46
1 Institutional Investors, Risk/Performance and Corporate Governance: Practical Lessons from the Global Financial Crisis. Marion Hutchinson* Queensland University of Technology, Australia Michael Seamer University of Newcastle, Australia Larelle (Ellie) Chapple Queensland University of Technology, Australia Prepared for presentation at The International Journal of Accounting Symposium, Zhongnan University of Economics and Law, China This version: May 2013 Keywords: Institutional investors, corporate governance, risk and performance. *Corresponding author.

Institutional Investors, Risk/ Performance and Corporate ...€¦ · association by acting as a substitute monitoring mechanism when governance is low. 3 Introduction The purpose

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    0

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Institutional Investors, Risk/ Performance and Corporate ...€¦ · association by acting as a substitute monitoring mechanism when governance is low. 3 Introduction The purpose

1

Institutional Investors, Risk/Performance and Corporate Governance: Practical Lessons

from the Global Financial Crisis.

Marion Hutchinson*

Queensland University of Technology, Australia

Michael Seamer

University of Newcastle, Australia

Larelle (Ellie) Chapple

Queensland University of Technology, Australia

Prepared for presentation at The International Journal of Accounting Symposium,

Zhongnan University of Economics and Law, China

This version: May 2013

Keywords: Institutional investors, corporate governance, risk and performance.

*Corresponding author.

Page 2: Institutional Investors, Risk/ Performance and Corporate ...€¦ · association by acting as a substitute monitoring mechanism when governance is low. 3 Introduction The purpose

2

Institutional Investors, Risk/Performance and Corporate Governance: Practical Lessons

from the Global Financial Crisis.

Abstract:

The global growth in institutional investors means that firms can no longer ignore their influence

in capital markets. However, not all institutional investors have the same motives to influence the

firms they invest in. Institutional investors’ ability to influence management depends on the size

of their investment and whether they have any business relations with the firm. Using a sample

of Australian firms from 2006 to 2008, our empirical results show that the proportion of a

company’s shares held by institutional investors is positively associated with firm governance

ratings, risk and profitability. After controlling for potential reverse causality, the study shows

that firm governance practices, in particular risk management, board independence and engaging

a top-tier auditor are significantly associated with the size of institutional investment, but their

relative importance differs between the types of institutional investor. This study also

demonstrates the moderating role of governance on the association between risk and firm

performance. The negative association between risk and performance is moderated by

governance quality while large non-business institutional ownership moderates the negative

association by acting as a substitute monitoring mechanism when governance is low.

Page 3: Institutional Investors, Risk/ Performance and Corporate ...€¦ · association by acting as a substitute monitoring mechanism when governance is low. 3 Introduction The purpose

3

Introduction

The purpose of this paper is twofold. First, we determine whether firms’ governance practices

are important to institutional investors and second, we investigate whether institutional investors

differ in their influence over management and firm performance. We hypothesize that, first,

corporate governance significantly influences the size of institutional investment and, second, a

positive association between risk and performance depends on the type and size of institutional

investment. In particular, in examining the investment preferences and priorities of institutional

investors, we distinguish the motivations of two different types of institutional investors – active

investors and passive investors. This distinction is primarily determined by the economically

theoretical existence of significant potential business relationships between the firm and its

institutional investor.

As early on as Black (1998), empirical studies have tested the elusive - do institutional investors

have any impact on the performance of listed companies? Prior studies examine various events

or outcomes such as CEO turnover and attribute this to institutional monitoring based on the size

of ownership. Moreover, there are various ways to measure performance, including stock price

movements, as well as accounting measures such as Tobin’s Q, which may contribute to the lack

of consensus regarding the impact of institutional investors. In our study, we model the size and

type (distinguished by active or passive investment) of institutional ownership as a function of

corporate governance. Next we determine whether the size and type of institutional investor has

any influence over the association between risk and performance, measured as return on assets.

This is important for two reasons: first, the study distinguishes between active and passive

institutional owners, not just the size of ownership, and second, the investigation is during the

Page 4: Institutional Investors, Risk/ Performance and Corporate ...€¦ · association by acting as a substitute monitoring mechanism when governance is low. 3 Introduction The purpose

4

period leading up to and including the global financial crisis, when risk is high and performance

at the firm level is critical.

There is a branch of research devoted to the impact of activist institutional investors on the firms

they invest in. For example, Gillan and Starks (2007) provide a comprehensive overview of the

literature examining activism and its outcomes. However, as Gillan and Starks (2007) note, the

influence of institutional investors on the relationship between corporate governance and firm

performance still remains controversial due to the numerous measures of influence employed.1

In their recent review article, Brown, Beekes and Verhoeven (2011) acknowledge that an under-

researched question is whether outside shareholders with a large stake are active in ways that

improve firm performance. Further, they posit that it is more interesting to study the different

incentives across institutional investor categories. Consequently, further research is required in

order to establish whether institutional investors consider the governance practices of the firms in

which they invest and whether institutional investors actively monitor the risk and performance

of these firms.

The global financial crisis provides a unique setting to determine the consequences of

institutional investors’ involvement in and influence over corporate management and board

behaviour in the period leading up to the crisis. Our results show that during a period of

increasing risk, as measured by the standard deviation of returns, the size of institutional

investment is positively associated with high risk firms as well as firms with high governance

quality as measured by a comprehensive governance rating system.2 Further investigation reveals

1 “Chief among them [large shareholders] are short-term stock market reactions to announcement of shareholder initiatives, longer-term stock market and operating performance, outcomes of votes on shareholder proposals, and changes in corporate strategy and investment decisions in response to activism.” (Page 64). 2 Our measure of governance is provided by the Horwath-University of Newcastle Corporate Governance Reports (2007-2009).

Page 5: Institutional Investors, Risk/ Performance and Corporate ...€¦ · association by acting as a substitute monitoring mechanism when governance is low. 3 Introduction The purpose

5

that extensive risk management and top-tier auditors are important to both active and passive

institutional investors as demonstrated by the positive association between the proportion of

active and passive institutional investment and these governance factors. Passive investors that

have business relations with firms may be less willing to challenge management decisions, while

active investors that do not have business relations with the firm are more likely to contest

management. Consequently, we find board independence is only important to passive

institutional investors who prefer to rely on independent board monitoring rather that jeopardise

their business relations with management by direct intervention. Our results are significant while

controlling for potential reverse causality by using the inverse Mills ratio.

This study shows that during this period, when firms are experiencing increasing levels of risk,

there is a negative association between risk and performance (return on assets). However, there

is a positive association between risk and performance for firms with good governance as

demonstrated by high governance scores. The results of this study show that good governance

moderates the negative association between risk and performance. We also find that only large

active institutional ownership have any influence over the risk/performance association. We find

that the negative association between risk and performance is moderated by a high proportion of

ownership by active institutional investors. There is no significant association between risk and

performance for the proportion of passive institutional investment. However, these results are

not significant for firms with high governance scores. These results suggest active institutional

investors act as a substitute for poor governance to monitor the risk/ performance association.

The results of this study are important because they shed some light on the influence of different

types of investors in periods of increasing risk. Since the global financial crisis researchers have

called for more research into this area. (Bebchuck and Weisbach, 2009: 6)

Page 6: Institutional Investors, Risk/ Performance and Corporate ...€¦ · association by acting as a substitute monitoring mechanism when governance is low. 3 Introduction The purpose

6

“The financial crisis has intensified the ongoing debate about the role that shareholders should play in corporate governance. To some, increasing shareholder power and facilitating shareholder intervention when necessary is part of the necessary reforms. To others, activism by shareholders who potentially have short-term interests is part of the problem, not a solution. To what extent (and when) can shareholder activism improve firm value and performance? To what extent (and when) can shareholder activism produce distortions that make matters worse? Research by financial economists that seeks further light on these questions will provide valuable input to the questions with which decision-makers are wrestling.”

Background and Hypothesis Development

The monitoring role of institutional investors

Prior research argues that because all shareholders, both large and small, benefit from the actions

of monitoring shareholders without incurring costs, only large shareholders have significant

incentives to monitor management (Shleifer and Vishny, 1986; Noe, 2002). In addition, large

investors are more active monitors of management because they receive more of the benefits of

monitoring (Shliefer and Vishny, 1986; Jensen, 1993) and have more to lose from agency

conflicts (Alchian and Demsetz, 1972) particularly management horizon problems (Dechow and

Sloan, 1991).

When ownership is spread amongst a large number of smaller shareholders, there is no incentive

for any single owner to effectively monitor management (Gillan and Starks, 1998).

Consequently, institutional investors have the ability to influence management’s activities

directly through ownership in the firm, and indirectly by trading their shares in the firm (Gillan

and Starks, 2003). Heavy selling by these investors can cause the share price to decline, or can be

interpreted as bad news thereby triggering sales by other investors, further contributing to a

decline in share price (Parrino, Sias, and Starks, 2003; Baysinger, Kosnik, and Turk, 1991) and

an ensuing increase in the cost of capital. Subsequently, institutional investors have the capacity

to influence corporate management and board behaviour. For example, research in the US finds

Page 7: Institutional Investors, Risk/ Performance and Corporate ...€¦ · association by acting as a substitute monitoring mechanism when governance is low. 3 Introduction The purpose

7

that higher institutional ownership is associated with higher R&D expenditure (Baysinger et al.,

1991; Bushee, 1998; Wahal and McConnell, 2000) and capital expenditure (Wahal and

McConnell, 2000), increased likelihood and frequency of management earnings forecasts

(Ajinkya, Bhojraj, and Sengupta, 2005), more extensive social, ethical and environmental

disclosure (Solomon and Solomon, 2006), and reduced earnings management in Australian firms

(Hsu and Koh, 2005). The size of institutional investment is likely to affect their ability to

influence management and ensure that they operate in the interests of shareholders (Shleifer and

Vishny, 1986) as well as reducing the costs of acquiring information (Johnson et al., 2010).

