230
IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON SMALL HOUSEHOLDS IN VIETNAM LIVESTOCK SECTOR Pham Thi Ngoc Linh A thesis submitted in fulfilment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy SCHOOL OF AGRICULTURAL AND RESOURCE ECONOMICS Faculty of Natural and Agricultural Sciences May 2011

IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    1

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE

LIBERALISATION ON SMALL HOUSEHOLDS IN

VIETNAM LIVESTOCK SECTOR

Pham Thi Ngoc Linh

A thesis submitted in fulfilment of the requirements for the degree of

Doctor of Philosophy

SCHOOL OF AGRICULTURAL AND RESOURCE ECONOMICS

Faculty of Natural and Agricultural Sciences

May 2011

Page 2: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

ii

To my loved husband and son: Duc and Thanh

To my parents

Page 3: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

iii

CERTIFICATION

The thesis is my own composition, all sources have been acknowledged and my

contribution is clearly identified in the thesis.

The thesis has been substantially completed during the course of enrolment in this

degree at UWA and has not previously been accepted for a degree at this or another

institution.

This thesis does not contain work that I have published, nor work under review for

publication.

Pham Thi Ngoc Linh

May 2011

Page 4: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

iv

ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS

This thesis was completed with the valuable support of many people, to whom I am

indebted in one form or the other. However, all remaining shortcomings and mistakes in

this thesis are my own responsibility.

I would like to express my sincere thanks to Australian Centre for International

Agricultural Research (ACIAR) for granting me a John Allwright Scholarship to study

and complete my PhD at the University of Western Australia.

I would like to acknowledge my gratefulness to my principal supervisor, A. Prof. Dr.

Michael Burton, who has supported me in terms of knowledge, experience, material and

worthwhile comment. His tireless support has encouraged me to overcome difficulties

during my study. I remember his help in solving data problems and revising my papers

and thesis.

I take pleasure in offering my sincere appreciation to my co-supervisor, Dr. Greg

Hertzler, for his guidance and assistance. His critical comments and helpful suggestions

from the early stages of my study are acknowledged.

During the time of doing this thesis, I have also had external expert advice and

numerous supports from Dr. David Vanzetti from Crawford School of Economics and

Government, Australian National University. His excellent experience in dealing with

trade modelling helped me considerably in constructing and finalizing the trade part of

my thesis.

I whole-heartedly thank my sister, the best friend, Dr. Donna Brennan for gave me the

excellent opportunity of studying at UWA, and also for her continuous help and support

through my study time. Her experience and guidance helped me a lot, especially when

my supervisors were absent. Also, her sympathies and sharing both joy and sorrow with

me in the early stage of living far away from family was invaluable.

I would like to thank to School of Agricultural and Resource Economics, University of

Western Australia, for providing me the necessary facilities, excellent support and ideal

environment for undertaking research study. My thanks go to A. Prof. Dr. Ben White,

Sally Marsh, Helena Clayton, Jan Taylor and all teachers, staff and other colleges in

ARE, ACIAR scholarship officer Sharon Harvey, and AusAID officers at UWA:

Page 5: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

v

Rhonda Haskell, Cathy Tang, and Christine Kerin who have been willing to help and

assisted me during my study at UWA. My thanks go to Dr. Christine Davies for her

English editing for the final thesis.

I wish to thank Dr. Dang Kim Son, my boss for both sending and encouraging me to

study. I sincerely appreciate his support in both my work and study time. My thanks

also go to my colleges: Nguyen Ngoc Que, Nguyen Do Anh Tuan, Tran Thi Quynh Chi,

Nguyen Le Hoa, Truong Thu Trang and others, for their continuous support and for

doing my work during my candidature.

I could not finish my hard study time without the support of my friends, Tran Cong

Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran

Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen Van Liem, Vu Le Tu, Pham Lan

Huong, Nguyen Thanh Hai and others. I would like to thank them for their friendship,

help and sharing, both physically and mentally, from small to big daily issues of life

during my time in Perth.

Especially, I would like to thank my family, my parents, and my mother in law, who

supported me by taking care my son and family, and encouraging me by giving me

comfortable conditions to study and finish my PhD. Thanks go to my dad and mum,

who always trust in and encourage me to follow up a research career. Last but not least,

I am indebted to my beloved husband Dinh Ngoc Duc, and my adorable son Dinh Duc

Thanh, who are always behind me, for their endless belief in me, for sharing with me all

sweet and hard things in those days. Without their boundless love, trust and

encouragement, I would not have made it this far.

Perth, May 2011

Page 6: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

vi

ABSTRACT

Vietnam has negotiated a series of bilateral and multilateral trade agreements and has

made significant steps in integrating into the world economy. This integration is likely

to have both positive and negative effects on different stakeholders in the economy.

This study assesses the impacts of trade liberalisation on Vietnam’s small livestock

households on welfare, production and consumption behaviours, using a multi country

general equilibrium model (GTAP) at the macro level, linked with four, regionally

representative household models at the micro level.

A GTAP utility SplitCom is used to separate live pig and live poultry out of the general

livestock group prior to running several trade liberalisation scenarios. The household

model is linked to the trade model through changes in the prices of inputs and outputs

arising from different trade scenarios. Inside the household model, a recursive

household model is used, with a two-stage LES-AIDS model on the consumption side

and Cobb-Douglas functions on the production side.

The results of the simulations shows that Vietnam’s small households in the livestock

sector would benefit from almost all trade liberalisation scenarios considered here. The

largest benefit is generated by full liberalisation: by comparison there is almost no gain

from bilateral trade liberalisation with the USA. The voluntary trade liberalisation of

Vietnam in a unilateral liberalisation would generate some benefit for the country at the

national level without the need for negotiating with others, and also increase the welfare

of the households.

The changes in simulated prices lead to changes in the household’s welfare as a result of

changes in behaviour, including consumption, production (and hence profit), and also in

the time allocation decision of the household. In almost all trade liberalisation scenarios,

the decision to take more leisure as part of the utility maximising response contributes

about one quarter of the total increase in household’s welfare.

Assumptions that are made about how the labour market in structured, in both the

macro- and micro- models affect the impact on labour wages, and hence drive responses

of the household in the trade scenario simulations. The thesis reports the sensitivity of

the key findings of the research to these critical assumptions.

Page 7: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

vii

TABLE OF CONTENTS

CERTIFICATION ...........................................................................................................iii

ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS .............................................................................................iv

ABSTRACT.....................................................................................................................vi

LIST OF FIGURES ..........................................................................................................x

LIST OF TABLES ..........................................................................................................xii

ABBREVIATIONS ........................................................................................................xv

CHAPTER 1 : INTRODUCTION ....................................................................................1 

1.1. Introduction ..........................................................................................................1 

1.2. Background Information of Vietnam Agriculture................................................1 

1.3. General Methodology and Data for Study ...........................................................4 

1.4. Contribution to Knowledge..................................................................................6 

1.5. Outline of Thesis ..................................................................................................7 

CHAPTER 2 : OVERVIEW OF LIVESTOCK SECTOR IN VIETNAM.....................10 

2.1. The Development of Livestock Sector...............................................................10 

2.1.1. Pig Husbandry .............................................................................................12 

2.1.2. Poultry Husbandry .......................................................................................13 

2.1.3. Cattle and Other Animal Husbandries.........................................................14 

2.2. Issues in Development Process of the Livestock Sector in Vietnam.................15 

2.2.1. Scale of Production of Livestock Husbandry ...............................................16 

2.2.2. Quality and Productivity of Meat Production..............................................19 

2.2.3. Price and Quality of Livestock Feed ............................................................19 

2.2.4. Livestock Diseases and Animal Breeds........................................................22 

2.2.5. Other Trade and Marketing Issues ..............................................................23 

2.3. Policy Environment for Livestock Husbandry Development ............................26 

2.4. Summary ............................................................................................................28 

CHAPTER 3 : THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK OF AGRICULTURAL

HOUSEHOLD MODEL ...........................................................................................30 

3.1. The Basic Model ................................................................................................32 

3.2. Solving the General Model ................................................................................35 

3.3. Role of Labour Market.......................................................................................36 

3.4. Profit Effects ......................................................................................................40 

Page 8: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

viii

3.5. Summary ............................................................................................................42 

CHAPTER 4 : THE ECONOMETRIC MODELS .........................................................44 

4.1. Production of Agricultural Household ...............................................................45 

4.1.1. Production Elasticity....................................................................................49 

4.2. Consumption ......................................................................................................51 

4.2.1. Linear Expenditure System (LES) Model .....................................................51 

4.2.1.1. Adjusting the Wage of Agricultural Labour...........................................56 

4.2.1.2. Estimation of LES Model .......................................................................59 

4.2.2. Linear Approximately - Almost Ideal Demand System (LA-AIDS)

Model ............................................................................................................62 

4.3. Summary ............................................................................................................67 

CHAPTER 5 : VIETNAMESE HOUSEHOLD MODEL - INTERACTION

OF PRODUCTION AND CONSUMPTION DECISIONS .....................................68 

5.1. Calibration of the Model ....................................................................................68 

5.1.1. The Production Model..................................................................................69 

5.1.2. The Consumption Model ..............................................................................70 

5.1.3. Opportunity Cost of Each Working Day and Exogenous Income

in Base Year ..................................................................................................71 

5.2. The Interaction of Production and Consumption Decisions ..............................72 

5.3. Summary ............................................................................................................75 

CHAPTER 6 : VIETNAM’S TRADE LIBERALISATION AND

SIMULATION MODEL...........................................................................................76 

6.1.  Brief of Vietnam’s Trade Liberalisation Process and Commitments ............77 

6.2.  Trade Liberalisation in GTAP Model ............................................................81 

6.2.1.  Previous studies on Vietnam trade liberalisation .....................................81 

6.2.2.  GTAP database .........................................................................................84 

6.2.3.  Using SplitCom and Introducing New Sectors into GTAP

Database .......................................................................................................86 

6.2.4.  Trade Scenarios of Trade Liberalisation Simulation ................................89 

6.3.  Simulations with Different Modifications of GTAP Closures.......................90 

6.3.1 Closure A - Standard GTAP Closure ............................................................93 

6.3.2 Closure B - Non Standard Closure in Labour Market ..................................98 

6.3.3 Closure C - Modified Non-Standard Closure .............................................103 

6.3.3.1. Estimation of R .....................................................................................103 

6.3.4 Alternative Labour Assumptions and Real Wages ......................................108 

Page 9: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

ix

6.3.5 Changes of Vietnam’s Welfare under Alternative Closures .......................109 

6.4.  Summary ......................................................................................................111 

CHAPTER 7 : IMPACTS OF TRADE LIBERALISATION ON SMALL

LIVESTOCK HOUSEHOLDS - LINKAGES BETWEEN TRADE AND

HOUSEHOLD MODELS.......................................................................................113 

7.1. Price Changes in the Trade Scenario Simulations ...........................................113 

7.2. Price and Wage Transmission..........................................................................116 

7.3. Impacts of Trade Liberalisation on Households ..............................................118 

7.3.1. Impacts of Global Trade Liberalisation on Households in the

South............................................................................................................120 

7.3.2. Impacts of Global Trade Liberalisation on Households in

Different Regions ........................................................................................125 

7.3.3. Impacts of Unilateral Trade Liberalisation on Households in

Different Regions ........................................................................................128 

7.3.4 Impacts of Regional AFTA to Households in Different Regions.................131 

7.3.5 Impacts of Expansion of the Regional AFTA (ASEAN plus China,

Korea and Japan) to Households in Different Regions ..............................134 

7.3.6 Impacts of Bilateral Trade Liberalisation with the United State on

Households ..................................................................................................135 

7.3.7 Impacts of Bilateral Trade with EU and Multilateral Trade

Liberalisation on Households in Different Regions....................................136 

7.4. Impacts of Trade Scenarios, Opportunities and Threats in Each

Region ..........................................................................................................139 

7.5. Summary ..........................................................................................................146 

CHAPTER 8 : CONCLUSIONS ..................................................................................148 

8.1. Summary, Conclusions, and Policy Implications ............................................148 

8.2. Limitations of the Study and Potentials for Further Study ..............................153 

APPENDICES 157 

REFERENCES 205 

Page 10: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

x

LIST OF FIGURES

Figure 2-1: Herd Pig Number and Annual Growth Rate in Different Regions

of Vietnam......................................................................................................12

Figure 2-2: Herd Number of Poultry in Different Regions of Vietnam..........................13

Figure 2-3: Proportion of Beef and Buffalo Animals in the Total Herd in

Different Regions of Vietnam in 2007...........................................................15

Figure 2-4: Production Scale of Household Pig Raising ................................................17

Figure 2-5: Production Scale of Household Poultry Raising in 2006.............................18

Figure 2-6: Yield of Maize and Soybean (tons/ha) By Country in 2004........................20

Figure 2-7: Price of Maize in Vietnam and the World, 1998–2006 (USD/ton)..............21

Figure 2-8: Price of Soybean in Vietnam and the World, 1998–2006

(USD/ton).......................................................................................................21

Figure 2-9: Changes in Population, Income and Meat Consumption per capita ............23

Figure 2-10: Pig and Chicken Consumption per capita over Regions (kg) ....................24

Figure 3-1: Separation of Household Decisions .............................................................37

Figure 3-2: An Agricultural Household in Slack Season................................................38

Figure 6-1: Labour Market under GTAP Standard Closure - Closure A........................94

Figure 6-2: Labour Market of a Developing Country under GTAP Closure B ..............98

Figure 6-3: Unskilled Labour Market in Vietnam under Closure C .............................103

Figure 6-4: Changes in Real Wages under Scenario Simulations with

Different Possible Maximum Labour Supplies............................................108

