

.

46

3.5 THE REALLOCATION TIMING HYPOTHESIS

AND STAGE-OF-THE-BUSINESS-CYCLE EFFECT

3.5.1 The Reallocation Timing Hypothesis

The Reallocation Timing Hypothesis (RTH) is a branch of the SSH [see Davis (1987),

Mills, Pelloni and Zervoyianni (1995) and Oi (1987)]. It recognizes the role of pure

mobility shifts on unemployment but with emphasis on past patterns of labour reallocation.

Long term attachment to specific sectors, e.g. sector-specific human capital, information

mismatch between employer and employee, lump-sum sector-switching costs and sectoral

wage differentials, can either impede or speed up the influence of mobility. An

unfavourable shock displacing workers in the current period and reinforced by past patterns

of long term attachment to sectors may cause even higher unemployment as the reallocation

of workers to find jobs in other sectors is time-consuming and costly under unfavourable

labour market conditions. A favourable shock inducing workers to change sectors also

leads to unemployment but the magnitude of the increase is asserted to be relatively smaller

than that of an unfavourable shock. This arises because of abundant job opportunities and

reduced sector-switching costs. Since the RTH is grounded on the foundations of the SSH,

the underlying implications stated above (see section 3.2) still apply.

The RTH has been tested using alternative methods. First, Davis (1987) introduced a

horizon covariance cross-sectional measure of labour mobility for sector i, to take into

account past patterns of labour reallocation. It can be calculated as:

N

ζH

t,j = ∑ (eit / Et) [Δ1 log (eit) - Δ1 log (Et)] [Δj log (ei,t-1) - Δj log (Et-1)] (3.33) i =1

for j = 1, 2, …J periods. ζH

t,j indexes the time t direction of labour reallocation over a one-

period horizon relative to the t-1 direction over a j-period horizon. The terms Δ1 and Δj

each denote the first difference operators for the current and jth

periods. For example,

for the j = 1 period, [Δ1log (eit) - Δ1log (Et)] = [log (eit) - log (ei,t-1)] - [log (Et) - log (Et-1)].

For j = 2 (previous period), [Δ2 log (eit) - Δ2 log (Et)] = [log (ei,t-1) - log (ei,t-2)] –

[log (Et-1) - log (Et-2)]. This index provides a workable method of conditioning on past

patterns of labour reallocation in time-series data. Relatively large (small) values for ζH

t-1,

47

ζH

t-2,. indicate that the time t direction of labour reallocation reinforces (reverses) past

patterns of labour reallocation. Reinforcement (reversal) of recent past patterns of labour

reallocation exacerbates (mitigates) skill, location, and informational mismatches between

workers. Davis (1987) estimated the impact of the horizon covariance index using the

following specification of the unemployment equation:

J J J

Ut = βo + β1 DUM74 + ∑β2 ζt + ∑ β3jζH

t-j + ∑ β4j DMEt-j + j=0 j=0 j=0 J

∑ β5j DMRt-j + β6 µt-1 + β7 µt-2 + εt (3.34) j=0

where DUM74 is a dummy variable that equals zero prior to 1974 and one thereafter and

DME is the anticipated money supply growth rate. The error terms, β6µt-1 + β7µt-2 + εt,

follow an AR(2) process. A positive impact for the horizon covariance index on

unemployment was to be interpreted as evidence in favour of the RTH.

The alternative method by Davis (1987) is based on estimating the contemporaneous

correlations between labour reallocation measures and proxies for monetary compensation

and finished goods. According to the RTH, labour mobility and turnover are substitutable

over time. Labour mobility involves unemployment and other forms of foregone

production, which implies that movements in the value of foregone production across

sectors are negatively correlated with unemployment and the pace of labour reallocation.

The two monetary compensation proxies for the cross-sectoral average value of foregone

production are log [compensation index/producer price index (PPI)] and log [compensation

index/consumer price index (CPI)]11

. As these are broad-based measures to proxy for the

average value of foregone production across sectors, they are termed by Davis (1987) as

„cross-sectoral‟.

The deficiencies associated with the monetary compensation measures include the

difficulty in estimating the number of effective hours worked for workers, and the fact that

real wages (under long-term contracts) need not follow short-term movements in the

marginal product of labour. Two alternative proxies based on finished goods were also

adopted, namely, log (manufacturing finished goods inventory at constant prices) and log

(constant prices inventory/manufacturing sales). These are based on the argument that high

48

finished goods inventory levels indicate a lower level of foregone production which triggers

layoffs. Hence, a positive correlation between the finished goods proxies and labour

reallocation should result.

Davis (1987) tested this by letting the raw Lilien index series and the simulated

unemployment series represent the labour reallocation measures. The simulated series is

estimated as per equation (3.34) but without the ζH

t-j component, and with the raw Lilien

index taking its sample values and fixing other regressors in the equation at their sample

means. The proxies of the cross-sectoral average values of monetary compensation and

foregone production discussed above were adopted. A negative correlation between labour

reallocation and the monetary compensation measures and a positive one for the finished

goods were argued to be indicative of confirmation of the fundamental prediction of the

RTH.

3.5.2 The Stage-of-the-Business-Cycle Effect

Whilst the SSH is independent of aggregate economic conditions, the stage-of-the-

business-cycle effect stresses their role in explaining unemployment conditions. During a

recession, there is a tendency for unemployment spells to lengthen and so shocks inducing

sectoral mobility will therefore lead to higher unemployment. Conversely, during an

upturn, unemployment spells tend to be shorter. Consequently, a given rise in sectoral

mobility should result in a smaller increase in unemployment during upturns compared to

downturns. The stage-of-the-business-cycle effect asserts that although the direction of the

ζ-U relation is the same under the SSH and RTH, the magnitude of the increase in

unemployment will be higher during recessions than during boom periods.

The method of testing this type of asymmetric effect involves constructing a multiplicative

interaction variable and testing its effect on unemployment. In Mills, Pelloni and

Zervoyianni (1995), it was the product of the dispersion index, ζt, and S (where S takes

value one when real GNP is below its trend value and 0 otherwise). In Davis (1987), the

interaction variable was the product of RECESS (number of months to recession during the

quarter divided by three) and βζ (where β is the estimated coefficient of ζ). A positive

49

effect of ζt and these interaction variables was to be interpreted as evidence of the stage-of-

the-business-cycle effect.

3.6 CONCEPTUAL DIFFERENCES BETWEEN THE SSH, ADH AND RTH

3.6.1 Source of Sectoral Mobility

Some conceptual differences relating to the role/impact of sectoral mobility on

unemployment are established in this section. Although all hypotheses postulate a positive

ζ-U relationship, there is a difference in the acknowledgement of sectoral mobility as the

cause of unemployment. Whilst the SSH and RTH play up its significance, the ADH

excludes the possibility of this. This difference stems from the source of a sectoral shift. In

the SSH, the shifts are independent of aggregate demand disturbances and can be either

“pure” shifts arising from changes in worker characteristics and sectoral earnings

differentials, or sectoral mobility shifts arising from a supply-side disturbance. In the

ADH, the shifts are derived from pure shocks to aggregate demand, meaning that mobility

is a by-product of an aggregate demand disturbance. Whilst the ADH is based on factors

affecting the macro economy, the SSH has microeconomic foundations. The RTH marries

the two approaches. It is dependent on aggregate economic fluctuations, but it is these

macroeconomic conditions that influence the microeconomic behaviour of individuals.

3.6.2 Chain of Causation

The chain of causation between ζ and U differs between the hypotheses. Whilst it is

sectoral mobility that induces a recession (unemployment) in the SSH and RTH, it is a

recession (generated by an AD disturbance) that causes sectoral movements (which then

lead to unemployment) in the ADH. Although the RTH depends on the stage-of-the-

business-cycle, since past mobility behaviour governs current behaviour, sectoral mobility

is acknowledged as an integral factor generating unemployment. In other words, whilst the

primary cause of unemployment in the SSH and RTH is sectoral mobility, in the ADH it is

the AD disturbance itself.

50

3.6.3 Nature of Unemployment

There is a difference as to how the significance of the components of aggregate

unemployment is perceived amongst the hypotheses. The SSH argues that it is natural

unemployment arising from sectoral movements that causes aggregate unemployment

levels to rise. According to Lilien (1982), “much of the cyclical unemployment is better

described as fluctuations of the natural rate itself”. In contrast, the ADH asserts the role of

cyclical unemployment, since it can be viewed as a form of demand-deficient

unemployment. A negative demand shock would result in cyclical unemployment. The

RTH, however, does not explicitly indicate the nature of the unemployment generated.

3.7 METHODOLOGICAL DIFFERENCES

3.7.1 Methods to Test the SSH

There are methodological differences in the ways the hypotheses have been tested in the

empirical literature. For the SSH, the validation rests upon the statistical significance of the

mobility indices in unemployment models. In relation to the differences in the source of

the sectoral shifts, several measures of the mobility indices have been constructed.

The base measure is the raw Lilien index of equation (3.1). Numerous studies have used

this raw index to test the SSH, namely Lilien (1982), Loungani (1986), Davis (1987), Mills,

Pelloni and Zervoyianni (1995), Loungani and Rogerson (1989), Parker (1992), Palley

(1992), Lu (1996), Neelin (1987), Samson (1985), Saint-Paul (1993), Prasad (1997) and

Brainard and Cutler (1993). Two limitations of the raw index are noted: (a) it captures net

labour flows rather than gross labour flows [Prasad (1997)]; and (b) it assumes that only

pure sectoral shifts affect the dispersion in employment growth rates [Mills, Pelloni and

Zervoyianni (1995)] when aggregate demand and supply shocks could also influence the

dispersion in employment. Owing to these limitations, supply-side and unpredicted

mobility indices have been developed in other studies.

51

The mobility index attributed to supply shocks, introduced by Loungani (1986), is as

expressed in equation (3.9), but it should be noted this index captures only oil price shocks

and not other forms of aggregate supply disturbances. There are variants of the unpredicted

mobility indices intended to capture the sectoral movements from pure sectoral shifts

and/or sector-specific shocks. These indices are purged of aggregate demand disturbances

proxies, namely DMR [equation (3.25)] by Garonna and Sica (2000) and Neelin (1987),

aggregate employment [equations (3.26) and (3.29)] by Lu (1996) and Palley (1992), DMR

and DME [equation (3.31)] and government deficit [equation (32)] by Mills, Pelloni and

Zervoyianni (1995). Others include the index purged of aggregate supply shocks, i.e. an oil

price shock [equations (3.9), (3.11a) and (3.11b)] by Loungani (1986) and Mills, Pelloni

and Zervoyianni (1995).

3.7.2 Methods to Test the ADH

Several methods have been adopted to substantiate the relevance of the ADH, including the

use of predicted mobility indices, ζ-U co-movement approach and the U-V method.

Predicted Mobility Indices

The predicted indices capture the anticipated component of sectoral mobility attributable to

aggregate demand shocks, and their statistical significance in unemployment models is used

to inform on the relevance of the ADH. Two proxies of AD disturbances have been applied

when predicted indices have been constructed, i.e. DMR [equation (3.24)] by Garonna and

Sica (2000) and Neelin (1987) and aggregate employment [equation (3.30)] by Palley

(1992).

The σ-U Co-movement Approach

In the ζ-U co-movement approach, Abraham and Katz (1986) regressed sectoral mobility

on a variable for AD shocks (denoted by deviations of GNP from its trend growth), as per

equation (3.19). First, it was shown that ζt and ∆Ut were positively correlated, given the

negative correlation between the industrial trend growth rates [i.e. d(ln eit)/dt] and their

responsiveness in employment to cyclical fluctuations [i.e. the sum of the δ coefficients

52

from the regression of equation (3.19)]. Second, ΔUt and Ut bore a positive correlation for

the U.S. over 1949-1980 for 11 major sectors. From this, it was concluded that an

aggregate demand-driven ζt-∆Ut correlation could, through a positive ΔUt-Ut relationship,

lead to positive ζ-U co-movements.

The main critique of this method is that there is no direct assessment of the impact of ζ on

U to see if sectoral mobility really does or does not affect aggregate unemployment. As

such, there are limited studies using this method to validate the ADH. The majority of the

studies have used the predicted index approach, as it tackles the issue of whether sectoral

movements (arising from AD shocks) impact U directly.

U-V Method

The U-V correlation was used by Abraham and Katz (1986) to reveal which factors

(aggregate demand disturbances or sectoral shifts) were important in explaining aggregate

unemployment. As mentioned, Abraham and Katz (1986) stated that if the pure SSH

captured why the relationship between ζ and U was positive, that between ζ and V should

be positive, which implies a positive U-V relation. In contrast, the pure ADH suggests

there is a negative U-V relationship. There are, however, doubts over the U-V method

from the theoretical and empirical points of view.

Theoretically, the U-V relation need not be positive under the SSH. A negative U-V

relation is also consistent with the SSH in the presence of asymmetric hiring and firing

costs12

. Thus, by extending Weiss‟ (1984) model to include vacancies, Palley (1992)

illustrated that whilst a negative demand shock to a sector tends to reduce vacancies in that

sector, a positive shock to other sectors, which increases their job vacancies, may not

necessarily offset the decline in vacancies in the sector with the negative shock if it is costly

to hire additional workers in the other sectors. The net effect is an increase in aggregate U

and decline in aggregate V, i.e. a negative U-V relationship. Furthermore, it has been

shown that the correlation between U and V could be negative under the pure SSH and

positive under the pure ADH. Using an equilibrium job matching model, Hosios (1994)

identified circumstances where these particular correlations were possible13

. Under the

SSH, an increase in the price dispersion of output of firms in different sectors could lead to

53

a rise in the number of job searchers, a decline in the actual number of jobs and an increase

in the probability of finding a job, which result in higher unemployment and lower job

vacancies. Under the ADH, an increase in the separation rate could result in a higher

number of workers searching for jobs, leading to a rise in the layoff rate, which causes

higher unemployment and job vacancies.

The criticisms of this empirical approach focus on modelling and measurement issues.

The first lies in the approach to modelling with respect to the posited theoretical

relationship. Abraham and Katz (1986) computed 2 regressions for the U.S. and U.K. as

per equations (3.13) and (3.14). From the resultant positive ζ-U and negative ζ-U

relations, a negative U-V relationship was inferred, suggesting support for the ADH. As

both estimating equations are independent regressions, estimated separately for U on ζ and

V on ζ, respectively, it is not really appropriate to make inference about the U-V

correlation. Since the essence of the positive ζ-U relation is derived from the foundations

of the SSH, it appears that the conclusion arising from the 2 regressions tends to “mix” the

arguments of the ADH and SSH.

The other criticism is that the NHWI used in many studies may be an inadequate proxy for

the vacancy rate. Although Abraham and Katz (1986) concluded that the NHWI tracked

actual vacancies relatively well (by showing that the index and the actual vacancy rate for

Minneapolis/St. Paul were positively correlated with an R2 = 0.8), the evidence is only

based on 1 state. Also, as the NHWI is derived from the number of job advertisements, it is

possible that its increase is attributed to changes in employers‟ advertising practices and

declining newspaper competition [Wachter (1987)] and that the index had not been adjusted

for structural change in the labour market. The 35 per cent reduction of the NHWI by

Abraham and Katz (1986) to accommodate these concerns has been criticized as being

large [Wachter (1987)]. Moreover, since it is based on help-wanted advertising, shifts in

the demand and supply of help-wanted advertising that are unrelated to any change in

vacancies are not considered [Zagorsky (1990)]. Furthermore, even if registered vacancy

data were available for other countries, there may be other vacant jobs not registered with

the authorities14

. For example, adversely affected sectors could reduce job vacancies whilst

favourably affected sectors could recall former workers without relying on registered

advertising [Shin (1997a)].

54

Although the U-V relationship was the central argument of Abraham and Katz (1986), the

criticisms on its directional relationship, modelling techniques and statistical inference, and

adequacy of the NHWI as a proxy for the vacancy rate, appear to make it an inappropriate

approach. Not surprisingly, only a few studies [Davis (1987), Brainard and Cutler (1993),

Palley (1992) and Edin and Holmlund (1997)] have examined the U-V argument. The

majority have instead tested the ζ-U correlation with predicted indices instead.

3.7.3 Methods to Test the RTH and Stage-of-the-Business-Cycle Effect

The statistical significance of the horizon covariance index, as per equation (3.33), in

unemployment models and the contemporaneous correlations between labour reallocation

and proxies for the value of foregone production (as mentioned above) have been used by

Davis (1987) to examine the RTH. To ascertain if the stage-of-the-business-cycle effect

exists, the interaction variable, ζ.S, devised by Mills, Pelloni and Zervoyianni (1995), has

been used.

Therefore, taking into account the criticisms associated with some methods, the preferred

methodology for testing the hypotheses in this thesis is the use of the mobility indices in

unemployment regression models. The section below presents a critique of the mobility

indices in order to assess their suitability for the current study. It does not look at an

exhaustive list of the indices but rather highlights those where deficiencies in terms of

concept and methodology could occur and potentially pose problems for model estimation

and interpretation.

3.8 CRITIQUE OF THE MOBILITY INDICES

Raw Lilien Index

The most widely-used raw Lilien index has led to conflicting claims about the SSH for the

various economies for which research has been undertaken. From its construction outlined

in equation (3.1), the raw Lilien index accounts for the change in inter-sector movements in

excess of aggregate-level labour movements, and as such appears to be a suitable measure

55

of sectoral mobility. The main criticism of this index lies in its inability to capture pure

sectoral mobility purged of aggregate disturbances. This is critical because the SSH

postulates a positive relationship between unemployment and pure mobility. Nonetheless, it

will be applied in this thesis as it forms the baseline index from which other indices are

developed. This is in alignment with the other empirical studies which have used the raw

Lilien index as a benchmark, albeit with awareness of its major limitations.

The σt(p) and σt(up) Indices

The predicted ζt(p) and unpredicted ζt(up) indices were introduced by Garonna and Sica

(2000) for the Italian labour market, as added measures of inter-sector labour movements.

The construction of ζt(p) involves two sets of industry regressions, where:

log eit – log eit-1 = β0 + β1DMRt + β2DMRt-1 + β3T + β4AvgRest + uit

log Et – log Et-1 = β0 + β1DMRt + β2DMRt-1 + β3T + β4AvgRest + ut

with AvgRest as the weighted averages of the residuals from the estimated regressions for

each sector, where the shares of each sector in the total employment are utilized as weights.

The regressions for each sector consisted of regressing (log eit – log eit-1) on DMRt,

DMRt-1 and a time trend.

The introduction of the AvgRest measure rides on the argument that the unanticipated

money growth may not take into consideration all aggregate effects on both the sectoral and

aggregate employment growth rates which it would presumably take care of. However, the

inclusion of AvgRest need not necessarily pick up these additional aggregate effects, and,

more importantly, may introduce measurement errors since it can be considered as a

generated regressor which could potentially lead to inefficient estimates15

. In this case, the

construction may not have a solid basis, as the index is meant to pick up predicted shifts.

Consequently, its unpredicted counterpart, ζt(up), may not be the best indicator of

unpredicted mobility shifts. For these reasons, these two indices will not be used in this

thesis.

56

The σa1

t(up) Index

The ζa1

t(up) of equation (3.26) was used by Lu (1996) in an assessment of the SSH for the

U.S. labour market. The limitation of this index lies in the purging indicator, aggregate

employment, which may not be a strong indicator of aggregate demand per se as it is

negatively related with some other aggregate demand indicators. For example, in the case

of South Korea, it was negatively correlated (correlation coefficient in brackets) with the

ratio of public debt to GDP (-0.299) and ratio of exports to GDP (-0.388). For this reason,

the ζa1

t(up) index will not used in the current work.

The σt(r) Index

The unpredicted ζt(r) index of equation (3.10) was recommended by Loungani (1986) in a

study of the SSH in the U.S. It is a mobility index purged of both aggregate demand (i.e.

unanticipated money supply) and supply (i.e. PPI) factors. Because of this, there is a

concern that the index has been over-purged, and this probably accounts for the

inconsistency of the empirical findings associated with it. Depending on the number of

quarterly lags used, the Loungani (1986) study gave conflicting results, namely, the

estimated impact of the index was positive for ζt-1(r) and ζt-7(r), negative for ζt-3(r) and

ζt-4(r), and insignificant for the other lagged indices. Thus, this measure does seem to be

suitable for empirical work.

The σt(s) Index

Another index introduced by Loungani (1986) is the ζt(s) index of equation (3.9), and it is

the only one reflecting labour movements arising from supply side shocks in the form of oil

prices (PPI). The main concern with this index is its lack of currency. Since there have

only been minute changes in oil prices from 1980 to 2001, the supply shifts are negligible

and there is not much use for the index in the current thesis, particularly if the interest is on

the latter years.

57

The σp1

t(up) and σp2

t(up) Indices

Two SSH indices purged of aggregate supply influences in the form of the energy price

index (EP) are the ζp1

t(up) and ζp2

t(up) applied in the Mills, Pelloni and Zervoyianni (1995)

study for the U.S. economy. Unlike the ζt(s) index, these indices do not reflect movements

from supply influences, but rather movements that have been purged of such. These two

indices will be examined as their plotted series (see Appendix 5C in chapter 5) show

sufficient variability to warrant an examination, and „supply-side‟ indices are needed to

complement the array of the demand-related ones.

Horizon Covariance Index

The horizon covariance index captures inter-sectoral movements from past periods which

are deducted from movements in the present period. The index may not therefore be

suitable for the present study as the present study will be based on annual data and sectoral

movements from up to two years ago may be too distant to exert any influence on current

unemployment. Nonetheless, the use of the index should not be ruled out at this early

stage, as it has won favour in some of the influential literature [see Davis (1987)].

Interaction variable, σtSt

The interaction variable was introduced by Mills, Pelloni and Zervoyianni (1995) to assess

the stage-of-the-business-cycle effect. Given that the Asian Financial Crisis marks a major

turning point in Korea, the interaction variable may not be suitable for the current study.

This is because the post-Crisis era has only 4 annual data points, and because the cycle was

incomplete at the end of the data period examined. However, the interaction variable

should not be omitted at this stage, given the importance of the Asian Financial Crisis.

58

3.9 SUMMARY

This chapter has described the SSH, ADH, RTH and stage-of-the-business-cycle effect and

provided insights into the main conceptual and methodological issues. In summary:

a) The hypotheses not only differ in terms of the presumed impact of sectoral

mobility on unemployment but they also differ conceptually (i.e. source of

sectoral shifts, chain of causation and nature of unemployment) and

methodologically.

b) The method of testing the SSH involves several versions of the mobility index

(raw, supply-side and unpredicted indices purged of aggregate demand and/or

supply disturbances) as regressors in models of unemployment.

c) The methods to test the ADH comprise the ζ-U co-movement approach, U-V

argument and regressing the unemployment rate on a predicted mobility index.

d) The RTH and stage-of-the-business-cycle effect were subject to tests that took

the form of regressing unemployment on the horizon covariance index and

interaction variable, and computing the contemporaneous correlations between

labour reallocation measures and proxies for monetary compensation and

finished goods.

e) The current study will examine the hypotheses using mobility indices (i.e. raw

Lilien index, unpredicted/predicted indices, horizon covariance index and

interaction variable) in unemployment models.

f) Taking into consideration their suitability in terms of concept and methodology,

a total of eleven mobility indices will be utilised in this thesis to test the

hypotheses. They are the SSH indices [ζt, ζa2

t(up), ζm

t(up), ζgt(up), ζ

p1t(up), ζ

p2t(up)],

the ADH indices [ζa2

t(p), ζm

t(p), ζgt(p)], the horizon covariance index (ζH) and the

interaction variable (ζtSt).

The SSH, ADH, RTH and stage-of-the-business-cycle effect have been tested in many

studies in the empirical literature. The findings of these studies, covering various

economies, will be presented and discussed in the following chapter.

59

Endnotes:

1. Other studies examine the role of sectoral shocks on output growth rate [Long, Plosser and Charles (1987), Horvath

(2000) and Norbin and Schlagenhauf (1991)], or sectoral labour mobility on labour productivity [McCombie (1991)] or

sectoral mobility on the recall/retention of jobs [Idson and Valletta (1996)].

2. The other factors influencing the natural rate are labour market distortions (e.g. influence of unions, minimum wage

laws and unemployment insurance) and a change in the profile of the labour force.

3. The Conference Board is an independent global business membership and research organization, and equips businesses

with practical knowledge through issues-oriented research and senior executive meetings.

4. The connection between unemployment and output growth is often formally summarized by the statistical relationship

known as Okun‟s Law. The law relates decreasing unemployment rates with increasing output growth.

5. Abraham and Katz (1986) started the analysis from 1949, rather than 1948 as in Lilien (1982), since 1949 was the

earliest year for which they could obtain data on the help-wanted index.

6. Since Abraham and Katz (1986) stated that „ln Yt is log (GNPt)‟, it can be assumed that it is ln Yt = loge (GNPt), and

hence Yt is the GNPt series.

7. In the process of deriving the predicted and unpredicted indices, some studies have expressed the regression(s) in a

logarithmic series, i.e. as „log‟ [Garonna and Sica (2000), Neelin (1987) and Lu (1996)], whilst others have stated the

series was in natural logarithmic terms [Palley (1992)]. For the studies that do not give the base for the logs, it can be

assumed that they have used natural logs. However, to maintain comparability, this study presents the methodologies

according to the way each empirical study has stated their respective indices.

8. Neelin (1987) mentioned that these predicted and unpredicted indices are analogous to the one used in Lilien (1983).

9. The ζa2t(up) index is a hybrid of predicted and unpredicted indices. The predictive component is captured from the

change in sectoral employment and the unpredicted element arises from the residual component (εit) which presumably

captures pure sectoral influences. Whilst the index has elements of predictability, it is also considered as an index purged

of aggregate demand influences and will be used to test for the SSH in this thesis.

10. Using the average rate of return on capital for industry i in period t, Shin (1997a) computed a cross-sectoral variance

index, ζyit and purged ζy

it by regressing it on the current and lagged growth rates of GNP. However, since the rate of

return on capital is used instead of the employment growth rate, Shin‟s (1997a) study is not relevant to this thesis.

11. These proxies were estimated in logarithmic terms in Davis (1987).

12. Garonna and Sica (2000) also highlighted the role of hiring and firing costs for sectoral shifts in the Italian labour

market.

13. There was no empirical work undertaken for the equilibrium model outlined by Hosios (1994).

14. See Bureau of Labour Market Research, „Structural Change and the Labour Market‟, Research Report no. 11,

Australian Government Publishing Service, Canberra, 1987.

15. Refer to the next chapter for the problem of generated regressors.

60

CHAPTER 4

THE IMPACT OF SECTORAL MOBILITY ON UNEMPLOYMENT:

A REVIEW OF THE EMPIRICAL LITERATURE

4.1 INTRODUCTION

The previous chapter introduced the hypotheses concerning the impact of sectoral mobility

on unemployment: the SSH, ADH, RTH and the stage-of-the-business-cycle effect, and

discussed their conceptual and methodological differences. This chapter aims to review the

related empirical findings on the hypotheses. It then uses this review to indicate how the

empirical application for Korea (chapter 5) might proceed. The organization of the chapter

is as follows. The empirical review is conducted under sections 4.2 to 4.5. Sections 4.6 and

4.7 draw out practical implications for the study of the Korean labour market to be

undertaken in chapter 5, in terms of model specification and estimation. The link to the

microeconomic research on the determinants of sectoral mobility is identified in the

concluding section.

4.2 EMPIRICAL REVIEW ON THE SSH

Sections 4.2 to 4.4 discuss the empirical findings for the various hypotheses with reference

to Table 4.1, which presents the results for the impact of sectoral mobility on

unemployment for the U.S., with those for Canada and Italy reported in the footnote (owing

to the different variables used). Details on these studies are presented here to highlight

differences in the empirical approach. The findings of studies for several other countries –

Japan, Europe and Canada – will also be introduced below. The methodologies in these

studies are generally variants of those employed in the studies for the U.S. listed in Table

4.1. Given the differing hypotheses, and the spread of mobility indicators adopted

within/across the hypotheses, studies with similar indices will be compared under each

hypothesis. This approach establishes conceptual similarity and minimizes the need for

undue explanations where differing results across studies are merely due to conceptual or

methodological dissimilarity. A summary of the findings is found in section 4.5.

61

This section presents the empirical findings for the SSH. Owing to the array of mobility

indices used to test the SSH, the organization of each section is by index-type where the

findings of studies adopting the same type of mobility index are compared. The section

commences with findings from the raw Lilien index – the most commonly-used index, and

ends with the natural unemployment rate approach to testing the hypothesis.

4.2.1 The Raw Lilien Index

Among studies using the raw Lilien index, all for North America and Japan confirm a

positive and significant impact of sectoral mobility on aggregate unemployment. These

include Lilien (1982), Loungani (1986), Parker (1992), Loungani and Rogerson (1989),

Brainard and Cutler (1993), Davis (1987), Mills, Pelloni and Zervoyianni (1995) and Lu

(1996) for the U.S. and Samson (1985) and Neelin (1987) for Canada. Prasad (1997)

computed the raw Lilien index for Japan over 1970-1994 and found a negative relationship

with aggregate employment via graphical analysis, meaning that its impact on

unemployment was probably positive. Similar results were produced when lagged values

of the raw Lilien indices were introduced to cater for long run responses of sectoral

mobility on the macro economy in Lilien (1982), Loungani (1986), Brainard and Cutler

(1993), Davis (1987) and Lu (1996).

For the European economies, the studies acknowledged the role of sectoral mobility on

unemployment but the effect worked in the opposite direction. A negative correlation of the

raw Lilien index with aggregate unemployment was plotted by Saint-Paul (1997) for France

over 1964-1991 and by Garonna and Sica (2000) for Italy for 1952-1994. Rising public

employment in response to higher unemployment and labour market rigidities via

temporary contracts that hampered workers‟ ability to relocate to growth sectors or those

requiring more of specific products/services were the reasons cited for France for this

perverse finding. In Italy, the greater cyclical sensitivity of manufacturing employment vis-

à-vis services employment as compared to the U.S, and firing costs that exceeded hiring

costs (given the high job security) such that unemployment was kept low through sectoral

reallocations (via new hires and pull of new sectors) and interregional mobility were both

argued to have contributed to the negative ζ-U relation.

62

4.2.2 The Index Generated by Supply-side Disturbances

Sectoral movements generated by supply disturbances (oil price shocks) were captured by

an index developed in a single study by Loungani (1986). The lack of similar analyses

reflect the datedness of the 1970s global oil crisis, which has not warranted much research

given the stability of oil prices in latter years. Loungani‟s (1986) index generated by

supply-side disturbances had a positive impact on the unemployment rate for up to 4 lagged

periods.

4.2.3 Pure Sectoral Shift Measures

The pure sectoral shift measures are those that have been purged of the influences of

various aggregate demand and supply variables. With regards to the mobility index purged

of oil price shocks, Mills, Pelloni and Zervoyianni (1995) reported a positive ζ-U

correlation for the U.S. when a one-period lagged version of the mobility index was used.

Again, this is an isolated study which has not generated much interest in the literature,

possibly owing to the datedness of the 1970s oil shock.

Pertaining to the index purged of money growth, the effect on unemployment was positive

for the current period variable and negative for the four-period lagged variable for the U.S.

[Mills, Pelloni and Zervoyianni (1995)] but insignificant for Canada [Neelin (1987)].

When purged of government debt, the index‟s lagged effect was positive for a one-period

lagged variable but negative for a four-period lagged variable [Mills, Pelloni and

Zervoyianni (1995)]1. Conflicting results were produced when the index was purged of

aggregate employment. Palley (1992) reported positive influences for the current and one-

period lagged variables, but Lu (1996) reported an insignificant relationship for all three

lagged indices included in the estimating equation (see Table 4.1). This conflict may

reflect the inappropriateness of using overall employment as a purging tool rather than

specific AD variables.

Loungani (1986) purged the index of aggregate demand (DMR) and supply (oil price

shocks) variables. The one-period and seven-period lagged indices were found to have

significant effects on unemployment. There does not appear to be a convincing argument

for this pattern of significant effects. However, the index may be over-purged, and the

degree of support for the hypothesis under test provided by such results is therefore open to

debate.

Table 4.1 Studies on the Impact of Sectoral Mobility on Aggregate Unemployment in the U.S. Study Lilien (1982) Loungani

(1986)

Parker (1992) Brainard and

Cutler (1993)

Palley (1992) Loungani and

Rogerson

(1989)

Davis

(1987)

Mills, Pelloni and

Zervoyianni

(1995)

Lu

(1996)

Raw Lilien index Over 13

sectors

Over 65

industries

MLE 2SE

ζt 55.9** 0.29** 0.051** 0.0034 0.71+ 0.361**

ζt-1 18.9* 0.40** 0.708** 0.559** 0.37**

ζt-2 0.16 0.467** 0.384** -0.21*

ζt-3 -0.03 -0.136 0.335** 0.04

ζt-4 0.15 -0.123 0.138

ζt-5 0.39** 0.113

ζt-6 0.36** 0.224**

ζt-7 0.46** 0.288**

ζt-8 0.20 0.218**

ζt-9 0.203**

ζt-10 0.138

ζt-11 0.151

ζt-12 0.252**

Δζt 3.856**

Δζt-1 4.690**

Δζt-2 3.333**

Index purged of AD variables

ζmt(up) 2.268**

ζmt-4(up) -1.993**

ζgt-1(up) 4.364**

ζgt-4(up) -2.529*

ζa1t-1(up) 0.09

ζa1t-2(up) 0.32

ζa1t-3(up) -0.07

ζa2t(up) 18.00** 24.15**

ζa2t-1(up) 15.24* 14.72*

ζa2t-2(up) -5.99 -7.61

ζa2t-3(up) 7.91 6.19

Index purged of AS variables

ζp1t-1(up) 3.820**

ζp1t-3(up) -3.519**

ζp2t-3(up) -3.190**

Index purged of AD and AS

variables

ζt(r) 0.24

ζt-1(r) 0.38**

ζt-2(r) 0.10

ζt-3(r) -0.23

ζt-4(r) -0.20

ζt-5(r) 0.06

ζt-6(r) 0.08

ζt-7(r) 0.28**

ζt-8(r) 0.17

64

Table 4.1 Studies on the Impact of Sectoral Mobility on Aggregate Unemployment in the U.S. (continued) Study Lilien (1982) Loungani

(1986)

Parker (1992) Brainard

and Cutler

(1993)

Palley (1992) Loungani and

Rogerson

(1989)

Davis

(1987)

Mills, Pelloni

and

Zervoyianni

(1995)

Lu (1996)

MLE 2SE

Index attributed to AS shocks

ζt(s) 0.60**

ζt-1(s) 0.83**

ζt-2(s) 0.49**

ζt-3(s) 0.47**

ζt-4(s) 0.34**

ζt-5(s) -0.19

ζt-6(s) -0.12

ζt-7(s) 0.07

ζt-8(s) 0.09

Index attributed to Aggregate

shocks

ζat(p) -22.07** -47.42**

ζat-1(p) -21.19** -25.44**

ζat-2(p) -19.00** -14.40

ζat-3(p) -15.89* -13.63

Horizon Covariance Index

Quarterly data series

ζHt-1 0.598**

ζHt-6 0.279**

ζHt-12 0.166**

Annual data series

ζHt-1 -7.9

ζHt-4 28.9*

ζHt-1 6.13

ζHt-3 44.18**

Interaction variable

Quarterly data series

RECESS(βtζt + βt-1ζt-1) 0.172* 5

RECESS ∑ (βiζi ) i=0

0.046

10

RECESS ∑ (βiζi ) i=0

0.077

12

RECESS ∑ (βtζt + βt-1ζt-1) i=0

0.038

∆ (Stζt + St-1ζt-1) 1.210**

** significant at 5% level. * significant at 10% level.

+ : Based on bivariate correlation coefficient.

Note: 1. Although the Lilien indices have been categorized by type (raw, purged of AD/AS/Aggregate variables, pure indices, interaction variable) and by the number of lags, including that for the current period, the indices are not directly comparable across studies. This arises as the impacts of the Lilien indices on unemployment for these studies were based

on different methods of estimation, model specification and number of industries.

2. Findings on coefficients (in brackets) for other countries

Canada: Neelin (1987): Raw Lilien index (31.71) and Index attributed to AD shocks (101.52) were significant at the 5% level. Index purged of AD variables (-7.63) was insignificant.

Samson (1985): Raw Lilien index (81.7) was reported to be significant at the 5% level.

Italy: Garonna and Sica (2000): Index purged of AD variables (0.30) was significant at the 10% level and Index attributed to AD shocks (-0.70) was significant at the 5% level.

65

4.2.4 The Natural Unemployment Rate Approach

The empirical findings on the significance of the natural unemployment rate concur with

the foundations of the SSH (Table 4.2). Thus, the natural unemployment rate explained a

significant portion of the variations in the aggregate unemployment rate in Lilien (1982)

and Mills, Pelloni and Zervoyianni (1995). Furthermore, when alternative indices (index

purged of aggregate demand influences and interaction variables for the stage-of-the-

business-cycle effect) were included in the unemployment equation used to estimate the

natural rate in the latter study, the natural rate accounted for a slightly larger proportion of

the actual rate. Parker (1992) estimated the natural rate as the fitted value of the

unemployment equation with the unanticipated money growth and residual obtained from

the unemployment regression set equal to zero, and plotted this series against that of U. It

was observed that U exceeded U* during 1956-1964. Towards the late 1960s and early

1970s, U declined due to microeconomic factors (labour supply shortage associated with

the Vietnam war) and the U-U* disparity lessened. Given that the natural rate is that which

is attributable solely to microeconomic factors, the narrowing of the U*-U gap implies that

much of the unemployment in the 1970s was accounted for by natural (microeconomic)

factors, i.e. the natural rate. Samson (1985) plotted the U* series against the actual U series

over the 1957-1983 period and found a small deviation of 0.45 between the two series

(based on their average absolute values), implying that the natural rate could explain the

actual series relatively well. Loungani (1986) constructed two measures of the natural rate,

U*t(s) and U

*t(r), where the former was estimated from the regression associated with the

index attributed to the oil shock, and the latter with the unpredicted index. Using quarterly

data for the U.S. over j = 8 lags, these were calculated as:

8

U*t(s) = β0 + ∑ βj ζ t(s)-j and

j=0

8

U*t(r) = β0 + ∑ γj ζ t(r)-j

j=0

where β0 is the intercept estimate from the regressions and βj and γj were each the

estimated coefficients attached to the ζt(s) and ζt(r) variables. It was reported that U*t(s)

accounted for 20% of U, higher than the 5% reported for U*t(r).

66

Table 4.2 R2 between Actual Unemployment Rate and Natural Unemployment Rate

Study Lilien (1982) Mills, Pelloni and

Zervoyianni (1995)

Loungani (1986)

Between Ut and U*t Between ∆Ut and ∆U*t Between Ut and U*t

Index used

Actual

series

Detrended

series

Detrended series

ζt 0.74 0.60 0.52

ζt(s) 0.20

ζt(r) 0.05

ζm

t(up) 0.55

∆(Stζt + St-1ζt-1) 0.57

∆(Stζm

t(up)+St-1ζm

t(up)-1) 0.56

Whilst several studies have supported the general influence U* has on U, namely, Parker

(1992), Loungani (1986) and Samson (1985), a counter argument questioning the influence

of U* was presented by Murphy and Topel (1987a). They made use of a constant natural

rate argument to conclude a lack of support for the SSH. In theory, sectoral movements

under the SSH generate frictional unemployment which should lead to changes in the

natural rate. Using unit-record cross-sectional data for male employees in the U.S., it was

shown that only 2.4-4.0 per cent of the total unemployed were industry movers during

1968-1985, and that this proportion remained virtually constant throughout this period,

implying a constant natural rate of unemployment. Since changes in the natural rate are

implied under the SSH in that U* varies with frictional inter-sector labour movements,

Murphy and Topel (1987a) concluded that the constant natural rate (implied from the non-

varying 2.4-4 per cent) did not concur with the hypothesis. This contrasts with the other

evidence for the U.S., such as Parker (1992) and Lilien (1982), which illustrated a

fluctuating U* series over the period, but it should be noted that two different sets of data

are used to support the evidence for the SSH or lack thereof. Murphy and Topel‟s (1987a)

constant rate is implied from descriptive data covering males only, whilst Parker‟s (1992)

and Lilien‟s (1982) U* series has been estimated formally and covers both males and

females. Furthermore, in response, Lilien (1987) argued that Murphy and Topel (1987a)

misinterpreted the underlying implications of the SSH, where sectoral mobility is generated

by frictional movements as well as economic shocks.2 Thus, whilst Murphy and Topel

(1987a) interpreted inter-industry movements to arise from frictional labour movements,

such sectoral movements can also originate from economic shocks.

67

4.3 EMPIRICAL FINDINGS ON THE ADH

The methodologies to test the ADH comprise the use of predicted mobility indices, the U-V

relationship and ζ-U co-movement approach. The organization of this section is to

evaluate the empirical works according to these methodologies. For the latter approach, the

findings are not assessed since Abraham and Katz (1986) appears to be the single study

using the ζ-U co-movement method, and this has been described in the previous chapter.

4.3.1 The Predicted Mobility Indices

Predicted indices from aggregate demand disturbances have been used to test the ADH.

The two studies adopting this approach have reported opposite results. The ζ-U relation

was positive in Neelin (1987) for Canada but negative in Garonna and Sica‟s (2000)

analysis for Italy. For the latter, the inverse relation was held to reflect the differing

cyclical responsiveness of economic sectors which triggers unemployment, thereby leading

to the deduction that sectoral movements in Italy were generated from an AD disturbance

and that unemployment is cyclical. Thus, whilst the Canadian experience appears to

provide clear support for the ADH via its positive ζ-U relation, the Italian outcome can be

argued to be aligned to the ADH only in terms of the source of sectoral shifts and nature of

unemployment, and certainly not from the evidence of the directional influence of ζ on U.

A predicted index generated by aggregate employment was examined by Palley (1992) for

the U.S. over 1951-1988 for 11 sectors. A negative influence on unemployment from

mobility for the current-period index and indices lagged by three periods was reported.

This does not support the ADH, since the study for the U.S. by Abraham and Katz (1986)

asserted that there should be positive ζ-U co-movements. Since Palley (1992) and

Abraham and Katz (1986) cover the same economy and almost similar time periods but

reveal differing results, the method of filtering involved when constructing this form of

predicted index (i.e. the use of aggregate employment) remains questionable.

68

4.3.2 The U-V Relationship

As explained in the previous chapter, under the SSH the U-V relationship should be

positive, and ζ-U and ζ-V should both be positively related as well. Under the ADH, the

positive ζ-U association generates a negative ζ-V relationship following an aggregate

demand shock and the resulting U-V relation is inverse. In this section the empirical

support for the ADH from the correlation results of U-V and/or ζ-U and/or ζ-V is

examined. Generally, it is shown that the conclusions on the ADH using the U-V

relationship are contradictory.

Davis (1987) plotted the ζ, NHWI and unemployment inflows and outflow series for 1948-

1986. It was shown that: (a) periods of high (low) unemployment inflow and outflow rates

coincided with declining (rising) NHWI levels; and (b) periods of rapid rates of labour

reallocations accompanied high unemployment rates. The negative U and V correlation

and the positive ζ and U relationship appeared to be consistent with the ADH rather than

the SSH.

Brainard and Cutler (1993) estimated the Beveridge Curve by regressing the logarithm of

the vacancy rate against the current and lagged values of a cross-section volatility (CSV)

measure, the raw Lilien index and the unemployment rate3:

15 15

log Vt = β0 + ∑ β1jCSVt-j + ∑ β2jζt-j + β3logUt + εt (4.1) j=0 j=0

for 15 lagged quarters, where the CSV is a variance measure of sectors‟ stock market

excess returns. Whilst CSV and Ut exerted positive and significant influences on job

vacancies, the finding for ζ was ambiguous, being significant and positive for the first two

lagged years and insignificant for the third and fourth lagged years4. As the U-V relation

was negative and the ζ-V relationship ambiguous, the results did not appear to support the

ADH.

Similarly, the significance of the current and lagged values of the predicted and unpredicted

indices in a model of the aggregate vacancy rate (proxied by ratio of NHWI to total non-

agricultural employment) was examined by Palley (1992) using the following equation5:

69

3 3

Vt = β0 + β1T + β2Vt-1 + ∑ β3,t-jζt-j(p) + ∑ β4,t-jζt-j(up) + εt (4.2)

j=0 j=0

The results revealed the unpredicted indices were associated with reductions in the vacancy

rate. This negative ζ-V correlation concurs with the ADH rather than the SSH, which as

noted above asserts a positive ζ-V relation. However, the main criticism is that the

unpredicted indices were insignificant regressors of the vacancy rate even though the

coefficients were negative. The case for the U-V argument in Palley‟s (1992) study is

therefore weak.

The other study supporting the ADH is Edin and Holmlund (1997), using a U-V curve for

Sweden over 1983-1995. The increase in unemployment over the period was characterized

by a movement along the curve rather than a shift. It was concluded that higher

unemployment during 1994-1995 was brought about by aggregate demand shocks in the

form of a decline in public sector labour demand rather than by any mismatch in the

composition of labour demand and supply, suggesting a case for the ADH.

4.4 FINDINGS ON THE RTH AND STAGE-OF-THE-BUSINESS-CYCLE

This section presents the findings on the RTH and stage-of-the-business-cycle effect. The

section is presented according to the measure adopted to test the hypotheses. It begins with

an assessment of results based on the horizon covariance index and interaction variable,

followed by those using labour reallocation and foregone production proxies.

4.4.1 The Horizon Covariance Index

The horizon covariance index used by Davis (1987) to test the RTH was constructed for 8

non-agricultural industries with quarterly data for the U.S. This index, lagged by one, six

and twelve periods, had positive impacts on unemployment for 1953-1986. While this

appears to provide support for the RTH, the strength of this support has been questioned by

Oi (1987). He argued that the regression results of Davis (1987) were quite weak

statistically. Since the RTH has not been tested by any other studies, including Oi (1987),

70

no conclusion can be reached as to its relevance in general, or its potential relevance to the

Korean labour market.

4.4.2 Interaction Variables

To test the stage-of-the-business-cycle effect, Mills, Pelloni and Zervoyianni‟s (1995)

interaction variable, ζtSt, was computed over 30 industries for the U.S. during 1960-1991.

The interaction variable had a positive effect on unemployment. Davis‟ (1987)

RECESS(βtζt + βt-1ζt-1) variable was also significant for the U.S. during 1953 quarter 2 and

1986 quarter 2. These results were argued to be consistent with the stage-of-the-business-

cycle effect, i.e. the ζ-U impact intensifies during recessions and weakens during upturns.

However, Davis‟ (1987) interaction variable is not applicable to the current work in that it

has to be applied to quarterly data.

4.4.3 Labour Reallocations and Foregone Production

Davis (1987) is the single study examining the RTH using correlations between labour

reallocations and foregone production. The labour reallocation measures are the raw Lilien

index series and the simulated unemployment series as per equation (3.34), excluding ζH

t-j,

and with the raw Lilien index taking its sample values whilst fixing other regressors at their

sample means. The proxies for foregone production were log [compensation

index/producer price index (PPI)], log [compensation index/consumer price index (CPI)],

log (manufacturing finished goods inventory at constant prices), log (manufacturing

finished goods/PPI) and log (constant prices inventory/manufacturing sales). Negative

correlations were reported for both labour reallocation measures and the first two proxies

over 1953-1986, whilst positive correlations were reported for the detrended finished goods

measures for different time periods (see Table 4.3). These results were interpreted as

confirming the predictions of the RTH.

Two related criticisms were directed at Davis‟ (1987) conclusion by Oi (1987). First, the

correlations shown are rather small, and second, the R2 never exceeds 0.1. These criticisms

are certainly valid and appear to account for why the method of labour reallocations and

value of foregone production has not been used in other studies. Owing to the dearth of

71

comparison studies, and the criticism of the Davis (1987) study, this approach will not be

applied in this thesis.

Table 4.3 Contemporaneous Correlations between Labour Reallocation

and Average Value Proxies of Foregone Production Proxies for Foregone Production Simulated Unemployment Raw Lilien Index

Contemporaneous Correlation

R2 Contemporaneous Correlation

R2

Log (Compensation Index/PPI)

1953-1986 -0.227 0.009 -0.217 0.012

Log (Compensation Index/CPI)

1953-1986 -0.306 0.000 -0.250 0.004

Log (Manufacturing Finished

Goods Inventory/PPI)

1953-1986 0.091 0.298 0.185 0.033

Log (Manufacturing Finished Goods

Inventory at Constant Prices)

1959-1986 0.212 0.028 0.219 0.023

Log (Inventory at Constant Prices/

Manufacturing Sales)

1961-1985 0.710 0.000 0.359 0.000

Source: Davis (1987).

Note: Davis (1987) stated most correlations were significant at the 5% level except for one correlation.

However, this exception was not singled out.

4.5 SUMMARY OF EMPIRICAL FINDINGS

Based on the above review, the following can be concluded regarding the empirical

relevance of the hypotheses:

a) Empirically, the SSH appears to be supported by studies using the raw Lilien

index, supply-side index and pure indices purged of specific aggregate demand

and supply disturbances. The hypothesis is not a global phenomenon as the

contrasting experiences of European economies suggest that varied labour

market features and sectoral sensitivities influence the way mobility affects

unemployment. Given the widespread empirical acceptance of the SSH, this

thesis will consider the use of the SSH indices in model estimation.

72

b) The ADH appears to have less empirical acceptance compared to the SSH. In

view of the contradictory theories governing the U-V correlation, and the

absence of a direct assessment of the impact of ζ on U, tests of the ADH will be

based on the statistical significance of predicted mobility indices in

unemployment models.

c) The horizon covariance index and interaction variable have been reported as

significant in models of unemployment. Based on this, the current work will

adopt the same index and interaction variable to evaluate if the RTH and stage-

of-the-business-cycle effect hold for Korea.

4.6 EMPIRICAL APPLICATION

This section reviews the empirical methods adopted by the studies of the impact of sectoral

mobility in terms of the data-type and frequency, time periods, and model specification and

estimation. Reference is made to the recommended empirical framework for the thesis.

4.6.1 Type and Frequency of Data

The common form of data adopted in the studies is aggregate-level time-series data. The

majority have used annual data, which have the advantage of removing the effects of

seasonality and thus enabling assessment of the impact of sectoral mobility on structural,

frictional and cyclical unemployment independent of seasonal unemployment. Some

studies have used quarterly data, but these either showed the Lilien index to be insignificant

[Lu (1996)], ended up incorporating numerous lagged indices (6-12 lags) in the regression

to accommodate the longer-run effects of mobility [Loungani (1986), Neelin (1987), Davis

(1987) and Mills, Pelloni and Zervoyianni (1995)], or have had to make adjustment for the

seasonal component in the regression analysis, either by including seasonal dummies as

regressors [Neelin (1987)] or pre-adjusting the dependent variable [Davis (1987)]. Since

sectoral behavioural response is not highly volatile to swings in market activity compared

to a stock market response (where high frequency data are generally used), the use of

annual data for the current study should suffice.

73

4.6.2 Time Period

The majority of the analyses cover 3 decades in order to be able to capture the long run

dynamics of sectoral mobility. The exceptions are Loungani and Rogerson (1989) [1

decade], Samson (1985) and Neelin (1987) [2 decades], Brainard and Cutler (1993), Lu

(1996) and Garonna and Sica (2000) [4 decades] and Davis (1987) [6 decades]. Likewise,

the current work for Korea covers 3 decades, from 1971 to 2001.

4.6.3 Model Estimation

An unemployment regression containing variants of ζ will be the main approach to test the

hypotheses. Table 4.4 provides the model specification and method of estimation of the

unemployment equations in the main studies. Two types of time-series models (TSM) are

applied: single-equation and dual-equation models.

4.6.3.1 Single-Equation Models

The studies adopting a single-equation TSM are of the following general functional form:

J J

Ut = βo + ∑ β1j Xt-j + ∑ β2jUt-j + εt (4.3)

j=0 j=1

where Xt-j represents the current and/or lagged values of the variants of ζ and aggregate

demand/supply variables, and Ut-j represents the lagged values of the dependent variable.

One area of concern is that ζ could be correlated with other explanatory variables and this

poses potential problems of multicollinearity. Another more significant area of concern in

studies with single-equation models is the lack of adequate proxy variables for aggregate

demand/supply disturbances. Lu‟s (1996) GDP growth rate variable does not distinguish

whether it is an AD or AS variable6. Brainard and Cutler‟s (1993) CSV measure captures

the short-run dynamics of a shock and ignores its long-run impact on the labour market.

Aggregate disturbance variables are totally absent from Palley‟s (1992) specification7.

Accommodating such variables frequently involves the inclusion of DMR in the studies.

Since DMR itself is estimated from a money growth equation, this means that the

unemployment model is treated as a second equation, leading to the emergence of dual-

equation models.

74

Table 4.4 Unemployment and Money Growth Equations used

in Selected Studies of Sectoral Mobility Study Country/ Time

Period/Data-

type/Method of

Estimation for

Aggregate

Unemployment

Model Specification

Lilien (1982)

U.S., 1948-1980,

Aggregate-level time-

series annual data.

Method of Estimation

2-step estimation (2SE).

Aggregate Unemployment

1 2

Ut = βo + ∑ β1j ζt-j - ∑ β2j DMRt-j + β3 Ut-1 + β4 T + εt

j=0 j=0

Natural Unemployment Rate

U*t = ∑ βj2 (β0 + β1ζt-j + β4 Tt-j)

j=0

Note: The number of lags in the U*t equation corresponds with those for

the aggregate unemployment equation.

Money Growth Rate

DMt = α0 + α1 DMt-1 + α2DMt-2 + α3FEDVt + α4UNt-1 + DMRt

Abraham

and Katz

(1986)

U.S., 1949-1980,

Aggregate-level time-

series annual data.

Method of Estimation

2SE.

Aggregate Unemployment

1 2

Ut = βo + ∑ β1j ζt-j - ∑ β2j DMRt-j + β3 Ut-1 + β4 T + εt

j=0 j=0

Money Growth Rate

DMt = α0 + α1 DMt-1 + α2DMt-2 + α3FEDVt + α4UNt-1 + DMRt

Loungani

(1986)

U.S., 1947-1982,

Aggregate-level time-

series quarterly data.

Method of Estimation:

2SE.

Aggregate Unemployment

8 8

Regression 1: Ut = βo + ∑ β1j ζt-j - ∑β2j DMRt-j + β3 T + εt

j=0 j=0

8 8

Regression 2: Ut = βo + ∑β1j ζt(s)-j - ∑β2j DMRt-j + β3 T + εt

j=0 j=0

8 8

Regression 3: Ut = βo + ∑β1j ζt(r)-j - ∑β2j DMRt-j + β3 T + εt

j=0 j=0

Natural Unemployment Rate

J

U* t(s) = βo + ∑ β1j ζt(s)-j

j=0

J

U* t(r) = βo + ∑ β1j ζt(r)-j j=0

Note: The number of lags in the U*t equation corresponds with those for

the aggregate unemployment equation. No reason was given as to why the

trend variable was excluded. The U*t was probably meant to solely capture

the amount of unemployment attributable to sectoral movements.

Money Growth Rate

DMt = α0 + α1 DMt-1 + α2DMt-2 + α3FEDVt + α4UNt-1 + DMRt

Note: As the author did not specify the money growth equation, it is

assumed the equation follows that of Barro (1977).

75

Table 4.4 Unemployment and Money Growth Equations used

in Selected Studies of Sectoral Mobility (continued) Study Country/ Time

Period/Data-

type/Method of

Estimation for

Aggregate

Unemployment

Model Specification

Davis (1987) U.S., 1953-1986, Aggregate-level time- series quarterly data. Method of Estimation Joint-estimation of the unemployment and money growth equation using non-linear least squares.

Aggregate Unemployment Regression 1:

12 9 12

Ut = βo + ∑ β1j ζt-j + ∑β2j DMRt-j + ∑ β3j DMEt-j + β4 DUM74 j=0 j=0 j=0

+ β5 μt-1 + β6 μt-2 + εt Regression 2:

12 Ja 9 12

Ut = βo + ∑ β1jζt-j + ∑ β2j ζHt-j - ∑ β3j DMRt-j + ∑ β4j DMEt-j

j=0 j=0 j=0 j=0

+ β5 DUM74 + β6 μt-1 + β7 μt-2 + εt Note: a: J varies as 6 regressions were run separately with ζHt-1, ζHt-6,

ζHt-12, (ζHt-1 and ζHt-12), (ζHt-1, ζHt-6 and ζHt-10) and (ζHt-1, ζHt-4, ζHt-8 and ζHt-10). Ut is seasonally-adjusted for quarterly series. The error terms, βj μt-1 + βj μt-2 + εt, follow an AR(2) process. Regression 3: 12 9 12

Ut = βo + ∑ β1j ζt-j + β2 ζHt-1 + ∑ β3j DMRt-j + ∑ β4j DMEt-j + β5DUM74 j=0 j=0 j=0

J

+ β6RECESS (∑ βjζt-j) + β7 μt-1 + β8 μt-2 + εt j=0

Note: Ut is seasonally-adjusted for the quarterly series. 4 regressions were estimated separately for RECESS(∑βjζt-j) lagged by 1, 5, 10 and 12 periods. The error terms, βjμt-1 + βjμt-2 + εt, follow an AR(2) process. Money Growth Rate 12 4 4

DMt = α0 + ∑α1jDMt-j + ∑α2jBILLt-j + ∑α3jUNt-j + α4T + DMRt j=1 j=1 j=1

Note: BILL is the 3-month Treasury Bill rate.

Davis (1987) U.S., 1924-1985, Aggregate-level time- series, annual data. Method of Estimation Joint-estimation of the unemployment and money growth equation using non-linear least squares.

Aggregate Unemployment Regression 1:

2 2

Ut = βo + ∑ β1j ζt-j + β2ζHt-1 + β3ζHt-4 + ∑ β4j DMRt-j + β5mt + β6mt-1

j=0 j=0

+ β7 Gt + β8 T + εt Regression 2:

2 2

Ut = βo + ∑ β1j ζt-j + β2ζHt-1 + β3ζHt-4 + ∑ β4j DMRt-j + β5mt + β6mt-1

j=0 j=0

+ β7 Gt + β8 T + β9YD + εt Regression 3:

2 2

Ut = βo + ∑ β1j ζt-j + β2ζHt-1 + β3ζHt-3 + ∑ β4j DBRt-j + β5mt + β6mt-1

j=0 j=0

+ β7 Gt + β8T + β9YD + εt

Note: m is money supply multiplier, G is log of real government

expenditure and YD are the yearly dummies. Money Growth Rate DBt = α0 + α1 DBt-1 + α2FEDVPt + α3Ut-1 + DBRt

Note: DB is the money base growth rate and DBR is the residual from the

money growth rate regression. FEDVP is the predicted difference between

the actual and „normal‟ growth rate of federal government expenditure.

76

Table 4.4 Unemployment and Money Growth Equations used

in Selected Studies of Sectoral Mobility (continued) Study Country/ Time

Period/Data-

type/Method of

Estimation for

Aggregate

Unemployment

Model Specification

Mills, Pelloni and Zervoyianni (1995)

U.S., 1960-1991, Aggregate-level time- series quarterly data. Method of Estimation Cointegration and Error Correction Model.

Aggregate Unemployment

Regression 1: ΔUt = βo + β1 Δζt + β2 Δζt-1 + β3Δζt-2 + β4DMRt-6 + β5 (DMRt - DMRt-1) + β6DMEt + β7 DMEt-1 + β8DMEt-5 + β9 ΔUt-2 + β10ΔUt-4 + β11 ΔUt-5 + 2

β12 ΔUt-6 + β13 Δrt + β14 ∑ Δrt-3-j + β15 Δ(xt-2+ xt-3) + β16 Δxt-5 + εt j=0

Regression 2: ΔUt = βo + β1ζ

mt(up) + β2ζ

mt-4(up) + β3DMRt-6 + β4(DMRt - DMRt-1) +

β5DMEt + β6 DMEt-1 + β7DMEt-5 + β8 ΔUt-2 + β9ΔUt-4 + β10ΔUt-5 + 2

β11 ΔUt-6 + β12 Δrt + β13 ∑ Δrt-3-j + β14 Δ(xt-2 + xt-3) + β15Δxt-5 + εt j=0

Regression 3: ΔUt = βo + β1 Δζt + β2 Δζt-1 + β3 Δζt-2 + β4 Δ(Stζt + St-1ζt-1) + β5DMRt-6

+ β6 (DMRt - DMRt-1) + β7DMEt + β8 DMEt-1 + β9DMEt-5 + β10 ΔUt-2 +

2

β11Δ Ut-4 + β12 ΔUt-5 + β13 ΔUt-6 + β14 Δrt + β15∑ Δrt-3-j +

j=0

β16 Δ (xt-2 + xt-3) + β17 Δxt-5 + εt Natural Unemployment Rate

From Regression 1:

ΔU*t = β1Δζt + β2Δζt-1+ β3Δζt-2 + β9 ΔUt-2 + β10ΔUt-4 + β11 ΔUt-5 + β12ΔUt-6

From Regression 2:

ΔU*t = β1 ζm

t(up) + β2 ζm

t-4(up) + β8 ΔUt-2 + β9ΔUt-4 + β10 ΔUt-5 + β11 ΔUt-6

From Regression 3:

ΔU*t = β1Δζt + β2Δζt-1 + β3 Δζt-2 + β4 Δ(Stζt + St-1ζt-1) + β10 ΔUt-2

+ β11ΔUt-4 + β12 ΔUt-5 + β13 ΔUt-6

Note:

1. r is the logarithm of the short-run interest rate and x is the ratio of

exports to GNP.

2. The unpredicted index was purged of several aggregate demand/supply

variables: money growth, government expenditure as well as energy prices.

Separate regressions were estimated for each variant of the index.

3. The trend variable is excluded in the estimation of ΔU*t as it was not in

the original unemployment specification.

Money Growth Rate

ΔDMt = αo ΔDMt-1 + α1 ΔDMt-4 + α2 Δit-1 + α3 gt-1 + α4 ΔRt-1

+ α5ΔUt-1 + α6ΔUt-2 + α7 ECMt + seasonal dummies + DMRt

where ECMt = DMt - β1yt - β2 pt + β3 T + β4Rt + β5Ut,, y is income, p is

prices, T is the time trend, i is the inflation rate, g is government deficit and

R is the interest rate. Palley (1992)

U.S., 1951-1988, Aggregate-level time-series quarterly data (seasonally-adjusted). Method of Estimation Maximum likelihood estimation (MLE) for single-equation regression.

3 3

Ut = βo + ∑ β1jζa2

t(p)-j + ∑ β2 jζa2

t(up)-j + β3 Tt + β4 Ut-1 + εt

j=0 j=0

Note: Ut is seasonally-adjusted.

77

Table 4.4 Unemployment and Money Growth Equations used

in Selected Studies of Sectoral Mobility (continued) Study Country/ Time

Period/Data-

type/Method of

Estimation for

Aggregate

Unemployment

Model Specification

Parker

(1992)

U.S., 1956-1987,

Aggregate-level time-

series annual data.

Method of Estimation

Joint-estimation of the

unemployment and

money growth equation.

Aggregate Unemployment

Ut = βo + β1 ζt + β2 DMRt + β3 DMRt-1 + β4 DMRt-2 + β5 UIt + β6 MWt

+ β7 MILt + εt

Male Unemployment

UtM = βo + β1 ζt + β2 DMRt + β3 DMRt-1 + β4 DMRt-2 + β5 UIt + β6 MWt

+ β7 MILt + β8 ζrt + εt

Female Unemployment

UtF = βo + β1 ζt + β2 DMRt + β3 DMRt-1 + β4 DMRt-2 + β5 UIt + β6 MWt

+ β7 MILt + β8 ζrt + εt

Natural Unemployment Rate

U*t = βo + β1 ζt + β5 UIt + β6 MWt + β7 MILt

Money Growth Rate

DMt = α0 + α1 DMt-1 + α2DMt-2 + α3DMt-3 + α4FEDVt + α5UNt-1 + DMRt

Note:

1. MW is the ratio of federal minimum wage to economy-wide average

wage, UI is the ratio of unemployment insurance to average wage, MIL is

the number of military personnel per 1000 population and ζrt is the

dispersion measure for inter-regional mobility.

2. Regressions were estimated for the ζ based on inter-sectoral mobility (13

sectors) and inter-industry mobility (65 industries).

3. The dependent variable is the logarithm of Ut..

4. The disturbance term follows an AR(1) process. 5. The natural unemployment rate was estimated from the predictions of

the regression of aggregate unemployment. The trend variable is excluded

in the estimation of U*t as it was not in the original unemployment

specification.

Brainard and

Cutler

(1993)

U.S., 1948-1991,

Aggregate-level time-

series quarterly data.

Method of Estimation:

Single equation

regression.

Regression 1:

4 4

Ut = βo + ∑ β1j ζt-j + ∑ β2j CSVt-j + β3 Ut-1 + εt

j=1 j=1

Regression 2:

2 2

Ut = βo + ∑ β1j ζt-j + ∑ β2j CSVt-j + εt

j=1 j=1

Note: CSV is cross section volatility measure of the stock market.

The number of j lags are expressed in years in regressions 1 and 2.

Quarterly data are used in the regressions but the coefficients are expressed

in years, being the sum of coefficients for the quarters in that year.

Lu (1997) U.S., 1948-1994,

Aggregate-level time-

series annual/quarterly

data.

Method of Estimation:

Single equation

regression.

Regression 1:

3 2

Ut = βo + ∑ β1j ζt-j + ∑ β2j GDPGt-j + β3 Ut-1 + εt

j=0 j=0

Regression 2:

3 2

Ut = βo + ∑ β1j ζa1

t(up)-j + ∑ β2j GDPGt-j + β3 Ut-1 + εt

j=0 j=0

Note: GDPG is the real GDP growth. The regressions were estimated

using annual and quarterly series. The number of j periods refer to years

and quarters.

78

Table 4.4 Unemployment and Money Growth Equations used

in Selected Studies of Sectoral Mobility (continued) Study Country/ Time

Period/Data-

type/Method of

Estimation for

Aggregate

Unemployment

Model Specification

Loungani

and

Rogerson

(1989)

U.S., 1974-1984,

Aggregate-level time-

series annual data.

Method of Estimation:

Correlation Coefficient

Correlation Coefficient between Ut and ζt

Neelin

(1987)

Canada, 1961-1983,

Aggregate-level time-

series quarterly data.

Method of Estimation:

2SE.

Aggregate Unemployment

Regression 1:

4 8 8

Ut = βo + ∑β1jζt-j + ∑β2jDMRt-j + β3T + ∑ β4jUt-j + β5 SDt + εt

j=0 j=0 j=0

Regression 2:

4 4 8 8

Ut= βo +∑β1jζt(p)-j + ∑β2jζt(up)-j + ∑β3jDMRt-j + β4T + ∑ β5jUt-j + β6SDt + εt

j=0 j=0 j=0 j=0

Note: SD is the sum of seasonal dummies. The derivation of SD was not

specified in Neelin (1987).

Money Growth Rate

6 6 6

DMt = α0 + ∑ α1j U.S. GNPt-j + ∑ α2j U.S. Ut-j + ∑ α3jU.S. BILLt-j + j=0 j=0 j=0

6

∑ α4U.S. EXt-j + DMRt j=0

Note: U.S. GNP is the logarithm of real GNP, BILL is the 3-month treasury

bill rate and EX is the logarithm of U.S. exports. The U.S. variables were

included to avoid simultaneity bias.

Samson

(1985)

Canada, 1957-1983, Aggregate-level time-series annual data. Method of Estimation: 2SE.

Aggregate Unemployment Regression 1: Ut = βo + β1 ζt + β2DMRt-1 + β3 Ut-1 + β4T + εt Regression 2: Ut = βo + β1 ζt + β2DMRt-1 + β3 Ut-1 + β4 LFPRWt + εt Note: LFPRW is the ratio of women in labour force to total labour force Regression 3: Ut = βo + β1 ζt + β2DMRt-1 + β3 Ut-1 + β4 U.S. Ut + β5T + εt Regression 4: Ut = βo + β1 ζt + β2DMRt-1 + β3 Ut-1 + β4 U.S. U*t + β5 U.S. MSt

+ β6 U.S. MSt-1 + εt Note: MS is money supply. The sample period for regression 4 is 1957-1980. Natural Unemployment Rate (from Regression 3) U*t = βo + β1 ζt + β3 U*t-1 + β4 U.S. Ut + β5T As initial U*t-1 was not observable, actual U was used for the first observation. The value obtained was substituted back into the equation to generate the next U* until the last observations of ζt, U.S. Ut and T were utilized. Money Growth Rate DMt = α0 + α1 DMt-1 + α2DMt-2 + α3DMt-3 + α4FEDVt + α5Ut-1 + α6 DMtU.S. + DMRt Note: DMtU.S. is the U.S. M1 growth rate.

79

Table 4.4 Unemployment and Money Growth Equations used

in Selected Studies of Sectoral Mobility (continued) Study Country/ Time

Period/Data-

type/Method of

Estimation for

Aggregate

Unemployment

Model Specification

Saint-Paul

(1997)

France, 1964-1991,

Aggregate-level time-

series annual data.

Method of Estimation:

Graphical analysis.

Graphical analysis of Ut versus ζt

Garonna and

Sica (1997,

2000)

Italy, 1952-1994,

Aggregate-level time-

series annual data.

Method of Estimation:

2SE and graphical

analysis.

Aggregate Unemployment

Ut = βo + β1ζt(p) + β2ζt(up) + β3DMRt + β4DMRt-1 + β5Ut-1 + β6Ut-2 + εt

Money Growth Rate

∆Mt = α0 + β1∆Mt-1 + β2∆Mt-2 + β3GEXPVt + β4UEMPt + εt

DMt = α0 + α1 DMt-1 + α2DMt-2 + α3(GEXPDt – GEXPDt*) + α4UNt-1 +

DMRt

Note: ∆M is the actual money growth rate, GEXPV is the difference

between actual public and forecasted expenditure and UEMP is the ratio of

the unemployment rate to the employment rate.

Graphical analysis of Ut versus ζt.

Prasad

(1997)

Japan, 1970-1994,

Aggregate-level time-

series annual data.

Method of Estimation:

Graphical analysis.

Graphical analysis of annual employment growth versus ζt.

Note: Out of the above studies, only Abraham and Katz (1986), Garonna and Sica (2000) and Mills, Pelloni and

Zervoyianni (1995) mentioned using OLS as the method of estimation of the unemployment equation.

It is inferred that Brainard and Cutler (1993) and Lu (1996) employed least squares

regression in their model estimation8, with the underlying classical assumptions leading to

unbiased and consistent parameter estimates. Palley (1992) adopted Maximum Likelihood

Estimation (MLE) since the ζ‟s were generated regressors, and the OLS estimates will

therefore be consistent but inefficient [Pagan (1984) and Oxley and McAleer (1993)]. The

inefficient estimation arises with the predicted index as it is generated from an aggregate

employment equation and may be correlated with the error term of the unemployment

equation. This is not an issue, however, with the unpredicted index, which has been purged

of aggregate influences.

80

4.6.3.2 2-Stage Least Squares (2SLS)

To address the problem of the ζ‟s being generated regressors which could lead to

inefficient estimation, Palley (1992) also estimated the unemployment equation using Fair‟s

(1970) iterative 2SLS method corrected for second-order serial correlation. This procedure

is a combination of the grid search method used in some corrections for autocorrelation and

instrumental variables. It did not lead to any material change in the estimates compared

with Palley‟s (1992) MLE results that accommodate the serial correlation but not the

generated regressors issue. In other words, any inconsistency in the standard errors

associated with generated regressors in the estimating equation is inconsequential.

Subsequently, Palley (1992) focused only on the results that did not address the potential

problem of generated regressors. This is similar to the finding and approach in Mills,

Pelloni and Zervoyianni (1995) 9

.

4.6.3.3 Dual-Equation Models

The studies with dual-equation models use an aggregate unemployment equation and a

money growth equation of the following general form:

J J J

Ut = βo + ∑ β1j Xt-j + ∑ β2j Ut-j + ∑ β3j DMRt-j + εt (4.4)

j=0 j=1 j=0

J J J

DMt = βo + ∑ β1jDMt-j + ∑ β2j Ut-j + ∑ β3jYt-j + DMRt (4.5)

j=0 j=1 j=0

where the unanticipated money growth (DMR) is the residual of the money growth

equation and Y represents the current and/or lagged values of financial variables, e.g.

FEDV and the Treasury Bill. Compared to single-equation models, the DMR variable is

included as a regressor in equation (4.4) in order to capture the effects of an AD shock.

Several methods of estimating this type of model have emerged: 2-step estimation (2SE),

joint non-linear estimation and co-integration with error correction models.

81

2-Step Estimation

The majority of the studies that incorporate an unanticipated money growth variable adopt

Barro‟s (1977) 2-step method of estimation. These include Lilien (1982), Garonna and

Sica (2000), Abraham and Katz (1986), Neelin (1987), Loungani (1986) and Samson

(1985). The 2-step procedure involves the regression of:

i) DM on its lagged values and other variables to obtain DMR, the residual

(Equation 4.5);

ii) Ut on DMR (including other regressors) to estimate the impact of ζ on

unemployment (Equation 4.4).

Three areas of concern pertaining to the 2-step estimation can be noted. First, the 2SE

models share with single-equation models the potential problem of ζ being correlated with

other explanatory variables, as discussed earlier. Second, since DMR forms the unexpected

portion of money growth, it should be uncorrelated with any systematic components of

money growth. However, if the money growth equation is mis-specified (e.g. omission of

variables), DMR could be predictable and if so, capturing the element of a shock is lost in

the test of the hypotheses. Third, DMR, is a generated regressor from the money growth

model, and if measurement errors are neglected, the OLS estimates and standard errors will

be consistent but inefficient.

Lilien (1982) addressed the first problem by testing the orthogonality of DMR vis-à-vis ζ

by regressing ζ on its own lagged values and the current and lagged values of DMR. The

low R2 from the regression showed ζ to be exogenous, i.e. ζ captured the influence of real

variables only. Samson (1985) conducted tests for the correlation of DMR by regressing it

on all the right hand side variables of the DM equation plus its own lagged value. The low

t-statistic for the coefficient of DMRt-1 demonstrated DMR to be unpredictable. The

problem of generated regressors was addressed through joint non-linear estimation, which

has only been followed by Davis (1987) and Parker (1992)10

. The joint non-linear

estimation did not appear to lead to improvements in the quality of estimates, possibly

because cross-equation restrictions need to be adequately identified in accordance with a

clear knowledge of theoretical economic relationships11

. In line with more recent studies,

it will not be pursued in this thesis.

82

Cointegration and Error Correction Models (ECM)

An alternative method is co-integration with error correction models (ECM). The

advantage of this approach is that it incorporates the long run behavioural relationship of

money growth in the short-run co-integrating regression without any loss of efficiency or

consistency. Mills, Pelloni and Zervoyianni (1995) adopted this method to estimate their

model of money growth and unemployment. The money growth (ΔDM) equation was

expressed as an error correction model, i.e.

ΔDMt = βo Δ DMt-1 + β1 Δ DMt-4 + β2 Δ it-1 + β3 gt-1 + β4 Δ Rt-1 + β5 Δ Ut-1 +

β6 Δ Ut-2 + β7 ECMt + seasonal dummies + DMRt (4.6)

where ECMt is the error-correction term, i is the inflation rate, R is the interest rate and g is

the government deficit. The ECM term, expressed as a function of money growth, income

(y), prices (p), time trend (T), interest rates (R) and the unemployment rate (U), was

estimated as:

ECMt = DMt - β1yt - β2 pt + β3 T + β4 Rt + β5 Ut, (4.7)

and incorporated into the money growth equation (4.6). Equation (4.6) is an ECM since

the long run relationship of money growth is distinguished from the short responses of

other variables, ΔUt-j, ΔRt-1, Δit-j and ΔDMt-j. The co-integrating regression was estimated

using Stock and Watson‟s (1993) Dynamic Ordinary Least Squares (DOLS) method. In the

case of a single co-integrating vector with an I(1) system, the DOLS method essentially

involves regressing one variable on other contemporaneous regressors and their

corresponding leads and lags, as well as a constant, using OLS. Since the variables are co-

integrated in the regression and are integrated of the same order, the DOLS estimates are

argued to be asymptotically efficient. The authors have suggested that the methodology

adopted to estimate unanticipated money growth is a “clear improvement on the previous

approaches used to predict money growth in the sectoral shifts literature”.

The impact of ζ on unemployment was assessed using a co-integration equation. In this,

two conditions had to be met to ensure consistent and efficient estimates: (a) all variables

83

had to be stationary; and (b) the regression equation had to contain variables which were

integrated of order zero. Since the ratio of exports to GNP (x) and the logarithm of the

short-run interest rates (r) were I(1) and DME and DMR were both I(0), the first two

variables had to be differenced such that their series became stationary in the co-integrating

regression. The baseline unemployment equation (excluding ζ) was written as:

J J

ΔUt = ∑ β1jΔUt-j + ∑ ( β2j DMEt-j + β3jDMRt-j + β4j Δrt-j + β5j Δ xt-j ) + εt (4.8) j=1 j=0

The hypotheses were tested by including the first difference of the variants of ζ as

regressors. It is noted that in the final model (Table 4.4), the indices were differenced

several times for their series to be stationary.

Cointegration is not recommended for the current study. Mills, Pelloni and Zervoyianni

(1995) had a quarterly data series of about 124 observations, which far exceeds the 31

observations for the current work covering 1971-2001. The relatively short time span,

coupled with the low yearly data frequency, means that cointegration is not really a suitable

technique to apply, especially when studies have shown that increasing data frequency

yields considerable gains in power. Higher frequency data also perform better in tracking

historical relationships between variables [Ramirez and Khan (1999) and Zhou (2001)].

In terms of model estimation, 2SE is the recommended procedure for the current work.

Single-equation models are not relevant given the need to incorporate DMR. 2SLS could

be used to address the problem of generated regressors which may show up under 2SE, but

the choice of instruments is limited, and the findings by Palley (1992) indicate that the

issue is not paramount. Cointegration is not suited for the current study with the small

number (31) of observations. In applying a 2SE procedure, the empirical work of chapter 5

follows numerous reputable studies [Lilien (1982), Garonna and Sica (2000), Abraham and

Katz (1986), Neelin (1987), Loungani (1986) and Samson (1985)]. To assess whether

multicollinearity constitutes a problem, tests based on the DMR vis-à-vis ζ correlation will

be carried out. As economic time-series could be non-stationary, tests of stationarity will

be undertaken.

84

4.6.4 Model Specification

This section reviews the explanatory variables typically employed in the literature in terms

of practical relevance to the Korean economy and feasibility in modelling. Whilst the

model should capture explanatory variables linked to the contrasting predictions of the

hypotheses, there is a need to limit the number of model terms to minimise the chances of

multicollinearity.

4.6.4.1 Dependent Variable

The dependent variable in the majority of studies is the actual unemployment rate for the

current period. The exceptions are Mills, Pelloni and Zervoyianni (1995) and Palley

(1992), each of which treated the first difference and the logarithm of the unemployment

rate as the dependent variable12

. A reason for the former with quarterly data was to ensure

the series was stationary, established via first differencing (or logarithmic transformation)

[Coulson and Robins (1987)]. The logarithmic series was imposed as the series was

positive and the logarithmic transformation ensures that the predictions from the model are

also positive. For this thesis, the dependent variable will be the actual or change in the

unemployment rate, subject to tests of stationarity.

4.6.4.2 Explanatory Variables

In general terms, the explanatory variables employed in previous studies encompass the

mobility indices, lagged dependent variable, aggregate demand/supply, a time trend,

monetary factors and inter-country factors. More specifically, the variables comprise

aggregate demand policy indicators (DMR, DME, GNP, ratio of exports to GNP, short run

interest rate, government expenditure and the M2 multiplier), aggregate supply indicators

(post-1974 oil shock dummy variable), labour force characteristics (military personnel per

1000 population and working women/total labour force), monetary factors (ratio of federal

minimum wage to economy-wide average hourly earnings and ratio of recipients‟ average

weekly unemployment insurance to average weekly earnings of employed workers) and

inter-country influences (U.S. unemployment and U.S. money supply in the unemployment

model for Canada).

85

σ, Ut-j and DMR

Almost all studies include ζ, DMR and a lagged dependent variable. Hence, these three

variables should also be incorporated in the current study. The inclusion of the lagged

dependent variable was based on the assumption of a constant probability of finding a job

in every period in Lilien (1982). The inclusion of DMR has received considerable

empirical support and is consistent with rational expectation models of the way

unanticipated monetary policy influences the real economy.

Aggregate Demand Variables

Apart from DMR, DME [Davis (1987) and Mills, Pelloni and Zervoyianni (1995)], the real

GDP growth rate [Lu (1996)], government expenditure [Davis (1987)], exports and interest

rates [Mills, Pelloni and Zervoyianni (1995)] were some of the variables used to represent

aggregate demand disturbances. DMR, DME and interest rates represent influences

stemming from monetary policy. Government expenditure and exports variables were

incorporated to capture the effects of fiscal policy.

Mishkin (1982) and Gordon (1982) suggest that both DME and DMR affect output (and

unemployment). Moreover, the coefficient estimate of DME could indicate whether there

is long run neutrality of money growth on unemployment (The long run neutrality of

money growth exists if a permanent increase or decrease in money supply does not have

any long-term effect on the unemployment rate). The short-run interest rate in Mills,

Pelloni and Zervoyianni (1995) represented the influence of changes in the working-capital

costs of firms or of the inter-temporal substitution of leisure on unemployment. From the

theoretical perspective, therefore, there is a strong case to include the interest rate in the

estimating equation. However, the impact of the variable in Mills, Pelloni and Zervoyianni

(1995) was negative when a contemporaneously measured variable was used, and positive

when the third quarter lag was used. The effect may therefore be ambiguous if annual data

(i.e. sum of 4 quarters) are used.

Real government expenditure in the current period in Davis‟ (1987) annual time-series

study showed significant effects on the unemployment rate. Mills, Pelloni and Zervoyianni

86

(1995) found that the effect of the ratio of exports to GNP was positive for its 2nd

and 3rd

quarter lags but negative for its 5th

lag. On an annual basis, this means that the export

effect was positive up till 1 year, after which the effect worked in the opposite direction.

As Korea is an export-oriented economy with some degree of government intervention

[Hicks (1989)] via protectionism and trade barriers to imports, both the ratio of exports to

GDP (EX) and government expenditure are potential regressors. Following Barro (1977),

government expenditure will be used as a variable in the money growth equation in

deriving DMR. To prevent any likelihood of correlation, government expenditure will not

be included as a regressor in the unemployment model since it will already have been

included in the money growth model. The government deficit, expressed as a ratio of GDP

(G), will be used in the unemployment model to represent government intervention. The

real GDP growth rate will be excluded as it is unclear whether the disturbance it would

proxy is demand- or supply-induced, and hence the variable does not provide a basis for

testing the hypotheses of interest in this thesis.

Aggregate Supply variables

The post-1974 dummy (DUM74) in Davis (1987) captured the impact of supply shocks on

unemployment. This dummy had a significant effect on unemployment. The current work

will consider an oil shock variable. Rather than a dummy, which does not measure the

supply variable itself, an oil price indicator, i.e. producer price index for fuel (PPI), will be

included to capture the effects of aggregate supply on unemployment.

Time Trend

A time trend variable (T) was included in the unemployment equation of most studies to

capture demographic aspects as well as other time-varying behavioural characteristics of

the labour market (e.g. minimum wages). The inclusion of T together with the constant

term is equivalent to detrending the unemployment series so that its long run deterministic

behaviour [Harvey (1990)] can be analysed. This also ensures that the residuals are

stationary [Muscatelli and Hurn (1992)]. Whilst Lilien (1982) and Samson (1985) included

T along with the raw Lilien index, Neelin (1987) went further by including T together with

the predicted and unpredicted indicators. As the trend variable was significant and positive

87

in Lilien (1982) and Neelin (1987) [but not Samson (1985)], it is worth considering this

variable in the current study.

Other Factors

Two studies [Palley (1992) and Samson (1985)] included demographic characteristics of

the labour market: military population in the former and ratio of working women in the

latter. The military population is not relevant to Korea as it was included in Palley (1992)

to proxy the labour supply shortage in the U.S. arising from the 1960s Vietnam war, and no

major wars were fought by Korea during 1971-2001. Samson (1985) used the labour force

participation rate of women in place of the time trend variable, stating that it only captured

demographic changes13

. Given the limited degrees of freedom, and the fact that there are

many possible measures of demographic influences, a parsimonious approach via a time

trend variable is recommended for the current study.