Several international recommendations suggest that institutional investors should be active

monitors of corporate governance (e.g. Hampel Committee, 1998; Walker, 2009) based on the

assumption that as large shareholders institutional investors should act more like owners rather

than investors. In Australia, the Association of Superannuation Funds of Australia’s (ASFA,

20033) guidelines for superannuation (pension) fund trustees, encourages them to be active

shareowners. ASFA members are large institutional investors with a duty to invest in the best

interests of their beneficiaries and are encouraged by ASFA to vote on all company resolutions

where they hold shares. Despite these recommendations, pension funds have mainly left

relationships with their portfolio companies to their investment managers (Walker, 2009). Hsu

and Koh (2005) argue that the frequency of institutional investors’ trades and the fragmentation

of their ownership preclude active monitoring of the diverse firms in their portfolio.

Although large shareholders have the potential to solve some agency costs, they can also create

others. Research also suggests that there are several disincentives for institutional investors to

actively participate in the governance of portfolio firms (Stapledon, 1996; Webb, Beck and 3 Revised in April 2010.

Page 8: Institutional Investors, Risk/ Performance and Corporate ...€¦ · association by acting as a substitute monitoring mechanism when governance is low. 3 Introduction The purpose

8

McKinnon, 2003). Webb et al. (2003) refer to: high transaction costs; the use of index-tracking

funds; the inability of investors to influence company strategy; and, the free-ride of other

investors on the acquisition cost of the institutional investor. As long as the calculated costs of

exit are less than the costs of taking a more active role in the managerial functions, institutional

investors are more likely to choose exit, rather than company reform.

Institutional investors (and portfolio managers) are under pressure to show short-term returns as

they are rewarded and reviewed based on quarterly, or at most, annual performance results

(Aguilera, Rupp, Williams, and Ganapathi, 2007; Baysinger et al., 1991; Graves, 1988). As such,

these investors are pre-disposed to supporting investments when there is an immediate

association with profits, such as mergers and acquisitions, to maintain short-term

competitiveness rather than taking a long-term view in their investment decisions (Graves,

1988). Little is known about the consequences of the exponential growth of institutional

investment and the impact on corporate behaviour. This study empirically determines whether

increasing institutional investment, and the type of activism of the institutional owner, is

associated with a positive risk/performance relationship. Can and should institutional investors

effectively identify and monitor for systemic risk?

Institutional investor heterogeneity.

One issue that arises in measuring institutional influence is that not all institutions are willing or

able to exert influence; a growing body of corporate governance literature refers to this as

institutional investor heterogeneity (Agrawal, 2012). Using economic theories relating to

incentives, we distinguish broadly between ‘active’ investors, who have more economic

incentive to monitor, and ‘passive’ investors, who have less economic incentive to monitor based

Page 9: Institutional Investors, Risk/ Performance and Corporate ...€¦ · association by acting as a substitute monitoring mechanism when governance is low. 3 Introduction The purpose

9

on conjecture that they have competing incentives. The constructs of active versus passive

therefore are primarily driven by theory, not by actual observed evidence of monitoring

behaviour of the sampled firms.

One compelling distinction relies on recognising other significant business relationships that

investors have with their firms, based on the industry of the investor and the ordinary course of

their business. Hence, if an investor, by the nature of their business, would consider the investee

firm to be a consumer or customer of its business products of services, we see that as providing a

competing economic incentive to monitoring. The investor has other avenues of revenue and

business relationship with the investee that renders the cost of monitoring less motivating. On the

other hand, if an investor is in the primary business of investing, then the economic incentives to

monitor the activities of management of investee firms are much more compelling. Other studies

on institutional investors consider various methods of distinguishing institutional investor

incentives to monitor, for example political or social influences conflicting with the objective of

firm performance (Woidtke, 2001; Gillan and Starkes, 2000; Agrawal, 2012).

However, we follow Almazan, Hartzell, and Starks (2005) who divide institutional investors into

two groups, potentially active investors and potentially passive investors. As they assert, it is the

potential for monitoring that determines the division into the two groups. For example, Brickley,

Lease, and Smith (1988) examine a particular shareholder decision making context, charter

amendment. They suggest that institutional investors such as mutual funds and pension funds are

more likely to oppose management; compared to banks and insurance companies, who derive

benefits from their lines of business. Accordingly, we similarly refer to this latter category as

“passive”. Passive institutions face high monitoring costs because they could damage their

Page 10: Institutional Investors, Risk/ Performance and Corporate ...€¦ · association by acting as a substitute monitoring mechanism when governance is low. 3 Introduction The purpose

10

relationship with firm management and lose existing or potential business if they challenge

management directly.

In contrast, institutions such as investment companies, independent investment advisors and

public pension funds do not seek business relationships with the firms in which they invest (we

call these active institutional investors). Thus, active institutions without potential business ties

face lower monitoring costs as they are more likely to directly challenge management

(Borokhovich et al. 2006; Chen, Harford, and Li, 2007) and may be less reliant on certain

governance practices, such as board monitoring, to fulfil their monitoring and fiduciary

responsibilities.

Institutional investors and corporate governance

Corporate governance has been investigated as a means of attracting institutional investors

(Chung and Zhang, 2011). Research finds that institutional investors are more likely to invest in

firms with governance practices that concur with their fiduciary duties (Hawley and Williams,

2000) and to reduce their costs of monitoring (Bushee and Noe, 2000). Prior research suggests

that governance practices are associated with less information asymmetry (Byun, Hwang, and

Lee, 2011), better reporting quality (Beekes and Brown, 2006), greater transparency (Goodwin,

Ahmed, and Heaney, 2009; Kent and Stewart, 2008), are less likely to experience fraud (e.g.

Beasley, 1996; Farber, 2005) and report abnormal accruals (Davidson, Goodwin-Stewart, and

Kent., 2005; Klein, 2002; Peasnell, Pope, and Young , 2005; Peasnell, Pope, and Young, 2000).

Consequently, institutional investors are likely to be attracted to firms that follow recommended

governance practices regardless of the investor type. Thus, the size of institutional investment is

Page 11: Institutional Investors, Risk/ Performance and Corporate ...€¦ · association by acting as a substitute monitoring mechanism when governance is low. 3 Introduction The purpose

11

positively associated with firms’ governance ratings, which are based on their compliance with

recommended governance practices and governance quality.

This leads to our first hypothesis:

H1: Institutional investment is positively associated with governance quality.

However, the results of research testing whether institutional investors invest in firms with

certain governance practices are equivocal. This may be a consequence of failing to consider the

heterogeneity of institutional investors. Certain governance practices may be more important for

passive investors where monitoring costs are high but less important for active investors where

monitoring costs are low. As active investors are more likely to directly monitor management

they act as a substitute for certain corporate governance mechanisms. Further, in situations of

high uncertainty such as high market and firm risk, institutional investors demand more stringent

governance practices. Given that we expect institutional investors to have different relationships

with the firms in which they invest, certain governance practices are likely to be more (less)

important to different types of institutional investor.

Risk management practices.

Agency theory suggests that there are divergent risk preferences of risk-neutral (diversified)

shareholders and risk-averse managers, which necessitates monitoring by the board (Jensen and

Meckling, 1976; Subramaniam, McManus, and Zhang, 2009). Consequently, without

monitoring, risk-averse managers may reject profitable (but more risky) projects that are

attractive to shareholders who prefer the increased return from higher risk. Excessive managerial

risk-taking is not considered problematic because one firm’s failure will not affect a diversified

Page 12: Institutional Investors, Risk/ Performance and Corporate ...€¦ · association by acting as a substitute monitoring mechanism when governance is low. 3 Introduction The purpose

12

investor’s portfolio in any directional way. Gordon (2010:4) explains this notion “Competitors of

the failed firm may do better; suppliers to the failed firm may do worse, but the consequences are

“unbiased.” If all firms are taking good bets, however, then on average the diversified investor

will be better off”.

The challenge, from the shareholder point of view, is how to encourage managers to take all

positive net present value investment opportunities despite the likelihood that some will turn out

badly with the consequent risk of firm insolvency, which may destroy managers’ firm-specific

human capital investment. Therefore, how firms manage risk is important to all types of

investors. Firms’ risk management includes monitoring the level of risk the firm is exposed to

while keeping in mind the desire to maximise returns. The firm may have a separate committee

(risk management committee), which advises the board on the firm’s management of the current

risk exposure and future risk strategy (Walker, 2009). It is expected that the firm will make

decisions on risk exposure based on their perception of shareholders’ interests. Consequently,

there will be a positive association between the size of institutional investment and firm risk

because research tells us that shareholders prefer more risk (Jensen and Meckling, 1976; Pathan,

2009). This leads to our next hypotheses:

First, we expect a positive association between risk and the size of institutional investment due to

the anticipated higher return for greater risk.

H2a: Institutional investment is positively associated with the level of risk.

And second, we expect a positive association between the firm’s risk management practices and

the size of institutional investment for both types of investors as monitoring the risk exposure of

the firm is consistent with the fiduciary duties of institutional investors.

Page 13: Institutional Investors, Risk/ Performance and Corporate ...€¦ · association by acting as a substitute monitoring mechanism when governance is low. 3 Introduction The purpose

13

H2b: Institutional investment is positively associated with firms’ risk management

practices.

Top-tier auditor.

External auditors act as an assurance agent between the financial statements users and

management, by providing an opinion on the “true and fair” representation of the financial

reports. The report users rely on the auditors in the hope that they can detect any material

misstatements or financial fraud in the statements and increase the credibility of the accounting

numbers and disclosures (Healy and Palepu, 2001). Investors tend to regard financial reports

audited by top-tier auditors (Big 4) as high quality (Teoh and Wong, 1993).

The association of Big 4 auditors and audit quality are so interconnected much research uses Big

4 as a proxy for audit quality (Balsam, Krishnan and Yang, 2003; Bartov, Gul and Tsui, 2000).

The auditor literature posits that larger audit firms, often termed top-tier auditor firms, provide

higher quality audit services than smaller audit firms (Carcello and Neal, 2000). This is because

larger audit firms can access greater resources (Palmrose, 1988), provide more effective quality

control over their audits (Watts and Zimmerman, 1981), have greater industry specialization

(Dunn, Mayhew, and Morsfield, 2004) and have greater reputation capital at risk (DeFond and

Subramanyam, 1998). The literature also suggests top-tier auditors are often associated with

client firms with more effective corporate governance (Beasley and Petroni, 2001). Research

finds that top-tier audit firms require higher quality annual return disclosure by their clients

(Goodwin, Amhed, and Heaney, 2009; Kent and Stewart, 2008), are more effective at detecting

fraudulent financial reporting (Johnson, Jamal, and Berryman, 1991), and are more likely to

Page 14: Institutional Investors, Risk/ Performance and Corporate ...€¦ · association by acting as a substitute monitoring mechanism when governance is low. 3 Introduction The purpose

14

issue going-concern reports to companies experiencing financial distress (Mutchler, Hopwood

and McKeown, 1997) than non top-tier firms.