Figure 6-5: Changes in Welfare under Alternative Trade Scenarios with

Different Closures ........................................................................................109

Figure 7-1: Changes in Agricultural Production of Household in the South

under Global Trade Scenario .......................................................................120

Figure 7-2: Changes in Relative Prices of Outputs and Inputs and Changes in

Agricultural Production of Household in the South under Global

Trade Scenario .............................................................................................121

Figure 7-3: Changes in Profit of Agricultural Production of Household in the

South under Global Trade Scenario .............................................................122

Figure 7-4: Disaggregate Effects of Price and Income to Changes in

Consumption of Household in the South under Global Trade

Scenario Compared with Baseline (percentage) ..........................................122

Page 11: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

xi

Figure 7-5: Changes in Output Production and Farm Profit of Households in

Different Regions under Global Trade Scenario..........................................125

Figure 7-6: Changes in Consumption Quantities of Households in Different

Regions under Global Trade Scenario .........................................................127

Figure 7-7: Changes in Main Food Consumption of Households in Different

Regions under Global Trade Scenario .........................................................127

Figure 7-8: Changes in Agricultural Production of Households in Different

Regions under the Unilateral Trade Scenario ..............................................129

Figure 7-9: Changes in Food Consumption of Households in Different

Regions under Unilateral Trade Scenario (percentage) ...............................130

Figure 7-10: Changes in Quantity Consumption of Households in Different

Regions under AFTA in Comparison with Baseline (percentage) ..............132

Figure 7-11: Changes in Food Consumption of Households in Different

Regions under AFTA in Comparison with Baseline (percentage) ..............133

Figure 7-12: Changes in Production of Households in Different Regions

under AFTA+3.............................................................................................135

Figure 7-13: Changes in Production of Households in Different Regions

under Scenario of Bilateral Trade Liberalisation with EU...........................137

Figure 7-14: Changes in Production of Households in Different Regions

under Multilateral Trade Scenario ...............................................................137

Figure 7-15: Changes in Consumption of Households in Different Regions

under Scenario of Bilateral Trade Liberalisation with EU...........................137

Figure 7-16: Changes in Consumption of Households in Different Regions

under Multilateral Trade Scenario ...............................................................137

Figure 7-17: Changes in Main Food Consumption of Households in Different

Regions under Scenario of Bilateral Trade Liberalisation with EU ............138

Figure 7-18: Changes in Main Food Consumption of Households in Different

Regions under Multilateral Trade Scenario .................................................138

Figure 7-19: Welfare Changes of the South Household under Alternative

Scenarios with Different Assumptions of Labour Market ...........................145

Figure 7-20: Changes in Labour Allocation of Household in the South under

Alternative Scenarios with Different Assumptions on Labour

Market ..........................................................................................................145

Page 12: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

xii

LIST OF TABLES

Table 2-1: Annual Growth Rate in Agricultural Sector (percent)...................................11

Table 2-2: GDP and Share of Agriculture and Livestock in the Economy.....................11

Table 2-3: Number of Cattle and Annual Percentage Growth Rates (2000 –

2006) ..............................................................................................................14

Table 2-4: Average Weight of Lean and De-boned Meat by Region (percent)..............19

Table 2-5: Share of Pig and Chicken for Sale by Household (percent) ..........................25

Table 3-1: Selected Response Agricultural Price Elasticity With and Without

Profit Effect....................................................................................................42

Table 4-1: Arithmetic Means of Inputs and Outputs for four Regions ...........................47

Table 4-2: Neutral Technological Efficiency Parameters in Different Regions .............48

Table 4-3: Elasticity of Output, Labour Demand and Profit with Respect to

Selected Variables in the Production Functions ............................................50

Table 4-4: Description, Means, and Standard Deviation of Variables of

Quantity Consumption and Price Indices in LES ..........................................55

Table 4-5: Household’s Production Function for Composite Agricultural

Commodity.....................................................................................................57

Table 4-6: Instrumental Variables Estimates of Shadow Wage......................................58

Table 4-7: Comparison of Ratio of Instrumental Estimated Shadow Wages to

(Local) Market Wages over Years .................................................................59

Table 4-8: Estimated Parameters of LES of Household .................................................60

Table 4-9: Elasticities for LES with Respect to Selected Variables, with Total

Expenditure Assumed Exogenous .................................................................62

Table 4-10: Uncompensated Elasticity of LA-AIDS Model for Main Food

Commodities ..................................................................................................66

Table 5-1: Calibration of Neutral Technological Efficiency Parameters........................69

Table 5-2: Ratio of Using Raw Feed/Total Feed for Pig and Chicken Raising

(percent) .........................................................................................................70

Table 5-3: Calibration of Constants in LA-AIDS...........................................................71

Table 5-4: Household Response Elasticities with Farm Profit Alternatively

Exogenous and Endogenous in RRD .............................................................74

Table 6-1: GTAP Regional Concordance .......................................................................85

Table 6-2: GTAP Sectoral Concordance ........................................................................88

Page 13: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

xiii

Table 6-3: Alternative Trade Scenarios ..........................................................................90

Table 6-4: Vietnam’s Output and Trade Flows, 2001 (mill. USD) ................................92

Table 6-5: Initial Values (mill.USD) and Percentage Changes in Vietnamese

Outputs under Alternative GTAP Scenarios* with Closure A ......................95

Table 6-6: Price Changes in the Vietnamese Market under Alternative GTAP

Scenarios with Closure A (percentage)..........................................................97

Table 6-7: Changes in the Vietnamese Outputs and Unskilled Labour under

Alternative GTAP Scenarios with Closure B (percentage) ...........................99

Table 6-8: Price Changes in the Vietnamese Market under the Alternative

GTAP Scenarios with Closure B (percentage) ............................................100

Table 6-9: Price Changes of Consumption Commodities under Alternative

GTAP Scenarios with Closure B (percentage) ............................................102

Table 6-10: Percentage Changes in Vietnamese Market Prices under

Alternative GTAP Scenarios with Closure C (R=12%)...............................105

Table 6-11: Percentage Change in Consumption Commodity Price under

Alternative GTAP Scenarios with Closure C (R=12%)...............................107

Table 6-12: Number of Jobs Created for Unskilled Labour and its

Contribution to Total Social Welfare in Vietnam under Trade

Scenarios (percentage) .................................................................................110

Table 7-1: Matching between GTAP Sectors and Endowments in this Study

and their Concordance with Commodities and Goods in Vietnam’s

Household Models .......................................................................................115

Table 7-2: Average Wage of Labour at Current Price and Annual Growth

Rate ..............................................................................................................118

Table 7-3: Welfare Changes in Households in Different Regions under

Alternative Liberalisations Compare with Baseline (percentage) ...............119

Table 7-4: Disaggregated Changes in Main Food Consumption Quantity of

Household in the South due to Price and Expenditure Effects under

Global Trade Scenario (kg)..........................................................................124

Table 7-5: Ratio of Raw Feed and Price Change of Feed in Different

Households (percent) ...................................................................................126

Table 7-6: Changes in Labour Allocation of Households in Different Regions

under Global Trade Scenario Compared with Baseline

(percentage)..................................................................................................128

Table 7-7: Changes in Price and Consumption Quantity of Households in

Different Regions under the Unilateral Trade Scenario

(percentage)..................................................................................................130

Page 14: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

xiv

Table 7-8: Changes in Time Allocation of Households in Different Regions

under Unilateral Trade Scenario Compare with Baseline

(percentage)..................................................................................................131

Table 7-9: Changes in Production Outputs and Total Farm Profit of

Households in Different Regions under AFTA Compare with

Baseline (kg) ................................................................................................132

Table 7-10: Changes in Time Allocation of Households in Different Regions

under AFTA Trade Scenario Compare with Baseline (days) ......................134

Table 7-11: Changes in Prices of Consumption Commodities and Production

Inputs and Outputs in Vietnam under Bilateral Trade

Liberalisation with USA (percentage) .........................................................136

Table 7-12: Changes in Time Allocation of Households in Different Regions

under Alternative Liberalisations (percentage)............................................139

Table 7-13: Welfare Changes of Households in Different Regions under

Alternative Liberalisations Compared with Baseline (percentage) .............140

Table 7-14: Production Changes of the Households in Different Regions

under Alternative Liberalisations Compared with Baseline

(percentage)..................................................................................................141

Table 7-15: Changes of Time Allocation of Households in Different Regions

under Alternative Liberalisations Compared with Baseline

(percentage)..................................................................................................142

Table 7-16: Change Unskilled Labour Wage under Alternative GTAP

Scenarios with Different Assumptions of Labour Market

(percentage)..................................................................................................144

Page 15: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

xv

ABBREVIATIONS

ACFTA ASEAN-China Free Trade Area

ADB Asian Development Bank

AFR Africa

AFTA ASEAN Free Trade Area

AIDS Almost Ideal Demand System

AoA Agreement on Agriculture

ASEAN Association of South East Asia Nations

AUS Australia

B_T Beverages and Tobacco

BTA Bilateral Trade Agreement

CD Cobb-Douglas

CEE Central and East Europe

CEP Closer Economic Partnership

CEPT Common Effective Preferential Tariff

CGE Computable General Equilibrium

CH Central Highland

CHN China

CLMV Cambodia, Lao, Myanmar and Vietnam

CMT Beef and sheep meats

CPI Consumer Price Index

CRP Chemicals, rubber and plastic

CV Compensating Variation

CWGT Column users weights

EHP Early Harvest Program

ELE Electronic

EPA Economic Partnership Agreement

Page 16: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

xvi

EU European Union

EV Equivalent Variation

FAO Food and Agriculture Organisation of the United Nations

FAOStat FAO Statistics

FMD Foods Mouths Diseases

FSH Fishing

GATT General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade

GDP Gross Domestic Product

GEL General Exclusion List

GSO General Statistical Office

GTAP Global Trade Analysis Project

HS Harmonize System

IDN Indonesia

IFPRI International Food Policy Research Institute

IL Inclusion List

IND India

JPN Japan

KOR Korea

LA-AIDS Linear Approximation Almost Ideal Demand System

LAM Latin America

LDCs Least Developed Countries

LES Linear Expenditure System

MAN Manufactures

MARD Ministry of Agriculture and Rural Development

Mill. Million

MLK Milk and dairy products

MRD Mekong River Delta

MYS Malaysia

NCC North Central Coast

Page 17: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

xvii

NE North East

NES North East South

NL Normal List

NTBs Non-Tariff Barriers

NW North West

OAP Live animals sector

OCR Other crops

ODV Other developed countries

OFD Processed food

OLS Ordinary Least Square

OMT Pork, poultry, and other meats

OSO Oilseed and vegetable oil

PHL the Philippines

RES Natural resources, and petroleum product

RIC Paddy and processed rice

ROW Rest of the World

RRD Red River Delta

RWGT Row users weights

SAMs Social Accounting Matrices

SCC South Central Coast

SL Sensitive List

SPS Sanitary and Phytosanitary

STEs State Trading Enterprises

SUREG Seemingly Unrelated Regression

SVC Services

TBT Technical Barriers to Trade

TCN Transport, communication

TEL Temporary Exclusion List

THA Thailand

Page 18: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

xviii

TRIPs Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights

TWGT Trade users weights

TXT Textile and apparel

UN United Nations

UNCTAD United Nations Conference on Trade and Development

UNDP United Nations Development Programme

USA United States of America

USD USA Dollar

USDA United States Department of Agriculture

VF Vegetable and fruit

VHLSS Vietnam Household Living Standard Survey

VLSS Vietnam Living Standard Survey

VND Vietnam Dong

VNM Vietnam

WB World Bank

WITS World Integrated Trade Solutions

WTO World Trade Organisation

XEA Rest of East Asia

XSA Rest of South Asia

XSE Rest of South East Asia

XWGT Cross users weights

Page 19: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

1

CHAPTER 1 : INTRODUCTION

1.1. Introduction

The objective of this study is to analyse the implications of trade liberalisation on

Vietnam’s small-scale livestock producers. The study examines how household

production, consumption, leisure, working time and welfare are affected when prices

change due to trade liberalisation. The specific objectives are as follows:

• Evaluate the impact of trade liberalisation on Vietnam’s smallholder livestock

producers following Vietnam’s integration process into the world economy, by

connecting a computable general equilibrium (GTAP) with a household

production model for small livestock producers, simulating trade liberalisation

scenarios (in GTAP) and analysing changes to identify welfare effects at the

household level

• Investigate how the effects of trade policy changes impact on the national

economy as well as the livestock sector and their consequent effects on social

welfare.

• Assess impacts of trade liberalisation to changes in livestock producers'

household welfare. Analyse the reaction of smallholders that is represented by

their responsiveness in the supply of labour and demand for commodities and

leisure. By constructing a household model, behaviour of the household in

reaction to external impacts is captured, not only in terms of production

decisions, but also in term of consumption and household time allocation.

• Discuss opportunities and threats from trade liberalisation for smallholder

livestock producers.

1.2. Background Information of Vietnam Agriculture

Vietnam is located in the east of the Indo-Chinese peninsula (see map). The total natural

land resource of the country is 325 360 km2, of which 20-25 percent is used for

Page 20: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

2

agricultural production. Vietnam is divided into 64 provinces and 8 agro-ecological

regions.

With Gross Domestic Product (GDP) per capita of about 800 USD (2007) Vietnam is

still considered one of the world's poorest countries. Nevertheless, many observers note

the rapidly growing economy since the Doi Moi1 (renovation) in 1986 which

corresponds with the beginning of the transformation from a centrally planned economy

to one which is market oriented.