Neelin (1985) included macroeconomic indicators for economies other than that being

studied. Specifically, the U.S. unemployment rate and money supply were considered in an

analysis of the Canadian economy. These variables are not relevant for Korea as they were

specific to Canada which has established ties with the U.S. Palley (1992) included

minimum wages and unemployment insurance14

. As the minimum wage law in Korea was

enacted by the U.N. only from December 1986, and unemployment insurance is not

applicable to all sectors/industries in Korea, these variables will not be used in the current

study covering 1971-2001 for all major sectors. The growth rate in the M2 multiplier in

Davis (1987) was included to control for the effects of the collapse of financial

intermediation during the 1930s [Davis (1987) and Bernanke (1983)]. This variable is

therefore not relevant for the current analysis.

Capital Measures

Brainard and Cutler‟s (1993) measure of a sectoral shock - cross section volatility for 49

industries listed on the stock market - impacted unemployment in the U.S. positively over

1948-1991. Shin‟s (1997a) inter-sectoral shock measure, derived from accounting data on

returns to capital of manufacturing industries, showed a positive impact on unemployment

88

for the U.S. during 1961-1991. Loungani, Rush and Tave (1990) used the stock market

dispersion index of price growth rates among different industries as a proxy for

intersectoral shocks. They showed that the lagged values of this measure had significant

impacts on the unemployment rate. However, the CSV15

, returns to capital measure and

stock market dispersion index cannot be considered as proxies for dispersion in sectoral

employment as they are measures of movements in physical capital rather than human

capital. These studies adopted such indicators to measure the reallocations of sectoral

shocks on the capital market rather than on the labour market. Furthermore, the stock

market measures have been criticized in that the stock prices respond to expected future

shocks rather than current shocks [Shin (1997a)].

In short, the preliminary baseline unemployment equation to test the SSH, ADH, RTH and

stage-of-the-business-cycle effect can be written as follows:

J J J J

Ut = βo + ∑ β1jζt-j + ∑ β2j (DMEt-j + DMRt-j) +∑ β3jDMEt-j +∑ β4jDMRt-j +

j=0 j=0 j=0 j=0

J

∑ β5j Ut-j + β6 EXt-1 + β7Gt-1 + β8 PPI + β9 T + εt (4.9)

j=1

where ζ is a generic index representing the variants of the mobility index, horizon

covariance index and the interaction variable, the term J is the number of lags to be

determined by the statistical significance of the jth

lagged variable16

, and the

inclusion/exclusion of the regressors indicated will be dependent upon tests for

multicollinearity. There may be a need to keep the number of lags to a minimum for an

annual data series like that available for Korea. It may also be necessary to reparameterise

the final unemployment equation to correct for the presence of a unit root via differencing

to ensure the series is stationary.

4.6.5 Number of σ’s in the Regression Equation

The number of regression equations varied among the studies testing the SSH and ADH.

Studies using the raw Lilien index have generally presented a regression equation with a

single sectoral shift variable [Lilien (1982), Samson (1985), Parker (1992), Davis (1987),

Loungani and Rogerson (1989), Neelin (1987), Loungani (1986) and Mills, Pelloni and

89

Zervoyianni (1995)]. A model with either the predicted or unpredicted index was estimated

in Lu (1996), Loungani (1986) and Mills, Pelloni and Zervoyianni (1995). In the latter

study, separate equations were estimated for each unpredicted index purged of different AD

variables. Neelin (1987), Garonna and Sica (2000) and Palley (1992), however, included

both the predicted and unpredicted indices in a single regression equation.

On the RTH, both the raw Lilien index and the horizon covariance index were included in

the unemployment model of Davis (1987). Although the reason for the inclusion of both

indices was not stated, this was probably done to: (i) examine the impact of the current

sectoral mobility in conjunction with its past labour reallocations; or (ii) have a nested

model to see which was preferred. Pertaining to the stage-of-the-business-cycle model, the

specification of Mills, Pelloni and Zervoyianni (1995) involves the inclusion of the raw

Lilien index and the interaction variable. Whilst the coefficient of the raw index captures

the impact on unemployment for periods when GDP does not exceed its trend value, the

coefficient of ζtSt shows the additional impact of the raw index during stages when GDP

exceeds its trend value. The impact of the Lilien index when GDP exceeds its trend value

will be given by the sum of the coefficients of ζt and ζtSt. Where multiple indices are

entered into a single equation, as in the case of ζt and ζH in Davis (1987), and ζt and ζtSt in

Mills, Pelloni and Zervoyianni (1995), their joint and individual significance should be

examined.

4.6.6 Natural Unemployment Rate Approach

There are several ways in which the natural unemployment rate has been computed in the

empirical literature. This section presents these and indicates the approach that will be

taken in the study of the Korean labour market in chapter 5.

Lilien‟s (1982) natural unemployment rate series was computed as:

U*t = ∑ βj2 (β0 + β1ζt-j + β3 Tt-j) (4.10)

j=0

where the natural unemployment rate, U*, was a function of unemployment in the

preceding period, sectoral mobility and a trend term. Whilst estimation of the natural rate

90

seems like a straightforward calculation, there are problems in practice. According to

Samson (1985), the concern is that “if the βj2 is relatively large (greater than 0.5), the

summation cannot be truncated to just a few years because the expression decays too

slowly.” This limitation is of particular concern to the application in chapter 5, since there

are only 31 observations for this research, and so the summation cannot be extended too far

as it would result in a loss of too many observations.

Loungani (1986) presents two models of the natural unemployment rate. The first

comprises the estimated coefficients of the intercept and predicted index. The second

specification contains the intercept and the unpredicted index. These models can be written

as:

J

U*t(s) = βo + ∑ β1j ζt(s)-j

j=0

J

U*t(r) = βo + ∑ β1j ζt(r)-j j=0

There are two limitations of this approach. First, Ut-1, an integral part of many other natural

unemployment rate series, was not used as it was not in the original unemployment model.

Second, the trend variable was excluded even though it was part of the model of

unemployment, and there does not seem to be a reason for this omission. This suggests that

U* was probably just meant to solely capture the amount of unemployment attributable to

mobility.

Parker (1992) set the natural rate to be dependent on the estimated coefficients of an

intercept, the Lilien index, unemployment insurance, minimum wages and military

population ratio. That is, U*t = βo + β1 ζt + β5 UIt + β6 MWt + β7 MILt. The latter three

variables were used as the unemployment model did not have a trend term. Since the

unemployment insurance, minimum wages and military population variable are not relevant

to the unemployment model of the current study (which has a trend term), Parker‟s (1992)

version is not applicable. However, their use by Parker (1992) indicates that the time trend

coefficient should be used when computing U*.

91

Mills, Pelloni and Zervoyianni (1995) computed three versions of the natural rate, with

each of these depicting raw mobility, pure mobility and movements arising from the stages

of the business cycle. They can be depicted as follows:

ΔU*t = β1Δζt + β2Δζt-1 + β3Δζt-2 + β9ΔUt-2 + β10Δ Ut-4 + β11 ΔUt-5 + β12 ΔUt-6

ΔU*t = β1ζt(up) + β2ζt-4(up) + β8ΔUt-2 + β9ΔUt-4 + β10 ΔUt-5 + β11 ΔUt-6

ΔU*t = β1Δζt + β2 Δζt-1 + β3 Δζt-2 + β4 Δ(Stζt + St-1ζt-1) + β10ΔUt-2

+ β11ΔUt-4 + β12 ΔUt-5 + β13 ΔUt-6

The approach taken by Mills et al. (1995) shows that computation of the natural rate need

not be limited to the raw index but rather can be easily extended to the other forms of

mobility indices.

Samson‟s (1985) version (i.e. U*t = βo + β1 ζt + β3 U*t-1 + β4 U.S. Ut + β5 T ) not only

included the intercept, Lilien index and time trend variables, but the U.S. unemployment

rate and lagged value of the Canadian natural unemployment rate as well. For the latter, as

the initial value was not observable, the actual unemployment rate was used instead. The

U* value obtained was then substituted back into the equation to generate subsequent U*

values until all observations of ζt, U.S. Ut and T were used. This method is not feasible for

the current study for two reasons. First, the U.S. unemployment rate is not relevant in the

current study, as noted previously. Second, the method of using actual U for the first

observation will bias the results. Although it is stated in the study that the bias effect

decreases rapidly, this is not the case for Korea since 1970, i.e. the initial observation

period, occurs during the start of the oil crisis when the actual unemployment rate was high,

at 4.5%. A separate estimation of the Korean natural unemployment rate along the lines of

Samson‟s (1985) equation, excluding the U.S. Ut term (i.e. U*t = βo + β1 ζt + β3 U*t-1 +

β4 T ) gave rise to a high estimated natural rate of 2-5% throughout 1970-2001, which is

contrary to the natural rate series of being less than 2% in the empirical literature [Hayafuji,

Ikeda and Yamada (2003)].

What is apparent from most of the studies reviewed above is that U* is intended to capture

sectoral movements (via the ζ‟s) and the trend term (provided it is in the original

specification). Aggregate demand/supply variables are excluded on the premise that the

92

natural U* represents frictional unemployment brought about by inter-sector movements.

Hence, computation of the natural unemployment rate for the current work could be based

on an equation like the following:

U*t = β2 (β0 + β1ζt + β3 T) (4.10‟)

where ζ represents variants of the mobility indices, as in the case of Mills, Pelloni and

Zervoyianni (1995). The number of lags for ζ to determine U*t will be equivalent to those

adopted for the actual unemployment equation.

U* reflects frictional unemployment, and its links to U provide information on the SSH.

A close correlation is expected under this hypothesis as unemployment under the SSH

should be frictional. As such, the correlation coefficient between U*t and Ut has been used

to test the SSH.

In addition, Lilien (1982) and Loungani (1986) analysed the correlation coefficient of the

detrended series of U*t and Ut. The former detrended U*t by replacing the value of the

time trend in equation (4.10) with its average value over the period. It is noted that the

actual aggregate unemployment (Ut) was not detrended. The latter did not specify how U*

was detrended. However, it was reported that whilst U*t(s) accounted for 20% of the

variance of the detrended series, U*t(r) accounted for less than 5%. This approach of

detrending the U*t in Lilien (1982) could be applied to the current work.

It should be emphasized that construction of the natural unemployment rate series will be

undertaken provided the SSH can be shown to be valid in the Korean labour market.

4.6.7 Sectoral Mobility and Gender Unemployment

The review has focused on the impact of sectoral mobility on aggregate unemployment.

Sectoral mobility could have different impacts on the unemployment of men and women as

they differ in their sector-specific skills and experience. Recognising this, Parker (1992)17

analysed the impact of sectoral mobility (and inter-regional mobility, ζrt) on the male

93

unemployment rate (UtM

) and female unemployment rate (UtF) for the U.S. over 1956-1984

using the following estimating equations:

UtM

= βo + β1 ζt + β2 DMRt + β3 DMRt-1 + β4 DMRt-2 +

β5 UIt + β6 MWt + β7 MILt + β8 ζrt + εt (4.11)

UtF = βo + β1 ζt + β2 DMRt + β3 DMRt-1 + β4 DMRt-2 +

β5 UIt + β6 MWt + β7 MILt + β8 ζrt + εt (4.12)

It is noted that none of the explanatory variables are gender specific. It was found that the

raw Lilien index affected both male and female unemployment positively, although the

sectoral mobility appeared to have a stronger effect on males, with the statistically

significant parameter estimates for ζ being 0.0368 and 0.0234 for male and female

unemployment, respectively. Subject to the analysis of aggregate unemployment for

Korea, separate analyses of the impact of sectoral mobility on male and female

unemployment could be undertaken.

4.7 SUMMARY OF EMPIRICAL APPLICATION

The proposed empirical application for Korea can be summarized as follows:

a) The baseline time-series model to test the SSH, ADH, RTH and stage-of-the-

business-cycle effect will be as per equation (4.9). The explanatory variables

will be subject to tests for multicollinearity. All variables will be subject to tests

of stationarity, and differenced if necessary. The number of lags for each

explanatory variable will depend on the statistical significance of the lagged

variables, but lag length will be kept to a minimum for the annual data series

available for Korea.

b) The data to be used are aggregate-level time-series annual data covering 1971-

2001.

c) Compared to the other methods of model estimation, the 2SE procedure is the

recommended approach for the current study.

d) The models adopting the raw Lilien index and predicted and unpredicted indices

will be based on a single regression for each index. When the horizon

94

covariance index and interaction variable are considered, their impacts will be

estimated jointly with that of the raw Lilien index.

e) The natural unemployment rate equation is as specified in equation (4.10‟), with

the number of lags for ζ corresponding to the actual unemployment model. The

correlation coefficient of U* and U will be examined as a further test of the

SSH. Computation of the natural rate series is subject to the SSH being shown

to be valid in the Korean labour market.

f) The impact of sectoral mobility on the male and female unemployment rates

could be assessed separately, based on the model of equation (4.9). The merit of

this extension will, however, depend upon the results from the analysis of the

determinants of aggregate unemployment.

4.8 LINKS WITH RESEARCH ON DETERMINANTS OF MOBILITY

This chapter has provided an assessment of the empirical findings from research on the

impact of sectoral mobility on unemployment. It has used this review material to outline a

framework for a related study of the impact of sectoral mobility in the Korean labour

market. It concludes by linking the research on the impact of sectoral mobility with the

determinants of sectoral mobility, which constitutes the second part of this thesis.

The empirical study of sectoral mobility started with recognition of its impact on

unemployment in the seminal paper by Lilien (1982). This sparked a series of debates on

the SSH, later branching out to the ADH, RTH and stage-of-the-business-cycle effect. The

review of this chapter has drawn attention to the pertinent issues associated with index

construction, model testing and application of the results (e.g. finding U*t).

All studies on the mobility-unemployment relationship use aggregate-level time-series data.

This essentially takes the mobility that leads to unemployment as „given‟, or at best, being

caused by broad indicators of aggregate demand or aggregate supply. But how are these

changes in aggregate-level indicators linked to individual decision making? What

motivates workers to move across sectors of employment? This information needs to be

known if any policy implications drawn from the studies are to be implemented.

95

The next chapter focuses on the assessment of the hypotheses for Korea using the

modelling techniques learnt from the literature. Since aggregate-level data are used, it

serves as a complement to the more detailed and focused work undertaken on the

determinants of mobility using micro-level data in the second part of this thesis.

Endnotes:

1. Mills, Pelloni and Zervoyianni (1995) did not provide a reason for why ζ purged of government debt

influences had a positive effect for a one-period lagged variable and a negative effect for a four-period lagged

variable.

2. Thomas (1996a) suggested Murphy and Topel‟s (1987a) finding of higher unemployment being

accompanied by low levels of inter-industrial mobility was not necessarily inconsistent with the SSH. With

the aid of a theoretical model, he showed that if sectoral shocks led the declining sector to displace workers,

such workers will not switch sectors even if there is a higher probability of a job offer in the expanding (new)

sector if the job offer probability is offset by reservation wage changes that lead workers to accept a job in the

former sector. In this instance, higher unemployment is accompanied by declining sectoral movements.

3. Brainard and Cutler (1993) used the estimation of the Beveridge Curve to conclude if CSV was a

reallocation variable and ζ was an aggregate shock variable. An outward shift of the Beveridge Curve owing

to higher sectoral reallocations (from an increase in CSV) and greater unemployment in some sectors,

accompanied by increased labour demand and job vacancies, would provide evidence of the CSV being a

sectoral reallocation variable. In contrast, aggregate shocks would move the economy along the Beveridge

Curve. As ζ was only significant in explaining short-term unemployment, it was suggested as reflecting

aggregate shocks.

4. The equation is expressed in logarithmic terms as in Brainard and Cutler (1993). Although quarterly data

from 1948-1991 were used, the CSV and ζ coefficients and standard errors were presented in terms of lagged

years for up till 4 years (covering 15 lagged quarters). The coefficients were for the sum of the coefficients

from 4 quarters in that year. The standard errors were for that sum.

5. Palley (1992) reported the coefficients of the mobility indices from a single-equation maximum likelihood

estimation (MLE) and also an Iterative 2-stage least squares estimation (I2SLS). The results from the MLE

and I2SLS were similar.

6. Although Lu (1996) did conduct a regression with DMR and reported the results to be similar.

7. Palley (1992) indicated that the „inclusion (of DMR) would be important if one were interested in

constructing a series for the natural rate and subscribed to the anticipated policy ineffectiveness solution.‟

8. Brainard and Cutler (1993) and Lu (1996) did not specifically mention that the method of estimation was

OLS.

9. Mills, Pelloni and Zervoyianni (1995) looked into the issue of generated regressors and found that it was

not important. They re-estimated the unemployment equation jointly with the money growth equation using

the approach of McKenzie and McAleer (1992), which enables efficient estimates to be obtained. The re-

estimation showed that the standard errors were only slightly larger, and coefficient estimates deviated

slightly from their original estimates, implying that there were no errors made in statistical inference in their

original estimation.

10. Parker (1992) adopted Mishkin‟s (1983) approach of joint estimation.

11. The rational expectations hypothesis implicitly assumes that only unanticipated movements in money

affect real economic variables, e.g. output, unemployment. Since Davis (1987) stated that the cross equation

restrictions are „implied by the forecasting mechanism‟, one of the restrictions could be that only DMR affects

unemployment. Following Barro‟s (1977) study showing that only DMR affects unemployment, it may be

possible to infer the cross-equation restrictions imposed by Davis (1987). From Table 4.4, given Davis‟

(1987) money growth and unemployment equations:

DMt = α0 + α1 DMt-1 + α2DMt-2 + α3BILLt + α4UNt-1 + DMRt (1)

12 9 12

Ut = βo + ∑ β1j ζt-j - ∑β2j DMRt-j + ∑ β3j DMEt-j + β4 DUM74 + β 5 μt-1 + β6 μt-2 + εt (2)

j=0 j=0 j=0

and applying Barro‟s (1977) proposition to equation (1) that DMR is obtained solely from the history of DM

gives:

96

DMt = α0 + α1 DMt-1 + α2DMt-2 + DMRt (3)

The estimated unemployment equation with the estimated DMR from equation (3) should have a poorer fit (as

proven by Barro (1977) for the U.S. for 1946-1973). Substituting into the estimated equation (2), from the ^ ^

condition that DMR ≡ DM - DM, where DM is from the estimated equation (1), the „reduced form‟ unemployment becomes a function of (DMt-1 …..DMt-j), DMEt-j , DUM74, BILLt and UNt-1. The restrictions could be that the parameters associated with DMEt-j, DUM74, BILLt and UNt-1 are zero, such

that Ut = f (DMt-1 …..DMt-j). Davis (1987) did mention that BILLt and UNt-1 did not enter the unemployment

equation except through the money growth equation. Hence, the cross-equation restrictions could be

tantamount to testing the joint hypothesis: H0: α3 = α4 = β3 = β4 = 0.

In the same manner, applying Barro‟s (1977) proposition to Parker‟s (1992) equations below:

DMt = α0 + α1 DMt-1 + α2DMt-2 + α3DMt-3 + α4FEDVt + α5UNt-1 + DMRt

Ut = βo + β1 ζt + β2 DMRt + β3 DMRt-1 + β4 DMRt-2 + β5 UIt + β6 MWt + β7 MILt + εt

gives the reduced form unemployment equation to be a function of (DM t-1 …..DMt-j), FEDVt, UNt-1, UIt, MWt

and MILt. It is possible that the restrictions would be akin to testing the joint hypothesis that the parameters

of FEDVt, UNt-1, UIt, MWt and MILt are zero (i.e. H0: α4 = α5 = β5 = β6 = β7 = 0), such that Ut = f (DMt-1

…..DMt-j).

12. In addition to the actual unemployment series, Palley (1992) applied log and semi-log transformations to

the functional specification. This implies that the logarithmic series of the unemployment rate was also used.

However, only the results of the linear form are reported in the study.

13. Although Samson (1985) argued its inclusion suggests the presence of something studies have not been

able to model.

14. 1986 is close to the year used to distinguish two phases of the Korean economic experience in the current

work (based on tests of structural change conducted in the next chapter). However, since it was revealed that

the estimated relationships were similar across these phases, the implication is that the minimum wage did not

have a major impact on the model of unemployment.

15. The CSV was also criticized by Thomas (1996a). Brainard and Cutler (1993) argued that since the CSV

explained long unemployment spells, it could adequately capture sectoral shocks which had a longer lasting

impact on the macroeconomy. However, Thomas (1996a) argued that given the possibility of sectoral movers

experiencing shorter unemployment spells (since a sectoral shock could raise the probability of a job offer in

the expanding sector), the CSV would prove to be an inadequate measure as it is meant to capture long

unemployment spells.

16. Accordingly, J can vary across variables.

17. The other studies mentioned did not analyse the impact of sectoral mobility on male/female

unemployment. However, Loungani and Rogerson (1989), with the use of micro-data, reported that during

periods of recession, i.e. 1975, higher sectoral movements were observed for U.S. males aged 25 years and

over. The measure for sectoral movements was taken as the sum of the absolute change in sectoral

employment shares.

97

CHAPTER 5

SECTORAL MOBILITY AND UNEMPLOYMENT:

AN EMPIRICAL EXAMINATION FOR KOREA

5.1 INTRODUCTION

Much has been debated about inter-sector labour movements and their impact on

unemployment. A large part of this debate has centered on establishing the empirical

relevance of the hypotheses: the Sectoral Shift Hypothesis (SSH), the Aggregate Demand

Hypothesis (ADH) and the Reallocation Timing Hypothesis (RTH). The literature review

of chapter 4 did not establish firm conclusions on the relative importance of these

hypotheses. Moreover, there was a lack of evidence on the links between unemployment

and worker mobility for South Korea1. Accordingly, the mobility-unemployment debate

needs to be pioneered for this country. This chapter examines the impact of sectoral

mobility on unemployment for the Korean labour market.

Prior to the formal regression analysis, section 5.2 provides an overview of the aggregate

unemployment data and information on sectoral mobility for Korea. The baseline

unemployment model suggested by the literature review is restated, and the mobility

indicators are described, in section 5.3. The methodological framework in section 5.4 gives

special attention to the specification of the unemployment models and mobility indices.

Tests for structural change and serial correlation are used to modify the initial specification

of the models. Section 5.5 presents the results of the final models of unemployment, and

the main conclusions on the validity of the hypotheses for Korea are stated in section 5.6.

For reference purposes, the Appendices provide information on the derivation and plot of

the mobility indices, results from tests of stationarity and multicollinearity,

CUSUM/CUSUMSQ statistics from tests of structural change, and the estimated

unemployment equations.

98

5.2 TRENDS IN AGGREGATE AND SECTORAL UNEMPLOYMENT

The trends in aggregate and sectoral unemployment in Korea are viewed on a decade-by-

decade basis, as fundamental changes appear more obvious when data are examined over

periods of this length. The analysis commences in 1971, since sector unemployment data

are available from that year, and the first decade covers 1971-1980 instead. It will be

demonstrated that unemployment within sectors reflects the overall trend. This is followed

by an examination of changes in sectoral employment vis-à-vis aggregate unemployment. If

a consistent co-movement is detected, e.g. if sector-specific mobility and unemployment

rates move in the same direction, it might be reasonable to expect that sectoral mobility

could lead to an increase in aggregate unemployment.

5.2.1 Aggregate and Sectoral Unemployment

The aggregate unemployment rate fluctuated over 1971-2000, escalating in the first decade,

falling in the second and going up again in the final decade (Table 5.1). Between 1971 and

1980, increased unemployment was experienced in many industries: manufacturing,

construction, commerce, transport, storage and communications, and financial, business

services and real estate. In the second decade, the drop in the overall unemployment rate,

from 5.2% to 2.4%, was mirrored in all sectors/industries. In the third decade, the greater

unemployment experienced in all sectors except mining contributed to the rise in the

overall unemployment rate, from 2.4% to 4.1%. Thus, increases (decreases) in aggregate

unemployment are typically associated with increases (decreases) in unemployment within

each sector/industry.

5.2.2 Sector-specific Employment and Unemployment

As sector employment data are available from the ILO, two informal measures of sector

mobility, namely, changes in the sectoral shares of total employment and average annual

growth in sectoral employment, can be computed2. The data presented in Table 5.1 shows

that the average annual growth in sectoral employment over the decades has no obvious

relationship with changes in sector unemployment rates. Sectoral employment can

sometimes increase whilst the sector unemployment decreases, or vice versa. At other

99

times, employment growth and the unemployment rate in the sector can move in the same

direction. The same observation applies to changes in the share of sectoral employment

and changes in the annual unemployment rate.

Table 5.1 Employment and Unemployment By Sector Employment Share (%) Unemployment Rate (%)

1971 1980 1990 2000 1971 1980 1990 2000

Agriculture 48.4 34.0 17.9 10.6 0.6 0.4 0.2 0.5

Mining 0.9 0.9 0.4 0.1 4.2 3.1 1.3

Manufacturing 13.3 21.6 27.2 20.3 3.9 6.0 1.5 3.1

Utilities 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.3 10.7 6.4 .0 1.5

Construction 3.5 6.2 7.4 7.5 4.7 12.9 2.6 7.3

Commerce 15.6 19.2 21.8 27.2 2.2 3.9 1.6 3.6

Transport, Storage &

Communications 3.7 4.5 5.1 6.0 4.9 5.4 1.4 2.8

Financial, Business Services

& Real Estate 1.3 2.4 5.2 10.0 2.9 4.3 1.5 2.6

Community, Social &

Personal Services 13.0 10.9 14.6 18.0 2.9 2.9 1.1 5.9

Total 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 4.5 5.2 2.4 4.1

Average Annual Growth (%)

Employment Unemployment Rate

1971-

1980

1980-

1990

1990-

2000

1971-

1980

1980-

1990

1990-

2000

Agriculture -0.5 -3.6 -3.6 -4.2 -9.7 13.2

Mining 3.4 -4.4 -14.2 -3.1 -8.8

Manufacturing 9.2 5.2 -1.3 5.0 -13.1 7.7

Utilities 6.5 4.8 -0.9 -5.6

Construction 10.3 4.8 1.6 12.0 -14.8 10.8

Commerce 5.8 4.2 3.8 6.8 -8.7 8.6

Transport, Storage &

Communications 5.9 4.1 3.2

1.0 -12.6 7.2

Financial, Business Services

& Real Estate 10.8 11.0 8.4

4.4 -10.3 5.9

Community, Social &

Personal Services 1.4 5.9 3.8

-0.1 -8.9 18.1

Total 3.5 2.8 1.6 1.6 -7.4 5.5

Source: ILO LaborStat database.

Note: Some cells for the mining and utilites sectors are blank as the unemployment data supplied in terms

of thousands was „0‟. As such, the rates/growths cannot be computed.

Hence, this casual inspection of the employment and unemployment data for Korea from

1971 to 2000 does not provide any real indication of either the direction or strength of the

co-movement between worker mobility and unemployment. Whether this is due to the

informality of the approach, or due to the absence of an underlying relationship, cannot be

determined here. With these issues at hand, there is a need for a formal examination of the

links between sectoral mobility and aggregate unemployment.

100

5.3 MODEL FRAMEWORK

5.3.1 Baseline Model

From the literature review of chapter 4, the baseline unemployment equation to test the

SSH, ADH, RTH and stage-of-the-business cycle effect can be restated as:

J J J J

Ut = βo + ∑ β1jζt-j + ∑ β2j(DMEt-j + DMRt-j) +∑ β3jDMEt-j +∑β4jDMRt-j +

j=0 j=0 j=0 j=0

J

∑ β5j Ut-j + β6EXt-1 + β7Gt-1 + β8PPI + β9T + εt (4.9)

j=1

The right-hand-side of equation (4.9) comprises a comprehensive list of feasible

explanatory variables from the empirical review. The key variable depicting sectoral

mobility is ζ, which represents the generic version of variants of the mobility index. The

comprehensive list of indices and representation for the symbols are listed in Table 5.2.

Following the critique of the indices in chapter 3, eleven indices will be utilised in this

chapter to test the hypotheses: SSH indices [i.e. ζt, ζm

t(up), ζgt(up), ζ

a2t(up), ζ

p1t(up), ζ

p2t(up)],

ADH indices [ζa2

t(p), ζm

t(p), ζgt(p)], the horizon covariance index (ζH) and the interaction

variable (ζtSt).

Although the focus is on the mobility indices as an explanation for changes in aggregate

unemployment, the other explanatory variables are important, as their inclusion/exclusion

could lead to misleading statistical inference. A substantial part of this chapter is geared

towards arriving at an appropriate functional specification.

5.3.2 Methodology

The derivation of each ζ adopts the methodology proposed by Lilien (1982), Abraham and

Katz (1986), Parker (1992), Palley (1992), Davis (1987), Mills, Pelloni and Zervoyianni

(1995), Lu (1996), Neelin (1987), Samson (1985) and Loungani (1986) [see chapter 4].

This methodology is applied to Korea using aggregate-level time-series NSO data for 1971-

2001. The formula for index derivation is provided in Appendix 5A. Corresponding with

101

the majority of the studies, annual data are used as some variables are not available on a

quarterly basis.

5.3.3 Descriptive Statistics

The literature review discussed conceptual differences between the various indices which

might account for the variation in the results for the studies conducted to date. To provide

insight into the nature of the indices, each series is plotted for Korea in Appendices 5B and

5C. Each purged index exhibits an oscillating pattern over 1971-2001, reflecting

unpredictability of pure sectoral movements. For each predictive series, since sectoral

labour movements are generated by aggregate demand and/or supply disturbances, a

fluctuating pattern is also observed. A fluctuating pattern is observed for the raw Lilien

index, which incorporates both predicted and unpredicted movements.

The fluctuating pattern in the raw Lilien index has also been reported for other countries,

including the U.S. [see Lilien (1982), Abraham and Katz (1986), Davis (1987), Mills,

Pelloni and Zervoyianni (1995) and Parker (1992)], Canada [Samson (1985)] and Italy

[Garonna and Sica (2000)]. The other studies did not provide the series (numeric or

graphical) for their predicted or unpredicted indices, and hence no comparison with Korea

can be made.

The pair-wise correlations revealed that the unpredicted indices were not highly correlated.

This is not surprising, since these indices have been purged of different demand/supply

factors, and the mobility that each captures should therefore be different.

Similarly, given that the predicted indices are generated by differing demand/supply

variables, the low correlations among them reported in Appendix 5C are to be expected.

This means that each index generally contains independent information.

102

Table 5.2 Symbols of Sectoral Mobility Symbol Description Developed by Used for test

of

ζt Raw mobility index. Lilien (1982) SSH

ζm

t(up) Mobility index purged of anticipated

and unanticipated money growth.

Mills, Pelloni and Zervoyianni (1995) SSH

ζgt(up) Mobility index purged of the share of

government deficit to GDP.

Mills, Pelloni and Zervoyianni (1995) SSH

ζa1

t(up) Mobility index purged of aggregate

employment growth.

Lu (1996) SSH

ζa2

t(up) Mobility index depicting the dispersion

in sectoral employment growth

attributable to sectoral factors.

Palley (1992) SSH

ζp1

t(up) Mobility index purged of changes in the

energy price index (EP).

Mills, Pelloni and Zervoyianni (1995) SSH

ζp2

t(up) Mobility index purged of changes in the

energy price index (EP) and a quadratic

series for changes in EP.

Mills, Pelloni and Zervoyianni (1995) SSH

ζt(r) Mobility index purged of changes in

PPI for fuel and sectoral employment.

Loungani (1986) SSH

ζt(s) Mobility index attributed to changes in

PPI for fuel and sectoral employment.

Loungani (1986) SSH

ζt(up) Mobility index purged of current and

lagged values of unanticipated money

growth, and sectoral and total

employment growth.

Garonna and Sica (2000) SSH

ζa2

t(p) Predicted mobility index whereby the

unanticipated deviations in the inter-

sector labour movements have been

removed from changes in aggregate

employment.

Palley (1992) ADH

ζm

t(p) Mobility index predicted from changes

in the anticipated and unanticipated

money growth.

Derived in this thesis ADH

ζgt(p) Mobility index predicted from changes

in the share of government deficit to

GDP.

Derived in this thesis ADH

ζt(p) Mobility index predicted from (i)

current and lagged values of

unanticipated money growth; and (ii)

sectoral and total employment growth.

Garonna and Sica (2000) ADH

ζH Termed as Horizon Covariance Index.

Mobility index taking into account

sectoral labour reallocations in previous

periods.

Davis (1987) RTH

ζtSt An interaction variable.

ζt is the raw Lilien index; St equals 1

when GDP exceeds trend GDP, and is

defined to equal 0 otherwise.

Mills, Pelloni and Zervoyianni (1995) Stage-of-the-

business-

cycle effect

103

SSH Indices

Table 5.3 presents the descriptive statistics of the indices. Starting with the raw Lilien

index measure, a mean of 0.0274 is recorded, close to the mean of 0.025 in Lilien (1982)

and Abraham and Katz (1986) for the U.S., and 0.02737 in Samson (1985) for Canada.

Table 5.3 Descriptive Statistics of Ut, DMRt and ζ Variable Mean Standard Deviation

Aggregate Unemployment

Ut 3.9257 1.4583

Unanticipated Money Growth

DMRt 0.0010 0.0405

SSH indices

Raw Index

ζt 0.0274 0.0082

Purged of AD Shocks

ζm

t(up) 0.1455 0.0713

ζgt(up) 0.0228 0.0097

ζa2

t(up) 0.3214 0.2700

Purged of AS Shocks

ζp1

t(up) 0.0251 0.0111

ζp2

t(up) 0.0294 0.0109

ADH indices

ζa2

t(p) 0.0266 0.0090

ζm

t(p) 0.1387 0.0739

ζgt(p) 0.0173 0.0033

Horizon Covariance Index

ζH 0.0003 0.0003

Interaction Variable

ζtSt 0.0097 0.0148

The unpredicted indices are sub-components of the raw index. However, there is no

requirement from the construction of the indices for the unpredicted and predicted values to

sum to the raw index: their relative magnitudes will vary according to the impact

(positive/negative) of the specific influence being purged in each instance. All one should

expect is that the means and variances of the additional indices will differ from those of the

raw index.

Among the indices purged of demand influences, ζgt(up) has a lower mean value than the

raw index, presumably reflecting the purging of government factors which have a

104

uniformly positive effect on the underlying employment series. In contrast, the mean value

of ζm

t(up) is larger than the raw index because the values for DMRt and DMEt are negative

for several years. The average value of ζa2

t(up) is larger than that of the raw index, and this

may follow from the greater variability of the within-sector growth than the across-sector

growth in Korea. There is no benchmark for the comparison between this index and the

raw index as the time-series data were not furnished in Palley (1992).

For the indices purged of oil price shocks, namely ζp1

t(up) and ζp2

t(up), only slight deviations

in the mean values from the raw index were found. Considering that the oil shocks occurred

in the 1970s, changes in the oil price (using the producer price index for fuel) are minimal

from 1980 onwards. Hence, the purging of oil price changes should not result in

significantly lower values.

ADH indices

The ADH index that has been investigated most thoroughly is that predicted from changes

in aggregate employment, namely, ζa2

t(p)3. The predicted ζ

a2t(p) had an average value

similar to the raw index, which is not surprising since both account for the deviation of

sectoral employment growth rates from the aggregate rate4.

The current study introduces two further indicators to test the ADH. This is done using

actual aggregate demand indicators, namely, the money supply in the economy and the

ratio of the public deficit to GDP. Sectoral movements predicted from these two indicators

can be denoted by ζm

t(p) and ζgt(p), which form the predicted counterparts of ζ

mt(up) and

ζgt(up), respectively. They can be derived as follows:

N

ζm

t(p) = [ ∑ (eit / Et) ((Δlog(eit ) - Δlog(Et))f)2]

½

i =1

where (Δlog(eit) - Δlog(Et))f) is the fitted value from the industry-specific regressions of

(Δlog(eit ) - Δlog(Et)) on DMRt, DMRt-1, DMEt and DMEt-1.

N

ζgt(p) = [∑ (eit / Et) ((Δlog(eit ) - Δlog(Et))

f)2]

½

i =1

105

where (Δlog(eit ) - Δlog(Et))f is the fitted value from the industry-specific regressions of

(Δlog(eit ) - Δlog(Et)) on Gt and Gt-1. Gt is the ratio of the government deficit to GDP in

period t. Each of the N sector‟s employment in period t is denoted by the sector‟s eit, and

aggregate employment in period t is denoted by Et.

The mean of ζgt(p) is lower than the mean of the raw index, since it only picks up the

predicted components of a mobility shift, and the proxy for fiscal influences used here

appears to have a relatively modest role in this regard. For ζm

t(p), the higher mean reflects

the greater influence of monetary factors on inter-sector movements. Compared to their

unpredicted counterparts, ζm

t(up) and ζgt(up), their mean values are slightly lower, suggesting

that unpredicted events may exert a slightly greater influence on inter-sector movements.

Horizon Covariance Index and Interaction Variable

The horizon covariance index has a substantially smaller average value than the raw index.

This is not surprising as inter-sectoral movements from past periods are deducted from

movements in the present period. The possible unsuitability of the horizon covariance index

for annual data series was noted earlier. Nonetheless, since it is the only index available to

examine the RTH, it should not be ruled out at this stage. Given its considerably smaller

value, the index will be scaled by a factor of 100 in the estimations below.

The lower average value of the interaction variable compared to the raw index merely

illustrates the higher number of periods which saw GDP being above its trend value. In

particular, GDP exceeded its trend value for 20 out of the 31 yearly observations.

5.3.4 Stationarity

The unemployment model encompasses a time-series framework and it is imperative that

the variables are stationary to reduce the likelihood of serial correlation which could lead to

inconsistent and inefficient estimates, and spurious regressions which give high R-squared

values leading to misleading statistical inference. Dickey-Fuller/Augmented Dickey-Fuller

tests for each variable were conducted and the results showing their order of integration are

106

in Appendix 5D. All explanatory variables were stationary, save for DME and PPI, which

became stationary after first-differencing.

5.4 DUAL-EQUATION MODELLING

Following the common practice in this field of research, this thesis adopts a 2-step

estimation procedure to estimate the impact of ζt on Ut. The first step involves estimation

of a money growth equation to obtain DMR, which is then included as a regressor in the

unemployment equation. At the second step, the hypotheses are tested, through analysis of

the links between ζ and Ut, with other variables, including DMRt, held constant.

5.4.1 Estimation of Money Growth Equation

5.4.1.1 Review of Empirical Studies Estimating DMRt

The money growth model used in this thesis is based on the adaptive expectations

framework, outlined in Barro (1977), and this approach has been followed in the relevant

comparison literature, e.g. Lilien (1982), Abraham and Katz (1986), Loungani (1986),

Garonna and Sica (2000), Neelin (1987) and Samson (1985). Whilst the first three studies

make use of the DMRt term revised in Barro (1981), the latter three embark on their own

estimations for Italy and Canada. Mills, Pelloni and Zervoyianni (1995) estimated the

DMRt term using co-integration methods.

This section presents an overview of the studies estimating DMRt. In the Barro estimation,

the specification of money growth is:

DMt = α0 + β1DMt-1+ β2DMt-2 + β3FEDVt + α2UNt-1 + DMRt ,

where money growth (DMt) is computed as DMt = log Mt – log Mt-1, where Mt is the annual

average of M1, FEDVt is the difference between the real (FED) and normal federal

expenditure, i.e. FEDVt ≡ log (FED)t – [log (FED)]*t, and UN is the ratio of the

unemployment rate to the employment rate, i.e. UNt-1 = log [U/(1-U)]t-15

. Since FEDVt is

107

not directly observable, the adaptive expectations hypothesis postulates that it can be

generated from the formula:

[log (FED)]*t = ρ [log (FED)]t + (1-ρ) [log (FED)]*t-1

with ρ being the adaptive coefficient. Based on the average annual growth rate of federal

expenditure in the U.S. from 1949 till 1973, Barro (1977) estimated that the adaptive ρ

coefficient was 0.2, and used this value to compute the expected federal expenditure, and

substituted FEDVt into the money growth equation above to obtain DMRt. With the use of

quarterly data, the money growth model for 1941-1973, with t-values in parentheses, gave a

good fit, with an R-squared of 0.9.

ˆ DMt = 0.087 + 0.024DMt-1+ 0.35DMt-2 + 0.082FEDVt + 0.027UNt-1

(2.81) (1.60) (2.69) (5.47) (2.70)

R-squared = 0.9, Sample size: 132

Using annual data, Samson‟s (1987) specification for the Canadian money growth equation

for 1954-1983 was as follows:

ˆ DMt = -0.01 - 0.05DMt-1 + 0.25DMt-2 + 0.36DMt-3 + 0.35FEDVt + 0.90DMU.S.t + 0.07Ut-1 (-0.1) (-0.3) (1.3) (1.9) (2.6) (2.6) (1.8)

R-squared = 0.48, sample size: 30,

with DMU.S.t being the U.S. money growth. Whilst the Canadian money variables were

insignificant, except for DMt-3 at the 10 per cent level, the U.S. variable was significant,

which suggests that U.S. money growth affected the Canadian money growth more than the

country‟s own.

Neelin‟s (1987) Canadian money growth model over the period 1954:4 till 1984:3 (i.e.

sample size: 116) also included U.S. variables, namely the current and six lagged values of

log real U.S. GNP, the U.S. 3 month treasury-bill rate, log exports and the U.S.

unemployment rate. The results of the money growth model were not reported but it was

indicated that the U.S. variables were included to avoid simultaneity bias6.

108

Though the results were not reported, Garonna and Sica (2000) indicated that their analysis

of the money growth rate7 with the use of annual data over 1952-1994 (i.e. sample size of

43) for Italy comprised the regression of the actual money growth rate (∆Mt) on its two

lagged values, the difference between actual public and forecasted expenditure (GEXPVt)

and the ratio of the unemployment rate to the employment rate (UEMPt), written as:

∆Mt = α0 + β1∆Mt-1 + β2∆Mt-2 + β3GEXPVt + β4UEMPt + εt

with εt as the error term. Using quarterly data from 1960-1991 with 128 observations,

Mills, Pelloni and Zervoyianni‟s (1995) co-integrating equation for the U.S. was:

∆mt = 0.166∆mt-1 + 0.264∆mt-4 + 0.526it-1 - 0.487gt-1 - 0.0051∆Rt-1 + 0.020∆Ut-1

(0.073) (0.069) (0.163) (0.158) (0.0014) (0.009)

+ 0.032∆Ut-2 - 0.104ECMt-1 + seasonal dummies + DMR1,

(0.008) (0.022)

where ECMt = mt - 0.543yt – 1.000pt + 5.685it + 0.027Rt + 0.108Ut

R-squared = 0.92

where m, y and p are the logarithms of M1, real GNP and the GNP deflator, respectively, U

is the logistic transformation of UN, R is the long-run interest rate, i is the inflation rate, g

is the ratio of the government deficit to nominal GDP, and ECM is the error correction term

for the co-integrating equation. The money growth equation (∆mt) was estimated using

OLS and the standard errors are shown in parentheses.

Mills, Pelloni and Zervoyianni‟s (1995) co-integration method with quarterly data cannot

be applied to Korea. More mileage can be obtained from cointegration with high frequency

data. The current study with annual data has a short data span of only 31 observations.

5.4.1.2 Application to the Korean Case

Consolidating the explanatory variables from the above studies, the money equation for

Korea for a total of J lags is:

J DMt = α0 + ∑ β1j DMt-j + β2GEXPDVt* + β3UNt-1 + β4CPINt-1 + β5GDPNt-1

j =1 + β6GNt-1 + DMRt

109

The number of lags (J) is dependent on the statistical significance of the lagged DM

variable. As in Barro (1977), the money equation is expressed in logarithmic terms where:

GEXPDVt* = ρlog(GEXP)t – (1-ρ)log(GEXP)t-1

CPINt = log CPIt – log CPIt-1

GDPNt = log GDPt – log GDPt-1

GNt = log Gt – log Gt-1

with ρ as the adaptive coefficient. The terms CPINt, GDPNt and Gt measure, respectively,

the inflation rate, economic growth and change in the ratio of government deficit to GDP.

The interest rate is excluded since the data series from the Bank of Korea only started from

the 1980s. The term GEXPDVt* measures the difference between real and expected

government expenditure. With regards to ρ, the average annual growth of real government

expenditure for Korea over 1971-2001 is 0.05, and the GEXPDVt* series is presented in

Appendix 5B8. None of the explanatory variables were highly correlated: the pairwise

correlation coefficients did not exceed 0.8. The econometric approach adopted involves

moving from a general to a specific model until all the variables are significant. In

particular, it was found that UNt-1 and DMt-1 could be omitted.

The estimated version of the money equation for Korea over the 1971-2001 period, with the

t-ratios in parentheses, was:

DMt = 0.016 – 0.4141DMt-2 – 1.080GEXPDVt* - 0.570CPINt-1 + 1.717GDPNt-1 (1.06) (-2.44) (-1.79) (-1.70) (5.73)

- 0.150GNt-1 + DMRt

(-2.98)

R-squared = 0.60

Sample size: 31

LM statistic = 3.84

With the exception of the constant term, all of the variables are significant at the 10% level.

The fit of the model (R2 = 0.6) does not match that of the U.S., where the R

2 is 0.90, and

this could be attributed to the greater importance of the lagged dependent variables when

quarterly data are used in the study for the U.S. The model‟s fit is slightly better than the

110

model for Canada in Samson‟s (1985) work, based on annual data and having a similar

number of observations. The LM statistic ( ʅ2(1) = 3.84) indicates the absence of first-order

serial correlation at the 5% level of significance.

The DMR series has been fluctuating over 1971-2001 (Figure 5.1). DMEt, the predictable

portion of money growth, is the fitted values from the regression, and it is used in the

construction of several indices (see Appendix 5A). Since DMRt will be used as a regressor

in the unemployment models, the correlation matrix for DMRt and the other variants of ζ

was computed. DMRt was lowly correlated with these indices: 0.275 for ζt, -0.099 for

ζa2

t(up), 0.112 for ζm

t(up), 0.213 for ζgt(up), 0.099 for ζ

p1t(up), 0.067 for ζ

p2t(up), 0.173 for ζ

a2t(p),

0.041 for ζm

t(p), -0.051 for ζgt(p), -0.140 for ζH and -0.124 for ζtSt. Multicollinearity should

not therefore be a problem in the unemployment model where only these variables are

considered.

Figure 5.1 DMRt Series

-0.10

-0.08

-0.06

-0.04

-0.02

0.00

0.02

0.04

0.06

0.08

0.10

0.12

1972

1974

1976

1978

1980

1982

1984

1986

1988

1990

1992

1994

1996

1998

2000

DMR

year

111

5.4.2 Specification of Unemployment Equation

5.4.2.1 Unrestricted to Restricted Models

The second step involves estimation of the unemployment model. The approach towards

arriving at the final model is, as with the money growth equation, to move from the general

to the specific. The explanatory variables suggested by the literature comprise

(DMR+DME), DMR, ∆DME, ∆PPI, EX, G and U. As each variable was stationary, the

unrestricted model is rewritten as9:

Ut = βo + β1ζ + β2(DMEt + DMRt)+ β3DMRt + β4DMRt-1 + β5∆DME + β6Ut-1

+ β7EXt-1 + β8Gt-1 + β9∆PPI + β10T + εt (4.9‟)

This is likely to be an over-parameterised model10

.

The criteria adopted in this study towards model specification are low multicollinearity, the

absence of serial correlation and a high adjusted R-squared value. Pre-tests to detect

multicollinearity are carried out as serial correlation and the fit of the model are visible only

in the actual model estimation itself. The main practical test is the „R-squared delete‟

regression, a regression of each explanatory variable on all other variables, with a high R-

squared (or multiple correlation coefficient) being indicative of multicollinearity. The rule

of thumb is to delete variables where the R-squared from the individual tests is greater than

or equal to the R-squared of the original model of equation (4.9‟).

The relationships among all the explanatory variables were examined using a two-step

procedure. First, to determine if a pair of variables is highly correlated in the binary sense

(i.e. simple correlations), the benchmark used is a correlation coefficient of at least 0.5.

Second, the R-squared delete regression and its rule of thumb is then applied to variables

with a high correlation coefficient.

A „high‟ degree of correlation exists between DMRt and (DMRt+DMEt), ∆PPI and Ut-1, Gt-1

and T, and EXt-1 and (DMRt+DMEt) [Appendix 5E]. The R-squared delete regression was

first applied to (DMRt+DMEt), since it was highly correlated with the greatest number of

112

variables, with the specification of the estimating equation varying according to ζ. These

auxiliary regressions gave R-squared values greater than those of the original model. The

high value is due to its „high‟ correlation with DMR, with a coefficient of 0.6. Since DMt =

(DMRt+DMEt), this means that the unanticipated component of money growth is

accounting for a substantial portion of the change in actual money growth, and so the

information content of (DMRt+DMEt) itself will be minimal if DMR is included.

The variables with the next greatest number of „high‟ correlations were T, Gt-1 and EXt-1.

The R-squared delete regressions of T with each ζ resulted in R-squared values equal to or

greater than those of the original model (excluding DMRt+DMEt) for all ζ‟s except ζp1

t(up)

and ζtSt. For the latter two indices, the R-squared was only 0.1 point lower than the

original. Hence, T will be dropped from the model.

The regressions for EXt-1 gave R-squared values that were not uniformly greater or lower

than that of the original model (excluding DMRt+DMEt) for the various indices, and given

this, EXt-1 will not be removed at this stage. Also, the variable Gt-1 will not be omitted, as

its regression gave R-squared values that were lower than or equal to the R-squared values

of the original model (excluding DMRt+DMEt).

The R-squared delete regression for each of the ζ‟s gave R-squared values which were

lower than that of the original model [excluding T and (DMRt+DMEt)], indicating that

multicollinearity was not an issue. The independent regressions of Ut-1, Gt-1, EXt-1, ∆PPI

and ∆DME on all variables except T and (DMRt+DMEt) gave R-squared values that were

lower than the R-squared value of the original model.

These preliminary analyses therefore indicate that to minimize multicollinearity, only T and

(DMRt+DMEt) need to be omitted, resulting in the model outlined below.

Ut = βo + β1ζ + β2DMRt + β3DMRt-1 + β4∆DME + β5Ut-1

+ β6EXt-1 + β7∆PPI + β8 Gt-1 + εt (4.9a)

The deterministic behaviour of the explanatory variables of equation (4.9a) varies with the

index type. A preliminary estimation showed a number of insignificant variables for each

113

index. In moving towards a restricted model, one or two insignificant variables are omitted

at a time until the final model shows most variables to be significant. This is done to

ensure that there is no inadvertent omission of a significant variable (Hendry and Krolzig

(2001)]. In this process, those variables that were formerly significant remained so.

Depending on the model fit and the regression‟s standard error, one insignificant variable

can be tolerated. For instance, if model I with all significant variables has a lower fit and

higher standard error than model II with one insignificant variable, then the decision is to

select model II. In this instance, model II will have a higher adjusted R-squared and the

absolute t-value of that one insignificant variable will be greater than one, albeit not

sufficiently high to cross the 95% level of significance. By doing so, this leads to a

different specification for each index, and their restricted models, now termed as equation

(4.9a), are shown below.

For ζt and ζgt(up): Ut = βo + β1ζ + β2DMRt-1 + β3Ut-1 + β4EXt-1 + εt

For ζa2

t(up), ζm

t(up), ζm

t(p), ζgt(p) and ζ

a2t(p):

Ut = βo + β1ζ + β2DMRt-1 + β3Ut-1 + β4∆PPI + εt

For ζp1

t(up): Ut = βo + β1ζ + β2DMRt-1 + β3Ut-1 + β4∆PPI + β5Gt-1 + εt

For ζp2

t(up) and (ζt, ζH*100): Ut = βo + β1ζ + β2DMRt-1 + β3Ut-1 + β4∆PPI + β5 EXt-1 + εt

For (ζt, ζtSt): Ut = βo + β1ζ + β2Ut-1 + β3∆PPI + β4EXt-1 + εt

Compared to other studies using dual-equation models to test the SSH and ADH [Lilien,

(1982), Abraham and Katz (1986), Neelin (1987), Garonna and Sica (2000), Loungani

(1986) and Samson (1985)], the model of equation (4.9a) is more complex in that aggregate

demand (Gt-1, EXt-1) and aggregate supply (∆PPI) variables are included. Nonetheless, the

specification of the empirical studies noted above needs to be considered here for purposes

of comparison (i.e. a benchmark specification). Accounting for the appropriate number of

lags, the benchmark specification applied to Korea is:

Ut = βo + β1ζ + β1DMRt + β2DMRt-1 + β3Ut-1 + β4T + εt (5.1)

114

Hence, two restricted models, in equations (4.9a) and (5.1), will be estimated in this thesis.

These models are non-nested. Whilst the model of equation (5.1) has been adopted in most

empirical studies, the model of equation (4.9a) is an alternative model distinguished by the

inclusion of additional variables. The inclusion of these variables provides a basis for a

more complete understanding of the determinants of unemployment.

5.4.2.2 Preliminary Model Estimation

Having arrived at the restricted models, a preliminary estimation of the models is

undertaken to assess the robustness of the results, in that the statistical significance of

variables should, where appropriate comparisons can be made, be consistent across the

models, identifying problems (e.g. serial correlation) and possibly to narrow to a more

parsimonious specification. As such, no references to the other empirical studies will be

made in this sub-section. Also, establishing consistency in statistical significance is

essential since equation (4.9a) is more encompassing and the statistical significance in

equation (5.1) could be a case of omitted variables bias.

The SSH indices generated mixed results. Under equations (4.9a) and (5.1), ζt had a

significant, positive impact on aggregate unemployment (Table 5.4). Similarly, ζp1

t(up) and

ζp2

t(up), were associated with significant and positive impacts in both equations. For ζgt(up),

the higher the inter-sector labour movements in Korea, the higher the rate of unemployment

under equations (4.9a) and (5.1). ζm

t(up) and ζa2

t(up), however, were insignificant in each of

the equations examined.

The three ADH indices capturing mobility shifts predicted by aggregate demand

disturbances, ζa2

t(p), ζm

t(p) and ζgt(p). were insignificant for equations (4.9a) and (5.1). The

non-significance of ζa2

t(p) could reflect the shortcomings of index construction, as

highlighted earlier. The lack of significance for the ζm

t(p) and ζgt(p) variables suggests that

inter-sector movements brought about as a consequence of public budgetary considerations

or from monetary policy are not the cause of unemployment. As these policies are not

targeted on specific sectors (as measured here in the case of fiscal policy), these findings

are intuitively reasonable.

115

Table 5.4 Initial Parameter Estimates of ζ Regression with: Equation (4.9a) Equation (5.1)

Coefficient Adjusted R2 Coefficient Adjusted R

2

SSH indices ζt 66.279

(3.57) 0.628 63.753

(2.84) 0.567

ζ

mt(up) 2.929

(1.40) 0.509 3.512

(1.54) 0.477

ζ

gt(up) 59.688

(4.44) 0.685

54.755 (3.77)

0.635

ζa2

t(up) 0.957 (1.95)

0.525 1.112 (1.73)

0.489

ζp1

t(up) 57.142 (4.87)

0.719 56.363 (4.34)

0.674

ζp2

t(up) 52.495 (3.96)

0.663 34.266 (2.34)

0.530

ADH indices ζ

a2t(p) 5.766

(0.33) 0.474 -0.764

(-0.04) 0.428

ζ

mt(p) 2.820

(1.38) 0.508 3.060

(1.44) 0.472

ζgt(p) 11.183

(0.40) 0.475 -1.885

(-0.07) 0.428

Horizon Covariance Index ζt 62.432

(3.29) 0.627 69.067

(2.68) 0.553

and ζH*100 -3.841

(-0.73)

2.664

(0.44)

Interaction Variable

ζt 43.708

(2.61)

0.693 54.443

(2.10)

0.559

and ζtSt 31.450

(3.33)

8.560

(0.74)

Note: t-values in parentheses.

The raw Lilien and horizon covariance indices were incorporated into equations (4.9a) and

(5.1). Under each equation, the horizon covariance index was insignificant, corresponding

to the outcome in Davis (1987) for the U.S. using the annual data series for ζHt-1. This could

mean that the horizon covariance index should simply not be applied to annual data.

Likewise, the raw Lilien index was included together with the interaction variable ζtSt in

the current study. The results were inconsistent across the two restricted models. Whilst

the interaction variable showed a positive and significant coefficient under equation (4.9a),

it was insignificant under equation (5.1).

The preliminary estimation of the restricted models for the SSH, ADH and RTH indices

and the interaction variable therefore reveals mixed results. Whilst the estimated impacts

of some indices are consistent under alternative model specifications, the results also show

a lack of robustness of the estimates for other indices. Hence, there arises a need for further

116

consideration of the model. One issue that is an obvious candidate for examination is

structural change. This is examined below.

5.4.3 Structural Change

Considering that the data period extends over 30 years (1971-2001), and the world

economy experienced several shocks during this time (due to rises in oil prices in the

1970s, 1998 Financial Crisis), it is possible that a structural change occurred in the ζ-U

relationship for Korea. If this is the case, the results from Table 5.4 become invalid.

Statistical tests of structural change are applied in this section. Apart from Davis (1987),

who used a dummy variable (DUM74) to incorporate the impact of the oil shock, the other

empirical studies on the ζ-U relation do not consider the possibility of a structural change

in their models.

5.4.3.1 Prior Knowledge on Korean Unemployment

The detection of a structural break requires prior knowledge of a country‟s economic

experiences. Since the model attempts to explain unemployment, the categorization should

be based on the unemployment rate. From Table 2.1 and information on the Korean

economy in chapter 2, 3 distinct stages can be distinguished: Stage 1: 1970-1986

(unemployment of 3-5%); Stage 2: 1987-1997 (2-3%); and Stage 3: 1998-2001 (3-7%).

Since each stage is characterized by such different unemployment rates, there is a

possibility of a structural break between the phases. Armed with this, tests of model

stability, e.g. cumulated sum of residuals (CUSUM) and the squares of the residuals

(CUSUMSQ) tests are conducted.

5.4.3.2 Tests for Model Stability

CUSUM and CUSUMSQ Tests

The CUSUM and CUSUMSQ tests offer a general insight into whether models are stable

(i.e. coefficients remain constant) over time. Whilst a cost of this generality is limited

power, the tests nevertheless are often used to assess if models are stable, and where

117

instability is detected, the approximate dates where the structural change occurred. More

powerful techniques, such as a Chow test, or re-specification through the use of dummy

variables, can then be considered.

Appendix 5F shows the CUSUM and CUSUMSQ statistics for each index in graphical

form. Table 5.5 presents the CUSUM and CUSUMSQ statistics for equations (5.1) and

(4.9a) for the mobility indices. Looking at equation (5.1), the CUSUM stays within the

upper and lower boundaries for all the ζ‟s throughout the 31-year period. The CUSUMSQ,

however, is outside the confidence bounds for all the ζ‟s, suggesting parameter instability.

In the case of the SSH indices, the CUSUMSQ drifted outside the boundaries for the

1990/92-1997 period for ζt, ζm

t(up), ζa2

t(up) and ζp2

t(up). For ζp1

t(up), the CUSUMSQ is outside

the confidence bounds for 1981-1984. For ζg

t(up), the CUSUMSQ moves out of the

boundaries during 1980-1984 and 1996-1997. The ADH indices have a less common

configuration in terms of the time-frame in which the CUSUMSQ has drifted outside of the

confidence intervals, i.e. 1982-1997 for ζa2

t(p), 1970-1985 and 1996-1997 for ζm

t(p) and

1981-1984 and 1995-1997 for ζgt(p). For the horizon covariance index and interaction

variable, the CUSUMSQ shows that parameters are unstable during 1981-1993 and 1991-

1997, respectively. The general outcome is post-1997, where the CUSUMSQ statistic

returned to the confidence bounds for all indices11

.

With regards to the model of equation (4.9a), the CUSUM remains within the upper and

lower confidence intervals for all the ζ‟s for 1971-2001. Unlike the CUSUM statistic, the

CUSUMSQ statistic deviates outside the boundaries for all the ζ‟s, suggesting parameter

instability. Among the SSH indices, the CUSUMSQ is outside the confidence intervals

during 1988-1997 for ζm

t(up), 1983-1997 for ζa2

t(up), 1995-1997 for ζp1

t(up) and 1990-1997

for ζp2

t(up). For ζt and ζgt(up), only two phases are identified, where the CUSUMSQ is

outside the boundaries for the period 1970-1996. Like the SSH indices, the ADH indices

portray varied time intervals in which the CUSUMSQ has drifted outside of the confidence

bounds, i.e. 1985-1997 for ζa2

t(p), 1992-1997 for ζgt(p) and 1990-1997 for ζ

mt(p). The

horizon covariance index showed parameter instability during 1979-1981 and 1991-1997,

whilst the interaction variable exhibited unstable parameters during 1986-1997. The

common outcome is the post-1997 period, where the CUSUMSQ statistic returned back to

the confidence boundaries for nearly all indices.

118

Table 5.5 Phases in the Korean Labour Market from the CUSUMSQ Test Variable Phase 1 Phase 2 Phase 3

Equation (5.1)

SSH indices

ζt 1970-1991 1992-1997* 1998-2001

ζm

t(up) 1970-1989 1990-1997* 1998-2001

ζgt(up) 1970-1979 1980-1984* 1985-1995

1996-1997* (Phase 4)

1998-2001 (Phase 5)

ζa2

t(up) 1970-1989 1990-1997* 1998-2001

ζp1

t(up) 1970-1980 1981-1984* 1985-2001

ζp2

t(up) 1970-1991 1992-1997* 1998-2001

ADH indices

ζa2

t(p) 1970-1981 1982-1997* 1998-2001

ζm

t(p) 1970-1985* 1986-1995 1996-1997*

1998-2001 (Phase 4)

ζgt(p) 1970-1980 1981-1984* 1985-1994

1995-1997* (Phase 4)

1998-2001 (Phase 5)

Horizon Covariance Index

ζH*100 1970-1980 1981-1993* 1994-2001

Interaction Variable

ζtSt 1970-1990 1991-1997* 1998-2001

Equation (4.9a)

SSH indices

ζt 1970-1996* 1997-2001 nil

ζm

t(up) 1970-1987 1988-1997* 1998-2001

ζgt(up) 1970-1996 1997-2001 nil

ζa2

t(up) 1970-1982 1983-1997* 1998-2001

ζp1

t(up) 1970-1994 1995-1997* 1998-2001

ζp2

t(up) 1970-1989 1990-1997* 1998-2001

ADH indices

ζa2

t(p) 1970-1984 1985-1997* 1998-2001

ζm

t(p) 1970-1989 1990-1997* 1998-2001

ζgt(p) 1970-1991 1992-1997* 1998-2001

Horizon Covariance Index

ζH*100 1970-1978 1979-1981* 1982-1990

1991-1997* (Phase 4)

1998-2001 (Phase 5)

Interaction Variable

ζtSt 1970-1985 1986-1997* 1998-2001

In summary, from the CUSUMSQ tests, three phases pertaining to each index

corresponding to the periods where the CUSUMSQ has drifted outside the confidence

boundaries can be identified. Whilst phase 1 can generally be viewed as a period of model

stability, as the CUSUMSQ did not drift outside the confidence bounds, the latter phases

reflect instability, since the CUSUMSQ drifted outside the boundaries in phase 2, and

119

returned back to the boundaries in phase 3. Hence, potential structural breaks could occur

between phase 1 and 2, and between phase 2 and 3.

It is worth noting that the phases identified from the CUSUMSQ procedure are closely

associated with the „stages‟ outlined in section 5.4.3.1. Phase 1 covers 1970 till the

mid/late 1980s, close to stage 1 (1970-1986) with an unemployment rate of 3-5%. Phase 2

covers the mid/late 1980s to 1997, corresponding with stage 2 (1987-1997), where the

unemployment rate was 2-3%. Finally, both phase 3 and stage 3 represent the 1998-2001

post-Crisis period.

Harvey-Collier Statistic

The Harvey-Collier (HC) statistic is another test of model stability. For a total of N

observations and k parameters, the statistic is computed as:

r = N

s2

= [1 / (N- k -1)] ∑ (wr - w)2

r = k+1

_________________

where wr = (Ut – xt‟βt-1) / √ [1 + x‟t(X‟t-1Xt-1)-1

xt]

_ r = N

w = [1 / (N- k)] ∑ wr

r = k +1

with Ut being the actual unemployment rate, xt being the (k x 1) vector of regressors

associated with observations of Ut, βt-1 is the estimated regression coefficients computed

using the first (t-1) observations and Xt-1 is the matrix of full rank consisting of regressors

for the first (t-1) observations. The numerator term (Ut – xt‟βt-1) is the tth

recursive residual

and represents the expost forecast error using the former (t-1) observations. The HC

statistic is assessed against the t-distribution with N-k-1 degrees of freedom. If it exceeds

its critical value at a prescribed level of significance (i.e. 5% in this study), the null

hypothesis of model stability is rejected.

The HC is used in conjunction with the CUSUM/CUSUMSQ to check model stability. It is

not used in conjunction with the Chow test since the latter requires prior knowledge of the

120

time point at which the structural change occurs. From Table 5.6, two observations about

the HC statistic can be made. Under equation (4.9a), there is no clear-cut outcome of

parameter stability, since the statistic for some indices suggested stability, whilst that for

others did not. Some consistency is established under the model of equation (5.1), in that

model instability is suggested by the statistic for nearly all the indices.

5.4.3.3 Phase I and Phase II

Whilst the CUSUM results point towards stability, the CUSUMSQ results do not.

Likewise, mixed findings emerge from application of the HC test. This conflict can be

mediated by means of the Chow-test. The Chow-test will be applied to confirm if there

was a structural change between phase 1 and phase 2. The relevant F-statistic uses the error

sum of squares from the regressions of phase 1 (ESS1), phase 2 (ESS2) and for the two

phases (ESS), and can be computed as:

F = (ESS – ESS1 – ESS2) / k

(ESS1 + ESS2) / (n – 2k)

for k regression coefficients and n number of observations from phases 1 and 2. Table 5.6

shows the corresponding F-statistic for each index for each regression equation. The F-

statistic could not be computed for a few of the indices (indicated as „n.a.‟ in Table 5.6)

since the number of observations (n) did not exceed the number of parameters (k) for that

particular phase. Among those that could be computed, as the observed F-statistic did not

exceed the critical F (k, n-2k) at the 5% level for nearly all the indices for equations (5.1)

and (4.9a), it is reasonable to side with the CUSUM results of an absence of a structural

break between phase 1 and phase 2. From phase 1 till phase 2, the unemployment rate has

been 2-5%, with no sudden hikes or dips in this rate over 1970-1997.

5.4.3.4 Phase II and Phase III

Whilst the k parameters can generally be estimated from a phase 2 regression (as n2 > k),

the k parameters cannot be estimated for phase 3, as the k number of parameters exceeds

the number of observations (n3 < k). Consequently, the error sum of squares from the

121

regression of phase 3 (ESS3) will be zero, and the conventional Chow-test cannot therefore

be applied to phase 2 and phase 3. The test of the null hypothesis that the extra n3

observations have a similar structure as that of the first n2 observations is based on the

following F-statistic:

F = (ESS2+3 – ESS2) / n3

ESS2 / (n2 – k)

where ESS2+3 is the error sum of squares from the regression of phase 2 plus phase 3 and n2

and n3 are the number of observations for phases 2 and 3, respectively. If the computed F

statistic exceeds the critical F(n3, n2-k) value, the decision would be to reject the null

hypothesis of a common structural relationship [see Johnston (1984)].

With regards to equation (5.1), the F-statistic to test for a structural break between phases 2

and 3 could not be computed for several indices, as n2 < k or only two phases were

identified via the CUSUM and CUSUMSQ tests. These indices are again indicated as „n.a.‟

in Table 5.6. For the indices that could be computed, the null hypothesis is rejected for

ζa2

t(p) and the horizon covariance index. Given that a structural break was identified for

these two indices, and the corresponding CUSUMSQ and HC statistic suggest parameter

instability for nearly all indices, it is reasonable to suspect that a structural break occurred

between phase 2 and phase 3. From the CUSUMSQ tests, it is reasonable to conclude that

the structural break occurred around 1997/1998.

With regards to equation (4.9a), there is evidence of a structural break between phases 2

and 3 for ζa2

t(up) and ζa2

t(p), as their corresponding F statistic exceeded the critical value.

However, for these two indices, the HC statistics did not provide support for the structural

change hypothesis. Instead, the HC test pointed towards parameter instability for several

other indices (ζp2

t(up), ζm

t(p), ζgt(p), ζH and ζtSt). Nevertheless, given that the CUSUMSQ

result, F-statistic and HC test identified a break in the deterministic relationship for a range

of indices, it is reasonable to accept that a structural change happened between phases 2 and

3.

122

Table 5.6 F- and Harvey-Collier Statistics from Tests of Structural Change Equation (4.9a) Equation (5.1)

Phase I &

II

F

statistics

Phase II

& III

F

statistics

Harvey-

Collier

statistics

Phase I &

II

F

statistics

Phase II

& III

F

statistics

Harvey-

Collier

Statistics

ζt n.a. n.a.2 0.31 n.a. n.a. 2.96*

ζm

t(up) 0.90 2.71 0.72 0.30 8.75 2.24*

ζgt(up) n.a. n.a.

2 0.33 n.a. n.a. 2.66*

ζa2

t(up) 2.06 15.81* 1.07 0.42 8.89 2.76*

ζp1

t(up) n.a. n.a. 0.98 n.a. n.a. 2.58*

ζp2

t(up) 1.68 0.98 3.06* n.a. n.a. 2.90*

ζa2

t(p) 2.01 10.56* 1.00 2.39 9.92* 2.90*

ζm

t(p) 0.32 1.29 2.44* 2.08 3.68 3.27*

ζgt(p) 0.17 0.23 10.97* n.a. n.a. 3.14*

ζH*100 n.a. n.a. 0.78* 6.57* 11.89* 13.15*

ζtSt 1.68 3.42 2.45* n.a. n.a. 4.86*

* The observed statistic exceeds its critical value at the 5% level.

n.a. : not available as n ≤ k for that particular phase.

n.a.2 : not available as only 2 phases were identified.

Whilst it is not the case that each and every test from equations (5.1) and (4.9a) has

indicated that a structural change has occurred, several of the tests [CUSUMSQ and HC for

equation (5.1)] point towards model instability, which suggests the likelihood of a

structural change. Taking into account the prior knowledge (from chapter 2) that the Asian

Currency Crisis marked a dramatic turning point and brought Korea to recession after 1997,

with unemployment reaching 7% in 1998 after low rates of 2-3% in the preceding years, it

is plausible to suspect that the structural break took place in 1998. The use of a post-Crisis

structural dummy variable in the following section will assist in confirming if a change did

occur between phase 2 and phase 312

.

One empirical study found that sectoral labour reallocation shocks played an important role

in the decline of Korea‟s unemployment since the 1960s up till the mid-1990s, although the

study did not preclude the possibility of the importance of other multiple structural

parameters (productivity growth, return to market relative to non-market activities,

bargaining power of workers, real interest rates and matching technology) [Chang, Nam

and Ree (2004)]. This finding strengthens the case of a structural change in the mobility-

unemployment relationship in Korea.

123

5.4.3.5 Accommodation of Structural Change

The identification of a structural break around 1998 necessitates an alteration to the

specification of the unemployment models, accommodated through the use of a post-Crisis

dummy variable:

D = 0 for observations during 1971-1997;

= 1 for observations during 1998-2001.

The structural dummy informs on whether a break actually occurs and also provides,

indirectly, information on its source. The other studies have not accommodated the

consequences of a structural change, even though they cover periods of major change (e.g.

Vietnam war13

). Perhaps the unemployment consequences of these were not as pronounced

as that of the Asian Currency Crisis.

Since there is no prior knowledge pertaining to the source of the structural change, i.e.

whether it is brought about by an intercept shift, changing mobility effect or an alteration to

the effects of other explanatory variables, the ideal procedure would be to interact the

dummy variable with all explanatory variables to identify the source.

The limited number of annual data points in the post-Crisis period, namely 4 years, in

Korea poses constraints. Taking equation (5.1) as an example, the number of interaction

dummies with the explanatory variables (i.e. 5 including the intercept term) exceeds the

number of data points in the post-Crisis period. A feasible approach is to include an

intercept dummy and a mobility interaction dummy for each model. This way, the number

of structural dummies per equation (i.e. 2) stays within the boundary of the number of data

points (observations), and the importance of changes in the impact of the key variable of

interest can still be assessed.

Both the intercept dummy and mobility interaction dummy are included in the model

initially. This approach has the advantage in overcoming any result which may appear to

be sensitive to the order in which the dummies have been inserted in the model14

. Under

the modified approach, equation (5.1) can be converted to:

124

Ut = α1 + α2D + β1ζ + β2ζ D + γ1DMRt + δ1DMRt-1 + λ1Ut-1 + Ω1T + εt (5.1‟)

with α2 measuring the shift in intercept during the Crisis and β2 the additional impact of the

mobility index. The statistical significance of the dummies will assist in pinpointing the

source of structural change. Testing the null hypothesis, i.e. Ho: α2 = 0, is tantamount to

testing the homogeneity of intercepts before and after the structural break, and testing Ho:

β2 = 0 represents testing for a change in the deterministic relationships between mobility

and unemployment.

The pair-wise correlation matrix revealed that D, ζtD, ζm

t(up)D, ζgt(up)D, ζ

a2t(up)D, ζ

p1t(up)D,

ζp2

t(up)D, ζa2

t(p)D, ζm

t(p)D, ζgt(p)D, (ζH*100)D and ζtStD were not highly correlated with

DMRt, DMRt-1, Ut-1 and T, with their respective pair-wise correlation coefficients being

below 0.6.

Each dummy/interaction dummy was retained when it was significant at the 5% level. This

led to the equations below for equation (5.1‟).

Ut = α1 + β1ζt + β2ζtD + γ1DMRt + δ1DMRt-1 + λ1Ut-1 + Ω1T + εt

Ut = α1 + α2D + β1ζm

t(up) + β2ζm

t(up)D + γ1DMRt + δ1DMRt-1 + λ1Ut-1 + Ω1T + εt

Ut = α1 + α2D + β1ζgt(up) + β2ζ

gt(up)D + γ1DMRt + δ1DMRt-1 + λ1Ut-1 + Ω1T + εt

Ut = α1 + β1ζa2

t(up) + β2ζa2

t(up)D + γ1DMRt + δ1DMRt-1 + λ1Ut-1 + Ω1T + εt

Ut = α1 + β1ζp1

t(up) + β2 ζp1

t(up)D + γ1DMRt + δ1DMRt-1 + λ1Ut-1 + Ω1T + εt

Ut = α1 + α2D + β1ζp2

t(up) + β2 ζp2

t(up)D + γ1DMRt + δ1DMRt-1 + λ1Ut-1 + Ω1T + εt

Ut = α1 + β1ζa2

t(p) + β2ζa2

t(p)D + γ1DMRt + δ1DMRt-1 + λ1Ut-1 + Ω1T + εt

Ut = α1 + β1ζm

t(p) + β2ζm

t(p)D + γ1DMRt + δ1DMRt-1 + λ1Ut-1 + Ω1T + εt

Ut = α1 + α2D + β1ζgt(p) + β2ζ

gt(p)D + γ1DMRt + δ1DMRt-1 + λ1Ut-1 + Ω1T + εt

Ut = α1 + β1ζt + β2ζH*100 + β3(ζH*100)D + γ1DMRt + δ1DMRt-1 + λ1Ut-1 + Ω1T + εt

Ut = α1 + β1ζt + β2ζtSt + β3ζtStD + γ1DMRt + δ1DMRt-1 + λ1Ut-1 + Ω1T + εt

The „preferred‟ model for each index from equation (4.9a), after consideration of the

hypotheses that α2 = 0 and β2 = 0, is as follows:

Ut = α1 + β1ζt + β2ζtD + δ1DMRt-1 + λ1Ut-1 + η1EXt-1 + εt (4.9a‟)

Ut = α1 + α2D + β1ζm

t(up) + β2ζm

t(up) D + δ1DMRt-1 + λ1Ut-1 + τ1∆PPI + εt

Ut = α1 + α2D + β1ζgt(up) + β2ζ

gt(up)D + δ1DMRt-1 + λ1Ut-1 + η1EXt-1 + εt

125

Ut = α1 + β1ζa2

t(up) + β2ζa2

t(up) D + δ1DMRt-1 + λ1Ut-1 + τ1∆PPI + εt

Ut = α1 + β1ζp1

t(up) + β2 ζp1

t(up)D + δ1DMRt-1 + λ1Ut-1 + τ1∆PPI + ς1Gt-1 + εt

Ut = α1 + α2D + β1ζp2

t(up) + β2 ζp2

t(up)D + δ1DMRt-1 + λ1Ut-1 + τ1∆PPI + η1EXt-1 + εt

Ut = α1 + α2D + β1ζa2

t(p) + β2ζa2

t(p) D + δ1DMRt-1 + λ1Ut-1 + τ1∆PPI + εt

Ut = α1 + α2D + β1ζm

t(p) + β2ζm

t(p)D + δ1DMRt-1 + λ1Ut-1 + τ1∆PPI + εt

Ut = α1 + α2D + β1ζgt(p) + β2 ζ

gt(p)D + δ1DMRt-1 + λ1Ut-1 + τ1∆PPI + εt

Ut = α1 + α2D + β1ζt + β2ζH*100 + β3(ζH*100)D + δ1DMRt-1 + λ1Ut-1 + τ1∆PPI + η1EXt-1 + εt

Ut = α1 + β1ζt + β2ζtSt + β3ζtStD + λ1Ut-1 + τ1∆PPI + η1EXt-1 + εt

The equations for the various indices indicate dissimilar sources of structural change. This

is not surprising given the differences in the concept and construction of the indices. Under

equation (5.1), the homogeneity of intercepts is revealed for most indices whilst the

heterogeneity of intercepts is apparent in equation (4.9a) for the majority of indices An

alteration in the mobility-unemployment relationship is shown for all indices in both

models.

In general, the statistical significance of the dummy variable and the interaction dummies

agree with the CUSUMSQ results, which suggest model instability. It is possible to

conclude that a structural break occurred between phase 2 and phase 3. The source of

structural change varies among the indices, though this is expected since each index is

constructed to capture different sets of influences.

5.4.4 Re-specification of Unemployment Models

In this section, an attempt is made to tighten the augmented models. This is desirable as the

inclusion of the dummies improved the fit of the model by about 40-50% but resulted in a

few insignificant variables. These changes in the statistical significance are not surprising

given the structural change. In the process of tightening the models, the mobility indices (if

insignificant) will not be omitted as their significance, or lack thereof, is central towards

establishing the claims of the hypotheses.

The re-specified equation (5.1*) was estimated using OLS. A fairly common observation is

that DMRt was insignificant and its omission led to the same or better model fit for ζt,

126

ζgt(up), ζ

a2t(up), ζ

p1t(up), ζ

a2t(p), ζ

mt(p), ζH*100 and ζtSt. Likewise, the exclusion of DMRt-1 and

DMRt gave a better fit for the regressions with ζm

t(up), ζgt(up), ζ

p2t(up) and ζ

gt(p). The revised

equation (5.1*) for each index becomes:

Ut = α1 + β1ζt + β2ζtD + δ1DMRt-1 + λ1Ut-1 + Ω1T + εt

Ut = α1 + α2D + β1ζm

t(up) + β2ζm

t(up)D + λ1Ut-1 + Ω1T + εt

Ut = α1 + α2D + β1ζgt(up) + β2ζ

gt(up)D + λ1Ut-1 + Ω1T + εt

Ut = α1 + β1ζa2

t(up) + β2ζa2

t(up)D + δ1DMRt-1 + λ1Ut-1 + Ω1T + εt

Ut = α1 + β1ζp1

t(up) + β2 ζp1

t(up)D + δ1DMRt-1 + λ1Ut-1 + Ω1T + εt

Ut = α1 + α2D + β1ζp2

t(up) + β2 ζp2

t(up)D + λ1Ut-1 + Ω1T + εt

Ut = α1 + β1ζa2

t(p) + β2ζa2

t(p)D + δ1DMRt-1 + λ1Ut-1 + Ω1T + εt

Ut = α1 + β1ζm

t(p) + β2ζm

t(p)D + δ1DMRt-1 + λ1Ut-1 + Ω1T + εt

Ut = α1 + α2D + β1ζgt(p) + β2ζ

gt(p)D + λ1Ut-1 + Ω1T + εt

Ut = α1 + α2D + β1ζt + β2ζH*100 + β3(ζH*100)D + δ1DMRt-1 + λ1Ut-1 + Ω1T + εt

Ut = α1 + β1ζt + β2ζtSt + β3ζtStD + δ1DMRt-1 + λ1Ut-1 + Ω1T + εt

For equation (4.9a*), the fit of the model improved following the omission of DMRt-1 for

ζgt(up), ζ

a2t(up) and ζ

gt(p), ∆PPI and DMRt-1 for ζ

a2t(p) and ζ

mt(p), EXt-1 for ζH*100 and ζtSt,

DMRt-1 and Ut-1 for ζp1

t(up), DMRt-1 and EXt-1 for ζp2

t(up), and DMRt-1 and ∆PPI for ζm

t(up).

For ζt, no omission was necessary. The revised models are:

Ut = α1 + β1ζt + β2ζtD + δ1DMRt-1 + λ1Ut-1 + η1EXt-1 + εt

Ut = α1 + α2D + β1ζm

t(up) + β2ζm

t(up) D + λ1Ut-1 + εt

Ut = α1 + α2D + β1ζgt(up) + β2ζ

gt(up)D + λ1Ut-1 + η1EXt-1 + εt

Ut = α1 + β1ζa2

t(up) + β2ζa2

t(up) D + τ1∆PPI + λ1Ut-1 + εt

Ut = α1 + β1ζp1

t(up) + β2 ζp1

t(up)D + τ1∆PPI + ς1Gt-1 + εt

Ut = α1 + α2D + β1ζp2

t(up) + β2 ζp2

t(up)D + λ1Ut-1 + τ1∆PPI + εt

Ut = α1 + α2D + β1ζa2

t(p) + β2ζa2

t(p) D + λ1Ut-1 + εt

Ut = α1 + α2D + β1ζm

t(p) + β2ζm

t(p)D + λ1Ut-1 + εt

Ut = α1 + α2D + β1ζgt(p) + β2 ζ

gt(p)D + λ1Ut-1 + τ1∆PPI + εt

Ut = α1 + α2D + β1ζt + β2ζH*100 + β3(ζH*100)D + δ1DMRt-1 + λ1Ut-1 + τ1∆PPI + εt

Ut = α1 + β1ζt + β2ζtSt + β3ζtStD + λ1Ut-1 + τ1∆PPI + εt

127

5.5 FINAL MODEL ESTIMATION

5.5.1 Treatment for Serial Correlation

Table 5.7 presents the OLS estimates of the mobility indices from the final specifications.

The LM statistic was used to test for the presence of serially-correlated errors15

. Given the

use of annual data, only first-order serial correlation was considered. First-order serial

correlation was prevalent in equation (5.1*) with ζH and equation (4.9a*) with ζp1

t(up),

ζH*100 and ζtSt. This is of particular concern as the t-values will typically be inflated with

positively correlated error terms. Accordingly, a Cochrane-Orcutt (CO) correction for serial

correlation was applied to the affected equations16

.

Where serial correlation has been detected, the CO estimates are displayed alongside the

OLS estimates. As using CO estimation results in a loss of the first observation, which is

substantial in the current application considering that the dataset is based on only 31 data

points17

, a Prais-Winsten transformation is applied to preserve the first observation,

whereby it is written as:

U1* = U1 (1- ρ2)1/2

; and

X1* = X1 (1- ρ2)1/2

where X denotes the set of explanatory variables in the estimating equation. Compared to

the OLS estimates, there were differences in the size of the parameter estimates and t-

values when the estimates corrected for serial correlation are considered. In particular, the

t-values of several of the OLS estimates were larger in the presence of serial correlation.

Having specified the models to reflect structural change, reduced multicollinearity and

serial correlation, and omitted irrelevant variables, reliable, consistent and efficient CO

estimates can be obtained to examine the validity of the SSH, ADH and RTH hypotheses.

In general, compared to the OLS estimates of Table 5.4, the fit of the model has improved

substantially, with the adjusted R-squared ranging from 0.7 to 0.9. This improvement

arises due to the modelling of structural change.