Institutional investors place considerable reliance on the content and the quality of audited

statements (Velury, Reisch, and O’Reilly, 2003). Velury et al. (2003) find that audit quality4 is

positively associated with the size of institutional investment. Consequently, the size of

institutional investment is likely to be associated with the firm being audited by a top-tier

auditor, which facilitates institutional investors monitoring and fiduciary responsibilities.

This leads to our next hypothesis:

H2c: The size of institutional investment is positively associated with firms audited by a

top-tier auditor.

Board monitoring

According to agency theory, the board of directors is a vital component of corporate governance

based on the premise that the characteristics of the board members determines the board’s ability

to monitor and control managers, provide information and counsel to managers, monitor

compliance with applicable laws and regulations, and link the corporation to the external

environment (Carter, D’Souza, Simkins, and Simpson, 2010). The board either directly, or

following advice from the risk management committee, monitors the risk the firm is exposed to

while keeping in mind the desire to maximise returns. The board oversees management of the

firm’s current risk exposure and future risk strategy (Walker, 2009). Consequently, institutional

investors with greater monitoring costs will favour firms with board structures that comply with

recommended governance practice. 4 Velury et al. (2003) classify audit quality as auditor industry specialisation.

Page 15: Institutional Investors, Risk/ Performance and Corporate ...€¦ · association by acting as a substitute monitoring mechanism when governance is low. 3 Introduction The purpose

15

The ASX CGC recommends that the board of directors should consist of a majority of

independent directors (ASX CGC, 2007). This recommendation reflects an agency theory

perspective that independent directors are more representatives of shareholders and therefore

better contribute to the provision of independent monitoring of management (Fama and Jensen,

1983; Jensen and Meckling, 1976; Pincus, Rusbarsky, and Wong, 1989). While the ASX CGC

(2007) do not recommend the size of the board, research suggests that as board size increases, so

does the incremental cost of poorer communication, diffusion of responsibility and ineffective

decision making (Yermack, 1996). Conversely, a larger board may bring a greater depth of

knowledge and diverse skills essential for monitoring risk and compensation practices.

Consequently, the size of institutional investment is likely to be associated with the size of the

board.

The ASX CGC (2007) also recommends that the chair of the board and the position of CEO

should not be held by the same person. When the CEO is also the board chair they may be

motivated to act opportunistically, undertaking such activities as empire building and excessive

or unrelated diversification without independent oversight (Baysinger and Hoskisson, 1990).

Jensen (1993) argues that management domination of the board is particularly evident when the

CEO also serves as board chair. Combining these roles reduces the board’s ability to adequately

monitor management for two reasons. Firstly, it renders the board less reliant on independent

directors and secondly, it creates a potential for conflict as the dual CEO/board chair attempts to

represent both management and shareholders.

The empirical evidence supports the premise that boards with dual CEO/chairs are less effective

in controlling management than boards where the roles are segregated. For example Forker

(1992) finds firms with a non-executive chairman are more likely to disclose information about

Page 16: Institutional Investors, Risk/ Performance and Corporate ...€¦ · association by acting as a substitute monitoring mechanism when governance is low. 3 Introduction The purpose

16

share options than firms chaired by a CEO. Research finds that firms with a CEO who

simultaneously serves as board chair are also more likely to misstate financial statements

(Efendi, Srivastava, and Swanson, 2007), have announcement returns of greater magnitude

(Masulis, Wand, and Xie, 2007) and manipulate earnings (Dechow, Sloan, and Sweeney, 1996)

than firms where the roles are segregated. Da Silva Rosa, Filippetto, and Tarca (2008)

investigate a sample of Australian companies subject to ASIC action in relation to a range of

disclosure, accounting and other governance matters and find these companies were less likely to

comply with ASX best practice, particularly with respect to segregation of the roles of CEO and

board chair. Consequently, we expect a negative association between CEO duality and

institutional investment.

We suggest that the corporate governance characteristics that relate to board monitoring are only

important to passive institutional investors because they face higher monitoring costs given their

business relation with the firm. Further, if active institutional investors can be counted on to

closely monitor management then boards may not need to be as independent. Previous research

supports this notion as Jiambalvo, Rajgopal, and Ventkatchala (2002) find blockholders are

efficient external monitors of accounting quality and can substitute for an independent audit

committee. However, they did not differentiate between investor type or the size of their

investment in the firm.

H2d: The size of passive institutional investment is positively associated with board

monitoring.

Risk and performance

Page 17: Institutional Investors, Risk/ Performance and Corporate ...€¦ · association by acting as a substitute monitoring mechanism when governance is low. 3 Introduction The purpose

17

Firm risk, as a measure of the firm’s information environment and the risk of its operating

environment, is also a potentially important determinant of firm performance. There is

considerable research that finds that high growth firms (high investment opportunities) have high

levels of risk. Skinner’s (1993) seminal paper finds that asset risk varies as a function of the

investment opportunity set. Excessive managerial risk-taking is not considered problematic to a

diversified shareholder because one firm’s failure will not affect a diversified investor’s portfolio

in any directional way. The typical finance approach for explaining a positive association

between risk and return is that investors receive a risk premium for accepting higher levels of

risk.

In contrast, Bowman (1980) finds that the relationship between risk and return could be negative

when accounting measures are used as measures of return. Bowman (1980) tested his hypothesis

that prosperous firms will avoid high risk investments because the consequences of failure will

affect their reputation while poorly performing firms will pursue risky investments in the hope

that high returns will reverse their poor performance. Bowman tested this hypothesis by

examining annual reports over a nine-year period for over 1,500 companies in 85 different

industries, and found that higher returns (ROE) carried lower risk and lower returns carried

higher risk (Raynor, et al., 2010).

Raynor et al. (2010: 105) state “risk is prospective—forward-looking and unavoidably based on

subjective assessments of the probability of future outcomes—while results (the returns to the

investment) are retrospective and much more nearly in the realm of facts”. The objective of this

study is not to prove or disprove Bowman’s hypothesis, only to report what we have observed

from the data.

Page 18: Institutional Investors, Risk/ Performance and Corporate ...€¦ · association by acting as a substitute monitoring mechanism when governance is low. 3 Introduction The purpose

18

Firm risk refers to the underlying volatility of firms’ earnings and has been identified as a source

of agency conflict (Bathala and Rao, 1995). Firms design their governance practices to monitor

managerial behaviour and to curb sub-optimal risk-taking. Christy, Matolcsy, Wright, and Wyatt

(2013) use stock return volatility as their measure of risk when testing the association between

corporate governance variables and risk. They find that the volatility of stock returns is

negatively associated with governance variables, board independence and qualifications.

Consequently, we suggest that governance quality has the potential to moderate sub-optimal risk-

taking which results in a negative association between risk and performance. The previous

discussion leads to the following hypothesis:

H3a: The negative association between risk and performance is moderated by the quality

of firm governance.

We posit that active institutional shareholders are more likely to monitor the risk/performance

relation as they are not restricted by a business association with the firm and are more likely to

influence proxy voting if their demands are not met. Prior US research finds that institutional

investors with no business relations with the investee firm are more active in voting on

antitakeover amendments (Brickley, Lease, and Smith, 1988) and influence firm innovation

(Kochhar and David, 1996). More recently, Bebchuch and Weisbach (2009) note that activist

hedge funds (non-business related investors) do not commonly seek to acquire the investee

company. Instead they try to affect the way in which the company is run or to get the company to

be acquired by someone else. Consequently, it can be inferred that passive institutional investors

do not actively influence managerial choices due the costs associated with damaging their

potential business relations with the investee firm and the subsequent increase in monitoring

costs.

Page 19: Institutional Investors, Risk/ Performance and Corporate ...€¦ · association by acting as a substitute monitoring mechanism when governance is low. 3 Introduction The purpose

19

Further, the size of the institutional investor’s ownership means they may have some ability to

influence proxy voting (Johnson, Schnatterly, Johnson, and Chiu, 2010). Subsequently, we

expect the size of active institutional investment to moderate the negative association between

risk and performance. We do not expect such pressure to be exerted by passive investors and

therefore expect that a significant association between risk and performance does not depend on

the size of passive institutional investment. Based on the preceding discussion, the following

hypothesis is posited:

H3b: The negative association between risk and performance is moderated by the size of

active institutional investment.

Method

Sample selection

Australia has the fourth-largest investment market in the world and pension funds control about

75% of Australia’s investment capital. Consequently, a study of the relationship between

institutional investors and Australian firms provides an important contribution to an

economically important area of research. The sample was constructed from the Top 400 firms in

terms of market capitalisation listed on the ASX, which was reduced to 316 as each firm is

required to be in Top 400 for each year (2006-2008) and to lag variables into 2009. The sample

was further reduced due to lack of institutional investor data for some companies. The final

sample consists of an unbalanced panel data set of 256 firms listed on the Australian Securities

Exchange for the years 2006 to 2008 (714 observations) based on the availability of the relevant

data. Ownership data is collected from the Osiris data base and archival data on firms’ corporate

governance characteristics is hand collected from the company annual reports. Financial

Page 20: Institutional Investors, Risk/ Performance and Corporate ...€¦ · association by acting as a substitute monitoring mechanism when governance is low. 3 Introduction The purpose

20

variables are provided by Aspect FinAnalysis. Risk measures are obtained from the Centre for

Research in Finance (CRIF) risk measurement service of the Australian School of Business,

University of New South Wales.