With 72.5 percent of the population

living in rural areas and 59 percent of

labour working in the agricultural sector

(year 2007), the agricultural sector is the

foundation of the economy. Over the

recent past, GDP growth of the

agricultural sector has been relatively

stable at around 4.3 percent per year.

Vietnam has also progressed from a

national chronic food shortage to one of

the world’s leading exporters of

agricultural products including rice,

coffee, tea, and rubber. Economic

growth, national food security,

improvement of income and lives of the

majority of people, and the reduction in

the number of people living under the

poverty line were largely made possible

by the Doi Moi reforms. The remarkable

economic growth that resulted from

these reforms was based largely on rural

households which have become the new

unit of agricultural production.

1 Refers to the decollectivisation and market orientation of the Vietnamese agriculture sector

VIETNAM AGRO-ECOLOGICAL REGION MAP Note: NE: North East, NW: North West, RRD: Red River Delta, NNC: North Central Coast, SCC: South Central Coast, CH: Central Highland, NES: North East South, MRD: Mekong River Delta

Page 21: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

3

In the agricultural sector, livestock is considered as one of the important pillars of a

sustainable development strategy (IFPRI 2001). Given limited prospects in the growth

of rice production and changing patterns of demand both in Vietnam and in the world

market, the livestock sector can help to achieve higher and more stable rural incomes,

reduce the incentive for the flow of migrants from rural to urban areas, make the

farming system sustainable in the long run, and contribute to the alleviation of rural

poverty, especially among ethnic groups in mountainous areas.

For many parts of Vietnam, large animals (i.e. bull, cow, and buffalo) are important

primarily not for their meat and milk products, but for the draught power they provide

for crop production and local transportation. Livestock raising (especially swine and

cattle) are a major source of fertiliser. In addition, livestock is important for providing

high quality protein to millions of smallholders thus enhancing their nutrition.

After the Doi Moi, the livestock industry has developed with an average growth rate of

5.4 percent per year, higher than the crop and service2 sectors. However, there are many

issues which constrain producer profitability in the livestock sector such as high feed

price, low productivity, and poor veterinary system.

Livestock in Vietnam are predominantly raised in small-scale household production

units. At present, smallholder producers supply the majority of meat in the market, with

most households operating individually in the production and marketing of livestock

and livestock products. They are constrained by poor access to markets, very low scale

operations, poor access to improved genetics, and high-quality forage and concentrate

feed, and poor animal husbandry and nutrition. However, for most of these households,

raising livestock is an important source of income providing at least 50 percent of cash

income in the household (Lapar et al. 2003).

Since 1995, Vietnam officially joined the world economy by becoming a member of the

Association of South East Asia Nations (ASEAN), signed a bilateral trade agreement

(BTA) with USA in 2000, and became a member of World Trade Organisation (WTO)

in 2007, after 11 years of negotiation. Implementation of multilateral and bilateral trade

agreements has opened a door for Vietnam to integrate into the global economy

providing both opportunities and threats to the agriculture sector. In the case of the 2 Refers to service subsector in agriculture

Page 22: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

4

livestock industry, there may be both supply and demand side effects. For example,

income growth may increase demand for meat, but the domestic industry may also have

to compete with imported produce. Reducing protection on domestic maize may make

feed prices decrease, but the opportunity cost of labour in livestock production may

increase. Thus it is not clear whether livestock households, especially smallholders, will

be worse or better off as a result of trade liberalisation.

1.3. General Methodology and Data for Study

In order to assess the impacts on small households as a consequence of trade

liberalisation, an international trade model is linked with a household model. In general,

the modelling process of the study includes three main steps:

Step 1: At the micro level, a household model is built where the household utility is

optimised in the context of a number of constraints such as budget constraint, time

constraints and production technology.

Step 2: At the macro level, a multi-country general equilibrium model with its focus on

worldwide trade policy - Global Trade Analysis Project Model (GTAP) - is used to

simulate trade liberalisation.

Step 3: The trade model and household model are linked together and the results of

changes in welfare, production and consumption behaviours, etc. of the household are

presented. Given the aim of investigating the reaction of the household in trade scenario

simulations, price changes for consumption commodities as well as production factors

including labour in the agricultural sector, which are derived from the GTAP

simulation, are incorporated into the household model as policy shocks. In this step, the

study only examines the one-way effects of trade liberalisation on households, and not

their influence on trade.

A variety of empirical methods are used in the study. For example, econometric models

such as Linear Approximation Almost Ideal Demand System (LA-AIDS) and Linear

Expenditure System (LES) are applied in step 1 to estimate parameters for functions of

consumption, production, and utility of the household. In step 2, the GTAP software

SplitCom is used to separate pig and poultry out of the aggregate group of livestock in

Page 23: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

5

the standard GTAP aggregation. Other statistical analysis is also applied to estimate the

price and wage transmission among regions within the country, when the two models

are linked together in step 3.

The study uses data from the Vietnam Household Living Standard Survey (VHLSS

2004) as the main source for constructing the econometric and household models. The

total survey sample was 45 900 households, of which 36 720 households were surveyed

for income only, the other 9180 households for both income and expenditure. The

sample covers and represents 3063 communes, over eight ecological regions (Red River

Delta, North East, North West, North Central Coast, South Central Coast, Central

Highland, North East South, and Mekong River Delta), and almost all provinces in the

country. Since the study especially focused on small-scale households in the livestock

sector, around 7000 of the 9180 households are chosen for analysis. Data from a survey

on the Vietnam livestock sector of the International Food Policy Research Institute

(IFPRI 2001) is also used for additional information about small households who raise

livestock and other criteria of economic and farming systems in Vietnam.

In constructing the household model, the whole country is divided into four regions:

Red River Delta, Northern upland (includes North East and North West), Central region

(includes North Central Coast, South Central Coast and Central Highland), and South

(includes Mekong River Delta and North East South). Each region represents an

ecological area where agro-ecological and economy conditions are largely similar, so

one household model is constructed to represent each region.

The GTAP model version 6.2, with a database for 2001 is used in step 2. The database

includes 96 countries/regions and 57 individual sectors. The database includes all data

on trade, production, consumption, tariff and etc. for Vietnam individually; therefore

the Vietnamese economy with all its factor and activity flows is represented in the

model. However, it does not identify the pig and chicken sectors separately, which are

subsumed within “livestock”. Generating new sectors of pig and chicken to introduce

into the GTAP database are based on extracting data from sources of United Nations

(UN): Comtrade, International Statistics, World Integrated Trade Solutions (WITS),

Statistics of Food and Agriculture Organisation (FAOStat), and Social Accounting

Matrices (SAMs) of various countries.

Page 24: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

6

In addition, the study uses other sources of primary and secondary data and information

including government institutions and organisations in Vietnam, such as the Ministry of

Agriculture and Rural Development (MARD), General Statistical Office (GSO),

Research Institute for Market and Prices. Information also comes from documents and

databases of the United Nation’s and international organisations and financial

institutions: United Nations Development Programme (UNDP), United Nations

Conference on Trade and Development (UNCTAD), United States Department of

Agriculture (USDA), World Bank (WB), Asian Development Bank (ADB), IFPRI, etc.,

and other non-government organisations in Vietnam.

1.4. Contribution to Knowledge

The major contribution to knowledge derived from this study is development of a link

between the trade liberalisation GTAP results and a household model to examine

changes in welfare as well as behaviours in production and consumption of small

livestock producers in Vietnam following trade liberalisation. GTAP has been used

since 1992 with some previous applications to Vietnam (Nguyen & Ezaki 2005, Daude

2004, Nin et al. 2003, Holst 2004, Vanzetti & Pham 2006). Household models have

been developed for around 30 years and applied to many countries (Barnum & Squire

1979a, Chen & Ravallion 2002, Taffesse 1999, Kumar & Ramasamy 2003, Schnepf &

Senauer 1989, Janvry et al. 1995, Quazi 1992, Edmeades et al. 2004), but this is the

first application to the livestock sector in Vietnam, although there have been some other

microeconomic models developed (MacAulay et al. 2001, Hertzler & MacAulay 2000,

Seshan 2005, Holst 2004, Jensen & Tarp 2005). This is also the first application linking

a GTAP macro model to a household micro-level model for the livestock sector in

Vietnam.

By linking GTAP with a household model, the study examines how small livestock

households react to changes in economic policies, especially in the context of trade

liberalisation. This is especially important, given that livestock plays a very important

role in the agricultural sector and small households are dominant in livestock production

in Vietnam. Analytical results from the household model also allow one to see how

household behaviours change when they are both consumers and producers. Taking into

account how income is affected by production, via profit, thereby influencing

consumption, gives a more accurate assessment.

Page 25: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

7

Using SplitCom to disaggregate pig and chicken sectors from the GTAP aggregate

database is the other contribution to knowledge, allowing for a more accurate measure

of change in household production to different price signals.

1.5. Outline of Thesis

The thesis contains eight chapters; brief summaries of subsequent chapters follow.

Chapter 2, “Overview of the Livestock Sector in Vietnam” reviews development of the

sector in recent years. The main characteristics of livestock production in Vietnam, such

as small-scale production, low productivity, low quality of both livestock products and

feed, poor state of animal health and veterinary services are then presented. The policy

environment and strategy of the Vietnamese government for future sector development

is also mentioned.

Chapter 3, “The Theoretical Framework of Agricultural Household Model” presents a

theoretical framework of a general model of an agricultural household, in which the

household chooses on-farm production, off-farm labour supply consumption of market

purchased goods, home produced goods, and leisure time in order to maximise its

utility.

The commodity and leisure demand of the household is defined by relations of prices

and income, and income is partly determined by the household’s production activities.

Since consumption behaviour is not independent of production behaviour, a recursive

property of the model is established. Conforming to the principles of a recursive model,

the assumptions in the household model are: household is price-taker in all markets and

all markets exist; commodities are homogeneous, including the labour market; decisions

relating to the total stock of land and labour are treated as given; and intertemporal

allocation and risk are omitted.

Chapter 4, “Econometric Models for Household Production and Consumption” includes

particular approaches to estimating production and consumption aspects of the

agricultural household. The production segment of the model is analysed employing a

Cobb-Douglas (CD) production function to estimate outputs and input demand. The

consumption side is specified using two stages: LES for a broad grouping of goods and

Page 26: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

8

expenditures in the first stage, with the integration between demand for commodities

and the allocation of time for leisure and labour supply. In the second stage, expenditure

for each of individual commodities in the main food group is allocated using an LA-

AIDS model.

Econometric models are used to estimate parameters for functions of consumption,

production, and utility of the household. Data for the model estimation are primary data

of the VHLSS 2004, which represents all agro-ecological regions in the country. In

estimating the LES model, one has to deal with the issue of there being an incomplete

labour market, and hence market wages may not represent the opportunity cost of

family labour. To overcome this, a technique is used to estimate the “shadow wage” as

the opportunity cost of family’s labour.

Chapter 5, “Vietnamese Household Model - Interaction of Production and

Consumption Decisions” calibrates the household model. A representative household

model of each region, in which the model's elements and relationships are determined

based on the econometric results of Chapter 4, is presented. In the model construction,

the two sides (production and consumption) of the model are linked together. Hence the

reaction of the household to an exogenous change is presented. The whole process is

calibrated in Excel, and the utility maximising response to changes in conditions for the

household is determined using Excel solver.

By constructing the integrated household model, households' responses to policy

changes in both consumption and production are captured. The effects on consumption,

due to the “profit effect” arising from the change in farm production, yield more

realistic results than an examination of consumption in isolation.

Chapter 6, “Vietnam’s Trade Liberalisation and Simulation Model” briefly presents the

process and main commitments of Vietnam in the trade liberalisation process. Hence a

multi-country general equilibrium GTAP is used to simulate trade liberalisation

scenarios. Since the final objective of the study is to examine impacts of trade

liberalisation on small livestock households raising pigs and chicken, and this level of

detail is not present in the GTAP database, the software SplitCom is applied to

introduce live pig and chicken sectors into the GTAP database prior to running

simulations.

Page 27: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

9

Results of trade liberalisation simulations under different closures in the GTAP model

are presented. The main changes in output, welfare, trade balance and prices are derived

from GTAP. Modifying closures in GTAP helps modelling become a more useful tool

in the analysis of economic impacts of policy changes, since it presents more accurately

the situation of resource allocation and usage of endowments, in this case of unskilled

labour, especially in the context of overwhelming unemployment in developing

countries.

Chapter 7, “Impacts of Trade Liberalisation on Small Livestock Household - Linkages

between Trade and Household Models” presents an analysis of how households would

be affected by changes in trade scenarios. By linking the trade and household models

together, households' changes in welfare, production and consumption behaviours as

well as time allocation between work and leisure are captured. Reviewing changes

under alternative assumed liberalisation scenarios and labour market conditions leads to

policy conclusions on the opportunities and threats from trade liberalisation for

smallholder livestock producers.

Chapter 8, “Conclusions” provides a summary of the contribution of the thesis. Some

conclusions and policy implications in the context of trade liberalisation for small

livestock producers are drawn. Limitations of the study and suggestions for further

study also are presented.

Page 28: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

10

CHAPTER 2 : OVERVIEW OF LIVESTOCK SECTOR IN

VIETNAM

The agricultural sector, accounting for 57 percent of labour force in the country, is the

foundation of Vietnam’s economy. Since Doi Moi, the GDP growth of the agricultural

sector has been relatively stable increasing at around 5.03 percent per year on average

(GSO 2008). By allocating production factors, especially land to individual households,

liberalising economic relations, and opening the country to external markets, Doi Moi

helped Vietnam to progress from a nation of chronic food shortages to one of the

world's leading exporters of agricultural products (Castella & Dang 2002). The

fundamental changes in technical, economic and social issues that accompanied the

transition transformed agricultural production, resource management and land use, and

the institutions helped the economy in general and the agriculture sector in particular to

achieve a remarkable level of growth.