128

Table 5.7 Final Model: Parameter Estimates of ζ, D and ζD and LM Statistic Regression with: Equation (4.9a*) Equation (5.1*) OLS CO LM statistic OLS CO LM statistic ζt 48.951

(2.923) n.u. 2.13 8.992

(0.470) n.u. 1.62

ζtD 61.209 (3.245)

102.679 (4.942)

ζm

t(up) -2.632 (-1.752)

n.u. 0.93 -2.189 (-1.532)

n.u. 0.15

ζm

t(up) D 33.046 (6.873)

27.576 (5.276)

D -5.957 (-5.574)

ζgt(up) 17.057

(1.226) n.u. 0.48 4.775

(0.388) n.u. 0.33

ζgt(up) D 127.108

(4.639) 120.865

(5.152)

D -2.734 (-3.453)

ζa2

t(up) 0.534 (1.209)

n.u. 1.41 -0.017 (-0.036)

n.u. 0.36

ζa2

t(up) D 3.583 (4.794)

4.453 (5.488)

ζp1

t(up) 41.745 (2.862)

37.936 (3.145)

10.14 9.647 (0.791)

n.u. 1.62

ζp1

t(up) D 40.369 (2.779)

38.484 (3.184)

70.992 (5.488)

ζp2

(up) 4.908 (0.432)

n.u. 0.84 -11.504 (-0.971)

n.u. 0.30

ζp2

(up) D 130.095 (4.954)

131.703 (5.011)

D -3.281 (-3.641)

-2.502 (-2.050)

ζa2

t(p) -9.096 (-0.557)

n.u. 2.19 -34.363 (-2.301)

n.u. 2.10

ζa2

t(p)D 303.477 (3.149)

103.779 (5.272)

D -7.982 (-2.743)

ζm

t(p) -1.698 (-0.933)

n.u. 0.18 -0.317 (-0.181)

n.u. 1.74

ζm

t(p)D 21.052 (4.295)

11.857 (4.461)

D -2.685

(-2.826)

ζgt(p) 19.137

(1.210) n.u. 0.15 -10.173

(-0.645) n.u. 1.59

ζgt(p)D -340.299

(-7.254) -272.188

(-5.095)

D 7.772 (8.010)

7.552 (7.915)

ζt 67.704 (4.115)

48.106 (2.820)

6.30 46.071 (1.920)

19.849 (0.962)

5.97

ζH*100 0.825 (0.165)

0.256 (0.060)

2.746 (0.515)

1.057 (0.244)

ζH*100D 132.806 (3.666)

191.558 (2.229)

165.745 (2.651)

105.074 (1.316)

ζt 20.535 (1.325)

39.579 (2.691)

3.09 11.868 (0.601)

n.u. 1.14

ζtSt 158.621 (3.723)

9.646 (0.954)

-6.115 (-0.712)

ζtStD 158.621 (3.723)

61.011 (3.810)

108.882 (4.793)

Note: t-values in parentheses. n.u.: not undertaken.

129

The regressions with three indices (ζp1

t(up), ζH*100 and ζtSt) had to be corrected for serial

correlation. Comparing the OLS and CO estimates in Table 5.7, the standard errors were

higher for ζp1

t(up) and ζtSt under equation (4.9a*), those for ζH*100 under equations (5.1*)

and (4.9a*) under OLS estimation. A likely reason is that their post-Crisis interaction

dummy variables constitute 4 data points, and perhaps this period is not sufficiently long to

give the higher standard errors under CO estimation. Nonetheless, the standard errors of the

regressions under CO estimation are fairly close to those under OLS estimation. The CO

estimates can be considered to be valid for statistical inference.

It is noted that serial correlation is not prevalent in regression equations with the other

indices, and their OLS estimates are unbiased, consistent and efficient, and valid for

statistical inference. Compared to the OLS estimates of Table 5.4, the fit of the newly

specified models improved, with the adjusted R-squared of at least 0.8. For reference

purposes, the estimating equations of these final unemployment models (as per Table 5.7)

can be found in Appendix 5G.

5.5.2 Sectoral Mobility during the Pre-Crisis Period (1971-1997)

The unemployment equations (5.1*) and (4.9a*) were also estimated for 1971-1997 to

ascertain if the mobility-unemployment relationship found for this truncated data period is

consistent with that established with the larger sample (1971-2001) after accommodating

the structural break. This is a test of the adequacy of the way the structural break has been

modelled. Since the 1998-2001 observations are removed, the interaction variables with D,

and D itself, are excluded. The same equations cannot be estimated for 1998-2001 as the

number of parameters exceeds the number of observations.

The SSH/ADH indices and horizon covariance index, which were insignificant for 1971-

2001, were also insignificant for 1971-1997 in both models, confirming that predicted and

unpredicted mobility as well as past labour reallocations did not cause unemployment

during the pre-Crisis period. Pertaining to the stage-of-the-business-cycle effect, ζtSt

remained insignificant for equations (5.1*) and (4.9a*) for 1971-1997.

130

Thus, where the mobility indices were insignificant variables for 1971-2001, they were also

insignificant for 1971-1997. Likewise, whilst the index [i.e. ζa2

t(p)] was significant for the

full data period under equation (5.1*), it was also significant for the pre-Crisis period. This

implies that modelling of the 1997 structural break using the dummy variable does not

introduce any distortions to the fundamental relationships between mobility and

unemployment over 1971-1997.

Table 5.8 1971-1997: Parameter Estimates of ζ Regression with: Equation

(4.9a*)

Equation

(5.1*)

ζt 16.147

(1.020)

9.619

(0.627)

ζm

t(up) -2.296

(-1.848)

-2.140

(-1.776)

ζgt(up) 6.336

(0.459)

5.038

(0.389)

ζa2

t(up) 0.227

(0.777)

0.047

(0.128)

ζp1

t(up) 14.603

(1.267)

5.289

(0.425)

ζp2

t(up) 6.563

(0.658)

-10.989

(-0.980)

ζa2

t(p) -14.500

(-1.469)

-28.891

(-3.155)

ζm

t(p) -1.563

(-1.312)

-1.172

(-0.879)

ζgt(p) 10.870

(0.728)

-8.213

(-0.550)

ζH*100 0.261

(0.079)

0.854

(0.242)

ζtSt 8.945

(1.325)

-2.148

(-0.293)

1. All figures are OLS except for the CO

estimates (applied with Prais-Winsten

transformation) of ζt, ζm

t(up), ζgt(up), ζ

gt(p) and

ζp2

t(up) under equation (5.1*).

2. t-values in parentheses.

5.6 VALIDITY OF THE HYPOTHESES

The main focus of this analysis is to see if sectoral labour movements generate aggregate

unemployment and this is to be done through examination of the statistical significance of

the mobility indices. With the variety of indices, there arises a need to establish the set of

indices which are robust under the alternative restricted models. Since equations (4.9a*)

and (5.1*) are similar in that: (i) equation (5.1*) has its roots in the basic Lilien approach,

131

while equation (4.9a*) is a more encompassing version of the former equation; and (ii) the

structural change has been modelled into both equations, the result in terms of the

significance of the mobility indices must at least be broadly consistent across these two

models.

5.6.1 Validity of the SSH

Each SSH index has been purged of differing influences and it is important to examine the

validity of the SSH by comparing the findings with studies of similar index type.

Raw Lilien Index

The raw Lilien index was significant under equation (4.9a*) but insignificant under

equation (5.1*). However, its interaction with the dummy variable was significant and

positive for both models. The finding under equation (4.9a*) is consistent with the

numerous studies for North America and Japan reporting a significant positive impact on

unemployment: Lilien (1982), Loungani (1986), Abraham and Katz (1986), Parker (1992),

Loungani and Rogerson (1989), Brainard and Cutler (1993), Davis (1987), Mills, Pelloni

and Zervoyianni (1995) and Lu (1996) for the U.S., Neelin (1987) for Canada and Prasad

(1997) for Japan. It contradicts findings from Europe: France [Saint-Paul (1997)] and Italy

[Garonna and Sica (2000)], which showed mobility to affect unemployment in the opposite

direction. As mentioned in chapter 4, the negative effect has been attributed to labour

market rigidities in France, i.e. temporary contracts and rising public sector employment,

and the high firing costs and differences in cyclical sensitivities in Italy‟s manufacturing

and services sectors.

The sensitivity of the results under the alternative models may, in addition to the potential

omitted variables bias in the two non-nested models, reflect the deficiency of the raw index

in aligning with the concept of the SSH. Several studies have criticized the index and opted

and/or recommended alternative indices to examine the SSH, even though it was reported

to be significant. These include Loungani (1986), Palley (1992), Mills, Pelloni and

Zervoyianni (1995), Lu (1996), Neelin (1985) and Garonna and Sica (2000). It is the intent

of the following sub-sections to do likewise.

132

Pure Sectoral Shifts Purged of AD disturbances

Similar results were produced for ζm

t(up), ζgt(up) and ζ

a2t(up) under equations (5.1*) and

(4.9a*), in that they had an insignificant impact on unemployment. In the unpredicted

sense, a mobility-unemployment relationship did not exist before 1997 in Korea.

Consistency in findings was displayed in the post-1997 findings. All three interaction

variables, i.e. ζm

t(up)D, ζgt(up)D and ζ

a2t(up)D, had positive and significant coefficients under

equations (5.1*) and (4.9a*). The post-Crisis finding agreed with the reports of the

empirical studies in terms of the ζ-U impact, although the data periods differ. Whilst the

findings for the first two were in tandem with Mills, Pelloni and Zervoyianni (1995), that of

ζa2

t(up) replicated the findings of Palley (1992) for the U.S.

The structural change brought about by the Crisis caused a phenomenal change in the way

sectoral mobility affected unemployment. Taking equation (5.1*) with ζgt(up) as an

example, the coefficient estimate during the pre-Crisis period was 4.775 while the post-

Crisis impact, estimated as ∂Ut/∂ζgt(up) = 4.775 + 120.865ζ

gt(up), exceeds that of the pre-

Crisis magnitude. Evaluated at the mean of ζgt(up), it equals 7.500. The onset of the Crisis

led to a much greater influence of mobility movements on unemployment.

The robustness in the result and its concurrence with the empirical literature (in terms of

statistical significance only) seems to point towards the existence of the unpredicted ζ-U

relationship during 1998-2001. For this period, it seems possible to validate the claims of

the SSH for pure mobility purged of demand disturbances.

Pure Sectoral Shifts Purged of Supply Influences

Whilst ζp2

t(up) was insignificant under both equations, ζp1

t(up) was only positive and

significant under equation (4.9a*). Given the lack of robustness in results, not much can be

deduced from the impact of pure shifts purged of supply shocks on unemployment.

Moreover, the insignificant results are in conflict with the outcome for ζp1

t(up) in Mills,

Pelloni and Zervoyianni (1995) for the U.S., but it should be noted that that study covered

the earlier 1961-1991 period, where supply shocks may have been more important.

133

The post-Crisis mobility effect for ζp1

t(up) and ζp2

t(up) showed results similar to those for the

indices purged of AD disturbances, in that both ζp1

t(up)D and ζp2

t(up)D became positive and

significant under both models. In terms of the ζp1

t(up)-U impact, the result is consistent with

Mills, Pelloni and Zervoyianni (1995) for the U.S., although the data periods differ. The

mobility effect was magnified dramatically in the post-Crisis period. The coefficient for

ζp2

t(up) in equation (4.9a*) was 4.908 for the pre-Crisis period but was very much larger

after the Crisis, i.e. ∂Ut/∂ζp2

t(up) = 4.908 + 130.095ζp2

t(up). Evaluated at the mean of ζp2

t(up),

this equals 8.700.

In summary, the post-Crisis findings for Korea suggest that an unpredicted ζ-U relationship

existed. What appears to hold is the following:

a) The impact of unpredicted mobility on unemployment was not felt prior to

1998. This is a common finding across unemployment models with the pure

mobility indices. The finding coincides with results obtained from estimates

based only on 1971-1997 data.

b) Pure sectoral movements purged of demand and supply disturbances seem,

however, to have led to higher aggregate unemployment during the post-Crisis

period. During this period, workers changing sectors will have exacerbated any

unemployment problem. Job replacements may not have been as easy as in the

past as job seekers in this more recent turbulent period will need further time to

acquire skills in the emerging high-skilled jobs, compete with existing workers

with higher productivity, and compete with technology which has made much of

the unskilled labour redundant, i.e. the jobless growth phenomena to be

mentioned in chapter 9.

The claims of the SSH seem valid for the post-Crisis period for Korea, given the robustness

of the results across the various forms of unpredicted indices and the consistency with

related empirical work. However, as highlighted earlier, data limitations in terms of the

low number of observations for the post-Crisis period prevent strong conclusions from

being drawn. The unpredicted ζ-U relationship could be more effectively studied if the

dataset for the post-Crisis period covered a longer time frame.

134

As an added comment, preliminary estimations suggest that much of the unemployment

generated in the post-Crisis period could be non-frictional. As the SSH itself has not been

fully validated, statements about the nature of unemployment generated by pure inter-sector

movements can only be tentative at this stage. For reference purposes, however, a

discussion on the SSH and the natural unemployment rate is provided in Appendix 5H.

5.6.2 Relevance of the ADH

The predicted indices capturing aggregate demand shocks are ζm

t(p), ζgt(p) and ζ

a2t(p). The

former two ADH indices had an insignificant impact on unemployment for equations

(4.9a*) and (5.1*). Thus, from the perspective of mobility predicted from changes in

anticipated money supply and the government deficit to GDP ratio, the ADH is irrelevant to

Korea during the pre-Crisis period. However, whilst the interaction variable of ζm

t(p)D was

positive and significant under both models, the interaction variable of ζgt(p)D gave a

negative and significant result, thereby suggesting that the ADH could only be validated for

Korean mobility arising from changes in the money supply. It also suggests that in the

post-Crisis period, monetary policy would increase the mobility rate as compared to fiscal

policy (via a reduction in the public deficit), which works in the reverse direction.

Where predicted mobility is measured by removing unanticipated deviations in the sectoral

labour movements from changes in aggregate employment [i.e. ζa2

t(p)], the index was

insignificant under equation (4.9a*) but negative and significant in equation (5.1*). Despite

this inconsistency in statistical significance, the fundamental relationship between

unemployment and ζa2

t(p) appears to be inverse - the coefficient in the significant instance is

-34.363 and the point estimate is also negative in the equation with the insignificant

estimate. The inverse relationship continued to prevail during the Crisis period. For

example, from equation (5.1*), the mobility effect on unemployment, i.e. ∂Ut/∂ζa2

t(p) =

-34.363 + 103.779ζa2

t(p), was equal to -31.60 when evaluated at the mean of ζa2

t(p).

It is possible to conclude the lack of relevance of the ADH for Korea in the pre-Crisis

period for predicted mobility arising from changes in the money supply and government

deficit. Though the post-Crisis results indicate a predicted ζ-U correlation, caution must be

exercised in forming conclusions given the limited number of data observations.

135

5.6.3 Applicability of the RTH

Earlier, the issue of the horizon covariance index being a poor measure for the annual data

series was raised. The regression findings appear to confirm this. First, under equations

(5.1*) and (4.9a*), ζH*100 was an insignificant variable. Second, the standardized

coefficient18

for the index (0.033) was one of the smallest values in equation (5.1*) and was

the lowest value in equation (4.9a*) [0.020], signifying it had the least impact on

standardized unemployment. This is not surprising as the index captures the influence of

labour mobility over the preceding two years, which seems too wide an interval to affect

unemployment in the present year. Consequently, interpreting the results of its interaction

variable, ζH*100D, though positive and significant, would be meaningless as we are left

with two data points. The 1998 data point reflects movements of 1996 and 1999, 2000 and

2001 each point towards mobility in 1997, 1998 and 1999. Since the Crisis started

sometime around 1997-1998, only the 2000 and 2001 data points will reflect the Crisis‟

impact. Thus, estimation with the horizon covariance index with an annual data series

appears to be impeded by a major, insurmountable, measurement issue.

Furthermore, the results do not concur with the Davis (1987) study for the U.S. Using

annual data, Davis (1987) reported the coefficient for ζHt-1 to be insignificant. The point

estimate reported was negative, whereas those in this study were positive. It is noted that

the support for the RTH in Davis‟ (1987) study was rooted in regressions using quarterly

data, and for the annual data series for ζHt-3 and ζHt-4 only. Oi (1987) also questioned the

influence of the RTH, since Davis (1987) reported weak correlations.

In short, the RTH cannot be validated for Korea for two reasons. First, the measurement

problem associated with ζH*100 for annual data renders it an unsuitable index, and its

insignificance in the various models estimated appears to confirm this. Second, the

findings for Korea differ from those reported in the empirical literature [Davis (1987)] but

this is primarily due to the general lack of robustness in the results obtained using,

alternatively, annual and quarterly data series.

136

5.6.4 Sectoral Movements and Stage-of-the-Business-Cycle Effect

The regressions of equations (5.1*) and (4.9a*) showed that ζtSt was an insignificant

variable. This finding for the post-Crisis phase in Korea does not concur with that for a

more stable economic setting reported by Mills, Pelloni and Zervoyianni (1995) for the

U.S. Since there are limitations associated with the raw Lilien index, the variable St was

made to interact with other unpredicted and predicted indices.

Pre-Crisis Finding

To assess if the stage-of-the-business-cycle effect applies to unpredicted sectoral

movements, additional interaction variables were created by multiplying St by each

unpredicted index. Each of the five sets of new variables [(i) ζm

t(up), ζm

t(up)St and

ζm

t(up)St D, (ii) ζgt(up), ζ

gt(up)St and ζ

gt(up)St D, (iii) ζ

a2t(up), ζ

a2t(up)St and ζ

a2t(up)St D, (iv) ζ

p1t(up),

ζp1

t(up)St and ζp1

t(up)St D, and (v) ζp2

t(up), ζp2

t(up)St and ζp2

t(up)St D] was entered into the

regressions of equations (5.1*) and (4.9a*) in place of ζt, ζtSt and ζtStD. The regressions

revealed the unpredicted ζSt‟s to be insignificant (Table 5.9), implying that pure inter-

sector labour movements did not lead to higher aggregate unemployment during the period

1971-2001.

The stage-of-the-business-cycle hypothesis was also tested for mobility predicted by

demand disturbances. For the regressions with the ADH indices, each set of variables, i.e.

ζa2

t(p), ζa2

t(p)St and ζa2

t(p)St D, ζm

t(p), ζm

t(p)St and ζm

t(p)St D and ζgt(p), ζ

gt(p)St and ζ

gt(p)St D, was

entered into equations (5.1*) and (4.9a*) instead of ζt, ζtSt and ζtStD2. The interaction

variables ζa2

t(p)St, ζm

t(p)St and ζgt(p)St were insignificant, suggesting that the business cycle

effect is inapplicable during 1971-2001 for predicted labour movements.

Thus, the stage-of-the-business-cycle argument cannot be extended to predicted and

unpredicted sectoral labour movements. As the SSH and ADH did not exist for most forms

of mobility during 1971-2001, it is not surprising that the stage-of-the-business-cycle effect

does not apply to predicted and unpredicted mobility.

137

Table 5.9 Parameter Estimates of ζ, ζSt and/or ζStD Equation

(4.9a*)

Equation

(5.1*) ζt 39.579*

(2.691) 11.868 (0.601)

ζtSt 9.646 (0.955)

-6.115 (-0.712)

ζtStD 61.011* (3.810)

108.882* (4.793)

ζm

t(up) -1.735 (-1.114)

-1.582 (-1.050)

ζm

t(up)St 1.548 (0.626)

-0.208 (-0.095)

ζm

t(up)StD 10.808* (3.824)

13.553* (4.868)

ζg t(up) 21.176

(1.402) 12.803 (0.958)

ζg t(up)St 8.635

(0.565) -8.604

(-0.983) ζ

g t(up)StD 53.955*

(3.319) 88.535* (5.410)

ζa2

t(up) 0.450 (1.005)

-0.012 (-0.024)

ζa2

t(up)St 1.047 (1.237)

0.161 (0.197)

ζa2

t(up)StD 2.638* (2.448)

4.293* (3.692)

ζp1

t(up) 35.263* (3.604)

11.276 (0.914)

ζp1

t(up)St 9.603 (0.960)

-7.632 (-0.956)

ζp1

t(up)StD 29.660* (2.535)

77.691* (5.244)

ζp2

t(up) 26.182 (1.786)

+

-9.153 (-0.546)

ζp2

t(up)St 6.143 (0.646)

-0.890 (-0.105)

ζp2

t(up)StD 36.470* (3.243)

80.124* (5.243)

ζa2

t(p) 2.438 (0.140)

-37.531* (-2.531)

ζa2

t(p)St 14.901 (0.890)

-15.145 (-1.400)

ζa2

t(p)StD 51.966* (2.306)

125.556* (5.063)

ζm

t(p) -0.149 (-0.081)

-0.309 (-0.173)

ζm

t(p)St 4.173 (1.658)

-0.363 (-0.152)

ζm

t(p)StD 4.476 (1.426)

12.244* (3.299)

ζg t(p) -55.588

(-1.377) -40.205 (-0.943)

ζg t(p)St 43.784

+

(1.772) 10.465 (0.383)

ζg t(p)StD -0.732

(-0.024) 96.677

+

(1.859)

* significant at 5% level. + significant at 10% level.

Note: All are OLSE except for equation (4.9a*) with ζa2

t(p),

ζa2

t(up), ζm

t(up) and ζgt(p), and equation (5.1*) with ζ

gt(p) and

ζm

t(up) which are CO estimates applied with a Prais-Winsten

transformation.

138

Post-Crisis Finding

From the results of the predicted and unpredicted ζStD variables, the majority of the indices

point towards a positive and significant coefficient. Although this may suggest some

evidence in favour of the business-cycle effect during the post-Crisis period, two notable

limitations with regards to the dataset prevent the formation of any conclusion pertaining to

the post-Crisis period. The 4 annual data points for the 1998-2001 period are too few

observations to confidently ascertain if the stage-of-the-business-cycle effect really existed.

This is compounded by the fact that at the end of the data period (2001), the most

pronounced business cycle in the data series was incomplete. Any examination of this

hypothesis for Korea can only be conducted over a longer time frame. This is outside the

scope of this thesis.

5.7 CONCLUDING REMARKS

The impact of sectoral mobility on unemployment with regards to the Korean labour

market was examined in this chapter. This examination was conducted from the

perspective of the four main hypotheses: SSH, ADH, RTH, and the stage-of-the-business-

cycle effect. Owing to the contradictory evidence from the empirical studies, the extensive

list of indices and wealth of explanatory variables gathered from the literature, lengthy,

rigorous steps had to be followed to ensure reliable estimates were obtained prior to

statistical inference.

In terms of specification, the approach was to move from an unrestricted to a restricted

model. As an all-encompassing model would have led to over-parameterisation and

multicollinearity, tests were conducted to determine if any of the regressors were

correlated. It was also necessary to ensure the series of each variable was stationary and to

avoid instability in the regression.

With a time period of 31 years, the likelihood of a change in the deterministic relationship

in the variables within each model would be quite high. This is especially so following

from events like the 1998 Asian Financial Crisis, which led to a severe recession in Korea

139

[The World Bank (1999)]. For the majority of models and indices, the tests indicated a

structural break between 1971-1997 and 1998-2001. The identification of these structural

breaks gave rise to a more appropriate functional form with the creation of dummy and

interaction variables. Serial correlation was detected in several estimating equations and

was corrected with the Cochrane-Orcutt iterative method where applicable. The final

estimates gave rise to a better fit of the models and were considered to be valid for

statistical inference.

The non-uniqueness in model specification meant that robustness of the regression results

under alternative models had to be established a priori. Having established robustness in

the results between the two models [i.e. equations (4.9a*) and (5.1*)], it was possible for

conclusions pertaining to the validity of the SSH, ADH, RTH and stage-of-the-business-

cycle to be reached. However, it was not possible to conclude if the RTH applies to Korea,

owing to the problems in using the horizon covariance index for an annual data series, lack

of congruency with the empirical literature, and lack of robustness in the results of the

related empirical literature.

In terms of the pre-Crisis period, there is a general lack of relevance of the SSH, ADH and

stage-of-the-business-cycle effect for the Korean economy. For the post-Crisis period, the

results tend to support the first two hypotheses, but do not support the stage-of-the-

business-cycle effect.

For the post-1997 period, the limited data (4 observation points) seem to provide evidence

in favour of the post-Crisis effect for the SSH and ADH. However, this limitation (i.e.

short span) of the aggregate-level data prevents the full validation of these two hypotheses,

and it is only when more data become available for the post-Crisis period that appropriate

empirical testing will be possible. The implications of the stage-of-the-business-cycle

effect could not be examined effectively owing to the limited data available (i.e. only 4 data

points). Furthermore, it may not be meaningful to examine this hypothesis when the last

data point reflects a mid-point of the most pronounced cycle in the data series.

Nonetheless, since the aggregate-level data findings have indicated that the SSH/ADH

could apply to Korea, and that the nature of unemployment arising from pure sectoral

140

movements could be non-frictional after the Crisis, it could imply that the SSH/ADH are

new phenomena for Korea. What existed for the developed countries much earlier in the

last century appears to have only started for this NIE in recent years19

.

What we would like do in this current thesis, therefore, is extend the research from

aggregate-level data to longitudinal data using the same period of 1998-2001. Part II of the

thesis therefore uses unit-record data to study the factors that motivate inter-sector mobility.

Such knowledge may be useful when seeking solutions to future unemployment problems

through changes to labour mobility.

Endnotes:

1. South Korea will be referred to as Korea hereinafter.

2. The formal indices of sectoral mobility gathered from the literature review are to be analysed later.

3. A part of the reason is that a substantial portion of the ADH discussions has been centred around the U-V

correlation initiated by Abraham and Katz (1986).

4. Additional measures that were examined but not reported on are ζa1

t(up), ζt(s), ζt(r), ζt(p) and its corresponding

unpredicted series, ζt(up). See chapter 3 for a critique of these indices.

5. DMt and UNt were found to be stationary.

6. In the current study, these U.S. variables will not be included because, unlike Canada, the U.S. and Korean

economies are not integrated. To address the possibility of simultaneity bias, checks on the correlation

between DMRt and the other explanatory variables of the unemployment equation will be carried out. These

checks are undertaken as correlation between variables may indicate simultaneity bias, and if overlooked this

may lead to biased estimation [Barrows (2004)].

7. Garonna and Sica (2000) referred to the series as „money growth rate‟. Since it is an aggregate demand

indicator, it is most likely to be the money supply growth for Italy.

8. Barro (1977) indicated that the growth of the public sector at 5% per year (ρ = 0.2) would not seem to be

permanently sustainable. The Korean case of ρ = 0.05 appears reasonable.

9. The term, ζ, represents the generic sectoral mobility index covering all predicted and unpredicted indices.

It does not have a subscript for time t. The term with the subscript for time t, ζt, is the raw Lilien index. The

change variables denoted by the prefix „∆‟ are with respect to the immediate past period.

10. The similarity is based on the type of the variables as the number of lags and difference operators will

differ depending on tests of stationarity and data frequency in the case for Korea. Since annual data are used,

the number of lags for each variable was kept to a minimum. If not, the influence of a variable lagged by, say,

more than one year becomes dated. For the ζ‟s, the indices lagged by one time period were insignificant for

most regressions under equation (5.1). The DMR was lagged by one time period since DMRt was

insignificant in most regressions. It was not lagged by two periods since the annual data series for the

regressions would start from 1972, meaning a further loss of observations and degrees of freedom.

11. The CUSUM and CUSUMSQ techniques, and the associated significance lines, are often viewed as

„yardsticks‟ rather than formal statistical tests. The timing of any structural change is difficult to pinpoint

accurately using this procedure, and the plots need to be examined in association with prior knowledge. The

point at which the structural change commences is often when the plotted line starts to deviate upwards or

downwards.

12. It should be noted that since the absence of a structural break between phase 1 and phase 2 was

established, the Chow test could also have been conducted for (phase 1 plus phase 2) versus phase 3.

However, this is not necessary given the varied findings above. It would be better to proceed straight to the

structural dummy variable approach to ascertain the occurrence and source of structural change.

13. The only study was Parker (1992), where a military variable was incorporated into the unemployment

model to pick up the manpower influences of the Vietnam war.

141

14. A prior test that involved estimating a model with only the mobility dummy first, followed by the

inclusion of the intercept and mobility dummies, showed the statistical significance of the dummies to alter

according to the order of inclusion.

15. This LM statistic is computed as (N-1)R2, where R

2 comes from the auxiliary regression of the estimated

OLS error term on all explanatory variables together with the lagged value of the estimated error term for

(N-1) observations, with N being the total number of observations.

16. The tightening of the models could equally have been done following a correction for serial correlation

without any material change to the findings. The regressions with ζH and ζtSt under equation (4.9a*) and ζH

under equation (5.1*) were corrected for serial correlation. The findings showed that the intercept dummy

and/or mobility interaction dummies remained insignificant under both equations.

17. Greene (2003) conducted a Lagrange Multiplier test with a sample size of 19.

18. The standardized coefficient in the SPSS program expresses the impact of the independent variable in

terms of standard deviation units, i.e., whether the number of standard deviations the dependent variable

increases or decreases with a one standard deviation increase in the independent variable. The standardized

coefficient is calculated by multiplying the non-standardized coefficient by the ratio of the standard deviations

for the independent and dependent variables. A standardized coefficient of a single independent variable in a

multiple regression will assist in determining whether it has a greater or lesser effect on the dependent

variable as compared to the effects of other independent variables.

19. See „The World Bank (1999) „Republic of Korea: Establishing a New Foundation for Sustainable

Growth‟, Report No. 19595 KO, Nov 2, 1999‟.

142

(This page is left blank intentionally.)

143

PART II: THE FACTORS AFFECTING SECTORAL MOBILITY

PREAMBLE

Part I examined, from the perspective of the four hypotheses: SSH, ADH, RTH, and the

stage-of-the-business-cycle effect, the impact of sectoral mobility on unemployment.

Based on aggregate-level data, the key finding was the significant impact that unpredicted

and predicted sectoral mobility had on aggregate unemployment in Korea during the post-

Crisis 1998-2001 period. The four hypotheses, however, had little relevance for periods

prior to this. The mobility-unemployment relationship therefore appears to be a new

phenomenon in Korea, though it has been a characteristic of developed countries like the

U.S. and Canada for earlier periods. There is a need to understand the sectoral mobility

associated with this type of unemployment in Korea. This is the aim of the research

presented in Part II, where the causal factors of sectoral mobility are analysed using

longitudinal data for Korea for the 1998-2001 period.

The literature review in the next three chapters seeks to gather ideas for the current work

from the research undertaken on various forms of labour mobility. Chapter 6 presents

theoretical and conceptual issues in labour mobility and outlines the proposed empirical

framework. Chapter 7 reviews the literature on forms of labour mobility other than sectoral

mobility and extracts salient points for the current research. Chapter 8 conducts a review of

the empirical evidence on the factors affecting sectoral mobility. Finally, chapters 9 and 10

contain the empirical application for Korea, with emphasis on the overall labour force in

the former and separate analyses for males and females in the latter. The key conclusion is

that sectoral mobility is a multi-facetted phenomenon encompassing a range of factors,

including monetary and macroeconomic variables, worker and industry characteristics, and

the sectoral shock.

144

145

CHAPTER 6

THE THEORETICAL AND CONCEPTUAL ISSUES

IN LABOUR/SECTORAL MOBILITY

6.1 INTRODUCTION

This chapter introduces the main theoretical and conceptual issues in the microeconometric

study of labour mobility. The various forms of labour mobility are defined in section 6.2

and the three theories of sectoral/industrial mobility are presented in section 6.3. A generic

theoretical model describing the main motivations behind labour mobility is outlined in

section 6.4. This model provides a framework within which the empirical literature can be

studied (see chapter 8). It also forms the basis for the empirical analyses presented later in

the thesis (see chapters 9 and 10). While the focus of this thesis is on sectoral or industrial

mobility, the empirical literature reviewed covers other forms of labour mobility, including

union/non-union mobility, public-private sector mobility and rural-urban mobility. The

reason for this broad approach is that research into sectoral/industrial mobility appears less

advanced, and hence there may be much to be learned from careful study of the

econometric techniques, databanks and research questions from these other types of labour

mobility. Then, the empirical models used in study of the various forms of mobility are

presented in section 6.5. A summary of the chapter and the implications for the empirical

model are presented in the final section.

6.2 WHAT IS LABOUR MOBILITY?

Labour mobility is a very general term. It can be applied to movement of labour across

countries, across regions within a country, across occupations, industries or broad sectors of

an economy, such as the union and non-union sectors, government versus non-government

sectors and rural versus urban sectors.

There is a vast amount of literature dealing with the movement of labour across countries:

International migration has been a major research issue for most of the last century [Borjas

146

(1994), Bartel (1989), Chiswick (1991), Chiswick and Miller (1985), Chiswick, Le and

Miller (2008) and Dustmann (1993)]. A range of international migration issues have been

examined in Asia. Seok (1999), for example, examined Korea‟s foreign worker labour

immobility during the post-1997 Asian Financial Crisis, and attributed this to the fact that

small and medium-sized firms preferred to hire migrant labour at lower wages, while these

workers remained as their potential gain in earnings from re-migration did not exceed the

costs of returning to their countries of origin. Chew (1990) investigated issues related to

the brain drain in Singapore and highlighted the number of Singapore emigrations in the

1980s. Manning‟s (1999) study focused on implications of the influx of foreign labour into

Singapore from developing countries. Bartram‟s (2000) study highlighted that, in contrast

to other advanced industrial countries with positive migrant inflow, Japan experienced

negative labour migration in the post-World War II period.

Intra-regional migration is also of importance, with researchers attempting to account for

the rise and decline of parts of a country, the growth and demise of regional concentrations

of specific groups of people, and even patterns of settlement within cities [Tomes and

Robinson (1982a), Antolin and Bover (1997), and Fanni, Galli, Gennari and Rossi (1997)].

There have been a number of studies on intra-regional migration and these have

emphasized various patterns. Rogers and Henning (1999), for example, reported that

during the periods 1975-1980 and 1985-1990, foreign-born Americans showed a slightly

higher likelihood of crossing state boundaries than their native-born counterparts. Cutler,

Glaesar and Vigdor (1999) highlighted a trend for black migration during the period 1980-

1996 from the ghettos to cities/suburbs that previously had a predominantly all-white

population. Jeong (2003) showed that wages and large corporate employment raised the

likelihood of regional mobility in Korea over the period 1995-2002.

Occupational mobility is a popular field of study for economists interested in individual

economic well-being. A person‟s occupation offers a good guide to their economic

standing in society, and changes in the individual‟s occupation over time offer useful

insights into their economic progress. Occupational mobility can also be studied at the

aggregate (group) level where a change in the occupational mix over time can help explain

147

why particular groups fare better than others in the job market. For example, if males are

concentrated in trades occupations, and women in services, a shift in the jobs generated in

the economy away from trades towards services would, ceteris paribus, lead to more

favourable labour market outcomes for females than for males. Similarly, if the scope for

productivity gains differs across occupations, knowing how the occupational mix changes

over time will be fundamental to an appreciation of the origins of economic growth, for

example, whether it is so-called jobless growth or is associated with employment growth.

Examples of studies on occupational mobility include Flyer (1997), Kim (1998),

Greenhalgh and Stewart (1985), Miller (1984) and Chiswick, Lee and Miller (2005). Flyer

(1997) reported that the projected earnings was a positive and significant variable in the

initial occupation choice of college graduates. Greenhalgh and Stewart (1985) showed that

British men experienced greater upward mobility and achieved higher occupational status

than women. Miller (1984) presented a model of job matching and occupational choice,

demonstrating that it was optimal for young workers with lesser work experience to switch

occupations. Kim (1998) found that workers who change occupations experienced smaller

wage gains, were less skilled, lower educated and had lower market experience than

workers who do not change occupations. Chiswick, Lee and Miller (2005) found that

although there was a drop in occupational attainment from the last job in the origin to the

first job in the destination for male immigrants in Australia, upward occupational mobility

was possible with post-immigration investments.

As with occupational mobility, labour mobility across broad sectors of the economy

involves individual behaviour which could have implications for the economy. Sectoral

mobility takes various forms. One of the more common types is mobility between union

and non-union sectors [Heywood (1993) and Hahn (1996)]. Other forms of labour mobility

include that between government and non-government sectors [Borland, Hirschberg and

Lye (1998) and Blank (1985)] and rural and urban sectors [Todaro (1981), Zahn (1971) and

Tcha (1993)]. For the latter form of mobility, Zahn (1971) and Tcha (1993) examined the

determinants of worker movements for Japan and Korea, respectively.

Industrial or sectoral mobility is the main topic for the current study. As mentioned in Part

I of the thesis, one of the reasons for this study is that sectoral or industrial mobility is often

associated with structural changes and cyclical movements in the economy. This link has

148

been drawn in a number of studies. Studies associating sectoral mobility and cyclical

variations in unemployment include Abraham and Katz (1986), Blanchard and Diamond

(1989), Brainard and Cutler (1993), Lilien (1982) and Loungani and Rogerson (1989) for

the U.S. labour market, Garonna and Sica (2000) for the Italian labour market, and Prasad

(1997) on industrial mobility for the Japanese manufacturing sector. One point worth

noting is that these studies adopt aggregate-level time-series data. Interest in the individual

behaviour that leads to sectoral (industrial) mobility commenced around the late 1980s, and

this was facilitated by access to unit-record longitudinal data. Studies taking this approach

include Osberg (1991), Osberg, Gordon and Lin (1994), Vanderkamp (1977) for Canada,

Loungani and Rogerson (1989), McLaughlin and Bils (2001), Fallick (1993) and Neal

(1995) for the U.S.

These studies focus on the conventional definitions of economic sectors/industries.

Alternative definitions using micro-level datasets were developed in other studies. For

example, Thomas (1996b) constructed two sectors: (a) pre-displacement sector, which is

the original sector of employment of displaced workers; and (b) the remainder of the labour

market for Canada. Osberg, Mazany, Apostle and Clairmont (1986) categorized sectors as

central or marginal, where the former consisted of the goods-producing primary sector that

used capital intensive technology, including the resource and construction sectors, and the

latter comprised other manufacturing firms not in the central sector and personal services

industries.

The studies above have primarily been concerned with the movement of labour across

economic sectors of the economy. All the types of mobility considered can be examined

within a common framework. This framework is a standard neo-classical model that

depicts individuals as moving from one state (country, region, occupation or

industry/sector) to another if the gains from moving outweigh the costs. These gains and

costs can be either monetary or non-monetary. A model of mobility is outlined and used as

a basis for a more detailed review of the literature in section 6.4. Prior to that, the theories

pertaining to the origins of sectoral mobility will be presented in the section below.

149

6.3 THEORIES OF SECTORAL/INDUSTRIAL MOBILITY

Three theories on the origins of sectoral mobility emerge from the literature, namely, the

worker-employer mismatch theory, the sectoral shock theory and the bridging theory.

These theories are basically about model specification.

6.3.1 Worker-Employer Mismatch Theory

The worker-employer mismatch theory relies on the mismatch between workers and jobs to

generate sectoral mobility. Mobility is modelled as a function of wages and worker/job

characteristics. Workers change sectors if there is a change between their current and

expected circumstances; in the form of higher perceived wages in the new sector and/or

non-pecuniary benefits in new sector and/or or a better job-match between worker

characteristics and new job requirements. Hence, workers could change sectors if the

following matches occur:

a) workers‟ expected wages match with the prospective employers‟ wage offer;

b) workers‟ expectations of the non-wage benefits of the job, e.g. working hours

and benefits, match with the new job characteristics; and

c) workers‟ individual skill sets, e.g. demographic profile, qualification and

experience, match with employer demands and requirements for the job.

Whether one or all of the above matches occur following a sectoral switch really depends

on the individual worker and employer. For example, whilst one worker will switch sectors

if his skill set meets a firm‟s requirements even if the wages do not, another worker will

require that both his skill set and wage levels are in accordance with expectation before a

sectoral change takes place.

As both workers and employers are heterogeneous, the probability of moving to another

sector will differ across workers. It takes time and resources for workers to acquire

information about available job prospects and for employers to acquire information about

potential applicants. Moreover, there is uncertainty about this job information. The theory

150

suggests that workers will seek to maximize their expected wages based on the information

acquired and make a decision on a sectoral switch. Employers will optimally assign jobs to

workers based on the available information about the workers. Optimizing behaviour

within this framework can generate sectoral mobility for some workers and stability for

others. The theory relies on worker heterogeneity and imperfect information in job markets

to generate mobility and is applicable to all forms of sectoral mobility. Many studies of

union/non-union, public-private and rural-urban mobility and the majority of the studies of

sectoral/industrial mobility are based on this theory.

6.3.2 Sectoral Shock Theory

The sectoral shock theory subscribes to the view that sectoral shocks are responsible for

generating sectoral/industrial mobility. A sectoral shock can take the form of changing

tastes, technology, input price, product demand and productivity. Sector-specific shocks

are believed to affect the pattern of labour demand which leads to sectoral reallocations in

the labour market [Helwege (1992) and Clark (1998)]. For example, after a sectoral shock,

the demand for the product of that sector rises, the wages in that sector rise and this attracts

workers from other sectors, thereby generating labour mobility. There are a number of

studies measuring the impact of a sectoral shock on mobility, namely Gulde and Wolf

(1998), Jovanovic and Moffitt (1990), Brainard and Cutler (1993), Altonji and Ham (1990)

and Clark (1998).

Two distinctions must be made between the worker-employer mismatch and sectoral shock

theories. First, whilst the former relies on worker heterogeneity and imperfect markets to

generate mobility, it is implied in the latter that labour movements can occur even when

workers are homogeneous in a perfectly competitive labour market [Clive and Jovanovic

(1988)]. Specifically, in a perfect market, each homogenous worker is deemed to have an

equal probability of changing sectors [Mincer and Jovanovic (1981)] following a sectoral

shock. Second, there are implications pertaining to the empirical application. The sectoral

shock approach could be used if gross flows were equal to net flows. That is, if sectoral

shocks are the only reason for generating mobility, workers move from one specific sector

to another in response to a sectoral shock. Since the sectoral shock theory rules out other

causes of mobility, it implies that gross flows of labour should be equal to net flows. In

151

contrast, under the mismatch theory, mobility occurs owing to reasons other than a sectoral

shock. Workers move across sectors in both directions, and gross flows can be larger than

net flows.

6.3.3 Bridging Theory

Bull and Jovanovic (1986) argued that labour mobility may be caused by shifts in the

derived demand for labour on the part of firms/sectors and by mismatches between workers

and jobs. Furthermore, Jovanovic and Moffitt (1990) stated that a model that relies solely

on the impact of sectoral shocks on labour demand or concentrates on sector/worker

mismatch is likely to lead to misinterpretation of the empirical results. Hence, the

“bridging” theory subscribes to the view that labour mobility can be modelled in two ways:

via a shift in labour demand and also generated by employer-employee mismatch. This

bridging view was mooted by Clive and Jovanovic (1988) in theory only. The study that

tested this theory was Jovanovic and Moffitt (1990), where wages, worker characteristics

and a sectoral shock variable were incorporated into the mobility equation. Since mobility

is also generated by an employer-employee mismatch, it operates in the presence of

worker/employer heterogeneity and imperfect job markets. Each worker faces an unequal

probability of a sectoral switch.

6.4 MODEL OF LABOUR MOBILITY

The model outlined below is developed as a tool to explain worker movement from one

sector to another. The model has as its starting point the approach taken by Le and Miller

(1998). They developed a model of labour market choice incorporating an individual‟s

current and future earnings streams as well as the non-pecuniary aspects of alternative

employment states. This is a conceptual advance over other models of labour market

choice that are based only on the differential in current earnings associated with alternative

employment states.

Let yai(t) represent the annual earnings of an individual i in sector „a‟ in period t, and ybi(t)

be the annual earnings of the individual in sector „b‟ for period t. The lifetime earnings of

this individual in sectors „a‟ and „b‟ would each be:

152

T T

Yai = ∫ yai(t)e-rt

dt and Ybi = ∫ ybi(t)e-rt

dt 0 0

where r is a discount rate that is constant across individuals.

If the individual aims to maximize the net present value of their lifetime wealth, then they

will choose to move to sector „a‟ if Yai – Ybi – Ci > 0, where Ci reflects the difference in

non-pecuniary aspects and any non-recoverable costs of moving between sectors. This

decision rule may be approximated by ln Yai – ln Ybi – ci > 0, where ci is the cost of shifting

sector (and differential in non-pecuniary benefits) normalized by the earnings in sector „b‟.

This model may be rendered empirically tractable by using Willis and Rosen‟s (1979)

specification for the earnings generation process. This incorporates current earnings and

initial earnings in a simple geometric growth model, namely,

( ) ( ) aig t

ai aiy t y t e dt and ( ) ( ) big t

bi biy t y t e dt ,

_ _

where yai and ybi are the individual‟s initial earnings in sectors „a‟ and „b‟, and gai and gbi

are the growth rates of earnings in these two sectors, with r > gai, gbi. Over an infinite time

horizon,

∞ __

Yai = ∫ yai(t)e-rt

dt will be equal to Yai = yai / (r - gai) and

0

∞ __

Ybi = ∫ ybi(t)e-rt

dt equal to Ybi = ybi / (r - gbi).

0

When considering the choice of sector of employment, it is useful to work with this model

in the context of a discrete choice framework. Hence define an index function

Ii = ln Yai - ln Ybi - ci . (6.1)

The individual is assumed to choose sector „a‟ where Ii 0 and sector „b‟ where Ii < 0. By

_ _

expressing the index function as Ii = ln yai - ln ybi – ln(r-gai) + ln(r-gbi) - ci, and applying a

153

Taylors series expansion for ln(r-gai) and ln(r-gbi) around the mean values of the arguments,

the following expression may be derived:

1 2 3 4[ln ln ]i ai bi iai biI y y g g c . (6.2)

where the βs are the parameters that will be estimated to show how initial earnings in each

sector and growth rates in earnings in these sectors affect the underlying index that is used

to determine the choice of sector.

The index function could also be expressed in terms of current earnings and growth rates,

_ _

using the fact that ln yai(t) = ln yai + gait and ln ybi(t) = ln ybi + gbit. Thus,

Ii = γ1 + γ2 [ ln yai(t) - ln ybi(t) ] + γ3gai + γ4gbi - ci. (6.3)

The cost of moving between sectors (ci) can be modelled for inclusion in the index

function. Hence write ci = Ziδ, where Zi is a vector of observable variables influencing the

non-monetary differences in employment in sector „a‟ compared with „b‟. It also includes

any costs associated with moving between sectors. A sectoral shock (Si) can also be

incorporated into the model. Thus, substituting ci = Ziδ, and adding Siφ to represent the

sectoral shock, we obtain:

Ii = γ1 + γ2 [ ln yai(t) - ln ybi(t) ] + γ3 gai + γ4 gbi - Ziδ - Siφ. (6.4)

In this index function, which represents the latent tendency to move from sector „b‟ to

sector „a‟, the term ln yai(t) - ln ybi(t) represents the differential in current earnings while the

terms for the growth rates, γ3gai and γ4gbi, provide the foundation for a model that

incorporates future or permanent earnings. Finally, the terms Ziδ and Siφ each represent the

mobility effects associated with the costs of sectoral mobility and a sectoral shock.

In addition to monetary factors, worker and job characteristics, sector-specific shocks have

been reported to affect sectoral/industrial mobility [Gulde and Wolf (1998), Jovanovic and

Moffitt (1990), Brainard and Cutler (1993), Altonji and Ham (1990) and Clark (1998)].

154

Each sector is subject to shocks resulting in the movement of workers (i.e. sectoral

mobility), where workers are expected to move from lower to higher productivity sectors.

Although sector-specific shocks could affect worker wages, a sectoral labour change is

typically argued to occur prior to a change in wages. For example, a productivity shock

will first cause a worker to reallocate to a higher productivity sector before he can expect to

receive higher wages. A non-monetary shock (e.g. change in labour input demand) causing

workers to switch sectors may not necessarily result in a wage change. Therefore, sectoral

shocks cannot be fully reflected in the sectoral wage differential. For this reason, the

sectoral shock variable is introduced into equation (6.7) as a separate explanatory variable.

It was earlier noted that limitations on labour mobility in Korea appear to give rise to

unemployment. This unemployment needs to be incorporated into the Le and Miller

model. The Todaro (1984) model of worker mobility between rural and urban sectors is

useful in this regard, as it explicitly recognized the way unemployment can impinge on the

labour mobility process. In this model, an individual‟s decision to move is based on

considerations of income maximization and the perceived expected earnings stream in the

new sector. Applying Todaro‟s model to a generic form of sectoral mobility, it is assumed

that sector „b‟ is characterized by market clearing, while the higher income sector, sector

„a‟, has an above market-clearing wage and „wait‟ unemployment. If the probability that

the individual secures a job in sector „a‟ at their potential income in period „t‟ is pi(t), then

expected wages are given by the term ( ) ( )i aip t y t . Examples of studies applying the

concept of expected wages include Miller and Neo (2003) in an analysis of U.S. and

Australian labour market flexibility and immigrant adjustment, and Gyourko and Tracy

(1988) in an analysis of public versus private sector wages in union and non-union sectors.

In Miller and Neo (2003), the expected earnings was constructed by adjusting earnings

using the probability of unemployment. Both the earnings and unemployment measures

were from multivariate models of these labour market outcomes. Similarly, in Gyourko

and Tracy (1988), the expected public-sector (private-sector) wage was computed as the

weighted average of the expected public/union (private/union) and public/non-union

(private/non-union) wages. The actual earnings differential of workers from two sectors of

155

choice (e.g. public/union versus public/non-union) with similar observable characteristics

was used in the calculations.

It is generally noted that the probability of securing a job correlates positively with the

length of time a person spends in the new sector. Longer term movers would have more

contacts and better information systems than new movers. The longer the individual has

been in the new sector, the higher his probability of obtaining a job and the higher is his

expected income in that period. There are, however, alternative arguments on this matter.

It can be argued, for example, that a longer duration of wait unemployment increases the

difficulty in obtaining a job as there would be a stigma attached to the individual‟s

employment history. In this case, the probability term would be negatively correlated with

time. For ease of modelling, it is assumed that ( )i ip t p t , so expected wages are

piyai(t)1. Given this, the Le and Miller model can be extended as follows:

_

As yai(t) = yai(t)e dt, it follows that piyai(t), the expected annual earnings in sector „a‟,

can

be written as ( ) aig t

i aip y t e dt . Over an infinite time horizon, the expected wages,

0

( ) rt

i ai i aip Y p y t e dt

, will be equal to

The index function from equation (6.1) can now be modified to incorporate the probability

of finding employment in the non-market-clearing sector, and expressed as:

Ii = ln (piYai) – ln Ybi - ci.

This then gives:

_ _

Ii = ln pi ( yai / (r - gai)) – ln ( ybi / (r – gbi)) - ci.

Hence,

ln ln ln( ) ln ln( )i i ai bi iai biI p y r g y r g c . (6.5)

Using the Le and Miller method of applying a Taylors series expansion for ln (r - gai) and

ln (r – gbi) around the mean values of the arguments,

_ _ pi yai / (r – gai) as Yai = yai / (r – gai).

gait

156

1 2 3 4[ln ln ln ]i i ai bi iai biI p y y g g c . (6.6)

_ _ Given that ln yai(t) = ln yai + gait, ln ybi(t) = ln ybi + gbit and ci = Ziδ, and adding Siφ

which represents the sectoral shock, this gives:

Ii = γ1 + γ2 [ ln pi + ln yai – ln ybi] + γ3 gai + γ4 gbi - Ziδ - Siφ. (6.7)

where ln lni aip y represents the income level the individual expects to receive in the new

sector „a‟. The term [ln ln ln ]i ai bip y y now represents the anticipated differential in

expected current earnings. The term ln pi is reflecting wait unemployment.

Hence, it can be seen from the extended model that the worker movements from sector „b‟

to sector „a‟ are determined by the following:

a) Earnings in sector „a‟ versus sector „b‟, where earnings in the new sector should

be higher than the original sector in order to entice workers to move. This

could be regarded as a pull factor.

b) Lifetime wages in sector „a‟ versus sector „b‟. The new sector‟s permanent

incomes should be higher than the old sector‟s for a sectoral switch to occur.

This could also be treated as a pull factor.

c) Unemployment in sector „a‟ versus sector „b‟, where the level of unemployment

is greater in the high wage sector. This could be viewed as a factor that

moderates the pull factor noted above.

d) Non-monetary factors associated with the costs of mobility, which include a

range of demographic and socio-economic factors.

e) Sectoral shocks, which could lead to sectoral labour rellocations in the labour

market.

The transitory period of wait unemployment takes two forms: voluntary [Kim (1998)] and

involuntary [Thomas (1996b) and Addison and Portugal (1989)]. If individuals are

motivated by the pull factor of higher earnings in the new sector, inter-sectoral movements

are conceived to be voluntary, as mobility arises out of choice. Consequently, any wait

unemployment experienced in the new sector arising from the actions of wealth-

maximising individuals are voluntary. Wait unemployment can be involuntary where the

157

sectoral move arises out of necessity rather than choice. This could happen if individuals

lose their jobs due to employer-initiated actions [Fallick (1993)].

The empirical model of equation (6.7) is applicable to all three theories of sectoral mobility

described in the previous section. Under the mismatch theory, the model caters for wages

(with the inclusion of [ln ln ln ]i ai bip y y , gai and gbi terms) and worker/job

characteristics (subsumed under Zi). Under the bridging theory, the full model applies,

including the Si term, which now incorporates the sectoral shock element as well. In

contrast, the model becomes Ii = γ1 + Siφ under the sectoral shock theory, with Si

representing the stochastic shock.

Although not the focus of the thesis, the model can be generically applied to other forms of

labour mobility, since the terms „a‟ and „b‟ can each represent the employment states in

distinct sectors, i.e. union/non-union, public-private, and rural-urban sectors, or different

regions, e.g. region „a‟ versus region „b‟ and country „a‟ versus country „b‟. The

explanatory variables on the right-hand-side of equation (6.7) can represent the factors

affecting mobility. Nonetheless, regardless of mobility type, it should be noted that the

application of the model of equation (6.7) involves a study at the micro-level and not at the

aggregate level.

6.5 EMPIRICAL MODELS OF SECTORAL MOBILITY

The empirical models used in the analysis of the determinants of labour mobility consist of

single equation probability choice models, simultaneous equation models and competing

risks models. These models have been used in empirical study of union/non-union, public-

private, rural-urban and sectoral/industrial mobility. The first three forms of labour

mobility are of interest in the current thesis for three reasons. First, the theoretical model

used in much of the research is broadly the same as that outlined in section 6.4. In

particular, the typical model incorporates both a sectoral wage advantage and non-

pecuniary determinants. Second, much can be learned in terms of the type of data used.

Third, the econometric techniques and estimating equations cover a range of situations, and

158

this extensive coverage is useful for the empirical study of sectoral mobility, where the

empirical work is less advanced, and hence there is an advantage in being able to relate the

work to research in cognate areas.

A variety of databanks, estimation methods, coverage, dependent variables and explanatory

variables have been used. This section evaluates the relevance and implications for

modelling in the current work in terms of the general functional form, data-type, dependent

variable, coverage and estimation method.

6.5.1 Probability Choice Models

Functional Form

The probability choice models generally comprise one dependent variable and several

regressors, and are a form analogous to equation (6.7), namely:

Ii = Xi + ei (6.8)

where Ii is a latent (unobserved) tendency towards a move from sector „b‟ to sector „a‟, Xi

represents a range of monetary, economic and non-pecuniary explanatory variables, is the

vector of parameters to be estimated and ei is the stochastic disturbance term.

These models have usually been estimated using a probit, logit or linear probability method

of estimation, especially when micro data are used and the nature of the dependent variable

is dichotomous. This can be seen in studies of the other forms of labour mobility, namely,

Christie (1992), Farber and Saks (1980), van der Gaag and Vijverberg (1988), Gyourko and

Tracy (1988), Long (1975) and Long (1976), and in studies of sectoral/industrial mobility

by Osberg (1991), Osberg, Gordon and Lin (1994), Jovanovic and Moffitt (1990) and Neal

(1995). In the majority of studies based on aggregate-level data, ordinary least squares

estimation (OLS) was used2.

159

Although the empirical models in this area of research incorporate a wealth of monetary

and non-pecuniary determinants, they do not account for the lifetime earnings stream of

individuals that were included in the model outlined in section 6.4. In addition, although

several authors have recognized the importance of the expected wage differential, few have

attempted to use such a measure. In this regard, it is noted that while several studies refer

to an expected wage construct, this is a different concept from that developed in section 6.4.

For example, the wages in the union choice literature are computed on the basis of a full-

employment assumption, and hence are “expected” only in the sense that they refer to the

wages that the particular worker could expect to receive in the new sector. There is no

adjustment for wait unemployment. It should be possible, however, to make an adjustment

for unemployment with many datasets, including those for Korea, using the approach

adopted by Miller and Neo (2003).

The probability choice model of equation (6.8) is applicable to the three theories of sectoral

mobility depending on the inclusion of the variables under Xi. Likewise, it applies to the

conceptually-advanced empirical model of equation (6.7) where Xi is identical to

(γ1 + γ2[ln ln ln ]i ai bip y y + γ3 gai + γ4 gbi - Ziδ - Siφ).

Types of Data

Probability choice models have been estimated using four broad types of data. First, there

are micro datasets obtained from cross-sectional surveys. Examples are the union/non-

union and public-private sector studies of Christie (1992), Farber and Saks (1980), Borland

and Ouliaris (1994), Blank (1985), Hartog and Oosterbeek (1993), van der Gaag and

Vijverberg (1988), Gyouko and Tracy (1988), Long (1975) and Long (1976). Among the

various studies of sectoral/industrial mobility, those by Vanderkamp (1977) and Neal

(1995) have used cross-sectional micro datasets. Second, there are longitudinal datasets

which have been mainly used in the study of sectoral/industrial mobility, and these studies

include Osberg (1991), Osberg, Gordon and Lin (1994), Jovanovic and Moffitt (1990),

Loungani and Rogerson (1989), Fallick (1993) and Thomas (1996b). Third, some studies

have used aggregate-level cross-sectional data. These include the studies of public sector

mobility by Utgoff (1983) and rural-urban mobility by Schultz (1971) and Ghatak (1996).

160

Fourth, there are time-series studies conducted at various levels of aggregation. These

include Borland and Ouliaris (1994), Kenyon and Lewis (1997), Sharpe (1971), Carruth

and Disney (1988), Booth (1983), Bain and Elsheikh (1976) and Neumann and Rissman

(1984) for union/non-union mobility, Tcha (1993), Zahn (1971) for rural-urban mobility

and Ottersen (1993), McLaughlin and Bils (2001) and Jayadevan (1997) for

sectoral/industrial mobility.

The use of cross-sectional data has its limitations in that the data are subject to recall error

and their analysis confines the estimation to a single time-point, implying that dynamic or

longitudinal inferences are made on the basis of static analyses. One way of overcoming

these constraints is via the collection of longitudinal data, where workers who switched

industries are interviewed in adjacent time periods, and detailed information (original

industry and new industry) can therefore be collected on the workers who switch

sector/industry. This is illustrated in several studies of industrial mobility where

longitudinal datasets, enabling interviews and re-interviews to be conducted, were available

for analysis. The use of time-series data permits construction of both variables describing

labour market outcomes in previous periods and the lifetime earnings measure that is

central to the model of sectoral mobility employed. A structural change that affects an

economic sector may cause an imbalance in sectoral labour demand and supply. The socio-

demographic determinants of sectoral mobility are likely to be swamped by the

consequences of structural change. For example, in the absence of a structural change,

younger workers may have a higher likelihood of switching sectors if employment

opportunities appear strong in the new sector. However, when a structural change occurs,

e.g. a negative shock impacts the new sector, the new sector‟s performance and

employment levels may be reduced, and this same group of young workers may have a

higher probability of remaining in the old sector.

Aggregate-level data, cross-sectional or otherwise, have the merits of providing a rich

source of information about worker and job characteristics. However, there is a limitation

in that the conceptual models of aggregate-level data may mask the underlying relationship

through an averaging process. The results from the aggregate-level analysis may also be

sensitive to distributional characteristics of the data.

161

Longitudinal data available for the research on Korea are appropriate for the study on

sectoral/industrial mobility. Given the above discussion, this appears to be a strength of

the proposed analysis.

Coverage

A common observation in terms of coverage is that the studies of all forms of labour

mobility, using both aggregate and micro data, focus on employed persons3. The studies

with micro data tend to focus on the employed as full details are available in the data files.

Hence, in the current model, the focus will be on employed persons.

It is observed that several studies have analysed the determinants of sectoral mobility

separately for males and/or females [Osberg (1991), Neal (1995) and Osberg, Gordon and

Lin (1994)]. This is in view of the fact that the behaviour and motivation for mobility of

men and women are held to be different [Simpson (1988), Osberg (1991) and Osberg,

Gordon and Lin (1994)]. Furthermore, the estimated models for male mobility appear to be

statistically (in terms of goodness-of-fit) and economically (sign, magnitude and statistical

significance of particular regressors) superior to the results for females, which could

explain why most studies have focused on males [Osberg, Gordon and Lin (1994), Fallick

(1993) and Thomas (1996b)]. A similar approach will be undertaken for Korea. Separate

regression equations will be estimated for males and females, provided the gender mobility

patterns vary.

Dependent Variable

The dependent variable used in these models is a measured outcome variable that is linked

to the underlying propensity to choose a particular sector. For micro data, empirical work

is based on the individual‟s actual choice of sector in two adjacent time periods. This can

be seen in the sectoral mobility studies of Osberg (1991), Osberg, Gordon and Lin (1994)

and Jovanovic and Moffitt (1990). For aggregate-level data, the empirical work is based on

162

the change in, or proportion in, sectoral employment or the net change in employment of

the original and new sectors. The change variable in aggregate-level studies, e.g. Borland

and Ouliaris (1994), Kenyon and Lewis (1997), Carruth and Disney (1988), Bain and

Elsheikh (1996) and Sharpe (1971) in union/non-union studies and Jayadevan (1997) for

industrial mobility4, can be interpreted to mean that there are higher probabilities of

mobility into those industries characterized by higher employment growth. The proportion

of sectoral employment variable, e.g. Neumann and Rissman (1984) and McLaughlin and

Bils (2001), means that there has been an increase in the net inflow of labour into sector „a‟

when sector „a‟ has a proportionately higher increase in its share of employment between

period t and period t+1, compared to that of sector „b‟. In the current study, the dependent

variable will be a dichotomous variable, based on the actual change in sector/industry, since

micro data are available for the research.

6.5.2 Simultaneous Equation Models

One study that adopted a simultaneous equations approach is Zahn (1971), where equations

for both labour demand and labour supply were considered in the context of rural/urban

mobility. This approach was used as there may be simultaneous feedback between sectoral

movements and sectoral growth/unemployment. For example, lower growth in sector „a‟

might induce out-mobility to sector „b‟, but this out-mobility could also generate lower

growth in sector „a‟. In such an instance, OLS cannot be applied unless the system is

recursive, i.e. where there is a chain of causation from one factor to the next without any

feedback within the current period and the errors are uncorrelated [Booth (1983)]5. Where

these conditions do not hold, OLS will yield biased and inconsistent estimates. However,

most studies have eschewed the simultaneous equations approach in favour of simpler

methods of estimation. For example, Booth (1983), Ashenfelter and Pencavel (1969) and

Addison and Portugal (1989) have introduced lagged endogenous variables as regressors in

their single-equation models6. With these lagged variables, there is a distinction of time

periods and the causation between sectoral growth/unemployment and sectoral mobility can

be separately identified. The errors of the lagged variables will be uncorrelated7 and OLS

will be unbiased and consistent. Thus, the current empirical model will be based on a

single-equation, making use of lagged endogenous variables.

163

6.5.3 Vector Auto-regression Models

The methodology adopted by Prasad (1997) for Japan from 1959 to 1993 was a tri-variate

vector auto-regression model (VAR) of the following form:

et et-1 ε1t

wt = A(L) wt-1 + ε2t (6.9)

pt pt-1 ε3t

where et represents employment growth, wt is the growth in average real wages, pt is

the labour productivity growth rate, t the time index, A(L) is a 3x3 lag polynomial and ε is

the stochastic disturbance term. The VARs were estimated for each sector with one time

lag and a constant term. Although this methodology can be easily applied to aggregate-

level datasets, these VAR models are only useful in determining the correlations of relative

wages and employment. They do not differentiate a single dependent variable from the

independent variables and the chain of causation of variables cannot be ascertained. As

such, VAR models are not recommended for the current research8.

6.5.4 Sectoral Shock Measures

A useful point to note is that Gulde and Wolf (1998), Jovanovic and Moffitt (1990),

Brainard and Cutler (1993), Altonji and Ham (1990) and Clark (1998) measured the impact

of a sectoral shock on sectoral/industrial mobility. Sector-specific shocks, e.g. change in

tastes, technology, input prices, product demand and productivity, are believed to affect the

pattern of labour demand and this leads to sectoral reallocations in the labour market

[Helwege (1992) and Clark (1998)]. Given the existence of sectoral disturbances in the

economy, the empirical model should account for the stochastic shock element. The

technique of measuring sectoral shocks will be discussed in the later part of this thesis.

6.5.5 Time Periods

The data available from the Korean Labour and Income Panel Study (KLIPS) cover a

period of 4 years (1998-2001). This differs from the studies by Osberg (1991) and

Vanderkamp (1977), where regression results were estimated separately for different time

164

periods. As mentioned, the main advantage of using time-series data over a continuous

time horizon, 4 years in this case, is that it facilitates construction of appropriate lagged and

projected labour market outcomes variables for inclusion in the the estimating equation.

6.6 SUMMARY: MODEL APPLICATION FOR CURRENT RESEARCH

Probabilistic choice models appear to be more appropriate for the study of workers‟

movements between alternative employment sectors. From these models, maximum

benefits will be obtained if the following principles can be followed:

a) It is the expected, and not the actual, wage differential that should be applied to

the empirical model.

b) It is the lifetime earnings, and not present earnings, that should be embedded

into the empirical modelling. Individuals are maximisers of long-term income

and are not necessarily motivated to move to a new sector simply for immediate

and temporal gains. In practice, however, many researchers have had to use

only current earnings as the information required to calculate lifetime earnings

(i.e. longitudinal databases) has generally not been available.

c) Longitudinal data should be used where possible. Whilst cross-sectional data

provide a rich source of information on worker/job characteristics, time-series

data enable the assessment of the impact of structural changes on the labour

market and sectoral/industrial mobility. This data-type marries the benefits of

cross-sectional and time-series data.

d) The methods of estimation considered could be probit or logit models since the

dependent variable is dichotomous, and these methods generally yield

comparable results.

e) The dependent variable is a binary variable indicative of an individual‟s change

of sectors/industries.

f) Separate regressions could be estimated for each gender as mobility patterns of

males and females may differ. The extent to which this is necessary to

characterise the patterns of labour mobility in Korea can be tested statistically.

g) The empirical model can be used to test the three theories on sectoral/industrial

mobility: worker-employer mismatch, sectoral shock and bridging hypotheses.

165

This chapter has described the theoretical and conceptual issues of sectoral/labour mobility

for empirical modelling. The intent of the next chapter is to introduce the works on the

other forms of labour mobility, and extract the salient points for the current empirical

exercise.

Endnotes:

1. Furthermore, there is a difficulty in obtaining longitudinal data to model the duration dependence.

2. The exception applied to Loungani and Rogerson (1989) and Vanderkamp (1977) in sectoral/industrial

mobility where micro data were available.

3. The exception applies to Neal (1995) and Ottersen (1993) who concentrated on unemployed workers.

4. The growth rates in output and real wages per worker were the regressors in the equation.

5. Bain and Elsheikh (1976) recognized the problem of simultaneity between union density and price and

wage inflation but did not attempt to correct it in their empirical estimation of union/non-union sectoral

choice.

6. Booth (1983) and Ashenfelter and Pencavel (1969) adopted an instrumental variables (IV) approach where

price inflation was treated as endogenous. Addison and Portugal (1989) also used the IV approach to take

into account simultaneity between unemployment duration and the post displacement wage.

7. The Durbin H-statistic instead of the DW test for autocorrelation should be applied in a model which

contains lagged endogenous variables.

8. There are several studies of sectoral/industrial mobility that use a competing-risks model [Fallick (1993)

and Thomas (1996b)], but they focus on the unemployed. These models are generally based on a reduced-

form equation of the form: hij(t) = g (t, Xi, common components of labour market conditions in the old and

new sectors/industries), where hij is the probability that a worker who was unemployed at the beginning of

period t will make a transition from unemployment to employment in the new industry during period t, and t

is the number of periods of unemployment and Xi represents characteristics for individual i.

166

CHAPTER 7

REVIEW OF THE EMPIRICAL LITERATURE ON

OTHER FORMS OF LABOUR MOBILITY

7.1 INTRODUCTION

The previous chapter provided a theoretical foundation for the empirical modelling of

sectoral/labour mobility. As research on the determinants of sectoral/industrial mobility is

less sophisticated than the analyses of most other forms of mobility, it is possible that much

can be learned from studies of union/non-union, public-private sector and rural-urban

mobility that can assist the planned study of sectoral mobility. Accordingly, the primary

aim of the current chapter is to review studies on these other forms of labour mobility in

order to identify points relevant to the empirical analyses of sectoral mobility presented in

chapters 9 and 10. Section 7.2 covers union/non-union mobility, section 7.3 examines

public-private sector mobility while section 7.4 reviews rural-urban mobility. The final

section presents a summary of findings of relevance to the current empirical work.

7.2 UNION VERSUS NON-UNION MOBILITY

Union/non-union mobility refers to worker movements from the original non-union (union)

sector to the union (non-union) sector1. The rationale is that wealth maximizing individuals

will join the union sector if expected wages in that sector exceed current wages in the non-

union sector, ceteris paribus. As it is anticipated that the union wage will be above market-

clearing levels, there will be involuntary or wait unemployment, and it is the expected

rather than the actual wage in the union sector that will enter into the worker‟s calculations.

The studies on union choice generally adopt a model similar to that of equation (6.7),

except that the component of expected wages has not been factored into the worker‟s

calculations2.

There are numerous empirical studies focused on the determination of union choice, some

of which include Christie (1992), Borland and Ouliaris (1994), Sharpe (1971) and Kenyon

and Lewis (1997) for Australia, Booth (1983), Bain and Elsheikh (1976) and Carruth and

167

Disney (1988) for the U.K., and Neumann and Rissman (1984) and Farber and Saks (1992)

for the U.S. These studies generally relate union choice to monetary, macroeconomic and

non-pecuniary variables.

Table 7.1 outlines the main features of these studies, providing the data source, data-type,

coverage, model specification, method of estimation and relevant findings from the studies.

With regards to the data-type, whilst studies with micro cross-sectional data have generally

included a monetary variable (e.g. sectoral wage advantage) and a wide range of non-

pecuniary factors, the time series analyses with aggregate-level data have focused on the

macroeconomic factors and included lagged dependent variables. The approach to model

specification therefore depends to a certain extent on the type of data available.

The specification of variables is of particular interest to the current research. The effect of

monetary influences is generally captured by the earnings differential between the union

and non-union sectors. This component of the model corresponds to the current wage

advantage in the models of Todaro (1981) and Le and Miller (1998). An assessment of

whether cyclical fluctuations account for union/non-union mobility is generally made by

including the macroeconomic variables of unemployment, prices, wages and employment

rates in the union choice equations. These economic variables are generally included in

time-series analyses either as lagged independent variables or are differenced to the first-,

second- or third-order. This is in line with an earlier paper by Shister (1953), who argued

that both the rate and pattern of economic change were possible causes of unionization.

The influence of lagged dependent variables (i.e. union membership in previous time

periods) was also considered in several studies dealing with aggregate-level data [Sharpe

(1971), Booth (1983), Kenyon and Lewis (1990), Carruth and Disney (1988) and Borland

and Ouliaris (1994)]. There are several reasons for including the lagged dependent

variable. The “saturation effect” suggests that it is more difficult to increase trade union

membership in already highly unionized sectors owing to resistance from the remaining

non-unionised workers [Sharpe (1971) and Booth (1983)], and hence union density in

preceding periods might be expected to exert negative influences on current membership.

Another reason is that owing to reporting delays, union membership in preceding periods

might reflect some of the membership numbers for the current period [Carruth and Disney

(1988)].

168

Table 7.1 Selected Studies of Union/Non-Union Mobility

Study Source/Country/Time

Period, Data-Type and

Coverage

Dependent Variable,

No. of Regressors and

Explanatory Variables

Method of Estimation

and Relevant Findings

Christie (1992)

Source/Country/Time Period Australian National Social Science Survey, 1984. Data-type Unit-record cross-sectional data. Sample of population. Coverage 1,316 full-time and part-time wage earners aged 18 years and over from all Australian states.

Dependent Variable: Probability of union membership. No. of Regressors: 8. Explanatory Variables: Monetary: union/non-union

wage differential.

Socio-economic:

educational qualification,

experience, industry and

occupation.

Demographic: marital

status, sex and state.

Method of Estimation: Logit model. Relevant Findings: Workers are likely to join unions if the expected wages are higher. Males, diploma holders, experienced workers and those in Tasmania have a higher probability of joining unions. Marital status did not have an influential effect on the probability of union membership. Workers from agriculture, manufacturing, construction, wholesale trade, finance and public administration are less likely to join unions. Professionals, administrators, clerical, sales and service workers have a lower chance of union membership.

Farber and Saks (1980)

Source/Country/Time Period Individual votes from National Labor Relations Board elections, U.S., Jan 1972-Sep 1973. Data-type Unit-record cross-sectional data. Random sample of workers from 29 establishments in various industries. Coverage 817 union and non-union workers who were asked to participate in the vote, i.e. whether they preferred to join a union job or not.

Dependent Variable: Probability of an individual voting for a union job. No. of Regressors: 12. Explanatory Variables: Monetary: individual‟s position in intra-firm earnings distribution. Socio-economic: seniority, education, indicators for union causing relationship deterioration, union causing fairness improvement, chances for promotion, difficulty of finding job (DIFF), dissatisfied with job security (DS) and interaction variable (DIFF*DS). Demographic: race, sex, location and age.

Method of Estimation: Probit model. Relevant Findings: Workers who are at the lower end of the intra-firm earnings distribution, feel that they are unfairly treated, feel that chances for promotion in the non-union sector are not good, find difficulty in replacing jobs and are dissatisfied with job security are more likely to vote for unionization. Blacks are more likely to vote for unionization but older workers are not. Seniority, sex, education and location had little impact on the vote. The effects of demographic factors were controlled for in the study.

Borland and Ouliaris (1994)

Source/Country/Time Period Australian union membership data, 1913-1989. Data-type Aggregate-level time-series data. Coverage Total Australian workforce.

Dependent Variable: Change in union membership. No. of Regressors: 6. Explanatory Variables: Macroeconomic: employment in manufacturing and non-manufacturing sectors, UR in period t - UR in period t-2 and RW in period t-1 - RW in period t-3. Lagged dependent variable: union density in period t-1 and union density in period t-3.

Method of Estimation Engel and Granger (1987) method of co-integration using an error correction model. Relevant Findings: Employment in manufacturing and non-manufacturing have significant positive and negative impacts, respectively, on union membership. Unemployment and real wages showed a negative impact on union membership. An increase in union membership in previous periods increases union membership in the current period.

169

Table 7.1 Selected Studies of Union/Non-Union Mobility (continued)

Study Source/Country/Time

Period, Data-Type and

Coverage

Dependent Variable, No.

of Regressors and

Explanatory Variables

Method of Estimation

and Relevant Findings

Kenyon and Lewis (1997)

Source/Country/Time Period The data period covers 1948 to 1995. Data are from the Australian Bureau of Statistics‟ publications, including Trade Union Members and Trade Union Statistics. Data-type Aggregate-level time-series data. Coverage Total Australian workforce.

Dependent Variable: Change in union membership. No. of Regressors: 9. Explanatory Variables: Macroeconomic: RW in period t-1, UR in period t-1, employment in union sector in periods t and t-1, female employment in period t-1 and government employment in period t. Lagged dependent variable: union membership - total civilian employment in period t-1. Political: political dummy variable (1 = Labor Party in power, 0 = otherwise), Accord dummy variable (1 = during 1983-1990, 0 = otherwise) and dummy variable for post-1990 period.

Method of Estimation: OLS. Relevant Findings: Real wages had a positive effect on union membership. Any change in union employment in periods t and t-1, and government employment showed a positive influence. A change in female employment and a net increase in union membership over total employment in the previous period had a negative impact on union membership. Whilst the presence of the Labor party raised union membership, the Accord did not. The addition of a post-1990 dummy variable caused a negative shift in union membership. The unemployment rate had an insignificant effect on union membership.

Sharpe (1971) Source/Country/Time Period The data period covers 1907-1969. Data on union membership, unemployment and real wages obtained from the Labour Report of the Bureau of Census and Statistics. Employment data from the Australian Economic History Review and Yearbook of Commonwealth of Australia. Data-type Aggregate-level time-series data. Coverage Total Australian workforce.

Dependent Variable: Annual growth in trade union membership. No. of Regressors: 5. Explanatory Variables: Macroeconomic: growth in employment in the union sector, UR and RW in period t-1. Lagged dependent variable: Ratio of union membership to employment in period t-1. Political: dummy variable for institutional factors.

Method of Estimation: OLS. Relevant Findings: An increase in union sector employment leads to an increase in union membership. Real wages had an insignificant effect on unionization. The ratio of union membership to total employment in the previous period and the overall unemployment rate had negative effects on union membership. Institution factors exerted a positive impact.

Carruth and Disney (1988)

Source/Country/Time Period The data period covers 1896 to 1984 and are obtained from the following publications: U.K. Department of Employment (DE) Gazette (various issues), DE surveys of Trade Union membership and from the Census of Employment. Data-type Aggregate-level time-series data. Coverage Total British workforce.

Dependent Variable: Change in union membership. No. of Regressors: 10. Explanatory Variables: Macroeconomic: employment, employment, differential between wages and price in period t-1, UR, UR and union membership – employment in period t-1. Lagged dependent variable: union membership in previous periods t-1, t-2, and t-3. Political: dummy variable for political climate (0=Conservative government in power, 1=non-Conservative government).

Method of Estimation: OLS. Relevant Findings: Results are extracted from the model based on real wages after incorporating a dummy variable for political climate. Union membership has a positive effect on membership growth for up to period t-1. Real wages and unemployment have negative effects on the incentive to unionise. Any deceleration/acceleration to the change in unemployment has an offsetting effect. A positive change in employment and the presence of a non-Conservative government raises union density. Union membership net of employment in the previous period had an insignificant effect.

170

Table 7.1 Selected Studies of Union/Non-Union Mobility (continued)

Study Source/Country/Time Period,

Data-Type and Coverage

Dependent Variable, No.

of Regressors and

Explanatory Variables

Method of Estimation

and Relevant Findings

Booth (1983) Source/Country/Time Period

The data period covers 1895 to 1980. The data are obtained from the U.K. Census of Population and the following publications: Employment Gazette, The British Economy: Key Statistics and U.K. Annual Abstract of Statistics. Data-type Aggregate-level time-series data. Coverage Total British workforce.

Dependent Variable: Logistic transformation of union density1. No. of Regressors: 6. Explanatory Variables: Macroeconomic: price inflation, wage inflation and UR in periods t and t-1. Lagged dependent variable: percentage of union membership to the total workforce in periods t-1 and t-2.

Method of Estimation: OLS. Relevant Findings: Union membership for periods t-1 and t-2 exerted positive and negative impacts on union membership, respectively. The unemployment rate in the current period reduced union membership but the same variable in period t-1 tended to increase membership. Price inflation was an insignificant explanatory variable but wage inflation displayed a direct relation with union membership.

Bain and Elsheikh (1976)

Source/Country/Time Period As in Booth (1983). Data-type Aggregate-level time-series data. Coverage Total British workforce.

Dependent Variable: % change in union membership. No. of Regressors: 5. Explanatory Variables: Macroeconomic: prices, wages, and unemployment in periods t-1 and t-2. Lagged dependent variable: union density in period t-1.

Method of Estimation: OLS. Relevant Findings: Changes in prices and wages, and unemployment in period t-2 exerted positive effects on union membership. Union density and unemployment in period t-1 showed negative effects.

Neumann and Rissman (1984)

Source/Country/Time Period The data covers the period 1904-1980, obtained from the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics‟ Handbook of Labor Statistics, Wolman (1936) and Troy (1965). All sources are based on membership figures reported by unions. Data-type Aggregate-level time-series data. Coverage Total U.S. workforce.

Dependent Variable: % unionised. No. of Regressors: 11. Explanatory Variables:

Macroeconomic: inflation

rate, employment,

employment in periods t-1,

t-2 and t-3, UR and %

unemployed in periods t-1

and t-2.

Socio-economic: welfare in

period t (depicted by

government expenditure on

social welfare as a %GNP),

% representation elections

won by unions and %

demographic representation

in Congress.

Method of Estimation: OLS. Relevant Findings: Higher inflation increases union

membership. The unemployment rate

and change in employment in period

t-1 showed positive effects. Whilst

the change in employment in period t

had a negative impact, the change in

employment in periods t-2 and t-3

had insignificant effects. The %

unemployed in period t-1 exhibits a

positive impact but there is an

insignificant impact for the same

variable for period t-2. Social welfare

benefits reduce the attractiveness of

union membership. The higher the

percentage of representation

elections won by unions, the higher

the % unionised. The percentage of

demographic representation in

Congress had an non-influential

impact on union membership.

1. Derived as Z = ln [D/(1-D)]t where D is union density with a one time period lag. Annotation: UR denotes unemployment rate, RW denotes real wages.

denotes change in the variable between two time periods. denotes a second-order change in the variable between time periods. For example, yt = (yt – yt-1) = (yt – yt-1) – (yt-1 – yt-2).

171

A range of non-pecuniary influences has been examined in the union choice literature.

Included are the demographic and socio-economic composition of the labour force, in terms

of the age, race, sex, marital status, education, industry, occupation, seniority and

employment status of workers. Several studies have also added what Shister (1954) termed

as a “proximity influence”, which can be viewed as either physical proximity (e.g. rural-

urban-suburb, state), an employer- or employment-specific factor (e.g. relationship with

supervisor, fairness treatment of employee, promotional prospects, job security) or political

proximity, e.g. influence of political party on the union as in Kenyon and Lewis (1997) and

Carruth and Disney (1988).

The empirical findings from this body of research are also of interest, as they can show the

success or otherwise of this approach to modelling. The union/non-union wage differential

was found to have a positive and significant effect on the union choice decision by Christie

(1992). Farber and Saks (1980) went a step further to add a threshold point - workers at the

lower end of the intra-firm earnings distribution (earning less than $0.21/hour above the

infra-firm mean earnings of $0.49/hour) were more likely to join unions. This is consistent

with suggestions in the union literature that unions represent the political interests of lower-

income and disadvantaged persons. For example, see the discussion of the collective voice

“face” of unions in Freeman and Medoff (1984). These and the other studies demonstrate,

therefore, that monetary incentives can be modelled successfully when analyzing worker

mobility.

The studies that have examined the impact of economic variables on the rate of

unionization, however, have produced conflicting results in relation to the possible impact

of unemployment, level of employment and real wages. The relationship between

unemployment and union membership was negative in Borland and Ouliaris (1994), Sharpe

(1971) and Carruth and Disney (1988), but positive in Neumann and Rissman (1984),

Ashenfelter and Pencavel (1969) and Freeman (1989), and insignificant in Kenyon and

Lewis (1997). In the studies by Booth (1983) and Bain and Elsheikh (1976), the

unemployment rate lagged by different time periods also exhibited conflicting results.

Unemployment exerted a negative influence for the current period in Booth (1983) and for

period t-1 in Bain and Elsheikh (1976). The unemployment rate for period t-1 and that for

period t-2 tended to be associated with increased membership in Booth (1983) and Bain and

172

Elsheikh (1976), respectively. In part, the conflicting empirical evidence may reflect the

ambiguous nature of the theoretical predictions. On the one hand, it has been argued that

higher unemployment raises union density because unions are able to increase job security.

On the other hand, if unions are seen as a source of higher unemployment owing to their

wage-setting powers, the incentive to unionise will decline during periods of high

unemployment3.

Similarly, changes in the level of overall employment were found to have a positive effect

on union density in Carruth and Disney (1988), but a negative bearing in Neumann and

Rissman (1984). It should be noted that Sharpe (1971) considered a sectoral breakdown for

the employment variable, with the inclusion of employment in the union sector, which was

found to have a positive impact on union membership. However, as the number of studies

using sector-specific economic indicators is few, no firm conclusions can be formed.