Research Model

We formally investigate H1 and 2 using random effects generalised least square (GLS)

regression estimated with clustered-robust (also referred to as Huber-White) standard errors to

control for any serial dependence in the data (Gow, Ormazabal, and Taylor, 2010; Petersen,

2009). The results of the Hausman test determine that a random effect generalised least squares

(GLS) regression model is appropriate to test the panel data. Panel data is often cross-sectionally

and serially correlated thereby violating the common assumption of independence in regression

errors (Gow et al., 2010). Hence, clustered standard errors are unbiased as they account for the

residual dependence (Petersen, 2009). According to Petersen’s (2009) simulations, clustered

robust standard errors are correct in the presence of year effects (if year dummies are included),

with no assumed parametric structure for within-cluster errors, so that the firm effect can vary

both spatially and temporally.

The models for testing the hypotheses include 2 stages. Hypotheses 1 and 2 are formally

investigated using random effects generalised least square (GLS) regression estimated with

clustered-robust (also referred to as Huber-White) standard errors to control for any serial

dependence in the data (Gow et al., 2010; Petersen, 2009). The results of the Hausman test

determine that a random effect GLS regression model is appropriate to test the panel data. While

testing the first and second hypotheses we control for the potential problem of reverse causality

with the two-stage Heckman (1976) procedure. We first compute the Inverse Mills Ratio

Page 21: Institutional Investors, Risk/ Performance and Corporate ...€¦ · association by acting as a substitute monitoring mechanism when governance is low. 3 Introduction The purpose

21

(MILLS) (Heckman, 1976; Johnston and DiNardo, 1997) from the model that predicts the factors

that are associated with firm risk and institutional ownership. We then use the MILLS as an

additional control variable in the stage 2 model to determine the association between the size of

institutional holdings and the firm’s corporate governance practices. In addition, random effects

generalised least square (GLS) regression estimated with clustered-robust (also referred to as

Huber-White) standard errors is used in the second stage of the analysis to control for any serial

dependence in the data (Gow et al., 2010; Petersen, 2009).

We use 2SLS GLS random effects instrumental variables to test H3. We instrument variables

that are likely to be associated with performance but not related to governance practices. We test

the impact of increasing institutional ownership on firms’ performance by considering the

interaction between the size of institutional investment and risk. We test the size of institutional

investment by including a square term for both types of ownership. When institutional investors

own a small proportion of the firm shares, we expect that the negative association between risk

and performance will remain. However, when institutional investors own a large proportion of

the firm shares (ACTIVESQ; PASSIVESQ), we expect a positive association between risk and

performance. With this ownership concentration, active institutional investors have the incentive

and ability to pressure management to monitor risk and performance more closely. We expect a

positive association between the interaction term and the subsequent year’s performance

(ROAt+1).

The models for testing the hypotheses are:

ALLINST = β0 + β1CGSCORE + β2MILLS + β3ROAt + β5LNMKTCAP + β6MBVE

+β7INDADJSTD + ε (1)

Page 22: Institutional Investors, Risk/ Performance and Corporate ...€¦ · association by acting as a substitute monitoring mechanism when governance is low. 3 Introduction The purpose

22

ALLINST = β0 + β1RISKMGT + β2BDINDEP + β3BDSIZE + β4DUAL + β5AUDITOR +

β6ROAt + β7MILLS + β8LNMKTCAP + β9MBVE + β10INDADJSTD + ε.

(2)

ROA t+1 = β0 + β1CGSCORE + β2INDADJSTD + β6ROAt + β8ACTIVE +

β9PASSIVE + β10ACTIVE*STDEV + β11PASSIVE*STDEV + β12ACTIVESQ +

β13PASSIVESQ + β14ACTIVESQ*STDEV + β15PASSIVESQ*STDEV +ε.

(3)

Dependent variables

Following Almazan, Hartzell, and Starks (2005), institutional investors are categorized into two

groups based on their potential business relations with the firms in which they invest. The first

group is defined as passive owners due to the potential business relations with firms they may be

less likely to challenge management for fear of jeopardizing the relation. Osiris classifications

are used; with potentially passive institutions including banks and insurance companies. The

second group is defined as active owners, due to the expectation that they will not have

significant potential business relations with firms and are therefore more likely to directly

challenge management. These institutions include pension funds, other investment firms5 and

hedge funds. For each category, institutional investment is computed as the proportion of

institutional investors’ shares of total shares outstanding. The proportion of banks and insurance

companies’ ownership is added together (PASSIVE) and the proportion of pension funds and

other investment firms ownership is added together (ACTIVE).

5 Similar to pension funds, these are large listed firms that exist solely to invest in other firms.

Page 23: Institutional Investors, Risk/ Performance and Corporate ...€¦ · association by acting as a substitute monitoring mechanism when governance is low. 3 Introduction The purpose

23

Although there are various measures of firm performance used in prior research, this study uses

the firms’ return on assets (ROA) because (1) income-based risk is used in the analysis and ROA

also reflects the income of the firm, (2) ROA is likely to be influenced by the firm’s managerial

risk-taking behaviour, (3) it is a short-term measure of performance as it is based on annual

returns, and (4) it is a performance measure that is common amongst all firms thus allowing

comparability. ROA is measured as net income plus interest expense multiplied by (1-corporate

tax rate) and divided by total assets less outside equity interests.

Explanatory variables

Risk

Risk is the total risk of the firm and is measured as the standard deviation of the firm’s daily

stock returns for each fiscal year (STDEV). It is measured as the standard deviation of the rate of

return on equity for the company and is expressed as a rate of return per month computed from

the (continuously compounded) equity rates of return for the company’s equity.6 This measure

encompasses both systematic and unsystematic risk (Carr, 1997) and has been used extensively.

Risk is adjusted for industry risk by subtracting the firm’s STDEV from the industry standard

deviation of daily stock returns (INDADJSTD).

Corporate governance

We use a comprehensive measure of corporate governance (CGSCORE), which is a rating

system of corporate governance compiled by the University of Newcastle referred to as the

6 It is measured over the four-year period ending at the companies’ annual balance date. All measurable monthly returns in the four-year interval are included. Individual monthly returns measure total shareholder returns for the company, including the effects of various capitalization changes such as bonus issues, renounceable and non-renounceable issues, share splits, consolidations, and dividend distributions.

Page 24: Institutional Investors, Risk/ Performance and Corporate ...€¦ · association by acting as a substitute monitoring mechanism when governance is low. 3 Introduction The purpose

24

Horwath Report. It contains corporate governance rankings for Australia’s top 400 companies by

market capitalisation as at 30 June. The rankings are based on information about the Board and

its principal committees that is contained in the companies’ Annual Reports and related party

disclosures. The index is calculated in the same manner for all companies irrespective of their

size. The rating consists of a scoring system for several categories of governance (see

appendix1). The factors are identified with reference to national and international best practice

guidelines and research studies7. We then identify five components from the governance data:

risk management (RISKMGT), board independence (BDINDEP), board size (BDSIZE) and CEO

duality (DUAL), and top-tier auditor (AUDITOR) to determine whether governance

characteristics differ in importance for institutional investors.

Risk management. Companies are classified into one of three groups depending on the rigour of

their Enterprise Risk Management (ERM) strategies as determined from their disclosures as

required by ASX (measured as RISKMGT). Highest ranked are companies with formal ERM

policies with oversight delegated to a dedicated committee separate from the board (ranked 2),

next ranked are companies with formal ERM policies but no separate committee oversight

(ranked 1) and companies with no formal ERM policies are ranked lowest (0).

Board independence. Board independence is assessed according to compliance with the ASX

CGC (2007) definition of an independent director. Evaluation of independence is made from

information disclosed in either the corporate governance statement, related party note in the

financial statements or the director’s report in the company’s annual report. The measure

7 The maximum score for 2006 and 2007 is 125 and 135 for 2008. We therefore divide the score by 125 and 135 respectively to standardise the governance rating.

Page 25: Institutional Investors, Risk/ Performance and Corporate ...€¦ · association by acting as a substitute monitoring mechanism when governance is low. 3 Introduction The purpose

25

BDINDEP is based on the proportion of independent directors on the board (Vafeas, 2003;

Anderson and Bizjak, 2003).

Board size. There are two schools of thought with regard to optimal size. As size increases, so

does the incremental cost of poorer communication, diffusion of responsibility and ineffective

decision making (Yermack, 1996). Conversely, a larger board may bring a greater depth of

knowledge and diverse skills essential for monitoring. Consistent with prior research, this study

measures board size (BDSIZE) as the total number of members (e.g. Petra and Dorata, 2008).

CEO duality. Details of directors occupying the roles of CEO and board chair were obtained

from the Directors’ Report disclosures in the company annual report. CEO duality (DUAL) is a

dummy variable one when the CEO is also the chair, 0 otherwise.

Top-tier auditor. Four top-tier audit firms operated during the period of review. They consisted

of KPMG, PriceWaterhouseCoopers, Deloitte Touché Tohmatsu and Ernst and Young. All other

audit firms were classified as non top-tier. Company auditor was identified from the Audit

Report. This is a dummy variable coded 1 when the auditor is top-tier, 0 otherwise.

Control variables

We use the current years reported return on assets (ROAt) as it is likely to have an impact on the

size of both institutional investment and performance (ROAt+1). Inclusion of the lag of the

dependent variable is likely to mitigate concerns over reverse causality and omitted variables. To

the extent that omitted correlated variables are relatively stable, their effects can be captured by

lagged values of the dependent variable. Moreover, using a lagged dependent variable makes

reverse causality less plausible because, if profitability determines the levels of institutional

stockholding, why would institutional stockholding continue to explain future profitability even

Page 26: Institutional Investors, Risk/ Performance and Corporate ...€¦ · association by acting as a substitute monitoring mechanism when governance is low. 3 Introduction The purpose

26

when contemporaneous profitability is controlled for?8 Firm size is often included as a control

variable in previous corporate governance studies (e.g., Pathan, 2009) as an increase in firm size

is likely to lead to greater monitoring and hence the greater need for corporate control

mechanisms. We measure size as the log of market capitalisation (LNMKTCAP). We also

control for growth opportunities (market to book value of equity, MBVE). High growth firms’

investments may not come to fruition for some time in the future. Velury et al. (2003) suggests

that institutional investors are more likely to invest in firms with higher profitability than growth

opportunities. Their results were in the predicted direction but were not significant.