In order to have background information and understand the context of the study the

development progress of livestock sector since Doi Moi is reviewed here. This is

followed by emerging issues in that process, and finally, the policy environment and the

strategy of the Vietnamese government for future development of the livestock sector

are presented.

2.1. The Development of Livestock Sector

In the agriculture sector, livestock plays an important role and is considered an

important pillar of a sustainable development strategy. However, after successfully

implementing Doi Moi for some years, favouring development of the rice economy,

initial rapid economic growth has been slowing in recent years (World Bank 2000).

Given limited prospects in the growth of rice production and changing patterns of

demand both in Vietnam and the world market, the livestock sector may help to

increase and stabilise rural incomes, reduce incentives for flow of migrants from rural

to urban areas, make the farming system sustainable in the long run, and contribute to

the alleviation of rural poverty, especially among ethnic groups in mountainous areas

Page 29: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

11

(IFPRI 2001). For low income producers, livestock serve as a store of wealth, it

provides at least 50 percent of cash income in small households. It also still provides

draught power in many regions of Vietnam, provides organic fertilizer, and acts as a

source of transportation (Lapar et al. 2003).

As a consequence of adopting an agricultural diversification program over recent years,

the development of the livestock sector expanded considerably and has grown faster

than agriculture as a whole (Table 2-1). In addition, development of the livestock sector

was faster in the last decade of the 20th century than from 1954 to 1990 (Lapar et al.

2003).

Table 2-1: Annual Growth Rate in Agricultural Sector (percent)

1986–1990 1991–1995 1996–2000 2001–2007

Agriculture 3.4 4.85 6.38 3.94

Cultivation 3.3 4.77 6.54 3.34

Livestock 3.5 5.38 6.32 6.77

Source: Calculation based on data of GSO 2008, the production value of sectors are fixed for the year

1994

Along with development of the agricultural sector, the output value of livestock has

significantly increased by a factor of 4 from 1995 to 2007.

Table 2-2: GDP and Share of Agriculture and Livestock in the Economy

1995 2000 2005 2007

Agricultural output (billion VND) 85,508 129,140 183,342 236,935

Livestock output (billion VND) 16,168 24,960 45,226 57,803

Agriculture share in GDP (%) 27.18 24.53 20.97 20.33

Livestock share in GDP (%) 5.14 4.74 5.17 4.96

Source: GSO 2008. Calculated at current price.

Page 30: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

12

However, the contribution of livestock is still small, about 20 percent in the agricultural

sector, compared with 74 percent in the cultivation sub sector, and about 5 percent the

total economy in 2007

In the livestock sector, production has developed rapidly with the average liveweight of

livestock also growing at a remarkable rate annually. However, the increase in

aggregate liveweight was attributed mostly due to increases in the size of the national

herd, rather than improvement in productivity. Pig herd size increased by about 5

percent per year but average liveweight production increased by about 7 percent per

year. The size of the national poultry flock increased at an average rate of 5.9 percent,

and production (in liveweight) increased at an annual average rate of 6.3 percent (IFPRI

2001). Increases in the proportion of crossbred and exotic animals in livestock herds in

Vietnam were partially responsible for increases in off-take rates.

2.1.1. Pig Husbandry

The pig herd in Vietnam increased continuously over the last 20 years. The number of

pigs doubled from 12.3 million in 1990 to 24.9 million in 2003 and to 26.9 million in

2006, with the annual growth rate being 4.3 percent. The herd of sows expanded with an

average growth rate of 6.1 percent per year. In 2000, there were 2.8 million sows in the

country, increased to 4.33 million in 2006, making up more than 16 percent of the total

pig herd.

0

2

4

6

8

RRD NE NW NCC SCC CH NES MRD

regions

pig

herd

num

ber

(mill

hea

ds)

0%

2%

4%

6%

8%

10%

annu

al g

row

th r

ate

1995 2000 2007 annual grow th rate 1995-2000 annual grow th rate 2000-2007

Figure 2-1: Herd Pig Number and Annual Growth Rate in Different Regions of

Vietnam

Source: GSO 2008

Page 31: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

13

Pig breeding has been vigorously developed in the Red River Delta (RRD), North East

(NE), North Central Coast (NCC) and the Mekong River Delta (MRD). However,

industrial farms that apply large-scaled, industrialised and commercialised husbandry

are often located in the South areas of MRD and (North East South) NES. In 2007, pig

herd numbers in RRD and MRD were 6.9 and 3.8 million, respectively, and the growth

rates were 3.9 and 3.06 percent per year (GSO 2008).

Total liveweight of pig has also increased, from 560 000 tons in 1985, 1 million tons in

1998, about 1.4 million tons in 2000 to 2.5 million tons in 2006.

2.1.2. Poultry Husbandry

By 2006, poultry herd size had increased to 226 million including chickens, ducks,

geese, and swans. Chickens accounted for over 75 percent in the total population. The

rapid expansion of poultry started in 1990 with about 107 million heads, and this trend

increased strongly in the following years, before the bird flu epidemic in 2004. From

2001 to 2003, the annual growth rate of herd size was 9 percent, with a poultry

population of 254 million individuals in 2003 (GSO 2008).

0

20

40

60

80

RRD NE NW NCC SCC CH NES MRD

regions

poul

try

herd

siz

e (m

ill h

eads

)

2000 2003 2007

Figure 2-2: Herd Number of Poultry in Different Regions of Vietnam

Source: GSO 2008

Most of the poultry in Vietnam are found in four regions: NE, the RRD, NCC, and the

MRD, whose total flock accounts for almost 80 percent of all poultry. Duck husbandry

is mainly in the two river deltas as intensive broiler production has been forming in

Page 32: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

14

these regions to supply poultry meat to the biggest consumption centres of Ha Noi and

Ho Chi Minh City, and some big cities in the central region.

From 2001 to 2003, the poultry population had the highest growth, yielding 372.7 tons

and 4.85 billion eggs, accounting for 17 percent in total liveweight meats (MARD

2007). However, Figure 2-3 shows that in 2007 the poultry herd size was reduced

compared with 2003 in most regions due to the bird flu epidemics in the winter, since

year 2004.

2.1.3. Cattle and Other Animal Husbandries

In 2006, Vietnam had about 9.5 million cattle, of which 2.9 million were buffalo and

around 2 million were oxen. Due to the increase in demand for beef meat and milk, the

growth rate and expansion of the cattle herd has been high. From 2001 to 2006, the cow

herd’s growth was largest, with average annual growth at 22.4 percent. Beef increased

from 3.89 million in 2001 to 6.51 million in 2006 at an annual growth rate of 9.67

percent. In contrast, due to the mechanisation of agricultural production, increases in

buffalo numbers tended to slow down (MARD 2007).

Table 2-3: Number of Cattle and Annual Percentage Growth Rates (2000 – 2006)

2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006

Beef (million heads) 4.13 3.89 4.06 4.39 4.91 5.54 6.51

Beef growth rate (%) -5.74 4.37 8.13 11.85 12.83 17.51

Cow (million heads) 0.035 0.041 0.055 0.079 0.095 0.104 0.113

Cow growth rate (%) 17.14 34.15 43.64 20.02 9.47 8.72

Buffalo (million heads) 2.87 2.81 2.81 2.83 2.87 2.92 2.92

Buffalo growth rate (%) -2.09 0.00 0.71 1.41 1.74 0.00

Source: MARD 2007;

Cattle breeding is quite developed in the central provinces and in the NE. The NCC and

(South Central Coast) SCC have the largest cattle herds, accounting for 40 percent of

the beef industry in Vietnam. Buffalo is also concentrated in the NCC with 26 percent,

just after the NE, with 42 percent of total buffalo herds (GSO 2008).

Page 33: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

15

0%

10%

20%

30%

40%

50%

RRD NE NW NCC SCC CH NES MRD

regions

buffalo beef

Figure 2-3: Proportion of Beef and Buffalo Animals in the Total Herd in Different

Regions of Vietnam in 2007

Source: GSO 2008

Other trends in livestock development relate to increases in some animals such as goat

and sheep. Total goats and sheep in 2006 reached 1.52 million individuals, up from 0.57

million in 2001. Between 2001 and 2006 the average growth rate was 21.6 percent per

annum (MARD 2007).

2.2. Issues in Development Process of the Livestock Sector in Vietnam

Over the last 20 years, the livestock sector has made significant progress in terms of fast

growth rates, increased diversification in production, better responsiveness to market

requirements both in quantity and quality, etc. Hence, it contributed to improving

income of household producers and nutrition for people, especially in rural areas.

However, during its development, there has been concern about some emerging issues

such as the small-scale of livestock production, low productivity, low quality of

livestock products, high price and low quality of livestock feed, low level and poor

focus on genetic improvement, poor state of animal health and spread of disease, etc.,

which have implications for the sustainable development of the sector. In this section,

some main issues are presented.

Page 34: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

16

2.2.1. Scale of Production of Livestock Husbandry

As in other developing countries, Vietnam livestock production has evolved into three

types, namely subsistence, semi-commercial, and commercial industrial.

The subsistence type is largely based on crop production activity of the farm, with

animals subsisting on by-products from crop production. This system has been the basis

of household livestock production in the North and Central regions for many years. This

system still exists but at present its importance and popularity is decreasing.

The semi-commercial type is between the subsistence and commercial types. The

majority of households with this production system are likely to be more specialised in

livestock production than the subsistence type. The household is more likely to make

production decisions based on market price information. However, there is diversity in

management across households within this type of production system. Some households

use mainly feeds produced at home, while other households buy feed from the market.

This type of household often considers livestock husbandry as a secondary activity in

agricultural production, and its capability to link the production operations closely with

the market is also still limited. These households predominate in many rural areas, but

in varying proportions depending on the region.

The commercial/industrial type differs significantly from the household-based system.

The production is on a larger scale, often employing more hired labour, and using more

capital and industrial feed. Many farms of this type produce mainly for export and

under contract with a livestock processing company3. This commercial production type

is often found in the South, such as MRD and NES, where people have larger land areas

for husbandry. However, the number of commercial/industrial types is still quite

limited. In some regions, due to constraints on land, households find it hard to expand

production. In RRD, for instance, on average, a household often owns an area of only

about 500m2, which makes it difficult to increase pig numbers per year to hundreds of

animals.

Regarding scale, commercial pig farms often raise more than 30 sows and 100 fattening

pigs. The smaller farms that are considered as semi-commercial raise about 3 to 10

3 Under the form of contract farming.

Page 35: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

17

sows and 15 to 50 fattening pigs. Production from these two types consists of about 20

percent of total pig production. Farms with 1 to 3 sows, not more than 15 fattening pigs

per year or both sows and pigs are often considered small producers. This is a popular

system throughout Vietnam, with pig production accounting for as much as 80 percent

of total production (Dinh et al. 2006).

0%

20%

40%

60%

80%

100%

1994 2001 2006

1 head 2 heads 3-5 heads 6-10 heads > 11heads

Figure 2-4: Production Scale of Household Pig Raising

Source: calculated from Agricultural Census 1994, 2001, 2006

The proportion of households according to pig numbers raised is presented in Figure 2-

5. The data are extracted from three Agricultural Censuses in 1994, 2001, and 2006.

The figure shows that the number of large scale producers increased over time, however

the proportion is still low. In 2006, the number of households raising more than 11 pigs

per year accounted for only 8.33 percent of the total.

This situation is similar for small-scale production of poultry. The small-scale producer,

both semi-commercial and subsistent poultry farm, with less than 200 birds, raises about

80 percent of the total poultry in Vietnam (Figure 2-6). Meanwhile, households who

raise more than 200 birds and considered to commercial farms, account for only 0.5

percent of the total.

Page 36: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

18

27.39

39.25

28.05

4.8 0.51

<10 heads 10- 19 heads 20 - 49 heads 49-200 heads >200 heads

Figure 2-5: Production Scale of Household Poultry Raising in 2006

Source: calculated from Agricultural Census 2006

Small-scale production with traditional methods of poultry husbandry has existed for a

long time throughout Vietnam. This production type is characterised by a scavenging or

extensive system. Chicken, for instance, are allowed to scavenge in the garden without

fences, and are fed by scavenging and with supplementary home-produced grain like

paddy rice, maize, kitchen waste, etc. Due to the scavenging system, management is

poor, rearing time is longer, and chicken are more prone to disease, heat and cold stress,

low survival rates and low economic efficiency. The advantage of this system is the low

initial investment and use of local breeds. Even poor farmers can manage some dozens

of chicken. Although the system is not very productive or economically efficient, it is

adoptable by almost any household. The meat of chickens raised in this system is

preferred by many consumers for its taste and receives a premium price. This system

produces about 65 percent of total broiler chickens in Vietnam, or about 70 million

birds per annum (Lapar et al. 2003).

The commercial livestock production system of both pig and poultry has many

advantages such as high productivity, short rearing time, greater survival rates, lower

incidence of diseases, and ease of management. However, the proportion of the

households applying this production type is still quite modest since it requires a large

area and sufficient funds for husbandry.

At present, livestock are still predominantly raised in small-scale households, and their

production supplies the majority of meat in the market. However, according to

Page 37: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

19

specialists, this type of livestock husbandry does not have many opportunities for future

development, as they are likely to be pushed out of business in a more market-

orientated environment (Akter et al. 2003, Vu 2003).

2.2.2. Quality and Productivity of Meat Production

Small-scale production often uses kitchen waste and agricultural by-products for

livestock feed, uses local breeds, and applies traditional methods of husbandry.