Theoretically, the association of real wage with union choice is indeterminate. It has

generally been argued that this association will be negative, as decreases in wages that lead

to worker dissatisfaction should increase the desire to unionise. However, it is also possible

that workers might join unions to defend real wage gains so that real wages and

unionization will be positively correlated. Given these competing views, it should come as

little surprise that the empirical findings on the union density – real wage relationship are

mixed. Whilst Borland and Ouliaris (1994) and Carruth and Disney (1988)4 concluded that

real wages had a negative effect on union density, Kenyon and Lewis (1990) and Peetz

(1990)5 reported a positive impact. Real wages were found to have an insignificant effect

on unionization in the study by Sharpe (1971).

It was earlier argued that workers seek to maximize their economic wealth and so will join

unions if the perceived union wages are higher. This, however, is tied to a ceteris paribus

assumption that needs to be accommodated in empirical work. Worker characteristics differ

and each labour market exhibits different characteristics. The studies reviewed in Table 7.1

take account of such factors, although the empirical evidence is not always conclusive. For

example, sex and education were found to be significant explanatory variables in Christie‟s

(1992) model for Australia, but not in the study undertaken by Farber and Saks (1980) for

the U.S.

173

There are, however, limitations to these union choice models which the current study

should attempt to overcome. In particular, there appears to be a fundamental oversight

which could explain the conflicting results for business cycle variables. Earlier, it was

observed that sectoral labour movements are determined, in part, by unemployment in

sector „a‟ versus sector „b‟. In the union choice studies, however, an overall unemployment

rate variable is used. That is, there is no distinction as to whether the pool of the

unemployed is generated from the union sector or the non-union sector. This same line of

argument applies to the real wage and employment variables, where empirical studies fail

to differentiate between union/non-union employment and real wages. Kelly and

Richardson (1989) and Booth (1983) have also expressed doubts concerning the

explanatory power of estimating equations based on business cycle models. Sharpe (1971)

also indicated that a disaggregated sectoral unemployment rate might help to explain trade

union growth. The exclusion of these apparently appropriate explanatory variables could

lead to model misspecification, giving rise to misleading results. The empirical review in

chapter 8 addresses this issue6.

7.3 PUBLIC VERSUS PRIVATE SECTOR MOBILITY

Public-private sector mobility is another form of labour mobility7. Both of these sectors are

associated with different characteristics and influences. Whilst the private sector tends to

follow principles of profit-maximisation or cost-minimisation, the public sector is more

often subject to other social, political and non-economic influences. Workers with differing

personal characteristics have differing probabilities of choosing public versus private sector

employment, as they seek the job (or sector) where their specific set of characteristics will

receive the highest rewards. The public-private sector divide resembles more closely the

setting that will be used in the empirical work to be undertaken in this thesis, in that

movement between sectors for public and private sector workers generally involves a

greater set of changes than does movements between sectors for the union and non-union

workers examined above.

Many of the models of public-private sector mobility have a structure that is quite similar to

the empirical model of equation (6.7). Accordingly, this research has included both the

public-private sectoral wage differential and worker/job characteristics as explanatory

174

variables in the estimating equations used. Some examples include Borland, Hirschberg

and Lye (1996) for Australia, Blank (1985), Gyourko and Tracy (1988), Long (1975), Long

(1976) and Utgoff (1983) for the U.S., Hartog and Oosterbeek (1993) for the Netherlands

and van der Gaag and Vijverberg (1988) for Cöte d‟Ivoire.

Table 7.2 overviews the major approaches and findings from research into public-private

sector mobility. The public-private sector studies selected use unit-record cross-sectional

data and incorporate a wealth of monetary and non-pecuniary factors as regressors. The

exception, in this context, is Utgoff (1983) who uses aggregate-level cross-sectional data

and with a smaller number of regressors. However, unlike union/non-union studies with

aggregate-level time-series data, there do not appear to be any studies in the public-private

sector with macroeconomic factors and lagged dependent variables.

The explanatory variables in the private-public sector selection models consist of the

sectoral earnings differential and non-monetary factors. The latter comprises personal

characteristics (sex, age, race, marital status, educational qualification, intelligence quotient

(IQ), veteran status, years and levels of education, past school in non-English speaking

country, school attended, whether born in Asian/non-English speaking country, year of

arrival in Australia, field of study, reading, writing and arithmetic skills, geographic region,

age of youngest child and whether in capital city) and job characteristics (occupation, firm

size, experience and blue-collar versus white-collar status). In addition to these personal

and job characteristics, Hartog and Oosterbeek (1993) added social background indicators,

such as number of siblings, father‟s occupation and father and mother‟s education.

175

Table 7.2 Selected Studies of Public-Private Sector Mobility Study Source/Country/Time

Period, Data-Type and

Coverage

Dependent Variable,

No. of Regressors and

Explanatory Variables

Method of Estimation and Relevant

Findings

Borland, Hirschberg and Lye (1996)

Source/Country/Time Period Australian Bureau of Statistics (ABS) Training and Education Experience Survey 1993. Data-type Unit-record cross-sectional data. Sample of employees. Coverage 5,969 males and 3,376 females aged 15-64 years who were employed full-time as wage and salary earners.

Dependent Variable: Probability of selecting a public sector job. No. of Regressors: 13. Explanatory Variables: Demographic: age, marital status, age of youngest child and whether in capital city. Socio-economic: education level, age minus age left school, experience-squared, year of arrival in Australia, last school attended in non-English speaking country, field of study, whether born in Asian/non-English speaking country and state of residence.

Method of Estimation: Separate probit models for male and female employees. Relevant Findings: Males: The more experienced males residing in Victoria, South Australia (SA) and Western Australia (WA), who have attended a school in a non-English speaking country, arrived in Australia between 1964-1967, 1972-1975, 1986-1987 and 1990-1991, and who have studied Trade Qualification (TQ) in vehicle and food, Post-School Certificate (PSC) in science, computing and agriculture will have a lower likelihood of choosing the public sector. Those who have degrees in law, education, medicine, mathematics, IT, veterinary science, engineering, social sciences and TQ in electricals and electronics, arts, social sciences and crafts, are more likely to choose the public sector. Females: Women with longer job tenures, who are residing in NSW, Victoria, Queensland, SA and WA who arrived in Australia between 1984-1985 have a greater probability of choosing the private sector. Those with children between 0-2 years who have completed degrees in law, education and the social sciences, PSC in education, teacher training, nursing, other health and para-medical, and who arrived in Australia between 1968-1971 and 1972-1975 are more likely to choose the public sector instead.

Blank (1985) Source/Country/Time Period U.S. 1979 Current Population Survey (CPS). Data-type Unit-record cross-sectional data. Random sub-sample of the CPS, i.e. one-fourth of employed heads of households. Coverage 10,908 employed heads of households, of whom 8,344 are in the private sector and 2,564 are in the public sector.

Dependent Variable: Probability of individual being a private sector worker. No. of Regressors: 6. Explanatory Variables: Demographic: sex, race and geographic region. Socio-economic: veteran status, occupation, education level and experience.

Method of Estimation: Probit model. Relevant Findings: For the non-monetary variables, veterans, non-whites, higher-educated persons, workers in services and those in Washington D.C. and with more experience have a higher probability of choosing the public sector. Women showed no statistically distinguishable preference.

176

Table 7.2 Selected Studies of Public-Private Sector Mobility (continued) Study Source/Country/Time

Period, Data-Type and

Coverage

Dependent Variable,

No. of Regressors and

Explanatory Variables

Method of Estimation and Relevant

Findings

Hartog and Oosterbeek (1993)

Source/Country/Time Period Individuals from the Dutch province of Noord-Brabant obtained from addresses in the city population register of the Netherlands in 1983. Data-type Unit-record cross-sectional data. Sample of population. Coverage Males and females from 2,726 addresses in a single province.

Dependent Variable: Probability of selecting a public sector job. No. of Regressors: 8. Explanatory Variables: Monetary: public-private sector wage differential. Demographic: sex (female). Socio-economic: social background (no. of siblings, father‟s occupation, education of father and education of mother), personal characteristics (IQ, education level).

Method of Estimation: Endogenous switching regression model. Relevant Findings: Variables related to social background were unimportant in the determination of public sector employment, except for father‟s education which showed a positive effect. For personal characteristics, vocational and university graduates are more likely to work in the public sector. The higher the IQ, the lower the probability of the individual working in the public sector. Females were less likely to become public servants. The likelihood of public sector employment is higher the larger the predicted wage gain in the public sector.

van der Gaag and Vijverberg (1988)

Source/Country.Time Period Cöte d‟Ívoire Living Standards Survey (CILSS), 1985. Data-type Unit-record cross-sectional data. Sample of households. Coverage 513 wage earners from 1,600 households.

Dependent Variable: Probability of obtaining public sector job. No. of Regressors: 6. Explanatory Variables: Monetary: public-private sector wage differential. Demographic: sex, age and age-squared. Socio-economic: indicators for diploma at elementary, high school, higher and technical diplomas, reading, writing and arithmetic (RRR) skills and years of schooling.

Method of Estimation: Probit model. Relevant Findings: Women are more likely than men to be employed in the public sector. Age (up to 50 years) shows a positive effect on public sector employment. Elementary and high-school diplomas increase the likelihood of a public sector job. Higher and technical diplomas, years of schooling and RRR skills have insignificant effects. The sectoral wage differential is not significantly different from zero.

Gyourko and Tracy (1988)

Source/Country/Time Period U.S. 1977 CPS. Data-type Unit-record cross-sectional data. Sample of population. Coverage Full-time wage earners.

Dependent Variable: Probability of selecting private/union or private/non-union or public/union or public/non-union sector. No. of Regressors: 8. Explanatory Variables: Demographic: marital status, race, gender and region of residence (northeast, central, south and west). Socio-economic: veteran status, seniority status (junior and senior), level of college (1st, 2nd, 3rd and 4th year) and graduate status.

Method of Estimation: Multinomial logit model. The model had 4 distinct labour markets: private/union, private/non-union, public/union and public/non-union sectors. Relevant Findings1: Veterans, juniors,

graduates, those attending higher levels

of college education (3rd-4th year) and

lived in the western region had a higher

chance of selecting a public union/non-

union job. There was no distinct

preference for a public union/non-

union job versus private union/non-

union job for workers who are white,

married, male, seniors, have lower

level of college education (1st and 2nd

year) and lived in the northeast, central

and south regions.

177

Table 7.2 Selected Studies of Public-Private Sector Mobility (continued) Study Source/Country/Time

Period, Data-Type and

Coverage

Dependent Variable,

No. of Regressors and

Explanatory Variables

Method of Estimation and Relevant

Findings

Long (1975) Source/Country/Time Period

U.S. 1970 Census of Population. The reference year is 1969. Data-type Unit-record cross-sectional data. 1-in-1,000 public use sample of the 1970 census data. Coverage 40,578 males aged 14 years and over, of which 3,886 were black.

Dependent Variable: Probability of public sector employment. No. of Regressors: 6. Explanatory Variables: Demographic: indicators for males aged 14 years and over, males aged 18-34 years, workers in the southern region and non-southern region. Socio-economic: white-collar workers and blue-collar workers.

Method of Estimation: Linear probability model. Relevant Findings: The study concentrates on sectoral differences in employment for blacks relative to whites. The probability of public sector employment was higher for black white-collar and blue-collar workers, black males aged 14 years and over, and those aged 18-34 years. In both southern and non-southern regions, blacks were relatively more likely to be employed in the public sector rather than the private sector.

Long (1976) Source/Country/Time Period U.S. 1970 Census of Population. The reference year is 1970. Data-type Unit-record cross-sectional data. 1-in-1,000 public use sample of the 1970 census data. Coverage Male and female employees.

Dependent Variable: Probability of Federal Employment. No. of Regressors: 4. Explanatory Variables: Demographic: marital status (married and single) of workers. Socio-economic: indicators for white-collar workers, and occupation (professionals, managers and administrators).

Method of Estimation: Linear probability model. Relevant Findings: Females are less likely to be employed in the public service. Specifically, females who are white-collar workers, professionals, administrators and managers tend to be under-represented in the public service. Marriage has a negative impact on the probability of public employment among females, while being single had a positive but insignificant effect.

Utgoff (1983) Source/Country/Time Period U.S. 1972 Bureau of Labor Statistics‟ (BLS) data and 1972 Census of Manufactures. Data-type Aggregate-level cross-sectional data. Sample of the population (for BLS data on quit rates). Coverage Government employees.

Dependent Variable: Probability of quitting the public sector. No. of Regressors: 2. Explanatory Variables: Monetary: average hourly earnings. Socio-economic: firm size.

Method of Estimation: OLS. Relevant Findings: Larger firm size and higher average hourly earnings had a negative effect on the probability of quitting the public sector.

1. The Gyourko and Tracy (1988) study had four labour market choices: public union, public/non-union, private

union and private non-union. Since the focus is on the choice between two labour markets (public versus

private sector), the findings presented reflect the most significant result which will be independent of

union/non-union choice.

As argued previously, it would be expected that higher wages in the public sector would

induce wealth maximizing individuals to seek employment in that sector. Hartog and

Oosterbeek (1993) found that the larger the predicted wage gain in the public sector, the

higher the likelihood of public sector employment. In Borland, Hirschberg and Lye (1996),

public sector male and female employees had higher wages than their counterparts in the

private sector, implying that the higher-paid public sector would attract individuals to seek

employment in that sector. However, it has also been argued that there may be non-wage

178

benefits, e.g. job stability, working hours and fringe benefits, that are generally not

considered in the statistical analyses, and the presence of which mean that workers may

prefer the public sector even if monetary wages are higher in the private sector. In the case

of the Ivorian market, the sectoral earnings differential did not have a significant impact on

the choice of sectoral employment. Thus, with the exception of the Ivorian labour market,

the evidence for public-private sector mobility sits comfortably alongside that for

union/non-union choice models. Hence, emphasis can be placed on the estimated impact of

the sectoral wage advantage in both the union choice equation and the public sector/private

sector model.

The findings on education levels were consistent for all the studies represented in Table 7.2,

except for Borland, Hirschberg and Lye (1996). Specifically, public sector choice tended to

be associated with higher education levels, even though the specification of the education

variables differed across studies. In particular, Blank (1985) found that higher-educated

persons in the U.S. had a higher probability of choosing the public sector. Hartog and

Oosterbeek (1993) demonstrated that university graduates in the Netherlands were more

likely to work in the public sector than in the private sector. van der Gaag and Vijverberg

(1988) also found that public sector employees were, on average, better educated than

private sector employees for the Ivorian labour market. Gyourko and Tracy (1988) found

that graduates and persons with higher levels of diplomas had a greater likelihood of

choosing a public sector job. This is not surprising as the public sector has been perceived

as recruiting better educated persons to assist in the planning of policies and evaluation of

programmes.

It has been argued that certain groups, e.g. non-whites and women, may have a higher

probability of choosing the public sector. Non-whites may choose the public sector as the

work practices are less discriminatory. Women may prefer the public service given that the

work environment there is more family friendly, with practices facilitating intermittent

labour market attachment. The findings on the racial divide were consistent for the U.S.

Blacks and other non-whites were found to have a higher probability of choosing public

sector employment in the three studies conducted for the U.S. for the different periods of

analysis [Blank (1985), Long (1975) and Gyourko and Tracy (1988)]. For Australia,

179

being born in an Asian country did not have a significant impact on public-private sector

choice [Borland, Hirschberg and Lye (1996)].

The findings on the role of gender on public sector choice were inconclusive. Whilst van

der Gaag and Vijverberg (1988) and Gyourko and Tracy (1988) found that women were

more likely than men to choose public sector employment, Hartog and Oosterbeek (1993)

and Long (1976) reported that females were less likely to become public servants. Blank

(1985), however, reported that being female had a statistically insignificant impact on

public sector choice. Apart from the fact that the role of women at work varies in

importance across different countries, a possible reason for the mixed evidence could be a

failure to take adequate account of the composition of female employment by occupation,

industry etc. For instance, if the public sector in a country had a higher proportion of

clerical personnel compared to professionals, and if such workers are predominantly

female, then it could be expected that women, on the whole, would have a higher chance of

securing public sector employment, particularly if insufficient account is taken of

occupational structure in the estimations.

A final point to note in relation to the public-private sector selection models is that sectoral

unemployment does not appear to have been recognized in the analyses. This may be due

to data limitations. While datasets are available that contain information on the type of

work (e.g. occupation/industry) that individuals are seeking, and hence facilitate the

estimation of unemployment models for different sectors, this information may not be

available in the datasets used for the studies reviewed in Table 7.2.

7.4 RURAL-URBAN MOBILITY

Rural-urban mobility (or migration) is another type of labour mobility that has been

researched extensively8. Todaro (1969) and Harris and Todaro (1970) hypothesized that

rural-urban mobility is stimulated primarily by rational economic considerations of relative

benefits and costs, and it is mainly the expected urban-rural income differential that will

influence the individual‟s decision to move9. The studies on rural-urban mobility have

mainly been conducted for developing countries with a predominantly agrarian population,

180

i.e. Schultz (1971) for Columbia and Ghatak (1996) for India, as well as NIEs with a

substantial share of rural workers, namely Tcha (1993) for Korea and Zahn (1971) for

Japan. The relevance of these studies to the current analysis lies in the emphasis placed on

the monetary and non-pecuniary determinants.

Table 7.3 summarises the main findings of several studies conducted for the U.S., South

America and Asia. With the exception of Ghatak (1996), the authors have included the

sectoral wage differential as well as macroeconomic (e.g. overall unemployment and

economic growth rate), demographic (e.g. urban-rural population ratios, rural labour supply

and the age-sex distribution of the population) and a rich array of socio-economic (e.g.

education, violence indicators and travel time to city) elements in the rural-urban mobility

function.

These rural-urban studies use aggregate-level data. Whilst the aggregate-level time-series

analyses have incorporated macroeconomic variables, those with cross-sectional data, i.e.

Ghatak (1996) and Schultz (1971), have not. The absence of macroeconomic determinants

for cross-sectional analyses was also observed in the union/non-union and public-private

sector studies. This arises as cross-sectional studies are unable to track the consequences of

a structural change in the macroeconomy. In addition, as in the case of public-sector

studies, the rural-urban studies generally have a fewer number of regressors (6 or less)

when aggregate-level data are applied.

The primary explanatory variable in these studies is the rural-urban wage differential10

.

According to Todaro‟s model and the model outlined in chapter 6, there should be a clear

positive relationship between the wage differential and worker mobility, especially when

the probability of obtaining work in the urban sector is taken into account. However, this

clear theoretical prediction is not reflected in the empirical literature. The studies that are

consistent with the Todarian hypothesis, and report a positive relationship between the

urban-rural income ratio/differential and rural-urban movements, include Tcha (1993) for

the U.S. and Zahn (1971) for Japan. The sectoral wage differential was insignificant in the

study by Ghatak (1996). In contrast, Tcha‟s (1996) findings for the Korean labour force

did not support Todaro‟s hypothesis: he found that Korean villagers were willing to

181

sacrifice higher rural wages for lower incomes in return for better living conditions in urban

areas, provided the expected urban wages were at least 75 per cent of the original rural

income.

Table 7.3 Selected Studies of Rural-Urban Sector Mobility Study Source/Country/Time

Period, Data-Type and

Coverage

Dependent Variable, No.

of Regressors and

Explanatory Variables

Method of Estimation and

Relevant Findings

Tcha (1993)

Source/Country/Time Period Annual data of U.S., 1960-1987. Data-type Aggregate-level time-series data. Sample of population. Coverage U.S. migrants.

Dependent Variable: Net rural-urban migration rate1. No. of Regressors: 4. Explanatory Variables: Monetary: dynastic rural-urban income ratio. Macroeconomic: real growth rate of the economy and overall unemployment rate. Demographic: ratio of the rural population to urban population.

Method of Estimation: OLS (log-linear). Relevant Findings: Dynastic income ratio and economic growth rate had significant positive effects on rural-urban migration. Effects of the overall unemployment rate and ratio of the rural population to urban population were insignificant.

Schultz (1971)

Source/Country/Time Period Columbia, 1951 and 1964. Data-type Aggregate-level cross-sectional data. Sample of 131 Columbian municipalities drawn from 1951 and 1964 Population Census data. Coverage Males and females aged 7-51 years.

Dependent Variable: Net migration rate for rural population2. No. of Regressors: 5. Explanatory Variables: Monetary: rural wage. Socio-economic: school enrolment for children aged 5-9 years and 10-14 years, frequency of political violence and distance to travel to the next city. Demographic: growth rate of rural labour supply.

Method of Estimation: OLS. Relevant Findings: Rural wage has a negative effect on out-migration. An increase in the growth rate of the rural labour supply accelerates out-migration. School children aged 10-14 years are more likely to move to urban areas than those 5-9 years. The effect of greater distance to the next city spurs migration. An increase in rural violence encourages persons to move to urban areas.

Tcha (1993) Source/Country/Time Period Annual data of Korea, 1963-1988. Data-type Aggregate-level time-series data. Sample of population. Coverage Korean migrants.

Dependent Variable: Net rural-urban migration rate1. No. of Regressors: 4. Explanatory Variables: Monetary: dynastic rural-urban income ratio. Macroeconomic: real growth rate of the economy and overall unemployment rate. Demographic: ratio of the rural population to urban population.

Method of Estimation: OLS (log-linear). Relevant Findings: For the income variable, people are willing to move to urban areas until the expected dynastic income is 75% of the rural income. Economic growth rate had a positive effect on migration and the unemployment rate had a negative effect. The result for the ratio of the rural population to urban population was insignificant.

182

Table 7.3 Selected Studies of Rural-Urban Sector Mobility (continued)

Study Source/Country/Time

Period, Data-Type and

Coverage

Dependent Variable, No.

of Regressors and

Explanatory Variables

Method of Estimation and

Relevant Findings

Zahn (1971) Source/Country/Time Period

The data covers the period 1878 to 1937. Agricultural and industrial labour, real output and working age population are obtained from Ohkawa (1957). The capital stock series are estimated from Ohkawa‟s (1957) capital stock estimate and Rosovsky‟s (1961) savings data. Population data are from the Bank of Japan. Data-type Aggregate-level time-series data. Coverage Males and females aged 14 years and over.

Dependent Variable Industrial-agrarian labour force ratio. No. of Regressors Demand equation: 2. Supply equation: 2. Explanatory Variables:

Demand Equation

Industrial-agrarian required labour ratio is expressed as a function of the socio-economic (industrial-agrarian capital stock ratio) and macroeconomic (real output ratio and technical progress) factors.

Supply Equation

Industrial-agrarian labour force ratio is expressed as a function of the monetary (expected urban-rural income ratio) and demographic (an index of the age-sex distribution of the population) factors.

Method of Estimation: Simultaneous equation model using 2-stage least squares estimation. Relevant Findings: Demand Equation The industrial-agrarian real output ratio and technical progress have positive effects on the industrial-agrarian labour ratio. The industrial-agrarian capital stock ratio had a negative effect. Supply Equation An increase in the actual urban-rural wage ratio leads to out-migration. A higher number of working age persons and females both induce out-migration.

Ghatak (1996)

Source/Country/Time Period Census of Population 1971 and 1981 obtained from the Statistical Abstract of the Indian Union. Data-type Aggregate-level cross-sectional data. Coverage Rural and urban population for all Indian States.

Dependent Variable 3 variables: size/growth rate/density of urban population (UP). No. of Regressors: 1. Explanatory variables: Monetary: estimated rural-urban income differential.

Method of Estimation: OLS. Relevant Findings: For these 3 regressions, a higher urban-rural wage differential does not appear to induce out-migration.3

1. The rate is calculated using the actual and expected rural population (RP) data. The expected RP in period t is

calculated by multiplying RP in period t-1 (RPt-1) by the natural population growth rate allowing for births and

deaths (δt). Subtracting the actual RPt from RPt-1(1+ δt) gives net rural-urban migration.

2. Net migration rate is defined as the ratio of a net migration flow in the rural sector to the average size of the

local population. A negative migration rate means a net out-migration from the rural sector, and conversely for

a positive migration rate. 3. According to Ghatak (1996), several factors, i.e. moving costs, expected wages, skill levels, risk-taking

behaviour of individuals and borrowing and liquidity constraints, were not taken into consideration, and this could explain why the Todarian hypothesis was not supported.

The conflicting findings in relation to the estimated impact of the monetary variable could

be due to two factors. Firstly, as in the public-private sector studies, differences exist

between rural-urban work environments, individual preferences, culture of country etc., and

the effects of the monetary element are therefore not expected to be the same for studies

183

conducted in different contexts. Secondly, different measurements of the variable have

been used. Ghatak (1996), for example, computed the rural-urban income ratio using the

estimated agricultural and industrial incomes for India (in Rupees) at current prices, while

Zahn (1971) used the actual urban-rural income differential. In comparison, Tcha (1993)

calculated a dynastic income ratio of the weighted average of blue-collar and white-collar

incomes in the urban area to the income in the rural area, where the weights were chosen

iteratively and were related to time and altruistic discount rates between generations.

Schultz (1971) only considered the push factor of the rural wage as a determinant of

mobility.

The dynastic income ratio used by Tcha (1983) suggests that the wage differential should

account for altruism between generations which has multiplicative effects on a family‟s

decision to migrate. The average of blue-/white-collar incomes was also used in the

dynastic measure as migrants from rural areas typically have insufficient physical and

human capital, and are more likely to use the urban blue-collar income as their expected

income. This type of dynastic income measure is not relevant to analysis of

sectoral/industrial mobility. Whilst rural-urban migration decisions involving inter-regional

movements could cause multi-generational family migration, sectoral/industrial mobility is

usually independent of family migration.

The rural-urban mobility models do not have a sectoral breakdown of the unemployment

rate, unlike that suggested for the current empirical model. Such a breakdown is important

theoretically as sectoral movements could prevail in the presence of higher unemployment

in the new sector where migrants would be underemployed in the informal sector.

Underemployment is, however, difficult to measure, and this measurement problem may

explain the practice (of omitting unemployment rate variables) in applied work. In

comparison, the inclusion of the sectoral unemployment rates in the empirical work is

likely to be important in the current research, and it is practical to include relevant measures

in the estimating equations.

184

Several aspects of the rural-urban migration analyses are of value to the current study.

First, the use of the sectoral wage differential is notable and this variable can be considered

for inclusion in the current work. Second, the use of sectoral performance indicators in

rural-urban studies is an approach that can be followed. In the study of rural-urban

migration, individuals are argued to move from the lower-growth sector to the rapidly

growing sector. The variables indicative of sectoral growth comprise the industrial-

agrarian labour force, capital stock and real output [Zahn (1971)] and growth rate of rural

labour supply [Schultz (1971)]. Whilst the industrial-agrarian labour force ratio acts as a

demand-pull factor, where a higher ratio (e.g. from technology shock) causes urban wages

to rise and pulls people to migrate to urban areas, higher rural labour supply acts as a

supply-side factor causing rural unemployment and pushing people to migrate. For

sectoral/industrial mobility, it would be the growth (declining) sectors that induce workers

to move to (out of) their sectors.

7.5 SUMMARY: SALIENT POINTS FOR EMPIRICAL MODEL

The review of the literature in this chapter has highlighted the following points which

should inform the empirical work to be undertaken in chapters 9 and 10.

a) The determinants of sectoral mobility should be modelled within a framework

comprising a sectoral wage differential and the macroeconomic and non-

monetary factors associated with mobility.

b) A sectoral distinction in the macroeconomic variables, especially on

unemployment, is desirable.

c) The non-pecuniary determinants should also be measured on a sector-by-sector

basis where possible.

d) The type of data to be used affects model specification. The longitudinal data

that are to be used have the advantage that macroeconomic and lagged

dependent variables, which have been demonstrated to be significant

determinants of labour mobility, can be incorporated into the estimating

equation.

185

Endnotes:

1. It is recognized that the worker movement can be from the non-union sector to the union sector or from the

union sector to the non-union sector. For ease of exposition the discussion here is in terms of the former flow

of workers.

2. The sole exception to this appears to be Gyourko and Tracy (1988).

3. See Borland and Ouliaris (1994).

4. Carruth and Disney (1988) incorporated a dummy variable for political climate: 1 when the

Labour/Liberals were in power and 0 for the presence of a Conservative government. The initial regression

in the absence of the political dummy revealed that the real wage had a negligible effect on union

membership.

5. Peetz (1990) presented evidence on workers in the manufacturing sector. Those who experienced a decline

in real wage in the previous two years had a higher desire to unionise.

6. The exception applies to changing price levels, which were found to be directly related to union

membership in Neumann and Rissman (1984), Carruth and Disney (1988) and Bain and Elsheikh (1976). A

possible explanation for the non-conflicting result in this instance is that, unlike real wages and

unemployment, prices are not sector-specific. All individuals/workers, regardless of whether they are union

or non-union members, face similar price levels. It is noted that for Carruth and Disney (1988), the findings

reported are obtained from their nominal inflation model.

7. Private-public sector labour flows do occur, but for ease of exposition the review examines the public-

private sector mobility.

8. While there may be urban-rural labour flows, most literature addresses the more important rural-urban

flow, and this is the focus of this section.

9. Several authors, like Mincer (1978) and Borjas (1990), have questioned the hypothesis that migration

behaviour can be explained solely by the individual‟s income. Mincer (1978) examined decision making

within the family unit, particularly the effect of interactions between husband and wife on the probability of

migration. Borjas (1990) considered the welfare of children as a determinant in the migration function.

10. Earlier studies prior to Todaro [Jorgensen (1967) and Ranis and Fei (1964)] examined rural-urban

mobility using the wage differential.

186

CHAPTER 8

EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE:

FACTORS MOTIVATING SECTORAL/INDUSTRIAL MOBILITY

8.1 INTRODUCTION

This chapter reviews the empirical evidence on the factors motivating sectoral/industrial

mobility. These factors include monetary and macroeconomic characteristics, worker and

job characteristics, and sectoral shocks. Various labour markets are covered. Moreover,

where possible, results for both males and females, as well as for the overall labour force,

are reviewed.

The chapter categorises the studies according to labour mismatch, sectoral shock and

bridging theories. Section 8.2 gives a general introduction to the concept of

sectoral/industrial mobility and introduces the studies covered. Section 8.3 outlines the

impact of explanatory variables under the labour mismatch theory. These variables include

monetary and macroeconomic factors and worker and job characteristics. Section 8.4

focuses on the effects of a sectoral shock on mobility under the shock theory. The

implications from a single study based on the bridging theory are covered in section 8.5.

The impact of the explanatory variables on overall (i.e. both male and female workers)

mobility will first be reviewed. This will be followed by an examination of gender

differences in sectoral labour market outcomes. An assessment of the empirical studies of

sectoral mobility for the purpose of empirical modelling is given in section 8.6. A

summary of the findings is provided in the final section, together with suggestions on the

applicability of the explanatory variables to the current empirical study of Korea.

8.2 SECTORAL/INDUSTRIAL MOBILITY

Sectoral/industrial mobility is the main form of labour mobility of interest to the current

research. It is a complex matter involving a spectrum of factors in the individual‟s decision-

making process, and the costs and benefits involved are usually of far greater importance

than those that need to be considered in union/non-union or intra-sectoral mobility. In the

187

latter forms of mobility, wealth-maximising individuals select jobs similar to their former

jobs/sectors so that much of their human capital can be transferred to the new sector in

return for wage gains. Consequently, the costs of moving, and the wage gains required to

induce mobility, will usually be relatively minor. In comparison, the costs and barriers to

entry in inter-sectoral mobility are greater. As sector-specific skills may not be easily

transferable to other sectors, skills relevant to the new sector will need to be acquired, and

this means the investment costs necessary to facilitate the move may be considerable.

Moreover, limited market knowledge of the new sector may act as a barrier to entry

[Subrahmaniam, Veena and Parikh (1982) and Gallaway (1965)]. There may also be

psychic costs to moving that are of greater importance than in intra-sectoral mobility, e.g.

uncertainty about prospects in the new sector which pose as artificial barriers to entry

[Greenwood (1975), Gallaway (1965) and Vanderkamp (1977)]. These real and artificial

barriers to entry constitute a further cost that workers need to take into account in their

choice of sector/industry.

These issues are prominent in empirical studies of sectoral mobility. Under the labour

mismatch theory, the main studies of sectoral/industrial mobility are Osberg (1991),

Osberg, Gordon and Lin (1994) and Vanderkamp (1977) for Canada, Loungani and

Rogerson (1989), McLaughlin and Bils (2001) and Brainard and Cutler (1993) for the U.S.,

Prasad (1997) for Japan and Jayadevan (1997) for India. These studies covered employed

workers, where sectoral mobility rates of around 13% [U.S. males in Jovanovic and Moffitt

(1990) and Canadian employees in Osberg, Gordon and Lin (1994)] have been reported.

Inter-industrial movements are higher for the unemployed (about two-thirds of the

unemployed who gained employment changed their industry of employment in Thomas

(1996b)1 and Neal (1995)

2), but there are only a small number of studies of their behaviour.

The main contributions are Fallick (1993), Thomas (1996b), Neal (1995) and Kim (1998)

for the U.S.,3 and Ottersen (1993) for Sweden.

The studies of the sectoral shock hypothesis cover a range of countries, including Brainard

and Cutler (1993) and Clark (1998) for the U.S., Gulde and Wolf (1998) for the European

Union (France, Italy, Germany and Spain) and Altonji and Ham (1990) for Canada. The

sole study based on the bridging hypothesis was undertaken by Jovanovic and Moffitt

(1990) for the U.S.

188

8.3 DETERMINANTS UNDER THE MISMATCH THEORY

The aim of this section is to review the determinants covered in the studies of sectoral

mobility under the mismatch theory. Table 8.1 provides a selection of the relevant

empirical literature. The explanatory variables under the bridging theory in Jovanovic and

Moffitt (1990) are also presented so that the variables (excluding the sectoral shock) can be

compared with those under the mismatch theory. These studies are chosen as they cover a

wide range of the monetary, macroeconomic and non-pecuniary factors that appear to be

directly related to the current work. Additionally, the studies cover the main worker

groups, namely, the overall workforce as well as males and/or females. This is relevant to

the separate analyses undertaken later for males and females in the Korean labour market.

The determinants include a sectoral distinction for the monetary variable (e.g. wage

differential between the old and new industries or wages in the original and/or wages in the

new industries, industry per worker real wage growth rate and sectoral wages relative to

total wages) and macroeconomic factors (overall GNP and employment, employment in the

old and new industries, unemployment in the old and new industries and the ratio of

employment in the old industry to that of the new industry). Some of the macroeconomic

factors, e.g. average and real GNP growth, overall employment and unemployment and

unemployment duration, do not have a sectoral breakdown. Most of these variables were

analysed from the perspective of the ways they affected overall mobility. However, the

analysis of the impact of the overall unemployment rate and duration of unemployment

spell was extended to male and female mobility, and the analyses of the effects of wages in

the old/new sector and relative sectoral wages were undertaken for male mobility.

The non-pecuniary factors include worker and job characteristics. The worker

characteristics consist of demographic factors (sex, age, age of entry and marital status) and

socio-economic characteristics (education status, language ability, unionization, head of

household status, having children, skill levels, e.g. white-collar job, job tenure and

employment status). These characteristics are fixed for the worker and so there is no need

to consider sector-specific measures. The examination of the impacts of marital status,

tenure, employment status, occupational status, initial industry and working hours was

carried out for male/female mobility, and that of formal education for male mobility.

189

The job characteristics comprise working hours/weeks, training, industry, industry

performance, occupation, industry size, turnover, output, whether the industry provides

unemployment insurance/social benefits, product/work similarity4, type of job loss (e.g.

advance notification, due to slackness or shift in position) and male-female mix in the

industry. These variables tend to be sector- or industry-specific, and there are quite

considerable variations across industries in these factors. Consequently, it is expected that

most variables will exert greater influence on sectoral mobility than on other forms of

worker mobility. In addition, sector-specific shocks which are believed to affect certain

economic sectors causing sectoral mobility were included in many studies.

These studies either cover the employed or unemployed. As employed workers have greater

access to information markets, i.e. networks in other sectors and capital markets, and face

greater opportunity costs in changing sectors [Pissarides and Wadsworth (1989)], it is

expected that the personal characteristics and market conditions that affect their mobility

will differ from those for the unemployed. Where possible therefore, the empirical

determinants of mobility for these two groups need to be assessed separately.

It was earlier highlighted that several studies examine the determinants of sectoral mobility

separately for males and/or females. However, Osberg (1991) appears to be the only study

that compares the inter-industry mobility patterns of male and female employees. Gender

comparisons regarding the determinants of industrial mobility are therefore limited to the

explanatory variables covered in his study. Many studies focus on male mobility behaviour,

including Osberg (1991), Osberg, Gordon and Lin (1994), and Jovanovic and Moffit (1990)

for the employed, and Neal (1995), Fallick (1993) and Thomas (1996b) for the

unemployed. Other studies have covered either the overall workforce [Vanderkamp

(1977), Loungani and Rogerson (1989) and Ottersen (1993)], industry establishments

[McLaughlin and Bils (2001) and Jayadevan (1997)] or sectoral employment [Prasad

(1997), Gulde and Wolf (1998), Altonji and Ham (1990), Brainard and Cutler (1993) and

Clark (1998)].

190

Table 8.1 Probability Choice Studies of Sectoral/Industrial Mobility

under Worker-Employer Mismatch Theory Study Source/Country/Time-

period, Data-type and

Coverage

Dependent Variable, No. of

Regressors and Explanatory

Variables

Method of Estimation and Relevant

Findings

Studies of Employees

Osberg (1991) Source/Country/Time Period Labour Force Survey, Statistics Canada, 1980/1981, 1982/1983 and 1985/1986. Data-type Longitudinal data. Stratified random sample of households.

Coverage

Male and female workers. 1980/1981: 4,165 males 1982/1983: 3,751 males 1985/1986: 3,592 males 1980/1981: 2,756 females 1982/1983: 2,741 females 1985/1986: 2,682 females

Dependent Variable Probability that a worker changed industry of employment between Sep in year t and Feb in year t+1. No. of Regressors: 11. Explanatory Variables: Macroeconomic: unemployment rate and weeks unemployed. Socio-economic: Worker characteristics: initial industry, initial occupation, education status (years of schooling) and part-time worker status. Work characteristics: change in usual weekly hours, job tenure and job tenure squared. Demographic: Age and marital status (single = 1, 0 otherwise).

Method of Estimation: Separate regressions are run for males and females using a logit model. Relevant Findings: Unemployment did not exert any influence for males in the three periods; its effect for females during 1980/1981 and 1985/1986 was negative. Education status and marital status had non-influential impacts on mobility. Single and higher-educated men had higher industrial mobility only in 1980/1981. Age was an insignificant variable except for its negative influence on women in 1985/1986. Job tenure showed negative effects for both men and women in all time periods. For job tenure squared, positive effects were exhibited in all 3 periods except in 1985/1986 for females. This means that as job tenure increases, its positive influence increases at a less than linear rate. Male workers in the construction industry were more likely to leave the industry in all 3 time periods, and those in manufacturing and resources had higher mobility rates in 1982/1983. Females in construction and government had higher mobility rates in 1985/1986, and those in manufacturing, trade and finance, utitlies and transport exhibited higher mobility rates in 1982/1983. The occupational status effect was insignificant for men except for managers/professionals/technicians in 1980/1981, who were less likely to change sectors. Among women, higher mobility rates were seen by those in personal services in 1980/1981 and 1982/1983, those in clerical services in 1980/1981 and managers/professionals/technicians in 1982/1983. Women in all occupational groups displayed lower incidences of mobility in 1985/1986. The longer the number of weeks unemployed, the higher the probability of mobility for males and females for all periods. The changes in working hours did not have a significant impact except for males in 1982/1983 and 1985/1986. Except for females in 1980/1981, part-time workers are more likely to change industry.

191

Table 8.1 Probability Choice Studies of Sectoral/Industrial Mobility

under Worker-Employer Mismatch Theory (continued) Study Source/Country/Time-

period, Data-type and

Coverage

Dependent Variable, No. of

Regressors and Explanatory

Variables

Method of Estimation and Relevant

Findings

Studies of Employees

Vanderkamp (1977)

Source/Country/Time Period Canadian Insured Population for years 1965/1966, 1966/1967 and 1967/1968. Data-type Unit-record, cross-sectional data. Sample of Insured Population. Coverage 4,692 employees.

Dependent Variable Proportion of moves from industry i to j. No. of Regressors (linear model): 25. Explanatory Variables: Monetary: wage in original industry (Yi) and wage in new industry (Yj). Macroeconomic: unemployment in original industry (Ui) and unemployment in new industry (Uj). Socio-economic: Worker characteristics: formal education in original industry (EDi), education in new industry (EDj), (EDiEDj)

1/2, unionization in original industry (CAi), unionization in new industry (CAj), (CAiCAj)

1/2, change in occupation, change in province of employment and change in occupation and province of employment. Work characteristics: industry size (Pj), industry turnover and dummy variables for product similarity, location similarity and work similarity. Demographic: age of entry in original industry (Ai), age of entry in new industry (Aj), (AiAj)

1/2, male-female specialization in the original industry (Fi), male-female specialization in the new industry (Fj) and (FiFj)

1/2.

Method of Estimation: OLS for linear mobility model. Relevant Findings from Linear Model: For 1965/1966 and 1966/1967, the lower the wage in the original industry, the higher the likelihood of mobility. Conversely, higher wages in the new industry induce industrial mobility for all three periods. Higher unemployment in the original industry encourages industrial mobility. Unemployment in the new industry did not have a significant effect for 1966/1967 and 1967/1968. The larger the industry size and turnover, the higher the probability of mobility. Education, age of entry and male-female specialisation in the new and original industries displayed negative effects on industrial mobility. However, the effects of the coefficients on (EDiEDj)

1/2, (AiAj)1/2 and

(FiFj)1/2 were positive. Unionization in the

old and new industries had negative effects on mobility except for unionization in the new industry in 1965/1966. The effect of the coefficient on (CAiCAj)

1/2 was positive for 1965/1966 and 1966/1967. The change in occupation and change in occupation and province indicators had negative effects on industrial mobility. However, the change in the province of employment had a positive impact on mobility. The 3 dummy variables for product, location and work similarity showed positive and significant effects on inter-industry mobility.

Osberg, Gordon and Lin (1994)

Source/Country/Time Period 1986-1987 Labour Market Activity Survey (LMAS) extracted from the Labour Force Survey, Statistics Canada. Original interview conducted in Jan/Feb 1987 on labour market activities with a re-interview concerning activities in 1987 being conducted in Jan/Feb 1988. Data-type Longitudinal data. Stratified sample of households. Coverage Prairie and Atlantic male employees aged 16-69 years with hourly wages in both surveys. Initial sample is 8,570 males, out of which 1,095 changed industries.

Dependent Variable Probability of inter-industry mobility. No. of Regressors: 14. Explanatory Variables: Monetary: wage differential. Macroeconomic: no. of weeks unemployed. Socio-economic: Work characteristics: index of job availability, desire for more working weeks per year and desire for more work hours. Worker characteristics: education qualification (elementary, post-secondary, diploma, university), language (French speaking indicator), job tenure, received unemployment insurance indicator, received training in 1986 indicator, received social assistance indicator and used CEC1 in 1986 indicator. Demographic: age (16-19 years, 20-24 years and 25-34 years) and marital status (married).

Method of Estimation: Bivariate probit model of simultaneous choice between 3 states: immobility, inter-regional and inter-industry mobility during 1987. Relevant Findings: The wage differential did not exert any influence on inter-industry mobility. The greater the availability of jobs and the shorter the job tenure, the higher the probability of inter-industry mobility. Persons aged 16-19, 20-24 and 25-34 years, desiring a higher number of working weeks per year and more working hours per week, with a post-secondary education, with longer duration of unemployment and who received unemployment insurance and those who received training in 1986 showed a higher incidence of inter-industry mobility. French speakers, married persons, those with elementary, diploma or university education, those who used CEC and received social assistance displayed insignificant effects on industrial mobility.

192

Table 8.1 Probability Choice Studies of Sectoral/Industrial Mobility

under Worker-Employer Mismatch Theory (continued) Study Source/Country/Time-

period, Data-type and

Coverage

Dependent Variable, No. of

Regressors and Explanatory

Variables

Method of Estimation and Relevant

Findings

Studies of Employees

Jovanovic and Moffitt (1990)

Source/Country/Time Period National Longitudinal Survey of Young Men, U.S., 1968-1981. Data-type Longitudinal data. Survey sample of males. Coverage Male employees aged 14-24 years were interviewed in 1966 and who were 29-39 years in 1981 at the last interview. There are a total of 9,963 observations: 492 (1965-1968), 754 (1968-1970), 628 (1967-1969), 887 (1969-1971), 1,357 (1971-1973), 1,846 (1973-1975), 2,032 (1976-1978) and 1,967 (1978-1980).

Dependent Variable Probability of a sectoral move. No. of Regressors: 2. Explanatory Variables: Monetary: standard deviation of wage distribution. Socio-economic: Worker characteristics: Job experience (5 years, 8 years and 11 years). Aggregate Disturbance term: sectoral shocks.

Method of Estimation 1. Probit mobility equation estimated separately for each year as a function of education, experience, experience-squared, and race. Only the fitted probabilities at 5, 8 and 11 years of job experience are shown for each regression estimated for the years 1968 to 1973, 1975, 1978 and 1980. 2. The probability of a sectoral move was regressed on the standard deviation of the log (wage distribution) and standard deviation of sectoral shocks at 5, 8 and 11 years of job experience. Relevant Findings: 1. The probability of a sectoral move decreased for all experience levels (5 years, 8 years and 11 years of experience). Mobility fell much faster from 1968 to 1973 than from 1973 to 1981. 2. The larger the standard deviation in wages, the higher the probability of a sectoral move for all experience groups. The sectoral shock had a positive impact on the probability of sectoral mobility for workers with 5 and 8 years of work experience.

Loungani and Rogerson (1989)

Source/Country/Time Period U.S. Michigan Panel Study of Income Dynamics (PSID) 1974-1984. Data-type Longitudinal data. Sample of population. Coverage Workers in the labour force covering 26 industries with 8 time periods (208 observations).

Dependent Variable: Proportion of permanent industry switchers. 3 regressions were estimated for sectoral mobility: all sectoral switchers, from goods to services sector, and from services to goods sector. No. of Regressors: 3 Explanatory Variables: Macroeconomic: average real GNP growth between periods t and t+1 and real GNP growth in period t+2. Socio-economic: Worker characteristics: skill-mix (proportion of individuals in skill-intensive industries).

Method of Estimation: OLS. Relevant Findings: The average real GNP growth exerted a negative effect on the proportion of industry switchers from the goods to services sector and a positive effect for workers switching from the services to goods sector. Its impact in the regression for all industry switchers was insignificant. The higher the real GNP growth, the lower the proportion of industry switchers from the goods to services sector and for all industry switchers. The effect on movements from services to the goods sectors was not significant. The skill mix did not have a significant influence on the proportion of industrial switchers.

McLaughlin and Bils (2001)

Source/Country/Time Period U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics Survey of Establishments, 1964-1995. Time period for business & repair services, personal services and other professional services is 1972-1995. Data-type Panel data. Sample of establishments weighted to represent the aggregate. Coverage U.S. establishments in 22 industries.

Dependent Variable Natural logarithm of the proportion of industry‟s employment to aggregate employment. No. of Regressors: 2. Explanatory Variable: First difference of the natural logarithm of aggregate employment and the time trend variable.

Method of Estimation: OLS. Relevant Findings: Employment fluctuations in construction and all durable manufacturing industries are more than twice the size of aggregate employment fluctuations. Industries that exhibit cyclical movements in employment that are less than half the size of aggregate employment include agriculture, food and tobacco, communication and utilities, public administration, and several service industries.

193

Table 8.1 Probability Choice Studies of Sectoral/Industrial Mobility

under Worker-Employer Mismatch Theory (continued) Study Source/Country/Time-

period, Data-type and

Coverage

Dependent Variable, No. of

Regressors and Explanatory

Variables

Method of Estimation and Relevant

Findings

Studies of Employees

Jayadevan (1997)

Source/Country/Time Period Annual Survey of Industries published by Central Statistical Organisation (CSO) for the years 1973/1974 to 1979/1980, 1980/1981 to 1990/1991. Data-type Panel data. Sample of establishments weighted to represent the aggregate. Coverage Indian establishments in 18 manufacturing industries.

Dependent Variable Growth rate of employment in industry. No. of Regressors: 2. Explanatory Variables: Macroeconomic: output growth rate and real wages per worker growth rate.

Method of Estimation: OLS. Relevant Findings: Industries with higher output growth experienced higher employment growth for the two time periods and industries with higher growth in per worker real wages had lower employment growth for the 1980/1981 to 1990/1991 period.

Studies of the Unemployed

Neal (1995) Source/Country/Time Period U.S. Displaced Workers Survey (DWS), 1984/1986/1988/1990. The DWS was supplemented with the Current Population Survey. Data-type Unit-record, cross-sectional data. Sample of population. Coverage Unemployed males aged 20-61 years at survey dates.

Dependent Variable: Probability of switching industries. No. of Regressors: 12. Explanatory Variables: Macroeconomic: unemployment spell. Socio-economic: Worker characteristics: original industry employment/employment growth, experience, experience-squared, tenure, tenure-squared, years of schooling and occupation. Demographic: race (white), marital status (married) and indicator for persons with children.

Method of Estimation: Probit Model. Relevant Findings: The probability of switching industries was higher the longer the duration of unemployment. Married males, whites and those with a longer job tenure had a lower probability of changing industries. Professionals, craftsmen and operators showed lower probabilities of changing industries. The effects of having children, years of schooling and experience were insignificant. The probability of switching industries was higher the lower the original industry employment and employment growth.

Ottersen (1993)

Source/Country/Time Period Statistics Sweden. Monthly data on the number of layoffs for the years 1978-1987. Data-type Aggregated, time-series data. Coverage Unemployed workers.

Dependent Variable Probability of being hired in the new sector after being laid off from the original sector. No. of Regressors: 3. Explanatory Variables: Work characteristics: number of lay-offs in the original industry. Other variables: Monthly dummy variables and time trend variable.

Method of Estimation OLS. Relevant Findings: The higher the number of layoffs in the original industry, the lower the probability of being hired in the new sector.

1. Osberg, Gordon and Lin (1994) did not specify what CEC stands for. It could be some form of a social funding in Canada, e.g.

Council for Exceptional Children, which aims to assist children/youth with disabilities or those who are exceptionally gifted.

Note: Vanderkamp (1977) also estimated a non-linear mobility equation with multiplicative interaction variables using a composite costs of adjustment variable Vij and interacting it with Yi, Yj, Ui, Uj, Pj and industry turnover. Vij is constructed using variables in the linear

mobility equation weighted by coefficient estimates. Results are not shown.

The structure of this review of each determinant is as follows. First, where possible, a

priori knowledge of the variable‟s impact on mobility will be highlighted. Second, the

empirical findings, irrespective of whether the studies focus on the overall, male or female

mobility, are presented. Separate findings for the employed and unemployed will also be

given where they are available. The review for each explanatory variable will highlight

whether the studies have been extended to the disaggregated analysis by gender. Finally,

194

the variables‟ feasibility in terms of alignment with the theoretical model and applicability

to the current in-depth, unit-record research for the current thesis is considered.

8.3.1 MONETARY WAGES

Overall Wages

A number of studies use overall wages as an explanatory variable even though separate

wage measures for each sector would be preferred. Overall wages was expressed in terms

of the mean income ratio [computed as the ratio of (1963 income + 1964 income) to (1961

income + 1962 income)] in Cox (1971) and in logarithmic terms in Thomas (1996b).

Jovanovic and Moffitt (1990) used the standard deviation derived from a log wage

regression on race, education and experience to test the mismatch theory of sectoral

mobility. The use of the standard deviation follows from their theory, where the probability

of a worker changing jobs was inversely related to the ratio of the costs of moving to the

standard error of the wage distribution.

The empirical findings across studies based on employed workers are consistent (Table

8.2). A positive wage-mobility relationship was found in Cox (1971), where workers who

changed industries had higher incomes than those who did not. Jovanovic and Moffitt

(1990) found that the probability of a sectoral move was higher the larger the standard

deviation of log wages for all levels of work experience (5, 8 and 11 years). An overall

wage variable was included in the study of the unemployed by Thomas (1996b), but was

found to be insignificant.

The absence of a sectoral distinction in the wages variable in the studies noted above is a

major limitation. In the absence of this sectoral distinction, it needs to be assumed that the

overall wages influence mobility via wages in the new or old industry, though the actual

channel of influence cannot be ascertained. Where possible the wages variables should be

constructed on a sector-by-sector basis to enable the origin of its influence to be

established. This ideal practice will be followed in the empirical work for Korea reported

on later in this thesis.

195

Wages in New and Original Industry

Relatively high wages in the new sector are usually viewed as a pull factor in mobility

studies. However, they may not induce industrial mobility where the higher wages do not

offset any loss of industry-specific skills [Helwege (1992)] and the costs of moving. This is

in line with the model outlined in chapter 6, where both the monetary benefits and costs of

sectoral mobility are considered.

Mixed findings have been reported on the role of the wages as a pull factor. The studies of

mobility among employees by Vanderkamp (1977) showed that higher wages in the new

industry were a significant pull factor. Osberg, Gordon and Lin (1994) reported an

insignificant effect on inter-industry mobility for wages in the new sector. Jayadevan

(1997), however, found that rising per worker real wage growth lowered industrial

employment growth during 1980/1981 to 1990/1991. This meant that at the aggregate

level, higher industrial wages did not generate greater industrial mobility. The results were

also mixed among displaced workers. Fallick (1993) reported that rising wages in the new

industry induced higher industrial mobility. Kim (1998) reported that the industrial wage

premiums of switchers were about 50 per cent smaller than for stayers. This suggests the

unemployed are willing to accept wages at below market-clearing levels in the new sector;

possibly because they are faced with liquidity constraints [Mortensen (1986)] and their

reservation wage decreases with increasing lengths of unemployment [Kasper (1967)].

The original industry‟s wage level would generally be expected to impact on industrial

mobility. It works in the opposite direction to that outlined above for the „new‟ industry‟s

pull factor. The mitigating factors outlined above for wages in the new sector are also

relevant to wages in the old sector. The empirical findings are associated with mixed

results. For employees, a net negative effect was established by Vanderkamp (1977) for

two time periods and an insignificant effect was reported by Osberg, Gordon and Lin

(1994). For the displaced workers, however, higher wages appear to result in workers

becoming unemployed, and this in turn leads such workers to change industries in Fallick

(1993).

Hence, results pertaining to old and new sector wages are associated with mixed findings.

Expectations concerning the links between sectoral mobility and monetary variables cannot

therefore be formed on the basis of the empirical literature.

196

There is limited information on whether the impacts of the old and new sector wages differ

for males and females. Only Osberg, Gordon and Lin (1994) examine this issue, and they

focused only on male employees. They found that the old and new sector wages had a non-

influential impact on mobility among males.

It is worth pointing out that the element of expectations is absent in the empirical literature,

which means that the wage variables presented in Table 8.2 will not conform to the

theoretical model exposited in equation (6.7). In addition, most of the studies use the old

and/or new industry wages, and not the sectoral wage differential in their analyses. These

studies are therefore not fully comparable with the analyses to be conducted in chapters 9

and 10, which are based on the expected sectoral wage differential. One exception is

Osberg, Gordon and Lin (1994), who used the wage differential between movers and

stayers. The wage differential has a strong theoretical basis (see chapter 6), and will be

included in the empirical analyses to be conducted below5.

Table 8.2 Wages and Sectoral/Industrial Mobility Studies of Employees Osberg,

Gordon and Lin (1994)

Prasad (1997) Jovanovic and Moffitt (1990) Cox (1971) Jayadevan (1997) Vanderkamp (1977)

Probit Estimates

VAR estimates Probit estimates Descriptive data

OLS estimates OLS estimates

1959-1993

1974-1990

5 years 8 years 11 years Mean Income Ratio1

1973/74 to

1979/80

1980/81 to

1990/91

1965/66 1966/67 1967/68

Standard deviation of Log Wage Distribution 0.91* 1.26* 0.66* Industrial Real Wages Per Worker Growth Rate -0.91 -0.79*** Wage Differential between New and Original Industry

0.0037

Wages in Original Industry -0.0652** -0.0585** -0.0119 Wages in New Industry 0.0765** 0.0971** 0.0321** Growth Rates of Relative Sectoral Wages in VAR

Agriculture -0.26** -0.30** Construction -0.38** 0.11 Finance -0.44** -0.27** Manufacturing -0.25** -0.06 Mining -0.62** -0.80** Public Administration -0.81** -0.66** Services 0.12 -0.05 Trade -0.02 -0.27** Transport and Communications -0.10 -0.63** Utilities -0.50** -0.66** Same State, Same Industry 1.146 Same State, Different Industry 1.279 Different State, Same Industry 1.228 Different State, Different Industry 1.538 All Categories

1.177

Studies of the Unemployed Thomas (1996b) Fallick (1993) Kim (1998)

Weibull-competing risk estimates Hazard rate estimates

Descriptive data

UI recipients Non-UI recipients Job

Quitter Job

Loser Job

Quitter Job

Loser Industry

Switcher Industry Stayer

Log Wages

-0.06 -0.19 0.18 0.25

Wage in Original Industry 0.0025* Wages in New Industry Standard deviation of Industry Wage Premiums

0.16***

0.166 0.110

*** significant at 1% level. ** significant at 5% level. * significant at 10% level. 1. The mean income ratio is computed as (1963 income + 1964 income) / (1961 income + 1962 income). Note: The regression estimates shown are not comparable as their methods of estimation differ. Where the regression estimates are significant, the effect of wages on sectoral/industrial mobility is greater the larger the absolute magnitude of the estimate.

198

8.3.2 MACROECONOMIC FACTORS

Overall Unemployment

No clear links between inter-industry mobility and the overall unemployment rate have

been established in the empirical literature (see Table 8.3). For employees, Osberg (1991)

reported that unemployment had a negative effect only for females during 1980/1981 and

1985/1986. For the unemployed, the overall unemployment rate does not appear to be a

significant influence [Fallick (1993)].

The overall unemployment rate was used by Osberg (1991) in separate analyses of male

and female mobility. The results from these analyses showed that male mobility was not

affected by the overall unemployment rate, but this aggregate-level variable had a negative

effect on female mobility during several of the time periods analysed. In large part the

limited statistical success from the inclusion of the overall unemployment rate in models of

industrial mobility may be because this is not the best measure to capture any of the

influences noted above. A better measure would be to examine the separate roles of

unemployment in the old and new industries.

Unemployment in Old and New Industry

The theoretical model of chapter 6 asserts that higher unemployment in the original

industry induces sectoral movements to the new sector. Amongst employed persons,

higher unemployment in the original industry acted as a push factor for out-mobility in

Vanderkamp (1977) for all three time periods analysed. This is thus consistent with the

implications of the theoretical model. The effect of unemployment in the original sector

was, however, insignificant in Fallick‟s (1993) study of unemployed persons.

Unemployment in the new industry would generally be expected to discourage potential

entrants from moving into the new sector as their chances of securing a job in that sector

are lowered. However, this effect may be small where the wage gap between the sectors is

considerable. The empirical studies reveal mixed results. Unemployment in the new

industry did not exert any influence on the extent of inter-industry mobility among

employed workers in Vanderkamp (1977) in 1966/1967 and 1967/1968. However, there

was a surprising positive coefficient in Vanderkamp‟s (1977) study for 1965/1966.

199

Displaced workers in Fallick‟s (1993) study were not affected by unemployment levels in

the new industry.

The general observation is that studies using the old/new sectors‟ unemployment as

explanatory variables generate conflicting results, and hence predetermined views on the

unemployment-mobility relationship cannot be formed on this basis. In addition, the

literature does not appear to have examined whether sectoral unemployment rate variables

have different impacts on mobility for males and females, or whether within the separate

studies for males and females, the old/new sectors unemployment rate variable should be

defined in a gender-specific way rather than cover both males and females. Nonetheless,

the sectoral distinction in these variables aligns with the theoretical model where the push

or pull factor of mobility can be determined. From this perspective there is merit to their

inclusion in the empirical work in chapters 9 and 10.

Unemployment Spell

The theories/studies of labour mobility other than those of industrial mobility have assumed

either no intervening period of unemployment [Jovanovic and Moffitt (1990), Tobin (1972)

and Mattila (1974)] or that every job change involves an intervening unemployment spell

[Lucas and Prescott (1974)]. In comparison, the role of a spell of unemployment has been

examined in a number of studies of industrial mobility. Theoretically, as the spell

lengthens, workers would be expected to shift their search efforts towards new sectors and

to lower their earnings expectations [Pissarides and Wadsworth (1989)]. A positive effect

of spells of unemployment on industrial mobility among employed workers was reported

by Osberg (1991) and among male employees by Osberg, Gordon and Lin (1984).

The results for the unemployment spell variable in analyses for displaced workers have

been ambiguous. This may be attributed to the different coverage groups (i.e. quitters

versus losers, UI recipients versus non-UI recipients). Unemployed workers in Neal (1995)

and job quitters/losers who did not receive UI and losers who received UI in Thomas

(1996b) were more likely to change industries with a longer duration of unemployment6.

Conversely, the probability of moving sectors decreased with a longer spell among job

quitters who were UI-recipients. A likely reason for this is that since job quitters receive

some monetary compensation from UI, the opportunity cost of unemployment is lower than

200

when UI is not available, which mitigates the expected tendency to shift sectors as an

unemployment spell lengthens.

The analysis of the impact of the duration of unemployment on sectoral mobility has been

extended to separate analysis for males and females in several studies. Longer

unemployment spells were associated with greater mobility for both men and women in

Osberg (1991) during each of the three time periods examined, and for men in Osberg,

Gordon and Lin (1984). In particular, in Osberg (1991), the marginal effect of an

unemployment spell was higher for males in 1982/1983 and higher for females in

1980/1981 and 1985/19867.

Given the diversity of these findings for the unemployment spell variable, particularly for

the group of unemployed individuals for whom the variable should be more relevant, there

is arguably little benefit from including an unemployment spell variable in the empirical

application of chapters 9 and 10.

Overall Economic Growth and Employment

There are alternative viewpoints on the cyclical patterns associated with sectoral mobility

when aggregate indicators are used. Economic growth is usually associated with increases

in the rate of sectoral mobility. This occurs where the greater job availabilities associated

with an upturn encourage workers to switch sectors voluntarily. Alternatively, an economic

downturn can be associated with greater sectoral mobility where job losses/retrenchments

cause workers to seek employment in a new sector. The major study on this issue is

Loungani and Rogerson‟s (1989) analysis over the 1974 to 1984 period using a micro-

dataset for the U.S. Industry switchers in this study were defined as those who were

employed at the time of the base-year interview, i.e. year t, changed industries in year t+1

and who did not return to the original industry by year t+3. It was reported that the average

real GNP growth between years t and t+1 and the real GNP growth in year t+2 (i.e. the

growth rate of real GNP in the year following the initial industry switch) had negative and

significant effects on the proportion of industry switchers from the goods sector to the

services sector. This implies that if the declining goods sector was cyclically more

sensitive, mobility accelerates during a downturn. However, only the average GNP growth

between year t and year t+1 had a positive effect on the proportion of switchers from the

201

services to the goods sector. This implies that mobility from the acyclical services sector to

the cyclical goods sector accelerated during an economic upturn.

McLaughlin and Bils (2001) estimated the cyclical sensitivity of industries by regressing

each industry‟s share of employment on aggregate employment. The cyclical sensitivity

can be regarded as a measure of the degree of sectoral mobility in each industry. Aggregate

employment fluctuations could be expected to influence a particular industry‟s share of

employment, which in turn reflects the labour inflow/outflow from that sector.

It was shown that some industries had cyclical movements in employment less than half the

size of that of aggregate employment (agriculture, food and tobacco, communication and

utilities, public administration and several service industries), while other industries

(construction and all durable manufacturing) had employment fluctuations that were more

than twice that of aggregate employment.

The studies above therefore show that the sign of the relationship between economic

growth and mobility depends on the cyclical sensitivity of industries. This prevents strong

general priors on the impact of economic growth on mobility from being drawn. A further

reason why strong general priors cannot be drawn is that the coverage of industries is also

not all-encompassing: McLaughlin and Bils‟ (2001) approach involved industry-specific

regressions and Loungani and Rogerson‟s (1989) analysis focused only on the broad

industry grouping of „goods‟ versus „services‟. Including individuals from various

industries in a single regression appears to offer a superior encompassing test of the

relationship between economic growth and mobility. Notwithstanding the limitations

associated with GDP growth itself, overall employment can be regarded as inferior to the

GDP variable since the employment variable can be viewed as largely duplicating the

information content of an unemployment variable (as employment plus unemployment

equals the labour force, which may not vary greatly from period to period). To avoid this

possible duplication, a GDP growth variable will be used as the measure of economic

performance in the applied work in this thesis.

202

Table 8.3 Unemployment, Employment, GNP and Sectoral/Industrial Mobility

Studies of Employees Osberg (1991) Osberg,

Gordon and

Lin (1994)

Logit estimates Probit estimates

Males Females

1980/81 1982/83 1985/86 1980/81 1982/83 1985/86

Overall Unemployment Rate -0.0261 -0.0312 0.0028 -0.136*** 0.0255 -0.0651*

No. of Weeks Unemployed 0.0519*** 0.055*** 0.0526*** 0.0537*** 0.0453** 0.0738*** 0.0071**

Vanderkamp (1977) Loungani and Rogerson (1989) McLaughlin and Bils (2001)

OLS estimates

OLS estimates

OLS estimates

1965/66 1966/67 1967/68 All Industry switchers

Goods to services

Services to Goods

Unemployment in Old Industry

0.1006** 0.0708** 0.0706**

Unemployment in New Industry

0.0674** -0.0025 0.0217

Average Real GNP Growth between Periods t and t+1

-0.008 -0.037* 0.076**

Real GNP Growth in Period t+2

-0.040** -0.041** -0.014

Overall Employment in:

Agriculture -1.06***

Mining -0.56

Construction 1.67***

Metals 1.76***

Machinery 1.74***

Transportation Equipment 1.73***

Other Durables 1.21***

Food & Tobacco -0.65***

Textiles, Apparel & Leather 0.33

Paper, Printing & Publishing 0.03

Chemicals, Petroleum & Rubber

0.48***

Transportation 0.35***

Communications and Utilities -0.67***

Wholesale Trade -0.01

Retail Trade -0.11

Finance, Insurance & Real Estate

-0.39***

Business & Repair Services 0.55***

Personal Services -0.33*

Health Services -1.00***

Education -0.59***

Other Professional Services -0.63***

Public Administration -0.53***

Studies of the Unemployed Fallick (1993) Neal (1995)

Hazard rate estimates Probit estimates

Overall Unemployment Rate -0.021

Unemployment in Old Industry

-0.029

Unemployment in New Industry

-0.15

Years since Displacement 0.05**

*** significant at 1% level, ** significant at 5% level, * significant at 10% level.

Note: The regression estimates shown are not comparable as their methods of estimation differ. Where the regression estimates are significant, the effect

of unemployment/employment/GNP on sectoral/industrial mobility is greater the larger the absolute magnitude of the estimate.

203

8.3.3 WORKER CHARACTERISTICS

Age

In general, increasing age is expected to be linked to a lower incidence of sectoral/industrial

mobility. Younger workers are expected to have a higher degree of sectoral mobility as

they have a longer period over which they can gain any rewards associated with the change

of jobs [Creedy and Thomas (1982)]. In comparison, older workers who face greater costs

of moving [Jovanovic and Moffitt (1990)] and have a smaller amount of time to recoup the

costs [Creedy and Thomas (1982)] are expected to be less mobile. Moreover, the chances

of moving are likely to fall with age because of accumulation of sector-specific experience

and knowledge. The ability to learn new job skills required in the new sector also

diminishes with age.

It is observed that age has been viewed in empirical research as a personal characteristic

applicable to all individuals (i.e. age of individual) and with reference to specific industries

(i.e. age of entry into industry). The same expectations apply to both forms of the variable.

A decline in labour mobility with increasing age has been found in many studies [see for

example, Mincer and Jovanovic (1981) and Antolin and Bover (1997)], and has come to be

termed a socioeconomic by-law [Byrne (1975)]. This finding carries over to the literature

on industrial mobility among employed workers (see Table 8.4). Thus, older women had a

lower incidence of industrial mobility in Osberg (1991) in 1985/1986 whilst younger males

had a greater industrial mobility in Cox (1971) and Osberg, Gordon and Lin (1994). Both

the age of entry into the old industry and into the new industry had negative impacts on

industrial mobility in Vanderkamp (1977)8.

Declining mobility with age is also a characteristic of the unemployed. Thus, Thomas

(1996b) reported that younger job quitters (UI and non-UI recipients) and job losers who

did not receive UI aged 16-19 years had higher probabilities of switching industries.

Similarly, older displaced workers in Fallick (1993), and job quitters and losers aged 45-49

years who received UI in Thomas (1996b), were less likely to switch industries.

204

Where separate analyses have been undertaken for males and females, age has been

negatively related to industrial mobility among male employees in Cox (1971) and Osberg,

Gordon and Lin (1994) and among female employees in Osberg (1991) for 1985/1986.

However, age did not exert any significant influence on mobility over a number of time

periods in Osberg (1991): 1980/1981, 1982/1983 and 1985/1986 for males and 1980/1981

and 1982/1983 for females.

Table 8.4 Age and Sectoral/Industrial Mobility

Studies of

Employees

Osberg (1991)

Osberg, Gordon

and Lin

(1994)

Cox (1971)

Vanderkamp (1977)

Logit estimates Probit estimates

Descriptive data

OLS estimates

1980/81 1982/83 1985/86 1965/67 1966/67 1967/68

Males

Age -0.0073 -0.0052 -0.167

Females

-0.0167 0.0129 -0.034***

16-19 yrs 1.033**

20-24 yrs 0.67**

25-34 yrs 0.33**

27-35 yrs 17.9%

36-62 yrs 11.6%

Age of Entry into Old Industry

-0.2288** -0.2308** -0.2388**

Age of Entry into New Industry

-0.1995** -0.2219** -0.2257**

(AiAj)1/2 0.4425** 0.4562** 0.4669**

Studies of the Unemployed

Fallick (1993)

Thomas (1996b)

Hazard rate estimates Weibull-competing risk estimates

UI recipients Non-UI recipients

Age -0.1013*** Job Quitters Job Losers Job Quitters Job Losers

16-19 years

45-49 years

1.54**

-0.63*

0.43

-0.71**

1.02**

-0.40

1.35**

0.07

*** significant at 1% level, ** significant at 5% level, * significant at 10% level.

Note: The regression estimates shown are not comparable as their methods of estimation differ. Where the regression estimates are

significant, the effect of age on sectoral/industrial mobility is greater the larger the absolute magnitude of the estimate.

205

From the studies above, the negative age-mobility relationship is nearly always reported for

all labour groups, and this expectation is to be carried over to the empirical analysis later in

this thesis. Either the linear variable of Osberg (1991), the dummy variables of Osberg,

Gordon and Lin (1994) or a quadratic function in age could be used. The dummy variable

and quadratic function in age are more general and therefore appear to offer a sounder

starting point for empirical analysis.

Gender

A gender variable has been included in several studies to capture mobility differences

between men and women. Two forms have been used: as an industry characteristic (e.g.

male/female mix in the industry) and as a personal characteristic. Vanderkamp‟s (1977)

industry characteristic variable reflected male-female specialization. It was computed for

both the original and new industries, and each of these measures was associated with

negative effects on industrial mobility. This was interpreted to mean that a higher

proportion of males relative to females in the original industry acted as a barrier to outward

mobility whilst a higher proportion in the new industry was a barrier to entry. Fallick

(1993) incorporated a dummy variable for females in his study of the unemployed and

reported that they had a higher likelihood of industrial mobility (Table 8.5).

Based on the findings of these empirical studies, as well as patterns established in the

general labour economics literature, a gender difference in mobility behaviour is expected

for the empirical work presented later in this thesis. Moreover, this expectation is a basis

for conducting the separate analyses for males and females. The gender variable will be

used as a personal characteristic rather than as an industry characteristic (i.e. the gender mix

of the industry) as this is the usual practice in recent applied labour economics research.

206

Table 8.5 Gender and Sectoral/Industrial Mobility Study of Employees Study of the Unemployed

Vanderkamp (1977) Fallick (1993)

OLS estimates Hazard rate estimates

1965/67 1966/67 1967/68

As a Personal Characteristic

Female 0.27***

As an Industry Characteristic

Male-female Specialization in Old

Industry (Fi)

-0.0910** -0.0834** -0.0662**

Male-female Specialization in New

Industry (Fj)

-0.0248** -0.0364** -0.0459**

(FiFj)1/2 0.1057** 0.0957** 0.0999**

*** significant at 1% level, ** significant at 5% level.

Note: The regression estimates shown are not comparable as their methods of estimation differ. Where the regression estimates are significant, the effect of gender on sectoral/industrial mobility is greater the larger the

absolute magnitude of the estimate.

Family Indicators: Marital Status, Head of Household and Children

It has been suggested that workers with greater family commitments, e.g. married persons,

heads of households and persons with children, have lower propensities to switch industries

as any adverse consequences (e.g. temporary loss of income) will impact more intensely on

them than on other groups. However, marital status did not exert significant effects on the

propensity to switch sectors for employees in Osberg (1991), except for 1980/1981. Among

the unemployed, married persons displayed lower incidences of mobility in Neal (1995).

The results for unemployed heads of households in Fallick (1993) were as expected, with

lower probabilities of changing industries. However, having children was not associated

with any significant influence on industrial mobility in Neal (1995). The studies that have

examined the determinants of mobility behaviour separately for men and women have

concluded that marital status generally did not have any significant impact on industrial

mobility for either males or females, as seen from Osberg (1991) and Osberg, Gordon and

Lin (1994)9. There is no evidence on whether the impacts of the household head and

children indicators on mobility differ between men and women.

Owing to these conflicting findings and the limited number of studies, preconceived views

about marital status/head of household status vis-à-vis mobility are difficult to arrive at.

207

This contrasts with the situation with respect to marital status and head of household

variables in many other areas of labour market research (e.g. wage determination,

occupational attainment). This difference is likely due to the sparse nature of research on

sectoral mobility at the present time. Accordingly, the marital status and head of household

variables will be used in the current unit-record analysis.

Table 8.6 Marital Status/Head of Household and Sectoral/Industrial Mobility

Studies of Employees Osberg (1991) Osberg, Gordon and

Lin (1994)

Males Females

1980/81 1982/83 1985/86 1980/81 1982/83 1985/86

Marital Status

Single = 1

Otherwise = 0

0.345* 0.209 -0.126 0.862 0.236 0.1005

Married = 1

Otherwise = 0

-0.012

Studies of the Unemployed

Fallick (1993) Neal (1995)

Marital Status

Currently married -0.151**

Head of Household -0.40***

With Children 0.016

*** significant at 1% level, ** significant at 5% level, * significant at 10% level.

Formal Education

The influence of formal education on the probability of moving to a new sector/industry is

indeterminate a priori. Education level is both a stock of acquired skills and a signal of

one‟s ability to learn. Whether these attributes are rewarded more in the original sector

(which would retard mobility) or new sector (which would encourage mobility) is an

empirical matter. This is viewing education as a personal characteristic.

Education can also be viewed as an industry characteristic, measured as the mean education

level or the education composition of the workforce of the industry in question. A highly

educated workforce within an industry could act as a barrier to entry into that industry,

especially if potential entrants view it as lessening their chances for securing higher paid

jobs which are generally associated with higher education.

208

Table 8.7 Education and Sectoral/Industrial Mobility

Studies of Employees Osberg, Gordon

and Lin (1994)

Vanderkamp (1977)

Probit estimates OLS estimates

1965/67 1966/67 1967/68

As a Personal Characteristic

Elementary -0.016

Post-secondary 0.15**

Diploma 0.057

University 0.032

As an Industry Characteristic

Education in Old Industry (EDi) -0.3018** -0.3735** -0.4052**

Education in New Industry (EDj) -0.2635** -0.3553** -0.3807**

(EDiEDj)1/2 0.5318** 0.6765** 0.7673**

Studies of the Unemployed Fallick (1993) Neal (1995) Kim (1998)

Hazard rate estimates

Probit estimates

Descriptive data

Industry

Switcher

Industry

Stayer

No. of grades of school

completed

0.052***

Years of schooling -0.007

Standard deviation of education 0.46 0.83

*** significant at 1% level, ** significant at 5% level.

Note: The regression estimates shown are not comparable as their methods of estimation differ. Where the

regression estimates are significant, the effect of education on sectoral/industrial mobility is greater the larger the absolute magnitude of the estimate.

From Table 8.7, the effects of education on mobility appear to differ according to how it is

measured and according to the population studied. Higher education (diploma and

university compared to post-secondary levels) did not appear to affect the mobility of the

employed in the study by Osberg, Gordon and Lin (1994). Vanderkamp (1977) included

separate education variables (ED) for the original and new industries as industry

characteristics. The coefficient of both variables were negative and of similar magnitude.

For the unemployed, the effects of education were mixed. Fallick (1993) showed that

education had a positive effect on industrial mobility. However, Neal (1995) reported the

years of schooling to have an insignificant impact. Kim (1998) compared the standard

deviation of the education levels of industry stayers and switchers, and found that industry

209

switchers have smaller industry dispersions in education. Kim (1998) proposed that the

probability of an industry switch was greater among marginal workers, e.g. low- (high-)

educated workers in high- (low-) wage industries, and the results showed that switchers

were marginal in terms of the smaller standard deviation measure.

There is limited evidence on whether the links between educational attainment and mobility

differ between males and females, and so comment on this is not provided. The superiority

of the education variable as a personal or industry characteristic cannot be determined on

the basis of consistent findings, although the former is more relevant for unit-record

analysis, is consistent with the practice in most recent applied labour market studies, and

has the merit of capturing a personal characteristic that can readily be seen as a policy

variable. For these reasons the level of education of the individual will be included in the

estimating equation used for the study of the Korean labour market.

On-the-job Training

It has been suggested that on-the-job training may be a more appropriate measure of a

worker‟s knowledge of the job than formal education and hence have a greater influence on

labour mobility [Parent (1999)]. On-the-job training can take two forms: general and

firm/sector-specific [Creedy and Thomas (1982) and Becker (1964)]. In general training,

the marginal productivity of trainees is the same across sectors. If the post-training wage is

below the workers‟ improved marginal productivity, it would be economically irrational for

the trained person to remain in the same firm/sector and the likelihood of switching sectors

is greater. In firm/sector-specific training, the worker‟s improved productivity is not

transferable to other firms/sectors. In this situation, an organization would be more willing

to bear some of the costs of training, and Becker (1964) argues that both the costs of, and

returns to, firm/sector specific training will be shared by employer and employee, which

will tend to lock workers into their existing jobs and limit mobility.

210

The fundamental difficulty with on-the-job training compared to formal education is that it

is not easily measured. Most on-the-job skills are acquired through learning-by-doing

[Oatey (1970)] rather than from formal training programmes, and learning-by-doing is

generally not quantifiable. The usual proxy variables of tenure and labour market

experience capture the influence of a range of factors (e.g. life-cycle factors, cohort effects)

and attributing any statistical relationships between these variables and labour mobility to

on-the-job training is therefore difficult.

The proxy measures for on-the-job training considered in the literature are job tenure and

labour market experience [Neal (1995) and Burdett (1978)]. An individual with a longer

job tenure or labour market experience is more likely to switch sectors if the relevant work

experience/training acquired in the years worked represents general training. Offsetting

this are other factors like benefits received. Thus, workers with longer job tenures,

experience and greater training may be less willing to move and give up seniority rights

like job security, pension benefits, seniority-based pay, longer vacation periods and

promotional advantages [Mincer and Jovanovic (1981) and Neal (1995)].

There is an issue of the specification of the tenure/experience variables that also is of

relevance. Some studies use a linear specification for these variables and others a more

general quadratic function. The studies that use a linear specification are reviewed first

below followed by those that present tenure in its quadratic form. For the linear

specification where there are more studies, the findings for job tenure are covered prior to

the findings for experience. For the quadratic functional form, however, there are fewer

studies and the two proxies are dealt with together.

Studies using job tenure as a proxy for on-the-job training have produced consistent results

among employed workers but not among the unemployed. Osberg (1991) reported that job

tenure reduced the likelihood of industrial mobility for all three time periods examined for

males and females. Job tenure was also associated with a reduced likelihood of industrial

mobility for males in Osberg, Gordon and Lin (1994). Thus, the evidence on the links

between tenure and mobility is similar for both male and female workers. The findings,

211

however, differed among unemployed persons. A longer prior job tenure reduced the

probability of inter-industry mobility for displaced workers in Fallick (1993) and Neal

(1995), and for job quitters and job losers who received UI, and job quitters who did not

receive UI in Thomas (1996b). The tenure effect was insignificant for job losers who did

not receive UI in Thomas (1996b). Kim (1998) showed that industry switchers had smaller

standard deviations in tenure at the time of job displacement compared to industry stayers.

This can be interpreted to mean that switchers would have had shorter tenures during the

pre-displacement period. Hence, a shorter tenure tends to increase the chances of an

industry switch.

In terms of labour market experience, the probability of a sectoral move decreased for all

employed workers with longer work experience (5, 8 and 11 years) in Jovanovic and

Moffitt (1990). Contradictory findings were reported for the unemployed. Labour market

experience had an insignificant effect on the probability of inter-industry mobility for

displaced workers in Neal (1995). Industry switchers and stayers both had fairly similar

standard deviations in work experience during the period of job displacement in Kim

(1998). It can be inferred that as switchers and stayers would both have similar work

experience in the pre-displacement period, the effect of experience on the likelihood of an

industry switch is non-influential.

In cases where tenure/experience is entered in quadratic form, an examination of the partial

derivatives shows that the effects are in the same direction across all reasonable

tenure/experience levels, and the discussion that follows focuses on the most common

effects without digressing to deal with turning points that occur at high levels of tenure/

experience. From Table 8.8, where the partial derivative of tenure/experience is negative

across all reasonable tenure levels, the coefficient of the quadratic term is positive in

Osberg (1991) for males for all three periods and females for 1980/1981 and 1982/1983,

and in Neal (1995) for the unemployed. This indicates that the negative influence of

tenure/experience on sectoral mobility diminishes as tenure/experience increases.

The only study that captured training directly was Osberg, Gordon and Lin (1994), where it

was reported that training received in the previous sector exerted a positive and significant

212

impact on inter-industry mobility. However, this measure will not be dealt with in the

current work owing to the difficulty in determining a suitable across-the-board measure of

training for individuals in the KLIPS10

.

In summary, consistent results are revealed in the studies of job tenure/experience and

mobility for employed workers. Given the strength of these findings, a negative

relationship between tenure/experience and mobility would be expected in the current

work, both for the aggregate-level analyses and for the separate analyses to be undertaken

for males and females. Given the evidence in favour of non-linear relationships between

mobility and tenure/experience, tenure/experience should be examined using a quadratic

function.

Table 8.8 On-the-job Training and Sectoral/Industrial Mobility

Studies of

Employees

Osberg (1991) Osberg,

Gordon and

Lin (1994)

Jovanovic and Moffitt (1990)

Logit estimates Probit

estimates

Probit estimates

Males Females Probability of a Sectoral Move

1980/81 1982/83 1985/86 1980/81 1982/83 1985/86 1968 1969 1970 1971 1973 1975 1978 1980

Job Tenure -0.0124*** -0.0184*** -0.0139*** -0.258*** -0.0216*** -0.0107** -0.00016**

Job Tenure-squared 0.00002*** 0.000032*** 0.000027*** 0.000057*** 0.000045*** -0.00001

Years of Experience

5 years 0.25 0.25 0.22 0.18 0.20 0.21 0.19 0.15

8 years 0.23 0.28 0.20 0.20 0.16 0.17 0.18 0.15

11 years 0.23 0.20 0.17 0.17 0.15 0.15 0.17 0.14

Received Training

in 1986

0.27**

214

Table 8.8 On-the-job Training and Sectoral/Industrial Mobility (continued)

Studies of the

Unemployed

Thomas (1996b) Fallick

(1993)

Neal (1995) Kim (1998)

Weibull-competing risk estimates Hazard rate

estimates

Probit estimates Descriptive data

UI recipient Non-UI recipient

Job

Quitters

Job

Losers

Job

Quitters

Job

Losers

Industry

Switcher

Industry

Stayer

Tenure/10 -0.02** -0.01** -0.01* -0.004

Job Tenure -0.023*** -0.024**

Job Tenure-squared 0.001***

Standard deviation

for Tenure

1.35 1.85

Experience -0.010

Experience-squared 0.0001

Standard deviation

for Experience

1.64 1.71

*** significant at 1% level, ** significant at 5% level, * significant at 10% level.

Note: The regression estimates shown are not comparable as their methods of estimation differ. Where the regression estimates are significant, the effect of on-the-job training on

sectoral/industrial mobility is greater the larger the absolute magnitude of the estimate.