Results

Table 1 Panel A reports industry and investment frequency of the sample and shows that the

main industry in the sample is metals and mining at 18.4 percent followed by diversified

financials at 10.67 percent. Metals and mining is the main investment sector for both types of

investors followed by energy for the passive investor group and diversified financials for the

active investor group. Table 1 Panel B reports the descriptive statistics for the variables related to

institutional investment, firm governance and financial performance characteristics for the three

years. The results show that there is very little change in the governance variables over time and

this is to be expected (see Brown et al., 2011). However, there is considerable growth in

institutional investment from 2006 with a mean of 44 percent of issued shares to 2008 where

institutional investment is 71 percent of issued shares on average. We also identify that the

period under investigation is one of increasing total risk. Total risk (STDEV) was 10.07 in 2006

growing to 13.16 in 2008. Industry adjusted risk was 5.55 in 2006 and 7.96 in 2008.

8 We thank the reviewer for clarifying this point.

Page 27: Institutional Investors, Risk/ Performance and Corporate ...€¦ · association by acting as a substitute monitoring mechanism when governance is low. 3 Introduction The purpose

27

Insert Table 1 here

The results of correlating the transformed variables are reported in Table 2. There are significant

correlations with the CGSCORE and most of the variables. Consequently, VIF statistics were

run to test the issue of multicollinearity. The VIFs were all below 3 indicating that

multicollinearity is not an issue with the data.

Insert Table 2 here

3.4. GLS Regression results

The results of testing H1 are reported in Table 3. After controlling for potential reverse causality

by testing factors that are likely to be associated with firm risk in stage one9, the results show a

positive and significant association between the CGSCORE and the size of institutional

investors’ investment (B = 60.52; p < 0.001), thus supporting H1. We also find a positive and

significant association between risk (INDADJSTD) and the size of institutional investment (B =

1.13; p < 0.01) and ROAt (B = 32.09; p < 0.01) which suggests that institutional investors invest

in firms with higher risk and returns. The results also show that the size of institutional

investment is negatively associated with investment opportunities (MBVE). This result is

consistent with Velury et al. (2003) suggesting that institutional investors prefer short-term

profitability over future returns. These results remained consistent for each type of institutional

investor.

Next, institutional investors and active and passive investors’ ownership is tested to determine

the governance characteristics that are important to each type of investor (H2b to H2d). Risk

9 Stage one tests the association between risk (beta), institutional investors and 20 industry categories.

Page 28: Institutional Investors, Risk/ Performance and Corporate ...€¦ · association by acting as a substitute monitoring mechanism when governance is low. 3 Introduction The purpose

28

management and a top-tier auditor are valuable to both active and passive institutional investors

to meet monitoring and fiduciary duties, thus supporting H2b and H2c. Board independence and

size is only significantly associated with the size of passive institutional investment supporting

H2d. More independent boards are likely to challenge management decisions thus reducing the

monitoring costs of passive institutional investors and alleviating any problems they may face in

directly challenging management. The size of institutional ownership is not significantly

associated with CEO duality.

Insert Table 3 here

Before testing H3, we test the main effects of governance, institutional investment and firm

performance by running the regression without the interaction terms using GLS regressions and

report the results in Table 4 Panel A. We find that the following years performance (ROAt+1) is

positively associated with firm governance (CGSCORE) (B = 0.053; p < 0.05) and negatively

associated with risk (B = -0.003; p < 0.01). Return on assets is not associated with the size or

type of institutional investor. Next we test whether corporate governance or institutional

investors moderate the negative association between risk and performance by including the

interaction terms (Panel B). The results show a positive association between risk and

performance and firm governance (B = 0.015; p < 0.001)10. This association suggests that better

risk management is associated with firms’ corporate governance practices which in turn are

associated with better firm performance (H3a). In contrast, increasing the size of passive

investor’s investment with increasing firm risk is negatively associated with ROAt+1. However

this result is only marginally significant and does not control for potential endogeneity.

10 The individual governance measures are not reported as they are not significantly associated with ROAt+1.

Page 29: Institutional Investors, Risk/ Performance and Corporate ...€¦ · association by acting as a substitute monitoring mechanism when governance is low. 3 Introduction The purpose

29

The results of testing H3b using 2SLS regression are reported in Panel C of Table 4. We turn

our attention to the interaction terms to determine whether the type or size of institutional

investment has any impact on the risk/performance relationship. There is a negative association

between risk (INDJSTD) and performance (ROAt+1) for firms with low active institutional

investment (B = -0.0003; p < 0.01). However, interacting active institutional investment squared

with risk results in a positive association between risk and performance (B = 2.39e-06; p < 0.01).

There is a convex relation between risk and performance for firms with large active institutional

investment. That is, the size of active institutional investment has a moderating impact on risk.

The result suggests that increasing active institutional ownership from low levels increases risk

without increasing performance. It is only when active institutional investors have a large

enough investment in the firm that they have the incentive to monitor excessive risk-taking

where the possibility of failure increases. Future research could determine whether the

association between institutional investors and risk and return on assets is at the expense of long-

term investment strategies as indicated by the negative association between institutional

investment and growth opportunities found in this study.

Insert Table 4 here

Robustness tests

We split the sample at the median of MBVE to test whether the associations between risk and

performance and institutional investors found in this study also depend on whether the firm is a

high or low growth firm. There were no significant associations between risk and performance

for passive or active institutional investment for either high or low growth firms. However,

separating the sample into the top and bottom quartile of the CGSCORE (< 0.546 and > 0.864)

Page 30: Institutional Investors, Risk/ Performance and Corporate ...€¦ · association by acting as a substitute monitoring mechanism when governance is low. 3 Introduction The purpose

30

we find that the associations between risk and performance that were moderated by the size of

active institutional investment are not significant for high governance quality firms (see Table 5).

From this result we conclude that active institutional investors with no business ties to the

investee firm act as monitors of the risk and performance relationship when governance is weak.

Insert Table 5 here

Conclusion

Institutional investors are an important component of capital markets, especially in times of

increasing risk. However, there are significant differences among institutional investors and the

institutional context in which they exist. First, this study shows that firms’ corporate governance

practices are an important determinant of the size of institutional investment. We find that the

fraction of firms’ shares held by institutional investors increases with a comprehensive measure

of governance quality, regardless of the type of institutional investor. Further investigation shows

that risk management and top-tier auditors are important to all types of institutional investors;

however, board monitoring is only important to institutional investors with a business

relationship with the firm. That is, firms with higher monitoring costs.

Kashyap, Rajan, and Stein (2008) suggest that the global financial crisis resulted from excessive

risk-taking, highlighting the importance of monitoring risk. In the period leading up to the

global financial crisis, investors sanctioned high levels of risk in the pursuit of high returns.

Consequently, it is important to determine whether institutional investors differ in their ability to

influence managements’ pursuit of short-term returns. We categorize institutional investors

based on their ability to influence management. The ability to influence management depends on

the size of the investment and whether the firm has or could have business dealings with the

Page 31: Institutional Investors, Risk/ Performance and Corporate ...€¦ · association by acting as a substitute monitoring mechanism when governance is low. 3 Introduction The purpose

31

investor. Further, the results of this study show that the size of institutional investment is

positively associated with firm risk (standard deviation of returns) and profitability (return on

assets).

We find that high governance quality and institutional ownership moderate the negative

association between risk and performance (return on assets). Monitoring risk and performance is

critical in periods of increasing risk as experienced in the years leading up to and including the

global financial crisis. Our results suggest good corporate governance practices are associated

with the optimal combination of risk and performance. While large active institutional

shareholders appear to influence the mix of risk and performance, they do so when governance

practices are weak. In contrast, when active institutional investment is low, there is a negative

association between risk and performance. The risk-performance relationship does not depend

on passive institutional investment. Our results highlight that the ability of market forces

(institutional investors) to influence short-term returns depends on the type and size of

institutional investment. More importantly we demonstrate the importance of corporate

governance quality on the performance of the firm when risk is increasing,

Page 32: Institutional Investors, Risk/ Performance and Corporate ...€¦ · association by acting as a substitute monitoring mechanism when governance is low. 3 Introduction The purpose

32

References Agrawal, A. (2012). Corporate governance objectives of labor union shareholders: Evidence from proxy voting. Review of Financial Studies, 25(1): 187-226. Aguilera, R.V., Rupp, D. E., Williams, C. A., and Ganapathi, J. (2007). Putting the S back in CSR: A multi-level theory of social change in organizations. Academy of Management Review, 32 (3): 836-863. Ajinkya, B., Bhojraj S., and Sengupta, P. (2005). The association between outside directors, institutional investors and the properties of management earnings forecasts. Journal of Accounting Research, 43(3): 343-376. Alchian, A. A., and Demsetz, H. (1972), Production, information costs, and economic organization. The American Economic Review, 62(5): 777-795. Almazan, A., Hartzell, J., and Starks, L. (2005). Active institutional shareholders and managerial compensation. Financial Management, 34: 5-34. Anderson, R. C., and Bizjak, J. M. (2003). An empirical examination of the role of the CEO and the compensation committee in structuring executive pay. Journal of Banking and Finance, 27(7): 1323-1348. Association of Superannuation Funds of Australia (2003). Active share ownership guidelines for superannuation fund trustees. ASFA Best Practice Paper 17, Available at www.superannuation.asn.au/ArticleDocuments/116/bp17.pdf Australian Security Exchange Corporate Governance Council. (2007). Corporate Governance Principles and Recommendations (2 ed.). Sydney: Australian Security Exchange Corporate Council. Balsam, S., Krishnan, J., and Yang, J. S. (2003). Auditor industry specialization and earnings quality. Auditing: A Journal of Practice & Theory, 22: 71-97. Bartov, E., Gul, F.A., and J. S. L. Tsui. (2000). Discretionary-accruals models and audit qualifications. Journal of Accounting and Economics, (December): 421-452 Bathala, C. T., and Rao, R. P. (1995). The determinants of board composition: An agency theory perspective. Managerial and Decision Economics, 16, 59-69.

Baysinger, B.D., and Hoskinson, R. (1990). The composition of boards of directors and strategic controls: Effects on corporate strategy. Academy of Management Review, 15(1): 72-87. Baysinger, B.D., Kosnik, R.D., and Turk, T.A. (1991). Effects of board and ownership structure on corporate strategy. Academy of Management Journal, 34(1): 205-214.