Therefore its productivity and quality of meat is often low.

In comparison with other countries, the average weight of a pig in Vietnam stands at 70-

80 kg for live hog (feed over 8 months) compared to an average of 100-120 kg

elsewhere in the world fed for only 6.5 months. The average slaughter weight of beef

cattle in Vietnam is around 300 kg fed over 27 months compared with about 500 kg

over 15 months in other countries. Using local breeds is a major reason for lower

productivity. The average carcass weight of a local pig is about 68.5 percent of the live

weight, while the world average (with the exotic breeds) is about 80 percent. The

average rate of local pig lean meat accounts for only 35 percent, compared with 55

percent of the world level (Dinh et al. 2006).

Table 2-4: Average Weight of Lean and De-boned Meat by Region (percent)

Region

North Central South

Average

Local pig 33.6 36 34 34.5

Cross-breeding pig 40.6 41.4 46 42.6

Beef 35.7 37.5 36.7 36.6

Source: IFPRI 2001

2.2.3. Price and Quality of Livestock Feed

Animal feed has an important role in livestock production and accounts for about 70

percent of total production cost (Akter et al. 2003, Nguyen & Tran 2005). Its quality is

a key determinant of animal growth and health. Recently, industrial feed factories have

developed and expanded. However, the price and quality of livestock feed has been a

Page 38: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

20

concern for producers, especially small ones. Industrial feed prices in Vietnam are

higher in comparison with those in other countries, even ASEAN countries in the same

region. For example, complete feed for pig fattening in Vietnam was about 28 percent

higher than that in Malaysia in 2000 (IFPRI 2001). One reason for this is the relatively

higher price of key materials used in feed production including maize, soybean, and

others.

In Vietnam, maize is the second largest food crop after rice. Recently, the area planted

to maize and yield has increased sharply, with average growth reaching 6.2 and 6.1

percent per year, respectively. Soybean also has developed, with annual average growth

in area and output of 4.2 percent and 8.3 percent, respectively (GSO 2008). However,

yield of maize and soybean in Vietnam is very low compared to other countries.

Currently, maize yield in Vietnam is 56 percent of Chinese maize yield and only one

third of USA maize yield. Similarly, yield of soybean in Vietnam is about 60 percent of

average world yield, only two third of Chinese yield and 40 percent of USA soybean

yield.

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

9

10

Maize Soybean

Vietnam

China

Thailand

United States

Figure 2-6: Yield of Maize and Soybean (tons/ha) By Country in 2004

Source: FAO 2005

In 2005, Vietnam used about 11 million tons of animal feed, not including green forage

and other vegetables. According to an estimate by MARD, with the development of

livestock husbandry, the requirements for industrial feed will increase by about 10 to 15

percent annually (Nguyen & Tran 2005). Based on the domestic capacity and

requirement, it is estimated that each year Vietnam needs to import about 60 percent of

raw materials including maize, soybean, dry soybean cake, milled bone and the other

raw materials to produce industrial feed.

Page 39: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

21

However, in recent years, the import tax on raw materials has ranged from 5 to 7.5

percent, compared with other countries in the region, which have no tax on these

products (IFPRI 2001). This is one of the reasons for the high cost of feed in Vietnam,

however normally, feed prices in Vietnam (maize, soybean) are 30–40 percent higher

than the world market (Figures 2-8, 2-9), so these import taxes are not the only reason

for the divergence.

0

40

80

120

160

200

1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006

pri

ce (

US

D/ t

on

)

retail price in VN world price

0

100

200

300

400

500

600

1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006

pri

ce (

US

D/ t

on

)

retail price in VN world price

Figure 2-7: Price of Maize in Vietnam and

the World, 1998–2006 (USD/ton)

Figure 2-8: Price of Soybean in Vietnam

and the World, 1998–2006 (USD/ton)

Source: Domestic prices for maize and soybean summarised from Review 'Today index price' published

weekly by Price and Trade Department, GSO. World price extracted from Indexmuni of the IMF 2008

(http://indexmundi.com/commodities)

Not only do prices differ, so too does quality between industrial feed produced by

domestic companies with imported feed or produced by foreign-owned companies in

Vietnam. Good quality animal feeds have relatively high prices compared to inferior

quality feeds. Animal feeds produced locally by private local feed companies are

generally perceived to be of lower quality than those produced by foreign-owned feed

milling companies (IFPRI 2001). However, with loose regulations for labelling and

product quality certification, it is difficult to differentiate between low and high quality

feeds on the market. Consequently, farmers’ decisions to purchase feed are largely

driven by price. Small producers, in an attempt to reduce cost due to limited finances,

choose lower priced feeds, without considering the effects on the quality of animals

produced.

Page 40: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

22

2.2.4. Livestock Diseases and Animal Breeds

Livestock producers also face the risk of livestock disease. In a normal year, mortality

can be up to 3.69, 2.28 and 2.48 percent of total herd of exotic pigs, crossbred pigs and

local pigs, respectively. For chicken this rate is even higher with 14.67 percent of local

breeds and 5.31 percent of exotic chickens (IFPRI 2001). Due to limited prevention and

treatment, especially in small households, animal diseases have spread widely in recent

years. Loss of production due to diseases in the livestock sector is very serious and

pushes up production costs. There are many reasons for this, mainly a veterinary system

with inadequately trained staff, poor data collection, storage, and retrieval systems, and

lack of monitoring which limits the effectiveness of veterinary extension services.

Since winter 2004, the avian influenza outbreak resulted in large losses for poultry

husbandry in Vietnam. As each winter season approaches, the risk of another larger

outbreak concerns people. According to an estimate by the World Bank, the outbreak in

winter 2004 resulted in the output value of the poultry sector in Vietnam declining by

15 percent. The net impact of avian influenza was estimated, from the combined effect

on poultry and egg production and subsequent livestock production, as 0.12 percent of

total GDP (World Bank 2005). This estimate did not include economic losses in general

due to the outbreak such as reduced tourism, vaccination costs and compensation for

producers. Due to the large population of small producers in Vietnam, losses from the

outbreak were felt most by small-scale producers. Many found themselves in debt when

their birds died or were culled, especially if they borrowed from banks for their

production (Leod et al. 2005).

The adoption and accession to improved animal breeds is an increasing issue in

livestock husbandry. There is a difference between small and large scale producers in

the adoption of exotic breeds. According to an IFPRI survey, choosing exotic breeds is

heavily dependent on the farm size. For pig husbandry, around 10 percent of small

farms have exotic breeds in their inventories, whilst over 55 percent of large farms have

some exotic pigs and 45 percent consist entirely of exotic pigs. Adoption of exotic

breeds by poultry farms is higher than by pig farms. However, the numbers are only 22

percent for small chicken farms and 70 percent for large farms (IFPRI 2001).

Page 41: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

23

One factor that influences low levels of exotic breed adoption by small producers is the

lack of access to exotic genetics. Small farms often purchase breeding stocks from other

farmers or from traders. Only 8 percent of pig producers and 18.6 percent of chicken

producers indicate that they purchase breeds from government agencies, who often

supply exotic and high quality breeds (IFPRI 2001).

This situation occurs for reasons: on one hand, government breeding centres generally

operate inefficiently and with high transaction costs they find it difficult to supply small

numbers of livestock to scattered producers; on the other hand, management systems of

small households, which use low cost feed and salvage kitchen waste are more suited to

local breeds rather than the exotic ones. This livestock raising method helps small

producers save costs.

2.2.5. Other Trade and Marketing Issues

With a population of about 85 million people (2007), Vietnam has a large market for

animal products. With income increases, the demand for livestock products has risen

dramatically in recent years. Figure 2-10 shows the increasing trend in meat

consumption per capita when people have more income available.

0

2

4

6

8

10

12

1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007

year

GD

P p

er c

apita

(m

ill.

VN

D)

0

5

10

15

20

25

30

35

40

mea

t co

nsum

ptio

n pe

r ca

pita

(kg

)

GDP per capita (in the 1st axis) total meat per capita beef and buffalo pork poultry

Figure 2-9: Changes in Population, Income and Meat Consumption per capita

Source: GSO 2008. Meat per capita consumption is live weight meat per capita (kg)

Page 42: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

24

Among livestock products, pork is consumed the most, with over 75 percent of total

meat. One reason is its cheap price and it is customary to eat pork compared with other

meat types. Poultry is the second most popular meat to consume. Figure 2-11 presents

pig and chicken consumption per capita over the regions.

In terms of quantity, pig consumption in urban areas is much higher than in rural areas,

but there is little difference for chicken. However, in terms of quality, consumer

requirements in urban areas are rather different to rural areas. About 36 percent of

households in urban areas prefer to buy high quality meat despite relatively higher

prices (Lapar et al. 2003). They are willing to pay a premium of about 6 to 16 percent

above the regular price if they can be sure of receiving high quality and safe products.

0

4

8

12

16

20

RRD NE NW NCC SCC CH NES MRD

region

cons

umpt

ion

per

capi

ta (

kg)

Pork Urban Pork Rural Chicken Urban Chicken Rural

Figure 2-10: Pig and Chicken Consumption per capita over Regions (kg)

Source: calculated from VHLSS 2006

Regarding consumption habits, Vietnamese consumers prefer fresh meat rather than

frozen or processed meat4, especially in rural areas. Processed meat consumption in

households is less than 5 percent of total meat volume5. For daily consumption,

consumers often buy fresh meat products from wet markets, where almost all livestock

products produced in Vietnam are sold.

Even though consumption per capita has increased over recent years, Vietnam’s

consumption is quite low compared with other countries. The most recent data shows

4 The processed meat is popularly in the form of canned meat such as slices, ham, and sausage. 5 Calculated from VHLSS 2006

Page 43: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

25

that in 2003, when meat consumption per capita of Vietnam was about 26 kg, the

numbers for China, Malaysia, USA and Europe were 54 kg, 48 kg, 123 kg, and 91 kg,

respectively (FAOStat 2008). This gap suggests that the potential domestic market for

meat in Vietnam is quite high. Thus, focusing on the domestic market is still an efficient

strategy, especially since Vietnam does not have a high comparative advantage in

livestock production for export.

However, in order to meet the requirements of markets and have opportunities to

expand livestock production, livestock households need to overcome some difficulties

in trade and marketing.

Most trading activity takes place locally, with most small farmers selling at the farm

gate, as there is little access to organised markets and auctioning systems. Information

about markets, prices and other supporting information is limited. The lack of a

widespread system of organised live animal markets in Vietnam means that the majority

of marketing and distribution of live animals and animal products is undertaken through

a network of marketers operating in informal groupings and often undertaking

exchanges on a face-to-face basis. Table 2-4 reports the proportion of pig and poultry

sold to different stakeholders in the marketing channel, rather than to final consumers or

assemblers and distribution companies of livestock products.

Table 2-5: Share of Pig and Chicken for Sale by Household (percent)

Assemblers Retailers Slaughterhouses Wholesalers

Pig producers

Small-scale 23 12 60 5

Large scale 30 30 40 0

Chicken producers

Small-scale 50 25 0 25

Large scale 40 50 0 10

Source: IFPRI 2001

Page 44: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

26

The marketing channels of livestock husbandry are complicated and involve many

stages. Stakeholders usually involved in the channel include producers, assemblers,

wholesalers, processors, retailers and consumers. There are often four middlemen:

traders, wholesalers, slaughterhouses/meat processors, and retailers. Live pigs and

piglets are primarily sold to traders, wholesalers and slaughterhouses while pig

carcasses and other meat products are usually sold to retailers or directly to consumers

in wet markets. Marketing channels in the chicken marketing system are similar to those

of the pig marketing system. Live chickens are usually sold to wholesalers and retailers,

while carcasses are sold to wholesalers, retailers or directly to customers. Through

marketing channels, profits are shared in many segments and final prices of the products

are also affected6.

Moreover, due to the predominantly small-scale operations and wide dispersion of

production units, costs of collection, selection, and classification of assemblers also

increase. In addition, the high risk of getting poor quality animals from various sources

with uncertain product quality, add to the costs in terms of moral hazard. Specifically,

when buying from uncertified sources, the uncertainty about product quality imposes a

tax on the value of the good, so that the buyer will not be motivated to pay the real

market price, but rather would offer to pay a lower price, thus generating a loss in

potential income to the producer.

2.3. Policy Environment for Livestock Husbandry Development

In the last sections, a review of livestock sector development and issues in development

were presented. For a clearer picture about the livestock husbandry situation in

Vietnam, the policy environment and strategy for the development of the sector in

recent years and the near future are now presented.

Since implementing economic reforms, a set of policies that support the development of

the agricultural sector in general was promulgated. In these, policies such as admitting

households as one unit in agricultural production, allocating production factors and land

6 According to research of IFPRI, the marketing margin (difference between farm gate price and retail price) of pig meat in 2001 varied from 40 percent of farm gate price in the North East to 76 percent in the Central Highlands

Page 45: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

27

to each individual household, and opening the economy to external markets contributed

to remarkable growth of Vietnam’s agricultural sector.

For sustainable development of the agricultural sector, a diversification strategy was

adopted in which the livestock sector was considered a major component. However,

unlike the rice or sugar sectors, there was no specific set of government policies in place

for the livestock sector (Lapar et al. 2003) but the policies supporting the development

of the sector often form part of the framework in the general policy for agriculture.

For example, with resolution No.10 issued in 1988, households are recognised as

independent economic units and have the right to use their land over the long term (30

to 50 years), they are their own bosses and can decide how and what to produce and sell

and where to get their inputs7. This and other policies on lending to families and

agricultural extensions, connect two paramount resources, labour and land, in order to

develop agriculture to the utmost. This was an impetus for households to help their

productivity and sell products for more income. With limited prospects for high benefit

through rice production alone, and rapid demand increases for meat due to population

growth and urbanisation, livestock husbandry was chosen by households to develop in

response to market demand.