215

Occupation

Occupation is reflective of skill levels, and has been measured in mobility studies by initial

occupation, change in occupation and as a proportion of individuals in skill-intensive

occupations (see Table 8.9). There are alternative viewpoints regarding the industrial

mobility behaviour of skilled and semi-skilled workers. On the one hand, skilled workers

could exhibit „mobility stickiness‟ [Subrahmanian, Veena and Parikh (1982)] if skills are

team-specific and jobs rely on the existing net of workers [Mailath and Postlewaith (1990)

and Chillemi and Gui (1997)] in the original sector. On the other hand, by virtue of their

skill being vital in certain industries [Neal (1995)], skilled workers may be scouted for their

talent, potential injection of new ideas or productivity [Murphy and Topel (1990)]. White-

collar jobs are also more likely to be advertised than blue-collar jobs [Abraham (1987)] and

the rate of mobility for such workers may be higher. The change in occupation was

examined by Vanderkamp (1977), who argued that such changes impose additional costs to

mobility in the form of acquiring new skills and retraining for a different occupation.

The initial occupation was examined by Osberg (1991) for the employed and Neal (1995)

and Fallick (1993) for the unemployed. Osberg (1991) reported that higher probabilities of

industrial mobility were reported by female personal service workers for all three periods

examined (1980/1981, 1982/1983 and 1985/1986), female managers, professionals and

technicians in 1982/1983 and 1985/1986, and female clerical and sales workers in

1980/1981 and 1985/1986. Male managers, professionals and technicians in 1980/1981

were also more likely to change industries. Fallick (1993) reported that displaced workers

who were in the technical, sales or administration, precision production, craft and repairs or

who were operators, fabricators and labourers in the old industry had higher propensities to

switch sectors. In contrast, Neal (1995) reported that unemployed workers who were

professionals, craftsmen and those who were operators were less likely to be industry

switchers. The empirical findings revealed mobility stickiness for job losers who received

UI [Thomas (1996b)]11

. The change in occupation was a deterrent to industrial mobility in

Vanderkamp‟s (1977) empirical work. In terms of the proportion of individuals in skill-

intensive occupations, higher skill levels did not exert any significant effect on sectoral

mobility in Loungani and Rogerson (1989).

216

This mixed evidence therefore does not provide a basis for establishing priors on whether

the mobility behaviour of skilled and unskilled workers will differ. Similarly, as Osberg

(1991) is the only study that addresses whether mobility patterns across occupations differ

for males and females, and the extent to which his findings generalize to other countries

and time periods is not clear, priors for the role that occupation may have in the separate

analyses to be conducted for men and women cannot be formed.

Part of the reason for the conflicting results on the role of occupation in the empirical

literature may be the different variables used (initial occupation, change in occupation,

dummy variables, industry averages). However, it seems that there are grounds for a

reasoned choice in this regard. Between the first two types of variables mentioned above,

the change in occupation is less preferred as it depicts another form of labour mobility,

namely, occupational mobility, and so may potentially be endogenous. In contrast, the

initial occupation variable is exogenous, and has an unambiguous interpretation, and for

this reason is preferred for the empirical work. For consistency with the representation of

other worker characteristics in the model, the initial occupation will be categorized as a

dummy variable (i.e skilled versus unskilled).

Table 8.9 Occupation and Industrial Mobility

Studies of Employees Osberg (1991) Vanderkamp (1977) Loungani and Rogerson (1989)

Logit estimates OLS estimates OLS estimates

Males Females

Occupational status 1980/81 1982/83 1985/86 1980/81 1982/83 1985/86 1965-66 1966-67 1967-68 All Industry

Switchers

Goods to Services

Services to Goods

Proportion of individuals in skill-intensive occupations (professionals/managers/craftsmen)

-0.70 0.94 -1.42

Initial Occupation

Personal service -0.216 0.159 0.151 1.313** 2.215*** -0.623**

Clerical/sales -0.394 0.113 -0.0219 1.459** 0.808 -1.352***

Managerial/Professional/Technical -0.658*** -0.099 -0.113 0.913 1.161* -1.211***

Change in occupation -0.0310** -0.0233** -0.0272**

Studies of the Unemployed Thomas (1996) Fallick (1993) Neal (1995)

Weibull-competing risk estimates Hazard rate estimates Probit estimates

UI recipients Non-UI recipients

Occupational status Job Quitters

Job Losers Job Quitters

Job Losers

White-collar occupation 0.04 -0.25* -0.22 0.06

Initial Occupation

Technical/sales/administration -0.12*

Precision production/craft/repair 0.27*

Operator/fabricator/labourer -0.23*

Farming/forestry/fisheries -0.031

Services 0.14

Manager 0.008

Professional -0.390***

Technician -0.259

Sales -0.134

Clerk -0.186

Service worker 0.053

Crafts worker -0.266***

Operative -0.188*

*** significant at 1% level, ** significant at 5% level, * significant at 10% level. Note: The regression estimates shown are not comparable as their methods of estimation differ. Where the regression estimates are significant, the effect of occupation on sectoral/industrial mobility is greater the

larger the absolute magnitude of the estimate.

218

Industry

Two studies have analysed the role of the initial industry in determining sectoral mobility,

namely Osberg (1991) and Thomas (1996b) [see Table 8.10]. Osberg (1991) found that

workers were more likely to move out of certain industries. These included male workers

from the construction industry for each of the three time periods examined, males in

manufacturing and resources for 1982/1983, females in construction and government in

1985/1986 and females in manufacturing, trade and finance, and utilities and transport in

1982/1983. Thus, between males and females, it is evident that their probabilities of

changing sectors vary depending on their initial industry. The results pertaining to the

initial industry were not significant for the unemployed in the study by Thomas (1996b).

Table 8.10 Initial Industry and Industrial Mobility

Studies of Employees Osberg (1991)

Logit estimates

Males Females

1980/81 1982/83 1985/86 1980/81 1982/83 1985/86

Construction 0.849*** 1.279*** 0.665** 0.759 2.127***

Trade, finance 1.060***

Government 0.559 1.262***

Utilities, transport 1.700***

Manufacturing 0.776*** 1.820***

Resources 0.82*

Studies of the Unemployed Thomas (1996b)

Weibull-competing risk estimates

UI-recipients Non-UI recipients

Job Quitters

Job Losers

Job Quitters

Job Losers

Primary/manufacturing -0.06 0.02 -0.12 0.16

*** significant at 1% level, ** significant at 5% level, * significant at 10% level.

Note: The regression estimates shown are not comparable as their methods of estimation differ. Where the

regression estimates are significant, the effect of industry on sectoral/industrial mobility is greater the larger the

absolute magnitude of the estimate.

Thus, while the empirical basis is limited, it appears that the initial industry is likely to

impact inter-industry mobility and hence this variable should be considered in the current

study. This is particularly the case if policy relevance is an issue, as it is obviously

important to know if mobility varies across industries. Gender differences from this

perspective also seem likely [see Osberg (1991)] and should be established for the Korean

219

labour market if possible. Hence variables for the initial industry will be included in the

mobility equations used in chapters 9 and 10.

Employment Status, Unionisation, Alternative Sources of Income and Region

A number of other potential determinants of worker mobility have been considered, e.g.

employment status in Osberg (1991), unionization in Vanderkamp (1977), unemployment

insurance in Osberg, Gordon and Lin (1994) and Fallick (1993), social assistance in

Osberg, Gordon and Lin (1994) and region by Vanderkamp (1977) and Thomas (1996b).

The empirical evidence relating to the latter four factors is not reviewed as it is not relevant

to the empirical analyses to be conducted below.

The research on the impact of employment status on sectoral mobility is relevant to the

current work and the finding by Osberg (1991) will be reported here. Osberg (1991)

focused on full-time versus part-time workers, although it seems that other categorizations

could be used, such as employees versus employers, own account workers and workers in

family business. Part-timers and employees are expected to have a higher incidence of

industrial mobility as they are less emotionally attached to their current job/sector than full-

time employees. This was confirmed in Osberg (1991), where male and female part-time

workers were both associated with higher mobility rates (see Table 8.11). Since Osberg

(1991) is the sole study of sectoral mobility that covers employment status, the findings

should not be generalized to other samples. However, the apparent strength of the results,

their accord with intuition, and the policy and social relevance of knowledge of whether

sectoral mobility varies by employment status provide sound reasons for considering an

employment status variable in the study of mobility in the Korean labour market.

220

Table 8.11 Employment Status and Industrial Mobility

Osberg (1991)

Males Females

1980/81 1982/83 1985/86 1980/81 1982/83 1985/86

Part-time worker in initial sector

0.616** 1.145*** 0.876*** -0.138 1.066*** 0.925***

*** significant at 1% level, ** significant at 5% level, * significant at 10% level

8.3.4 JOB/INDUSTRY CHARACTERISTICS

Different sectors are associated with different job characteristics and work environments,

and these differences can impact an individual‟s mobility decision. Consistent with the

implications of the empirical model, as workers have to make ex ante decisions about

switching industries, the decision becomes a function of the expected job/industry

characteristics in addition to the other characteristics discussed above (e.g. expected

wages). Studies of public-private sector mobility in particular have stressed the importance

of the non-monetary aspect in mobility, as the two sectors operate under different work

environments. These non-monetary characteristics might include working hours/weeks,

work/product similarity and industry size and turnover.

Working Hours/Weeks

Variation in working hours/weeks has been noted as a prominent determinant of labour

market mobility in a number of studies [e.g. Arnott, Hosios and Stiglitz (1988)]. Although

employers may require fixed work hours, workers can increase their work hours by

changing sectors and a change in working hours or a desire to change the work hours

should be positively associated with mobility. From Table 8.12, the indicators of this

dimension of labour supply include the change in the individual‟s usual weekly hours

between periods t (original interview) and t+1 (re-interview) in Osberg (1991), and the

individual‟s desire for more working hours/weeks per year in Osberg, Gordon and Lin

(1994). In the latter study, it was envisaged that a greater amount of time that could be

spent at work in the new sector would increase earnings for individuals and thus lead to a

221

higher probability of a sectoral switch. A potential problem in using the change in weekly

hours lies in its non-exogeneity. The labour supply as measured by the change in weekly

hours may change as an individual changes sectors. Hence, the desire to work more hours is

probably a superior variable.

Despite its apparent importance, only two studies have examined the links between

working hours and sectoral mobility. Osberg (1991) reported that an increase in the usual

working week showed a positive effect on the industrial mobility behaviour only for males

in 1982/1983 and 1985/1986. Osberg, Gordon and Lin‟s (1994) results were as expected,

i.e. individuals desiring more working weeks/hours had higher probabilities of a sectoral

change.

In terms of working hours/weeks, the study by Osberg (1991) does not always point

towards a positive relationship between industrial mobility and working hours/weeks. The

empirical findings are thus inconsistent. The evidence also points to the industrial mobility

– working hours relation differing for males and females, with this labour supply factor

being important for males but not for females. Given the inconclusive evidence, and the

fact that the data are not available for all individuals in the KLIPS dataset, the hours data

will not be considered in the thesis.

Product and Work Similarity

Product and work similarity are other factors associated with the work environment. An

individual‟s propensity to change sectors/industries is expected to be higher the greater the

similarity across sectors of the characteristics of the products handled and work

environment. This arises as similarity of the products handled enhances the transferability

across industries of skills and knowledge, and similarity in work environment reduces the

psychic costs of adjustment [Vanderkamp (1977)]. Workers will therefore aim to relocate

to industries that are “close” to their current industry so that much of their human capital

acquired will be transferable [Fallick (1993)]. Vanderkamp (1977) operationalised the

product and work similarity concepts by classifying industries into eleven product groups

(product similarity) and into two work types: light (including mental activity) and heavy

222

(including manual and physical activity). Two dummy variables were used (Dummy = 1 if

the industries had similar product/work, Dummy = 0 otherwise). Positive correlations

between industrial mobility and product/work similarity were reported by Vanderkamp

(1997) for the years 1965/1966, 1966/1967 and 1967/1968, except for work similarity in

1967/1968.

Unfortunately Vanderkamp (1977) appears to be the only study that assesses the impact of

product and work similarity on the sectoral mobility of labour. There do not appear to be

any studies that examine gender differences in this dimension of sectoral mobility. This is

surprising given the intuition behind the inclusion of the variable in Vanderkamp‟s (1977)

study. A likely reason for this is the arbitrary nature of the categorization that needs to be

employed. Product/work similarity variables certainly have potential importance for the

research on Korean sectoral mobility, given that they signify ease of skill transferability

into the new sector. However, application depends on data availability, and the

arbitrariness of the definition noted above is a strong argument against the use of this set of

variables. Accordingly, product and work similarity variables will not be considered

further in this thesis.

Table 8.12 Working Hours, Product Similarity, Work Similarity and Industrial Mobility

Studies of Employees Osberg (1991) Osberg, Gordon

and Lin (1994)

Vanderkamp (1977)

Logit estimates Probit estimates

OLS estimates

Males Females

1980/81 1982/83 1985/86 1980/81 1982/83 1985/86 1965/66 1966/67 1967/68

Change in usual weekly hours

(period t+1 – period t)

-0.00035 0.0373*** 0.0169** 0.0023 0.0041 -0.0107

Desire more weeks per year 0.19**

Desire more hours per week 0.43**

Product Similarity1

(=1 if similar, =0 otherwise)

0.6094** 0.6020** 0.5391**

Work Similarity2

(=1 if similar, =0 otherwise)

0.0451** 0.0490** 0.0302

*** significant at 1% level, ** significant at 5% level. 1. Dummy variable indicating product similarity (Dummy x 10-2). The industries are classified into 11 product groups.

2. Dummy variable indicating work similarity (Dummy x 10-2). The industries are divided according to two types of work effort: light (including mental activity) and heavy (including

manual and physical activity). Note: The regression estimates shown are not comparable as their methods of estimation differ. Where the regression estimates are significant, the effect of the working hours/product

similarity/ work similarity on sectoral/industrial mobility is greater the larger the absolute magnitude of the estimate.

224

Size of Original and New Industries

Industry size is typically measured in empirical studies of worker mobility by the level of

employment or changes in employment and, to the extent that the contractions and

expansions in employment reveal declining or growing trends for specific industries, the

variable can reflect industry performance. Higher employment in the initial industry could

be viewed as a good indication of the industry‟s job market prospects/availability and lower

costs of finding a job in that industry [Neal (1995)]. Thus, a negative correlation between

mobility and employment growth in the old industry, and a positive association between

mobility and size of the new industry, are to be expected.

In terms of the size of the old industry, the expected negative relationship was reported by

both Fallick (1993) and Neal (1995) [see Table 8.13]. However, both of these studies cover

displaced workers only, and this approach does not appear to have been applied to other

groups or in separate analyses of the mobility of male and female employees.

With respect to the size of the new sector, higher employment was shown to be positively

correlated with industrial mobility in Vanderkamp (1977) for the three time periods

analysed. Similarly, lower job availabilities in the new industry (observed from the no-job-

available index) reduced the likelihood of industrial mobility for males in Osberg, Gordon

and Lin (1994). To the extent that lower job availabilities is an indication of lower

employment in a sector, the positive correlation between the new sector‟s size and mobility

is implied in the latter study.

While these findings are interesting, the limited number of studies of employed workers is a

shortcoming of research in this particular area. It prevents strong conclusions from being

drawn, whether for the aggregate labour force or for males and females separately.

Nevertheless, the ready availability of measures of employment size means that the impacts

of size of the original and new industries can be easily addressed in the current empirical

study. In this context, it is noted that the industry size variables (i.e. for original and new)

can be both examined in a single regression model as simultaneity does not appear to be an

225

issue. At any time t, the pool of workers in one industry differs from the pool of workers in

another.

Industry Turnover and Output

It is believed that higher turnover or output for an industry is generally indicative of its

ability to recruit, which raises the probability of finding a job and encourages inter-industry

mobility. However, higher turnover or output may also mean a greater chance of

retrenchment, which would be expected to be a deterrent to industrial mobility.

Vanderkamp (1997) reported a positive and significant relationship between turnover in the

new industry and industrial mobility. Jayadevan (1997) introduced the industrial output

growth rate as a performance indicator in an analysis of the manufacturing sector. Using

establishment data that covered all workers, it was found that a higher growth in output was

positively associated with higher employment growth or a higher net inflow of labour.

Among the unemployed, Ottersen (1993) showed that the number of layoffs in the original

sector was negatively associated with the probability of being hired in the new sector.

The different measures employed in these studies, as well as the vastly different

populations studied, prevents a consensus on the impact of industry performance on

sectoral mobility from emerging. Moreover, analysis of the industry performance –

sectoral mobility relationship has not been conducted for separate samples of males and

females. However, as with some other variables, there is considerable practical/policy

appeal in having knowledge of the links between industry performance and sectoral

mobility. For this reason, the applied work below will consider this relationship. In

assessing the variables, Vanderkamp‟s (1977) turnover indicator has the merit of

distinguishing the old versus new sectors so that the actual channel of influence on mobility

can be determined. However, the information is not about sectoral performance per se but

the sector‟s ability to recruit or retrench. Jayadevan‟s (1997) industry output (or GDP

growth) is a viable indicator as it reflects the economic performance of the sector, but it

lacks the sectoral distinction preferred for the current study and is confined to the

manufacturing sector. Hence, for the current work, it is recommended that a sectoral

performance indicator in the form of GDP growth be adopted with a sectoral distinction.

226

Table 8.13 Sectoral Performance Indicators and Sectoral/Industrial Mobility

Studies of Employees Jayadevan (1997) Osberg, Gordon

and Lin

(1994)

Vanderkamp (1977)

OLS estimates Probit

estimates

OLS estimates

1973/74 to 1979/80 1980/81 to 1990/91 1965/66 1966/67 1967/68 Industry Size

Employment in New Industry 0.0553** 0.0488** 0.0423**

No-Jobs Available Index in New Industry1

-1.98**

Industry Turnover Turnover in New Industry 0.0167** 0.0105** 0.0171**

Output Growth Rate 0.64*** 0.47***

Studies of the Unemployed Fallick (1993) Neal

(1995)

Ottersen

(1993)2

Hazard rate estimates Probit

estimates OLS

estimates

Industry Size Employment in Old Industry -4.7** -0.032***

Employment Growth in Old

Industry

-1.460***

Employment in New Industry -44.0

Ratio of Employment in the

New Industry to Employment in Old Industry

0.0012

Industry Turnover Layoffs in the Old Sector -2.01***

*** significant at 1% level, ** significant at 5% level.

1. The index is calculated as the difference between individuals from the same industry (who responded that a shortage of jobs created

difficulties in finding employment during their periods of non-employment) against the weighted national average of individuals in

another industry for the same occupation.

2. The dependent variable was the probability of being hired in the new sector conditional upon the fact that the workers were laid off

from the original sector. Note: The regression estimates shown are not comparable as their methods of estimation differ. Where the regression estimates are

significant, the effect of sectoral performance indicators on sectoral/industrial mobility is greater the larger the absolute magnitude of the estimate.

8.4 DETERMINANTS UNDER SECTORAL SHOCK THEORY

Table 8.14 outlines the main features of three studies that have examined the impact of

sectoral shocks on shifts in sectoral employment under the sectoral shock theory. Six

measures of sectoral shocks were considered: the annual sectoral employment growth rate

[Gulde and Wolf (1998)], the residual of an AR regression on the lagged growth rate of

employment [Gulde and Wolf (1998)], the standard error of a sectoral shock [Jovanovic

and Moffitt (1990)], the residual from a regression on the innovation (steady-state) variance

in aggregate employment [Altonji and Ham (1990)], the residual of a VAR regression of

the variance in industrial employment [Clark (1998)] and the industry-specific excess stock

returns [Brainard and Cutler (1993)].

227

The approach taken varies considerably across these studies. Gulde and Wolf (1998) used

the spatial correlation of the shock measures along the national (i.e. European Union) and

sectoral dimension for both the AR(1) measure of the shock and sectoral employment

growth rates. This correlation technique is not recommended as it merely measures the

association of sectoral shocks amongst countries and various sectors, and not the impact of

a shock as measured under a formal regression. Jovanovic and Moffitt (1990) regressed the

probability of a sectoral move for various groups of workers on a sectoral shock variable,

where the measure of a shock was provided by the standard deviation of residuals from

sector-specific AR(2) regressions of the log annual U.S. employment. Altonji and Ham‟s

(1990) shock variable was derived from the residual of a regression on the innovation

variance in aggregate employment in the Canadian labour market. This innovation

variance was expressed as a function of the variances of the national, provincial, sectoral

and U.S. shocks [derived from the residual of an AR(2) regression of U.S. GNP]. The

impact of the sectoral shock was determined via regression of the shock on each sector‟s

employment growth rate. Clark‟s (1998) model involved estimation in two forms, namely,

a VAR model and error models. The VAR model (for K lags) was estimated as:

K

Xt = ∑ ζk Xt-k + et k=1

where Xt is a vector of regional and industrial employment rates of growth, ζk is the vector

of regression coefficients and et is the error term. The error models were estimated as:

er,t = θrct + ∑ αrt εit + µrt i

ei,t = θict + εit + ∑ βrtµrt r

for industry i and region r, with ct, εit and µrt each representing unobserved national,

industrial and regional shocks. The θ coefficient represents the impact of a national shock.

Whilst the α coefficient measures the impact of the industry i shock in region r, the β

coefficient measures the impact of the region r shock in industry i. In particular, the

response of an industrial (sectoral) shock can be measured by the α coefficient in the error

model.

A concern with the measures adopted in Altonji and Ham (1990) and Clark (1998) is that

the various shock measures (national, provincial and sectoral) may be mutually

228

correlated12

, which could mean potential problems of multicollinearity. Brainard and

Cutler (1993) regressed the excess industrial employment change on the industry specific

excess stock returns. This dependent variable was the sum of residuals over several time

horizons arising from a regression of the change in the logarithm of each industry‟s

employment on a constant and the change in the logarithm of total employment. A concern

with the excess returns measure is that it is a capital measure rather than a labour market

measure. Furthermore, the excess returns variable does not appear to have great

explanatory power (R2 ranged from 0.001 to 0.007).

Despite the differences in methodology, the studies reviewed in Table 8.14 have a common

finding, namely that sector-specific shocks affect sectoral/industrial mobility. Gulde and

Wolf (1998) reported that sectoral shocks to the transport and food industries exhibited the

strongest spatial correlations, while the agricultural and textiles industries had smaller

correlations. Jovanovic and Moffitt (1990) found that sectoral shocks (as measured by the

residual of an AR regression on the lagged growth rate of employment) affected labour

mobility positively for workers with 5 and 8 years of experience. Alternative measures of

sectoral shocks were used (Lilien index and net flows of sectoral employment) but these

had insignificant effects on labour mobility. It was argued that the reason for the poor

performance of these alternative measures is that they include foreseen components of

changes arising from a sectoral shock, compared to the standard error of sectoral shocks

which accounts for the unanticipated effects following an exogenous shock. Altonji and

Ham (1990) established a positive impact of a sectoral shock on each sector‟s employment

growth for most industries up to 5 years, after which the effect dissipated. Clark‟s (1998)

study indicated that sector-specific shocks had a greater influence than the national shock

on the variance of industrial employment. Brainard and Cutler (1993) reported that the

excess stock returns to industry significantly predicted industrial employment growth,

although the effects were small.

229

Table 8.14 Sectoral Shocks and Sectoral/Industrial Mobility under Sectoral Shock Theory Gulde and Wolf (1998) Brainard and Cutler

(1993) Jovanovic and Moffitt (1990)

Annual

Employment

Growth Rate Measure

Residual of

AR(1)

Regression Measure

Industry‟s Excess

Returns2

Standard deviation

of Sectoral Shocks3

Lilien

Index3

Net Flows in

Sectoral

Employment3

Years of Experience

5 years 3.28* -4.51 -0.96

8 years 2.78*

-7.40 -1.54*

11 years 1.39

-8.23

-0.64

Quarters

1 0.0061* 4 0.0523***

8 0.0815***

12 0.0964***

16 0.1165***

20

0.1340***

Correlation patterns:

Shocks to

Employment Growth1

Agriculture 0.0532 0.0686

Construction 0.449 0.0211

Food 0.3007 0.2505 Chemicals 0.1623 0.0480

NM minerals 0.3099 0.2093

Metal products 0.1457 0.1108 Textiles 0.0136 0.0223

Paper, printing 0.1120 0.1139

Transport equipment 0.2557 0.1252 Other manufactures 0.2228 0.2066

Transportation 0.1713 0.2909

Fuel and power 0.1711 0.2067 Market services 0.1682 0.0815

Other services 0.0730 0.0558

Mean 0.1574 0.1329

Altonji and Ham (1990) Clark (1998)

OLS Residual Estimate4

Time Horizon

Shares of

Fitted Variance due

to Industry

Impact of Industry Shock on own-sector

0 1 2 3 4

Forestry 1.108 0.312 0.073 0.014 0.001 -

Mining 1.737 0.137 0.032 0.011 0.007 0.819 Manufacturing 1.540 0.845 0.364 0.117 -0.006 0.710

Construction 0.654 0.349 0.207 0.124 0.068 0.726

Transportation and

Utilities

0.416

Transportation 0.430 0.124 0.043 0.016 0.006

Trade 1.232 0.449 0.183 0.067 0.023 0.786 Finance, Insurance

and Real Estate

0.709

Finance 1.515 0.516 0.176 0.060 0.020 Services 0.991 0.305 0.123 0.022 0.000 0.709

Government 0.494 0.275 0.161 0.091 0.050 0.938

*** significant at 1% level. * significant at 10% level. 1. The higher the correlation, the greater the association of a sectoral shock with that sector‟s employment.

2. The larger the magnitude of the industry‟s excess returns, the greater the impact of a sectoral shock. The effects occur up to 20

quarters. 3. Where the regression estimates are significant, the effect of a sectoral shock on sectoral/industrial mobility is greater the larger the

absolute magnitude of the estimate. The Lilien index was described in chapter 3. 4. The impact of a sectoral shock on the growth rate of each industry‟s employment is higher the larger the absolute magnitude of the

residual estimate. The effects disappear after 5 years. 5. The impact of an industry shock is higher the larger the share of the fitted variance due to industry. Note: The regression estimates shown are not comparable as their methods of estimation differ.

230

In summary, whilst a range of methods have been used in the literature, several of these

seem less suited to the current study than others. Gulde and Wolf‟s (1998) correlation

technique is unsuitable, as it offers only a measure of association. Moreover, the spatial

component of the shock measure computed across the European countries is not relevant to

the current study which focuses on one country (i.e. Korea). The shock measures in Altonji

and Ham (1989) and Clark (1998) could have multicollinearity problems and Brainard and

Cutler‟s (1993) capital measure may not be relevant where the focus is on labour market

pressures. Thus, it appears that the AR technique employed by Gulde and Wolf (1998) and

Jovanovic and Moffitt (1990) to measure an industrial shock is the preferred approach for

the current work.

8.5 DETERMINANTS UNDER BRIDGING THEORY

The study by Jovanovic and Moffitt (1990) attempted to model sectoral/industrial mobility

based on the bridging theory (refer to Table 8.1). This section will not review the findings

for specific variables from this study since this was done in the sections above. Instead, the

further implications for modelling will be highlighted.

Jovanovic and Moffitt‟s (1990) model included one monetary variable (the standard

deviation of the wage distribution) and the sectoral shock variable. The monetary variable

was constructed by first estimating a log wage regression by year as a function of

education, experience, experience-squared and race. The predicted monetary variable and

sectoral shock were then entered into the mobility regression, which was estimated using

samples of workers at 3 levels of experience, 5, 8 and 11 years.

The main feature of the Jovanovic and Moffitt (1990) study of relevance to the current

study is the inclusion of the variables typically included in tests of the mismatch theory as

well as the sectoral shock variable. This approach will be followed in the empirical

chapters of this thesis.

231

8.6 ASSESSMENT OF EMPIRICAL STUDIES OF

SECTORAL MOBILITY FOR MODELLING

The sections above have reviewed the findings on specific variables in the empirical

literature, and where possible have commented on whether parallel variables should be

included in the empirical application to Korea. The lessons from past research can be

extended to issues associated with data-type, coverage, model specification, variable-type

and method of estimation. Under each of these headings, general observations from

empirical studies are identified below, followed by a critical assessment. Where possible,

links with the theoretical model and studies of other forms of mobility (in chapters 6 and 7)

are made. For reference, Table 8.1 has outlined the features of the studies of

sectoral/industrial mobility pertaining to the source, data-type, coverage, model

specification, dependent variable and method of estimation.

Data-type

Studies of sectoral mobility have been based on three types of data: longitudinal or unit-

record time-series13

, unit-record cross-sectional and aggregate-level datasets. Studies with

longitudinal data include Osberg (1991), Osberg, Gordon and Lin (1994), Jovanovic and

Moffitt (1990) and Loungani and Rogerson (1989), whilst those with cross-sectional data

comprise Vanderkamp (1977) and Neal (1995). The studies using aggregate-level datasets

are McLaughlin and Bils (2001), Jayadevan (1997) and Ottersen (1993).

Chapters 6 and 7 (and Part I) recommended the use of micro-level data for the study of the

factors affecting mobility to facilitate an in-depth understanding. Thus, studies with

aggregate-level data are less favoured since only broad-level patterns can be identified.

Amongst studies with unit-record data, analyses with time-series or cross-sectional data

appear to be equally valuable, as the former is able to cater for a time dimension in the

analyses, and the latter can provide an in-depth profile of industry movers. The KLIPS is a

unit-record longitudinal dataset which marries the two data categories bringing together the

benefits of both into a single estimating equation.

232

Coverage

The studies reviewed in Table 8.1 cover three labour groups5: the overall workforce

[Vanderkamp (1977), Loungani and Rogerson (1989) and Ottersen (1993)], males [Osberg,

Gordon and Lin (1994), Jovanovic and Moffitt (1990) and Neal (1995)] and separate

analyses for males and females [Osberg (1991)]. It is seen that most studies have examined

either the overall or male workforce, save for Osberg (1991). As the mobility patterns of

males and females may differ, chapter 6 recommended that the analyses be disaggregated

by gender. Against this background, the Osberg (1991) study appears to have an advantage

over the others by extending its analysis to female mobility. The current thesis will examine

mobility behaviour for the pooled workforce, and also conduct separate analyses for the

male and female workforces in Korea.

Model Specification

The model specification recommended in the previous chapter involved a mix of monetary

and non-monetary variables. Several studies of sectoral mobility have used such a

specification, namely, Osberg (1991), Vanderkamp (1977), Osberg, Gordon and Lin

(1994), Jovanovic and Moffitt (1990), Loungani and Rogerson (1989) and McLaughlin and

Bils (2001). Jovanovic and Moffitt (1990) is distinguished by also including a stochastic

shock variable. Therefore, in terms of the specification, these studies are more relevant for

the current work than those focusing only on the sectoral shock variable, i.e. Gulde and

Wolfe (1998), Brainard and Cutler (1993), Clark (1998) and Altonji and Ham (1990) [refer

to Table 8.14].

Sectoral Distinction of Variables

One of the points gathered from chapters 6 and 7 was that a sectoral breakdown for both

monetary and non-pecuniary variables was desirable. However, only a few of the studies

listed in Table 8.1 have accommodated this, namely the sectoral wage differential in

Osberg, Gordon and Lin (1994), sectoral wages, size and unemployment in Vanderkamp

(1977) and sectoral performance in Jayadevan (1997). The current study will be based on

sectoral-specific variables where possible.

233

Dependent Variable and Method of Estimation

Chapter 6 indicated that the dependent variable should be binary, indicative of an

individual‟s change of sectors/industries, and this should be analysed with a probit or logit

model. Selected studies, i.e. Osberg (1991), Osberg, Gordon and Lin (1994), Jovanovic

and Moffitt (1990) and Neal (1995), have used the probit or logit model to examine the

probability of a sectoral move. These are more relevant to the empirical model of equation

(6.7) than those studies using the proportion/growth rate of industry movers/moves and

OLS for estimation.

In summary, there is no one single study that accommodates all the relevant features for the

current work. The empirical model is a combination of the features implied from its

theoretical origins (outlined in chapter 6) and extracted from other studies of various forms

of mobility (in chapter 7).

8.7 SUMMARY OF EMPIRICAL STUDIES OF SECTORAL MOBILITY

This chapter has described the various ways worker mobility has been modelled. The

empirical evidence from sectoral/industrial mobility can be succinctly stated. It should be

noted that only variables where at least two studies reported a similar finding are discussed

in this paragraph. The main determinants of sectoral/industrial mobility appear to be overall

wages, unemployment duration, age, tenure, working hours, size of the old/new industry

and sectoral shocks. Among the employed, the variables that were positively associated

with sectoral/industrial mobility were overall wages, working hours, size of the new

industry and sectoral shocks. Unemployment duration, age and tenure were shown to have

a negative impact on mobility. Among the unemployed, only age, tenure and size of old

industry, which had negative effects on industrial mobility, were statistically significant.

Only a few studies reported that separate analyses were conducted for males and females.

Unemployment spell, employment status, working hours/weeks and size of new industry

were positively associated with male mobility, whilst age and tenure had negative impacts.

234

Employment status and unemployment spell had positive influences on female mobility,

whilst age, tenure and the overall unemployment rate had negative effects on female

mobility. The remaining variables considered for the separate gender groups, namely

marital status for both groups and working hours/week for females, were statistically

insignificant.

Table 8.15 lists the explanatory variables used and findings in the studies of

sectoral/industrial mobility. The applicability of these variables with respect to the current

analysis for the Korean workforce is also summarized in this table. Whilst sections 8.3 and

8.4 have reviewed the explanatory variable in terms of conceptual alignment with the

theoretical model and research on sectoral mobility, an assessment of the variables on

issues of measurement and applicability for the Korean labour market, and availability of

data in the KLIPS dataset, is also provided in the table.

Given the varied evidence and few common findings for each explanatory variable, few

firm general conclusions can be drawn. Even fewer can be drawn concerning gender

differences in the determinants of mobility. However, this should not be viewed as overly

alarming, as there are conflicting hypotheses regarding the impact of most variables on

industrial mobility. Thus, the impact of many variables cannot be determined prior to the

empirical application. The analysis on the determinants of industrial mobility in Korea to

be undertaken in chapters 9 and 10 will adopt a comprehensive approach which may enable

comment on the array of findings in the literature to date.

235

Table 8.15 Assessment of the Explanatory Variables

Explanatory Variables Findings Applicability Measurement/Remarks Monetary Variables Overall Wages P (E)

I (U) No

This variable is not recommended as

there is no sectoral distinction.

Wages in the New Sector/Industry

M (E) M (U)

Yes Individual‟s average monthly income in the new sector, adjusted for the chances of finding employment. This variable will be used to compute the expected sectoral wage differential.

Wages in the Original Sector/Industry

M (E) P(U)

Yes Individual‟s average monthly income in the original sector. This variable will be used to compute the expected sectoral wage differential.

Sectoral Wage Differential I (E) Yes Wage differential between individual‟s monthly income in the new sector and individual‟s monthly income in the original sector. This variable will be adjusted for the chances of finding employment.

Wage Growth in the New Sector/Industry

n.r. Yes The annual growth rate of wages (in percentage terms) in the individual‟s new sector/industry.

Wage Growth in the Original Sector/Industry

n.r. Yes The annual growth rate of wages (in percentage terms) in the individual‟s original sector/industry.

Macroeconomic Variables Overall Unemployment N (E)

I (U) No This variable is not recommended as

there is no sectoral distinction.

Unemployment in the New Sector

M (E) Yes The unemployment rate of the individual‟s new sector. A lagged variable should be used if simultaneity occurs with sectoral/industrial mobility.

Unemployment in the Original Sector

P (E) I (U)

Yes The unemployment rate of the individual‟s original sector. A lagged variable should be used if simultaneity occurs with sectoral/industrial mobility.

Unemployment Duration

P (E) M (U)

No The data pertain to the unemployed for aggregate-level datasets.

Overall Economic Growth M Yes Overall GDP growth rate.

Overall Employment M No This variable is not recommended as it should simply capture influences similar to the unemployment variable.

Inflation Rate n.r. No All workers face the same price levels and changes regardless of sectors.

236

Table 8.15 Assessment of the Explanatory Variables (continued)

Explanatory Variables Findings Applicability Measurement/Remarks Worker Characteristics Age N (E)

N (U) Yes Age of individual (in years).

Gender M (E-males)

P (U-females) Yes Gender of individual entered as a

dummy variable for males versus females.

Race n.r. No A racial distinction is not relevant for predominantly mono-cultural societies like Korea.

Language n.r. No The findings were insignificant. Furthermore, the variable is not needed as the common/commercial language in Korea is Korean.

Marital Status P (E) N (U)

Yes Marital status of an individual (married versus non-married) entered as a dummy variable.

Household Head N (U) Yes Household head status of an individual entered as a dummy variable to distinguish if the person was a household head.

Children I (U) No This variable is not recommended as its

effect was found to be insignificant.

Formal Education M (E) M (U)

Yes Education status entered as a dummy variable to distinguish tertiary versus non-tertiary educated workers.

On-the-job Training P (E) No The data on on-the-job training are difficult to quantify.

Tenure N (E) N (U)

Yes Job tenure of the individual measured in years is available.

Initial Industry M (E) I (U)

Yes The initial industry of an individual.

Occupation Status M (E) M (U)

Yes Occupational status of an individual (skilled versus semi-skilled) entered as a dummy variable.

Employment Status M (E) Yes Employment status of an individual [employee versus other workers (employer, own account workers, family workers)] entered as a dummy variable.

Unionisation n.r. No The data are not available for non-employees in Korea.

Region n.r. No The data are only available for region of birth, and not region of present residence.

Alternative Sources of Income

n.r. No The KLIPS had poor data quality as the majority of respondents did not know whether they had social assistance.

237

Table 8.15 Assessment of the Explanatory Variables (continued)

Explanatory Variables Findings Applicability Measurement/Remarks Job/Industry Characteristics Working Hours/Weeks P (E) No There was a relatively high number of

KLIPS respondents who did not indicate their working hours/weeks. Therefore, the number of observations for this variable compared to the other explanatory variables is relatively low.

Product/Work Similarity P (E) No The level of product/work similarity cannot be ascertained from the KLIPS.

Size of Original Industry N (U) Yes Level of industry employment in the individual‟s original industry.

Size of New Industry P (E) I (U)

Yes Sum of industries‟ employment except that of the individual‟s original industry.

Industry Turnover P (E) N (U)

No The separation and accession rates were not available for the agricultural sector.

Performance of Original Industry

n.r. Yes Value-added growth rate of individual‟s original industry.

Performance of New Industry n.r. Yes Value-added growth rate of individual‟s new industry (i.e. all other industries except individual‟s original industry).

Sectoral Shock

P

Yes

Residual of an AR regression on employment that is lagged by one or more time-periods.

Annotation: P : one or more studies reported a positive effect on mobility. N : one or more studies reported a negative effect on mobility. I : one or more studies reported an insignificant effect on mobility. M : Mixed findings among studies/groups/periods. It can refer to differing results among multiple studies and/or

across time periods for same work group in the same study, or for different groups (e.g. males and females) in the same study.

E : Employed persons. U : Unemployed persons. n.r.: The variable was not reviewed. Note: Where neither „E‟ nor „U‟ is indicated, the variable covers the macro-economy.

8.8 SUMMARY OF LESSONS DRAWN FROM THE LITERATURE

Numerous lessons have been drawn from the theoretical and empirical review in the first

three chapters of Part II, covering both sectoral mobility and other forms of mobility.

Chapter 6 provides the theoretical basis for model application and estimation. The

extended Le and Miller (1998) model (as per equation 6.7) is the recommended tool where

conceptual advancements are introduced in the form of the expected sectoral wage

differential and lifetime earnings. Probit- or logit-type regressions are deemed as most

suitable, catering for the use of dichotomous dependent variables which adequately reflect

238

dual mobility states, namely, to move or to stay. Gender analyses on mobility, which are

usually neglected in the literature, could be conducted depending on findings of gender

differences in Korea. The model can be applied to test the three theories of sectoral

mobility covering the worker-employer mismatch, sectoral shock and bridging hypotheses.

Chapter 7 reviews other forms of labour mobility (union/non-union, public-private, rural-

urban) and gives a general framework for specification of the current model. The

recommendations are to establish a model that includes a sectoral wage differential as well

as macroeconomic and non-monetary factors; a sectoral distinction for the unemployment

variable, and sectoral breakdown for non-pecuniary variables where possible. Longitudinal

datasets are superior to cross-sectional datasets as they are a rich data source and cater for

time-series analyses. The latter attribute is desirable for the current study as

macroeconomic and lagged dependent variables, which have been found to be significant

determinants of mobility, can be incorporated into the empirical model.

Chapter 8 is the critical literature review where empirical evidence is canvassed from

studies of sectoral/industrial mobility that could be a yardstick against which analyses of

the determinants of mobility in Korea are assessed. However, varied evidence and

conflicting hypotheses prevent the formation of firm conclusions for each variable. The

determinants reported to be significant covered an array of monetary factors (overall

wages), macroeconomic factors (unemployment duration), worker characteristics (age,

tenure and working hours), job characteristics (size of the old/new industry) and sectoral

shocks. This spread of factors, coupled with the limitation in the number of common

findings, gives rise to the adoption of a comprehensive approach in model specification for

the current work.

The final section of chapter 8 (section 8.7) summarizes the applicability of the explanatory

variables with respect to the current analysis, taking into account issues related to

measurement, the Korean labour market and data availability. The determinants to enter

into worker‟s mobility function are the sectoral wage differential, sectoral wage

growth/unemployment/size/performance, GDP growth, sex, age, marital status, educational

attainment, head of household status, occupational status, employer status, job tenure and

239

the sectoral shock. The investigation into the determinants of sectoral mobility in Korea

begins in chapter 9, followed by the study disaggregated by gender in chapter 10.

Endnotes:

1. Refers to 751 job losers and quitters who changed industries out of a total of 1,089 who went through at

least 1 week of unemployment but gained employment either in the new or old industry.

2. Refers to 1,685 workers who changed industries out of a total of 2,641 employees. The 2,641 were

unemployed in the 5 years before the survey date but they had gained full-time employment at the point of the

survey.

3. Several studies [Podgursky and Swaim (1987), Madden (1987, 1988) and Addison and Portugal (1989)]

recognized the importance of industrial mobility but did not examine this form of worker mobility behaviour.

These studies focused on the wage losses of displaced workers instead.

4. The industry was classified into eleven product groups to distinguish product similarity and two work

groups (light – mental activity, and heavy – manual/physical activity) for classifying work similarity.

5. It is noted that Prasad (1997) examined the correlations between the growth rates in relative sectoral

employment and relative sectoral wages. The relative measures of these variables were the deviations from

the aggregate growth rates. Negative and significant correlations between relative wages and employment

were found in agriculture, construction, finance, manufacturing, mining, public administration and utilities

during the 1959-1993 period. This measure is not suitable for the current study as it is a bi-variate correlation

study, not regression analysis. 6. Results from Thomas (1996b) were inferred from Figures 1 and 2 for a standard worker who receives/does not receive UI according to the route of job separation (quit or loss). The standard worker is one who worked in a service industry in a blue-collar occupation for 2.2 years, did not belong to a union and had an hourly wage rate of $9.16. The results are the probability of the u-r transition from being unemployed in sector „a‟ to being employed in sector „b‟, Mjb (tu), conditional upon the length of the unemployment spell (tu) and job separation status (j). Mjb (tu) = hjb (tu) / [hjb (tu) + hja (tu)], where hj represents the hazard rates of transition. 7. The marginal effect is measured by β*ρ*(1-ρ)*100, where β is the regression coefficient and ρ is the

proportion of industry movers. In Osberg (1991), the marginal effects for males were 0.23, 0.18 and 0.21 for

1980/1981, 1982/1983 and 1985/1986, respectively. For the same corresponding periods, the marginal effects

for females were 0.26, 0.12 and 0.32.

8. It is noted that the coefficient of (AiAj)1/2

was positive.

9. Amongst the unemployed, Neal (1995) reported that married males had a lower likelihood of switching

industries.

10. The KLIPS questionnaire classifies training (excluding regular schooling) according to training in a

private institution, authorized vocational institute, public vocational institution, in-house training by firms etc.

Since there are a variety of training programmes, those who received training would have had different types

of training which may or may not be relevant to the new sector. Furthermore, not all individuals would have

received training, especially the non-employees.

11. This does not support the view in Neal (1995) that switchers forfeit compensation for industry skills.

12. Altonji and Ham (1990) and Clark (1998) made mention of possible correlations between shock measures

but assumed the errors were independently distributed in the models.

13. A number of studies use datasets that follow individuals or firms over time. These can be described as

unit-record time-series datasets. In this thesis, these will be referred to via the usual terminology of

longitudinal or panel datasets.

240

CHAPTER 9

EMPIRICAL STUDY ON THE DETERMINANTS

OF SECTORAL/INDUSTRIAL MOBILITY IN KOREA

9.1 INTRODUCTION

The literature review in chapter 8 indicated that there is a solid empirical foundation for the

understanding of worker mobility. It was suggested that the main determinants of sectoral

labour mobility in the U.S., Canada, Sweden and India are monetary, economic,

demographic and socio-economic factors. However, three gaps in the research were

identified. First, there is a dearth of mobility studies for Asia. This chapter attempts to fill

this void in the literature by modelling mobility behaviour in Korea. Second, there are a

number of inconsistencies in the results reported. For example, there are few common

findings with regards to the relationship between inter-industry mobility and worker

characteristics. The current study will attempt to account for these inconsistencies. Third,

the studies reviewed often focus on one set of variables (e.g. demographic) to the exclusion

of others (e.g. monetary). It is the intent of this chapter to conduct an all-encompassing

formal study covering monetary, economic, demographic and socio-economic factors,

which no other study has done.

The objective of this chapter will therefore be to comprehensively examine the

determinants of sectoral/industrial mobility for the Korean workforce. The chapter is

organized as follows. Section 9.2 introduces the data source, concepts, coverage and time

periods used in the empirical work. A generic model of sectoral/industrial mobility is

presented in Section 9.3. Sections 9.4 and 9.5 present descriptive statistics of the variables

used in the regression analysis of sectoral mobility, as well as selected

predicted/recomputed monetary and sector-level variables. The results of the empirical

analysis of the determinants of sectoral mobility are presented and discussed in Section 9.6.

A series of extensions of the empirical model are considered in Section 9.7. These include

assessing the impact of an individual‟s industry of origin on sectoral mobility as well as an

empirical test of three theories of mobility: worker-employer mismatch, sectoral shock and

bridging theories. A summary of the empirical findings and concluding comments are

241

given in the final section. The list of variables and the rules followed when deriving them

are provided in Appendices 9A and 9B.

9.2 DATA SOURCES, CONCEPTS AND COVERAGE

This chapter is based on both unit-record and aggregate-level data. The unit-record data

were obtained from the Korean Labor and Income Panel Study (KLIPS) conducted by the

Korea Labor Institute (KLI)1. The aggregate-level data were obtained from the Korea

National Statistical Office (NSO).

There are five ideal prerequisites for a micro-level dataset on inter-industry mobility: (i) the

sample should be representative of the working population; (ii) the dataset should be large;

(iii) individuals must be surveyed at least twice; (iv) the data should extend over a fairly

long period; and (v) individuals should report income and industry at the time of the

interview rather than over the past year [McLaughlin and Bils (2001)]. The unit-record

data available in the KLIPS sample satisfy these prerequisites.

9.2.1 KLIPS Data

Although there are several national labour surveys in Korea, i.e. Current Population Survey,

Special Survey of Employment, Survey of Labour Mobility and Basic Survey of Wages,

these are cross-sectional in nature. Cross-sectional data do not cater for the construction of

many of the variables that are prominent in studies of mobility behaviour, and the KLI was

set up to enable the collection of longitudinal data that might overcome these and to

facilitate in-depth study of the labour market and mobility issues. The KLIPS that it has

collected is a longitudinal study of a representative sample of households and individuals

living in urban areas in Korea. It is the first panel survey in Korea on labour-related issues.

The first wave was launched in 1998 in the midst of the Asian Financial Crisis.

The KLIPS sample is an equal probability sample of households from the seven

metropolitan cities and urban areas in eight provinces in Korea. The sampling frame was

from the 1995 Korean mid-term census. Out of 21,675 census unit areas, 951 sampling

unit areas were selected. For each sampling unit, five to six households were randomly

242

chosen. The KLIPS sample yielded 5,000 households in the first wave, with some 13,321

household members aged 15 years and over being successfully interviewed. These 5,000

households represent the original panel in the study.

The study comprises four waves of data that were collected from 1998 till 2001. The initial

sample of households were interviewed in 1998 (wave 1), with follow-up interviews in

1999 (wave 2), 2000 (wave 3) and 2001 (wave 4). New joiners, namely those who have

blood or economic ties to the original panel members, were added to the sample in waves

2-4. Where a panel member moved out and formed an independent household with his/her

new family (e.g. spouse), then the new family members were treated as new joiners to the

original panel. Additionally, if an outside party joins one of the existing households

surveyed (e.g. via marriage), he/she was also included in the interview. Each person is

identified by a unique personal identification number (PID).

The field work for the KLIPS started in May and ended around September each year, with

the majority of household interviews being completed by end-August. Consequently, the

survey reference month is treated as end-June (mid-point) each year.

Any analysis on mobility needs a time dimension to assess if mobility occurred. This paper

looks at the mobility over one year, i.e. between year t-1 and year t. Sectoral/industrial

mobility is defined as having occurred if a person switched industries between year t-1 and

year t. This establishes one of the selection criteria for the current study‟s dataset, namely

that a person must participate in at least two consecutive survey years and have reported

positive incomes and valid data on the industry of employment in the two years. It is

possible to identify such persons by using the PID to match respondents in the datasets of

adjacent years. One advantage in using a one-year time dimension to examine mobility is

that persons who switch industries with longer intervening unemployment spells can be

included in the study.2

As the KLIPS attempts to track members who moved out of the original household, the

KLIPS dataset does not depend on residential stability. Since at the aggregate level, inter-

industry mobility includes inter-industry movers who change their place of residence, this

means that the measure of industrial mobility available for use in this thesis will not

243

underestimate aggregate inter-industry labour mobility. This an advantage over Osberg‟s

(1991) study, for example, where movers were dropped from the original Canadian sample

of households and thus his measure of the dependent variable was the conditional

probability of inter-industry mobility, given residential stability. Since the residential

movers in Canada comprised 3% of the initial sample, if the probabilities of residential and

inter-industry mobility are positively correlated, Osberg‟s (1991) estimate of the probability

of sectoral mobility would be biased downwards.

Notwithstanding these advantages, several limitations of the dataset must be pointed out.

The past year‟s data can be captured fairly accurately for waves 2-4, as respondents, having

been interviewed in the first wave, are aware of the subsequent interviews and will

probably record and report the information at the time of the interview and/or provide an

update of the change of information from the previous year‟s survey. The responses for the

initial wave, however, could be subject to greater recall error as respondents were being

interviewed for the first time and did not know previously that they had to provide answers

to their income/industry over the past year. So the actual dollar income earned or specific

industry group for the initial wave may not be accurate. Nevertheless, there is consistency

in all the waves in the sense that the past year‟s information refers to the past 12 months.

This even applies to the initial wave. Some respondents may have reported a series of jobs

in the past but it is possible to ascertain the previous year‟s income/industry based on the

start dates and quit dates of the previous job. So the data for wave 1 are fixed to a specific

time period of one year, i.e. as at June 1997.

The other limitation lies in the length of the time period available for research. The four-

year time series, though adequate for research on some labour market characteristics (e.g.

unemployment duration), may not be sufficiently long to capture effects on mobility over

an individual‟s working life. Furthermore, as mobility patterns are detected at the same

month every year (i.e. June), it would not be possible to ascertain the seasonal responses in

mobility behaviour. Unless mobility patterns can be tracked quarterly/six-monthly instead

of annually, any seasonal effects on inter-industry mobility should be interpreted with

caution.

To obtain information about individuals during the pre-move period (year t-1) and post-

move period (year t), the data items from the previous wave‟s dataset were appended to the

244

current wave‟s dataset via matching with the PID. The list of data items and their

derivations are supplied in Appendix 9A. Moreover, for the initial 1998 wave, respondents

were asked to provide their previous income, industry, occupation, employment size,

employment status, start dates and quit dates, and so these records could be considered for

inclusion in the set of inter-industry movers for the study below.

The analysis focuses on a subset of the population in the dataset, namely persons aged 20-

64 years. The age group is chosen as the mobility patterns for younger workers (aged less

than 20 years) are affected by schooling behaviour, whilst those for older workers (beyond

64 years) are influenced by retirement behaviour. To model mobility that is affected by

schooling or retirement behaviour is beyond the scope of the thesis. Therefore, the focus is

on workers aged 20-64 years. This is in line with Oi‟s (1987) recommendation to include

adults aged 20-64 years as this offers a „cleaner statistic measuring variations in labour

market activity‟. Respondents with non-positive income, those who did not report either an

old/new industry, and those who did not provide valid data on any other question used in

the analysis are excluded from the sample. Consequently, the sample for the current study

amounts to 10,691 person-year observations covering the period 1998-2001 (about 4 years

per person). In addition, one variable, working hours in the individual‟s original sector, was

excluded owing to its significantly fewer number of observations (6,161).

The structure of the sample dataset varies from that used in past studies. Cross-sectional

analyses of mobility behaviour have been conducted for different periods with periodic

gaps. For instance, Osberg (1991) analysed 3 sets of years: 1980 to 1981, 1982 to 1983 and

1985 to 1986, with a periodic gap between the second and third set. This study‟s panel

dataset combines the mobility records of individuals from 4 consecutive waves: 1997 to

1998, 1998 to 1999, 1999 to 2000 and 2000 to 2001. By repeatedly interviewing the same

respondents over the years, there are no periodic gaps and mobility behaviour can be more

readily analysed in conjunction with the continuous time-series macroeconomic data which

can be embedded into this type of data structure. With the inclusion of relevant time-series

macroeconomic data in micro-level panel data, the explanatory power of the regression

analysis of sectoral mobility is likely to be enhanced.

245

9.2.2 Korea NSO Data

The macroeconomic variables and sectoral indicator variables considered from the

literature review to have influence on mobility decisions, namely: overall/sectoral GDP

growth rate, sectoral/industrial employment size and unemployment rate, and annual

growth rates in sectoral/industrial income, are obtained from the Korea NSO. In addition,

the sectoral shock measure is estimated using industrial employment data from the NSO.

9.2.3 The Role of Interim State of Unemployment

The sample of 10,691 covers employed persons who reported an industry of employment as

at year t-1 and year t. This does not preclude the possibility of such persons being out of

employment between periods t-1 and t. The purpose of this section is to demonstrate that

ignoring any interim states of unemployment does not affect the analysis of sectoral labour

flows. By doing so, the various states of employment/non-employment and the relationship

between gross and net labour flows are highlighted. The approach here is to examine the

inflows and outflows of labour from a larger sample with fewer restrictions, and to compare

these to the proposed final sample of 10,691 observations, where additional restrictions are

imposed to permit a more refined analysis. In addition, this preliminary analysis will

provide the reader with information on how the sample of 10,691 observations evolved.

9.2.3.1 Sectoral Labour Flows

Table 9.1 shows the labour flows based on a sample of persons aged 20-64 years, where

individuals can report either their new or old industry, or both. That is, respondents need

not report all of the information on wages, job tenure, employment status, occupational

status and educational attainment. This gives us a larger sample size of 29,474 person-year

observations. This sample constitutes industry stayers (Es), inter-industry movers,

employed workers in year t-1 who become unemployed, moved out of the labour force or

did not report any industry in year t (denoted by Uo, where the subscript refers to outflows)

as well as the unemployed, those not in the labour force (NILF) or who did not report any

industry in year t-1 who entered into employment and reported their industry in year t

246

(denoted by Ui, where the subscript refers to inflows). Among inter-industry movers, the

inflow of entrants into a particular industry is represented by Ei, and the outflow, by Eo.

The gross inflow of labour into an industry from year t-1 to year t will comprise workers

from other industries as well as the unemployed and those formerly NILF3. That is, gross

labour inflow = Ei + Ui. For example, the gross inflow of labour into the agricultural

sector (302) consists of workers from the non-agricultural sector (237) and those formerly

unemployed or persons NILF (65).

At the same time, the gross outflow of labour from an industry consists of workers who

changed to other industries as well as those who became unemployed or moved out of the

labour force4. The gross outflow from the agricultural sector, for example, is 390,

and this includes movers into the non-agricultural sector (328) and persons who

become unemployed or choose not to participate in the labour force (62). Thus,

gross outflow = Eo + Uo.

Table 9.1 Gross and Net Labour Flows based on Sample of 29,474 Observations New Industry

Old Industry

Uo 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Gross

Outflows

Net

Flows

Ui 65 3 254 7 153 507 78 266 350

1 62 1567 1 85 1 45 99 15 46 36 390 88

2 101 16 8 7 0 7 6 0 0 1 138 125

3 1295 60 3 4420 7 152 573 90 217 174 2571 1393

4 17 2 0 5 64 3 6 3 7 0 43 10

5 432 24 1 121 4 1483 118 36 114 52 902 244

6 1259 72 0 389 1 129 4770 102 246 233 2431 666

7 146 11 2 54 0 38 76 1162 56 32 415 -1

8 598 28 3 151 11 92 187 57 2451 151 1278 199

9 648 24 0 112 2 39 193 35 127 2518 1180 151

Gross

Inflows 302 13 1178 33 658 1765 416 1079 1029 Annotation for Industry:

1 (Agriculture), 2 (Mining), 3 (Manufacturing), 4 (Utilities), 5 (Construction), 6 (Commerce), 7 (Transport, Storage &

Communications), 8 (Financial, Real Estate & Business Services) and 9 (Community, Social & Personal Services). Uo : Employees in an industry in year t-1 who become unemployed or moved out of the labour force or did not report any

industry in year t.

Ui : Unemployed or those not in the labour force/did not report any industry in year t-1 who entered into an industry of employment in year t.

Note: As at year t-1, Uo and Ui are mutually exclusive. As at year t, Uo and Ui are mutually exclusive.

The net labour flow is taken as the difference between the gross outflows and inflows.

Mathematically, the net flow = (Eo + Uo) – (Ei + Ui.). The example of the agricultural

sector reveals a net outflow of 88 persons. From Table 9.1, the gross outflow exceeds the

247

gross inflow for all sectors/industries except for transport, storage and communications.

This pattern is not surprising since the data collection was during the post-Asian Financial

Crisis period which witnessed numerous business closures and job losses on an economy-

wide scale. An outflow of labour in nearly all sectors/industries is thus to be expected.

9.2.3.2 Missing Industry Information

The provision of a respondent‟s industry information in period t-1 and period t is a critical

key for the empirical exercise. In the dataset, some workers did not state their industry of

employment in either survey period t-1 or period t. Their numbers are represented by

Uiinterim

and Uointerim

in Table 9.2. From Tables 9.1 and 9.2, Ui = Ui*

+ Uiinterim

and

Uo = Uo* + Uo

interim. From the first equality, Ui

interim denotes persons who did not report any

industry in period t-1 but reported an industry of employment in period t. The Ui* category

comprises persons formerly in non-employment in period t-1 who entered into employment

in period t. For the second equation, Uointerim

are those who had a job/industry reported in

period t-1 but did not provide their industry of employment in period t. The Uo*

category

represents workers formerly in employment in period t-1 who became unemployed or left

the labour force in period t. Since such persons under Uiinterim

and Uointerim

categories did

not report any industry information in one of the time periods, they are excluded from the

final sample.

It is observed that missing industry information does not really affect the comparison of

gross flows and net flows in the KLIPS. Compared to Table 9.1, when Uiinterim

and Uointerim

are ignored, gross outflows still exceed the gross inflows for all sectors/industries in Table

9.2. Furthermore, the labour movements of inter-industry movers (i.e. the Eo‟s and Ei‟s) of

Table 9.2 are very similar to those of Table 9.1. One difference between Table 9.1 and

Table 9.2 is the net flow data for the transport, storage and communications industry, where

the net flow turned positive, from -1 to 5. The small disparity of 6 persons stems from the

difference between Uiinterim

(19) and Uointerim

(13). Thus, from this exercise, the non-

importance of the non-stated industry categories is illustrated.

Table 9.2 Gross and Net Labour Flows based on Sample of 29,474 Observations New Ignoring Uo

interim Industry

Old

Industry

U*o Uointerim 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Gross

Outflows

Net

Flows

Gross

Outflows

Net

Flows

U*i 0 62 2 198 5 126 429 59 208 279

Uiinterim 3 1 56 2 27 78 19 58 71

1 60 2 1567 1 85 1 45 99 15 46 36 390 88 388 89 2 98 3 16 8 7 0 7 6 0 0 1 138 125 135 123 3 1240 55 60 3 4420 7 152 573 90 217 174 2571 1393 2516 1394 4 16 1 2 0 5 64 3 6 3 7 0 43 10 42 11 5 406 26 24 1 121 4 1483 118 36 114 52 902 244 876 245 6 1197 62 72 0 389 1 129 4770 102 246 233 2431 666 2369 682 7 133 13 11 2 54 0 38 76 1162 56 32 415 -1 402 5 8 582 16 28 3 151 11 92 187 57 2451 151 1278 199 1262 241 9 626 22 24 0 112 2 39 193 35 127 2518 1180 151 1158 200 Gross Inflows 302 13 1178 33 658 1765 416 1079 1029

Gross Inflows

Ignoring

Uiinterim

299 12 1122 31 631 1687 397 1021 958

Annotation for Industry : See Table 9.1.

249

9.2.3.3 Missing Survey Information

It is observed that the sample of 29,474 observations contains respondents who did not

provide information on all of the potential determinants of sectoral mobility to be examined

in the statistical analysis. To effectively conduct the empirical analysis of mobility, the

latter group, numbering 12,544 over the four waves (see top panel of Table 9.3), had their

records removed. Additionally, persons who entered into/out of the states of non-

employment marked out by intervals of one year, or those who did not report an industry of

employment in either period t-1 or period t (U0 and Ui), were also excluded (see section

9.2.3.2). The remaining sample of 10,691 observations in the bottom panel of Table 9.3

consists of stayers (Es) and movers (Eo and Ei) who reported all of the survey information.

Under these sample exclusions, it is can be seen that the comparison of gross outflows and

gross inflows in the sample of 10,691 observations differs from that of the unabridged

sample of 29,474 observations. The net labour flow is now positive for the agricultural,

mining and manufacturing sectors, and negative for utilities, construction, commerce and

the services industries. Therefore, missing survey information on the other explanatory

variables appears to affect the relative sizes of the gross and net flows. Unfortunately, the

importance of this to the statistical analyses conducted below cannot be ascertained, either

through formal modelling5 or by drawing on the literature (where the issue does not seem to

have been discussed).

Table 9.3 Industry Breakdown of 29,474 Sample with/without Survey Information New Industry

Old Industry

Uo 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Total

excl. Uo

Ui 65 3 254 7 153 507 78 266 350

Respondents who did not report other survey information*

1 62 1154 1 46 0 17 58 3 16 22 1317

2 101 12 3 5 0 0 2 0 0 0 22

3 1295 45 3 2362 3 76 308 37 91 76 3001

4 17 1 0 2 37 1 3 0 3 0 47

5 432 9 0 61 1 726 54 15 45 28 939

6 1259 46 0 209 0 51 2879 42 110 115 3452

7 146 6 1 21 0 16 36 543 24 9 656

8 598 21 0 62 3 55 90 20 1202 74 1527

9 648 15 0 60 1 20 100 14 58 1315 1583 Total excl. Ui 1309 8 2828 45 962 3530 674 1549 1639 12544

250

Table 9.3 Industry Breakdown of 29,474 Sample with/without

Survey Information (continued) New

Industry

Old Industry

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Gross

Outflows

Net

Flows

Respondents who reported all of the required survey information

(based on 10,691 observations)

1 413 39 1 28 41 12 30 14 165 83

2 4 5 2 7 4 1 18 13

3 15 2059 4 76 265 53 126 99 638 180

4 1 2 27 2 3 3 4 15 -3

5 15 1 61 3 757 64 21 69 24 258 -11

6 26 180 1 78 1891 60 136 118 599 -8

7 5 1 33 22 40 619 32 23 156 -51

8 7 3 89 8 37 97 37 1249 77 355 -111

9 9 52 1 19 93 21 69 1203 264 -92 Gross Inflows 147 8 712 25 422 1114 285 732 706

Annotation for Industry, Uo and Ui : See Table 9.1. * : This comprises respondents who reported both their original and new industries but did not provide any information for at least

one of the following variables: old wage, new wage, job tenure or occupation. These records were excluded to obtain the main sample of 10,691 observations.

9.2.3.4 Interim States of Unemployment

The sample of 10,691 observations will include those who may have experienced an

interrupted spell of unemployment between period t-1 and period t. Out of this sample,

there are some 826 workers who encountered an unemployment spell during the interim

period, as shown in Table 9.4. The difference between these workers and the Uiinterim

and

Uointerim

groups is that they reported their industry of employment as at the survey reference

dates. Hence, they can be effectively classified under their industry of employment, as

shown in Table 9.4.

The purpose in this section is to illustrate that even if the 826 persons were excluded, the

main features of the comparison of the gross outflows and gross inflows carry over from

the comparisons shown in Table 9.3. There is a net outflow of labour from the

agricultural, mining and manufacturing sectors, and a net inflow into the utilities,

construction, commerce and services industries. Therefore, ignoring the state of intervening

unemployment does not affect the labour flows in this study of inter-industry mobility.

251

Table 9.4 Gross and Net Labour Flows based on Sample of 10,691 Observations New

Industry

Old

Industry

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9

Interim Unemployment between period t-1 and period t

1 6 0 3 0 1 3 1 0 1

2 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0

3 0 0 170 0 9 14 4 15 4

4 0 0 1 2 1 0 1 0 0

5 0 0 7 0 85 3 5 5 2

6 0 0 16 1 7 147 17 15 6

7 0 0 2 0 0 4 31 4 1

8 0 0 11 0 3 12 2 82 7

9 0 0 5 0 4 9 2 10 85

Number of persons with uninterrupted employment

Gross

Outflows

Net

Flows

1 407 0 36 1 27 38 11 30 13 156 74

2 4 5 2 0 7 4 0 0 1 18 13

3 15 0 1889 4 67 251 49 111 95 592 179

4 1 0 1 25 1 3 2 4 0 12 -5

5 15 1 54 3 672 61 16 64 22 236 -8

6 26 0 164 0 71 1744 43 121 112 537 -25

7 5 1 31 0 22 36 588 28 22 145 -30

8 7 3 78 8 34 85 35 1167 70 320 -97

9 9 0 47 1 15 84 19 59 1118 234 -101

Gross Inflows 82 5 413 17 244 562 175 417 335

Annotation for Industry: See Table 9.1.

9.3 GENERIC MODEL OF SECTORAL/INDUSTRIAL MOBILITY

The generic model of sectoral labour mobility adopted for the study of individuals‟ choice

between two sectors given in the index function of equation (6.7) is restated here:

Ii = γ1 + γ2 [ ln pi + ln yai – ln ybi] + γ3 gai + γ4 gbi - Ziδ - Siφ.

The actual and expected incomes, measured over the individuals‟ lifetimes, represented in

the model are as described earlier. Zi is an all encompassing vector of economic,

demographic and socio-economic factors, Si represents the stochastic shock term, δ is a

vector of coefficients for Zi and θ is the coefficient for Si. This generic model enables us to

test three theories of sectoral mobility: the worker-employer mismatch, sectoral shock and

bridging theories of sectoral mobility that were outlined in chapter 6.

The index, Ii, is a latent variable for the propensity of workers to move across industries. It

is not observed. Rather, what is observed is a binary indicator of whether workers moved

252

(I*i). It takes the value 0 when individual i did not switch sectors/industries, and the value 1

if individual i did switch sectors/industries, between period t-1 and period t. It can be

linked to the latent index Ii as follows: I*i = 1 if Ii ≥ 0 ; I

*i = 0 otherwise.

The dataset classifies the sectors/industries according to the Korean Standard Classification

of Industries. The sectors/industries are categorized into nine major groups: agriculture;

mining; manufacturing; utilities; construction; commerce; transport, storage &

communications; financial, real estate & business services; and community, social &

personal services. Hence, I*i is assigned the value 1 if the respondent switched between

these industry groups.

As mentioned in the literature review, the standard OLS method of estimation is not

recommended. This is because the dependent variable is binary and hence it is not normally

distributed and the distribution of the residual term will be heteroscedastic. This violates

one of the assumptions of OLS regression, and so statistical inference would not be valid.

Therefore, a logit model is used, with the estimates being obtained using the method of

maximum likelihood, similar to Osberg (1991). The logit regression does not require the

dependent variable to be normally distributed. However, it does retain some of the other

requirements of OLS regression: error terms must be independent and the relationship

between the logit of the dependent variable and the explanatory variables must be linear in

coefficients.

9.4 DESCRIPTIVE STATISTICS

This section presents the descriptive statistics of the variables to be included in the current

study. Given the selection criteria described above and the complexity of the KLIPS

survey design, the section first explores the possibility of incorporating survey weights in

the KLIPS sample. This is in line with the theoretical recommendations outlined in several

studies, that survey weighting achieves greater precision in the sample statistics [Kish

(1965), Kish and Frankel (1974), Scott and Watson (1982) and Watson and Fry (2002)].

This also permits an assessment of whether the usage of a longitudinal dataset for Korea

can be aligned with that of the longitudinal datasets of advanced countries which adopt

253

survey weighting [Thompson, Fong, Hammond, Boudreau, Driezen, Hyland, Borland,

Cummings, Hastings, Siahpush, Mackintosh and Laux (2006) for an inter-country tobacco

study, and Watson (2004) and Watson and Fry (2002) for Australia].

9.4.1 Survey Weights

The KLIPS dataset does not have survey weights that accommodate aspects of the survey

design, sample attrition or new entrants. A review of recent studies covering a wealth of

topics using the KLIPS longitudinal data have shown that none have attempted to develop

survey weights to address the issue. These include Nam (2007) on asset distribution, Kim

(2004a) on family background and education, Cho (2005) on household wealth, Sawangfa

(2007) on job satisfaction, Kim (2003) on IT job training, Young (2005) on ageing, Kang

(2004) and Kim (2004b) on university prestige and choice of study, Young (2006) on social

class and gender differentials, Chang and Yang (2007) on non-standard employment, Seong

(2007) on union participation, Son (2007a) and Son (2007b) on job training for women, and

Jung, Moon and Hahm (2007) on age, gender, sector and job satisfaction.

As the weighting of the survey data may affect the precision and/or interpretation of the

regression results, it is the intent of this section to determine whether this might be an issue.

An approach that can be taken in this regard that is within the scope of this thesis is to

construct a series of variable weights, and then compare the descriptive statistics using

these weights with those obtained from non-weighted data.

In terms of constructing survey weights from the current KLIPS dataset, the aims are

twofold: (i) to adjust the basic characteristics of the sample so that they align with the

national benchmark at the time of the wave 1 data collection, and (ii) to account for sample

attrition and cater for new entrants at the subsequent waves 2, 3 and 4. Thereafter, the set

of weighted descriptive statistics will be compared with the non-weighted set to determine

if the weighting process renders a substantive difference to the statistics.

254

9.4.1.1 Wave 1 Weights and the Population

Although the original KLIPS survey consist of 5,000 households, from which individuals

of 20-64 years of age amount to 29,474 person-year observations, this includes individuals

with incomplete information. The final sample for the regression analysis consists of the

10,691 observations with complete information on the variables used in the statistical

analyses. This sample of 10,691 as at wave 1 is treated as the population for the purpose

of developing the survey weights below.

The purpose of the wave 1 weights is to align the sample labour force profile as at wave 1

to that of the national labour force profile. This national benchmark is obtained from

Korean NSO employment data for 1998. Three stratification variables are used when

constructing the weights, namely sex, education status and employment status. The year

1998 is used to coincide with the time the data for wave 1 were gathered.

In the weighting process, individuals‟ basic characteristics (as at wave 1) and initial

industry were assigned an expansion factor, which is the ratio of the national composition

of the labour force to that of the wave 1 sample for the respective variable in question. The

variable is then multiplied by the weighting factor, i.e. X x weighting factor, where X is the

dummy variable (equals 1) for the characteristic in question. Table 9.5 below presents the

weights for the basic characteristics. For example, in the case of females, the weighting

factor is 1.27 (i.e. 0.400/0.315) where the numerator is the 1998 national proportion of

employed females and the denominator is the sample proportion of females as at wave 1.

The individual value for each female is 1 x 1.27.

Table 9.5 Wave 1 Weights Variable Weighting Factor

Sex

- Male

0.88

- Female 1.27

Education Status

- Graduate

1.35

- Non-graduate 0.95

Employment Status

- Employee

0.78

- Employer 1.81 Source: Author‟s calculations from KLIPS dataset and Korean NSO data.

255

In addition to the wave 1 weights, the variables sex, employment status and education

status are also weighted by the probabilities of survival and for being a new entrant as

described below. The methodology for deriving the weighted means and standard

deviations of these socio-demographic variables is found in Appendix 9C.

9.4.1.2 Weights for Sample Attrition

Sample attrition occurs in the KLIPS, though non-response, respondents moving out of the

original household or become out of scope (e.g. missing survey information as described in

the previous section). The surviving pool in the subsequent wave is therefore the cohort of

individuals from the previous wave which did not become out of scope and continued to

exist in the original household. The probabilities of survival in the KLIPS sample were

0.44, 0.35 and 0.38 for waves 2, 3 and 4, respectively6. Weights for each wave were

increased by their wave 1 weight modified by a factor inverse to their probability of

survival in that wave, i.e. P(survivalw).

It is noted that the probabilities of survival are below the norm. This is owing to the

selection criteria and method of data processing adopted. As mentioned, selection involved

the inclusion of individuals 20-64 years, those who took part in consecutive waves in the

original KLIPS survey and those with non-negative incomes and those with complete/valid

survey information for the regression analysis. The processing of the KLIPS dataset,

especially with the data completeness checks, was done irrespective of waves so as to

include more individuals in the sample for the regression analysis. This resulted in a lower

survival rate when examined on a wave-by-wave basis.

9.4.1.3 Weights for New Entrants

To counter-balance the low probabilities of survival, weights are included to account for

new entrants to the KLIPS sample in waves 2, 3 and 4. New entrants exist in the KLIPS

sample because they are either new joiners to the KLIPS survey, e.g. new members to the

household or re-entrants from previous waves. The probability of being a new entrant for

each wave is the proportion of new entrants to the total number of individuals for each

wave. For waves 2, 3 and 4, the probabilities are 0.57, 0.65 and 0.62, respectively. Weights

256

for each wave are modified to a factor inverse to the probability of being a new entrant in

that wave, i.e. P(new entrantw).

For both survivors and new entrants, the weights are computed differently depending on

whether the variable is categorical or continuous. The continuous variables comprise age,

tenure, GDP growth, sectoral shock, the sectoral wage differential as well as the old and

new sector wages, unemployment, wage growth, size and performance. The categorical

variables in the KLIPS are industry mover status, sex, marital status, education status,

employment status, occupational status, head of household status and the initial industry.

Together, the weights of survivors and new entrants are incorporated into the computation

of the descriptive statistics. Given that the KLIPS is a complex sample, the weighted

means and standard deviations are appropriately termed as „complex statistics‟. The

complex statistics are computed differently depending on whether the variable is

continuous or categorical. Appendix 9C lists the methodology for deriving the complex

statistics for both types, taking into account the probabilities of survival and of being a new

entrant.

9.4.2 Descriptive Statistics: Complex Statistics

Table 9.6 presents the descriptive statistics for the weighted and non-weighted series from

the KLIPS sample of 10,691 observations covering the four job waves (1998 till 2001).

The list of explanatory variables is in Appendix 9A. From Table 9.6, the means for the

non-weighted and weighted series are fairly similar for all variables, except for mover

status, which is smaller under the weighted series, pointing towards the lower share of

industry movers in subsequent job waves. The lower share of movers in the latter years

reflects the state of labour market adjustment. Workers are more likely to switch sectors

arising from retrenchments or business closure during the immediate year of the Crisis (i.e.

wave 1) as compared to the latter years.

A smaller standard deviation is noted for most variables, reflecting the greater precision in

estimation under the weighted series. This is to be expected as the variance from a complex

sample (e.g. clustered or stratified) is usually smaller than that under simple random

sampling [Jolliffe (2002/2003)]. This can be summarized using the design effect (deff),

257

which gives the net effect of various complexities of the sample as compared to simple

random sampling. It is „the ratio of the actual variance of a sample to the variance of a

simple random sample of the same number of elements‟ [Kish and Frankel (1973)], and can

be computed as:

deff = Varianceweighted / Variancenon-weighted .

Since the standard deviation rather than the variance is usually used for statistical inference

in regression models, the design effect is often computed in square-root terms, i.e.

____ __________________________

√ deff = √ Varianceweighted / Variancenon-weighted .

From Table 9.6, the design effect is slightly less than 1 for most variables, reflecting the

lower standard deviation under complex sampling. As the design effect is close to 1, this

means that the sample variance under the weighted series only deviates marginally from

that under the non-weighted series. The means of the variables under the two methods of

computation in Table 9.6 are also similar. Thus, the weighting process does not contribute

to a significant difference in the descriptive statistics of the explanatory variables listed.

Hence, the descriptive statistics in this section refer to the non-weighted set.

The majority of workers are industry stayers, which is not surprising as several authors

have highlighted the constraints confronting workers considering change to their industry

of employment. Nonetheless, the share of inter-industry movers is large enough (23%) to

facilitate the study of sectoral mobility, and is quite similar to the mobility rates reported in

Jovanovic and Moffitt (1990) [13%-26%], Osberg (1991) [14%], Osberg, Gordon and Lin

(1994) [13%] and Osberg, Mazany, Apostle and Clairmont (1986) [20%-36%].

258

Table 9.6 Means and Standard Deviations for Korean Workers, Aged 20-64 years

Mean

(or Percent)

Standard

Deviation

Mean (or

Percent)

Standard

Deviation

___

√deff

Non-weighted series Weighted series

Monetary variables

Ln (Expected New Industry Wage) 4.59 0.67 4.61 0.66 0.985

Ln (Original Industry Wage) 4.34 1.03 4.47 0.84 0.816

Growth Rate of New Industry Wage (%) 4.29 6.45 6.48 4.08 0.633

Growth Rate of Original Industry Wage (%) 4.22 6.56 6.46 4.09 0.623

Macroeconomic variables

Unemployment Rate in New Industry in Period t-1 (%) 3.84 2.81 4.60 2.38 0.847

Unemployment Rate in Original Industry in Period t-1 (%) 3.82 2.78 4.57 2.36 0.849

Worker characteristics

Industry Mover (%) 23.1 42.14 16.0 33.36 0.792

Male (%) 64.6 47.82 64.3 47.53 0.994

Age at Former Interview (yrs) 39.7 10.66 40.0 10.39 0.975

Original Job Tenure (yrs) 7.12 8.22 7.42 7.39 0.899

Married Person (%) 73.4 44.18 73.6 43.70 0.989

Household Head (%) 52.9 49.92 55.5 47.91 0.960

Educational Attainment: Graduate (%) 14.6 35.29 16.0 36.35 1.030

Professional/Associate Professional (%) 7.5 26.33 8.1 27.18 1.032

Employee (%) 79.8 40.17 80.3 34.44 0.857

Initial Industry (%)

Agriculture 5.4 22.62 4.5 20.40 0.902

Mining 0.2 4.63 0.2 2.94 0.6351

Manufacturing 25.2 43.43 24.7 43.10 0.993

Utilities 0.4 6.26 0.4 6.28 0.995

Construction 9.5 29.32 9.4 29.11 0.993

Commerce 23.3 42.27 23.2 42.19 0.998

Transport, Storage & Communications 7.2 25.93 7.6 26.44 1.020

Financial, Real Estate & Business Services 15.0 35.71 16.3 36.76 1.029

Community, Social & Personal Services 13.7 34.41 13.7 34.45 1.001

Industry characteristics

Original Industry Size (no.) 3,556 1,573 3,555 1,578 1.003

New Industry Size (no.) 3,533 1,585 3,543 1,579 0.996

Original Industry Growth Rate (%) 5.36 8.33 7.76 5.93 0.7122

New Industry Growth Rate (%) 5.33 8.33 7.73 5.95 0.7142

GDP Growth Rate (%) 4.42 4.15 6.37 0.00

Sectoral Shock

Residual of AR(1) Regression (micro-level) 3.45 100.93 5.02 56.17 0.5573

Residual of AR(1) Regression (by wave) 0.37 0.1335 0.02 0.01 0.0754

Cross-sector Standard Error of Residual

of AR(1) Regression 0.18 0.0954 0.17 0.08 0.839

Sample Size 10,691 10,691

Source: KLIPS dataset, KLI. Note: Since the annual GDP growth rate does not vary within each wave, the weighted standard deviation is zero. Hence, its design

effect cannot be computed. See Appendix 9C.

1. The lower standard deviation (weighted series) is due to fewer individuals in mining. The standard deviation is zero for waves 2 and 3 for new entrants and wave 4 for new entrants/survivors. Hence, the design effect is relatively low.

2. The lower design effect reflects the lower standard deviation (weighted series) for old/new industry growth for new entrants in waves

3 and 4. Since these variables vary by wave only, the standard deviation for each wave merely reflects distributional differences amongst new entrants and survivors.

3. The standard deviations on a by-wave basis are generally less than 100 except for wave 3 for survivors. This accounts for the lower

overall weighted standard deviation of 56. Hence, the design effect is lower. 4. Since the residual is derived from a regression for each wave, the residual on a by-wave basis is negligible. Any deviation within each

wave reflects distributional differences between survivors and new entrants and is negligible. Thus, the descriptive statistics between

the weighted and non-weighted sets differ and the design effect is small.

259

In terms of worker and job characteristics, there are proportionately more males (65%) than

females (35%) in the Korean sample. There are proportionately more married persons

(73%), employees (80%) and household heads (53%) in the sample than the respective

complementary categories (the non-married, non-employees and non-household heads).

There are relatively fewer graduates (15%) and professionals (8%). The typical worker is

40 years of age and has accumulated 7 years of work experience in his original/current job.

The initial industries for most individuals are concentrated in the manufacturing sector

(25%), commerce sector (23%) and financial, real estate and business services industries

(15%).

The monetary indicators favour the new sector/industry. Thus, the new industry‟s expected

wages (in natural logarithms) exceed the old industry‟s actual wages, and the annual

average growth rates in income of the workers‟ new industries are marginally higher than

the rates in their old industries.

On average, the GDP growth rates and employment sizes of workers‟ new industries were

lower than those of their original industries. The lower growth suggests that the influence

of the sector‟s past performance on a sectoral move may not be compelling. The average

lagged annual unemployment rate was slightly higher for new industries. That is, at the

aggregate level, movement to a new sector will involve a trade off of higher unemployment

for higher wages.

It is observed that the comparison of old versus new sector monetary and sector-level

variables remains unchanged under the weighted and non-weighted series. The average

GDP growth rate of the industries of employment reported by Korean workers in the

sample was 4%.

The typical worker experienced a sectoral shock whilst working in their original industry

during 1998-2001. This is revealed by the positive mean values from the alternative

measures of a sectoral shock. There are two approaches to estimating the AR(1) residual

designed to capture the unanticipated effects on sector-specific employment between two

time periods. The first, the residual of an AR(1) regression7 (micro-level), is computed by

regressing the individual industry‟s employment in period t on that of period t-1, and

260

taking the difference between the fitted and estimated values of industry employment for

each individual record. The second AR(1) residual (by wave) was estimated in a similar

fashion to that of Jovanovic and Moffitt (1990). The natural logarithm of the industry‟s

employment AR(1) regression was estimated for each year (i.e. four years) and the

corresponding four standard errors from these regressions were then inserted into the

dataset for each record8. All individual records within the same wave (or year) would have

the same value. It is not surprising that the standard deviation was significantly smaller

than for the first AR(1) measure.

The shock measures are estimated across all sectors/industries of the economy and

comparison data need to be constructed in a similar way9. The positive mean value of the

AR(1) residual (by wave) is comparable in size with Jovanovic and Moffitt‟s (1990) shock

measures, which ranged from 0.006 to 0.031 during 1968-1980 in the U.S.