Page 33: Institutional Investors, Risk/ Performance and Corporate ...€¦ · association by acting as a substitute monitoring mechanism when governance is low. 3 Introduction The purpose

33

Beasley, M.S. (1996). An empirical analysis of the relation between the boards of directors composition and financial statement fraud. The Accounting Review, 71: 443-465. Beasley, M. S., and Petroni, K. R. (2001). Board independence and audit-firm type. Auditing, 20: 97-114. Bebchuk, L.A. and Weisbach, M.S. The state of corporate governance research, NBER Working Paper Series # 15537 available at http://www.nber.org/papers/w15537

Beekes, W. and Brown, P. (2006). Do better-governed Australian firms make more informative disclosures? Journal of Business Finance, 33(3&4): 422-450. Black, B S. (1998) Shareholder activism and corporate governance in the United States, in Newman, P., Ed, The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics and the Law, Stockton Press: New York.

Borokhovich, K., Brunarski, K., Harman, Y., and Parrino, R. (2006). Variation in the monitoring incentives of outside stockholders. Journal of Law and Economics, 49:651–98. Bowman, E.H. (1980). A risk/return paradox for strategic management, Sloan Management Review, 21: 27-31.

Brickley, J., Lease, R., and Smith, C. (1988). Ownership structure and voting on antitakeover amendments. Journal of Financial Economics, 20: 267-292. Brown, P., Beekes, W., and Verhoeven, P. (2011). Corporate governance, accounting and finance: A review. Accounting and Finance, 51(1): 96-172. Bushee, B. J. (1998). The influence of institutional investors on myopic R&D investment behaviour. Accounting Review, 73: 305–33. Bushee, B.J. and Noe, C. (2000). Corporate disclosure practices, institutional investors and stock return volatility. Journal of Accounting Research, 38(supplement): 171-202. Byun, H-Y., Hwang, L-S., and Lee, W-J. (2011). How does ownership concentration exacerbate information asymmetry among equity investors? Pacific-Basin Finance Journal, 19: 511–534. Carcello, J. V., and T. L. Neal. (2000). Audit committee composition and auditor reporting. The Accounting Review, 75 (October): 453-467. Carter, D., D'Souza, F., Simkins, B., and Simpson, W.G. (2010). The gender and ethnic diversity of US boards and board committees and firm financial performance. Corporate Governance: An International Review, 18(5): 396–414. Chen, X., Harford, J., and Li, K. (2007). Monitoring: Which institutions matter? Journal of Financial Economics, (86), 279-305.

Page 34: Institutional Investors, Risk/ Performance and Corporate ...€¦ · association by acting as a substitute monitoring mechanism when governance is low. 3 Introduction The purpose

34

Christy, J.A., Matolcsy, Z.P., Wright, A., and Wyatt, A. (2013) Do board characteristics influence the shareholders’ assessment of risk for small and large firms? Abacus. Doi: 10.1111/Abac.12005.

Chung, K.H., and Zhang, H. (2011). Corporate governance and institutional ownership, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 46(1): 247–273. Da Silva Rosa, R., Filippetto, J., and Tarca A. (2008) ASIC actions: canaries for poor corporate governance? Accounting Research Journal, 21(1): 67–86. Davidson, R., Goodwin-Stewart, J. and Kent, P. (2005) Internal governance structures and earnings management. Accounting and Finance, 45: 241-267. Dechow, P. M. and Sloan, R. G. (1991). Executive incentive and horizon problem. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 14(1): 51-89. Dechow, P. M., Sloan, R.G., and Sweeney, A. (1996). Causes and consequences of earnings manipulation: An analysis of firms subject to enforcement actions by the SEC. Contemporary Accounting Research, 13: 1-36. DeFond, M.L., and Subramanyam, K.R. (1998). Auditor changes and discretionary accruals. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 25(1): 35-67. Dunn, K., Mayhew, B., and Morsfield, S. G. (2004). Auditor industry specialization and client disclosure quality. Review of Accounting Studies, 9(1): 35-58. Efendi, J., Srivastava, A., and Swanson, E.P. (2007). Why do corporate managers misstate financial statements? The role of in-the-money options and other incentives, Journal of Financial Economics, 85:667-708. Fama, E., and Jensen, M. (1983). Separation of ownership and control. Journal of Law and Economics, 26: 301-325. Farber, D.B. (2005). Restoring trust after fraud: Does corporate governance matter? The Accounting Review, 80(2): 539-561.

Forker, J.J. (1992). Corporate governance and disclosure quality. Accounting and Business Research, 22:111-24. Gillan, S. L., Starks, L. T. (1998). A survey of shareholder activism: Motivation and empirical evidence. Contemporary Finance Digest, 2, 10-34. Gillan, S.L and Starks, L.T (2000). Corporate governance proposals and shareholder activism: The role of institutional investors. Journal of Financial Economics, 57: 275–305.

Page 35: Institutional Investors, Risk/ Performance and Corporate ...€¦ · association by acting as a substitute monitoring mechanism when governance is low. 3 Introduction The purpose

35

Gillan, S. L., and Starks, L. T. (2003). Institutional investors, corporate ownership, and corporate governance: Global perspectives. In Sun, L. (ed.), Ownership and Governance of Enterprises: Recent Innovative Developments. New York: Palgrave/Macmillan, 36–68. Gillan, S. L., and Starks, L. T. (2007). The evolution of shareholder activism in the United States. Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, 19:55–73. Goodwin, J., Ahmed, K. and Heaney, R.A. (2009). Reporting the impact of the adoption of international financial reporting standards in Australia: Does corporate governance help us to understand reporting behaviour? ABACUS, 45(1): 124-145. Gow, I.D., Ormazabal, G., and Taylor, D.J. (2010). Correcting for cross-sectional and time-series dependence in accounting research. The Accounting Review, 85(2), 483-512. Graves, S.B. (1988). Institutional ownership and corporate R&D in the computer industry. Academy of Management Journal, 31(2), 417-428. Hampel Committee (Committee on Corporate Governance (Sir Ronald Hampel, chair)). (1998). Final Report, Gee Publishing: London. Hawley, J.P. and Williams, A.T. (2000). The Rise of Fiduciary Capitalism: How Institutional Investors Can Make Corporate American More Democratic. University of Pennsylvania Press. Healy, P.M. and Palepu, K.G. (2001). A review of the empirical disclosure literature. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 31(1-3): 405-440. Heckman, J. J. (1976). The common structure of statistical models of truncation, sample selection and limited dependent variables and a simple estimator for such models, Annals of Economic and Social Measurement, 5 (4): 475-492.

Horwath (2006). Corporate Governance Report, Horwath Pty Ltd, Sydney, Australia. Horwath (2007). Corporate Governance Report, Horwath Pty Ltd, Sydney, Australia. Horwath (2008). Corporate Governance Report, Horwath Pty Ltd, Sydney, Australia. Hsu, G.C.M. and Koh, P.-S. (2005). Does the presence of institutional investors influence accruals management? Evidence from Australia. Corporate Governance, 13(6):809-823. Jensen, M. C. (1993). The modern industrial revolution, exit, and the failure of internal control systems. Journal of Finance, 48(3), 831-880. Jensen, M. C., and Meckling, W. H. (1976). Theory of the firm: Managerial behaviour, agency costs and ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 3(4): 305-360.

Page 36: Institutional Investors, Risk/ Performance and Corporate ...€¦ · association by acting as a substitute monitoring mechanism when governance is low. 3 Introduction The purpose

36

Jiambalvo, J., Rajgopal, S. and Ventkatchala, M. (2002). Institutional ownership and the extent to which stock prices reflect future earnings. Contemporary Accounting Research, 19: 117–145. Johnson, R.A., Schnatterly, K., Johnson S.G., and Chiu, S-C. (2010). Institutional investors and institutional environment: A comparative analysis and review. Journal of Management Studies 47(8): 1590-1613.

Johnson, P.E., Jamal, K., and Berryman, R.G. (1991). Effects of framing on auditor decisions. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 50:75-105.

Kashyap, A., Rajan, R., and Stein, J. (2008). Rethinking capital regulation. Working paper. University of Chicago. Kent, P. and Stewart, J. (2008). Corporate governance and disclosures on the transition to international financial reporting standards, Accounting and Finance, 48(4):649-672. Klein, A. (2002). Audit committee, board of director characteristics and earnings management. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 33: 375-400. Kochhar, R. and David, P. (1996). Institutional investors and firm innovation, a test of competing hypotheses. Strategic Management Journal, 17:73–84. Masulis, R. W., Wang, C. And Xie, F. (2007). Corporate governance and acquirer returns. The Journal of Finance, 62: 1851–1889 Mutchler, J.F., Hopwood, W., McKeown, J.C. (1997). The influence of contrary information and mitigating factors on audit opinion decision on bankrupt companies. Journal of Accounting Research, 35: 295–310. Noe, T. (2002). Investor activism and financial market structure. Review of Financial Studies, 15(1): 289-318. Palmrose, Z. (1988). An analysis of auditor litigation and audit service quality. The Accounting Review, (January): 55-73. Parrino, R., Sias, R. W., and Starks, L. T. (2003). Voting with their feet: Institutional investors and CEO turnover. Journal of Financial Economics, 68: 3-46. Pathan, S. (2009). Strong boards, CEO power and bank risk-taking. Journal of Banking and Finance, 33(7): 1340-1350. Peasnell, K. V., Pope, P. F. and Young, S. (2005). Board monitoring and earnings management: Do outside directors influence abnormal accruals? Journal of Business, Finance and Accounting, 32: 1311-46.

Page 37: Institutional Investors, Risk/ Performance and Corporate ...€¦ · association by acting as a substitute monitoring mechanism when governance is low. 3 Introduction The purpose

37

Peasnell, K. V., Pope, P. F. and Young, S. (2000). Accrual management to meet earnings targets: UK evidence pre-and post-Cadbury. The British Accounting Review, 32(4): 415–445. Petersen, M. (2009). Estimating standard errors in financial panel data sets: Comparing approaches. The Review of Financial Studies, 22(1): 435-480. Petra, S. T., and Dorata, N. T. (2008). Corporate governance and chief executive officer compensation. Corporate Governance: An International Review, 8(2), 141-152. Pincus, K., Rusbarsky, M., and Wong, J. (1989). Voluntary formation of corporate audit committee among NAS-DAQ firms. Journal of Accounting and Public Policy, 8(4), 239-265. Raynor, M., Ahmed, M. and Shulz, J. (2010). It’s a mad, mad, mad, mad world, Deloitte Review, 7: 101-111. Shleifer, A., and Vishny, R. (1986). Large shareholders and corporate control. Journal of Political Economy, 94:461–88.