There were some other policies and programs such as supported programs from the

government for crop varieties and livestock breeds, hunger alleviation and poverty

reduction programs, etc., which also supported the development of the livestock sector.

These policies are often designed and combined into one general supporting policy. At

the national level, program 125 provides 10 to 13 billion VND every year for

supporting the cost of breeding of pigs, cows, and poultry for producers; Program 225

provides about 100 billion VND to upgrade research institutes which develop crop

seeds, and animal breeds, and to subsidize seed imports and promote seed

multiplication; the program for agricultural extension provides a subsidy of about 30 to

50 billion VND each year, to support the transfer of new technologies into agricultural

production. In addition to that, many programs are conducted at the provincial level to

7 Before then, under the collectivisation period, household members took part in production as workers and received salaries. The farmer-workers did not have any decision about cost-benefit in production. Since their salary was fixed and not affected by their works, they contributed as little as they could, this led to an unavoidable collapse of the collective system.

Page 46: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

28

support agricultural production in general, therefore it is difficult to define the full

extent of support for the livestock sector (Barker et al. 2001).

The Vietnamese government continuously values livestock husbandry as an important

economic sector in agricultural production, contributing to the agricultural growth rate.

As an orientation for development of the livestock sector in the future, a Livestock

Sector Development Strategy to 2020 was developed at the end of 2007. The general

objectives were three-fold, that by 2020: (i) increase the share of livestock in

agricultural sector GDP to 42 percent (from an estimate of 32 percent in 2010); (ii)

increase the use of commercial feeds in total feeds to 71 percent; and (iii) monitor and

control a number of dangerous animal diseases such as Foot and Mouth Diseases

(FMD) and avian influenza (MARD 2007).

These objectives are being pursued through more rigorous planning from feed,

production, slaughtering, processing to marketing; using advanced science and

technology to improve productivity and quality of livestock products; supporting

livestock production through commercial farms and industrial farms at the same time

reorganising small household producers; and supporting other services in the livestock

sectors such as extension, market information, breeds and feed supply, etc.

2.4. Summary

Recently, the livestock sector has developed considerably, both in quantity and quality.

This development has been considered a major component in agriculture, contributing

to the agricultural diversification program not only in response to increased demand but

also as a source of higher, more stable incomes and better nutrition for people.

However, the development level of the Vietnam livestock sector is still low, in

comparison with other similar economies. In the development process, the sector also

faces many issues such as low productivity, low quality of livestock products, high

price and low quality of livestock feed, slow improvement, poor genetics, animal

diseases, etc. The complexity of these issues represents a challenge for the sustainable

development of the sector.

Livestock production in Vietnam is undertaken predominately at the household level, by

producers who are non-specialised. These households generally undertake cropping in

Page 47: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

29

addition to raising livestock and they usually keep more than one type of livestock in a

mixed raising system, which often combines pigs and chickens. The traditional method

of raising livestock with local breeds and low cost feed products does not produce good

quality and high standard meat products with competitive prices.

In the future, confronted with opportunities to expand the livestock sector, the question

of how to develop the livestock production system effectively is important. The strategy

of the Vietnamese government is to develop the modern livestock system to large-scale,

intensive commercial farms to meet rising market requirements. In that context, how the

small livestock producers with traditional systems, which are the largest sector in the

rural areas, can cope with change is an important question. In particular, how they can

adjust to the challenges presented by trade liberalisation, is the question that this thesis

aims to address.

Page 48: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

30

CHAPTER 3 : THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK OF

AGRICULTURAL HOUSEHOLD MODEL

The analysis of the household is an area of concern in all the social sciences:

anthropology, economics, sociology, etc. However, each discipline approaches the

household on the discipline's own terms. From the point of view of the economist, they

come to an analysis of the household from their earlier focus on the individual (as

consumer) and the firm (as producer) to the neglect of the family and have been

concerned primarily with defining the household in relation to production and

consumption.

A basic model with a conventional approach of maximising a utility function is useful

for understanding decision making of an agricultural household, since it can be used to

integrate information on their production and consumption activities. Such models have

been widely applied to households in developing countries (Braverman & Hammer

1986; Barnum & Squire 1979a; Strauss 1984; Ellis 1988; Singh et al. 1986; Janvry &

Sadoulet 1995). The main difference with this kind of model compared to applications

of consumer choice theory is that it provides a methodology for integrating an

agricultural household’s production and consumption decisions into a unified

theoretical and econometric framework. It means that, when consumers maximise their

utility, they are confronted with not only a limited budget, but also time and technology

constraints of the household.

The first model to integrate production and consumption decisions in the analysis of the

peasant household was proposed in the 1920s by Chayanov, a Russian agricultural

economist (Thorner et al. 1966), and later developed by Mellor in 1963, Sen in 1966,

and Nakajima in 1986 and others.

In the Chayanov model, the household seeks to maximize its utility, where utility is

derived from the consumption of goods produced on the farm, purchased goods, and

leisure. By combining utility maximization from consumption theory with the

production function from production theory, the Chayanov model provides a foundation

Page 49: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

31

for the integrated models of household decision making. The conclusions of the

Chayanov model are linked to key assumptions regarding the interaction between the

household and markets. Most notable among these assumptions are that the household

lacks access to a wage labour market and that the household has unlimited access to

land. These assumptions lead to a prominent feature of the Chayanov model, namely,

the demographic cycle (or "life-cycle") hypothesis. Chayanov proposed a positive link

between the household's level of work effort and the consumer to worker ratio (c/w)

within the household. (Thorner et al. 1966).

The new Home-economics model is a refinement of the neoclassical theory of

consumption. In it, Becker provides an alternative model of time allocation within the

household (Becker 1965, 1991). Utility is redefined in the “new home economics

model” so that, rather than being based on purchased goods and services, the utility of

the household is based on home produced commodities. The household members

combine their time and human capital with purchased goods and services to create these

home produced commodities, otherwise known as “Z-goods”8. In general, most items

purchased by the household must be combined with household labour in order to

contribute to utility levels. In the model, the household, rather than the individual, is

clearly established as the unit of analysis. The model also has one advantage in

comparison with the previous one, as it provides a logical structure for exploring the

links between utility maximization and the allocation of time to productive activities.

More specifically, the model postulates that the time (or labour) of household members

is allocated according to the opportunity cost of each member's time. Finally, given that

the new home economics model is based on the assumption of full access to wage

labour markets, it means that the value of wage work, home production, and leisure are

all assigned an opportunity cost equal to the market wage rate.

In this chapter, a combined model of an agricultural household as both producer and

consumer is presented. The model was proposed by Barnum and Squire and further

developed in Singh, Squire, and Strauss (Barnum & Squire 1979a; Strauss 1984; Singh

et al. 1986). In the model, the demand side is determined by prices and income as

normal, however, income is partly determined by household production activities.

8 “Z-good” is produced for consumption by the household only. An example of a Z-good would be meals prepared at home, or higher-order goods such as “nutrition”, or “shelter”.

Page 50: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

32

Therefore consumption behaviour is not independent of production behaviour. Under

some key assumptions this establishes a recursive property of the model: production

decisions are assumed to be made independently of consumption, but production profits

influence consumption. The framework of the model and relation between household

labour and labour market are presented in the next section, and detailed analytical

framework of the property is in Appendix A3.1.

3.1. The Basic Model

In general, an agricultural household is assumed to maximise its utility function. This is

specified as a function of market purchased goods, home produced goods and leisure

time9, and is written succinctly as:

),,,( iaMCLUU i =1, …., (3-1)

where

L = leisure

C = own-consumption of agricultural output

M = consumption of market purchased goods

ai = household characteristics (for example, number of dependents)

Clearly, L, C, and M could be vectors of commodities or leisure consumption for

different members of the household. However, in this particular application there is no

concern for intra-household distribution, so the household is assumed to maximise its

joint utility function as a whole.

This optimisation is subject to certain constraints. In the household model, the objective

function is constrained by three restrictions on household actions.

The first one is the technology constraint(s):

),( , AdDFF j j = 1,…,m, (3-2)

Where

9 The model is presented in this part is developed by Barnum, Squire, and Singh (Barnum & Squire 1979a, Singh et al. 1986)

Page 51: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

33

F = total agricultural output

D = total labour inputs (both of household and hired) used in production of F

dj = other variable inputs, range of j from 1 to m

A = area of land used in F production

The production function of the household is assumed to be quasi-convex and increasing

in inputs, but marginal product is decreasing in inputs. The household can produce more

than one output, and hence have more than one technology constraint. However, total

land for cultivation activity is (here) assumed to be fixed.

The household has the opportunity of utilising its total endowment of time either

working on- or off-farm, or for leisure:

offf HHLT (3-3)

As mentioned above, total working time for on-farm work, D, includes both household

working labour and labour hired from outside (if needed).

hiredf HHD (3-4)

So if combining (3-3) and (3-4) together, we can rewrite the time constraint of the

household as follows:

hiredoff HHDLT (3-5)

where

T = total household time available for labour

L = leisure

D = total labour inputs (both of household and hired) used in production of F

Hf = level of household labour working on-farm

Hoff = level of household labour working off-farm

Hhired = level of hired labour working on-farm

Page 52: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

34

The household maximises its utility subject to a budget constraint, which states that

total expenditure for physical commodities can not exceed the total money that the

household gets from work plus exogenous income. Assume that household labour and

hired labour are perfect substitutes and face the same wage rate:

jjhiredoff dwpFRHHwpCqM )( (3-6)

where

R = non-wage, non-farm net other income

q = price of M

p = price of C

w = wage-rate

Hoff = time working off- farm of household labour

Hhired = working time of labour hired in for farm

wj = prices of other variable factors

From this constraint, it can be seen that the role of the labour market is especially

emphasised in the model. In order to simplify the problem, those three constraints are

collapsed into a single constraint, namely the “full income” constraint as follows:

wTRwLpCqM (3-7)

where jj dwwDDpF )( is net profit from household’s agricultural

production. The left-hand side of the equation (3-7) is total expenditures of the

household and includes “expenditure” on leisure valued at the wage rate and the right-

hand side is an augmented version of Becker’s concept of “full income”, which is the

sum of any non-wage, non-farm net other income (R), a measure of the farm’s profits

(∏), and the value of the household’s stock of time (wT) (Becker 1965). Since land is

treated as a fixed factor, the rent payments or receipts, if any, are captured in the

definition of R.

This 'full income' constraint in particular distinguishes agricultural household models

from other approaches and highlights the interdependency between consumption and

Page 53: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

35

production decisions made at the household level. Farm technology, quantities of fixed

inputs, and prices of variable inputs and outputs affect household consumption

decisions since they determine the size of the farm profit portion of the full income

constraint. Thus, this approach permits identification of linkages between farm

household production and consumption decisions.

3.2. Solving the General Model

By rearranging the full income constraint, now the problem of the household is

maximising its utility (3-1) with the constraint (3-7). The household can choose

quantities of the consumption for commodities and labour input for agricultural

production. Forming the Lagrangian, the household problem takes the following form:

)(),,( * wLpCqMYMCLU (3-8)

Where λ is the Lagrangian multiplier and Y* is the value of the full income that results

from profit maximising behaviour:

**** ),,( wDdwAdDpFRwTRwTY jjj (3-9)

where D* is labour input that the household chose for the farm’s agricultural production

to get maximum profit Π*, with land cultivation fixed A . Maximizing utility subject to

the full income constraint yields the following first-order conditions:

0

wL

U

L (3-10a)

0

qM

U

M (3-10b)

0

pC

U

C (3-10c)

0*

wLpCqMY

(3-10d)

The marginal conditions of the equations (3-10) can be solved to yield three demand

equations for choice variables C, M, L as follows:

Page 54: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

36

),,,,( *iaYwpqCC (3-11a)

),,,,( *iaYwpqMM (3-11b)

),,,,( *iaYwpqLL (3-11c)

where ai are household characteristics. The demand system follows neoclassical theory,

where demand depends upon prices income and possibly household characteristics.

However, in the household model, full income, Y*, is determined by technological

production in the equation (3-9). Therefore changes in the factors that influence

production, profit and hence change in Y* will lead to changes in consumption

behaviour.

The model is also set up under some simplified assumptions, which help derive

consumer demand, output supply and variable input demand equations by modelling the

farm household decision-making process recursively as two separate stages, despite

their simultaneity in time. These assumptions briefly include: the household is a price-

taker in all markets and all markets exist; commodities are homogeneous, including the

labour market; decisions relating to the total stock of land and labour are treated as

given; intertemporal allocation and risk are omitted (Barnum & Squire 1979b).

3.3. Role of Labour Market

As mentioned in the last section, the assumption of the existence of a labour market,

and homogeneity in labour are particularly important in solving a recursive agricultural

household model. The dual role of an agricultural household as both producer and

consumer lets it make decisions at two disaggregated levels; that is one of an individual

farmer determining labour, and as the individual household deciding upon leisure or

supplying labour.

Page 55: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

37

Figure 3-1: Separation of Household Decisions

The important implication of an active labour market is that household decisions about

the level of production and labour use can be made independently of household

decisions about consumption. In Figure 3-1 the relationship between household profit

and the amount of labour employed is represented by the curve π, which in turn is a

function of the physical production function and exogenous prices (P), at a particular

level of agricultural production technology. Given the objective of maximising profit,

and subject to prices of inputs, including labour cost, the household chooses the optimal

amount of labour to use on the farm at Hf = D* (where the marginal return to labour is

equal to the wage rate). The decision does not depend on household preference of

leisure, rather, it depends only on the production technology, and inputs and output

prices. Hence the difference between labour supply availability (DS) and labour demand

for farm (D*) is labour worked off-farm, Hoff. Since the household has access to a labour

market, and there is no restriction on the mix of household and hired labour, the

separation property allows separate estimation of consumer and producer sides of the

model.