The third measure of sectoral shock is given by the cross-sector standard error of the

residual of an AR(1) regression of the natural logarithm of industry employment. This

estimates the unobservable effects on sectoral employment independent of the effects on

aggregate employment. For each observation, it is computed as:

[eit/Et x (res(ln eit) – res(ln Et))]1/2

,

where eit is the industry‟s employment, Et is aggregate employment, res(ln eit) is the

residual of an AR(1) regression of industry employment and res(ln Et) is the residual of an

AR(1) regression of aggregate employment.

Table 9.6 shows that the mean value of the cross-sectoral standard error of this AR(1)

residual was 0.18, and this is much smaller than the AR(1) residual (micro-level) measure.

This is due to the fact that it removes the unanticipated effects of a shock on overall

employment, and as such it allows the effect on a specific sector to be examined in

isolation. Therefore, it might be reasonable to expect that this might be the most

appropriate measure for the empirical study.

These descriptive statistics give a preliminary indication of some worker/job and monetary

variables that might be influential in the mobility decision. The patterns between old and

261

new sectors in many of these variables are consistent with expectations. However, in the

case of sectoral growth rates, the new sector‟s rate is lower than the old sector‟s, and for

unemployment rates, the new sector‟s rate is higher. A further examination of these

variables is required. The extent to which patterns more consistent with economic theory

emerge from the study of individual-level data will be examined in the later part of this

chapter.

9.5 DERIVATION OF PREDICTED/RECOMPUTED VARIABLES

As the examination of sectoral mobility involves industry movers and stayers, and the study

focuses on the motivation behind a movement from the old sector to the new, there must be

some observable differences in the explanatory variables for movers and stayers. This

leads to problems for the researcher in the case of stayers, for whom there is no designated

new industry, especially for variables that make use of aggregate-level industry data, and

for the monetary variable which involves computation of the new sector‟s wage, i.e. the

sectoral wage differential. The purpose of this section is to compute suitable values for

these variables for industry stayers.

Sector-level Variables

The potential new sector-level values for industry stayers are not observed for the wage

growth, lagged unemployment rate, sectoral size and sectoral performance variables. If the

current sector values are assigned to the new sector variables, there is a high correlation

between the old-new variables: ga versus gb (0.889), Ua,t-1 versus Ub,t-1 (0.875), sizea versus

sizeb (0.728) and GDPa versus GDPb (0.793). These correlation coefficients are less than

one only because the old and new industries for movers differ.

To overcome this problem, the sector-level variables for movers are constructed using the

average across all industries other than the stayer‟s original industry value as the new

industry values. These re-computed new sector values should not exhibit high correlations

with the values for the old sectors. The remaining explanatory variables, namely the

262

individual characteristics and GDP growth, are not affected as they remain unchanged for

each individual in the sample datasets.

The list of the data items following these changes and their corresponding annotation are

supplied in Appendix 9B.

Sectoral Wage Differential

The issue of determining an appropriate „new sector‟ value also arises for the sectoral wage

differential for stayers, as their old sector wage, but not their potential new sector wage, is

observed. A related issue is that the actual wage data available at the micro-level contain

both an observed predictable element and an unobserved stochastic component. This could

lead to biased estimates if the stochastic component is related to the error term in the

mobility equation.

The possibility of biased estimates with the use of actual wage data can be accommodated

through the use of predicted wages. The variable in question is the expected sectoral wage

differential. For this, the individual‟s new and old sectors‟ wages, and the new sector‟s

unemployment rate, need to be derived to arrive at the wage differential term. For

reference purposes, these derived data items will be termed the „predicted new sector‟s

wage‟, „predicted old sector‟s wage‟, „predicted new sector‟s unemployment rate‟ and

„predicted expected sectoral wage differential‟.

9.5.1 Predicted Sectoral Wages

The computation of the predicted old/new sector‟s wages adopts the methodology of Tomes

and Robinson (1982a) in their estimation of the determination of wages for two different

regions in the context of Canadian interprovincial migration. The methodology of Tomes

and Robinson (1982a) is an example of what Borjas (1980) refers to as using a „clean‟

proxy for a wage variable that has econometric problems associated with it. Offered wages

are usually held to be dependent on personal attributes, and so the wage functions for sector

a (ln yai) and sector b (ln ybi) for an individual i can be constructed as:

263

ln yai = Xiβa + uai (9.1)

ln ybi = Xiβb + ubi (9.2)

where Xi is the set of observable personal characteristics (sex, age, marital status,

educational attainment, head of household status, occupational status, employer status and

job tenure)10

, βa and βb are the vectors of parameters associated with each sector to be

estimated for the corresponding explanatory variables, and uai and ubi are the unobservable

components representing the general ability and other factors applicable to sectors a and b,

respectively, but which are not captured under Xi. The dependent variables, ln yai, and

ln ybi, are the individual‟s actual wages (expressed in natural logarithms) in the new sector

and old sector, respectively.

Since industry movers and stayers each experience different levels of utility from changing

sectors or remaining immobile, the sample is self-selected into mover and stayer sub-

samples, and the estimation of the individual wage equations (9.1) and (9.2) is based on

these truncated samples. Predicted wages are then obtained from the industry-specific

wage regressions for movers and stayers. It is noted that these equations are not corrected

for sample selection bias, as undertaken by Tomes and Robinson (1982a), as there is a lack

of variables in the dataset that can be used as legitimate identifying variables in the

selection equation. Furthermore, there have been recent dissatisfaction with the selection

bias methodology where the correction might reduce the accuracy of coefficient estimates

[Puhani (2000) and Stolzenberg and Relles (1997)].

As several studies have revealed inter-industry wages to vary [Carrington and Zaman

(1994), Dickens and Katz (1987), Gibbons and Katz (1992), Helwege (1992), Keane (1993)

and Krueger and Summers (1987)], and some industries may value particular employee

attributes more highly than others, an industry-specific approach to the estimation of the

wage regressions of equations (9.1) and (9.2) is recommended11

.

Predicted Wage for Movers

As in the case of Tomes and Robinson (1982a), wage regressions are undertaken for each

mover and stayer sub-sample. For movers, the term ln ybi is the actual wage reported by

264

individual i in period t-1 in the old industry and ln yai is the corresponding wage reported in

period t in the new industry. Specifically, as mobility in the KLIPS sample is measured

annually, new (old) sector earnings are based on data reported in the first (previous) year of

each survey wave, i.e. 1998 (1997) for wave 1, 1999 (1998) for wave 2 and 2000 (1999)

and 2001 (2000) for waves 3 and 4, respectively.

To obtain the predicted wages for movers in the new (old) industry, ln yai (ln ybi) is

regressed on the Xi‟s for each industry. The fitted values, ln yap

(ln ybp), constitute the

predicted wages for movers in the new (old) industry. Each mover will have a different

predicted wage for the old/new sector computed for incorporation into the mobility

equation. In this regard, the KLIPS dataset is superior to the Tomes and Robinson (1982a)

data, as wages for movers are estimated before and after a sectoral switch. Therefore, the

predicted wages for movers would be:

ˆ ln ya = Xβa from the new industry; and ˆ ln yb= Xβb from the old industry.

It is noted that incomes in the four years of the survey need not be adjusted to the real

(1998) values using the CPI. Since the final model is about the sectoral wage differential,

the real and actual wage differentials are the same as both old/new sector wages are

adjusted by the same deflator12

. This is in line with empirical studies of sectoral mobility

adopting a sectoral wage differential [Osberg, Gordon and Lin (1994)] or old/new sector

wages [Vanderkamp (1977) and Fallick (1993)] which do not make use of a wage deflator.

In addition, recent studies using the KLIPS wage data (though not about sectoral mobility)

have not adopted real wages in their analyses, including Son (2007a), Son (2007b), Kim

(2003), Kang, Park and Lee (2007) and Kang (2004).

Predicted Wage for Stayers

For stayers, the predicted wages in the old industry are obtained from an industry-specific

regression of ln ybi on Xi. The reported old sector wages are based on the previous year,

namely 1997 for wave 1, 1998 for wave 2, 1999 for wave 3 and 2000 for wave 4. Each

stayer will have a different predicted wage for the old sector.

265

As mentioned earlier, the estimation of predicted wages in the new industry for stayers will

pose a problem since their old and new industries are the same. The dataset gives the actual

wage of period t, and not the potential wage that could be achieved in an alternative

industry. To overcome this limitation, the procedure adopted by Tomes and Robinson

(1982a) is used. They treated the new destination as a single alternative comprising all

destinations other than that in which the individual (stayer) was observed in period t. For

example, for an industry stayer working in the commerce sector, the new sector‟s wage is

the average wage across all sectors other than the commerce sector.

To obtain „ln yai‟ for a typical stayer, the aggregated earnings for stayers reported across all

industries other than the original industry is divided by the number of stayers in all

industries other than the original industry, which is then expressed in natural logarithmic

terms. These averages are argued to provide a general idea of what could be earned

following a sectoral move. Earnings (i.e. ya) are based on data observed in the first year

each survey wave was conducted, i.e. 1998 for wave 1, 1999 for wave 2 and 2000 and 2001

for waves 3 and 4, respectively. Stayers from the various „original‟ industries will have

differing ln yai‟s, but those from the same „original‟ industries (for the same survey wave)

will have similar ln yai‟s.

It should be noted that many observations would have the same value for ln yai for the

obvious reason that earnings in the new sector (ya) are not realized or observed by industry

stayers. The variability within each stayer sub-sample needed for the industry-specific

regression to be feasible arises because stayers from different survey waves will have

dissimilar ln yai‟s.

Having derived stayers‟ new sector wages, industry-specific regressions of ln yai on Xi were

then estimated and used to generate a predicted „new‟ sector wage. The corresponding

fitted values, ln yap, constitute the predicted potential wages for stayers in the new industry.

Since the regression is undertaken on Xi which contains a set of characteristics unique to

each individual, each ln yap value would be unique. Therefore, in the case of stayers, the

predicted wages would be:

266

n-1 ˆ ln ya = ∑ Xβj / n-1, which is the average of predictions for the n-1 industries; and j=1 ˆ ln yb= Xβb for the original industry.

The Tomes and Robinson (1982a) method is preferred over that used by Osberg, Gordon

and Lin (1994) for the current study. The former method reflects the sectoral wage

differential in that there is an old sector wage and a potential new sector wage for each

individual. This treatment is consistent with the fact that mobility decisions are made in the

ex ante period. The latter method, where predicted wages were obtained from regressions

as per equations (9.1) and (9.2) for each mover/stayer subsample using individuals‟ actual

reported incomes, merely reflects the prevailing wage differential between movers and

stayers. That is, the new sector wage for stayers is based on the regression estimates for all

movers rather than being the average wage for all industries other than the stayer‟s original

industry.

At this stage, it should be noted that the modelling of the sectoral wages as per equations

(9.1) and (9.2) for inclusion in the mobility equation requires some identifying

restriction(s). This issue of variable identification was also raised in Tomes and Robinson

(1982a). Sectoral mobility, as per the main model in Table 9.10, is found to be independent

of marital status and occupational status. Although these two variables were placed into the

mobility equations, marital status was insignificant in all three regressions of the

unrestricted model and occupational status was insignificant in regression 3 (refer to section

9.6 below) as well as in the main model in Table 9.10. Thus, marital status and

occupational status influence sectoral mobility only via sectoral wages.

In addition, another form of identification arises from aggregation. Rewrite the predicted

wages for movers as:

ˆ ln ya

p = Xβa from the new industry; and

ˆ ln yb

p = Xβb from the old industry;

and for stayers as:

267

n-1 ˆ ln ya

p = ∑ Xβj / n-1; and

j=1 ˆ ln yb

p = Xβb for the original industry.

It can be seen that it is this averaging process, in addition to variable identification, which

gives rise to the low correlations between the predicted variables and the other variables

included in the mobility equation.

Predicted New Sector’s Unemployment Rate

The new sector‟s unemployment rate (Uat) can be derived in the same manner as outlined

above for wages via the industry-specific regression of Uat on the individual characteristics

for inter-industry movers. This gives the predicted unemployment rate (Uatp) for movers.

For stayers, the new industry is once again treated as all industries outside the original

industry and the corresponding Uat is the average rate across all industries other than the

stayer‟s original industry. For example, for stayers from commerce, Uat for the new

industry (non-commerce) is computed as:

[UNEMPnon-commerce / (UNEMPnon-commerce + EMPnon-commerce)] x 100,

where UNEMPnon-commerce and EMPnon-commerce are the levels of unemployment and

employment, respectively in all sectors outside commerce. It is noted that the employment

and unemployment data are obtained from the Korean NSO. Published data are used since

these can be considered to be the information available in the marketplace that rational

income-maximizing individuals will make use of to assess their potential mobility

outcomes. The regression of Uat on individual characteristics is undertaken to derive the

predicted rate (Uatp) for stayers.

Each mover/stayer will have a different predicted rate. For movers, the predicted

unemployment rate would be:

ˆ Uat

p = Xβa for the new industry; and

ˆ Ubt

p = Xβb for the original industry.

268

Uatp and Ubt

p for movers are derived via industry-specific regressions using the mover sub-

sample covering four waves of data in the KLIPS.

For stayers, the predicted unemployment rates are:

n-1 ˆ Uat

p = ∑ Xβj / n-1; which is the average of predictions for the n-1 industries; and

j=1 ˆ Ubt

p = Xβb for the industry of origin.

It is noted that the predicted unemployment rates are estimated from industry-specific

regressions using the stayer sub-sample covering four waves of data.

This approach to modelling unemployment rates for inclusion in the mobility equation

embodies the same form of variable identification as was used for wages in that marital

status and occupational status affect inter-sectoral mobility only via the sectoral

unemployment rates. The averaging process of Uat for stayers, another form of

identification, implies that perfect collinearity between the predicted variables and the other

determinants of mobility would never arise.

Predicted Expected Sectoral Wage Differential

With the predicted variables, Uatp, ln yai

p and ln ybi

p, the predicted expected sectoral wage

differential can be computed for each individual as:

ln(pya)p

- lnybp = ln [(1- Uat

p) x yai

p] - ln (ybi

p).

Actual versus Predicted Wage Differential

A comparison between actual (as per the original dataset in Table 9.6) and predicted wages

is undertaken to ensure that the algorithms used to derive the predicted variables have not

altered the basic patterns in the data. The key variable for comparison is the expected

sectoral wage differential. The mean values for the actual and predicted variables are

presented in Table 9.7. It is clear that the use of predicted variables in the empirical work

should not introduce any major distortions, as the mean values of the actual and predicted

variables are fairly similar in magnitude. Thus, the mean values of the actual and predicted

269

expected sectoral wage differential are both higher for movers than for stayers, conforming

to the theory that income-maximising individuals will switch sectors for the monetary

benefit. Moreover, it is observed that the predicted variables have lower standard errors

than the actual variables, attributed in large part to the fact that the stochastic elements

associated with actual wages have been removed.

Table 9.7 Actual versus Predicted Monetary Variables Actual Predicted

Movers

Mean

Standard

Deviation

Mean

Standard

Deviation

Expected New Sector Wages 4.43 0.66 4.37 0.28

Old Sector Wages 3.90 1.33 3.91 0.64

Unemployment Rate 5.43 3.44 5.43 3.06

Expected Sectoral Wage

Differential

0.52 1.35 0.45 0.60

Stayers

Expected New Sector Wages 4.63 0.66 4.81 0.04

Old Sector Wages 4.47 0.88 4.47 0.33

Unemployment Rate 3.88 2.71 3.88 1.84

Expected Sectoral Wage

Differential

0.16 0.76 0.34 0.34

Source: KLIPS dataset

Note: For ease of comparison between actual and predicted variables, the non-

weighted series is presented.

9.5.2 Sector-level Variables

Sectoral Unemployment, Size and Performance

Given the high correlation between the old-new sector-level variables mentioned earlier,

that arises primarily because stayers‟ old and new industries are the same, a rework of the

„new‟ sector variables (the lagged unemployment rate, sectoral size and performance, and

sectoral wage growth) for stayers is in order. Following Tomes and Robinson‟s (1982a)

treatment of the new destination as a single aggregated alternative, the new industry for the

stayers‟ sector-level variables will be all industries other than the original industry. The

sector-level data are obtained from the Korean NSO. As mentioned above, these can be

treated as the data available in the marketplace that income-maximizing agents make use of

in their mobility decisions13

.

270

The new sector‟s size is the average size of all industries other than the stayer‟s original

industry. The new sector‟s GDP growth and lagged unemployment rate are computed

using aggregates for all industries other than the stayer‟s original industry. For instance,

the growth in GDP at current prices across all industries other than agriculture in

period t (GDPnon-agriculture,t) over GDP in period t-1, (GDPnon-agriculture,t-1), is computed as:

[(GDPnon-agriculture,t - GDPnon-agriculture,t-1)/GDPnon-agriculture,t-1] x 100.

The average unemployment rate across all industries other than agriculture is computed as:

[UNEMPnon-agriculture /(UNEMPnon-agriculture + EMPnon-agriculture)] x 100,

where UNEMPnon-agriculture and EMPnon-agriculture each represent the unemployment level and

employment level in all industries other than agriculture. The pair-wise correlations

between these recomputed variables (marked with an asterisk) are substantially lower than

those initially presented: U*a,t-1 versus Ub,t-1 (0.460), size*a versus sizeb (-0.227) and GDP*a

versus GDPb (0.380).

New Sector’s Wage Growth

The descriptive statistics for the annual sectoral wage growth are given in the first two

columns of Table 9.6. Given that the data cover the Asian Financial Crisis period, it is

observed that all industries experienced negative wage growth in 1998. As the wage

growth variable is supposed to represent lifetime earnings, an individual would probably

look at „the industry average‟ rather than a year-on-year measure so that his/her decision

would be more fully informed.

Based on this principle, the wage growth variables were computed using information on the

previous five years. A 5-year period is chosen as it appears to be long enough to average

out the fluctuations observed in the data. Thus, for wave 1, the old/new industry wage

growth rate is computed based on the average annual compound growth rate (ACGR) over

the 1994-1998 period; for wave 2 over the 1995-1999 period; for wave 3 covering 1996-

2000; and for wave 4 extending from 1997 to 2001. For example, for T number of periods

(i.e. 5 in this study), the ACGR for the 1998 wages (y1998

) over the 1994 wages (y1994

) is

computed as follows:

271

ACGR = [(y1998

/ y1994

)1/(T-1)

- 1 ] x 100.

With regards to the new sector, the decision would be whether to move using information

about the new sector‟s future earnings. For each mover, the wage growth is based on the 5-

year average annual compound growth rate in the mover‟s new industry. In line with the

method used for the wage data, fitted values (g*p

at) from a regression of the new sector‟s

wage growth on individual characteristics (sex, age, marital/occupational/employment

status, educational attainment and tenure) are used. This method is similar to Willis and

Rosen (1979), where the wage growth functions for college and non-college attendees were

regressed on individual characteristics. The wage growth regressions are not corrected for

selection bias for the reasons mentioned above. The wage growth effects in the modelling

of worker mobility are identified through marital status and occupational status influencing

mobility only via the wage growth rates. This type of identification is again coupled with

that achieved through the averaging of the predictions for the larger stayers component of

the sample, as discussed in the next paragraph.

In the case of stayers, as their old and new sectors are the same in periods t-1 and t, the

Tomes and Robinson‟s (1982a) treatment of the new sector as an aggregated alternative is

employed. The new sector income is computed as the earnings for all industries other than

the stayer‟s original industry. Stayers for each different year (1998 till 2001) from each

„original‟ industry will have differing earnings. Thereafter, the 5-year average annual

compound growth is applied. For wave 1, the new industry wage growth rate is computed

over 1994-1998, wave 2, over 1995-1999, wave 3 over 1996-2000, and wave 4 over 1997-

2001. Predicted values, obtained from industry-specific regressions of average wage growth

on stayer‟s individual characteristics, are used in the model. In addition to variable

identification, the averaging process of the new wage growth rates for stayers suggests that

the problem of perfect collinearity in the mobility equation that includes the predicted wage

growth variable would be avoided.

Old Sector’s Wage Growth

The lifetime earnings potential in a mover‟s original industry is proxied by using the

average annual wage growth of that old industry over the last five years. Again, fitted

272

values (g*p

bt), from the regression of the old sector‟s wage growth on individual

characteristics, are used in the estimations.

In the case of stayers, since their old and new industries are the same, their annual wage

growth, derived from their reported earnings in period t-1 and period t, is indicative of the

old sector‟s wage growth. It is noted that the use of individual data is in tandem with Willis

and Rosen‟s (1979) estimation of lifetime earnings (conditioned on actual school choices in

the U.S.), which made use of each individual‟s reported initial and latest earnings to

compute a wage growth variable. However, there are anomalies associated with the use of

individual data in the present application, and these will be addressed below.

The average wage growth was an astounding 127.66%, with a large standard deviation of

258.87. These values could perhaps be explained by considering the data period covered,

which is just after the onset of the Asian Financial Crisis when the Korean labour market

underwent tremendous adjustments. These adjustments can be seen in the pattern in the

average wage growth over time. As an example, whilst the average growth was 110.80% in

1998 and 146.96% in 1999, it later tapered to 84.01% in 2000 and 34.00% by 2001. On the

one hand, there are workers who experience phenomenal recovery in actual wages after

apparently suffering major income setbacks during the Crisis period. On the other hand,

there are workers with negative wage growth who failed to recover from the Crisis. Such

outliers should be discarded for the purpose of modelling lifetime wage growth, as this

wage growth would be expected to follow a reasonably steady pattern, and should not

reflect temporary surges or dips arising from external disturbances. The outliers should be

progressively excluded until a reliable growth pattern is achieved.

Given that the 5-year industry average annual wage growth over 1998-2001 using

aggregate-level data is about 6-7%, the KLIPS sample unit-record data spanning all

industries should have a similar average wage growth. To achieve a reliable growth pattern

across respondents in the KLIPS, the top 10% and bottom 5% of outliers had to be removed

in the calculation of lifetime wages. It is noted that more observations from the high-end

growth distribution are removed since the magnitude of wage increases exceeded that of the

decreases, and there are more respondents with positive growth. Additionally, workers who

changed job status between periods were removed in the computation of lifetime wages as

273

their inclusion could distort the annual wage growth rate. These cover a change from part-

time to full-time work and vice versa, or from regular (job contracts exceeding 1 month) to

irregular work (include job contracts of less than 1 month, including daily-rated work) and

vice versa14

.

Removing the top 10%, bottom 5% and individuals with a changed job status gives an

average wage growth of 6.20 with a standard deviation of 25.92 for industry stayers15

. The

average growth in the sample now reflects the industry average of 6-7% with aggregate-

level data. The annual wage growth for each industry was then regressed on the personal

attributes of this sub-set of stayers. The estimated regression equation was then used to

predict a wage for all industry stayers. This enables maximum usage of the dataset. The

average predicted wage growth rate from this exercise is 6.12%, with a much lower

standard deviation of 3.45. This approach to constructing a wage growth variable for

inclusion in the mobility equation identifies the effects of the old sector‟s wage growth via

exclusion restrictions (marital status and occupational status) and through having multiple

(for each industry) equations for generating the predicted variables.

A sensitivity test was conducted to ensure the regression results of the main model

presented later in Table 9.10 are not sensitive to changes in the sample of stayers used to

construct the wage growth variable. An extra 1% of observations at the upper end of the

distribution were removed. The average predicted wage growth rate was then computed

again, and the inclusion of this alternative measure in the main model resulted only in slight

changes to the regression coefficients (of around 1 decimal point). Thus, the results are

robust to this change in the sample used for the underlying regression for the wage growth

calculations for industry stayers.

With this combination of past industry data and the individual-level variables, the pair-wise

correlation coefficient between g*p

at and g*p

bt is 0.007, which is much lower than that for

the aggregate-level, of 0.889.

274

9.5.3 Descriptive Statistics of Predicted/Recomputed Variables

Having derived predicted monetary variables and recomputed the sector-level variables, a

re-look at the descriptive statistics that are to be used in the main model is in order. For

comparative purposes, the non-weighted and weighted series are presented. Similar to the

case for actual data, the design effect is less than 1 for most predicted/recomputed

variables. However, it is usually not much less than 1, implying that little is lost by

focusing on the unweighted data. The description in this section therefore applies to the

non-weighted series.

As in the case for actual variables, the average predicted expected new sector‟s wage was

higher than the average predicted old sector‟s wage. With regards to lifetime earnings, the

average predicted wage growth in the new sector (5.72%) is slightly less than that of the old

sector (6.12%), a pattern different from when the actual variables (as per the first two

columns of Table 9.6) are used. A breakdown revealed that this pattern applied to industry

stayers only. Since stayers constitute most of the sample, this pattern is to some extent the

result of averaging over five years for the new sector compared with the two years for the

old sector. It could also be due to the fact that an arbitrary decision was made by leaving

out the top 10% and bottom 5% to compute the sample 2-year average wage growth in the

old sector, and the descriptive statistics simply reflect the conservative approach taken in

this regard.

The average lagged annual unemployment rate was also slightly higher for the new sectors

when the recomputed rates were used. This is a similar scenario to when the actual

variables were used, suggesting again that a move to the high-wage new sector involves a

trade off for higher unemployment. Conforming to the pattern of Table 9.6, the

recomputed new sector size is smaller than the old sector size, and the recomputed new

sector‟s average growth rate is lower than the old sector‟s, once again suggesting that the

impact of the sector‟s past performance on mobility may not be as great.

275

Table 9.8 Means and Standard Deviations for Predicted and Recomputed Variables

Mean

Standard

Deviation Mean

Standard

Deviation

___

√deff

Monetary variables Non-weighted series Weighted series

ln(pya)p 4.71 0.23 4.74 0.17 0.739

lnybp 4.34 0.48 4.38 0.38 0.792

g*p

at (%) 5.72 0.90 5.74 0.77 0.856

g*p

bt (%) 6.12 3.46 6.15 3.61 1.043

Sector-level variables

U*a,t-1 (%) 4.64 2.12 5.49 1.04 0.4911

Ub,t-1 (%) 3.82 2.78 4.57 2.36 0.849

size*a (no.) 2,432 950 2,365 784 0.825

sizeb (no.) 3,556 1,573 3,555 1,578 1.003

GDP*a (%) 4.59 5.93 6.69 2.63 0.4441

GDPb (%) 5.36 8.33 7.76 5.93 0.712

Sample size 10,691 10,691

Source: KLIPS dataset. Annotations and description of variables are in Appendix 9B.

1. Compared to the weighted series, the high standard deviation for the non-weighted

U*a,t-1 and GDP*a series (and hence their lower design effects) reflects the higher

values in wave 2, the period following the Crisis when Korean workers are in the

initial stages of adjustment. It is noted that the design effects were closer to 1 for the

non-predicted series since aggregate-level data was used.

It can be seen that the predicted/recomputed statistics (non-weighted series) are generally

consistent with the actual variables. Thus, the derivations of predicted and recomputed

variables has not altered the way the mean monetary, macroeconomic and industry

characteristics differ in terms of the old-new sector comparison.

9.6 EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS: DETERMINANTS OF SECTORAL

MOBILITY

Having established the extended Le and Miller (1998) model, a reliable dataset and derived

variables to accommodate econometric issues associated with the original data, the

statistical analysis can be conducted. Prior to examining the determinants of sectoral

mobility, an attempt has to be made to arrive at the main model from the most general

model suggested by the review of past studies. There are three issues: (i) moving from an

unrestricted to a restricted model; (ii) determining if the weighted results should be used;

and (iii) deciding on the most suitable measure of sectoral shock.

Prior to the conduct of unrestricted-to-restricted modelling, a correlation matrix was

computed for all explanatory variables to detect multicollinearity. It was found that the

276

overall GDP growth rate was highly correlated with the new sector‟s performance and

lagged unemployment rate, with a correlation coefficient of at least 0.8. The other

variables were not highly correlated, having correlation coefficients of less than 0.6. To

minimize potential multicollinearity, and given the data shortcomings in that there is a

discrepancy in the time periods [i.e. the GDP growth rate is estimated at year-end (January

till December) whilst mobility (and annual employment) is estimated at mid-year (June

year t-1 till June year t)], and that GDP growth, being measured at yearly intervals, will not

capture any shorter-term cyclical effects, this variable will be excluded from subsequent

specifications.

Table 9.9 lists the estimated coefficients from an unrestricted model, using alternative

measures of a sectoral shock. This unrestricted model is based on a non-linear mobility

relationship for both age and job tenure. The first set of estimates in the left-hand panel is

based on the residual of the industry-specific AR(1) regression (micro level). Those in the

middle panel are based on the residual of the industry-specific AR(1) regression (by wave),

which was adopted by Jovanovic and Moffitt (1990) for the U.S. The third set in the right-

hand side panel is based on the cross-sectoral standard error of residuals from the industry-

specific AR(1) regression16

. It should be noted that the three models presented in Table 9.9

are non-nested and this may make comparison of the models difficult. While a nested

model can include all three shock regressors in the estimating equation, collinearity,

especially between the AR(1) (by wave) and AR(1) (micro level) residuals, prevents this17

.

The determination of the main model and the appropriate shock regressor will have to be

based on the number of significant regressors in the model as well as the overall fit of the

model.

Before the main model is determined, an attempt is made to weight the results and compare

the weighted and non-weighted results. Although the coefficient estimates will not be

seriously affected with complex sampling in large samples, the t-statistic, confidence

intervals and model selection will be biased if these complexities are not taken into

account. The t-statistic (tβ‟) under the complex KLIPS sample can be computed as:

___

tβ‟ = tβ /√deff

277

where tβ is the t-statistic for a regression estimate of β under the assumption of simple

random sampling18

. The weighted t-values are presented in Table 9.9. The comparison is

thus based on the statistical significance of the weighted and non-weighted t-values.

It can be seen that the statistical significance of the explanatory variables does not alter

whether the weighted or non-weighted t-statistic was used. This applies to all three

regressions. The design effect appears to have a modest effect at best. From here, the

logit estimates are therefore based on the non-weighted series. The use of non-weighted

KLIPS data concurs with previous studies, including Nam (2007), Kim (2004a), Cho

(2005), Sawangfa (2007), Kim (2003), Young (2005), Kang (2004), Kim (2004b), Young

(2006), Chang and Yang (2007), Seong (2007), Son (2007a), Son (2007b) and Jung, Moon

and Hahm (2007).

When the residual of an AR(1) regression (micro level) of the individual industry‟s

employment is used, the t-test indicates that sex, age, age-squared, marital status,

employment status, the new sector‟s wage growth and old sector performance did not

significantly influence the probability of a sectoral move at the 5% level. In addition to the

first five variables, the new sector‟s performance and tenure-squared were shown by the

corresponding t-statistic to be insignificant when the AR(1) residual (by wave) was used in

the regression. When the cross-sectoral standard error of residuals from the sector-specific

AR(1) regression of the natural logarithm of annual employment was used, only

occupational status and marital status were not significant influences (at the 5% level) on

the probability of a worker being classified as an inter-sector mover.

Table 9.9 Unrestricted Model: Logit Regression on Probability of Sectoral/Industrial Mobility Variable Regression 1 Regression 2 Regression 3

Coefficient t-

statistic

tβ‟ Coefficient t-

statistic

tβ‟ Coefficient t-

statistic

tβ‟

Constant -2.573 -4.961 -5.654 -9.986 -6.814 -10.634 ln(pya)

p-lnybp 0.627 7.43 8.877 0.467 5.328 6.366 0.783 7.431 8.878

g*pat -0.006 -0.192* -0.224* -0.076 -2.343 -2.737 0.123 3.533 4.127

g*pbt -0.138 -13.76 -13.193 -0.127 -11.248 -10.784 -0.102 -8.385 -8.039

U*a,t-1 -0.472 -17.275 -35.183 -0.423 -15.337 -31.236 -0.411 -14.271 -29.065 Ub,t-1 0.080 5.797 6.828 0.120 8.475 9.982 0.038 2.082 2.452 SEX (Females) -0.006 -0.073* -0.073* 0.096 1.143* 1.150* -0.181 -2.048 -2.060 AGE -0.033 -1.446* -1.483* -0.028 -1.163* -1.193* -0.069 -2.717 -2.787 AGESQ/100 0.039 1.419* 1.435* 0.036 1.254* 1.268* 0.081 2.695 2.725 TENURE -0.036 -3.266 -3.633 -0.033 -2.937 -3.267 -0.044 -3.565 -3.966 TENURESQ/100 0.071 2.233 2.229 0.062 1.904* 1.900* 0.215 5.909 5.897 MS (Non-married) -0.067 -0.767* -0.776* -0.088 -0.983* -0.994* 0.020 0.203* 0.205* HEAD (Non-heads) 0.413 5.458 5.685 0.177 2.133 2.222 0.462 5.438 5.665 EDA (Non-graduates) 0.208 2.137 2.075 0.193 2.008 1.950 0.215 2.053 1.993 OCC

(Non-professionals, non-associate professionals) -0.468 -3.305 -3.203 -0.464 -3.183 -3.084 0.130 0.753* 0.730* ES (Non-employees) -0.016 -0.180* -0.210* -0.082 -0.935* -1.091* 0.259 2.717 3.170 SIZEb/1000 0.197 8.914 8.887 0.183 8.115 8.091 -0.413 -12.177 -12.141 SIZE*a/1000 1.507 31.193 37.810 1.419 30.518 36.992 1.952 23.375 28.333 ∆ GDPb 0.001 0.143* 0.201* 0.038 8.149 11.445 0.029 6.17 8.666 ∆ GDP*a 0.208 25.963 58.475 0.000 -0.048* -0.108* -0.104 -11.348 -25.559 SHOCK -0.005 -11.250 -13.409 7.518 19.873 23.687 28.519 26.093 31.100 Nagelkerke R-squared 0.544 0.571 0.661

Chi-square statistic (20) 4,765.829 5,046.267 6,136.711

Sample size 10,691 10,691 10,691

* insignificant at 5% level.

Note:

1. SEX, MS, HEAD, EDA, OCC and ES are categorical variables. The text in parentheses refers to the reference group for the binary variable.

2. The distinction among the regressions lies in the SHOCK variable, computed for each regression as follows:

Regression 1- residual of the industry-specific AR(1) regression (micro-level);

Regression 2 - residual of the industry-specific AR(1) regression (by wave); and

Regression 3 - cross-sectoral standard error of residuals from the industry-specific AR(1) regression.

279

In terms of the number of insignificant variables, regression 3 has the lowest number of

such variables (two) compared to regressions 1 and 2 (each with seven insignificant

variables). The model under regression 3 had a better fit than the models under regressions

1 and 2. The Nagelkerke R-squared19

measure is 0.661, compared to 0.544 under

regression 1 and 0.571 under regression 2. Given the higher number of significant

variables and the better fit, regression 3, with the cross-sectoral standard error of residuals

as the sectoral shock, is viewed as superior to the first two regressions. In addition, the

cross-sectoral measure can be considered to be better by looking at the sign and size of the

coefficients. The coefficient for the AR(1) (micro-level) measure was negative, indicating

that using a shock that affects the individual-level (and not the sectoral-level) may not be

suitable. In contrast, both the AR(1) (by wave) and cross-sectoral measures have positive

coefficients, with the latter registering a larger magnitude. Considering the data period

covered, the large magnitude reflects the dramatic impact the Crisis had on mobility via a

disturbance to the economic sectors. Hence, the cross-sectoral standard error of residuals is

regarded as a reasonable measure of a sectoral shock reflective of the period in question.

To arrive at the restricted model of Table 9.10 from regression 3, the insignificant marital

status and occupational status variables are omitted. The restricted model can be

considered to be the main model used in analyzing the determinants of inter-sector

mobility. It will be termed the main model from here. The marginal effect for each

explanatory variable is included to highlight their relative importance on the dependent

variable20

.

With the high number of statistically significant variables, it is not surprising that the

overall goodness-of-fit chi-squared statistic (6,136) rejects the null hypothesis that none of

the independent variables are linearly related to the log odds of the dependent variable. The

good fit of the model can be attributed to the inclusion of the sectoral shock as well as the

macroeconomic time series data. Compared to studies based purely on cross-sectional

studies, the model would appear to be superior in terms of model specification. In addition,

to test whether the model‟s results are sensitive to changes in specification, each predicted

variable (sectoral wage differential or growth) was omitted in turn from the main model. It

was observed that the regression results for the other explanatory variables remained

280

unchanged in coefficient sign and significance. This suggests that the model is robust

under alternative specifications.

9.6.1 Monetary Variables

Expected Sectoral Wage Differential

The expected sectoral/industrial wage differential term is based on the Le and Miller (1998)

model and the Todarian hypothesis, which stipulates that worker movements are influenced

by higher expected earnings in the new sector compared to lower actual earnings in the

original sector. Empirically, the findings concur with the model and hypothesis. The

propensity to move to a new sector is increased the higher the expected industrial wage

differential. Specifically, higher expected wages raise the propensity to move by 13.89

percentage points. This is, for example, about 3 times the estimated partial effect on

mobility of being a non-graduate rather than a graduate. Thus, the role of expectations and

the comparison of the net monetary benefits in the alternative employment state are clearly

evident in the mobility decision for Korean workers.

In order to establish the relative importance of the wage and unemployment components of

the expected wage in the new industry, the main model was estimated with the same set of

explanatory variables but with the actual industrial wage differential21

replacing the

expected wage differential. The results obtained were similar to those reported in Table

9.10, which suggests that workers‟ decisions are based mainly on actual wage differentials.

The reason for this outcome can be seen mathematically. The expected wage variable,

ln [ya(1-Uat)] – ln yb, can be expressed as ln ya – ln yb + ln (1-Uat). As unemployment rates

in the new sector are quite low (on average 4%), the final term in the expected wage

variable will be close to zero. The expected wage differential and actual wage differential

will therefore be quite similar.

281

Table 9.10 Main Model: Logit Regression on Probability

of Sectoral/Industrial Mobility Variable Coefficient t-statistic Marginal Effect

Constant -6.796 -10.869 n.a.

ln(pya)p-lnyb

p 0.782 7.424 13.89

g*pat 0.122 3.514 2.17

g*pbt -0.104 -8.625 -1.84

U*a,t-1 -0.411 -14.278 -7.30 Ub,t-1 0.038 2.066 0.67 SEX (Females) -0.181 -2.063 -3.21 AGE -0.067 -2.847 -1.19 AGESQ/100 0.079 2.796 1.41 TENURE -0.044 -3.548 -0.78 TENURESQ/100 0.082 2.258 1.46 HEAD (Non-heads) 0.463 5.458 8.22 EDA (Non-graduates) 0.232 2.275 4.12 ES (Non-employees) 0.257 2.700 4.56 SIZEb/1000 -0.412 -12.145 -7.31 SIZE*a/1000 1.946 23.422 34.58 ∆ GDPb 0.029 6.213 0.52 ∆ GDP*a -0.104 -11.326 -1.85 SHOCK 28.444 26.15 21.87 Nagelkerke R-squared 0.661

Chi-square statistic (18) 6,136.117

Sample size 10,691

n.a. : not applicable

Note : 1. SEX, HEAD, EDA and ES are categorical variables. The text in parentheses

refers to the reference group for the binary variable.

2. The elasticity measure is used for the SHOCK variable.

Lifetime earnings

The lifetime earnings of the two employment states, as stipulated in the Le and Miller

(1998) model, are represented by the average annual growth rates in the incomes of the

original and destination industries. These variables have not been used in previous studies

of industrial mobility, although they were part of Willis and Rosen‟s (1979) model of the

demand for college education. For the current work, it should be noted that there is a

practical data limitation in examining lifetime earnings. As the sample covers 4 waves,

permanent income is interpreted as being permanent in the context of the short to medium

term (based on 4 waves of data), and not over the entire working lifecycle of a person.

The propensity to switch industries is raised when permanent income in the new sector

increases. A one percentage point higher wage growth is likely to increase the probability

of moving sectors by 2.17 percentage points. This finding reinforces the idea, based on the

282

relatively high costs of sectoral mobility, of individuals viewing industrial mobility as a

more permanent switch and as being a lifetime decision. In contrast, the likelihood of

changing industries is greater the lower the original industry‟s lifetime income. A one

percentage point lower growth rate in the original sector is likely to increase the occurrence

of moving by 1.84 percentage points. Thus, the lifetime earnings stream is clearly an

important consideration in the mobility decision, with higher permanent income in the new

industry acting as a pull factor and lower permanent wages in the original industry acting as

a push factor of mobility.

It is observed that the probability of a sectoral move is less sensitive to the pull and push

factors of the new and old sectors‟ permanent earnings compared to the current expected

wage differential. In other words, the elasticities of mobility with respect to a change in the

wage growth in the old sector (-0.49) and a change in the wage growth in the new sector

(0.54) is lower (in absolute value) than the elasticity with respect to the expected wage

differential (0.60)22

. Hence, among Korean workers, the lure of new sector wages appears

to have greater weight.

9.6.2 Macroeconomic Variables

Unemployment Rate

The original and new industries‟ unemployment rates were each entered into the workers‟

mobility decision process as lagged variables23

. Strong priors cannot be formed in relation

to the impact of the original and new industries‟ unemployment, as there appears to be only

a single study on employees [Vanderkamp (1977)]24

. In the current study, the higher the

unemployment rate in the original industry, the higher the likelihood of out-mobility. In

particular, every one percentage point increase in the unemployment rate increases the

outflow of labour from the old sector by 0.67 percentage points. This suggests that workers

view the higher chances of unemployment in their original sector as a signal of higher risks,

and hence tend to move out of the sector of origin to look for an alternative job. This

finding is consistent with Vanderkamp‟s (1977) study, which showed a positive

unemployment-mobility relationship in the old sector.

283

The findings of the current study show that higher unemployment in the new sector

deterred sectoral mobility. Specifically, an increase in the new sector‟s unemployment rate

by one percentage point is associated with a reduction in the inflow of labour into the new

sector of 7.30 percentage points. In a sectoral move, most workers move into a new sector

in anticipation of higher wages, but they may have to be unemployed for a while, i.e.

experience some form of wait unemployment before entering into employment in the new

sector. The greater the chances of being unemployed, the lower the workers‟ expected

wages, and the lower will be the chances of a sectoral switch for workers. This result for

Korea concurs with the Todarian hypothesis, which postulates an inverse relationship

between the unemployment rate and probability of obtaining a job in the new sector. It is,

however, contradictory to Vanderkamp‟s (1977) report of a positive unemployment-

mobility correlation for the new sector for the 1965/1966 period.

The old-new sector results are consistent, as lower job availabilities should limit mobility

into the new sector and encourage out-mobility from the old sector. In terms of the

magnitude of the effect of the unemployment rate, the absolute value of the new sector

variable (0.411) is greater than that of the old sector (0.038). Perhaps Korea workers are

more influenced by the lack of job availabilities and are daunted by the possibility of not

securing a job in the new sector.

9.6.3 Worker Characteristics

Gender

The gender variable is measured as a dummy variable indicating if the worker is a male

(= 1) or a female (= 0). The current research reports females to have a lower propensity of

industrial mobility than males. In particular, females are 3.21 percentage points less likely

to move to a new industry than males. The finding is inconsistent with Fallick‟s (1993)

study, which reports that females have higher probabilities of changing industries, but it

supports the general view that male and female mobility patterns differ.

284

Age

Age is entered in the estimating equation in quadratic form. The coefficient on the linear

age variable is negative and the coefficient on age-squared is positive. Thus, the negative

influence of age on sectoral mobility diminishes with rising age, and actually becomes

positive among older age groups. It is noted that the negative age-mobility relationship is

consistent with the findings of the empirical studies among employees: Osberg (1991) for

women in 1985/1986 and Osberg, Gordon and Lin (1994). Among the unemployed, the

negative relation is also portrayed in Thomas (1996b) for younger job quitters (UI and non-

UI recipients) and job losers (non-UI recipients) who had higher probabilities of mobility,

and for older job quitters and losers (UI recipients) who had lower mobility rates. The non-

linearity of the age effect on mobility is illustrated in Figure 9.1. This figure shows the

relationship between age and the probability of mobility for a specific worker profile (male,

graduate, head of household and employer) with monetary, macroeconomic, tenure and

industry variables equal to the sample means. From the calculation of the partial effect,

which measures the slope of the probability function25

, the turning point occurred at 43

years of age.

Figure 9.1 Probability of Sectoral Mobility and Age

0.0000

0.0500

0.1000

0.1500

0.2000

0.2500

0.3000

0.3500

0.4000

20 22 24 26 28 30 32 34 36 38 40 42 44 46 48 50 52 54 56 58 60

Probability

Age (years)

285

Job Tenure

Original job tenure was computed for industry movers and stayers in the current work using

slightly different algorithms. For stayers, the difference (in years) between the start date of

the current (and original) job and survey reference date was taken. For movers, job tenure

was computed as the difference between the start and quit dates of the previous job.

Job tenure was entered in the estimating equation in quadratic form. The coefficient on the

linear tenure variable was negative and the coefficient on tenure-squared was positive.

However, while the tenure-mobility relationship is U-shaped (see Figure 9.2)26

, for most of

the sample the relationship will be negative (as the positive effect holds only after tenure of

27 years). The negative tenure-mobility relation is consistent with a number of reports:

Osberg (1991) for male and female employees in 1980/1981, 1982/1983 and 1985/1986,

Osberg, Gordon and Lin (1994) for male employees, Fallick (1993) and Neal (1995) for

unemployed workers and Thomas (1996b) for job losers and quitters who received UI, and

job quitters who did not receive UI. Thus, this finding suggests that more experienced

workers who have more to sacrifice, e.g. seniority-based pay, longer leave periods and

pension benefits, are less likely to switch sectors.

Figure 9.2 Probability of Sectoral Mobility and Tenure

Probability

0.0000

0.0500

0.1000

0.1500

0.2000

0.2500

0.3000

0.3500

0.4000

1 3 5 7 9 11 13 15 17 19 21 23 25 27 29 31 33 35 37 39 41 43 45 47 49

Tenure (years)

286

Family Indicators: Marital Status and Household Head

A dummy variable was used to indicate if a person was married. The data findings

revealed that little, if any, of the variation in sectoral mobility could be attributed to marital

status. The variable was consequently omitted from the regression analysis. This is a

finding consistent with Osberg (1991) for males in 1982/1983 and 1985/1986, and females

in 1980/1981, 1982/1983 and 1985/1986, and Osberg, Gordon and Lin (1994), but it

contradicts Neal (1995), who showed that married men have a lower likelihood of

switching sectors.

A dummy variable was also used to indicate if the individual is a household head

(1 = household head, 0 = non-head). This household head variable was significant in the

analyses reported in Table 9.10. The probability of changing sectors was lower if the

person was a household head. The marginal effect was 8.22 percentage points. This finding

is consistent with the study of sectoral mobility among unemployed workers in the U.S. by

Fallick (1993), and supports the general view of household heads facing greater risks in

changing sectors owing to greater family commitments.

The significant finding for the household head and the insignificant one for marital status

can be reconciled. Since there can be only one head but more than one married person in

the household (see the descriptive statistics, where about three-quarters of the KLIPS

sample are married persons but only half are household heads), the family burden and risks

associated with changing sectors for a married person are lessened. As such, the mobility

effect will be dissipated for married persons.

Educational Attainment

If education is viewed as an indicator of one‟s learning ability or adaptability, it should

have a positive impact on mobility. If, however, employers favour more practical work

qualifications, such as current job scope, post-school track record and training attended,

then formal education need not have a positive influence on sectoral mobility. The measure

of education available in the survey related to the respondent‟s highest qualification

attained. Accordingly, this study focuses on whether the mobility patterns of graduates and

287

non-graduates differ. This is examined though the use of a dummy variable, set equal to

one for graduate status, and set equal to zero for non-graduates. The results showed that

non-graduates had a higher propensity to switch sectors, with the marginal effect being 4.12

percentage points. In a sense, the current findings are consistent with Kim (1998) who

inferred that lower-educated persons tended to be industry switchers among the

unemployed. The finding is, however, contradictory to Neal (1995) who reported that the

number of years of schooling (and most likely higher education levels) had an insignificant

impact on mobility, and Fallick (1993) who revealed that the number of grades of school

completed (and hence higher education levels) had a positive impact on industrial mobility.

Occupational Status

Inter-sectoral mobility may vary according to the workers‟ skills. In broad terms, the

differences in mobility rates between skilled and unskilled workers will most likely be

closely linked to any skill biases associated with a structural change in the economy. In this

study, the skill indicator is a person‟s occupation. A person is denoted as being skilled if

he/she was a professional or associate professional, and a dummy variable is used to

differentiate these skilled workers from their unskilled counterparts. The results show that

little of the variation in mobility could be attributed to occupational status in Korea. The

variable was subsequently omitted from the regression.

This finding is consistent with some of the results in Osberg (1991). Three occupational

groups were formed in this study: managerial/professional/technical, clerical/sales and

personal services, where the first group can be considered to be skilled workers, and the

latter two groups viewed as unskilled workers. Osberg (1991) reported that occupational

status was an insignificant determinant of the mobility of male workers in the 1982/1983

and 1985/1986 periods.27

However, the current study‟s finding does not concur with

Osberg‟s (1991) report for males in 1980/1981 and females in 1985/1986, where lower

tendencies of mobility among skilled workers were found, and for skilled females in

1982/1983, where higher probabilities of mobility were established. In particular, it must

be noted that the mixed result in Osberg (1991) for the same gender group (females) for

different time periods within an interval of just one year (i.e. 1980/1981 and 1982/1983) is

an area of concern, since few major behavioural changes in the labour force characteristics

288

can be observed within a short time span. There thus appears to be a lack of robustness in

the study of the Canadian labour market. It is also noted that the insignificant result

remained in the current study even when the logistic regression was undertaken for a

different time period, i.e. 1999-2001 (excluding the immediate post-Crisis year of 1998).

Employment Status

The employment status variable was included in the estimating equation to assess if

employees had a higher propensity to change sectors than their non-employee counterparts.

A dummy variable was used to distinguish employees (= 1) from non-employees (self-

employed/unpaid family workers) (= 0). The data revealed that non-employees were more

likely (by 5 percentage points) to move to a new sector. These employers were most likely

to be owners of small firms or business start-ups, with few or no employees, limited

contingency funds and more modest plans, thereby making the firm closure process easier

and the change to a new job/sector more probable.

Since the data period covers 1998-2001, a probable explanation could be associated with

the mid-1997 Asian Financial Crisis. The onset of the Crisis arose from large-scale capital

inflows into the country, and rapid increases in lending in the 1990s to firms which over-

invested at low profitability levels [Radelet and Sachs (1998), Tanzer (1999) and Akyüz

(2000)]. This led to massive debt obligations on the part of firms and eventual bankruptcies

in large conglomerates as well as small and medium-sized establishments (SMEs)

[Gregory, Harvie and Lee (2002)]. It is probable that employers owning the SMEs (which

had lower contingency funds) were the first to encounter the adverse effects of the Crisis.

Results from a separate regression omitting the first wave of observations in the KLIPS

sample showed that the partial effect was higher (7 percentage points). However, when the

first two waves of observations were omitted, employment status became an insignificant

variable. This is reflective of the immediate adverse impact the Crisis had on employers.

289

9.6.4 Industry Characteristics

Sectoral Size

The size of the original industry is measured by its employment size. In the current study,

the larger the size of the individual‟s original industry, the lesser the likelihood of changing

sectors. The elasticity of mobility with respect to an increase in the original industry‟s size

was -0.32. This implies that Korean workers may be reluctant to move out of their initial

sector of employment when it has greater job opportunities. This result is similar to the

negative impact reported by Fallick (1993) and Neal (1995) for their studies on the

unemployed. This similarity of result with the empirical literature should be observed with

some reservation, however, since these comparison studies focus on the unemployed who

may have quite different behavioural responses.

For the new industry, a larger size had a positive effect on sectoral mobility. The elasticity

of mobility with respect to an increase in the new industry‟s size was 1.50. This suggests

that Korean workers could be moving into the new sector because of its employment

opportunities. The result is consistent with the findings reported by Vanderkamp (1977)

and Osberg, Gordon and Lin (1994). It is noted that the result for this explanatory variable

is robust: Even when the finer initial industry data of Table 9.11 are included later in the

model, the coefficient of the new industry size is still positive and significant.

Sectoral Performance

The effect of sectoral performance is pursued in the current study by using the industry‟s

GDP growth rate as an indicator of industry performance28

. The results reveal that the

likelihood of a sectoral move from the old industry was higher the higher the GDP growth

rate of the initial industry. An increase in the growth rate of the original industry by one

percentage point raised the probability of mobility by 0.52 percentage points. This result is

unexpected, although several commentators have drawn attention to so-called jobless

growth as being a characteristic of many modern economies (Burgess and Green (2000)

and Mitchell (2000)]. Under this hypothesis, higher growth in a sector will not require an

increase in labour. This arises as the high growth could be spurred by a technological

290

upgrade or enhanced worker productivity. Moreover, the number of job vacancies arising

from the growth could be insufficient to cater for the rising number of the long-term

unemployed in the sector. Hence, this finding supports the jobless growth hypothesis that

higher growth in the old sector, brought about by technological advancements, leads to

labour obsolescence and a reduction in employment, resulting in out-mobility.

The effect of the new industry‟s GDP growth was negative. Higher growth in the new

industry deterred workers from entering into these industries. The marginal effect was

registered at 1.85 percentage points. This result is unexpected, but like the results for the

old industry‟s growth, is consistent with the jobless growth hypothesis. Better performance

in the new sector arising from a technological upgrade, leading to labour obsolescence, will

be insufficient to cater to more jobs, let alone provide jobs for new entrants into the sector.

Hence, a lower probability of mobility into the new high-growth sector is implied.

There is consistency in argument as the findings for both the old and new industry

performance align with the jobless growth hypothesis. Since the hypothesis is a

characteristic of a developed economy, it points towards the modernization of the Korean

economy.

9.6.5 Sectoral Shock

The sectoral/industrial shock variable is intended to capture unanticipated variations in

labour movements in the particular industry. From Table 9.10, it can be seen that a sectoral

shock resulted in greater sectoral labour reallocations in the Korean labour market. This

finding is consistent with many studies [Gulde and Wolf (1998), Brainard and Cutler

(1993), Jovanovic and Moffitt (1990), Altonji and Ham (1990) and Clark (1998)], which

have demonstrated that sectoral labour movements are not immune to the effects of a

sectoral shock.

It should be emphasized that the effect of the sectoral shock is highly significant in Korea.

The elasticity of sectoral mobility with respect to a change in the sectoral shock is large, at

21.8729

. This large effect is not surprising, given the dramatic impact of the unprecedented

Crisis. When the AR(1) residual (by wave) measure was used under the main model, the

291

elasticity of sectoral mobility with respect to the sectoral shock was still large, at 5.7530

. A

separate regression (not reported here) showed that the explanatory power of the model

dropped substantially, from 0.661 to 0.530 (measured by the Nagelkerke R-squared), when

the shock variable (cross-sectoral measure) was excluded. Therefore, the sectoral shock

variable plays a very important role in accounting for mobility in the Korean labour market.

Korea is an open, export-oriented economy, and unanticipated events affecting the

macroeconomy and labour market would also impact severely on various sectors of the

economy.

9.7 EXTENSIONS OF THE MODEL

This section considers two extensions of the above empirical model. The first extension

focuses on the individual‟s initial industry, in line with the work by Osberg (1991) for the

employed and Thomas (1996b) for the unemployed. The second part of this section

proceeds to test the various theories of sectoral mobility implied in the literature: worker-

employer mismatch, sectoral shock and bridging theories of sectoral mobility.

9.7.1 A Focus on the Initial Industry

The initial industry of an employee was included in the estimating equation to permit

assessment of which industries can be distinguished on the basis of their incidence of

industrial mobility. A set of eight dummy variables indicating the worker‟s original

industry of employment was incorporated in this study. Table 9.11 shows the regression

results for the initial industry variables. It is noted that by including these variables the

explanatory power of the regression improved further, to 0.676.

The results show that the propensity to change sectors varied according to the initial

sector/industry. The propensity of a sectoral move was lower if the worker was from the

construction and commerce sectors. In contrast, the probability of changing sectors was

higher if the worker originated from the agricultural sector and financial, real estate and

business services, and community, social and personal services industries, with the

marginal effects being 23.16 percentage points, 14.59 percentage points and 10.94

percentage points, respectively. The effects associated with initial employment in mining,

292

utilities and transport, storage and communications were insignificant. The variation in the

probability of worker mobility across industries possibly reflects that each industry

possesses different characteristics, like working conditions, job opportunities and

performance.

Table 9.11 Logit Regression on Probability of Sectoral/Industrial Mobility:

A Focus on the Initial Industry, Selected Coefficients Variable Coefficient t-statistic

Marginal

Effect

Agriculture 1.304 4.893 23.16

Mining -0.727 -0.198* -12.92

Utilities -0.430 -0.503* -7.63

Construction -0.461 -2.157 -8.19

Commerce -2.278 -14.391 -40.47

Transport, Storage & Communications -0.129 -0.726* -2.29

Financial, Real Estate & Business Services 0.821 5.304 14.59

Community, Social & Personal Services 0.616 3.665 10.94

Nagelkerke R-squared 0.676

Chi-square statistic (23) 6,329.946

Sample size 10,691 * insignificant at 5% level.

Note: 1. In addition to the initial industry variables, the model contains all variables in Table 9.10

except for the old industry size, sex and employment status. Compared to the other

explanatory variables, the correlation coefficient of the old industry size with each of the

initial industry variables was higher. The inclusion of the old industry size in the regression

would have led to unusually large estimates for the initial industry variables, a possible case

of multicollinearity. The sex and employment status variables were excluded from the

regression as they became insignificant after the inclusion of the initial industry variables.

2. The initial manufacturing sector, which had the largest number of observations, is excluded

from the regression.

9.7.2 Empirical Test: Theories of Sectoral Mobiliy

The three theories of sectoral/industrial mobility, namely the worker-employer mismatch,

sectoral shock and bridging theories, are tested in this section. These theories are about

model specification, and the distinction lies in the inclusion/exclusion of the industrial

shock variable.

The starting point for testing these theories will be the estimation of the main model of

sectoral mobility in Table 9.10. The critical explanatory variable for consideration is the

exogenous industrial shock variable. By singling out this variable, equation (6.7) can be

expressed as:

293

Ii = α + β1X1i + ….. + βkXki + θSi + μi (6.7‟)

where α is the constant term, X1 to Xk represent the k monetary, macroeconomic,

worker/job characteristic regressors, S is the industrial shock measure, and μ is the

stochastic error term. The β‟s and θ are the parameters to be estimated for the X‟s and S,

respectively.

Worker-Employer Mismatch Theory

Under the worker-employee mismatch theory, the emphasis is on the null hypothesis that

the effect of the industrial shock variable is zero (H0 : θ = 0), and this can be tested against

the alternative hypothesis (H1 : θ ≠ 0). The null hypothesis should be rejected under this

theory. The test can be implemented using the t-test. The t-statistic computed for the

industrial shock variable was 26.150 for the main model. As the computed t-statistic far

exceeded its critical value, the null hypothesis should be rejected. That is, the effect of the

sectoral shock cannot be ignored. The worker-employer mismatch theory is thus rejected

for the Korean labour experience.

Sectoral Shock Theory

The sectoral shock theory has an emphasis on the test of the null joint hypothesis that the

joint effects of the monetary, macroeconomic, demographic and socio-economic variables

are zero (H0 : β1 = β2 ….. = βk = 0), and this can be tested against the alternative

hypothesis that at least one of these exogenous variables is significant. This null means

that the industrial shock variable is the sole factor accounting for sectoral movements. A

test can be implemented using the chi-square statistic, computed as twice the difference

between the log likelihoods of the main model and the reduced model. The reduced model

is formed by omitting all variables other than the sectoral shock variable. As the observed

difference in the chi-square statistics between the main model (6,136) and the reduced

model (3,610) was 2,526, much larger than its critical value, the null hypothesis is rejected.

Thus, a model with sole reliance on the industrial shock will be inadequate in analyzing the

determinants of industrial mobility in the Korean labour market.

294

Bridging Theory

Under the bridging theory, testing the determinants of sectoral mobility has a focus on

testing the null hypotheses, i.e. H0 : β1 = β2 ….. = βk = 0 and H0 : θ = 0, that all variables,

including the sectoral shock, are insignificant If this theory is correct, the null hypotheses

should be rejected. The alternative is that at least one of the

monetary/macroeconomic/demographic/socio-economic variables and/or the sectoral shock

is significantly different from zero. Since the results of the main model of Table 9.10

provide strong evidence of significant β‟s and θ, the null hypotheses are rejected. The

Korean experience favours the bridging theory of sectoral mobility.

To assess if the bridging theory holds under an alternative technique, an approach along the

lines of Jovanovic and Moffitt (1990) is followed. This method rests on the assumption

that the effects of worker characteristics on mobility are via wages. Hence, rather than

including all variables in a single equation as per equation (6.7), a wages equation was first

estimated where the log of wages was expressed as a function of worker characteristics.

The standard error of this wage regression was obtained. Similarly, a measure of the

sectoral shock given by the standard deviation of residuals was obtained from an AR(2)

regression of each industry‟s log annual U.S. employment31

. Specifically, for each year

from 1968 to 1980, Jovanovic and Moffitt (1990) used the National Longitudinal Survey of

Young Men to regress log wage on education, experience, experience-squared and race to

obtain the standard errors of the annual wage regressions.

The wage measure is meant to capture the underlying wage deviations independent of

differences in worker characteristics. The sectoral shock is the AR(2) residual (by wave),

termed in the study as the across-sector standard deviation of residuals, and it was obtained

from log annual U.S. industry employment regressions. The binary dependent variable (1 =

mover, 0 = stayer) represented the probability of a sectoral move. It was regressed on the

standard error of the log wage distribution and the sectoral shock variable (i.e. the across-

sector standard deviation of residuals). The wage variable was significant, showing that the

mobility of U.S. workers was influenced by monetary differentials, even after accounting

for personal differences such as race, education and experience. The results showed that

the impact of a sectoral shock was positive and significant. The study concluded that since

295

the standard errors of wages are not constant, sectoral shocks would first affect wages,

which would then affect mobility. The significance of both variables provided support for

the bridging theory.

The Jovanovic and Moffitt (1990) model is implemented in this study as follows. To obtain

the standard error of the log wage distribution, the natural logarithm of individual workers‟

reported wages was first regressed on worker characteristics for each year, from 1998 to

2001. The available characteristics are sex, educational attainment, marital status,

employment status (self-employed or otherwise), age, age-squared, tenure and tenure-

squared. The standard errors from each of the four annual wage regressions were then

obtained, giving four values for each regression. The sectoral shock variable is the AR(1)

residual (by wave). Using the same binary dependent variable (1 = mover, 0 = stayer) as in

the main model to represent the probability of sectoral mobility, the dependent variable is

regressed on these two variables, with the logit estimates being shown in Table 9.12. The

results showed that although the sectoral shock variable was significant, the standard error

of the logarithm of the wage distribution was not.

It should be noted, however, that this technique is not a direct application of Jovanovic and

Moffitt (1990). Compared to Jovanovic and Moffitt (1990), the limited variation in the

wage variable for the Korean case (4 years compared with 13 years) may have accounted

for the weaker result with respect to this variable. Furthermore, the approach to estimation

differed. Jovanovic and Moffitt (1990) estimated the probability function for a typical

worker for each period with the number of observations in parentheses: 1966-1968 (492),

1967-1969 (628), 1968-1970 (754), 1969-1971 (887), 1971-1973 (1,357), 1973-1975

(1,846), 1976-1978 (2,032) and 1978-1980 (1,967). In comparison, estimation in the

current application was for the entire dataset from 1998-2001 covering 10,691

observations.

However, when alternative measures of a sectoral shock were used, namely the cross-

sectoral standard error of residuals from the industry-specific AR(1) regression and the

residual of an AR(1) residual (micro-level) under regressions 2 and 3, respectively, the

wage variable became significant. However, the sectoral shock variable was significant

296

only in regression 2. Thus, the bridging theory of mobility is supported only when the

cross-sectoral shock measure is used32

.

It must be emphasized that the results of the model are inconsistent under alternative

measures of a sectoral shock, in that the signs of the estimated coefficients also differ

across specifications. Under the unrestricted models of Table 9.9, the direction of influence

for the two shock measures also differed.

Table 9.12 Logistic Regression of Sectoral/Industrial Mobility on Wages

and Alternative Measures of Sectoral Shock, Selected Coefficients

Variable Coefficient t-statistic

Regression 1

Constant -4.4672 -42.624

Standard Error of ln(original industry wage) -0.9373 -0.650*

AR(1) residual (by wave) 10.1056 14.691

Nagelkerke‟s R-squared 0.270

Sample size 10,691

Regression 2

Constant -7.6044 -52.623

Standard Error of ln(original industry wage) 3.3707 30.470

Cross-sectoral measure 16.4984 39.879

Nagelkerke‟s R-squared 0.531

Sample size 10,691

Regression 3

Constant -4.7448 -43.733

Standard Error of ln(original industry wage) 3.8030 34.261

AR(1) residual (micro-level) -0.0003 -1.000*

Nagelkerke‟s R-squared 0.270

Sample size 10,691

* insignificant at 5% level.

The explanation for this difference may rest with the levels of disaggregation used in the

construction of the three shock measures. The effect on sectoral mobility is positive when

industry-level data are applied [cross-sectoral measure and AR(1) (by wave)] and negative

when micro-level data [(AR(1) (micro-level)] are used. This pattern is replicated in the

unrestricted model. Judging from the higher pseudo R-squared values and the lower

standard deviation, this suggests that a shock measure with industry employment data is

297

better than one estimated at the micro level. The support for this can be seen from a

conceptual standpoint as the measure of a sectoral shock should ideally reflect an external

disturbance impacting a sector as an entity, which the industry data seem to represent. In

contrast, the micro-level AR(1) indicator represents a shock that affects the labour market

at the individual level, which may not necessarily be reflective of the sectoral/industrial

outcome. In addition, between the two measures estimated at industry level, since

regression 2 gave a better fit, this also suggests that the cross-sectoral standard error of

residuals is a better measure.

Another reason for the disparity lies in the correlation of the shock measures with the

standard error of the log wage measure. The AR(1) residual (by wave) and AR(1) residual

(micro-level) are quite highly correlated with the standard error of the log wage

distribution, with the correlations estimated at 0.989 and -0.586. This change in sign also

suggests these two measures have different information content, which is not surprising

since the former is derived from industry-level data whereas the latter is from individual

data. In comparison, the correlation between the wage measure and the cross-sectoral

measure is the lowest, at 0.304. Furthermore, multicollinearity will exist if the AR(1)

residual (by wave) is applied, posing potential problems in statistical inference. Therefore,

owing to its higher pseudo-R-squared value, lower correlation with the log wage

distribution, which minimizes problems in statistical inference, and that the bridging theory

of mobility is supported when it is used, the cross-sectoral standard error of residuals is

deemed to be the better indicator of a sectoral shock.

It is also worth mentioning why Jovanovic and Moffitt‟s (1990) method of model

specification (i.e. two explanatory variables) was not adopted as the main model for the

current thesis. First, it can be seen that the results of the model are inconsistent for the

same wage variable when alternative measures of a sectoral shock were adopted. Second,

the assumption of worker characteristics influencing mobility indirectly is not widely

accepted, as many other studies have demonstrated such effects to be direct. Third, the

sectoral wage differential, a critical deterministic factor, and other industry characteristics,

are ignored in the analysis.

298

9.8 SUMMARY

This chapter provides a study of the determinants of sectoral/industrial mobility in the

Korean labour market. Since sectoral mobility is a complex phenomenon, a wide variety of

monetary, macroeconomic, worker and job characteristics were entered into the mobility

function. The findings are summarized below.

The Korean sectoral mobility experience supports the bridging theory for the overall

workforce. Labour movements occur as a result of monetary, macroeconomic,

demographic and socio-economic factors as well as from a sectoral shock.

The monetary element in the new sector is an important pull factor, with higher expected

wages attracting workers to the new sector. Similarly, higher monetary rewards in the

original sector serve to reduce worker mobility. In terms of lifetime earnings, whilst higher

permanent incomes in the new sector encourage worker mobility, those in the old sector

have a deterrent effect. On the whole, the findings on the monetary variables provide

strong evidence for the theoretical predictions implied by the Le and Miller (1998) model.

Considering that the new industry‟s unemployment rate had a negative effect on mobility

for the overall workforce, it can be viewed as a factor that moderates the monetary pull

factor. Perhaps Korean workers will not change sectors until an employment contract is

secured. Higher unemployment in the new sector will tend to lower workers‟ expectations

of obtaining higher wages, reducing the likelihood of a sectoral switch and lowering the

probability of obtaining a job in the new sector. The Korean experience provides support

for the Todarian hypothesis, in that individuals move for higher expected wages and that

the new sector‟s unemployment rate and probability of gaining new employment are

inversely related. It was also found that rising unemployment in the old sector led to out-

mobility from that sector.

With the exception of age and tenure, the alternative views and reported results from the

literature review do not support clear predictions about the relationships between mobility

and worker characteristics. Several of the findings from the current empirical analysis of

the Korean labour market are similar to those reported in other studies. But where the

findings deviate, the differences seem to be attributable to differences in model

299

specification (where an exogenous shock factor is included), coverage (employees rather

than the unemployed) and measurement issues. An alternative view is that the results

reported here reflect behavioural patterns of sectoral mobility unique to the Korean

experience: inter-industry movers are more likely to be younger non-graduate males who

are not household heads, have lesser work experience and who are non-employees.

Among the industry characteristics, Korean workers are more likely to move out from

smaller-sized sectors and move into larger-sized ones with greater employment

opportunities. In terms of sectoral performance, the workforce is more likely to exit from

high-performance sectors, and they seem to be prevented from entering high-performance

sectors, a finding attributed to the jobless growth hypothesis.

The sectoral shock has been shown to be a highly influential determinant of industrial

mobility, consistent with the bridging theory and the empirical findings reported in other

studies. For the overall pooled sample, the sectoral shock explained a major portion of

sectoral movements from 1998 to 2001 in Korea. For example, if this shock variable was

excluded, the Nagelkerke R-squared is substantially reduced, from 0.661 to 0.530.

This chapter has provided us with an understanding of the motivations behind

sectoral/industrial mobility in the context of the Korean labour market. In a nutshell, it can

be seen that sectoral mobility is a multifaceted phenomenon involving a spread of factors.

Although these factors affect mobility differently when different samples are considered,

there is at least some form of consistency in terms of the monetary incentive and the

influence of the sectoral shock. The results conform to the bridging theory. The bridging

theory of sectoral mobility, covered by one author, gives a broader view on mobility,

combining the effects of labour market characteristics and other unanticipated elements.

The current study has embarked on a more advanced research methodology. The

comprehensive set of factors and model implications sourced from numerous studies,

including those of the other forms of labour mobility, gave a broader dimension to the

research. The availability of a combination of cross-sectional and time-series data has not

only enabled a more in-depth analysis into the wealth of variables explored, but it has also

facilitated inclusion of variables reflecting both past and expected labour market outcomes.

The inclusion of micro- and macro-data improved the explanatory power of the regression.

300

The checking of the potential importance of survey weights to the KLIPS data is unique to

the current work. Apart from these, since potential workers make exante decisions about

the future, the conceptually-advanced model, which rides on expectations and the lifetime

income stream, appears to be highly appropriate in modelling this form of mobility

behaviour.

Endnotes:

1. See www.kli.re.kr. The KLI was founded as a government-sponsored research organization in May

1988. Since its establishment, it has conducted policy-oriented research on a wide range of labour issues. The

key issues include labour market participation and employment, industrial relations, human resource

management, worker welfare, labour laws and regulations. The KLIPS is the first panel survey on labour-

related issues in Korea, and serves as a valuable data source for microeconomic analysis of labour market

activities and transitions. The availability of longitudinal data through the KLIPS facilitates in-depth analytic

studies of labour supply and mobility, including schooling and the school-to-work transitions of youth, job

mobility and labour market transitions, unemployment experience, job training and education, working

conditions and welfare, childcare and female labour force participation, income and consumption, health and

retirement. The survey design and management of the KLIPS is based on the longitudinal surveys conducted

in advanced countries, e.g. U.S. Panel Study of Income Dynamics (PSID) and National Labor Survey (NLS).

2. Osberg (1991) noted that his short period of employment mobility of 6 months may exclude persons with

long intervening spells of unemployment.

3. It also comprises persons who were employed previously but did not provide information on their industry.

4. This also includes persons who did not report an industry in year t.

5. The missing survey information could be addressed, in principle, using the selection bias correction

techniques discussed below. However, the absence of information on key demographic and employment

variables effectively precludes the estimation of a satisfactory selection equation.

6. This means that the attrition rate does not vary according to any demographic or employment

characteristics.

7. An AR(1) regression was used instead of an AR(2), as in Jovanovic and Moffitt (1990), as the first

differenced series of each of the nine sectors/industries employment was stationary.

8. The standard errors of the regression for each regression by year are in parentheses: 1998 (0.5755), 1999

(0.4041), 2000 (0.2783) and 2001 (0.2451).

9. It is noted that the AR(1) residual mean value cannot be compared directly with Gulde and Wolf‟s (1998)

correlation measure since Gulde and Wolf (1998) used it to determine the association of sectoral shocks

amongst countries and various sectors.

10. Tomes and Robinson‟s (1982a) set of observable characteristics comprised schooling, experience, degree,

training, ability, language and urban/rural/farm location.

11. It is noted that wage estimations for the mover and stayer sub-samples were also undertaken by Osberg,

Gordon and Lin (1994), for old wages in period t-1 and new wages in period t, for their study of sectoral

mobility. They estimated the predicted wages for movers and stayers from the regressions of the new wage

(individual‟s 1987 reported income) on personal characteristics and the old wage (individual‟s 1986 reported

income), also on personal characteristics within each mover/stayer subsample. The fitted values formed the

predicted wages and the difference between the predicted wages of movers and those of stayers formed the

wage differential. The difference with the Tomes and Robinson (1982a) methodology is that the new sector

wages for industry stayers is as reported and not the average of all industries outside the stayer‟s original

industry.

12. The real wage differential adjusted to the 1998 deflator (wdiff1 = ln (yai/CPI1998) – ln (ybi/CPI1998)) and the

actual wage differential (wdiff2 = ln yai - ln ybi) are the same as the two ln (CPI) terms offset each other. In

the stricter sense, yat and ybt could be adjusted by different deflators. Since ya is measured at period t and yb at

period t-1, the new difference (newdiff) = ln (yat/CPIt) – ln (ybt/CPIt-1). Since there is no „i‟ term, the

difference between this adjusted variable and actual wages is subsumed into the constant term.

13. It is noted that the sector-level variables were re-computed and not predicted to avoid potential problems

in statistical inference associated with collinearity. If the sector-level variables are predicted from regressions

of U*a,t-1, Ub,t-1, size*a, sizeb, GDP*a and GDPb on the set of individual characteristics (Xi), and the mobility

301

model then consists of these predicted sector-level variables (superscripted with p) in addition to other

variables:

Ii = α + ..+ β1U*p

a,t-1 + β2 Upb,t-1 + β3size*

pa + β4size

pb + β5GDP*

pa + β6GDP

pb + βiXi + μ.

with α and μ being the constant term and error terms, respectively, then as the predicted values are: ^ ^

U*pa,t-1, U

pb,t-1, size*

pa, size*

pb, GDP*

pa, GDP

pb = α + βiXi,

the predicted sector-level variables are linear combinations of the same set of predictors, and so will be highly

collinear. There were numerous pair-wise correlation coefficients exceeding 0.5 including U*pa,t-1 with size*

pa,

GDP*p

a and GDPpb, U

pb,t-1 with size

pb, size

pb with GDP*

pa and GDP

pb as well as GDP*

pa with size

pb and

GDPpb. It is noted that these variables are not perfectly correlated owing to the averaging process. Whilst the

old sector values are obtained from movers‟ and stayers‟ original industries, and the new sector values for

movers are obtained from their new industries, the new sector value for stayers is the average of predictions of

all industries other than the stayers‟ original industry. It is this averaging process that gives the less-than-

perfect correlation.

14. Not all respondents in the KLIPS sample reported job status. The removal of individuals reporting a

changed job status (i.e. part-time to full-time and vice versa, regular to irregular employment and vice versa)

is based on available responses only.

15. Removing the bottom 10% would have given a high average wage growth of 9.65%, which exceeds the

industry average of 6-7%.

16. Some degree of collinearity amongst the three shock measures exists, as shown by the following

correlation matrix:

AR(1) (micro-level) AR(1) (by wave) Cross-sectoral standard

error of residuals from

industry-specific AR(1)

regression

AR(1) (micro-level) 1.000 -0.624 -0.168

AR(1) (by wave) -0.624 1.000 0.306

Cross-sectoral standard

error of residuals from

industry-specific AR(1)

regression

-0.168 0.306 1.000

17. A separate regression using the Lilien index as an alternative measure of industrial shock resulted in ten

insignificant variables, including the expected sectoral wage differential.

18. The formula for tβ‟ follows from Kish (1965) [refer to page 259] where it is mentioned that the effective t-

statistic adjusted for the design effect is: ____

tβ / √deff

19. See Nagelkerke (1991). The Nagelkerke R-squared is a modification of the Cox and Snell statistic to

ensure that it varies from 0 to 1. The Cox and Snell R-squared is an attempt to imitate the interpretation of the

multiple R-squared based on the likelihood, but its maximum can be less than 1, which makes it difficult to

interpret. It is measured by R2 = 1 – exp[-2/n{logL(β) – log L(0)}] where logL(β) and log L(0) denote the log

likelihoods of the fitted and null models, respectively. Nagelkerke‟s R-squared divides Cox and Snell‟s R-

squared by its maximum in order to achieve a measure that ranges from 0 to 1. This maximum is defined as

max(R2) = 1 – exp{2n

-1log L(0)}. The Nagelkerke R-squared = R

2 / max(R

2).

20. The marginal effect of a variable in a logit model (expressed in percentage terms) is given as ρ(1- ρ)β x

100, where ρ is the mean of the dependent variable and β is the estimated logit coefficient. It shows the partial

effect of an exogenous variable on the probability of a sectoral move. For a quadratic term, e.g AGE, the

marginal effect is estimated as (β0 + 2 β1 AGE) ρ (1- ρ).

21. The actual industrial wage differential is computed as ln(Wage in New Sector) – ln(Wage in Original

Sector). The sectoral wages are based on the predicted values.

22. As the comparison of marginal effects can be sensitive to units of measurement, the elasticity measure is

used instead. The elasticity of sectoral mobility with respect to (w.r.t.) a change in the wage growth rate is

computed as: ∂ρ/∂ğ x (ğ/ρ) = marginal effect x (ğ/ρ) where ρ is the probability of sectoral mobility and ğ is

the average wage growth in the original or new sector. The elasticity of mobility w.r.t. a change in the

expected wage differential is derived from the equation:

∂ρ/∂ln(pya/yb) = marginal effect, which gives ∂ρ/∂(pya/yb) x (pya/yb) = marginal effect,

and thus elasticity = marginal effect /ρ.

23. As mentioned in the literature review, the sectoral unemployment rates were included in the mobility

equation as lagged variables. A two-stage least squares test of simultaneity, following the methodology of

302

Addison and Portugal (1989), was undertaken. The logistic regression of the probability of a sectoral move

(Ii) on the new sector‟s unemployment rate in the current period (Uat) showed Uat to be significant and

positive. At the same time, for the Uat equation, out-mobility to the new sector led to further increases in the

new sector‟s unemployment rate. This points towards evidence of simultaneity bias in equations that

incorporate the Uat term. Hence, the sectoral unemployment rates were entered as lagged variables.

24. While a higher unemployment rate in the current sector would reflect poorer job prospects there, it could

also indicate poor job prospects in other sectors as well.

25. For age, the partial effect is measured by [-0.067 + 2(0.079)(Age)] ρ(Age) [1- ρ(Age)] where ρ(Age) is the

probability of changing sectors at a particular age.

26. Figure 9.2 shows the relationship between tenure and the probability of mobility for a specific worker

profile (male, graduate, head of household and employer) with monetary, macroeconomic, age and industry

variables equal to the sample means.

27. Vanderkamp‟s (1977) „change of occupation‟ variable is not directly comparable with this study.

28. One isolated study by Jayadevan (1997) reported a positive correlation between employment growth and

industrial output growth.

29. As the cross sectoral shock variable is measured in natural logarithmic terms, the marginal effect is

computed as ∂ρ/∂ln(X) = ∂ρ/∂X x X, where X is the cross-sectoral standard error of residuals variable, X is

the mean of the cross sectoral shock variable (equals 0.1802) and 505.28 is estimated from the partial effect

formula: β x ρ(1- ρ) x 100; with β being the regression coefficient and ρ being the average probability of a

sectoral move. Since the comparison of marginal effects can be sensitive to units of measurement, the

elasticity measure is used instead. The elasticity of mobility w.r.t. a change in the sectoral shock is derived

from the equation ∂ρ/∂X x X = marginal effect, and thus elasticity = marginal effect / ρ = β x ρ (1- ρ)/ ρ =

28.444 x 0.231(0.769)/0.231 = 21.87.

30. The AR(1) (by wave) residual is measured in natural logarithmic terms. The elasticity of mobility w.r.t. a

change in the sectoral shock, computed as β x ρ(1- ρ)/ρ, is 7.518 x 0.231(0.769)/0.231 = 5.78.

31. No reason was mentioned for why an AR(2) regression of log U.S. employment was used, but it is likely

that the AR(2) series was stationary. The current thesis adopts an AR(1) series for sectoral employment as the

employment series for the 9 major sectors/industries, using annual data, over the period 1998-2001 was tested

and found to be stationary.

32. Numerous studies [Lilien (1982), Abraham and Katz (1986), Loungani (1986), Parker (1992), Lu (1996),

Mills, Pelloni and Zervoyianni (1995) and Garonna and Sica (2000)] use the Lilien index to represent sectoral

movements in their analyses of the impact of sectoral mobility and unemployment. It is noted that the other

measures of sectoral shock, i.e. Lilien index and net labour flow index, are not used here as they are measures

of sectoral reallocations of labour movements and do not focus on the unobservable labour movements.

303

CHAPTER 10

GENDER DIFFERENCES IN SECTORAL MOBILITY IN KOREA

10.1 INTRODUCTION

The preceding chapter examined the determinants of sectoral mobility using data pooled

across males and females. This chapter extends the work by considering males and females

separately. In this way it develops past research, as only a few studies have moved beyond

pooled data to examine mobility patterns, namely, Osberg (1991) and Osberg, Gordon and

Lin (1994) for Canada, and Jovanovic and Moffitt (1990), Neal (1995) and Thomas

(1996b) for the U.S. However, not all of these studies consider both the male and female

workforces, and so there is only limited evidence on gender differences in sectoral

mobility.

The chapter also aims to assess whether the differences in mobility between males and

females are related to differences in individual and industry characteristics or to differences

in gender preferences in the demand for sectors (e.g. labour market attachment) and in the

ways that males and females are treated by firms in hiring/firing decisions. In doing this it

draws upon the wage discrimination literature to provide the analytical framework. From

this perspective, the part of the gender difference in mean mobility rates that can be linked

to differences between males and females in the observable individual and industry

characteristics will be termed the „explained‟ gender mobility differential. Similarly, the

remainder of the gender difference in mobility rates, which presumably arises due to gender

preferences or discrimination, will be termed „unexplained‟ (by the regression model). The

decomposition methods used in this type of work thus give emphasis to the differences

between males and females in the ways sectoral mobility is determined1.

Prior to the empirical analysis of the determinants of mobility and application of the

decomposition technique, brief statements on the empirical model, sample datasets and a

test of whether the male and female samples should be examined separately are presented

in sections 10.2 and 10.3. Section 10.4 outlines the similarities and differences between

males and females in terms of their characteristics that form the basis of the model. The

304

empirical findings from the separate logit models of sectoral mobility for males and

females are discussed in section 10.5. Empirical tests on the three theories of sectoral

mobility are presented in section 10.6. Finally, the decomposition analysis is presented in

section 10.7, followed by a conclusion in section 10.8.

10.2 MODEL AND SAMPLE DATASET

The general model of sectoral labour mobility for the study of individuals‟ choice between

two sectors stated in the previous chapter can be applied to specific gender groups as

follows:

Iim = γ1m + γ2m[ln pim + ln yaim – ln ybim] + γ3mgaim + γ4mgbim- Zimδm - Simθm + vim (10.1)

Iif = γ1f + γ2f[ln pif + ln yaif – ln ybif] + γ3fgaif + γ4fgbif - Zifδf - Sifθf + vif (10.2)

Iim and Iif are the latent (i.e. unobserved) variables for the probability of a sectoral move for

males and females, respectively. The indices, I*

im and I*if, are the observed dependent

variables for males and females, respectively. They indicate whether a sectoral move has

taken place. I*im and I

*if take the value 1 if male/female workers changed sectors, and the

value 0 if a change did not occur. These observed variables are linked to their

corresponding latent indices as shown below:

I*im = 0 if Iim < 0;

= 1 if Iim ≥ 0; and

I*if = 0 if Iif < 0;

= 1 if Iif ≥ 0.