Solomon, J. F. and Solomon, A. (2006) Private social, ethical and environmental disclosure. Accounting, Auditing & Accountability Journal, 19(4 ): 564-591.

Stapledon, G.P. (1996). Disincentives to activism by institutional investors in listed Australian companies. Sydney Law Review, 18: 152-192. Stein, J.C. (1989). Efficient capital markets, inefficient firms: A model of myopic corporate behaviour. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 104(4): 655-669. Subramaniam, N., McManus, L., and Zhang, J. (2009). Corporate governance, firm characteristics and risk management committee formation in Australian companies. Managerial Auditing Journal, 24(4), 316-339. Teoh, S., and Wong, T. (1993). Perceived auditor quality and the earnings response coefficient. The Accounting Review, 68(2): 346-67. Vafeas, N., (2003). Length of board tenure and outside director independence. Journal of Business Finance and Accounting, 30 (7–8): 1043–1064. Velury, U, Reisch, J.T., and O’Reilly, D.M. (2003). Institutional ownership and selection of industry specialist auditors. Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting, 21: 35-48. Wahal, S., and McConnell, J.J. (2000). Do institutional investors exacerbate managerial myopia? Journal of Corporate Finance, 6: 307–329. Walker, D. (2009). A review of corporate governance in UK banks and other financial industry entities: Final recommendations. Retrieved 20 May 2010. from http://www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/d/walker_review_261109.pdf.

Page 38: Institutional Investors, Risk/ Performance and Corporate ...€¦ · association by acting as a substitute monitoring mechanism when governance is low. 3 Introduction The purpose

38

Watts, R., and Zimmerman, J., (1981). The markets for independence and independent auditors. Working Paper, University of Rochester. Webb, R., Beck, M., and McKinnon, R. (2003) Problems and limitations of institutional investor participation in corporate governance. Corporate Governance: An International Review, 11: 65-73. Woidtke, T. (2002). Agents watching agents? Evidence from pension fund ownership and firm value. Journal of Financial Economics, 63: 99–131. Yermack, D. (1996). Higher market valuation of companies with a small board of directors. Journal of Financial Economics 40:185–211.

Page 39: Institutional Investors, Risk/ Performance and Corporate ...€¦ · association by acting as a substitute monitoring mechanism when governance is low. 3 Introduction The purpose

39

Appendix 1

BOARD OF DIRECTORS Independence Board Chair and CEO Board size Board Meetings AUDIT COMMITTEE AC Exists AC Independence AC Chair AC Number Meetings AC Size AC Financial Expertise REMUNERATION COMMITTEE RC Exists RC Independence RC Chair RC Size NOMINATION COMMITTEE NC Exists NC Independence NC Chair NC Size EXTERNAL AUDIT Non-audit Fees RISK MANAGEMENT ERM policies with oversight delegated to a dedicated committee separate from the board (2) formal ERM policies but no separate committee oversight (1) no formal ERM policies (0).

DIRECTOR CONDUCT/ TENURE& DISCLOSURE Code of Conduct Independent directors have tenure < 10 years

Restrictive Share Trading policy General Corporate Governance Disclosure

TOTAL SCORE

Page 40: Institutional Investors, Risk/ Performance and Corporate ...€¦ · association by acting as a substitute monitoring mechanism when governance is low. 3 Introduction The purpose

40

Table 1 Panel A industry and investment frequency (N =712)

number % Passive % Active % 1 energy 64 8.99 9.58 8.92 2 materials (excl metals & mining) 29 4.07 4.97 4.24 3 metals & mining 131 18.40 18.42 17.84 4 capital goods 62 8.71 7.92 8.92 5 commercial services & supplies 41 5.76 6.81 5.85 6 transportation 12 1.69 1.47 1.75 7 automobile & components 8 consumer durables & apparel 12 1.69 2.03 1.75 9 consumer services 24 3.37 3.50 3.51

10 media 38 5.34 6.08 5.56 11 retailing 37 5.20 5.52 5.26

12 food & staples retailing + household & personal products 9 1.26 1.66 1.32

13 food beverage & tobacco 28 3.93 4.24 4.09 14 health care equipment & services 18 2.53 3.13 2.63

15 pharmaceuticals & biotechnology & life sciences 20 2.81 2.95 2.92

16 banks 21 2.95 3.13 3.07 17 diversified financials 76 10.67 4.79 9.50 18 insurance 11 1.54 2.03 1.61 19 real estate (excl investment trusts) 26 3.65 3.13 3.65 20 real estate investment trusts 21 software & services 35 4.92 5.89 4.97 22 technology hardware & equipment 3 0.42 0.55 0.44 23 telecommunication services 5 0.70 0.92 0.73 24 utilities 10 1.40 1.29 1.46

712 100 100 100 PASSIVE: Bank and insurance company ownership divided by total issued shares; ACTIVE: Pension funds, investment firms and hedge fund ownership divided by total issued shares.

Page 41: Institutional Investors, Risk/ Performance and Corporate ...€¦ · association by acting as a substitute monitoring mechanism when governance is low. 3 Introduction The purpose

41

Table 1: Panel B Descriptive statistics ALL YEARS (N = 712) 2006 (N=220) 2007 (N=241) 2008 (N=251) Variable- Continuous Mean Median Std.dev Mean Median Std.dev Mean Median Std.dev Mean Median Std.dev

ALLINST 54.31% 47.72% 40.63% 43.75% 38.01% 31.68% 47.05% 41.06% 35.23% 70.55% 66.51% 47.02% PASSIVE 10.47% 6.44% 12.31% 6.31% 3.12% 8.233% 10.58% 7.14% 12.08% 14.01% 10.31% 14.21% ACTIVE 43.84% 39.17% 32.82% 37.44% 34.15% 27.35% 36.46% 32.24% 27.78% 56.54% 51.19% 37.64% CGSCORE 0.69 0.71 0.22 0.65 0.67 0.22 0.69 0.72 0.21 0.71 0.73 0.22 BDINDEP 52% 50% 24% 51% 50% 24% 52% 56% 24% 52% 50% 25% BDSIZE 6.44 6.00 2.12 6.38 6.00 2.17 6.46 6.00 2.14 6.48 6.00 2.06 ROAt 0.07 0.07 0.14 0.06 0.08 0.14 0.07 0.08 0.14 0.07 0.07 0.13 MKTCAP($A000) 4548105 547150 17494656 4190038 463694 15622609 5242508 664432 19282235 4195210 489787 17191798 MBVE 4.11 2.65 5.771 4.32 2.91 8.176 5.03 3.23 6.51 2.943 1.950 3.635 STDEV 11.07 9.10 6.40 10.07 8040 6.11 9.80 8.00 5.77 13.16 11.20 6.71 INDADJSTD 6.51 4.80 6.01 5.55 3.90 5.79 5.87 4.40 5.38 7.96 6.10 6.50 Variable- Dichotomous Coding

No. of firms in sample

% of sample Coding

No. of firms in sample

% of sample Coding

No. of firms in sample

% of sample Coding

No. of firms in sample

% of sample

RISK MGT 0 72 10.1% 0 39 12.3% 0 30 9.5% 0 39 12.3% 1 217 30.5% 1 108 34.2% 1 99 31.3% 1 108 34.2% 2 423 59.4% 2 169 53.5% 2 187 59.2% 2 169 53.5% AUDITOR 1 579 81.3% 1 249 78.8% 1 253 80.1% 1 260 82.3% DUAL 1 61 8.6% 1 26 8.2% 1 25 7.9% 1 28 8.9% Definitions: ALLINST: All institutional ownership divided by total issued shares; PASSIVE: Bank and insurance company ownership divided by total issued shares; ACTIVE: Pension funds, investment firms and hedge fund ownership divided by total issued shares; CGSCORE: firms total score divided by maximum score; BDINDEP: number of independent directors divided by board size; BDSIZE: number of directors on the board; RISKMGT: Dummy variables 2 = rigorous ERM policies with oversight of a dedicated (separate) committee, 1 = formal ERM policies but no separate committee oversight (oversight by board), 0 = no formal ERM policies (or dedicated committee oversight); AUDITOR: Dummy variable 1 if audited by top-tier auditor, 0 otherwise; DUAL: Dummy variable 1 if CEO is also chair of the board, 0 otherwise.

Page 42: Institutional Investors, Risk/ Performance and Corporate ...€¦ · association by acting as a substitute monitoring mechanism when governance is low. 3 Introduction The purpose

42

Table 2: Pearson Correlations (N = 712)

ROAt CG SCORE

INDADJSTD

RISK MGT

BDINDEP BDSIZE AUDITOR DUAL MBVE

ALL INSTIT PASSIVE ACTIVE

LNMKTCAP

ROAt 1 CGSCORE 0.179** 1

INDADJ STD -0.388** -0.341** 1

RISKMNGT 0.213** 0.663** -0.296** 1 BDINDEP 0.117** 0.805** -0.306** 0.460** 1

BDSIZE 0.121** 0.446** -0.325** 0.420** 0.340** 1 AUDITOR 0.035 0.378** -0.188** 0.350** 0.373** 0.312** 1

DUAL -0.027 -0.270** 0.196** -0.224** -0.142** -0.142** -0.190** 1 MBVE 0.043 -0.033 0.185** -0.023 -0.051 -0.062 -0.078* 0.061 1

ALLINSTIT 0.179** 0.387** -0.135** 0.333** 0.368** 0.248** 0.266** -0.098** -0.043 1 PASSIVE 0.123** 0.352** -0.061 0.277** 0.359** 0.162** 0.219** -0.081* -0.027 0.725** 1

ACTIVE 0.175** 0.348** -0.145** 0.308** 0.321** 0.246** 0.247** -0.091* -0.043 0.966** 0.523** 1 LNMKT

CAP 0.163** 0.472** -0.337** 0.334** 0.454** 0.639** 0.292** -0.122** 0.018 0.276** 0.229** 0.256** 1

**. Correlation is significant at the 0.01 level (2-tailed). *. Correlation is significant at the 0.05 level (2-tailed). CGSCORE: firms total score divided by maximum score; INDADJSTD: total risk is calculated as the standard deviation of firm daily stock returns for each fiscal year; ALLINST: total institutional investors ownership divided by total issued shares; PASSIVE: Bank and insurance company ownership divided by total issued shares; ACTIVE: Pension funds, investment firms and hedge fund ownership divided by total issued shares; RISKMGT: Dummy variables 2 = rigorous ERM policies with oversight of a dedicated (separate) committee, 1 = formal ERM policies but no separate committee oversight (oversight by board), 0 = no formal ERM policies (or dedicated committee oversight); BDINDEP: number of independent directors divided by board size; BDSIZE: number of directors on the board; AUDITOR: Dummy variable 1 if audited by top-tier auditor, 0 otherwise; DUAL: Dummy variable 1 if CEO is also chair of the board, 0 otherwise; ROAt: [Net Income + Interest Expense*(1-Corporate Tax Rate)]/[Total Assets - Outside Equity Interests]; MKTCAP: Closing share price on the last day of the company's financial year * number of shares outstanding at the end of the period; MBVE: closing share price on the last day of the company's financial year / shareholders equity per share.