However, this separation is very sensitive to violations of the assumptions of the

household model, of which the most important is an incomplete labour market10. Figures

10 There are a number of reasons why the household model could not be solved separately, such as preferences of farmers for working (on- or off-farm), family and hired labour are not perfect substitute, and the markets are incomplete. However, in the scope of this section, only the case of an imperfect labour market is considered to see the important role of taking part in the labour market

w

Hoff

U

DDS

$

0 Hf =D*

π {F(D,diA);P}

Page 56: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

38

3-2 and 3-3 illustrate the role of a competitive labour market in decision making of an

agricultural household. Maintaining the assumption of perfect substitution of household

and hired labour, there are two cases which are most relevant in the “real world”:

“surplus labour” where off-farm opportunities are very limited, especially in a slack

season or after harvest time, and “labour shortage” in the peak season.

Figure 3-2: An Agricultural Household in Slack Season

Figure 3-2 shows a case of an agricultural household with limited opportunities to work

outside the farm11. Firstly, with the market wage w, the household would work on-farm

up to Hf, then supply the rest of the household labour Hoff12

to the labour market to get

the utility at U. Assume that there is a constraint on the amount of labour that can be

supplied off-farm H*off, which is less than Hoff. In that case, the income/labour frontier is

given by F’, which is production curve F(D,dj,A)+wH*off in the figure. Then, the

household will sell H*off of family labour to the market to have wH*

off off-farm income.

If applying the market wage for their farm, they only supply labour to farm work up to

the D* level, hence there is still some surplus labour in the household. In this case, the

11 The figure is drawn by the author, based on the discussion of Benjamin and Souficas (Benjamin 1992; Skoufias 1994), 12 Labour worked off-farm, Hoff, is the difference between total labour supply and labour working on farm, Hf.

U*

F(D,dj,A)

0

$

H*off

w

w*

U

F’=

F(D,dj,A)

+ wH*

off

wH*

off

D*D Hf Hoff Hf

*

Page 57: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

39

household can increase utility by employing more labour on the farm till H*f, where the

opportunity cost of each day working is not the market wage w anymore, but w*<w

defined as the shadow wage. By supplying labour to H*f, the utility of the household

now is U*, lower than the utility U that the household could achieve if there was no

constraint on the labour market.

Figure 3-3: An Agricultural Household in Peak Season

Figure 3-3 shows the situation of an agricultural household in peak season, when there

is a shortage in labour. The figure includes two parts. Part A shows the standard

outcome where labour is hired in, without limit. The figure assumes that the labour

market is perfect, at the market wage rate w, as a producer, the household maximises

U

U*

w*

$

H*hired

w

F(D,dj,A)

- wH*

hired

D Hf Hf* D*

Hhired

F(D,dj,A)

- wHhired

U

w

$

D Hhired

0 Hf DD

F(D,dj,A)

- wHhired

0

Part A

Part B

Page 58: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

40

their farm profit by producing at DD, using Hf household labour and Hhired13

labour

bought from the market, and get utility at U.

Part B shows the outcome when there is a limit on the amount of labour that can be

hired in. It is assumed that labour will be hired to the limit. The farm production

function is moved down a line with slope equal to the wage, so that the horizontal

displacement is equal to the limit. The intersection of this function with the vertical axis

indicates the profit that can be enjoyed from hired labour alone. The function then

indicates that increase in income earned as additional household labour is applied.

Utility maximisation occurs at the normal tangency between this function and the

highest indifference curve. In the first case, where the limit is exactly equal to the

amount of hired labour required - the constraint is not binding effectively. The

household with production function F, indicated by F(D,dj,A)- wHhired, chooses to

supply household labour at Hf, and pay wHhired to hire labour from market. By

construction, it can be seen that the optimal utility achieved is the same as if the market

were “unconstrained” at utility U. However, if the limit is genuinely constraining, only

H*hired labour can be hired from market, at the wage rate w* > w, the household supplies

the household labour to the farm till H*f, then a lower level of utility can be achieved, at

U*.

Both of the cases above illustrate the non-separation property of the household model if

the labour market is not perfect. Then, the decision of taking leisure and demanding

labour for the farm is a convolution, and depends not only on production technology,

prices of inputs, but also characteristics and composition of the household.

3.4. Profit Effects

As mentioned above, one of the major results of the agricultural model is the linkage

between production and consumption through profit. This section presents how the

consumption of a commodity changes when its price changes, if the household both

produces and consumes that commodity. In accordance with the previous section, the

commodity is C, with price p.

13 Labour hired from market is to cover the shortage between required labour DD and supply of household labour, Hf.

Page 59: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

41

From the demand equation of C, the total change in quantity demanded, dC, where the

change in its price, dp, is determined as:

p

Y

Y

C

p

C

dp

dC

*

* (3-12)

The first term on the right hand side of the equation (3-12) is the standard substitution

effect. For normal goods, the change in the quantity consumed, given a change in its

own price, is negative. The second term captures the profit effect. A change in the price

of agricultural goods changes profit and hence full income through equation (3-9).

Then, in turn, full income changes the quantity demanded for C in equation (3-11a).

The second term can be expressed as:

dpDFp

dpp

Ydp

p

Y

Y

C)(**

**

*

(3-13)

Therefore equation (3-12) can be rewritten:

dpFp

C

dp

dC)(

As F(D) (the quantity of agricultural output) is always positive, the second term is

unambiguously positive, while, according to neoclassical demand theory, the first term

is negative for a normal good. Thus the total change in quantity demanded is the net

effect of two opposing substitution and profit effects.

Therefore, the “profit effect” is considered as a distinctive feature of the household

model. In applying the model, there are some policy implications different from those

that would be arrived at by traditional methods. Previous research results show the

advantages of the household model. Table 3-1 presents various studies in the literature

where notable differences in price elasticities with and without incorporation of the

“profit effect”.

Page 60: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

42

Table 3-1: Selected Response Agricultural Price Elasticity With and Without

Profit Effect

Agricultural

commodity

Non-agricultural

commodity

Labour supply

Country/economy

A B A B A B

Taiwan -0.72 0.22 0.13 1.18 0.21 -1.59

Malaysia -0.04 0.38 -0.27 1.94 0.08 -0.57

Korea, Rep. of -0.18 0.01 -0.19 0.81 0.03 -0.13

Japan -0.87 -0.35 0.08 0.61 0.16 -1.00

Thailand -0.82 -0.37 0.06 0.51 0.18 -0.62

Sierra Leone -0.74 -0.66 -0.03 0.14 0.01 -0.09

Northern Nigeria -0.05 0.19 -0.14 0.57 0.03 -0.06

Source: Singh, Squire, and Strauss, 1986, Table 1-2, p.26.

A: Agricultural price elasticity without profit effect, B: Agricultural price elasticity with profit effect

However, the possible outcome of the total effect of price change on consumption is

highly dependent on what dominates: the substitution or profit effect, and varies across

each empirical study.

3.5. Summary

This chapter briefly presents an agricultural household model. As producers, the

household tries to maximise its net income with respect to levels of outputs and inputs,

subject to constraints determined by market prices, fixed factors and technology. As

consumers, the household maximises utility with respect to the quantity of goods

consumed, and leisure, subject to the constraints determined by the market prices

(includes wage), income, total time available, etc. However, in the household model,

additional flexibility regarding the consumption response to income change is allowed.

Through the “profit effect”, the two sides of production and consumption are linked

together in a recursive decision making.

Page 61: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

43

The model of household behaviour presented above is a semi-commercial household

farm with a competitive labour market. As in other LDC countries, this type of

agricultural household is common in Vietnam, and lies on a continuum between wholly

commercialised farms only employing hired labour and marketing all output and a pure

subsistence farm using household labour and producing solely for home consumption.

This study applied this theoretical framework to build a representative household model

for Vietnamese small-scale livestock households. The results from econometric

estimation of the production and consumption sides of the model are presented in the

next chapter. Then the integration of these two sides allows for the construction of a full

simulation model of the household. The impacts on the household from trade policy

change can be simulated by integrating the trade and household model.

Page 62: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

44

CHAPTER 4 : THE ECONOMETRIC MODELS

In this chapter, econometric models of production and consumption behaviour of the

agricultural household are presented. Developed as a recursive household model, the

production segment of the model is analysed employing a Cobb-Douglas (CD)

production function to estimate output, and hence profit from the farm. The

consumption side is specified using two stages: the Linear Expenditure System (LES)

for a broad grouping of goods and expenditures in the first stage, with the integration

between demand for commodities and the allocation of time for leisure and labour

supply. In the second stage, expenditure for each individual commodity in the main

food group is allocated using the Linear Approximation Almost Ideal Demand System

(LA-AIDS).

In this empirical study, econometric models are estimated from primary data of the

Vietnam Household Living Standard Survey 2004, a multi-purpose household survey.

The total survey sample was 45 900 households, in which 36 720 households report

income only, with 9180 households reporting both income and expenditure. The sample

covers and represents 3063 communes, over eight ecological regions14 and for almost

all provinces of the country. The survey included detailed questions on a household’s

characteristics and composition; income, expenditure, and saving; labour activities of

adults and children; health care and education access; housing and durable goods;

electronics; land holding and non-agricultural activities. The survey was carried out in

May and September 2004 (GSO 2004) with all questions relating to production and

consumption being framed for the previous 12 months. Therefore, even though the

avian influenza outbreak occurred in the winter of 2004, data collected from the survey

represents a normal year of the household.

Since this study pays specific attention to small-scale households in the livestock sector,

around 7000 of the 9180 households were chosen for research purposes15. In this

14 The ecological regions are Red River Delta, North East, North West, North Central Coast, South Central Coast, Central Highland, North East South, and Mekong River Delta 15 The classification of a household in the livestock sector is based on the criteria of gross value of production, includes value from raising livestock, cultivation production and other activities. This methodology is adopted from the research on Vietnam livestock sector of International Food Policy

Page 63: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

45

research, the country is divided into four regions16: Red River Delta, the Northern

upland (includes North East and North West, in short NE+NW), the Central region

(includes North Central Coast, South Central Coast and Central Highland), and the

South (includes Mekong River Delta and North East South). Each region represents

ecological areas where agro-ecological and economy conditions are similar, and there is

a degree of homogeneity in farming system or activities of the household in production.

4.1. Production of Agricultural Household

All characterisations of the theoretical model seem to be suitable for the present study.

In Vietnam, most agricultural households take part in both livestock and other

agricultural crop production (mainly rice cultivation). Small-scale livestock production

accounts for as much as 80 percent of total livestock product in the country. Each

agricultural household often keeps 1–2 sows or less than 10 fatteners and/or some

dozens of chicken per year. For the purpose of the research, it was assumed that a

representative household produces only three commodities: paddy rice, pigs, and

chickens.

For the production segment of the household model, a direct estimate of the production

functions is employed, and the Cobb-Douglas functional form is chosen because of

analytical tractability.

Production functions take specific forms as follows:

rrrrrice VDAF 321

0 (4-1a)

ii

ii

iiii VDGF 321

0 i = pig, chicken (4-1b)

where A is land for rice production and is fixed, D is labour requirement, V are variable

inputs and G is feed for pigs or chickens. It is assumed that these production functions

can be estimated independently. It is also possible that there will be spatial

Research Institute (IFPRI 2001). Other criteria such as economic and farming systems are also considered for the purpose of household stratification. 16 In general, the researchers often divide Vietnam into 3 regions, the North, the Center, and the South based on the ecological conditions. However, in the realization that, RRD is in the delta, near by Ha Noi, the capital of the country, so the people in that area seem to have more opportunities to access to market and the other services rather than the people in the mountainous areas (NE and NW), therefore dividing the North into RRD and Up north mountainous areas (includes NW and NE) is necessary.

Page 64: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

46

autocorrelation, given specific local conditions may affect spatially close farms.

However, detailed spatial information is not available on households and hence

consideration of any spatial correlation is limited to the fixed effects associated with

estimating regional models.

In the survey, only information on the total cost for each kind of input variable for

production, not the quantities, were available. In order to estimate input quantities for

production for the purpose of production function regression, the price of inputs are

required. Therefore price information was collected from the database of the

Vietnamese Institute for Market and Prices. This covers almost all agricultural and

consumption commodities’ retail prices over districts and provinces, weekly. The local

market price for each kind of variable input from the database was used as the price that

the household has to pay. According to Justino and Litchfield (2002), commune or local

prices often reflect accurately the prices faced by the households, since those

households as a commune usually have a single market where they purchase similar

goods at the same price.

Table 4-1 (next page) presents basic information on mean inputs and output levels of

rice, pig and chicken production of agricultural households in the four regions.