The explanatory variables are as described earlier, with the m and f subscripts each

denoting male and female workers. The terms vim and vif denote the stochastic disturbances

for males and females. As in the estimation for the pooled dataset, the logit method of

estimation will be used in this disaggregated analysis.

The sample dataset for males and females are subsets of the pooled dataset. There are

6,906 person-year observations for the regression for males and 3,785 person-year

305

observations for the regression for females. The list of data items for males and females is

given in Appendix 10A. The general characteristics of the data follow that of the pooled

data in that the re-computed sector-level variables exhibit lower correlations than those

displayed for the original variables2.

10.3 VALIDITY OF POOLING THE DATASET

Prior to the analysis, it would be worthwhile to test if the male and female samples should

be pooled into a single sample. The approach is to make use of a gender dummy variable

(F = 1 for females, F = 0 for males) to test if the individual coefficients differ between the

gender groups. A chi-squared test of whether all coefficients for males are simultaneously

different from the respective coefficients for females is also presented. Thus, to test if the

mobility relationship is the same for both gender groups, the female dummy variable (F) is

inserted in the general equation together with a series of interaction terms (FX‟s):

Ii = γ1 + γ*1F + (β1X1 + β2X2 +……….βkXk) + (β

*1FX1 + β

*2FX2 +……….β

*kFXk) + ui

It can readily be seen that the estimated models for each gender group are:

Males: Ii = γ1 + (β1X1 + β2X2 +……….βkXk) + ui

Females: Ii = (γ1 + γ*1) + (β1+β

*1)X1+ (β2+β

*2)X2 + …….. (βk+β

*k)Xk + ui

Whilst the β‟s will be the estimated coefficients for males, the (β+β*)‟s will be the

coefficients for females. The t-tests of the null hypotheses H0: β*‟

s = 0 will indicate if the

individual slope coefficients for females differ from those for males. The t-test of the null

hypothesis H0: γ*1 =0 will show if the intercepts in the male and female mobility

regressions are similar.

306

Table 10.1 Logistic Regression of „Full‟ Model Variable Coefficient Standard

Error

t-value

Constant -16.844 2.177 -7.737

ln(pya)p-lnyb

p 1.181 0.259 4.560

g*p

at 0.821 0.047 17.468

g*p

bt -0.400 0.022 -18.182

U*a,t-1 -0.713 0.065 -10.969

Ub,t-1p 0.384 0.050 7.680

∆ GDP 0.484 0.067 7.224

AGE -0.055 0.010 -5.500

TENURE -0.067 0.011 -6.091

MS (Non-married) 1.435 0.233 6.159

HEAD (Non-heads) 1.175 0.210 5.595

EDA (Non-graduates) 0.330 0.243 1.358*

OCC (Non-professionals, non-associate

professionals) -2.030 0.453 -4.481

ES (Non-employees) 0.278 0.234 1.188*

SIZE b/1000 1.130 0.247 4.575

SIZE*a/1000 3.410 0.414 8.237

∆ GDPb 0.025 0.018 1.389*

∆ GDP*a -0.415 0.034 -12.206

SHOCK 17.924 2.653 6.756

Female Dummy (F) -10.949 2.313 -4.734

F x [ln(pya)p-lnyb

p] 1.579 0.491 3.216

F x g*pat 0.606 0.148 4.095

Fx g*p

bt 0.246 0.039 6.308

F x U*a,t-1 -1.852 0.244 -7.590

F x Ub,t-1 0.169 0.139 1.216*

F x ∆ GDP 0.715 0.151 4.735

F x AGE 0.006 0.020 0.300*

F x TENURE 0.059 0.024 2.458

F x MS (Non-married) -0.471 0.394 -1.195*

F x HEAD (Non-heads) -0.143 0.437 -0.327*

F x EDA (Non-graduates) 0.311 0.433 0.718*

F x OCC (Non-professionals, non-

associate professionals) 0.839 0.843 0.995*

F x ES (Non-employees) 0.772 0.435 1.775

F x SIZEb/1000 -3.551 0.474 -7.492

F x SIZE*a/1000 0.567 0.798 0.711*

F x ∆ GDPb -0.051 0.032 -1.594*

F x ∆ GDP*a -0.154 0.067 -2.299

F x SHOCK 57.356 6.973 8.225

Chi-square statistic 10,044.774

Nagelkerke R-squared 0.922

Sample (6,906 males and 3,785 females) 10,691 Source: Pooled KLIPS dataset. This dataset differs from the pooled dataset in the previous chapter as several variables were constructed separately for the male and female samples: monetary variables, lagged unemployment rates, sectoral sizes and sectoral shock.

* insignificant at 10% level.

307

Table 10.1 shows the t-statistic for each coefficient. The intercepts in the male and female

regressions are clearly different. There are eight gender interaction terms that are

insignificant at the 10% level, and ten statistically significant interaction variables. In

particular, the individual coefficients for females that are significantly different from the

corresponding coefficient for males are the three monetary variables, lagged new sector‟s

unemployment rate, GDP growth, employee status, tenure, old sector size, new sector

performance and sectoral shock. Furthermore, the chi-square statistic for the test that the

female dummy and interaction terms can be excluded from the model is 550. This exceeds

the critical value and so the hypothesis that there is no significant difference between the

models of worker mobility for males and females is clearly rejected. The industrial

mobility relationship should therefore be estimated separately for males and females.

10.4 DESCRIPTIVE STATISTICS FOR MALES AND FEMALES

This section outlines the similarities and differences between male and female workers in

Korea in terms of the monetary and macroeconomic variables, and worker and job

characteristics that are the basis of the model of industrial mobility. As noted in the

introduction, differences between males and females in these variables may contribute to an

understanding of the reasons for any gender differences in the sectoral mobility of the two

groups.

The means and standard deviations for the KLIPS male sample of 6,906 observations and

the female sample of 3,785 observations covering the four job waves (1998 till 2001) are

listed in Table 10.2. A „t‟ statistic for the test of whether the mean values for each male

and female variable are significantly different from each other is reported in the last column

of the table3.

As in the case of the pooled sample, the majority of male and female workers are industry

stayers, with the mean mobility rates being 23.5% for males and 22.3% for females.

Although the share of movers for men and women do not differ significantly, there could be

differences in the means of the explanatory variables between men and women. If this is

the case, it implies that there must be differences in the estimated coefficients of the

308

individual and job characteristic, since these differences in behavioural patterns are needed

to offset differences in mean values of characteristics to give the similar mean rates of

sectoral mobility for males and females.

Table 10.2 Means and Standard Deviations for Male and Female Workers, Aged 20-64 years Males Females tβ

Mean (or %)

Standard Deviation

Mean (or %)

Standard Deviation

statistic

Monetary variables

Ln (Expected New Industry Wage) 4.82 0.28 4.65 0.69 -17.20*

Ln (Original Industry Wage) 4.13 2.25 4.01 0.58 -3.10*

Growth Rate of New Industry Wage (%) 3.13 3.65 6.74 1.76 57.23*

Growth Rate of Original Industry Wage (%) 13.50 6.33 10.60 5.42 -23.81*

Macroeconomic variables

Unemployment Rate in New Industry in Period t-1 (%) 5.07 2.39 3.97 1.57 -25.37*

Unemployment Rate in Original Industry in

Period t-1(%) 4.20 2.98 3.23 1.79 -18.27*

GDP Growth Rate (%) 4.21 4.17 4.81 4.09 7.10*

Worker characteristics

Industry Mover (%) 23.5 42.40 22.3 41.63 -1.38

Age at Former Interview (yrs) 40.44 10.19 38.31 11.33 -9.95*

Original Job Tenure (yrs) 7.88 8.34 5.72 7.80 -13.09*

Married Persons (%) 78.4 41.18 64.4 47.89 -15.83*

Household Head (%) 69.7 45.94 22.2 41.56 -52.90*

Educational Attainment: Graduate (%) 17.1 37.64 10.0 30.02 -9.96*

Professional/Associate Professional (%) 7.2 25.89 8.0 27.13 1.42

Employee (%) 78.2 41.32 82.7 37.83 5.58*

Initial Industry (%)

Agriculture 5.6 22.92 5.1 22.05 -0.95

Mining 0.3 5.24 0.1 3.25 -1.81+

Manufacturing 25.6 43.64 24.6 43.09 -1.05

Utilities 0.5 7.20 0.2 3.98 -2.87*

Construction 12.1 32.67 4.6 21.06 -12.75*

Commerce 21.0 40.72 27.5 44.66 7.65*

Transport, Storage & Communications 9.0 28.63 4.0 19.70 -9.51*

Financial, Real Estate & Business Services 15.0 35.70 15.0 35.74 0.06

Community, Social & Personal Services 11.0 31.24 18.8 39.04 11.27*

Industry characteristics

Original Industry Size (no.) 1,966 722 1,741 936 -13.87*

New Industry Size (no.) 1,411 439 1,037 558 -38.19*

Original Industry Growth Rate (%) 4.91 8.31 6.17 8.33 7.43*

New Industry Growth Rate (%) 4.38 6.07 4.98 5.63 5.00*

Sectoral Shock

Cross-sector Standard Error of Residual of AR(1) Regression 0.1697 0.0798 0.1867 0.1417

0.07

Sample Size 6,906 3,785

Source: KLIPS dataset. * significant at 5% level.

+ significant at 10% level.

Note: As this is a preliminary test, the statistics are generated directly from the KLIPS sample, i.e. the non-weighted series is used.

309

The Table 10.2 data show that male and female workers differ considerably in terms of

both individual and job characteristics. Among the monetary variables, there were

statistically significant differences between the two groups in terms of the expected

incomes in the new sector, original income and wage growth in both sectors. Males, on

average, reported higher expected and actual earnings. Their expected incomes in the new

sector exceeded those of females by 17 percentage points. Their original incomes were

greater by 13 percentage points. In terms of the old sector‟s lifetime income, male workers

also reported higher earnings than their female counterparts, with their average growth rate

exceeding that of females by 2.9 percentage points. However, the new sector‟s future

earnings for males were lower than those of their female counterparts, by 3.6 percentage

points. So whilst men have greater immediate income gains in the new sector than women,

they would do better in terms of wages growth by remaining in their present sector.

Nonetheless, a breakdown of the data for each gender group revealed that inter-industry

movers had higher future incomes in the new sector than industry stayers.

The descriptive statistics showed that men, on average, experience higher unemployment

than women in both the new and original sectors. For example, the new sector‟s male

unemployment rate was 5.07%, more than 1 percentage point higher than the 3.97% female

rate. The original sector male unemployment rate was 4.20%, which is also greater than the

female rate of 3.23%. Although these data indicate that a higher proportion of men

encounter unemployment, it should be noted that the female unemployment rate can be a

hazy measure. To the extent that females can be „secondary‟ wage earners, they have a

greater tendency to withdraw from the labour force rather than search for work. This

means that the female measured unemployment rate could understate the true

unemployment rate in each sector.

In terms of worker characteristics, there are significant differences between males and

females in terms of age and tenure. The average male (aged 40 with 8 years of experience)

is two years older and has two years more work experience than the average female (aged

38 with 6 years of experience). There are also marked differences in terms of marital

status and head of household status. Whilst 78% of male workers are married and 70%

assume headship in the household, only 64% of females are married with a lower 22%

heading households. In terms of educational attainment, men appear to be more educated,

310

with a considerably higher proportion of graduates (17%) than their female counterparts

(10%).

The variables that do not vary substantially between the two gender groups are employment

status and occupational status. Men have a slightly lower share of employees (at 78%) than

do women (83%). Men and women have similar shares of professionals and associate

professionals, of 7-8%.

In terms of the initial industry, there are differences in the proportional representation by

gender for industries other than mining, manufacturing and financial services. The

industries where males have a higher proportional representation than females are

agriculture (6% versus 5%), utilities, construction (12% versus 5%) and transport and

communications (9% versus 4%). Females were more concentrated in the commerce sector

(28% of females work there compared to 21% of males) and community, social and

personal services (19% for females versus 11% for males).

There are statistically significant differences between men and women in the size of the

original and new industries. Reflecting the greater number of male workers, the average

sizes of both the original and new industries were larger for males than for females.

However, for both gender groups, the new sector‟s size was less than that of the old sector,

suggesting a move towards smaller-sized industries for both groups.

Since there are no gender-specific GDP data, the average GDP growth rate is similar

among males and females, at 4-5%. The statistical difference in GDP growth rates shown

by the t-statistic is mainly due to the uneven distributions of males and females across the

KLIPS sample/sectors. This also applies to sectoral performance, where there is no gender-

specific data, and where the growth rate for the female workforce was slightly higher (by

about 1 percentage point) than that of their male counterparts.

There is, however, also a significant gender difference in the measure of sectoral shock,

given by the cross-sectoral standard error of the residuals of an AR(1) regression4. That is,

an exogenous shock in the original sector has differing magnitudes for the male and female

workforces.

311

The data therefore show that male and female workers differ in terms of both individual

and job characteristics. Given the similarity in the sectoral mobility rates of males and

females, the differences in the mean values of the explanatory variables reported here

suggests that mobility for each gender group is determined by a different set of explanatory

variables. Differences in the behavioural relationships as well as the difference in mean

values of variables will therefore need to be considered in this evaluation of male and

female mobility behaviour.

10.5 GENDER DIFFERENCES IN THE DETERMINANTS

OF SECTORAL MOBILITY

When the model of sectoral mobility was estimated on the separate samples of males and

females, it was found that there were more insignificant variables than in the pooled sample

analysis, an outcome that may be attributed to the smaller sample sizes5. In determining the

final models in this disaggregated anlaysis, three criteria were applied: the fit of the model,

the number of insignificant variables, and having the same variables in the models

estimated for males and females to facilitate the decomposition analysis in the later part of

the chapter.

Prior to conducting the initial gender regressions, a correlation matrix of the explanatory

variables was computed for the separate male and female datasets. The GDP growth rate

was highly correlated with the new sector‟s lagged unemployment rates and new sector

performance, with a coefficient of at least 0.8 in the male dataset. In addition to these two

variables, it was also highly correlated with the old sector‟s lagged unemployment rate in

the female dataset. The remaining correlation coefficients were all more modest, being 0.6

or lower. To minimize the likelihood of multicollinearity and given the measurement issues

about the GDP growth rate raised in the previous chapter (in terms of discrepancy in time

periods and data frequency, and that it is based on a broad-based economy-wide scale), the

GDP growth rate will again be omitted from the estimating equation. It is noted that the

high correlation between age and age-squared, and between tenure and tenure-squared, is to

be expected and they will be retained in the model.

312

The analysis conducted on the separate male and female samples is based on the non-

weighted data. This is undertaken to synchronise with the non-weighted regression results

of the pooled sample, where it was found that the use of weighted statistics led to minimal,

if any, change to the material conclusions. Furthermore, a weighting exercise undertaken

for males and females (not shown) showed that the statistical significance of the variables

remain unchanged regardless of whether the weighted or unweighted t-values were used.

The starting point for this empirical analysis was the estimation for the male and female

samples of the extended model used for the pooled dataset, as set out in Table 10B in

Appendix 10B. This model was characterized by a number of insignificant variables.

Under the initial regression for males, the insignificant variables at the 5% level were age-

squared, tenure, tenure-squared, educational attainment, old sector size and employment

status. Since the squared terms for age and tenure were non-influential, linear specifications

for these variables were tried. Under this linear model, the same variables remained

insignificant save for tenure, which became significant. For the unrestricted female

regression, in addition to the first four variables noted above for males, age and

occupational status were also insignificant at the 5% level. Using a linear specification for

the age and tenure variables for females led to the same variables being insignificant,

except for age6. Hence, linear age- and tenure-mobility relationships are implied by these

gender-specific regressions.

Table 10.3 presents the results of the restricted model when estimated separately for male

and female workers. There is a high number of statistically significant variables in each

model. The models for both samples have a good fit, with the Nagelkerke R-squared being

0.912 for males and 0.908 for females7. The analysis of Table 10.3 will first proceed with

the discussion of the results from the monetary and macroeconomic variables, followed by

individual and job characteristics and the sectoral shock variable.

10.5.1 Monetary variables

There are several studies of sectoral mobility that have provided separate analyses for

males and females. These, however, have not discussed gender differences in the impact of

monetary variables (expected or lifetime wages). Accordingly, any gender differences in

313

the effects of the monetary variables in the current set of empirical analyses will not be able

to be compared with empirical findings reported in the literature. Rather, the discussion

below will be limited to the between-gender differences from the current analysis, with

reference to findings from some single-sex studies where possible.

Expected Sectoral Wage Differential

In the analysis of the data pooled across males and females (chapter 9), the expected

sectoral wage differential had a positive and significant effect on sectoral mobility. This

finding is replicated in the separate analyses for males and females. The higher the

expected wage differential between sectors, the greater the probability of male and female

mobility. The elasticity of mobility with respect to a unit change in the expected wage

differential is 0.61 for men and 1.79 for women. Thus, empirically, the results of the

disaggregate study concur with the Le and Miller (1998) model.

The „actual‟ wage differential variable (results not reported here) yielded results similar to

those reported for the expected wage differential term. Hence, the male regression showed

that the coefficient of actual wages (1.03) was only slightly larger and the fit of the model,

as measured by Nagelkerke R-squared (0.91), was the same as the Table 10.3 result. For

the female regression, the coefficient of „actual‟ wages (1.91) was only slightly smaller

than that reported in Table 10.3, as was the fit of the model (Nagelkerke R-squared at

0.905). The similarity of the findings based on the expected and „actual‟ wage differential

has its basis in the argument advanced in relation to analysis of the pooled data: since

average Uatp rates are quite low for males (5%) and females (4%), the final term in the

expected wages measure [ln yap – ln yb

p + ln (1-Uat

p)] will be close to zero, meaning that

expected wages will be close to actual wages.

314

Table 10.3 Logistic Regression of Sectoral/Industrial Mobility by Gender Variable Males Females

Coefficient t-statistic Marginal

Effect

Coefficient t-statistic Marginal

Effect

Constant -7.526 -8.601 n.a. -18.148 -11.080 n.a.

ln(pya)p-lnyb

p 0.796 3.192 14.32 2.298 7.137 39.81

g*pat 0.714 18.297 12.83 1.099 9.944 19.04

g*p

bt -0.408 -18.779 -7.33 -0.229 -9.238 -3.97

U*a,t-1 -0.366 -9.501 -6.58 -1.401 -10.392 -24.27

Ub,t-1 0.477 11.086 8.57 1.037 9.236 17.97

AGE -0.047 -5.043 -0.84 -0.043 -2.958 -0.74

TENURE -0.061 -5.685 -1.10 -0.003 -0.166* -0.05

MS (Non-married) 1.372 6.053 24.67 0.959 3.437 16.62

HEAD (Non-heads) 1.121 5.330 20.15 1.245 3.804 21.58

OCC

(Non-professionals,

non-associate

professionals) -2.128 -5.257 -38.25 -0.667 -1.379* -11.56

ES (Non-employees) 0.218 0.974* 3.92 1.112 3.669 19.27

SIZEb/1000 0.492 1.940+ 8.85 -2.855 -8.378 -49.46

SIZE*a/1000 2.937 7.702 52.79 3.150 6.729 54.58

∆ GDP*b 0.057 3.706 1.02 0.158 7.871 2.74

∆ GDP*a -0.240 -12.255 -4.32 -0.315 -8.583 -5.46

SHOCK 20.221 6.591 15.47 74.706 13.082 58.05

Nagelkerke R-squared 0.912 0.908

Chi-square statistic (16) 6,426.520 3,410.659

Sample size 6,906 3,785

* insignificant at 5% level.

+ significant at 10% level.

n.a. : not applicable

Note : For the SHOCK variable, the elasticity measure is used. The elasticity of mobility w.r.t. a change in

the sectoral shock is measured as: elasticity = marginal effect / p = β x p(1-p)/p. For males, elasticity =

20.221 x 0.235(0.765)/0.235 = 15.47. For females, elasticity = 74.706 x 0.223(0.777)/0.223 = 58.05.

Lifetime Earnings

For the pooled sample analyses of chapter 9, the effects of the individuals‟ lifetime earnings

streams, as captured by the wage growth terms, were found to differ between sectors. The

probability of moving was raised by higher wage growth in the new sector. For the original

sector‟s wage growth, a move out of the original sector was less likely if the original

sector‟s permanent earnings were higher. The separate analyses undertaken by gender

mirrored these results.

Male workers were more likely to move to the new sector for higher permanent earnings.

For a unit increase in income growth, male mobility increased by 13 percentage points.

Similarly, lifetime earnings in the new sector exerted a positive impact on female mobility

315

behaviour. Females were 19 percentage points more likely to enter into the new sector for

every unit increase in wage growth.

For the original sector, lower lifetime earnings induce male workers to change sectors. For

every unit decrease in income growth, men are 7.33 percentage points more likely to move.

The deterrent effect was also evident among women: women were 3.97 percentage points

more likely to change sectors for every unit decline in the growth rate.

From this examination of the results for the monetary variables, it can be concluded that

both men and women are motivated by the initial monetary gains and are equally

responsive to the prospect of earning higher lifetime incomes in the new sector. The extent

of the impact of lifetime income is also greater in the new sector than the old sector,

judging from the magnitude of the parameter estimates and the marginal effects. The

gender analyses therefore supports one of the predictions of the Le and Miller (1998)

model, that individuals move to alternative employment states in anticipation of higher

lifetime earnings. It also confirms the expectation that higher earnings in the new sector act

as a pull factor and lower earnings in the original industry act as a push factor for male and

female mobility. The consistency of the findings for males and females is reassuring, from

the perspective of informing on the robustness of the results.

10.5.2 Macroeconomic Variables

The macroeconomic variables included in this empirical analysis are the unemployment

rates in the original and new industries. The results obtained for the study of males and

females in the Korean labour market do not appear to have any direct counterparts in the

literature; hence only comparisons with general, aggregate-level, studies can be provided

below.

Sectoral Unemployment Rate

In the analysis of chapter 9, where the sample was pooled across males and females, the

original sector‟s unemployment rate had a positive effect on sectoral mobility. Similarly, in

316

the analyses disaggregated by gender, the old sector‟s unemployment rate had a positive

impact on the likelihood of both males and females moving across sectors. For males, the

marginal effect of a one percentage point increase in the unemployment rate was 8.57

percentage points. For females, the marginal effect was 17.97 percentage points. Thus, it

appears that the original sector‟s unemployment rate acts as a push factor of mobility.

For the new sector‟s lagged unemployment rate, the separate analyses for males and

females replicate the overall sample result that the odds of a move to the new sector are

lowered the higher the new sector‟s unemployment rate. For male workers the marginal

effect was 6.58 percentage points. For female workers, the marginal effect was 24.27

percentage points for every one percent increase in the unemployment rate8. The Table

10.3 results are consistent with the Todarian hypothesis, which asserts a negative

relationship between the unemployment rate and the probability of gaining employment.

These findings for males and females are internally consistent in that lower job

opportunities lead to out-mobility from the old sector and deter mobility into the new

sector. The results for Ub,t-1 (U*a,t-1) also held when U*a,t-1 (Ub,t-1) was omitted from the

estimating gender equations. These features, and the similarity with the findings reported

in chapter 9, point to the results with respect to the macroeconomic variables being quite

robust.

10.5.3 Worker Characteristics

Gender differences in the impact of a number of worker characteristics, i.e. age, job tenure,

family indicators, employment/occupational status and educational attainment variables, are

of interest. Several recent studies have focused on these issues, and they afford a basis,

albeit limited, for comparison in this section. Where applicable, these comparisons will be

highlighted.

Age

The analyses conducted for the pooled sample indicated a non-linear, negative age-mobility

relationship. As noted above, the preliminary examination of the data indicated that the

317

mobility-age relationship for the separate male and female samples were linear. Consistent

with the aggregate-level analysis, however, these relationships were also negative. Among

men, the chances of moving decreased by 0.84 percentage points per additional year of age.

Among women, the probability of moving sectors declined by 0.74 percentage points for

every extra year of age. These gender findings correspond with the negative age-mobility

correlation for males in Osberg, Gordon and Lin (1994) and for females in 1985/1986 in

Osberg (1991). As noted before, this relationship is generally held to arise as older workers

have a shorter working period over which they can derive benefits from a different job

[Creedy and Thomas (1982)] and, due to the experience and knowledge they have acquired

in the original job/sector, they face greater costs in moving [Jovanovic and Moffitt (1990)].

Job Tenure

The analysis of the data pooled across the male and female samples revealed a non-linear,

generally negative tenure-mobility relation. When the analyses were undertaken separately

for males and females, however, the relationship between mobility and job tenure for males

was linear and negative, while that for females was statistically insignificant. However, for

consistency with the analyses for males, a linear specification was used in the estimating

equation for females.

Male workers with lengthy tenures were less likely to switch sectors, with their propensity

to move reducing by 1.10 percentage points per extra year of tenure. This finding conforms

with other studies for males: Osberg (1991), Osberg, Gordon and Lin (1994) and Neal

(1995) all reported a negative tenure effect. However, the insignificant tenure effect for

females differs from Osberg‟s (1991) study, which showed females to have lower mobility

probabilities with rising tenure.

Various suggestions for the difference in the impact of tenure on the mobility behaviour of

males and females can be advanced. These include a greater importance of firm-specific

training for male workers than for female workers, and, in general, a higher opportunity

cost of moving sectors for male workers than for their female counterparts. This could

arise from a higher proportion of older male workers with lengthy tenures holding senior

318

positions, and the high wages of their senior positions, in addition to other non-pecuniary

benefits, may not be readily available in the new sector.

Family Indicators: Marital Status and Household Head

The preliminary analyses in chapter 9 of the data pooled across males and females showed

that marital status was not a significant determinant of the propensity to change sectors.

The marital status variable was subsequently omitted from the estimating equation. The

separate analyses conducted for men and women, however, revealed marital status to be a

significant determinant of mobility. Whilst married men were 24.67 percentage points less

likely than their non-married counterparts to switch industries, females were 16.62

percentage points less likely than their non-married counterparts to change sectors. This

result for males is in line with Neal (1995), who shows married men to have lower

propensities of moving sectors. However, it differs from results reported by Osberg (1991)

for 1982/1983 and 1985/1986, and Osberg, Gordon and Lin (1994), where marital status

did not have a significant effect on sectoral mobility. The finding for females in the current

study, to the extent that married women have greater household responsibilities, comes

across as intuitively reasonable. However, the finding for females does not concur with

Osberg‟s (1991) study, where marital status did not impact on female sectoral mobility in

any of the three phases, 1980/1981, 1982/1983 and 1985/1986, for which the statistical

analyses were undertaken.

In the analysis for the entire sample of workers, heads of households had a lower incidence

of industrial mobility. Given the considerably higher proportion of male heads in the

sample, it is not surprising that this impact is mirrored in male mobility behaviour. Male

heads were 20.15 percentage points less likely to change sectors than males who were not

the household head. This finding aligns with the study of Fallick (1993), which revealed

unemployed male heads to have a lower incidence of industrial mobility, and supports the

view of household heads facing greater risks from an industrial switch arising from their

family responsibilities. Household head status also showed up as a significant deterrent of

female mobility, with the marginal effect being 21.58 percentage points. This could be due

to the fact that females heading households are single parents who are not able to afford to

incur the risks of changing sectors. A breakdown of the data revealed that nearly three-

319

fifths of the 840 female household heads in the sample were single, divorced, widowed or

separated.

Educational Attainment

In the previous chapter where the sample was pooled across male and female workers,

educational attainment was shown to have a significant impact on sectoral mobility, with

graduates being less likely to switch sectors. The preliminary analyses conducted for males

and females revealed that little, if any, of the variation in male or female mobility could be

attributed to educational attainment. The insignificant education variable was therefore

omitted from the estimating equation used in this chapter. The finding for males reported

here is consistent with Osberg, Gordon and Lin (1994) and Neal (1995). In this earlier

study, male elementary/diploma and university degree holders had similar rates of mobility.

There is no readily apparent reason for the different findings for the aggregate-level

analysis and these estimations undertaken on the separate male and female datasets, other

than the size of the sample. In this regard it is noted that the „t‟ on the educational

attainment variable in the aggregate-level analysis was typically around 2, and a halving of

the sample would itself reduce this value by around one-third in the preliminary analysis.

Occupational Status

Occupational status was shown to be an insignificant determinant of mobility in the overall

sample in chapter 9, and the variable was omitted from main set of analyses in that chapter.

The disaggregated gender analysis revealed a similar finding for women. Thus, among

Korean females, occupational status did not exert any impact on gender mobility. This

finding is consistent with the some of the results reported by Osberg (1991), where the

likelihood of a sectoral change was not significantly different for women in clerical and

sales occupations in 1982/1983 and for female managers, professionals and technicians in

1980/1981.

In the analyses undertaken separately in this thesis for males, however, skilled workers had

a higher likelihood of moving sectors, with their chances being 38.25 percentage points

greater than that of their unskilled counterparts. This finding is consistent with the results

320

in Osberg (1991), where men in the higher-skilled managerial/professional/technical

occupations were found to have a higher probability of mobility for 1980/1981. This

finding for males in Korea supports the view of skill levels being vital to certain industries‟

operations [Neal (1995)] and workers with vital skills will be more likely to switch to

industries requiring such skills. Also, the finding supports the idea of skilled workers being

scouted for their talent and productivity [Murphy and Topel (1990)] and they will

consequently have a higher likelihood of switching sectors. The finding for females,

however, reflects mobility stickiness. Skilled females could be in more specialized

occupations which limit their range of alternatives and thus results in limited mobility.

Employment Status

In the analysis of the data pooled across males and females, non-employees had a greater

likelihood than employees of moving to new sectors/industries. This finding was replicated

in the analysis for females. Specifically, females who were non-employees were 19.27

percentage points more likely than employees to move across sectors. Among males,

however, employment status did not have a significant effect on mobility. It is not clear

why this variable should have different effects for men and women. The Asian Financial

Crisis adversely affected businesses and caused many employers/business owners to close

down. It could be that female employers/business owners were more likely to be in small

firms: such businesses have emerged as significant avenues for the economic empowerment

of women in the Asia-Pacific, as their flexibility in operations with minimum technology

and capital start-ups, and family-based nature favour women‟s decision to participate in the

labour force9. With limited access to resources and business networks, however, these

small businesses may have been more vulnerable and the hardest hit by the Crisis. The

mobility literature does not provide any evidence in this regard.

10.5.4 Industry Characteristics

The industry characteristics considered for inclusion in the model of sectoral mobility are

industry size and sectoral performance. Whilst the findings linking industry size to sectoral

mobility in the separate samples of males and females can be compared with findings from

the empirical literature, no comparison appears possible for sectoral performance.

321

Sectoral Size

In the previous chapter, the aggregate-level analyses revealed that a larger size of the

original sector reduced the probability of a sectoral move. This result carried over to the

separate study of female workers. The elasticity of female mobility with respect to an

increase in the size of the original sector was -2.22. In contrast, the original sector size

increased the likelihood of male mobility, with the corresponding elasticity of mobility at

0.38. The finding for males contradicts that in Neal (1995), where it was reported that the

industry size had a negative effect on mobility (although the study pertains to displaced

workers).

To account for the contrasting results between men and women, the female variable for the

original sectoral size was placed into the estimating equation for males. The coefficient of

this alternative variable was negative but insignificant, compared to the positive one when

the male variable was used. This suggests that a reason for the conflicting results is the

gender differences in the industrial composition, with males being concentrated in the

construction sector and females being concentrated in the commerce sector and in

community, social and personal services industries. In other words, it is not so much size

per se that is important, but it is the size of particular sectors of the economy.

The aggregate-level analyses also indicated that the probability of a sectoral move was

higher the larger the size of the new sector, and it was suggested that Korean workers

moved for greater employment opportunities. The separate analyses for males and females

reinforce this result. The elasticity of mobility in response to an increase in the new sector

size for females (2.45) was slightly larger than for males (2.25). This finding corresponds

with Osberg, Gordon and Lin (1994), where a positive association between male mobility

and industry size was reported, and it portrays the idea of workers moving in response to

employment availabilities in the new sector.

Sectoral Performance

The GDP by sector variable cannot be constructed separately for men and women. Hence

differences between men and women in this variable will only reflect gender differences in

322

the distribution of workers across industries. The earlier study of the overall sample showed

that stronger growth in the original sector raised the likelihood of a sectoral move.

Likewise, the gender studies replicated this finding, with higher growth in the original

sector increasing the probabilities of both male and female mobility, with the marginal

effects being 1.02 percentage points for males and 2.74 percentage points for females. As

in the case of the result from the study of the pooled sample, it appears that both male and

female mobility support the jobless growth hypothesis. This may be associated with the

technological advances in Korea, where the high-performing original sector has limited job

vacancies associated with the growth thereby leading to higher out-mobility rates.

For the new sector, better performance reduced the likelihood of a sectoral switch in the

aggregate-level analyses, and the disaggregated analyses conducted here revealed similar

results for both males and females. That is, a higher (lower) GDP growth rate reported in

the new industry decreased (increased) the probability of moving industries for males and

females. The marginal effects were -4.32 percentage points for males and -5.46 percentage

points for females. These findings are consistent with the jobless growth hypothesis, where

the high-performing new sectors with technological advancements have fewer job

opportunities, and hence the chances of a sectoral switch to the new sectors are lowered.

10.5.5 Sectoral Shock

The effect of the sectoral shock was large, positive, and significant for the overall

workforce. This result was mirrored in the analyses conducted for the separate samples of

males and females. The elasticity of mobility with respect to a change in the sectoral shock

variable was 15.47 for males and 58.05 for females. This finding for males is similar to the

result reported by Jovanovic and Moffitt (1990), who demonstrated the sectoral shock to

have a positive impact on the probability of male sectoral mobility10

. When this exogenous

sector shock variable was omitted from the regressions, the fit under the male model

dropped from 0.912 to 0.905, and that under the female model dropped from 0.908 to

0.761. It can thus be seen that the effect of the sectoral shock variable is greater among

female workers than among male workers, which is also reflected in the gender difference

in the coefficients of the sectoral shock variable given in Table 10.3.

323

10.6 A GENDER PERSPECTIVE ON THEORIES OF SECTORAL MOBILITY

The objective of this section is to assess the empirical relevance of the three theories of

sectoral mobility outlined earlier to the separate samples of male and female workers. The

tests of null hypothesis under each theory are the same as in the previous chapter.

10.6.1 Worker-Employer Mismatch Theory

With the regression for males, the t-statistic for the coefficient of the industrial shock, θ,

was 6.60. With the regression for females, the t-statistic for H0: θ = 0 was 13.08. Thus, the

null hypothesis of H0: θ = 0 is rejected for both gender groups. That is, the sectoral shock

is a significant factor in accounting for both male and female mobility patterns. For the

Korean workforce, gender models that are based on the worker-employer mismatch theory

and disregard the sectoral shock effect on mobility would be inadequate in accounting for

sectoral labour movements.

10.6.2 Sectoral Shock Theory

From the results displayed in Table 10.3, fourteen variables in the equation for males are

significantly different from zero at the 5% level. The chi-square statistics for the test of

whether all the non-sectoral shock variables add to the explanatory power of the model was

4,339. This exceeds the critical value and so the null hypothesis that these non-sectoral

shock variables are not important is rejected. The pure sectoral shock theory cannot be

applied to the study of male mobility. For the regression for females, there were fourteen

significant variables at the 5% level. The test of the null that all the non-sectoral shock

variables did not contribute to the explanatory power of the model yielded a test statistic of

1,599, which is far higher than the critical value. As in the case of the study of male

mobility, the pure sectoral shock theory is not applicable to the analysis of female mobility

behaviour.

324

10.6.3 Bridging Theory

Table 10.3 shows that the monetary, macroeconomic, demographic, socio-economic and

sectoral shock variables are significant in explaining male and female mobility. The

mismatch theory (i.e. testing H0 : θ = 0) and sectoral shock theory (i.e. testing H0 : β1 = β2

….. = βk = 0) are rejected for both groups and it appears that gender movements are best

described using the bridging theory.

The validity of these results was checked using the approach along the lines of the

Jovanovic and Moffitt‟s (1990) method that was discussed in Chapter 9. This involved

regressing the probability of a sectoral move on the standard error of the log wage

distribution and the sectoral shock. The wage and sectoral shock measures were significant

for both the male and female regressions, as shown in Table 10.4. It can be concluded,

therefore, that the bridging theory of sectoral mobility, that was previously held to apply to

the pooled data regression, applies also to the study of male and female mobility.

Table 10.4 Logistic Regression of Sectoral/Industrial Mobility on the Standard

Error of Wage Distribution and Sectoral Shock for Males and Females Variable Coefficient t-statistic

Male Regression

Constant -7.714 -42.810 Standard Error of ln(original industry wage) 3.167 25.256 Standard Error of Sectoral Shock 19.134 28.542 Nagelkerke‟s R-squared 0.498 Female Regression Constant -7.580 -28.128 Standard Error of ln(original industry wage) 2.778 12.518 Standard Error of Sectoral Shock 17.371 23.036 Nagelkerke‟s R-squared 0.622

Source: KLIPS dataset

Whilst the model specification of the above approach is similar to Jovanovic and Moffitt

(1990), the method is not a direct application in terms of data (4 years for the Korean case

compared with 13 years), difference in the sectoral shock variable (i.e. cross-sectoral

measure in this case), estimation of the probability function for males and females using

data for the entire sample period rather than using a series of sub-periods. With regards to

325

the latter, the current application was based on the male and female datasets of 6,906 and

3,785 observations respectively. Jovanovic and Moffitt (1990), however, estimated the

probability function for a typical worker for each period with the number of observations in

parentheses: 1966-1968 (492), 1967-1969 (628), 1968-1970 (754), 1969-1971 (887), 1971-

1973 (1,357), 1973-1975 (1,846), 1976-1978 (2,032) and 1978-1980 (1,967).

10.7 DECOMPOSITION ANALYSIS

The empirical analysis in the preceding section examined the determinants of sectoral

mobility by gender using a logit model developed from equations (10.1) and (10.2). Male

and female workers in Korea have different mobility behaviour, in that their sectoral

mobility is influenced by different sets of explanatory variables, and by different amounts

for particular explanatory variables. In particular, there is a statistically significant

difference in the intercept coefficients of the male and female regressions as well as in the

coefficients of the majority of the explanatory variables, namely, the monetary variables,

lagged new sector‟s unemployment rate, GDP growth, employee status, tenure, old sector

size, new sector performance and sectoral shock (Table 10.1). The aim of this section is

therefore to explore these gender differences more formally and in greater depth via a

decomposition technique.

From equations (10.1) and (10.2), the predicted probability of moving sectors for males (m)

and females (f) can be expressed as:

^ ^

movem = 1 / (1 + e-Im) , where Im = Xm βm

for males, and for females as:

^ ^

movef = 1 / (1 + e-If) , where If = Xf βf .

In this formulation, X is the all-encompassing vector of explanatory variables, including ^

the constant, and β is the associated logit regression coefficients. These two equations

indicate that the differences in the probability of a worker, male or female, moving will be

linked to differences in either the values of the explanatory variables or the estimated logit

326

coefficients. Differences in the latter will be due to the personal preferences of males and

females in their demand for sectors, or employer/industry preferences to recruit/retain male

or female workers. The aim of the decomposition explored in this section is to link

differences in the mobility rates of males and females to differences in the estimated logit

coefficients, and to differences between males and females in the values of the explanatory

variables.

This type of decomposition is widely used in the gender discrimination literature. It has its

intellectual roots in the studies of Blinder (1973) and Oaxaca (1973). These earlier studies

were based on regression equations estimated by ordinary least squares, and refinements

are necessary in this application to accommodate the non-linear, non-separable nature of

the logit model. These refinements are outlined in section 10.7.2. The results of the

decomposition analysis are presented in section 10.7.3.

10.7.1 An Overview of the Standard Decomposition Technique

Consider a linear probability mobility model, where the mobility outcome M takes the

value of 1 if a change of sectors occurs and 0 otherwise. The mobility outcome, evaluated

at the sample mean values of the regression variables, can be expressed as:

_ _ ^ Mm = Xm βm (10.3) _ _ ^

Mf = Xf βf (10.4) _ _

where for males (m) and females (f), Mm and Mf denote the average probability of _ _

sectoral mobility, Xm and Xf are the sample mean values of characteristics, and

^ ^

βm and βf are the estimates from the linear probability models.

If females receive the same return to their characteristics as males, the average hypothetical

mobility outcome for females will be:

_ _ ^

Mf* = Xf βm (10.5)

To obtain the impact of endowments on the difference in the average mobility outcomes

between males and females, equation (10.5) is subtracted from equation (10.3) to give

327

equation (10.6). The impact of the estimated coefficients on the difference in the mobility

outcome in equation (10.7) is derived by subtracting equation (10.4) from equation (10.5).

_ _ _ _ ^ Mm - Mf* = (Xm - Xf ) βm (10.6)

_ _ _ ^ ^ Mf* - Mf = Xf ( βm - βf ) (10.7)

The decomposition of the overall gap between the male and female outcomes can be

derived by adding equations (10.6) and (10.7) to give

_ _ _ _ ^ _ ^ ^

Mm - Mf = (Xm - Xf ) βm + Xf ( βm – βf ) (10.8)

The first component of the decomposition on the right-hand side of the above equation is

the part of the gap on the left-hand side due to differences in the endowments of males and

females. The second part is attributed to differences between males and females in the

parameter estimates. Equation (10.8) can be considered to be the standard model for

decomposition of differences in the labour market outcomes of males and females.

10.7.2 Application to Logit Models

The decomposition technique outlined above requires the underlying regression model to

be additive. It can be used with a linear probability model. However, modifications are

needed if the technique is to be used in conjunction with a logit or probit model. In the case

of these non-linear probability models (logit, probit), an appropriate method is the Farber

(1990) procedure. The starting point for this method is the average predicted probability

P(Xi βi) for the sample of individuals (i = males, females). This can be expressed as:

^ n ^

P(Xi βi) = 1/n ∑ F (Xij βi) (10.9) j=1

^

where Xij is a vector of the characteristics of the jth

individual in the ith

sample, βi is the logit

estimates from the sample dataset for group i, n is the number of individuals in the sample

and F( . ) is the cumulative distribution function. Applying this notation, the difference in

^ ^

the probability of sectoral mobility between males and females, i.e. P(Xmβm) - P(Xf βf), can

be decomposed as:

328

^ ^ ^ ^ ^ ^

P(Xmβm) - P(Xf βf) = [P(Xmβf) - P(Xf βf)] + [P(Xmβm) - P(Xmβf)] (10.10)

The first bracketed term on the right-hand side of the equation is the component of the

difference in rates of mobility of males and females due to the difference in the values of

their observable attributes, evaluated at the coefficient for females. In other words, it is the

portion of this mobility rate differential that can be explained by variations in the

characteristics of males in comparison to those of females if the mobility outcomes were

determined in accordance with the estimated female mobility behaviour. The second

bracketed term shows the portion of the mobility rate differential that is attributable to

differences between males and females in the way that each worker characteristic impacts

on mobility behaviour. This „behavioural‟ component is evaluated using the characteristic

of males. It is the unexplained component of the difference in mobility outcomes. It

generally reflects either or both of the following:

a) The difference between male and female preferences (since some parameter

estimates are for individual characteristics);

b) The unequal treatment of males and females in industry labour market practices

(since some regression coefficients are associated with industry characteristics).

The well-known index number problem in the Blinder (1973) decomposition can be

accommodated in the current study by also decomposing the differences in the probability

of sectoral mobility between males and females using:

^ ^ ^ ^ ^ ^

P(Xmβm) - P(Xf βf) = [P(Xmβm) - P(Xf βm)] + [P(Xfβm) - P(Xfβf)] (10.11)

This decomposition simply uses different weights from that outlined in equation (10.10).

Compared to the earlier method, the mobility rate differential due to differences in male

and female characteristics (i.e. first bracketed term on the right-hand side of the equation) is

evaluated as if the mobility outcomes were determined by the equation estimates for males

instead of those for females. That is, the explained difference due to gender differences in

characteristics is evaluated using the coefficients for males. In terms of the unexplained

difference (i.e. second bracketed term on the right-hand side of the equation), equation

(10.11) uses the endowments for females rather than those of males as the weighting

variable. Thus, the component gives the difference between the mobility outcomes of

329

males and females that is due to differences in the preferences of the two groups and/or the

unequal treatment of males and females by industry sources, evaluated using the

characteristics for female workers.

For the current research, the decomposition of the difference in the sectoral mobility rates

of males and females will be conducted using both equations (10.10) and (10.11).

10.7.3 Decomposition Results

The data for the application of the decomposition methods are from the same KLIPS

sample datasets for males and females used in the multivariate analyses presented earlier in

this chapter. The difference in the average probabilities of sectoral mobility can be

obtained from Table 10.2 or computed using the algorithm in the left-hand side of

equations (10.10) and (10.11). The explained and unexplained components were computed

using the estimated β coefficients and associated characteristics of each person in the

particular (male or female) sample. The terms on the right-hand side of equations (10.10)

and (10.11) were obtained as follows. First, predicted values for each individual were

computed for the male sample, where the characteristics for each record were multiplied by

the estimated βm and βf.

^ ^ These values were divided by the male sample size to give P(Xmβm) and P(Xmβf).

Likewise, from the female sample, the characteristics for every female record was

multiplied by the estimated βm and βf and predicted probabilities of mobility obtained.

^ ^ The average of these predicted values over the female sample gives P(Xfβm) and P(Xfβf).

Table 10.5 presents the decompositions of the difference in the average probability of

mobility between males and females. The left-hand panel of this table is for equation

(10.10) and the right-hand panel is for equation (10.11). As noted in section 10.4, males

have a 1.2 percentage point higher probability of mobility than females. This is the figure

presented in the first row of the Table (i.e. 0.012).

330

Table 10.5 Decomposition Results Variable Equation (10.10):

Farber Method

Equation (10.11):

Farber Method

Total Difference

P(Xmβm)-P(Xfβf)

0.012

0.012

Total Explained (due to characteristics)

P(Xmβf)-P(Xfβf)

P(Xmβm)-P(Xfβm)

-0.037

-0.113

Total Unexplained (due to coefficients)

P(Xmβm)-P(Xmβf)

P(Xfβm)-P(Xfβf)

0.049

0.125

Source : KLIPS gender datasets

The explained component is the portion due entirely to the differential between the

observed attributes of males and females. This component is negative under both methods,

but of different magnitude. If the mobility outcomes were determined according to the

estimates obtained for females, the probability of moving sectors for males would be 3.7

percentage points less than that of their female counterparts. If the mobility outcomes were

evaluated according to the estimates obtained for males, the endowment effect would be

-11.3. That is, ceteris paribus, the probability of switching sectors for males would be 11.3

percentage points less than that of females. This means that males have relatively less of

those characteristics associated with higher probabilities of moving in the logit model, and

they have relatively more of those characteristics associated with lower probabilities of

moving in the statistical analyses presented in Table 10.3.

The unexplained portion of the decomposition is positive under the two methods. It is 0.049

when equation (10.10) is used and 0.125 when equation (10.11) is used. In other words, for

the same set of male (or female) characteristics, males are more likely to switch sectors

than females. The results of the unexplained difference under both methods suggest that

the sectoral mobility behaviour of males is more sensitive to changes in worker and/or

industry circumstances than is the case for females. This either points towards differences

in preferences (e.g. males have stronger desire to change sectors, females prefer to remain

in the same sector owing to family commitments) or the unequal treatment in industry

practices between the sexes (e.g. employer reluctance to recruit females).

331

The greater ceteris paribus sectoral mobility among male workers in Korea than among

their female counterparts could be consistent with several scenarios. First, sectoral mobility

may be „good‟ in that it is associated with economic progress, and employers in the new

sector may be nepotistic towards males or discriminatory towards females in Korea.

Second, sectoral mobility may be „bad‟, being forced upon workers as a result of adverse

events. In this case, males may simply prefer to risk changing sectors whilst their female

counterparts may simply prefer to avoid the risks of a sectoral switch.

10.7.4 Explanatory Power of Observed Variables

The decomposition presented above does not assess the portion of the explained difference

attributable to each of the observed characteristics. Several studies have examined the

explanatory power of the individual observed characteristics, including Even and

Macpherson (1993), Doiron and Riddell (1994) and Nielsen (1998). This study adopts the

method of Even and Macpherson (1993). The portion of the explained difference from

equation (10.10) due to differences between males and females in the kth

explanatory

variable can be defined as:

_ ^ _ ^ _ _ ^ _ _ ^

[P(Xmβf)-P(Xfβf)] x [(Xmk – Xfk) βfk]/[(Xm – Xf) βf] (10.12)

_ ^ _ ^

where [P(Xmβf) - P(Xfβf)] is the explained difference evaluated at the coefficients for

^ _ _

females (βf) and, for the kth

explanatory variable, Xmk and Xfk are the mean values for

^

males and females, respectively, and βfk is the respective logit coefficient from the female

regression.

The method of Even and Macpherson (1993) can be modified to examine the explained

difference as per equation (10.11). Given that the explained difference is determined from

_ ^ _ ^

[P(Xmβm) - P(Xfβm)], the male regression coefficient is used in place of the female one.

That is, the portion of the explained difference due to the gender difference in the kth

explanatory variable can be written as:

_ ^ _ ^ _ _ ^ _ _ ^

[P(Xmβm)-P(Xfβm)] x [(Xmk – Xfk) βmk]/[(Xm – Xf) βm] (10.13)

332

^

where βmk is the respective logit coefficient from the male regression.

Table 10.6 shows the portion of the total explained difference that is attributed to each

explanatory variable. The overall explained gender difference in the mobility propensity

from equation (10.10) is -0.037. A substantial portion is linked to the new sector wage

growth, followed by the new and old sector lagged unemployment, sectoral shock, new

sector size, old sector wage growth, old sector size, sectoral wage differential, new and old

sector performance, age and job tenure. Under equation (10.11), the overall explained

gender difference in the probability of mobility is -0.113. The ranking in terms of

explanatory power is as follows: new and old sector wage growth, followed by the new

sector size, old sector lagged unemployment, new sector lagged unemployment, sectoral

shock, old sector performance, old sector size, job tenure, age, sectoral wage differential

and new sector performance.

Table 10.6 Explanatory Power of Observed Characteristics in Decomposition Variable Explanatory Power

Equation (10.10) Equation (10.11)

Total Explained

P(Xmβf)-P(Xfβf)

P(Xmβm)-P(Xfβm)

-0.037

-0.113

Portion Explained by:

ln(pya)p-lnyb

p 0.001 0.002

g*p

at -0.036 -0.116

g*p

bt -0.006 -0.053

U*a,t-1 -0.014 -0.018

Ub,t-1 0.009 0.021

AGE -0.001 -0.004

TENURE 0.000 -0.005

SIZEb/1000 -0.004 0.005

SIZE*a/1000 0.007 0.045

∆ GDPb -0.001 0.012

∆ GDP*a 0.001 -0.001

SHOCK -0.008 -0.014

Note: As the MS, HEAD, ES and OCC are dummy variables, their mean values are zero, the

explanatory powers cannot be computed.

Although the rankings of the explanatory power of the individual characteristics in

accounting for the explained difference differ for equations (10.10) and (10.11), there are

common notable patterns:

333

(a) The new and old sector wage growths account for a considerable portion of the

gender difference, as compared to the sectoral wage differential. This implies

that expected lifetime incomes play a greater role than the expected wage

sectoral wage differential in accounting for the gender difference.

(b) The individual characteristics of age and job tenure have considerably lower

explanatory power as they rank below the monetary, macroeconomic, monetary

and most sector-level variables.

(c) The sectoral shock contributes only a moderate amount to the explained

component, meaning that unanticipated events play some, albeit, slight, role in

the difference between the male and female mobility outcomes.

Finally, it is noted that the negativity of the total explained difference reinforces certain

patterns in the data. It supports the conclusion that men have relatively less of those

characteristics associated with higher probabilities of moving (Xm < Xf and βk > 0), as

depicted from the new sector wage growth, the old sector performance and the sectoral

shock under both equations (10.10) and (10.11), and relatively more of those characteristics

associated with lower probabilities of moving (Xm > Xf and βk < 0), as seen from the new

sector unemployment rate, old sector wage growth and age and job tenure. However, there

are other patterns which reinforce the data for females. First, women with relatively low

mean values in the observable attributes are associated with higher probabilities of mobility

(Xm > Xf and βk > 0), as is the case for the sectoral wage differential and old sector

unemployment rate. Second, women with relatively higher mean values in their attributes

are associated with lower likelihoods of switching sectors (Xm < Xf and βk < 0), as seen in

the new sector performance. Nonetheless, given the higher number of variables supporting

the effect for males (7) as compared to that for females (3), this implies that the reinforcing

effect for males is stronger than that for females in accounting for the total explained

difference.

334

10.8 CONCLUDING REMARKS

This chapter has extended the study of the determinants of inter-industry mobility by

considering males and females separately. The same empirical model and dataset that were

employed in chapter 9 are used for this disaggregated analysis. In general, the complexity

of this form of mobility for both males and females manifests itself in the array of

monetary, macroeconomic, demographic and socio-economic and sectoral shock variables

which were found to exert significant influences. The mobility patterns of both males and

females appear to be consistent with the bridging theory of sectoral mobility.

The results of the initial, expected and future monetary factors from the pooled dataset were

reflected in the analyses conducted separately for males and females. The mobility

decisions of both men and women are sensitive to the expectation of earning higher

incomes in the new sector. The future earnings potential also has a strong influence for

both males and females. Whilst the prospect of higher lifetime earnings entices workers

into the new sector, lower future wages induces out-mobility from workers‟ original sector

of employment. In general, it can be concluded that the results for males and females

support the theoretical model that places emphasis on the role that monetary factors play in

determining worker mobility across sectors. The consistency of the results for males and

females is appealing in terms of informing the importance of the monetary incentive in

inter-sectoral mobility decisions.

The higher the new industry‟s unemployment rate, the lower the likelihood of mobility for

the overall workforce. The separate analyses conducted for males and females mirrored

this result. This implied inverse relationship between the new sector‟s unemployment rate

and the probability of gaining new employment and the idea of workers moving for higher

expected gains suggests some alignment of the results of this chapter with the Todarian

hypothesis. The original sector‟s unemployment rate acts as a push factor of male and

female mobility, with a higher unemployment rate leading to out-mobility.

The majority of the results for worker characteristics from the analyses of the data pooled

across males and females carried across to the analyses conducted separately for males and

females. Among males, the variables where this was the case were age, tenure and head of

335

household status. Thus, among male workers, the industry movers tended to be younger,

skilled, non-married, non-heads of households with shorter work experience. Educational

attainment and employment status did not appear to exert any influence on male mobility.

Among females, the results for age, head of household status and employment status were

the same as for the aggregate-level analysis. Female industry movers tended to be younger,

single/widowed/separated/divorced, non-employees and non-heads of households.

Educational attainment, occupational status and job tenure were insignificant variables in

the study of female mobility.

In terms of sector size, the pooled data analyses suggested that Korean workers tend to be

squeezed out from the smaller sized sectors and enter into larger ones. Whilst this entry

behaviour carries over to both males and females, the exit tendency is evident among

female workers only. These results support the idea of worker mobility being affected by

job opportunities. The overall workforce is also more likely to exit from high-performance

industries. However, high-performance sectors are not associated with higher „in‟ mobility

rates. The deterrence of entry into the better performing industries reported in chapter 9 is

mirrored in the disaggregated analyses of the current chapter, and it is consistent with the

so-called jobless growth hypothesis. However, since there are no data on sectoral

performance disaggregated by gender, this interpretation should be treated with some

caution.

The sectoral shock has been shown to be a highly influential determinant of industrial

mobility in the pooled sample, accounting for a large portion of sectoral movements from

1998 to 2001. The analyses disaggregated by gender conducted in this chapter revealed that

shocks were highly significant in each set of analyses, although the influence appears to be

stronger on female mobility.

The regressions undertaken separately for males and females point towards differences in

the determinants of their sectoral mobility. The results of the decomposition presented in

section 10.7 show that male workers in Korea have higher average propensities to switch

sectors than their female counterparts. The explained difference reveals males to have

relatively less (more) of those characteristics associated with higher (lower) probabilities of

changing sectors in the logit model of mobility. The variable that has the greatest

336

explanatory power under both decomposition methods employed is the new sector wage

growth. The unexplained difference showed that for the same set of given male (or female)

endowments, male workers have a greater likelihood of changing sectors than their female

counterparts. That is, in terms of sectoral mobility behaviour, males are more sensitive to

changes in worker and/or industry characteristics than females.

This chapter improves the current understanding of the determinants of male and female

sectoral mobility. The major contribution lies in the study to the lesser-researched labour

markets of Asia, South Korea in this case, and in the more informative approach towards

examining the gender differences in labour market outcomes via decomposition techniques.

Endnotes:

1. This technique has been used in comparisons of gender groups [Blinder (1973), Blinder (1976), Oaxaca

(1973) and Cotton (1988)], unionized/non-unionised groups [Farber (1990) and Even and Macpherson

(1993)] and racial groups [Masters (1974), Smith and Welch (1989) and Reimers (1983)].

2. Formerly, the pair-wise correlations for the original variables were ga versus gb (0.932 for males, 0.852 for

females), Ua,t-1 versus Ub,t-1 (0.879 for males, 0.928 for females), sizea versus sizeb (0.730 for males, 0.733 for

females) and GDPa versus GDPb (0.777 for males, 0.819 for females). The pair-wise correlations for the re-

computed variables were g*p

at versus g*p

bt (-0.404 for males and -0.202 for females), U*a,t-1 versus Ub,t-1 (0.484

for males, 0.621 for females), size*a versus sizeb (-0.206 for males, -0.255 for females) and GDP*a versus

GDPb (0.369 for males, 0.398 for females).

3. The observed tβ statistic arises from a simple regression of Y = α + βX + v, where Y is the variable in

question, α (constant term) represents the mean value for the variable for males, X is a gender dummy

variable that takes a value of 0 for males and 1 for females, and hence β is the difference between the mean Y

values of males and females, and v is the stochastic error term. The tβ statistic will indicate whether male and

female characteristics are significantly different.

4. The pooled data results in the previous chapter have shown the cross-sectoral standard error of the residuals

of an AR(1) regression to be the more appropriate indicator.

5. Owing to the smaller sample sizes, the initial industry variables were not explored in the male and female

models.

6. While the tenure variable was insignificant, it is retained in the specification to be consistent with the

model for males. To maintain the same set of explanatory variables for the decomposition analysis of the

mean outcomes of males and females, a few insignificant variables were retained in either gender model: job

tenure and occupational status for females and employment status for males.

7. The same strategies for identification are used in this chapter as were discussed for the analysis for the data

pooled across males and females in the previous chapter. First, education status was used in the estimation of

the predicted new/old sector wages, unemployment rate and lifetime wages but not in the restricted gender

mobility models. Second, the aggregation process, where the new sector variables (wages, wage growth and

unemployment rates) are aggregated across all industries other than stayers‟ original industries, minimizes the

likelihood of perfect collinearity.

8. When the lagged old and new sectors‟ unemployment rates for males were each placed into the equation

for females, the marginal effects were smaller in absolute magnitude, at 2.27 percentage points and 4.70

percentage points, respectively. Although there was a change in the directional impact of the new sector male

unemployment rate, given its smaller marginal effect, it could mean that the female unemployment rate is a

less reliable measure than the male unemployment rate.

9. Refer to: United Nations Economic and Social Commission for Asia and the Pacific (1999) „Emerging

Issues and Developments at the Regional Level: Socio-Economic Measures to Alleviate Poverty in Rural and

Urban Areas - Empowerment of Women in Asia and the Pacific‟, Fifty-Fifth Session, 22-28 Apr 1999,

Bangkok, ESCAP Paper Number 1133, Feb 1999.

10. Jovanovic and Moffitt (1990) did not study the impact of the sectoral shock on female sectoral mobility.

337

CHAPTER 11

THE SYPNOSIS

11.1 INTRODUCTION

The main aims of this thesis were to: (i) provide an in-depth understanding of sectoral

mobility; (ii) extend the coverage of the study of sectoral mobility to the lesser-researched

labour markets of Asia; (iii) provide analyses disaggregated by gender to facilitate gender

comparisons within a single dataset; and (iv) provide an empirical basis that policy makers

could use in a focus on worker mobility as a way of reducing unemployment.

There were two parts to the thesis. Part I examined sectoral mobility from the perspective

of its impact on unemployment for the Korean economy. Part II provided a detailed study

of the determinants of sectoral mobility for the overall, male and female labour forces.

This chapter is the sypnosis to the entire thesis. Section 11.2 is the summary for Part I while

section 11.3 outlines the main findings for Part II. Notable links between the two parts are

established in section 11.4. These links are used to provide directions for further research

and policy implications in the conclusion section.

11.2 PART I: SECTORAL MOBILITY AND UNEMPLOYMENT

The thesis opened with its introduction (chapter 1) and preview of Korea‟s economic

history (chapter 2). Following this, Part I (chapters 3 to 5) studied the impact sectoral

mobility had on unemployment. This covered the hypotheses related to the topic, namely,

the sectoral shift hypothesis (SSH), aggregate demand hypothesis (ADH), reallocation

timing hypothesis (RTH) and stage-of-the-business-cycle effect, from both theoretical and

empirical perspectives. It also presented an application of this line of work to the Korean

labour market.

338

The Hypotheses

The SSH was developed by Lilien (1982) who postulated that there was a direct

relationship between sectoral mobility and aggregate unemployment. Under this

hypothesis, the form of mobility which leads to unemployment was that which originated

from pure sectoral shifts purged of aggregate demand/supply disturbances, and/or sectoral

reallocations arising from a supply-side disturbance. The empirical finding from Lilien‟s

(1982) study for the U.S., undertaken for 11 economic sectors covering 1948-1980, clearly

supported his view.

Subsequent developments of the links between sectoral mobility and unemployment have

questioned the source of the mobility and have also looked at the role of past sectoral

reallocations and the stage of the business cycle. Thus, Abraham and Katz (1986) put

forward the ADH. Whilst this also maintains that there will be a positive relation between

mobility and unemployment, it was argued that the relevant form of mobility was that

predicted from aggregate demand influences. Abraham and Katz (1986) tested this

hypothesis using the same 11 economic sectors and time period used in the Lilien (1982)

study. The RTH, advanced by Davis (1987), is an extension of the SSH which

acknowledges the role of mobility on unemployment, but adds that past sectoral

reallocations of labour induced by economic shocks also lead to higher unemployment. The

stage-of-the-business-cycle effect, introduced by Mills, Pelloni and Zervoyianni (1995),

suggests a higher magnitude of increase in unemployment following sectoral mobility shifts

during recessions as compared to boom periods. So whilst the SSH is independent of

aggregate economic conditions, the latter three hypotheses stress the importance of

aggregate economic conditions in accounting for the ζ-U relationship1.

The Empirical Review and Model

Chapters 3 and 4 presented the literature review on sectoral mobility vis-à-vis

unemployment. Studies conducted in the U.S., Canada, Europe and Asia were covered.

The theoretical hypotheses were expounded in chapter 3 and the empirical studies were

reviewed in chapter 4. The theoretical portion provided insights into both conceptual and

methodological issues. Distinct differences between the hypotheses were noted, in the role

339

of sectoral mobility on unemployment, concept (i.e. source of sectoral shifts, chain of

causation and nature of unemployment) and methods of testing. Of special significance to

the empirical modelling were the different methods (regression, U-V relationship, ζ-U co-

movement approach, graphical techniques and natural unemployment rate approach) and

mobility indices (taken to be the regressors in unemployment models) adopted for each

hypothesis. Whilst tests of the SSH made use of the raw Lilien index, the supply-side

index and pure/unpredicted indices purged of aggregate demand and/or supply

disturbances, those conducted for the ADH, RTH and stage-of-the-business-cycle effect

each involved indices predicted from aggregate demand factors, the horizon covariance

index and interaction variables2.

The empirical literature revealed a widespread, though not global, acceptance of the SSH in

the North American and Asian studies based on the raw Lilien index, supply-side index and

pure indices. The divergent finding established for Europe was thought to be associated

with different sectoral sensitivities and labour market features. In particular, an inverse

relationship between mobility and unemployment was reported by Garonna and Sica (2000)

for Italy for 1952-1994 and by Saint-Paul (1997) for France over 1964-1991. In Garonna

and Sica‟s (2000) study, the divergent finding was attributed to interregional mobility,

lower cyclical sensitivity of manufacturing-services employment in the U.S. as compared to

Italy, and firing costs exceeding hiring costs. Labour market rigidities (temporary jobs,

public sector employment) that impeded worker movements to sectors with higher growth

or requiring more specialized labour was the reason cited for the atypical finding for

France. Compared to the SSH, the ADH had much less empirical support, with conflicting

results being reported by studies adopting the various forms of predictive indices. It was

only the Canadian study by Neelin (1987) which supported the ADH. The differing cyclical

responsiveness of economic sectors was once again the reason advanced for the non-

positive ζ-U relation for Italy in Garonna and Sica (2000). Palley‟s (1992) study of the

U.S. economy for nearly the same time period (1951-1988) as Abraham and Katz (1986)

reported a negative influence of predicted mobility on unemployment. It has been argued

that this finding was likely to be associated with limitations of the method of filtering the

predicted index. There is, however, empirical support for the RTH and the stage-of-the-

business-cycle effect. However, the literature dealing with these is sparse, and is

essentially confined to the originators themselves.

340

For the purpose of empirical modelling for Korea, there are several important lessons from

the empirical literature. These include the need to develop a baseline unemployment model

with a comprehensive set of explanatory variables and predictive and unpredicted mobility

indices, and the need to use rigorous econometric testing (e.g. stability and stationarity

tests) if unbiased and consistent estimates are to be obtained3.

The Mobility-Unemployment Relationship in Korea

The empirical examination for the Korean labour market of the impact of mobility on

unemployment was presented in chapter 5. It was primarily geared towards testing the

SSH, ADH, RTH and stage-of-the-business-cycle effect for Korea. A thorough econometric

procedure that involved assessing the suitability of each mobility index, considering

measurement errors, testing for stationarity, multicollinearity, structural change, model

specification, and serial correlation, and conducting regression analyses for truncated

periods was employed. Conclusions were based on the robustness of results under

alternative models. Special attention was paid to the use of dummy variables to cater for

the structural break that occurred in 1998 during the Asian Financial Crisis. This aligned

the econometric models to economic realities.

Pre-Crisis Finding

The empirical analyses revealed a general lack of applicability of the SSH, ADH and stage-

of-the-business-cycle effect for Korea for the pre-Crisis period. With regards to the RTH,

however, measurement issues associated with the horizon covariance index limited the

research that could be done in the current study.

The results for the SSH were consistent across the models based on the various predicted

index measures. Similar findings were established from the regression models for the full

data period (1971-2001) that accommodate structural change and the models for the

truncated 1971-1997 period. The lack of relevance of the ADH for Korea applied to

mobility predicted from changes in the money supply and government deficit. Hence,

neither predicted nor unpredicted sectoral mobility led to higher unemployment in the pre-

Crisis phase in Korea.

341

The analysis of the data revealed that the stage-of-the-business cycle effect did not

influence the way that pure mobility shifts impacted unemployment during the pre-Crisis

period. This finding was established for the various forms of pure mobility shifts purged of

aggregate demand and supply influences, as well as the predicted mobility arising from

changes in the money supply, government deficit and aggregate employment.

Post-Crisis Finding

If validation of the hypotheses was based on regression findings and robustness of the

results alone, then the claims of the SSH, ADH and stage-of-the-business-cycle effect are

supported during the post-Crisis period. In other words, pure mobility purged of aggregate

demand and supply influences, and mobility predicted from changes in money supply and

the public debt, led to higher unemployment in Korea.

However, it was noted in chapter 5 that too much should not be read into these conclusions.

The low number of observations for the period made statistical inference problematic, even

though there was a well-tested and comprehensive model in place. This constraint of a

limited number of observations also restricted the effective examination of the stage-of-the-

business-cycle effect, since the most pronounced business cycle in Korea‟s recent history

has not yet been complete. There is a need for further assessment of these hypotheses once

a longer time series is available.

Nonetheless, Part I ended on an optimistic note. The strength of the regression findings in

relation to the SSH/ADH was argued to demonstrate their potential for use in

unemployment policy. What had occurred in the West in the last millennium seems to be

making its mark in Asia from 1998. Therefore, the lessons learnt from the West and the

benefits of a new microeconomic policy for addressing sectoral mobility in Asia could be

immense. To address the topic of sectoral mobility, the thesis recommended a micro-level

study of the factors motivating sectoral mobility. This provided the focus for Part II of the

thesis.

342

11.3 PART II: THE FACTORS AFFECTING SECTORAL MOBILITY

Part II (chapters 6-10) focused on the factors that motivate labour mobility. It presented a

literature review on labour mobility. To obtain a broader perspective on the topic, the

review covered union/non-union, public-private sector and rural-urban mobility, as well as

the sectoral mobility that is the focus of this thesis. Part II then provided an empirical

application to the Korean economy of a model of sectoral mobility. Equations were

estimated for the overall workforce and for separate samples of male and female workers.

Building the Empirical Model

The second part (chapter 6) began by introducing a model based on Le and Miller (1998)

which marries the concepts of the expected wage differential and wait unemployment.

Moreover, rather than focus on contemporary measures, the model was based on lifetime

earnings streams. This reflects the fact that individuals maximise long-term incomes. The

model has the added ability to differentiate between the influences of income and

unemployment in the two sectors in this study. The model accommodates both monetary

and non-monetary factors as well. Chapter 6 closed with proposals for the current

empirical work. The model proposed has a dichotomous dependent variable (to be

analysed using a logit or probit procedure), with explanatory variables to cater for a range

of factors affecting sectoral mobility. It makes use of a longitudinal database, which

provides a wealth of information on worker/job characteristics and enables an assessment

of mobility covering multiple periods. The proposed model is also sufficiently general to

enable an investigation of gender differences in the determinants of sectoral mobility.

Assembling the Factors

Chapter 7 presented a review of the literature on other forms of labour mobility. This was

not exhaustive but it nevertheless supplied a number of prominent pointers for the current

work. These included the importance of including a sectoral wage differential in the

estimating equation together with the macroeconomic and non-pecuniary factors that have

been included in most studies to date. It also suggested that the macroeconomic (e.g.

343

unemployment) and non-pecuniary variables should be measured separately for the two

sectors. These suggestions were incorporated into the model estimated in chapter 9.

Chapter 8 contains the review of the sectoral mobility literature. The chapter outlined the

findings reported for a range of variables, and explored the feasibility of each variable for

inclusion in the current work. The determinants of sectoral mobility explored comprised the

monetary (overall wages, wages in the old/new sector, wage growth in the old/new sector),

macroeconomic (overall unemployment, unemployment in the old/new sector,

unemployment duration, overall economic growth, overall employment and inflation rate),

worker characteristics (age, gender, race, language, marital status, household head status,

with children indicator, formal education, on-the-job training/tenure, initial industry,

occupational status, employment status, unionization, region and alternative sources of

income), job characteristics (working hours/weeks, product/work similarity, size of old/new

industry, industry turnover and sectoral performance indicators) and sectoral shocks.

Findings from Empirical Studies

The review revealed a low degree of consistency in findings across the studies. In this

context, consistency refers to the situation where at least two studies reported a similar

result for the variable in question. Even given this rather weak definition, only about half

(i.e. eight) of the above-mentioned explanatory variables had „consistent‟ results. Among

employees, sectoral mobility was positively associated with overall wages, working hours,

size of the new industry and sectoral shocks, and negatively related with age, tenure and

unemployment duration. Among the unemployed, two variables appeared to be

systematically related to mobility in a negative manner, namely age, tenure and size of old

industry4.

In terms of male mobility, whilst age had a negative effect on mobility, unemployment

spell, employment status, working hours/weeks and size of new industry had positive

effects. For female mobility, employment status and unemployment spell were associated

with positive influences, whilst age and the overall unemployment rate affected mobility

negatively. For both groups, job tenure was associated with a negative impact while

344

marital status was typically an insignificant regressor. The other insignificant variable

included working hours/weeks for females.

Given the low level of consistency, limited number of studies spread across differing

groups (i.e. employed, unemployed, male, female, job loser/quitter) and even conflicting

hypotheses regarding the impact of most variables on sectoral mobility, clear priors

pertaining to the impact of the determinants of sectoral mobility were not established for

most variables. In this light, the choice of variables for inclusion in the current study was

based mainly on feasibility in terms of data availability from the KLIPS dataset. For the

study of overall, male and female mobility, the set of factors therefore included wages in

the old/new sector, wage growth in the old/new sector, unemployment in the old/new

sector, GDP growth, age, gender (for study on the overall workforce only), marital status,

household head status, educational status, tenure, occupational status, employment status,

initial industry, size of old/new sector, sectoral GDP growth and sectoral shock.

Building the Data/Dataset

The all-encompassing empirical modelling of the factors that motivate Korean sectoral

mobility was carried out in chapter 9. The value assigned to a good dataset for empirical

analysis should not be understated and one-sixth of the chapter was committed to

establishing the credentials of the KLIPS dataset. The micro-level KLIPS contained the

information required to construct the monetary variables and description of worker

characteristics. This was supplemented with NSO data for the macroeconomic factors, job

characteristics and sectoral shock. The combination of the micro- and macro-level data

enhanced the explanatory power of the regression.

The benefits of the KLIPS dataset included the fact that it comprised data from four waves

(1998 till 2001), which facilitated analysis of the influences of both lagged and expected

influences on inter-sectoral worker mobility, was an equal probability sample of households

- which minimized sampling bias, had a good coverage across seven metropolitan cities in

eight provinces, was independent of residential stability so that individuals who moved

in/out of households were traced thereby maintaining continuity in the survey information,

and included persons with intervening unemployment spells which prevented loss of

345

individual records. A section in chapter 9 was dedicated to illustrating the non-importance

of these interim unemployment states with regards to the study of labour mobility. The

KLIPS dataset satisfied the five ideal pre-requisites outlined in the literature [McLaughlin

and Bils (2001)], of being a large dataset, representative of the working population,

surveying the individuals at least twice, extending over a fairly long period, and ensuring

that the data items on income and industry are provided at the point of the interview rather

than over the past year.

The subset of the KLIPS dataset used in the statistical analysis comprised 10,691 persons in

the working-age group (20-64 years) from 4 waves of data collection. This purged sample

was obtained after respondents with non-positive income, those with missing information

on their old/new industry, and those with invalid information on other questions used in the

model were excluded.

The limitations of the KLIPS dataset were also pointed out. The information on the past

year‟s income in the initial wave may be subject to recall error since the survey had just

commenced. Also, the 4 years‟ worth of information may be insufficient to capture an

individual‟s mobility over his/her working life. The reader should, however, bear in mind

that the KLIPS is Korea‟s first panel data for labour issues and it nonetheless provides a

good start for research.

Deriving Reliable Variables

The descriptive overview revealed that the share of industry movers (23%) was comparable

with the mobility rate in other empirical studies. The descriptive statistics also showed that

the old versus new sector variables aligned to expectations. The exceptions were sectoral

growth where their new sector rates were lower, and unemployment where the new sector

rates were higher. In terms of the latter, the old-new sector pattern is consistent with the

theoretical model involving wait unemployment where workers switch sectors and

experience wait unemployment.

Special attention was paid to ensuring the derivation of the variables was appropriate. An

important issue in this regard is the similarity of the old and new sector variables (e.g.

346

wage, unemployment, wage growth, sector size and performance) for stayers. This led to

very high correlations of old-new sector variables. As multicollinearity may be associated

with misleading inference, ways of circumventing the problem had to be implemented. This

included Tomes and Robinson‟s (1982a) method of treating the new sector as a single

potential alternative destination for the sector-level variables, predicting the sectoral wage

differential and unemployment via industry-specific regressions on personal characteristics

to remove the stochastic element, and estimating lifetime wages with a 5-year moving

average growth to average out year-on-year fluctuations. Consideration was also given to

the influence of outliers when constructing the lifetime wages variable. In the process of

deriving the predicted variables, the issue of model identification was addressed. Armed

with a conceptually-advanced model, a reliable dataset containing variables constructed in

ways that minimize the possibility of misleading inference, the regression equations were

estimated.

Given the complexities of the KLIPS sample, an attempt to assess the importance of survey

weighting was made. The comparison showed that the application of weights did not

change the material conclusions: the statistical significance of the explanatory variables

under the weighted and non-weighted series remained unaltered. The use of non-weighted

KLIPS data is in line with previous studies, i.e. Nam (2007), Kim (2004a), Cho (2005),

Sawangfa (2007), Kim (2003), Young (2005), Kang (2004), Kim (2004b), Young (2006),

Chang and Yang (2007), Seong (2007), Son (2007a), Son (2007b) and Jung, Moon and

Hahm (2007). Nonetheless, the checking of the potential importance of survey weighting is

unique to the current work. The final model was derived using the general-to-specific

modelling strategy.

The Determinants of Worker Mobility in Korea

The empirical results revealed the multi-dimensional nature of sectoral mobility in the

Korean labour market. The bridging theory, which suggests that mobility is a consequence

of monetary, macroeconomic, demographic and socio-economic factors as well as a

consequence of sectoral shocks, received support in the empirical analysis. The main

findings were:5

347

Consistent with the theoretical implications of the Le and Miller (1998) model,

the probability of a sectoral move was higher the greater the expected sectoral

wage differential.

Higher lifetime incomes in the new sector were a pull factor in the model of

mobility, and lower permanent incomes in the old sector were a push factor in

this model. The elasticities of mobility with respect to a change in the lifetime

income are lower than the elasticity with respect to the expected wage

differential.

There was an increased chance of out-mobility if lagged unemployment in the

old sector was higher. This finding was consistent with Vanderkamp‟s (1977)

study for the U.S. labour market. This suggests that Korean workers associate

higher unemployment with high risks and hence tend to move out of the old

sector.

Higher unemployment in the new sector deterred mobility. This intuitively

reasonable finding contrasts with results for the U.S. reported by Vanderkamp

(1977). The result in the current study supports the Todarian hypothesis which

postulates an inverse relationship between the unemployment rate and the

probability of obtaining a job in the new sector. It also implies that the greater

the chance of unemployment, the lower the expected wage and the lower the

chance of a sectoral switch.

In contrast to Fallick‟s (1993) study, females were found to have a higher

propensity towards industrial mobility than males. Nonetheless, this supports the

general view that mobility patterns differ between males and females.

A negative influence of age on sectoral mobility was established for most

workers in the Korean labour market. This negative effect diminishes with

rising age, and the age effect was predicted to become positive after 43 years of

age. The negative age-mobility relationship is consistent with empirical reports.

In general, higher mobility rates were reported for younger persons [younger

male employees in Cox (1971) and Osberg, Gordon and Lin (1994), and

younger job quitters (UI and non-UI recipients) and job losers (non-UI

recipients) in Thomas (1996b)] and lower mobility rates among older persons

[older women in Osberg (1991) for 1985/1986, older displaced workers in

Fallick (1993) and older job quitters and losers who received UI].

348

Individuals with longer job tenures have a lower probability of industrial

mobility. This relationship is likely to arise because the opportunity costs of

switching sectors are greater among those who have been with firms for longer,

due presumably to seniority-based pay, longer leave periods and pension

benefits, among other factors. This finding is in line with the results of Osberg

(1991) for males and females in 1980/1981, 1982/1983 and 1985/1986, Osberg,

Gordon and Lin (1994) for male employees, Fallick (1993) and Neal (1995) for

unemployed workers and Thomas (1996) for job losers and quitters who

received UI and job quitters who did not receive UI.

Marital status did not have any bearing on overall worker mobility in Korea.

This result is in line with the reports of Osberg (1991) for males in 1982/1983

and 1985/1986 and females in 1980/1981, 1982/1983 and 1985/1986, and

Osberg, Gordon and Lin (1994), but it is inconsistent with the Neal (1995) study

for married males. In tandem with Fallick (1993), household heads had a lower

chance of changing sectors, supporting the view that household heads have

greater family responsibilities which deter them from switching sectors.

Educational attainment had a significant effect on mobility, with non-graduates

being shown to have a higher propensity to switch sectors. This finding is

consistent with Kim (1998), who inferred that industry switchers tended to have

lower education levels. The finding however contradicts Neal (1995) who

revealed that higher education levels (represented by the number of years of

schooling) had an insignificant impact on mobility, and Fallick (1993) who

reported that higher education levels (represented by the number of grades of

school completed) had a positive effect on mobility.

Occupational status had an insignificant effect on sectoral mobility in Korea.

This finding is consistent with some results in the study by Osberg (1991),

where it was reported that occupational status was an insignificant determinant

of male mobility during 1982/1983 and 1985/1986. However, it differs from the

results in the same study for males during 1980/1981 and for skilled females

during 1982/1983 and 1985/1986.

Employers were more likely than employees to change sectors, especially

during the Crisis period. Those changing sectors are possibly owners of small

349

firms or new businesses with few employees and minimum funds. These

characteristics would have made closing their businesses and changing to a new

job/sector easier.

A larger-sized original industry had a negative effect on sectoral mobility. This

was held to imply that Korean workers may not be willing to change sectors

owing to plentiful job opportunities in the original sector. This finding was

similar to the results reported by Fallick (1993) and Neal (1995). However, as

these studies were for the unemployed, the comparisons should be noted with

caution.

Conforming to the results in the studies by Vanderkamp (1977) and Osberg,

Gordon and Lin (1994), a larger-size new industry raises the odds of a sectoral

switch. This suggests that Korean workers are changing sectors for employment

opportunities in the new industries.

The probability of out-mobility increased when the GDP growth increased in the

original industry in Korea. This result is unexpected, although it supports the

jobless growth hypothesis, where high growth could be attributed to an upgrade

in technology or worker productivity which leads to labour obsolescence and

thus results in a sectoral switch.

Higher growth in the new industry was shown to deter worker mobility. This

finding also supports the jobless growth hypothesis, whereby the advancements

in technology and worker productivity possibly limit the creation of jobs and

thus reduce the likelihood of mobility into the new high-growth sectors.

A sectoral shock is likely to generate greater sectoral labour reallocations in the

Korean labour market, a finding consistent with Gulde and Wolf (1998),

Brainard and Cutler (1993), Jovanovic and Moffitt (1990), Altonji and Ham

(1990) and Clark (1998).

Given the varied industry characteristics in terms of working conditions, job

opportunities and performance among other factors, the propensity to change

sectors depended on the worker‟s initial sector/industry. It was lower if the

worker was originally based in the construction and commerce sectors, and

higher if he/she came from agriculture, financial, real estate and business

services, and community, social and personal services. The effect was

350

insignificant if mining, utilities and transport, storage and communications were

the sectors/industries of origin.

The Factors Affecting the Mobility of Males and Females

Chapter 10 extended the analysis of mobility for the Korean labour market by conducting

separate analyses for males and females. These disaggregated analyses were based on the

same model, dataset, statistical methodology and procedures for creating variables as for

the initial set of analyses on data pooled across males and females. The review of the

descriptive statistics pointed towards distinct gender differences in terms of the explanatory

variables. These differences would be expected, a priori, to lead to differences in the

sectoral mobility of males and females. Tests confirmed that the relationships between

worker and industry characteristics and the sectoral mobility of males and females should

be estimated separately. The major findings are summarized below.

With the pooled data analyses, the probability of a sectoral move was raised

when the expected sectoral wage differential increased. Similarly, both male

and female mobility were also positively related to the differential in the

expected wages for the two sectors. The findings for males and females are

consistent with the theoretical implications of the Le and Miller (1998) model.

Higher lifetime wages in the new sector tended to act as a pull factor and raised

the odds of a sectoral move for both males and females. Corresponding to the

pooled data finding, both groups therefore can be viewed as income-maximising

individuals who change employment states in expectation of higher lifetime

wages.

Lower permanent earnings in the old sector, however, were established as a

push factor of both male and female mobility. This finding is also similar to

that reported in the analysis of the pooled data.

Higher unemployment in the original sector was found to be a push factor in the

analysis of both male and female mobility. This finding from the disaggregated

analysis replicated the study of the pooled data.

The probability of a sectoral switch was lower the higher the new sector‟s

unemployment rate for both males and females. As in the case of overall

351

mobility, the gender analysis supports the Todarian hypothesis of a negative

association between the unemployment rate and probability of gaining

employment.