Page 43: Institutional Investors, Risk/ Performance and Corporate ...€¦ · association by acting as a substitute monitoring mechanism when governance is low. 3 Introduction The purpose

43

Table 3: Random effects GLS regression with cluster robust standard errors.

ALLINST PASSIVE ACTIVE ALLINST

PASSIVE

ACTIVE

Coef. Coef. Coef. Coef.

Coef.

Coef. CONS -50.845 -22.310 -28.756 -18.189

-14.367

-4.166

(-1.60) (-2.41) ** (1.11) (-0.58)

(-1.60)

(-0.16) INDADJSTD 1.129 0.416 0.683 1.095

0.382

0.695

(2.76) ** (3.43) *** (2.07) * (2.88) ** (3.31) *** (2.27) * CGSCORE 60.518 19.872 40.691

(5.53) *** (6.09) *** (4.59) *** RISKMGT 10.487

2.583

7.850

(3.82) *** (3.19) *** (3.34) *** BDINDEP 21.694

12.121

10.055

(2.25) ** (4.46) *** (1.30) BDSIZE 2.230

0.058

2.137

(1.88) ! (0.18)

(2.17) * AUDITOR 14.120

2.530

11.445

(3.24) *** (1.82) ! (2.99) ** DUAL 1.868

0.137

1.681

(0.28)

(0.08)

(0.30) MILLS 6.795 2.502 3.208 -7.913

-3.386

-4.974

(0.27) (0.47) (0.15) (-0.350)

(-0.72)

(-0.26) ROAt 32.086 6.049 26.126 30.815

5.646

25.233

(2.93) ** (2.02) * (2.78) ** (2.85) ** (1.94) * (2.72) ** LNMKTCAP 2.715 0.796 1.941 0.603

0.486

0.149

(1.97) * (1.86) ! (1.74) ! (0.38)

(1.07)

(0.11) MBVE -0.533 -0.105 -0.425 -0.429

-0.085

-0.342

(-2.84) ** (-1.98) * (-2.49) ** (-2.38) ** (-1.55)

(-2.09) *

N 714 714 714 713

713

713

FIRMS 256 256 256 256

256

256 WALD 102.48 *** 115.83 *** 81.27 *** 146.54 *** 123.22 *** 119.87 ***

Rsq 0.184 0.154 0.154 0.218

0.191

0.176

Z statistics in parentheses significant at 0.001 ***; 0.01**; 0.05*; 0.10! levels Definitions: ALLINST: total institutional investors ownership divided by total issued shares; ACTIVE: Pension funds, investment firms and hedge fund ownership divided by total issued shares; PASSIVE: Bank and insurance company ownership divided by total issued shares; INDADJSTD: total risk is calculated as the standard deviation of firm daily stock returns for each fiscal year which is subtracted from the industry standard deviation of daily stock returns; CGSCORE: firms total score divided by maximum score; RISKMGT: Dummy variables 2 = rigorous RM policies with oversight of a dedicated (separate) committee, 1 = formal RM policies but no separate committee oversight (oversight by board), 0 = no formal RM policies (or dedicated committee oversight); BDINDEP: number of independent directors divided by board size; BDSIZE: number of directors on the board; AUDITOR: Dummy variable 1 if audited by top-tier auditor, 0 otherwise; DUAL: Dummy variable 1 if CEO is also chair of the board, 0 otherwise; MILLS: inverse mills ratio computed from the first stage regression; ROAt: current year ROA [Net Income + Interest Expense*(1-Corporate Tax Rate)]/[Total Assets - Outside Equity Interests]; LNMKTCAP: Closing share price on the last day of the company's financial year * number of shares outstanding at the end of the period, logged; MBVE: closing share price on the last day of the company's financial year / shareholders equity per share.

Page 44: Institutional Investors, Risk/ Performance and Corporate ...€¦ · association by acting as a substitute monitoring mechanism when governance is low. 3 Introduction The purpose

44

Table 4: GLS and 2SLS random-effects IV regression: Dependent variable firm performance

Panel A GLS Panel B GLS Panel C 2SLS

ROAt+1 ROAt+1

ROAt+1

Coef. Coef.

Coef. CONS 0.058 0.056

0.022

(03.98) (0.97)

(0.35) INDADJSTD -0.003 -0.010

0.003

(-2.46) ** (-3.84) *** (1.09) ROAt 0.548 0.519

0.586

(5.02) *** (4.30) *** (15.27) *** CGSCORE 0.053 -0.052

0.062

(2.12) * (1.54)

(2.58) ** ACTIVE -0.000 0.000

0.002

(-0.42) (0.10)

(2.42) ** PASSIVE -0.000 0.000

0.001

(-0.23) (1.33)

(0.44) CGSCORE*STD 0.015

(3.69) *** PASSIVE*STD -0.0001

-0.0001

(-1.68) ! (-0.46) ACTIVE*STD -9.60e-06

-0.000

(-0.31)

(-2.63) ** ACTIVESQ

-0.000

(-2.60) ** PASSIVESQ

-0.000

(-0.54) ACTIVESQ*STD

2.39e-006

(2.71) ** PASSIVESQ*STD

2.14e-06

(0.43) LNMKTCAP -0.002 0.001

-0.004

(-0.75) (0.26)

(-1.18) N 712 712

712

Firms 256 256

256 Wald 251.78 *** 400.05 *** 471.62 ***

Rsq 0.832 0.805

0.846 Z statistics in parentheses significant at 0.001 ***; 0.01**; 0.05*; 0.10! levels

Definitions: ROAt+1: following year ROA [Net Income + Interest Expense*(1-Corporate Tax Rate)]/[Total Assets - Outside Equity Interests]; INDADJSTD: total risk is calculated as the standard deviation of firm daily stock returns for each fiscal year which is subtracted from the industry standard deviation of daily stock returns; ROAt: current year ROA; CGSCORE: firms total score divided by maximum score; ACTIVE: Pension funds, investment firms and hedge fund ownership divided by total issued shares; PASSIVE: Bank and insurance company ownership divided by total issued shares; CGSCORE*STDEV: interaction term; ACTIVE*STDEV: interaction term; PASSIVE*STDEV: interaction term; ACTIVESQ: active ownership squared; PASSIVESQ: passive ownership squared; ACTIVESQ*STDEV: interaction term; PASSIVESQ*STDEV: interaction term; LNMKTCAP: Closing

Page 45: Institutional Investors, Risk/ Performance and Corporate ...€¦ · association by acting as a substitute monitoring mechanism when governance is low. 3 Introduction The purpose

45

share price on the last day of the company's financial year * number of shares outstanding at the end of the period, logged.

Page 46: Institutional Investors, Risk/ Performance and Corporate ...€¦ · association by acting as a substitute monitoring mechanism when governance is low. 3 Introduction The purpose

46

Table 5: 2SLS random-effects IV regression: Dependent variable firm performance

Panel A: Low CGScore Panel B: High CGScore

ROAt+1 ROAt+1

Coef Coef CONS -0.24136 0.103787

-0.96 0.89

INDADJSTD 0.00172 0.002084

0.36 0.15

ROAt 0.31382 0.601196

3.46 *** 10.75

ACTIVE 0.00386 -0.000006

1.87 ! 0.00

PASSIVE 0.00357 -0.001019

0.65 -0.61

PASSIVE*STD -0.00038 -0.000408

-0.60 -1.26

ACTIVE*STD -0.00053 0.000160

-2.50 ** 0.45

ACTIVESQ -0.00003 -0.000001

-1.82 ! -0.05

PASSIVESQ -0.00012 0.000012

-0.89 0.33

ACTIVESQ*STD 0.00001 -0.000001

2.39 ** -0.47

PASSIVESQ*STD 0.00001 0.000007

0.63 1.05

LNMKTCAP 0.01228 -0.003155

0.95 -1.01

N 178 195 Firms 82 95 Wald 77.91 *** 139.71 ***

Rsq 0.702 0.600 Z statistics in parentheses significant at 0.001 ***; 0.01**; 0.05*; 0.10! levels

Definitions: ROAt+1: following year ROA [Net Income + Interest Expense*(1-Corporate Tax Rate)]/[Total Assets - Outside Equity Interests]; INDADJSTD: total risk is calculated as the standard deviation of firm daily stock returns for each fiscal year which is subtracted from the industry standard deviation of daily stock returns; ROAt: current year ROA; ACTIVE: Pension funds, investment firms and hedge fund ownership divided by total issued shares; PASSIVE: Bank and insurance company ownership divided by total issued shares; ACTIVE*STDEV: interaction term; PASSIVE*STDEV: interaction term; ACTIVESQ: active ownership squared; PASSIVESQ: passive ownership squared; ACTIVESQ*STDEV: interaction term; PASSIVESQ*STDEV: interaction term; LNMKTCAP: Closing share price on the last day of the company's financial year * number of shares outstanding at the end of the period, logged.