The negative influence of age on mobility established in the analysis of the data

pooled across males and females was reflected in the separate analyses

undertaken for males and females. Thus, both older men and women have a

lower probability of changing sectors than their younger counterparts. These

gender results coincide with the reports of Osberg, Gordon and Lin (1994) for

males and the analysis in Osberg (1991) for females in 1985/1986.

The negative tenure-mobility relationship documented in the analyses for the

pooled sample carried across to the study of male mobility. This finding for

males corresponds with the results reported by Osberg (1991), Osberg, Gordon

and Lin (1994) and Neal (1995). The tenure effect was insignificant for

females. This finding for females contrasts with the results in Osberg (1991),

where there was a negative relation between tenure and mobility. The gender

difference in the tenure effect can be attributed to: a greater importance of firm-

specific training for males, a higher opportunity cost of switching sectors for

males and perhaps a higher proportion of older male workers with lengthy

tenures holding senior positions with high wages and other non-pecuniary

benefits.

The disaggregated analysis revealed that, among both males and females,

married persons have a lower chance of changing sectors. This finding differed

from the analysis of the pooled data in chapter 9, and supports the view that

married persons have greater family responsibilities and are thus prevented from

changing sectors. The result for males aligns with Neal‟s (1995) study but it

contrasts with the studies of Osberg (1991) for 1982/1983 and 1985/1986, and

Osberg, Gordon and Lin (1994), where the marital status effect was

insignificant. The finding for females differed from that in Osberg‟s (1991)

study, where the marital status variable was insignificant for females for

1980/1981, 1982/1983 and 1985/1986.

The separate analyses undertaken for males and females replicated the

aggregated study, where household heads were associated with a lower

352

propensity to change sectors. The finding for males is in line with Fallick‟s

(1993) study of unemployed males. In the case of females, the majority of

household heads (three-fifths) in the KLIPS are single parents (single, divorced,

widowed or separated), for whom the financial burdens of job change may be

particularly daunting.

The analysis of the pooled sample showed that non-graduates had a higher

incidence of mobility than graduates, although the effect was of marginal

significance. The analysis for the smaller separate samples of males and

females suggests little, if any, of the variation in mobility was associated with

educational attainment. The insignificance of the graduate status variable

among males is consistent with the findings reported by Osberg, Gordon and

Lin (1994) and Neal (1995). A possible reason for this may be that tenure and

practical training are more important in the job match process than formal

education for men and women in Korea.

Whilst skilled males were shown to have a lower probability of moving sectors,

the skill effect was non-influential among females. This finding for females

reflected the results of the aggregated study which showed the occupational

status variable to be an insignificant determinant of mobility. Nonetheless, the

result for males supports the view of skill levels being critical to certain

industries‟ operations and of skilled workers being scouted for their talent. The

findings for both males and females are consistent with some of the results

reported in Osberg (1991): the analyses for 1980/1981 for males and the

analyses for 1980/1981 and 1982/1983 for females.

The pooled study revealed that non-employees had a greater propensity to

change sectors, particularly during the Crisis where many businesses were

forced to close down. The disaggregated study attributed this to female non-

employees: the effect of the variable for non-employee status on male mobility

was insignificant.

The pooled study revealed that a larger-size old industry reduced the odds of a

sectoral switch. In the analyses conducted separately for males and females, a

larger-size original sector lowered the odds of a sectoral move for females but

the effect was insignificant for males. This latter result contrasts with Neal‟s

353

(1995) negative result for the original sector size for the unemployed.

Corresponding to the pooled result, a larger-sized new sector raised the odds of

a sectoral move for both males and females. This result suggests that workers

may move in response to employment availabilities in the new sector. The

finding for males corresponds with the results reported by Osberg, Gordon and

Lin (1994). In comparison, males appear to be lured by greater employment

opportunities in the new sector rather than in the old.

Sectoral GDP growth variables were included in the analysis, but it was noted

that these will largely capture differences in the distribution of the male and

female workforces across industries. It was therefore suggested that the results

should be treated with caution. The old sector growth variable displayed a

positive correlation with male/female mobility whilst the new sector growth had

a negative relationship with male/female mobility. These results reflect the

finding from the pooled study.

A sectoral shock was shown to lead to more intense male and female labour

movements across sectors. This result is similar to that reported on the basis of

the study of the pooled sample.

In summary, the vast majority of the results for the separate samples of males and females

mirror those of the pooled data, particularly those associated with variables that were

stressed in the theoretical model, i.e. the monetary variables (expected sectoral wage

differential, sectoral lifetime incomes), macroeconomic variables (sectoral unemployment)

and sectoral shock variable. The robustness of these results across the pooled and

disaggregated analyses therefore gives a high degree of confidence in the analyses of

sectoral mobility.

The Gender Decomposition Result

The analyses conducted in chapter 10 on the separate samples of male and female workers

revealed that the factors affecting sectoral mobility differed between men and women. The

decomposition results showed that male workers in Korea have slightly higher average

probabilities of sectoral mobility than their female counterparts. The explained difference

shows that men have relatively less (more) of those characteristics associated with a higher

354

(lower) likelihood of switching sectors. The variable that contributed most to the explained

difference is the new sector wage growth. In terms of the unexplained difference, it was

found that for a similar set of male (or female) endowments, males had a higher chance of a

sectoral switch than females. That is, in terms of sectoral mobility behaviour, males are

more sensitive to changes in worker and/or industry characteristics than females.

11.4 THE POLICY IMPLICATIONS

Policy implications are presented in this section. The aim is to assess the current policy

measures in Korea in the post-Crisis era and see if further recommendations could be made

from this study of sectoral mobility.

11.4.1 Policy Measures in Post-Crisis Period

In chapter 2 it was reported that the unemployment levels, which had been low before

1997, soared during the Crisis. The Financial Crisis was an indication that Korea‟s

economic and labour market structure required a fundamental revision [Cheon and Jung

(2004)]. A Tripatite Commission, consisting of Government, Union and Employer‟s

Association, was formed to oversee and implement the revision.

The revisions comprised an IMF rescue package which involved restructuring industry and

various unemployment measures. Industrial restructuring applied to the chaebols, financial

sector and government investment corporations (GICs). There was a reduced reliance on

state-funding, a push for reforms to the ownership, supervision and accounting practices of

corporations, privatization of GICs and innovations in the public sector.

The comprehensive unemployment package comprised active measures to maintain and

create jobs [Jeong (2002)] and measures for the unemployed [Cheon and Kim (2004) and

Yoo (2005)]. Under the active measures, job maintenance included providing support for

employment adjustment and creation, introducing childcare centres at work and assisting in

job information and having mutual aid programmes for construction workers. Job creation

involved introducing jobs in SMEs, implementing training programmes (i.e. government-

355

supported internships, human resource development at SMEs, forest-cultivation

programmes) and establishing databases on public sector jobs and social welfare services to

supply information on temporary relief work for the unemployed.

The measures assisting the unemployed consisted of income support to the poor via

unemployment loans/benefits and wage guarantees, vocational training for re-employment

of the unemployed and female-householders, expansion of job security offices, and the

establishment of centres for working women. Each measure catered to different groups,

including those displaced as a result of dismissal, those who have difficulty with finding a

job, those who have become unemployed as a result of business closures or bankruptcies,

those from SMEs not covered by employment insurance, the middle-aged, elderly or non-

regular workers [Yoo (2005)].

11.4.2 Assessment of Policy Measures and Current Situation

The restructuring of the corporate/financial sector was prompt and the unemployment

measures were successful in that they appeared to help reduce unemployment for thousands

[Jeong (2002)]. The unemployment rate dropped from 7% in 1998 to 3% by 2001. These

measures were, however, short-term ones enacted by Korea to help overcome the Crisis.

Although Korea is in the aftermath of the Crisis, there are lingering effects. The prompt

restructuring of industry carried with it a social cost [Yoo (2005)]. Unemployment became

higher than the pre-Crisis levels, owing in part to the retraction of jobs in large companies

which have downsized and outsourced their business activities in response to industrial

restructuring. Job instability has increased as workers are re-employed into lower quality,

non-regular jobs, face recurrent unemployment and precarious earnings (as wages have

become more flexible) [Cheon and Jung (2004)]6. Job prospects are not glamorous for

youth owing to the higher demand for experienced personnel, and they are dim for elderly

women. There is a skill mismatch in the labour market: high-skilled jobs are shrinking as

a result of restructuring and there is a need to fill low-skilled work. The higher-educated

seem to have little desire to work in these lower-skilled jobs.

356

11.4.3 Policy Recommendations

KLI’s Long term Plan Required

The emergency measures were implemented to provide a short-term solution to the Crisis.

However, given the lingering effects of the Crisis noted above, a longer-term plan is

required. One such long-term plan has been recommended by the Korean Labor Institute

(KLI) [Jeong (2002)]. In summary, the basis of this plan is to:

a) Improve the quality of the labour force via investments in

vocational/professional training and labour market information and provision of

wage/promotion incentives.

b) Emphasise the importance of regional labour markets with a call for regional

unemployment data to be made available.

c) Assist younger unemployed workers via smooth transition from school to work,

creating job opportunities and increasing job market information.

d) Create more opportunities for public works programmes, e.g. IT jobs for

younger workers, forest cultivation/public road works for older workers.

e) Enhance work conditions for non-standard workers by catering for social

insurance and leave, improving administration and supervision, ensuring wage

equality for comparable work, identifying jobs which can be converted to

regular jobs, and providing vocational training to convert to regular jobs.

These recommendations are geared towards maintaining low levels of unemployment and

reducing job instability. These policies could be expanded to incorporate the implications

derived from the findings of Parts I and II of this thesis.

Combination of Macro- and Micro-policies

Part I of this thesis showed that the SSH and ADH applied to Korea over 1998-2001, but

given the short period, any policy inference is tentative. From this, a combination of macro-

and micro-level policies is implied. First, the relevance of the ADH to the Korean

economy points towards the adoption of macro-policy. The findings indicated that mobility

predicted from changes in money supply and government debt were significant

357

determinants of unemployment. Aggregate demand policies, via tight controls on the

money supply and a reduction in the public debt to reduce unemployment, would therefore

be relevant. The mechanism is that these lead to smaller predicted inter-sector labour

movements, which our empirical evidence has shown will alleviate unemployment.

Second, the applicability of the SSH suggests that macro-policies are insufficient.

Implementation of these in isolation would lead to a problem where the „government

cannot perfectly identity the characteristics of agents to implement the first-best re-

distributive policy‟ [Andersen (1997)]. Remedial action is required at the micro-level.

Possible Micro-policy Targets

The microeconomic analyses of Part II of this thesis form the basis for appropriate policy

responses. Prior to the identification of policy targets, the nature of unemployment in

relation to the type of mobility must be established. From the SSH, frictional

unemployment, occurring as a consequence of pure sectoral shifts, is not the problem as

mobility is regarded as part of reallocating resources to better sectors following a successful

job match.

The problem arises if there is an inefficient reallocation of labour resources. The SSH and

ADH suggest unemployment accompanies the reallocation of resources in response to

demand and supply shocks. Structural and cyclical unemployment generated from mobility

attributed to demand and supply shocks (SSH and ADH) would be the area of concern.

The situation is worsened if unemployment becomes prolonged and is coupled with job

instability. There may be a role for policy in encouraging better initial job matches and this

can be achieved through identifying characteristics of the labour force and sectors that are

associated with lower mobility so that the labour force can be made more resilient to

shocks. Sectoral mobility arising from these shocks should be minimized so that

unemployment is kept at low levels. This is where empirical findings on the determinants

of mobility become relevant. The SSH and ADH asserted a positive mobility-

unemployment relationship, and from this the main impetus is to reduce sectoral mobility

to lower non-frictional unemployment for Korea.

358

Table 11.1 lists the possible targets derived from the empirical findings on the determinants

of mobility. From the pooled and disaggregated analyses, the target groups are also

indicated. That is, in order to reduce mobility rates, the following targets and measures

could be introduced:

a) Narrow the expected sectoral wage differential gap.

This can best be done by raising the income levels of low-wage sectors via

increases in output and turnover. Ceteris paribus, this would mean that

prevailing rewards in high-wage sectors may no longer be sufficient to entice

worker movements across sectors.

b) Increase permanent incomes in low-wage sectors whilst maintaining7 permanent

incomes in high-wage sectors.

This can be achieved by emphasizing the concept of lifetime employment in all

sectors via skills upgrading for workers, funding businesses and encouraging

higher output and turnover in industries.

c) Enhance job stability for females.

By introducing more non-casual female employment, encouraging skills-

training and education for women, women would be better able to see a career

progression in their existing jobs which could encourage job stability.

d) Encourage young workers/inexperienced men to remain in their original sectors.

For younger persons, the recommendations by Jeong (2002), to create more job

opportunities and improve job information, clearly apply. In addition, official

recruitment policies in the public service for fresh graduates could be enacted so

that younger persons can look forward to a longer-term career path [Addison

(1997)]. For the more inexperienced male workers, a balance between

seniority- and performance-based wage systems should be established so they

can foresee a longer-term progression in their careers, thereby discouraging

them from considering a sectoral switch.

e) Encourage married men/women and household heads to return to the workforce

or to remain in their existing jobs.

This could be achieved by continuing to develop alternative arrangements in

family rearing (like childcare centres) for working married men/women and

household heads. This was first implemented as an emergency measure during

the Crisis period and should be ongoing for longer-term success.

359

f) Raise the standard of formal education.

This recommendation involves continuing with the training programmes and

vocational training for re-employment of the unemployed that were

implemented during the post-Crisis period as a short-term solution. These

should be ongoing to achieve longer-term success.

g) Provide career incentives for skilled men.

Under this initiative, it is envisaged that corporations could give incentives for

existing skilled male workers to remain in their current establishments, either

via monetary or non-pecuniary benefits. For newly recruited skilled male

workers, a progression in their career path could be made known in order to

increase job satisfaction and discourage job quits.

h) Promote entrepreneurship in existing sectors and assist employers in their

businesses to prevent business closures.

Under this proposal, funding could be provided for new business start-ups. In

other words, SMEs should be given more recognition [Garonna and Sica

(2000)]. This was enacted as an immediate measure in the Crisis period and

should be ongoing for longer-term success. In addition, there could be some

funding backup if new businesses are on the verge of failure so that business

owners need not resort to a sectoral switch. For female enterpreneurs, additional

maternity leave and childcare cover could be provided to encourage business

start-ups.

i) Raise GDP growth of all sectors by raising labour productivity8.

The main issue under this recommendation is to cater for multi-sector

production by increasing labour productivity in all sectors. As the phenomenon

of the jobless growth hypothesis appears to be at play in the Korean economy,

the focus should be to increase labour productivity in all sectors by increasing

the skill and technical competency of workers from all sectors in order to ease

mobility rates.

j) Make sectors more resilient so they can better respond to sectoral shocks.

The measures under item (i) can be applied to the sectors to achieve this further

objective.

k) Reduce out-mobility rates of workers in agriculture, and financial, business

services and real estate, and community, social and personal services industries.

360

The measures under items (a) to (i) can be applied with particular force for these

sectors.

In general, these policies are targeted at the overall, male and/or female labour force. The

exceptions pertain to marital status and occupational status, where the policies need to be

specific to males and/or females.

Some policy targets covered in the analysis in this thesis were not recommended even

though, from a simple application of the empirical findings, they can reduce sectoral

mobility. These include increasing (decreasing) the size of the old (new) sector and raising

(easing) the new (old) sector‟s unemployment rate. The reason for this is that the indirect

effect on unemployment via mobility may be more than offset by other more direct impacts

on the level of unemployment. It can also be noted that the potential policy target of

influencing sectoral GDP growth in order to achieve a differential impact on the sectoral

mobility, and hence the unemployment, of males and females is deemed inappropriate, as

the finding in chapter 10 reflects only gender differences in industrial distributions.

Table 11.1 Micro-policy Targets for Korea Target Target Group a) Narrow the expected sectoral wage differential gap. All b) Increase permanent incomes in low-wage sectors whilst

maintaining permanent incomes in high-wage sectors. All

c) Enhance job stability for females. Females d) Encourage young workers and the more inexperienced

males to remain in their original industries. Age Effect: All Tenure Effect: Men

e) Encourage married men/women and/or household heads to return to the workforce/remain in their existing jobs.

Married: Men and Women Household heads: All

f) Raise standard of formal education. All g) Provide career incentives for skilled men. Men h) Promote entrepreneurship in existing sectors and assist

employers in their businesses to prevent business closures.

All Priority group: Female entrepreneurs

i) Raise GDP growth in all sectors by raising labour productivity.

n.r.

j) Make sectors more resilient so they can better respond to sectoral shocks.

All

k) Reduce sectoral mobility rates of agriculture, and financial, business services and real estate, and community, social and personal services industries.

n.r.

All : The policy target is applicable to the overall, male and female labour forces. Men and Women: The policy target is applicable only to the separate analyses undertaken for males and females. n.r: not recommended from the separate analyses undertaken for men and women.

361

It is envisaged that these policies would aid in reducing the social costs of higher

unemployment as well as the job instability mentioned above. Whilst unemployment can be

alleviated via a mix of macro- and micro-policies, job stability could be achieved by

moderating mobility through the micro measures stated.

Integration of Policies with KLI’s Recommendation

Several of the policy measures stated above are inter-linked with the KLI‟s long-term plan.

The KLI‟s recommendation of investment in vocational training is related to the suggested

measures of training to increase lifetime incomes, moderating mobility amongst women

and younger workers, and raising the level of education of the workforce in general [items

(b), (c), (d) and (f)]. The measures to encourage younger workers to remain in the original

sectors are also applicable to the KLI‟s suggestion to tackle youth unemployment [item

(d)]. The measures to lower female mobility, encourage married women to work or remain

in their jobs can be related to the KLI‟s plan to improve job prospects for elderly women

[items (c) and (e)]. Lastly, whilst the suggestion to create IT jobs for younger persons is

related to the measures for moderating mobility rates of young workers [item (d)], the

forest cultivation public works programme for older workers will assist in reducing

mobility rates for workers in agriculture [item (k)].

Of interest to note also is that several suggestions from the KLI to tackle job instability

have the implied result of reducing sectoral mobility, which is the very goal the policies

from this study are geared at. The provision of wage incentives could prevent workers

from switching sectors (since higher wages in the existing jobs reduce mobility) and

assisting disadvantaged workers (young, elderly women, older workers and workers in non-

regular jobs) could discourage them from switching jobs/sectors, thereby lowering mobility

rates and subsequently alleviating unemployment problems.

Therefore, it can be seen that the policy targets derived from this study are in line with the

KLI‟s long-term plan. An integrated effort is thus required to combat the social costs of

unemployment in Korea.

362

11.5 DIRECTION FOR FUTURE RESEARCH

Part I of the thesis provided some preliminary insight into the positive mobility-

unemployment relationship for Korea from the perspectives of the SSH and ADH. Part II

augmented the research via an in-depth analysis of the factors that motivate sectoral

mobility. The thesis has reported an ample range of findings which can provide a basis for

further research.

The empirical support for the SSH/ADH and stage-of-the-business-cycle effect for Korea

was rather tentative owing to the limited amount of data available. The results suggest that

the „new‟ mobility-unemployment phenomenon appears to have just started in the post-

Crisis period for Korea, whereas it had been a feature of the labour markets of Western

countries since the 1980s. Future studies should examine the validity of these hypotheses

for Korea when more data are available. The benefit of this is that if the validity of the

hypotheses for Korea can be established with a higher degree of certainty, then the micro-

policies derived from the findings on the factors that motivate mobility can be implemented

with greater confidence. The year 1998 appears to have been a structural break and the

economy appears to be at a significant turning point. The traditional monetary and fiscal

policies are deemed insufficient. So a policy combination of micro- and macro-policies for

sectoral mobility could be an innovative tool in the new millennium.

There appears to be a dearth of studies for this type of research for Asia, possibly the

consequence of a lack of longitudinal data available for research. Some studies, like Prasad

(1997) who examined the mobility-unemployment relationship for the manufacturing sector

in Japan using informal graphical techniques, are informative but appear to fall short of the

rigor required in research that is to lead to the development of policy. In the case of Korea,

the KLIPS is the first panel study for labour issues, so it is a useful starting point. The

study of sectoral mobility could be extended to the NIEs (Japan, Hong Kong, Singapore

and Taiwan) and the rest of Asia so that the standard of research can be more aligned with

that of the Western countries. This is attainable if datasets like the KLIPS become

available for research in other developing countries. If similar research on sectoral mobility

can be undertaken for other countries in Asia, the lessons learnt from the West, and the

benefits of a new microeconomic policy via sectoral mobility for Asia, could be immense.

363

Endnotes:

1. Since the nature of unemployment was not expounded in the empirical application, it is not mentioned here.

2. The other methods are not mentioned owing to their unsuitability for the current work, namely the ζ-U co-

movement approach and U-V argument for the ADH, and computing contemporaneous correlations between

labour reallocation measures and the average value of foregone production for the RTH. In the case of the

former, there is an absence of a direct assessment of predicted mobility on unemployment. In the latter, the

seemingly non-existent correlations make the method not worthwhile.

3. The chapter suggested that separate analyses might be undertaken for males and females. Since it was not

undertaken owing to the findings obtained for the overall study, it was not mentioned.

4. No distinction in the mobility behaviour of the overall, male or female labour groups is made here.

5. Where no references are provided alongside the findings of the current study, it means that there was no

study that adopted the relevant variable.

6. In Cheon and Jung (2004), wages are more performance-based rather than seniority-based. However, this

change is only partial and the Korean employment system retains traits which separates it from the West, such

as honorary retirement, and seniority-based wages, especially for blue-collar workers in large companies and

union members.

7. According to the empirical result, the target should be to reduce permanent incomes in high-wage sectors.

However, owing to wage inflation and individuals‟ constant demand for higher wages, a lowering of the

lifetime incomes is not desired in the longer term. Hence the next best alternative is to maintain permanent

income levels in the already high-wage sectors.

8. According to the empirical results, to reduce mobility, the target should be to lower the GDP growth of the

old sector, and raise the GDP growth of new sector. Since a lower GDP growth is undesirable, and given the

phenomenon of the jobless growth hypothesis in Korea, the better alternative is to cater for multi-sector

production by raising labour productivity.

364

REFERENCES

Abraham, K. (1983) „Structural/Frictional vs. Deficient Demand Unemployment: Some

New Evidence‟, American Economic Review, vol. 73(4), pp. 708-724.

Abraham, K. (1987) „Help-wanted Advertising, Job Vacancies and Unemployment‟,

Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, vol. 1987(1), pp. 207-243.

Abraham, K. and Katz, L. (1986) „Cyclical Unemployment: Sectoral Shifts or Aggregate

Disturbances?‟, Journal of Political Economy, vol. 94(3), pp. 507-522.

Addison, J. (1997) „The U.S. Labour Market: Structure and Performance‟, article in

„Structural Changes and Labor Market Flexibility: Experience in OECD Countries‟,

edited by Horst Siebert, Mohr, Tübingen, pp. 187-222.

Addison, J. and Portugal, P. (1989) „Job Displacement, Wage Changes and Duration of

Unemployment‟, Journal of Labor Economics, vol. 7(3), pp. 281-301.

Akyüz, Y. (2000) „Causes and Sources of the Asian Financial Crisis‟, UNCTAC Geneva,

Paper presented at the host Country Event, Symposium on Economic and Financial

recovery in Asia, UNCTAD X Bangkok, 17 Feb 2000.

Alogoskoufis, G. and Smith, R. (1991) „On Error Correction Models: Specification,

Interpretations, Estimation‟, Journal of Economic Surveys, vol. 5(1), pp. 97-128.

Altonji, J. and Ham, J. (1990) „Variation in Employment Growth in Canada: The Role of

External, National, Regional and Industrial Factors‟, Journal of Labor Economics,

vol. 8(1), S198-S236.

Andersen, T. (1997) „Structural Changes and Barriers in the Danish Labour Market‟, article

in Structural Changes and Labor Market Flexibility: Experience in OECD Countries,

edited by Horst Siebert, Mohr, Tübingen, pp. 123-149.

Anderson, J. (1979) „Determinants of Bargaining Outcomes in the Federal Government of

Canada‟, Industrial and Labor Relations Review, vol. 32(2), pp. 224-241.

Antolin, P. and Bover, O. (1997) „Regional Migration in Spain: The Effect of Personal

Characteristics and of Unemployment, Wage and House Price Differentials using

pooled Cross-sections‟, Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, vol. 59(2), pp.

215-235.

Arnott, R., Hosios, A. and Stiglitz, J. (1988) „Implicit Contracts, Labor Mobility and

Unemployment‟, American Economic Review, vol. 78(5), pp. 1046-1066.

Ashenfelter, O. and Pencavel, J. (1969) „American Trade Union Growth: 1900-1960‟,

Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 83(3), pp. 434-448.

365

Austria, M. and Martin, W. (1995) „Macroeconomic Instability and Growth in the

Philippines, 1950-1987: A Dynamic Approach‟, Singapore Economic Review, vol.

40(1), pp. 65-81.

Bain, G. and Elsheikh (1976) Union Growth and the Business Cycle, Basil Blackwell,

Oxford.

Barro, R. J. (1977) „Unanticipated Money Growth and Unemployment in the United

States‟, American Economic Review, vol. 67(2), pp. 101-115.

Barro, R. J. (1980) „Inter-temporal Substitution and the Business Cycle‟ NBER working

paper no. 490, National Bureau of Economic Research.

Barrows, G. (2004) „Isolating Trade‟s Effects on Growth‟, paper submitted for the 2004

Moffatt Prize in Economics, Economics at About.Com (http://economics.about.com).

Bartel, A. (1989) „Where do the New U.S. Immigrants Live?‟, Journal of Labor

Economics, vol. 7 (4), pp. 371-391.

Bartel, A. and Koch, M. (1991) Internal Migration of U.S. Migrants’, Immigration, Trade

and the Labor Market, University of Chicago Press, United States.

Bartram, D. (2000) „Japan and Labor Migration: Theoretical and Methodological

Implications of Negative Cases', International Migration Review, vol. 34 (1), pp. 5-

32.

Becker, G. (1964) Human Capital: A Theoretical and Empirical Analysis with Special

Reference to Education, New York and London: Columbia University Press, 1964.

Becker, G. (1993) „Nobel Lecture: The Economic Way of Looking at Behaviour‟, Journal

of Political Economy, vol. 101(3), pp. 385-409.

Beggs, J. and Chapman, B. (1988) „Labor Turnover Bias in Estimating Wages‟, Review of

Economics and Statistics, vol. 70(1), pp. 117-123.

Bernanke, N. (1983) „Non-monetary Effects of the Financial Collapse in the Propagation of

the Great Depression‟, American Economic Review, vol. 73(3), pp. 257-293.

Bernstein, I. (1954) „The Growth of American Unions‟, American Economic Review, vol.

44(3), pp. 301-318.

Blackburn, M, and Neumark, D. (1992) „Unobserved Ability, Efficiency Wages and Inter-

industry Wage Differentials‟, Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 107(4), pp. 1421-

1436.

Blan, D. (1991) „Search for Non-wage Job Characteristics: A Test of the Reservation Wage

Hypothesis‟, Journal of Labor Economics, 1991, vol. 9(2), pp. 186-205.

366

Blanchard, O. and Diamond, P. (1989) „The Beveridge Curve‟, Brookings Papers on

Economic Activity, vol. 1989(1), pp. 1-60.

Blanchard, O. and Quah, D. (1989) „The Dynamic Effects of Aggregate Demand and

Supply Disturbances‟, American Economic Review, vol. 79(4), pp. 655-673.

Blank, R. (1985) „An Analysis of Workers‟ Choice Between Employment in the Public and

Private Sectors‟, Industrial and Labor Relations Review, vol. 38(2), pp. 211-224.

Bleany, M. (1992) „Sectoral Rigidities, Wage Inertia and Expectations‟, Australian

Economic Papers, vol. 31(59), pp. 303-310..

Blinder, A. (1973) „Wage-Discrimination: Reduced Form and Structural Variables‟,

Journal of Human Resources, vol. 8(4), pp. 436-455.

Blinder, A. (1976) „On Dogmatism in Human Capital‟, Journal of Human Resources, vol.

11(1), pp. 8-22.

Bradshaw, Y. and Naonan, R. (1997) „Urbanization, Economic Growth and Women‟s

Labour Force Participation. A Theoretical and Empirical Reassessment‟, Cities in the

Development World: Issues, changes and policy, Oxford University Press 1997.

Brainard, S. and Cutler, D. (1993) „Sectoral Shifts and Cyclical Unemployment

Reconsidered‟, Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 108(1), pp. 219-243.

Brown, P. and Browne, M. (1962) „Earnings in Industries of the United Kingdom, 1948-

1959‟, The Economic Journal, vol. 72(287), pp. 517-549.

Brown, R., Moon, M. and Zoloth, B. (1980) „Occupational Attainment and Segregation by

Sex‟, Industrial and Labor Relations Review, vol. 33(4), pp. 506-517.

Booth, A. (1983) „A Reconsideration of Trade Union Growth in the United Kingdom‟,

British Journal of Industrial Relations, vol. 21(3), pp. 377-391.

Borjas, G. (1980) „The Relationship Balance Between Wage and Weekly Hours of Work:

The Role of Division Bias‟, Journal of Human Resources, vol. 15(3), pp. 409-423.

Borjas, G. (1982) „The Politics of Employment Discrimination in the Federal Bureaucracy‟,

Journal of Law and Economics, vol. 25(2), pp. 271-299.

Borjas, G. (1990) „The Intergenerational Mobility of Immigrants‟, mimeo, University of

Chicago, 1990.

Borjas, G. (1994) „The Economics of Immigration‟, Journal of Economic Literature, vol.

32(4), pp. 1667-1717.

Borland, J., Hirschberg, J. and Lye, J. (1998) „Earnings of Public Sector and Private Sector

Employees in Australia: Is There a Difference?‟, Economic Record, vol. 74(224), pp.

36-53.

367

Borland, J. and Ouliaris, S. (1994) „The Determinants of Australian Trade Union

Membership‟, Journal of Applied Econometrics, vol. 9(4), pp. 453-468.

Bound, J. and Krueger (1991) „The Extent of Measurement Error in Longitudinal Earnings

Data: Do Two Wrongs Make a Right?‟, Journal of Labor Economics, vol. 9(1), pp. 1-

24.

Bull, C. and Jovanovic, B. (1988) „Mismatch versus Derived Demand Shift as Causes of

Labour Mobility‟, Review of Economic Studies, vol. 55(1), pp. 169-175.

Burdett, K. (1978) „A Theory of Employee Job Search and Quit Rates‟, American

Economic Review, vol. 68(1), pp. 212-220.

Bureau of Labour Market Research, „Structural Change and the Labour Market‟, Research

Report no. 11, Australian Government Publishing Services, Canberra, 1987.

Burgess, J. and Green, R. H. (2000) „Is Growth the Answer? in S. Bell (ed.) The

Unemployment Crisis in Australia: Which Way Out?, Cambridge University Press,

Cambridge, pp. 125-148.

Byrne, J. (1975) „Occupational Mobility‟, Monthly Labor Review, vol. 98, pp. 53-59.

Callagham, G. (1997) Flexibility, Mobility and the Labour Market, Ashgate Publishing Ltd.

Carrington, W. and Zaman, A. (1994) „Interindustry Variation in the Costs of Job

Displacement‟, Journal of Labor Economics, vol. 2(2), pp. 243-275.

Carruth, A. and Disney, R. (1988) „Where Have Two Million Trade Union Members

Gone?‟, Economica, vol. 55(217), pp. 1-19.

Chaison, G. and Dhavale, D. (1992) „The Choice Between Union Membership and Free-

Rider Status‟, Journal of Labor Research, vol. 13(4), pp. 355-369.

Chan, W. (1996) „Intersectoral Mobility and Short-Run Labor Market Adjustments‟,

Journal of Labor Economics, vol. 14(3), pp. 454-471.

Chang, Jiyeun and Yang, Sukyung (2007) „Non-standard Employment from the Social

Exclusion Perspective‟, working paper, Korea Labor Institute, Jun 2007.

Chang, Y., Jaeryang, N. and Changyong, R. (2004) „Trends in unemployment rates in

Korea: A search-matching model interpretation‟, Journal of the Japanese and

International Economies, 18(2), pp. 241-263.

Cheon, Byung-You and Jung, Ee-hwan (2004) „Economic Crisis and the Changes in the

Employment Systems in East Asia: The Cases of Japan and Korea‟, working paper,

Korea Labor Institute, Jun 2004, pp. 1-27.

Cheon, Byung You and Kim, Sungteak (2004) „Labor Market Policies to Meet Challenges

in the Korean Labor Market after the 1997 Financial Crisis‟, paper prepared for

368

International Conference on International Perspectives on Labor Market Institutions,

Seoul, Korea, Jul 19-20 2004, pp. 1-49.

Cho, Sang-Wook (2005) „Household Wealth Accumulation and Portfolio Choices in

Korea‟, Job Market paper, University of Minnesota, Oct 2005, pp. 1-43.

Choo, H. (1989) „The Asian Newly Industrialising Economies (NIEs): Are Economic

Miracles really Miraculous?‟, Singapore Economic Review, vol 34(1), pp. 2-12.

Chew, S. (1990) „Brain Drain in Singapore: Issues and Prospects‟, Singapore Economic

Review, Oct 1990, vol. 35(2), pp. 55-77.

Chillemi, O. and Gui, B. (1997) „Team Human Capital and Worker Mobility‟, Journal of

Labor Economics, vol. 15(4), pp. 567-85.

Chirco, A. and Colombo, C. (1996) „The AD-AS Model and Its Solutions: Some New

Results in a Disequilibrium Perspective‟, Australian Economic Papers, vol. 35(67),

pp. 263-281.

Chiswick, B. (1991) „Speaking, Reading and Earnings among Low-skilled Migrants‟,

Journal of Labor Economics, vol. 9(2), pp. 149-170.

Chiswick, B., Le, A. and Miller, P. (2008) „How Immigrants Fare Across the Earnings

Distribution in Australia and the United States‟, Industrial and Labor Relations

Review, vol. 61(3), pp. 353-373.

Chiswick, B., Lee, Y. L. and Miller, P. (2005) „Longitudinal Analysis of Immigrant

Occupational Mobility: A Test of the Immigrant Assimilation Hypothesis‟,

International Migration Review, vol. 39(2), pp. 332-353.

Chiswick, B. and Miller, P. (1985) „Immigrant Generation and Income in Australia‟,

Economic Record, vol. 61 (173), pp. 540-573.

Chiswick, B. and Miller, P. (1994) „The Determinants of Post-Immigration Investments in

Education‟, Economics of Education Review, vol. 13(2), pp. 163-177.

Choy, K. (1999) „Sources of Macroeconomic Fluctuations in Singapore: Evidence from A

Structural VAR model‟, Singapore Economic Review, Apr 1999, vol. 44(1), pp. 74-

98.

Christie, V. (1992) „Union Wage Effects and the Probability of Union Membership‟,

Economic Record, vol. 68(200), pp. 43-56.

Chuma, J. (1997) „Structural Change and the State of the Labour Market in Japan‟, article

in „Structural Changes and Labor Market Flexibility: Experience in OECD

Countries‟, edited by Horst Siebert, Mohr, Tübingen, pp. 257-289.

369

Clark, T. (1998) „Employment Fluctuations in U.S. Regions and Industries: The Roles of

National, Region-specific, and Industry-specific Shocks‟, Journal of Labor

Economics, vol. 16(1), pp. 202-229.

Clive, B. and Jovanovic, B. (1988) „Mismatch versus Derived-Demand Shift as Causes of

Labour Mobility‟, Review of Economic Studies, vol. 55(1), pp. 169-175.

Coe, D. (1990) „Insider-Outsider Influences on Industry Wages (Evidence from fourteen

Industrialised Countries), Empirical Economics, vol. 15(2), pp. 163-183.

Conlon, R. (1992) „Determinants of Manufacturing Industry Exports: A Comparative Study

of Australia, republic of Korea, Singapore and Taiwan‟, Australian Economic Papers,

vol. 31(59), pp. 427-442.

Cotton, J. (1988) „On the Decomposition of Wage Differentials‟, Review of Economics and

Statistics, vol. 70(2), pp. 236-243.

Coulson, N. and Robins, R. (1987) „A Test of the First-Difference Transformation in Time

Series Models‟, Review of Economics and Statistics, vol. 69(4), pp. 723-726.

Cox, D. (1971) „The Effect of Geographic and Industry Mobility on Income: A Further

Comment‟, Journal of Human Resources, vol. 6(4), pp. 525-527.

Creedy, J. (1974) „Labour Mobility, Earnings and Unemployment. Selected Papers – Inter-

regional Mobility: A Cross-section Analysis‟, Scottish Journal of Political Economy,

vol. 21(1), pp. 41-53.

Creedy, J. and Thomas, R. (1982) The Economics of Labor, Butterworths, London.

Cutler, D., Glaeser, E. and Vigdor, J. (1999) „The Rise and Decline of the American

Ghetto‟, Journal of Political Economy, vol. 107(3), pp. 455-506.

Dalziel, P. (1993) „Classical and Keynesian Unemployment in a Simple Disequilibrium

AS-AD Framework‟, Australian Economic Papers, vol. 32(60), pp. 40-52.

Darby, M., Haltiwanger, J. and Plant, M. (1985) „Unemployment Rate Dynamics and

Persistent Unemployment under Rational Expectations‟, American Economic Review,

vol. 75(4), pp. 614-637.

Davidson, C., Martin, L. and Matusz, S. (1988) „The Structure of Simple General

Equilibrium Models with Frictional Unemployment‟, Journal of Political Economy,

vol. 96(6), pp. 1267-1293.

Davis, S. (1987) „Fluctuations in the Pace of Labor Reallocation‟, Carnegie-Rochester

Conference Series on Public Policy 27, pp. 335-402.

Diamond, P. (1981) „Mobility Costs, Frictional Unemployment and Efficiency‟, Journal of

Political Economy, vol. 89(4), pp. 798-812.

370

Dickens, W. and Katz, L. (1987) „Inter-Industry Wage Differences and Industry

Characteristics‟, article in Unemployment and the Structure of Labor Markets, edited

by Lang, K. and Leonard, J., Basil Blackwell, Oxford, pp. 48-89.

Disney, R. (1990) „Explanations of the Decline in Trade Union Density in Britain: an

Appraisal‟, British Journal of Industrial Relations, vol. 28(2), pp. 165-177.

Dixon, R. (1982) „The Rate of Exploitation and the Wage Share as Weighted Sums of

Sectoral Measures‟, Australian Economic Papers, vol. 21(39), pp. 421-424.

Doeringer, P. and Piore, M. (1971) Internal Labour Markets and Manpower Analysis,

Lexington Books, D.C. Heath, Lexington , Mass.

Doiron, D. and Riddell, W. (1994) „The Impact of Unionisation on Male-Female Earnings

Differences in Canada‟, Journal of Human Resources, vol. 29(2), pp. 504-534.

Doucouliagos, C. (1997) „The Aggregate Demand for Labour in Australia: A Meta-

Analysis‟, Australian Economic Papers, vol. 36(69), pp. 224-242.

Duetsch, L. (1974-1975) „Structural Performance and the Net Rate of Entry into

Manufacturing Industries, Southern Economic Journal vol. 41, 1974-1975.

Dustmann, C. (1993) „Earnings Adjustment of Temporary Immigrants‟, Journal of Political

Economy, vol. 6 (2), pp. 153-168.

Edin, P. and Holmlund, B. (1997) „Sectoral Structural Change and the State of the Labour

Market in Sweden‟, article in „Structural Changes and Labor Market Flexibility:

Experience in OECD Countries‟, edited by Horst Siebert, Mohr, Tübingen, pp. 89-

122.

Ehrenberg, R. (1973) „The Demand for State and Local Government Employees‟, American

Economic Review, vol. 63(3), pp. 366-379.

Eickstein, O. and Wilson, T. (1967) „The Determination of Money Wages in American

Industry: Reply‟, Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 81(4), pp. 690-694.

Eisemann, D. (1956) „Inter-industry Wage Changes, 1939-1947‟, Review of Economics and

Statistics, vol. 38(4), pp. 445-458.

Eriksson, G. (1991) „Human Capital Investments and Labor Mobility‟, Journal of Labor

Economics, vol. 9(3), pp. 236-254.

Evans, S. and Lewis, P. (1986) „Demand, Supply and Adjustment of Farm Labour in

Australia‟, Australian Economic Papers, vol. 25(47), pp. 236-246.

Even, W. and MacPherson, D. (1993) „The Decline of Private Sector Unionism and the

Gender Wage Gap‟, Journal of Human Resources, vol. 28, pp. 279-296.

371

Faini, R., Galli, G., Gennari, P. and Rossi, F. (1997) „An Empirical Puzzle: Falling

Migration and Growing Unemployment Differentials among Italian Regimes‟,

European Economic Review, 41(3), pp. 571-579.

Fallick, B. (1992) „Job Security and Job Search in More than One Labor Market‟,

Economic Inquiry, vol. 30(4), pp. 742-745.

Fallick, B. (1993) „The Industrial Mobility of Displaced Workers‟, Journal of Labor

Economics, vol. 11(2), pp. 302-323.

Fair R.C. (1970) „The Estimation of Simultaneous Equation Models with Lagged

Endogenous Variables and First Order Serially Correlated Errors‟, Econometrica, vol.

38(3), pp. 507-516.

Farber, H. (1990) „The Decline of Unionisation in the United States: What Can Be Learned

from Recent Experience‟, Journal of Labor Economics, vol. 8, S75-105.

Farber, H. and Saks, D. (1980) „Why Workers Want Unions: The Role of Relative Wages

and Job Characteristics‟, Journal of Political Economy, vol. 88(2), pp. 349-369.

Farkas, G. and England, P. (1988) Industries, Firms and Jobs: Sociological and Economic

Approaches, Plenum Press, New York.

Finnie, R. and Garneau, G. (1997) „Earnings Patterns By Age and Sex‟, Canadian

Economic Observer, Vol. 10(10), Feature Article.

Flyer, F. (1997) „The Influence of Higher Moments of Earnings Distributions in Career

Decisions‟, Journal of Labor Economics, 1997, vol. 15(4), pp. 689-713.

Freeman, R. (1989) „On the Divergence of Unionism Among Developed Countries‟ NBER

working paper no. 2817, National Bureau of Economic Research.

Freeman, R. and Medoff, J. (1984) What Do Unions Do? Basic Books, New York.

Gallaway, L. (1963) „Labor Mobility, Resource Allocation and Structural Unemployment‟

American Economic Review, vol. 55(3), pp. 531-532.

Gallaway, L. (1965) „Structural Unemployment: Reply‟, American Economic Review, vol.

55(3), pp. 527-531.

Garbarino, J. (1950) „A Theory of Interindustry Wage Structure Variation‟, Quarterly

Journal of Economics, vol. 64(2), pp. 282-305.

Garonna, P. and Sica, F. (1997) „Intersectoral Labour Reallocations and Flexibility

Mechanisms in Post-war Italy‟, article in „Structural Changes and Labor Market

Flexibility: Experience in OECD Countries‟, edited by Horst Siebert, Mohr,

Tübingen, pp. 51-88.

372

Garonna, P. and Sica, F. (2000) „Inter-sectoral Labour Reallocations and Unemployment in

Italy‟, Labour Economics, vol. 7(6), pp. 711-728.

Gerwin, D. (1969) „Compensation Decisions in Public Organisations‟, Industrial Relations,

vol. 8(2), pp. 174-184.

Ghatak, A. (1996) „Labour Migration in the Indian States and the Todarian Hypothesis‟,

Asian Economic Review, vol. 38(2), pp. 212-228.

Gibbons, R. and Katz, L. (1992) „Does Unmeasured Ability Explain Inter-industry Wage

Differentials?‟, Review of Economic Studies, vol. 59(3), pp. 515.535.

Gordon, R. (1982) „Price Inertia and Policy Ineffectiveness in the U.S.‟ Journal of Political

Economy, vol. 90 (6), pp. 1087-1117.

Goss, E. and Schoening, N. (1974) „Search Time, Unemployment and the Migration

Decision‟, Journal of Human Resources, vol. 19(4), pp. 570-579.

Green, D. (1999) „Immigrant Occupational Attainment: Assimilation and Mobility Over

Time‟, Journal of Labor Economics, vol. 17(1), pp. 49-79.

Greene W. (2003) „Econometric Analysis‟, fourth edition, Prentice Hall.

Greenhalgh, C. and Stewart, M. (1985) „The Occupational Status and Mobility of British

Men and Women‟, Oxford Economic Activity, vol. 37(1), pp. 40-71.

Greenwood, M. (1975) „Research on Internal Migration in the United States: A Survey‟,

Journal of Economic Literature, vol. 5(3), pp. 397-433.

Gregory, G., Harvie, C. and Lee, H.H. (2002) „Korean SMEs in the Wake of the Financial

Crisis: Strategies, Constraints, and Performance in a Global Economy‟, paper no. 50

on CD, The 47th International Council for Small Business World Conference, San

Juan, Puerto Rico, 16-19 Jun, 2002.

Groshen, E. (1991) „Sources of Intra-Industry Wage Dispersion: How much Do Employers

Matter?‟, Quarterly Journal of Economics, Aug 1991, vol. 106, Issue 3, p. 869-884.

Groshen, E. (1991) „Five Reasons Why Wages Vary Among Employers‟, Industrial

Relations, vol. 30(3), pp. 350-381.

Gujarati, D. (1995) Basic Econometrics, 3rd

Edition, McGraw Hill, New York.

Gulde, A. and Wolf, H. (1998) „The Changing Skill Structure of Employment in German

Manufacturing: A Peek Inside the Industry Black Box‟, article in Globalisation,

Technological Change and Labour Markets, edited by Stanley W. Black, Kenver

Academic Publishers.

Gunderson, M. (1979) „Earnings Differentials between the Public and Private Sectors‟,

Canadian Journal of Economics, vol. 12(2), pp. 228-242.

373

Gunderson, M. (1980) „Public Sector Compensation in Canada and the U.S.‟, Industrial

Relations, vol. 19(3), pp. 257-271.

Gyourko, J, and Tracy, J. (1988) „An Analysis of Public and Private Sector Wages

Allowing for Endogenous Choices of Both Government and Union Status‟, Journal of

Labor Economics, vol. 6(2), pp. 229-253.

Hahn, J. (1996) „Pecuniary Mobility Costs in a Two-sector Model‟, Seoul Journal of

Economics, vol. 9(2), pp. 163-174.

Hall, R. (1975) „The Rigidity of Wages and the Persistence of Unemployment‟, Brookings

Papers on Economic Activity, vol. 1975(2), pp. 301-335.

Hall, J. (1991) „Notes and Comments: Sectoral Transformation and Economic Decline:

Views from Berkeley and Cambridge‟, Cambridge Journal of Economics, vol.15(2),

pp. 229-237.

Hall, P. and Treadgold, M. (1982) „Aggregate Demand Curves: A Guide to Use and

Abuse‟, Australian Economic Papers, vol. 21(38), pp. 37-48.

Hall, R. and Yellen, J. (1989) „The Beveridge Curve: Comments and Discussion‟,

Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, vol. 1989(1), pp. 61-76.

Hamilton, J. (1988) „A Neo-classical Model of Unemployment and the Business Cycle‟,

Journal of Political Economy, vol. 96(3), pp. 593-617.

Hansen, B. (1970) „Excess Demand, Unemployment, Vacancies and Wages‟, Quarterly

Journal of Economics, vol. 84(1), pp. 1-23.

Harris, J. and Todaro, M. (1970) „Migration, Unemployment and Development: A Two-

Sector Analysis‟, American Economic Review, 60(1), pp. 128-149.

Hartog, J. and Oosterbeek, H. (1993) „Public and Private Sector Wages in the Netherlands‟,

European Economic Review, 37(1), pp. 97-114.

Hartog, J. and Theeuwes, J. (1997) „The Dutch Response to Dynamic Challenges in the

Labour Market‟, article in Structural Changes and Labor Market Flexibility:

Experience in OECD Countries, edited by Horst Siebert, Mohr, Tübingen, pp. 151-

184.

Harvey, A. (1990) The Econometric Analysis of Time Series, 2nd

edition, BPCC Wheaton

Ltd., Exeter.

Hayafuji, T., Ikeda, M. and Yamada, H. (2003) „South Korea‟s Next Step‟, Apr 2003, SPP

542 International Financial Policy (extracted from www-personal.umich.edu).

Hayworth, C. and Rasmusseu, D. (1971) „Human Capital and Inter-industry Wages in

Manufacturing‟, Review of Economics and Statistics, vol. 53(4), pp. 376-380.

374

Heckman, J. and Sedlacek, G. (1985) „Heterogeneity, Aggregation and Market Wage

Functions: An Empirical Model of Self-Selection in the Labor Market‟, Journal of

Political Economy, vol. 93(6), pp 1077-1125.

Helwege, J. (1992) „Sectoral Shifts and Interindustry Wage Differentials‟, Journal of Labor

Economics, vol. 10(1), pp. 55-84.

Hendry, D. H. and Krolzig, H.-M (2001), Automatic Econometric Model Selection using

PcGets, Timberlake Consultants Ltd., London.

Henstridge, J. (2001) „The Household, Income and Labour Dynamics in Australia (HILDA)

Survey: Weighting and Imputation‟, HILDA Project Discussion Paper Series, Jul

2001, no. 3/01.

Heywood, J. (1993) „Efficient Labour Bargains, Unemployment and Non-union Wages: A

Two-sector Model‟, Australian Economic Papers, vol. 32(61), pp. 214-230.

Hicks, G. (1989) „The Four Little Dragons: An Enthusiast‟s Reading Guide‟, Asian-Pacific

Economic Literature, vol. 3(2), pp. 35-49.

Higgins, M. and Williamson, J. (1997) „Age Structure Dynamics in Asia and Dependence

on Foreign Capital‟, Population and Development Review, vol. 23(2), pp. 261-293.

Hill, J. (1984) „Australian Union Density Rates 1976-1982‟, Journal of Industrial

Relations, vol. 26(4), pp. 435-450.

Holtz-Eakin, D. and Rosen, H. (1991) „Municipal Labor Demand in the Presence of

Uncertainty: An Econometric Approach‟, Journal of Labor Economics, vol. 9(3), pp.

276-293.

Horn, S. (2004) „Guide to Standard Errors for Cross Section Estimates‟, HILDA Project

Technical Paper Series, Jan 2004, no. 1/04.

Horvath, M. (1998) „Cyclicality and Sectoral Linkages: Aggregate Fluctuations from

Independent Sectoral Shocks‟, Review of Economic Dynamics, vol. 1(4), pp. 781-808.

Horvath, M. (2000) „Sectoral Shocks and Aggregate Fluctuations‟, Journal of Monetary

Economics, vol. 45(1), pp. 69-106.

Hosios, A. (1994) „Unemployment and Vacancies with Sectoral Shifts‟, American

Economic Review, vol. 84(1), pp. 124-144.

Idson, T. and Valleta, R. (1996) „Seniority, Sectoral Decline and Employee Retention: An

Analysis of Layoff Unemployment Spells‟, Journal of Labor Economics, vol. 14(4),

pp. 654-676.

Jaffe, A., Day, L. and Adams, W. (1964) Disabled Workers in the Labor Market, The

Bedminster Press, New Jersey.

375

Jayadevan, C. (1997) „Inter-industrial Differences in Employment Growth Rates of

Organised Manufacturing Industry in India‟, Asian Economic Review, vol. 39(1), pp.

15-27.

Jeong, Insoo (2002) „Unemployment Schemes during the Financial Crisis in Korea:

Achievements and Evaluations‟, working paper, Korea Labor Institute, Dec 2002, pp.

71-94.

Jeong, Insoo (2003) „Interregional Labor Mobility‟, working paper, Korea Labor Institute,

May 2003.

Johnston, J. (1984) Econometric Methods, McGraw-Hill Book Company, Singapore.

Jolliffe, D. (2002/2003) „Estimating Sampling Variance from the Current Population

Survey: A Synthetic Design Approach to Correcting Standard Errors‟, Journal of

Economic and Social Measurement, vol. 28(4), pp. 239-261.

Jorgensen, D. (1967) „Surplus Agricultural Labour and the Development of a Dual

Economy‟, Oxford Economic Papers, vol. 19(3), pp. 288-312.

Jovanovic, B. (1979) „Job Matching and the Theory of Turnover‟, Journal of Political

Economy, vol. 87(5), pp. 972-990.

Jovanovic, B. and Moffitt, R. (1990) „An Estimate of a Sectoral Model of Labor Mobility‟,

Journal of Political Economy, vol. 98(4), pp. 827-852.

June, Ee-hwan and Cheon, Byung-You (2004) „Economic Crisis and the Changes in

Employment Systems in East Asia: The Cases of Japan and Korea‟, working paper,

Korea Labor Institute, Jun 2004, pp. 1-27.

Jung, Kwangho, Moon, M. Jae and Hahm, Sung Deul (2007) „Do Age, Gender and Sector

Affect Job Satisfaction? Results from the Korean Labor and Income Panel Data‟,

Review of Public Personnel Administration, vol 27(2), pp. 125-146.

Kang, C. (2004) „University Prestige and Choice of Major Field: Evidence from South

Korea‟, manuscript prepared for Presentation at the 2004 Far Eastern Meeting of the

Econometric Society, pp. 1-38.

Kang, C., Park, C. and Lee, M. (2007) „Effects of Ability Mixing in High School on

Adulthood Earnings: Quasiexperimental Evidence from South Korea‟, Journal of

Population Economics, vol. 20(2), pp. 269-297.

Kasper, H. (1967) „The Asking Price of Labour and the Duration of Unemployment‟,

Review of Economics and Statistics, vol. 49(2), pp. 165-172.

Katz, L. and Summers, L. (1989) „Industry Rents: Evidence and Implications‟, Brookings

Papers on Economic Activity. Microeconomics, vol. 1989(1), pp. 209-290.

376

Keane, M. (1993) „Individual Heterogeneity and Interindustry Wage Differentials‟, Journal

of Human Resources, vol. 28(1), pp. 134-161.

Kelly, J. and Richardson, R. (1989) „Annual Review Article 1988‟, British Journal of

Industrial Relations, vol. 27(1), pp. 133-154.

Kenyon, P. and Lewis, P. (1997) „The Decline in Trade Union Membership: What Role did

the Accord Play?‟, Murdoch University, Feb 1997, working paper no. 156.

Kim, D. (1998) „Reinterpreting Industry Premiums: Match-specific Productivity‟, Journal

of Labor Economics, vol. 16(3), pp. 479-504.

Kim, Hong-Kyun (2003) „Effect of IT Job Training on Employment and Wage Premium:

Evidence from Korea Panel Data‟, The Developing Economies, XLI-4, pp. 461-483.

Kim, K. (2004a) „The Effects of Family Background on Educational Continuation: From

Middle School to Graduate School‟ paper presented for COE Workshop, Feb 2,

Sendai, Japan and at KLIPS Conference, Feb 11, Seoul, Korea, pp. 334-354.

Kim, K. (2004b) „Expanded Opportunity, Persistent Inequality: Social Class and Gender

Differentials in School Transitions in Korea‟, paper prepared for the presentation at

the Association Coreene d‟Etudes Politiques Francaise‟s International Conference,

Nov 10, Seoul, Korea, 2004, pp. 1-27.

Kingston, G. and Layton, A. (1986) „The Tax Smoothing Hypothesis: Some Australian

Empirical Results‟, Australian Economic Papers, vol. 25(47), pp. 247-251.

Kish, L. (1965) Survey Sampling, John Wiley and Sons, New York.

Kish, L. and Frankel, M. (1974) „Inference from Complex Samples‟, originally published in

Journal of the Royal Statistical Society 36, Ser. B, 1-22, and republished as chapter 8

in Leslie Kish, Selected Papers (editors: Klaton, G.. and Heeringa, S.), John Wiley

and Sons, Hoboken 2002.

Korea Labor Institute, Questionnaire for Households, Korean Labor and Income Panel

Study, 1998.

Korea Labor Institute, Questionnaire for Paid Workers, Korean Labor and Income Panel

Study, 1998.

Korea Labor Institute, Questionnaire for the Unemployed, Korean Labor and Income Panel

Study, 1998.

Korea Labor Institute, Questionnaire for Households, Korean Labor and Income Panel

Study, 1999.

Korea Labor Institute, Questionnaire for Individuals, Korean Labor and Income Panel

Study, 1999.

377

Korea Labor Institute, Questionnaire for New Respondents, Korean Labor and Income

Panel Study, 1999.

Korea Labor Institute, Questionnaire for Households, Korean Labor and Income Panel

Study, 2000.

Korea Labor Institute, Questionnaire for Individuals, Korean Labor and Income Panel

Study, 2000.

Korea Labor Institute, Questionnaire for Households, Korean Labor and Income Panel

Study, 2001.

Korea Labor Institute, Questionnaire for Individuals, Korean Labor and Income Panel

Study, 2001.

Krongkaew, M. (1994) „Income Distribution in East Asian Developing Countries: An

Update‟, Asian-Pacific Economic Literature, vol. 8(2), pp. 58-73.

Krueger, A. and Summers, L. (1987) „Reflections on the Inter-industry Wage Structure‟,

NBER working paper no. 1960, National Bureau of Economic Research.

Krueger, A. and Summers, L. (1988) „Efficiency Wages and the Inter-industry Wage

Structure‟, Econometrica, vol. 56(2), pp. 259-293.

Krugman, P. (1981) „Intraindustry Specialization and the Gains from Trade‟, Journal of

Political Economy, vol. 89(5), pp. 959-974.

Lamberton, D. (1994) „The Information Revolution in the Asian-Pacific Region‟, Asian-

Pacific Economic Literature, Nov 1994, vol. 8(2), pp. 31-57.

Lang, K. (1989) „Trade Liberalisation of the New Zealand Labour Market‟, Research

Monograph 53, Oct 1989, New Zealand Institute of Economic Research.

Lanyard, R., Nickell, S. and Jackman, R. (1991) „Unemployment: Macroeconomic

Performance of the Labour Market‟, Oxford University Press, United Kingdom.

Le, A, (1999) „Empirical Studies of Self-Employment‟, Journal of Economic Surveys, vol.

13(4), pp. 381-416.

Le, A. and Miller, P. (1998) „Pitfalls in Including Current Earnings in Labour Market

Choice Estimating Equations‟, Australian Economic Papers, vol. 37(4), pp. 414-419.

Le, A. and Miller, P. (2004) „School Leaving Decisions in Australia: A Cohort Analysis‟,

Education Economics, vol. 12(1), pp. 39-65.

Lee, P. and Townsend, P. (1994) „A Study of Inequality, Low Incomes and Unemployment

in London, 1985-1992‟, International Labor Review, vol. 133(5-6), pp. 579-595.

378

Levine, D. (1991) „Just-Cause Employment Policies in the Presence of Worker Adverse

Selection‟, Journal of Labor Economics, vol. 9(3), pp. 294-305.

Lilien, D. (1980) „The Cyclical Pattern of Temporary Layoffs in United States

Manufacturing‟, Review of Economics and Statistics, vol. 51(1), pp. 24-31.

Lilien, D. (1982) „Sectoral Shifts and Cyclical Unemployment‟, Journal of Political

Economy, vol. 90(4), pp. 777-793.

Lilien, D. (1983) „A Sectoral Model of the Business Cycle‟, paper presented at the Hoover

Institute Conference, Jan 1983.

Lilien, D. (1987), comment in Murphy, K. and Topel, R. (1987a) „The Evolution of

Unemployment in the United States: 1968-1985‟, University of Chicago and National

Bureau of Economic Research.

Long, J. (1975) „Public-Private Sectoral Differences in Employment Discrimination‟,

Southern Economic Journal, vol. 42(1), pp. 89-96.

Long, J. (1976) „Employment Discrimination in the Federal Sector‟, Journal of Human

Resources, vol. 11(1), pp. 86-97.

Long, J., Plosser, J and Charles, I. (1983) „Real Business Cycles‟, Journal of Political

Economy, vol. 91(1), pp. 39-69.

Long, J., Plosser, J and Charles, I. (1987) „Sectoral versus Aggregate Shocks in the

Business Cycle‟, American Economic Review, vol. 77(2), pp. 333-336.

Loungani, P. (1986) „Oil Price Shocks and Dispersion Hypothesis‟, Review of Economics

and Statistics, vol. 18(3), pp. 517-530.

Loungani, P. and Rogerson, R. (1989) „Cyclical Fluctuations and Sectoral Reallocation.

Evidence from the PSID‟, Journal of Monetary Economics, vol. 23(2), pp. 259-273.

Loungani, P., Rush, M. and Tave, W. (1990) „Stock Market Dispersion and

Unemployment‟, Journal of Monetary Economics, 25(3), pp. 367-388.

Lu, J. (1996) „A Reconsideration of the Inter-industry Employment Dispersion‟, Economic

Letters, vol. 50(2), pp. 203-208.

Lucas, R. and Prescott, J. (1974) „Equilibrium Search and Unemployment‟, Journal of

Economic Theory, vol. 7(2), pp. 188-209.

Madden, J. (1987) „Gender Differences in the Cost of Displacement: An Empirical Test of

Discrimination in the Labor Market‟, American Economic Review, vol. 77(2), pp.

246-251.

Madden, J. (1988) „The Distribution of Economic Losses among Displaced Workers:

Measurement Methods Matter‟, Journal of Human Resources, vol. 23(1), pp. 93-107.

379

Mailath, G. and Postlewaith, A. (1990) „Workers Versus Firms: Bargaining over a Firm‟s

Value‟, Review of Economic Studies, vol. 57(3), pp. 369-380.

Manning, C. (1999) „Labour Markets in the ASEAN-4 and the NIEs‟, Asian-Pacific

Economic Literature, vol. 13(1), pp. 50-68.

Masters, S. (1974) „The Effect of Educational Differences and Labor Market

Discrimination on the Relative Earnings of Black Males‟, Journal of Human

Resources, vol. 9(3), pp. 342-360.

Mattila, J. (1974) „Job Quitting and Fricitonal Unemployment‟, American Economic

Review, Mar 1974, vol, 64(1), pp. 235-279.

McCombie, J. (1991) „The Productivity Growth Slowdown of the Advanced Countries and

the Inter-sectoral Relocations of Labor‟, Australian Economic Papers, vol. 39(56), pp.

70-85.

McCormick, B. (1997) „Regional Unemployment and Labour Mobility in the U.K.‟,

European Economic Review, vol. 41(3-5), pp. 581-589.

McGuire, T. and Rapping, L. (1967) „The Determination of Money Wages in American

Industry: Comment‟, Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 81(4), pp. 684-689.

McLaughlin, K. and Bils, M. (2001) „Interindustry Mobility and the Cyclical Upgrading of

Labour‟, Journal of Labor Economics, 2001, vol. 19(1), pp. 94-135.

Medoff, J. (1983) „U.S. Labor Markets: Imbalance Wage Growth, and Productivity in the

1970s‟, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, vol. 1983(1), pp. 87-128.

Miller, P. and Neo, L. (2003) „Labour Market Flexibility and Immigrant Adjustment‟,

Economic Record, Vol. 79(246), pp. 336-356.

Miller, P. and Rummery, S. (1991) „Male-Female Wage Differentials in Australia: A

Reassessment‟, Australian Economic Papers, vol. 30(56), pp. 50-69.

Miller, R. (1984) „Job Matching and Occupational Choice‟, Journal of Political Economy,

vol. 92(6), pp. 1086-1120.

Mills, T., Pelloni, G. and Zervoyianni, A. (1995) „Unemployment Fluctuations in the

United States: Further Tests of the Sectoral Shift Hypothesis‟, Review of Economics

and Statistics, vol. 77(2), pp. 294-304.

Mincer, J. (1978) „Family Migration Decisions‟, Journal of Political Economy, vol. 86(5),

pp. 749-773.

Mincer, J. and Jovanovic, B. (1981) „Labor Mobility and Wages‟, Studies in Labor

Markets, University of Chicago Press, Chicago Studies 1981, National Bureau of

Economic Research.

380

Mishkin, F. (1982) „Does Anticipated Monetary Policy Matter? An Econometric

Investigation‟, Journal of Political Economy, vol. 90(1), pp. 22-51.

Mishkin, F. (1983) „A Rational Expectations Approach to Macroeconometrics. Testing

Policy in Effectiveness and Efficient Market Models‟, NBER and University of

Chicago Press, Chicago.

Mitchell, W. F. (2000) „The Causes of Unemployment‟, article in The Unemployment

Crisis in Australia: Which Way Out?, edited by S. Bell, Cambridge University Press,

Cambridge, pp. 21-48.

Montgomery, J. (1991) „Equilibrium Wage Dispersion and Interindustry Wage

Differentials‟, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106(1), pp. 163-179.

Mortensen, D. (1986) „Job Search and Labor Market Analysis‟, in Handbook of Labor

Economics, vol. 2, edited by O. Ashenfelter and R. Layard, Elsevier Science

Publishers BV., pp. 849-919.

Murphy, K. and Topel, R. (1987a) „The Evolution of Unemployment in the United States,

1968-1985‟, University of Chicago and National Bureau of Economic Research,

reprint no. 1209.

Murphy, K. and Topel, R. (1987b) „Unemployment, Risk and Earnings: Testing for

Equalizing Wage Differences in the Labor Market‟, in Unemployment and the

Structure of Labor Market, edited by Lang, K. and Leonard, J., Basil Blackwell, New

York, pp. 103-140.

Murphy, K. and Topel, R. (1990) „Efficiency Wages Reconsidered: Theory and Evidence‟,

in Y. Weiss and G. Fishelson: Advance in the Theory and Measurement of

Unemployment, New York: St. Martin‟s Press, pp. 204-240.

Muscatelli, V. A. and Hurn, S. (1992) „Cointegration and Dynamic Time Series Models‟,

Journal of Economic Surveys, vol. 6(1), pp. 1-43.

Nagelkerke, N. J. D. (1991) „A Note on a General Definition of the Coefficient of

Determination‟ Biometrika, vol. 78(3), pp. 691-692.

Nam, Sang-Ho (2007) „Asset Distribution and Asset-poverty in Korea‟, Korea Institute for

Health and Social Affairs, pp. 1-25.

Neal, D. (1995) „Industry-Specific Human Capital: Evidence from Displaced Workers‟,

Journal of Labor Economics, vol. 13(4), pp. 653-677.

Neal, D. (1999) „The Complexity of Job Mobility Among Young Men‟, Journal of Labor

Economics, vol. 17(2), pp. 237-261.

Neelin, J. (1987) „Sectoral Shifts and Canadian Unemployment‟, Review of Economics and

Statistics, vol. 69(4), pp. 718-723.

381

Neumann, G. and Rissman, E. (1984) „Where have all the Union Members Gone?‟ Journal

of Labor Economics, vol. 2(2), pp. 175-192.

Nielsen, H. (1998) „Discrimination and Detailed Decomposition in a Logit Model‟,

Economic Letters, vol. 61, 1998, pp. 115-120.

Nickell, S. (1997) „Structural Change and the British Labour Market‟, article in Structural

Changes and Labor Market Flexibility: Experience in OECD Countries, edited by

Horst Siebert, Mohr, Tübingen, pp. 3-28.

Norbin, S. and Schlagenhauf (1988) „An Inquiry into the Sources of Macroeconomic

Fluctuations‟, Journal of Monetary Economics, vol. 22(1), pp. 43-70.

Oatey, M. (1970) „The Economics of Training: with respect to the Firm‟, British Journal of

Industrial Relations, vol. 8(1), pp. 1-21.

Oaxaca, R. (1973) „Male-Female Wage Differentials in Urban Labour Markets‟,

International Economic Review, vol. 14(3), pp. 693-709.

Ogawa, N. and Ermisch, J. (1996) „Family Structure, Home Time Demands and the

Employment Patterns of Japanese Married Women‟, Journal of Labor Economics,

vol. 14(4), pp. 677-702.

Ohkawa, K. (1957) The Growth Rate of the Japanese Economy since 1878, Kinokuniya

Bookstore Co. Ltd., Tokyo.

Oi, W. (1987) „Comments on the Relation Between Unemployment and Sectoral Shifts‟,

Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 27, North Holland, pp. 403-

420.

Oliveira-Martins, J. (1994) „Market Structure, Trade and Industry Wages‟, OECD

Economic Studies, Spring 1994, no. 22, pp. 131-154.

Osberg, L. (1991) „Unemployment and Interindustry Labour Mobility in Canada in the

1980s‟, Applied Economics, vol. 23(11), pp. 1707-1717.

Osberg, L., Gordon, D. and Lin, Z. (1994) „Inter-regional Migration and Inter-industry

Labour Mobility in Canada: A Simultaneous Approach‟, Canadian Journal of

Economics, vol. 27(1), pp. 58-80.

Osberg, L., Manzany, R., Apostle, R. and Clairmont, D. (1986) „Job Mobility, Wage

Determination and Market Segmentation in the Presence of Sample Selection Bias‟,

Canadian Journal of Economics, vol. 19(2), pp. 319-346.

Osberg, L. and Phipps, S. (1993) „Labour Supply with Quantity Constraints: Estimates

from a Large Sample of Canadian Workers‟, Oxford Economic Papers, vol. 45(2), pp.

261-291.

382

Osburn, J. (2000) „Interindustry Wage Differentials: Patterns and Possible Sources‟,

Monthly Labor Review, Feb 2000, Bureau of Labor Statistics, Washington.

Ottersen, E. (1993) „Sectoral Shocks and Structural Unemployment. An Empirical

Analysis‟, European Economic Review, vol. 37(1), pp. 115-133.

Oxley, L. and McAleer, M. (1993) „Econometric Issues in Macroeconomic Models with

Generated Regressors‟, Journal of Economic Surveys, vol. 7(1), pp. 1-40.

Pagan A. (1984) „Econometric Issues in the Analysis of Regressions with Generated

Regressors‟, International Economic Review, vol. 25(1), pp. 221-247.

Palley, T. (1992) „Sectoral Shifts and Cyclical Unemployment: A Reconsideration‟,

Economic Inquiry, vol. 30(1), p. 117-133.

Parent, D. (1999) „Wages and Mobility: The Impact of Employer-provided Training‟,

Journal of Labor Economics, vol. 17(2), pp. 298-317.

Park, Y. , Chung, C. and Wang Y. (2001), „Fear of Floating: Korea‟s Exchange Rate

Policy after the Crisis‟, Journal of the Japanese and International Economies, vol.

15(2), pp. 225-251.

Parker, J. (1992) „Structural Unemployment in the United States: The Effects of Inter-

industry and Inter-regional dispersion‟, Economic Inquiry, vol. 30(1), pp. 101-116,

Parnes, H. (1965) „Employment and Economic Growth‟, American Economic Review, vol.

55(1/2), pp. 270-272.

Peetz, D. (1990) „Declining Union Density‟, Journal of Industrial Relations, vol. 32(2), pp.

197-223.

Pekkala, S. and Tero, H. (2002) „Unemployment and Migration: Does Moving Help?‟

Scandinavian Journal of Economics, vol. 104(4), pp. 621-639.

Perry, L. (1991) „A Comment on Aggregate Demand‟, Australian Economic Papers, vol.

30(57), pp. 278-286.

Pissarides, C. (1985) „Short-Run Equilibrium Dynamics of Unemployment, Vacancies and

Real Wages‟, American Economic Review, vol. 75(4), pp. 676-690.

Pissarides, C. and Wadsworth, J. (1989) „Unemployment and the Inter-regional Mobility of

Labour‟, The Economic Journal, vol. 99(397), pp. 739-755.

Podgursky, M. and Swaim, P. (1987) „Job Displacement and Earnings Loss: Evidence from

the Displaced Worker Survey‟, Industrial and Labor Relations Review, vol. 41(1), pp.

17-29.

Prasad, E. (1997) „Sectoral Shifts and Structural Change in the Japanese Economy:

Evidence and Interpretation‟, Japan and the World Economy, vol. 9(3), pp. 293-313.

383

Price, R. and Bain, G. (1983) „Union Growth in Britain: Retrospect and Prospect‟, British

Journal of Industrial Relations, vol. 21(1), pp. 46-68.

Puhani, P. A. (2000) "The Heckman Correction for Sample Selection and its Critique",

Journal of Economic Surveys, vol. 14(1), pp. 53-68.

Qian, W. (1996) Rural Urban Migration and its Impact on Economic Development in

China, Ashgate Publishing Ltd.

Radelet, S. and Sachs, S. (1998) The Onset of the East Asian Financial Crisis, NBER

working paper no. 6680, National Bureau of Economic Research.

Ramirez, M. and Khan, S. (1999) „Cointegration Analysis of Purchasing Power Parity:

1973-96‟, International Advances In Economic Research, vol. 5(3), pp. 369-385.

Ranis, G. and Fei, J. (1964) Development of the Labor-Surplus Economy: Theory and

Policy, R.D. Irwin, Homewood, Ill.

Rao, B. (1991) „What is the Matter with Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply‟,

Australian Economic Papers, vol. 30(57), pp. 264-277.

Reimers, C. (1983) „Labor Market Discrimination against Hispanic and Black‟, Review of

Economics and Statistics, vol. 65(4), pp. 570-579.

Robinson, C. (1995) „Union Incidence in the Public and Private Sectors‟, Canadian Journal

of Economics, vol. 28(4b), pp. 1056-1076.

Rogers, A. and Henning, S. (1999) „The Internal Migration Patterns of Foreign-born and

Native-born Populations in the United States: 1975-80 and 1985-90‟, International

Migration Review, vol. 33(2), pp. 403-429.

Rogerson, R. (1987) „An Equilibrium Model of Sectoral Reallocation‟, Journal of Political

Economy, vol. 95(4), pp. 824-834.

Rosovsky, H. (1961) Capital Formation in Japan, 1868-1940, The Free Press of Glencoe,

New York.

Ross, A. and Goldner, W. (1950) „Forces Affecting the Industry Wage Structure‟,

Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 64(2), pp. 254-281.

Rotemberg, J. (1987) The New Keynesian Microfoundations, Sloan School of Management

and National Bureau of Economic Research, Massachusetts.

Riddell, C. (1986) Adapting to Change: Labour Market Adjustment in Canada, University

of Toronto Press, Canada.

Riddell, W. (1997) „Structural Change and Adjustment in the Canadian Labour Market‟,

article in Structural Changes and Labor Market Flexibility: Experience in OECD

Countries, edited by Horst Siebert, Mohr, Tübingen, pp. 223-256.

384

Ruser, J. (1991) „Workers‟ Compensation and Occupational Injuries and Illnesses‟, Journal

of Labor Economics, vol. 9(4), pp. 325-350.

Saint-Paul, G. (1997) „Labour Rigidities and the Performance of the French Economy‟,

article in Structural Changes and Labor Market Flexibility: Experience in OECD

Countries, edited by Horst Siebert, Mohr, Tübingen, pp. 29-50.

Saito, M. (1971) „An Inter-industry Study of Price Formation‟, Review of Economics and

Statistics, vol. 53(1), pp. 11-25.

Samson, L. (1985) „A Study of the Impact of Sectoral Shifts on Aggregate Unemployment

in Canada‟, Canadian Journal of Economics, vol. 18(3), pp. 518-530.

Sawangfa, Onnicha (2007) „Does Job Switching Lead to Greater Satisfaction?: Evidence

from South Korea‟, Jul 2007 (www.ppdoconference.org).

Schioppa, F. (1991) „A Cross-Country Comparison of Sectoral Mismatch in the 1980s‟,

article in Mismatch and Labour Mobility, edited by F. Schioppa, Cambridge

University Press, United Kingdom, pp. 1-43.

Schultz, T. (1971) „Rural-urban Migration in Columbia‟, Review of Economics and

Statistics, vol. 53(2), pp. 157-163.

Scott, A. and Holt, D. (1982) „The Effect of Two-Stage Sampling on Ordinary Least

Squares Methods‟, Journal of the American Statistical Association, vol. 77(380), pp.

848-854.

Seok, Hyunho (1999) „International Labor Migration and Financial Crisis in Korea‟,

Development and Society, vol. 28(1), pp. 139-165.

Seong, J. (2007) „Trends of Union Participation among Non-union Employees –

Introducing the data from the Supplement Questionnaire to the 8th

KLIPS‟, working

paper, Korea Labour Institute, Feb 2007.

Sharpe, I. (1971) „The Growth of Australian Trade Unions: 1907-1969‟, Journal of

Industrial Relations, vol. 13(2), pp. 138-154.

Shin, K. (1997a) „Inter- and Intrasectoral Shocks: Effects on the Unemployment Rate‟,

Journal of Labor Economics vol. 15(2), pp. 376-401.

Shin, K. (1997b) „Sectoral Shocks and Movement Costs: Effects on Employment and

Welfare‟, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 21(2-3), pp. 448-471.

Shister, J. (1953) „The Logic of Union Growth‟, Journal of Political Economy, vol. 61(5),

pp. 413-433.

Simpson, W. (1988) „Job Mobility and the Wage-gap between Single Males and Females‟,

mimeo, University of Manitoba.

385

Slichter, S. (1950) „Notes on the Structure of Wages‟, Review of Economics and Statistics,

vol. 32(1), pp. 80-91.

Smith, J. and Welch, F. (1989) „Black Economic Progress after Myrdal‟, Journal of

Economic Literature, vol. 27(2), pp. 519-564.

Son, Jaehee (2007a) „Reappraising the Job-Training Effect on Labor Market Outputs of

Korean Women‟, Department of Economics, University of California, pp. 1-31.

Son, Jaehee (2007b) „The Effect of Job Training on the Labor Market Outcomes of Women

in Korea: Empirical Analysis with Panel Data, 1998-2005‟, Department of

Economics, University of California, pp. 1-36.

Stock, J. and Watson, M. (1993) „A Simple Estimation of Cointegrating Vectors in Higher

Order Intergrated Systems‟, Econometrica, vol. 61(4), pp. 783-820.

Stoilov, V. (1965) „Structural Unemployment: Comment‟, American Economic Review,

vol. 55(3), pp. 527-531.

Stolzenberg, Ross M. and Relles, Daniel A. (1997) "Tools for Intuition about Sample

Selection Bias and its Correction", American Sociological Review, vol. 62(3), pp.

494-507.

Subrahmanian, K., Veena, D. and Parikh, B. (1982) Construction Labour Market: A Study

in Ahmedabad, Concept Publishing Company, New Delhi.

Tanzer, C. (1999) „The Asian Crisis and the Search for a New Global Financial

Architecture‟, paper submitted for the Global Policy Forum.

Tcha, M. (1993) „Altruistic Migration – Evidence for Korea and the U.S.A.‟, University of

Western Australia, Department of Economics, Discussion Paper 93.07.

The World Bank (1999), „Republic of Korea: Establishing a New Foundation for

Sustainable Growth‟, Report No. 19595 KO, Nov 2 1999.

Thomas, J. (1996a) „Sectoral Shifts and the Mobility of Displaced Workers: When are

Microdata Useful?‟ Economic Letters, vol. 52(3), pp. 337-343.

Thomas, J. (1996b) „An Empirical Model of Sectoral Movements by Unemployed

Workers‟, Journal of Labor Economics, vol. 14(1), pp. 126-153.

Thompson, M., Fong, G., Hammond, D., Boudreau, C., Driezen, P., Hyland, A., Borland,

R., Cummings, K., Hastings, G., Siahpush M., Mackintosh A. and Laux F. (2006),

„Methods of the International Tobacco Control (ITC) Four Country Survey‟, Research

Paper, Apr 2006, produced online by BMJ Publishing Group Ltd of the BMA,

assisted by Stanford University's HighWire Press (see www.tobaccocontrol.bmj.com).

386

Tobin, J. (1972) „Inflation and Unemployment‟, American Economic Review, vol. 62(1),

pp. 1-18.

Todaro, M. (1969) „A Model of Labour-Migration and Urban Unemployment in Less

Developed Countries‟, American Economic Review, vol. 59(1), pp. 138-148.

Todaro, M. (1981) Economic Development in the Third World, Longman, Inc., New York.

Tomes, N. and Robinson, C. (1982a) „Self-selection and Interprovincial Migration in

Canada‟, Canadian Journal of Economics, vol. 15(3), pp. 474-502.

Tomes, N. and Robinson, C. (1982b) „Family Labour Supply and Fertility: a Two-regime

Model‟, Canadian Journal of Economics, vol. 15(4), pp. 706-783.

Tomes, N. and Robinson, C. (1984) „Union Wage Differentials in the Public and Private

Sectors: A Simultaneous Equations Specification‟, Journal of Labor Economics, vol.

2(1), pp. 106-127.

Topel, R. (1986) „Local Labour Markets‟, Journal of Political Economy, vol. 94(3), S111-

S143.

Troy, L. (1965) Trade Union Membership, 1897-1962, National Bureau of Economic

Research, New York.

United Nations Economic and Social Council (1999) „Implementation of the International

Covenant on Economic, Social and Cultural Rights: Addendum: Republic of Korea‟,

State Party Report No. E/1990/5/Add. 19, United Nations, 5 Jan 1994.

United Nations Economic and Social Commission for Asia and the Pacific (1999)

„Emerging Issues and Developments at the Regional Level: Socio-Economic

Measures to Alleviate Poverty in Rural and Urban Areas - Empowerment of Women

in Asia and the Pacific‟, Fifty-Fifth Session, 22-28 Apr 1999, Bangkok, ESCAP Paper

Number 1133, Feb 1999.

Utgoff, K. (1983) „Compensation Levels and Quit Rates in the Public Sector‟, Journal of

Human Resources, vol. 18(3), pp. 394-406.

Vanderkamp, J. (1971) „Migration Flows, Their Determinants and the Effects of Return

Migration‟, Journal of Political Economy, vol. 79(5), pp. 1012-1031.

Vanderkamp, J. (1977) „Industrial Mobility: Some Further Results‟, Canadian Journal of

Economics, vol. 10(3), pp. 462-472.

van der Gaag, J. and Vijverberg, W. (1988) „A Switching Regression Model for Wage

Determinants in the Public and Private Sectors of a Developing Country‟, Review of

Economics and Statistics, vol. 70(2), pp. 244-252.

Wachter, M. (1970) „Cyclical Variation in the Interindustry Wage Structure‟, American

Economic Review, vol. 60(1), pp. 75-84.

387

Wachter, M. (1987) „Help-wanted Advertising, Job Vacancies and Unemployment.

Comments and Discussion‟, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, vol. 1987(1),

pp. 244-248.

Wannell, T. (1992) „Firm Size and Employment: Recent Canadian Trends‟, Canadian

Economic Observer, Vol. 5(3), Feature Article.

Watson, N. (2004) „Wave 2 Weighting‟, HILDA Project Technical Paper Series no. 4/04,

Jul 2004.

Watson, N. and Fry, T. (2002) „The Household, Income and Labour Dynamics in Australia

(HILDA) Survey: Wave 1 Weighting‟, HILDA Project Technical Paper Series no.

3/02, Sep 2002.

Weiss, L. (1984) „Sectoral Shifts and Assymmetric Adjustment Costs‟, mimeo, University

of Chicago, Illinois.

Willis, R. and Rosen, S. (1979) „Education and Self-Selection‟, Journal of Political

Economy, vol. 87(5), part 2, S7-S36.

Wolman, L. (1936) Ebb and Flow in Trade Unionism, National Bureau of Economic

Research, New York.

Yellen, J. (1984) „Efficiency Wage Models of Unemployment‟, American Economic

Review, vol. 74(2), Papers and Proceedings of the Ninety-sixth Annual Meeting of the

American Economic Association, May 1984, pp. 200-205.

Yoo, Kil-Sang (2005) „Financial Crisis and Unemployment Measures: The Experience of

Korea‟, working paper, Korea Labor Institute, Dec 2005.

Young, Jun-Chun (2005) „Population Aging, Fiscal Policies, and National Saving:

Prediction for Korean Economy‟, Department of Economics, University of Incheon,

pp. 1-29.

Young, Jun-Chun (2006) „Fiscal Impacts of Taxation on Pension in Aging Korea: A

Generational Accounting Approach‟, Department of Economics, University of

Incheon, May 2006, pp. 1-30.

Zagorsky, J. (1990) „Can Shifty Beveridge Curves be Trusted? New Findings in the

Unemployment-Vacancy Relationship‟, working paper, Boston University, Boston.

Zahn, F. (1971) „Sectoral Labour Migration and Sustained Industrialisation in the Japanese

Development Experience‟, Review of Economics and Statistics, vol. 53(3), pp. 283-

287.

Zhou, S. (2001) „The Power of Cointegration Tests versus Data Frequency and Time

Spans‟, Southern Economic Journal, vol. 67(3), pp. 906-921.