The results from ordinary least squares estimation of the CD production functions for

Vietnamese agricultural households are reported in Appendix A4.1. Here, the estimated

production functions are summarised as:

058.0223.0048.0059.061.00 pesticidefertilizerseedricerrice VVVDAF

095.0171.0584.00 pigpigpigppig VDGF

137.021.046.00 chickenchickenchickencchicken VDGF

Page 65: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

47

Table 4-1: Arithmetic Means of Inputs and Outputs for four Regions

Arithmetic means (whole year) RRD NE+NW Central South

Rice production

No. of households 1367 1280 1402 984

Area (ha) 0.38 0.44 0.47 1.82

Yield (ton/ha) 6.48 5.35 4.99 4.58

Labour (man-day) 92.73 167.79 113.03 44.58

Seed (kg/ha) 188.68 283.61 316.24 309.94

Chemical fertiliser (kg/ha) 430.04 321.47 459.88 474.79

Pesticide (bottles/ha) 47.95 30.71 38.61 72.20

Pig production

No. of households 1037 1176 1212 597

Pig output (kg) 333.97 262.40 246.85 766.58

Labour (man-day) 115.09 129.43 86.15 150.93

Feeding cost (mil. VND) 2.62 1.53 1.51 5.99

Veterinary cost ('000 VND) 62.93 40.35 55.06 316.27

Other costs ('000 VND) 253.70 283.99 253.64 584.37

Chicken production

No. of households 596 719 573 71

Chicken output (kg) 31.63 43.64 30.09 34.03

Labour (man-day) 15.65 39.63 19.27 10.00

Feeding cost ('000 VND) 365.85 426.87 215.30 233.13

Veterinary cost ('000 VND) 15.81 22.21 18.54 22.46

Other costs ('000 VND) 14.68 14.08 18.59 12.00

Page 66: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

48

The differences in technological productivity among regions are represented in the

differences in the constant terms:

Table 4-2: Neutral Technological Efficiency Parameters in Different Regions

Production function of RRD NE+NW Central South

Rice (α0r) 751.48 666.82 561.54 564.27

Pig (α0p) 0.98 0.98 1.08 1.25

Chicken (α0c) 0.78 0.82 0.91 1.21

All coefficients are significant at the 1 percent level, except for the technology

efficiency parameter for pigs (See Appendix A4.1 for more detail).

As mentioned in the previous chapter, it was assumed that the household maximises

profits with respect to labour, and other variable inputs in each production function.

Note that output supply elasticity can be obtained directly from the parameter estimates

of the linearly transformed CD production function. For instance, if 3210

VDAF ,

then elasticity of output supply to labour is:

2ln

ln

D

F

F

D

D

F (4-2)

Moreover, the profit maximising condition for the allocation of labour defines that the

household employs labour until the value of the marginal product equals the wage cost,

or:

wD

Fp

D

(4-3)

Accordingly, we can derive demand functions for labour from the production equation

and the profit maximisation condition, by multiplying both sides of equation (4-3) with

FD / then FwpD )/(2

Therefore demand functions for all factors can be generalised as FppX iii / ,

where Xi is demand of factor i (i = 2,…n), αi is parameter of the factor in CD production

function, pi is price of that factor, p and F are price and output of the agricultural

Page 67: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

49

product, respectively. Once all demand functions of variable inputs are given, we can

re-write the production function and profit function in terms of fixed factors and relative

prices as follows:

321/13

3

3

2

2

210

p

p

p

pAF (4-4)

pFXppFi

ii

ii )1( (i = 2,….n) (4-5)

Applying the general formula to production functions of pig and chicken, we derive

profit and production functions for rice, pig and chicken for RRD as follows17:

01.0086.0007.001.0446.0 )/()/()/()/(*13262 pesticidericefertilizerriceseedricericerice wpwpwpwpAF

ricericerice Fp*612.0

702.0767.0922.0 )/()/()/(*878.0 VpigpigpigGpigpigpig wpwpwpF

pigpigpig Fp*15.0

681.0739.0861.0 )/()/()/(*792.0 VchickenchickenchickenGchickenchickenchicken wpwpwpF

chickenchickenchicken Fp*193.0

4.1.1. Production Elasticity

This section outlines the derivation and calculation of the production elasticity relevant

to the agricultural household model. Using the parameters estimates above, a table of

labour demand, output supply, and profit elasticity to price of output and price of labour

for each agricultural activity was constructed (Table 4-3). These elasticities are

interpreted for their significance in production decisions and are used later to determine

the direction and magnitude of the profit effect and its impact on household output price

responsiveness.

17 Production functions for other regions are calculated in similar ways; however, different neutral technological efficient parameters lead to shifting of production functions along output value.

Page 68: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

50

Table 4-3: Elasticity of Output, Labour Demand and Profit with Respect to

Selected Variables in the Production Functions

Elasticity Variables

Output (Fi) Labour demand (Di) Profit (П)

Rice production function

Rice price (price) 0.634 1.634 1.634

Labour wage (w) -0.096 -1.096 -0.096

Technical efficiency (α0rice) 1.634 1.634 1.634

Pig production function

Pig price (ppig) 5.667 6.667 6.667

Labour wage (w) -1.140 -2.140 -1.140

Technical efficiency (α0pig) 6.667 6.667 6.667

Chicken production function

Chicken price (pchicken) 4.181 5.181 5.181

Labour wage (w) -1.088 -2.088 -1.088

Technical efficiency (α0chicken) 5.181 5.181 5.181

From the first two diagonal elements in each block of the above table, the own-price

elasticities of output and labour can be interpreted. Pig and chicken output produced are

very responsive to changes in price of that output (live pig and chicken prices,

respectively). The high responsiveness of demand for labour in livestock production to

changes in the labour wage is also clear, with elasticities of -2.140 and -2.088. These

values are similar to the value of -2.57 found by Haughton using data for Malaysian

agricultural households and also a CD production function (Haughton 1985).

The production elasticities are compared with results from other countries with similar

conditions to Vietnam. Results of elasticities of rice production function are, in general,

consistent with earlier studies about paddy farms in Muda River Valley, Malaysia

(Table 4-3). Responses of the household in paddy output and labour demand to price

changes of paddy and labour in this study are 0.634 and -1.096, which are quite close to

Page 69: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

51

0.61 and -1.47 that were found by Barnum and Squire for Malaysia (Barnum & Squire

1979a).

Table 4-3 also shows positive elasticities of labour demand for changes in price of

outputs, indicating that the household has an incentive to produce more when output

price increases, to get more profits, as expected. One important factor needed from the

production side for the agricultural household model is the impact of change in output

price and labour wage on profits, which will be used later to consider the reaction of the

household as both producer and consumer. Note that these elasticities of livestock

profits are quite large, hence promising very clear impacts of exogenous price changes

to changes in demand for commodities through profit effects.

4.2. Consumption

4.2.1. Linear Expenditure System (LES) Model

The first stage of demand analysis operates at an aggregate level, and identifies demand

functions for food commodities, other expenditure, and at the same time, the household

labour supply function was also obtained. The wage rate of labour plays an important

role not only in determining income, but also in the allocation of non-market time and

the demand for commodities (Becker 1965, Mincer 1963, Abbott & Ashenfelter 1976).

An assertion of the classical theory of consumer demand is that the consumer-worker

acts as if maximising the own-utility function. In this section, a direct utility function is

used, based on the LES (Stone 1954), which is extremely useful because it assumes

consumption is a linear function of prices and disposable income. Since the intra-

household distribution can not be considered in detail, it is assumed that the household

maximises its joint utility function, and the utility function for each individual member

is identical and additive over the number of household members. For an individual

member of the family the utility function is written as:

)ln( iii xu i = 1,….,n, (4-6)

where xi indicates per capita quantity consumption of the ith commodity, and γi are

committed quantity of ith commodity for consumption, n is the total members of the

Page 70: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

52

household, and i includes leisure as a consumption good, with 1i , and

0 iix

It is assumed that the household in this study consumes three broad groups of

commodities: main food, other food and other expenditure (including the industrial

commodity group and other daily expenditure), and leisure. Dependents are assumed to

consume all their available time in the form of leisure and to consume the same

quantities of other goods as do working family members. The household has n1 working

members and n2 dependents, and the total number of members is n = n1 + n2. For the

present application, the household utility is defined as:

)ln()ln()ln()ln()ln( 443322112111 mncncntnlnU ofdfd

(4-7a)

subject to

EqMCpCpwL ofdofdfdfd (4-8)

where cfd is per capita consumption of main food group of commodity Cfd, cofd is per

capita consumption of commodity group of other foods Cofd, m is per capita

consumption of industrial goods and other expenditure M, l is leisure for working

family members, and L is total leisure time; w, pfd, pofd, and q are wage of labour, price

indices of main food group, other food group, and industrial goods and other

expenditure group, respectively. E is full income as defined in the previous chapter.

Substituting l=t-s to the equation (4-7a), where t is the total time available per

individual, s is the quantity of time supplied to work activities, the utility function now

is:

)ln()ln()ln()ln()ln( 443322112111 mncncntnstnU ofdfd

(4-7b)

Dividing equally the household utility function for n, the problem now is maximising an

individual member’s utility function:

)ln()ln()ln()ln()1()ln( 4433221111 mcctkstku ofdfd

(4-7c)

Page 71: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

53

subject to nEqmcpcpstkw ofdofdfdfd /)( (4-8b)

where nnk /1 . Let 11 k and kww ' . It is apparent that the problem is that of the

standard linear expenditure system, for which the expenditure equations are

)/()( 432111 qppwnEwstw ofdfd (4-9a)

)/( 432122 qppwnEpcp ofdfdfdfdfd (4-9b)

)/( 432133 qppwnEpcp ofdfdnfdnfdnfd (4-9c)

)/( 432144 qppwnEqqm ofdfd (4-9d)

In this case, the system of equations (4-9) has the intuitively appealing interpretation

that each member of the household firstly sets aside subsistence expenditures on the

commodities and leisure, then allocates the difference between full income (per capita)

and the minimum subsistence expenditures, among leisure time and the various

commodities in the fixed proportions βi.

However, one of the problems in estimating the model is that the measurement of

leisure as a residual after deducting working time from total available time may

introduce a specification error (Abbott & Ashenfelter 1976). Following their approach,

the system of equations is modified by substituting (t - ) for 1 in the equation (4-9a).

This yields:

432111 ))(/1( qppwqMCpCpwLnwwswt ofdfdofdofdfdfd

4321111 )/(' qppwqmcpcpnLww ofdfdofdofdfdfd

Substituting L/n1 = st and st 1 we obtain

4321 ''' qppwtwqmcpcpswtwwwtwswt ofdfdsofdofdfdfds

which can be rearranged to form equation (4-10a).

Page 72: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

54

)'( 4321 qppwbwws ofdfd (4-10a)

Similar derivations can be used to obtain equations (4-10b), (4-10c), (4-10d)

)'( 43222 qppwbpcp ofdfdfdfdfd (4-10b)

)'( 43233 qppwbpcp ofdfdnfdofdofd (4-10c)

)'( 43244 qppwbqqm ofdfd (4-10d)

where qmcpcpkwsqmcpcpswb ofdofdfdfdofdofdfdfd '

The variables appearing in the demand system functions, such as expenditures of the

household on the broad group of commodities, and average working days, are simply

drawn from the database. The prices of consumed commodities are also needed for

estimation. However, in the VHLSS, the price of each individual commodity is not

collected. So we rely on computing the unit value, which is a “price” derived by

dividing expenditure by quantities bought or sold.

Since demands of broad groups of commodities are considered, the prices here are not

the price of each individual commodity, but a price index, formed from the formula:

n

iii qpp

1

(4-11)

where pi is the price of each individual commodity in the group, qi is quantity share of

each commodity in the total quantity consumed of the group. Each group includes n

commodities. Table 4-4 presents the mean and standard deviation of the variables as

used in LES.

Page 73: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

55

Table 4-4: Description, Means, and Standard Deviation of Variables of Quantity

Consumption and Price Indices in LES

Variables Description ('000 VND) Mean Std.Dev.

pfd Price index of food group 9.79 2.87

pofd Price index of other food group 3.81 1.44

cfd.pfd Expenditure on food group per capita/year 1098.34 383.22

cofd.pofd Expenditure on other foods per capita/year 538.18 380.19

m.q Expenditure on industrial and others per

capita/year

576.75 365.69

s Average working day of each labour/year (days) 193.06 70.36

k Ratio of labour/ number of people in the household 0.65 0.22

w Average market wage of agricultural labour 26.19 11.76

w* Adjusted wage of agricultural labour 12.02 10.80

In the demand system of equations (4-10), parameters of γi and βi need to be estimated.

The parameters 432 ,,, appear in each of the three expenditure and labour supply

equations, and thus the estimation procedure chosen that constrains the estimates of the

s' to be consistent across equations. Note that, for marginal budget shares to sum to 1,

4321 k must equal unity: that is an estimate of β1 can be obtained from

estimates of β2, β3, β4. In order to estimate appropriate parameters, identifying prices of

each commodity group and the opportunity cost for each day of labour is important.

In the initial method of LES estimation, labour wage, or in other words, opportunity

cost of each day of labour, is based on market wages. However, some households in the

dataset do not take part in the labour market in either selling or buying labour; they only

work on their farm. The main reason may be that those households face constraints in

seeking off-farm jobs, due to seasonal features of the agricultural sector, or the

households live in isolated areas. For them, using market wages as the opportunity cost

of labour may overstate, or undervalue the cost of family labour, and lead to an

inaccurate estimation of their reaction in demand. This raises the need to account for the

implicit value of family labour. That is presented in the following section.

Page 74: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

56

4.2.1.1. Adjusting the Wage of Agricultural Labour

The methodology developed here estimated a “shadow wage” for household labour,

who may be confronted with an imperfect labour market. This approach was applied to

estimate labour supply of the household when off-farm employment is limited

(Benjamin 1992), household and hired labour are imperfectly substituted (Deolalikar &

Vijverberg 1987, Jacoby 1992), or there is differences between female and male labour,

or between adult and child labour (Jacoby 1993, Menon et al. 2005), or farmers have

preferences towards working on- or off-farm (Lopez 1986, Skoufias 1994, Seshan

2005).

If the household does not take part in the labour market, the cost of family labour

cannot be evaluated at the market wage. And as their internal wages are unobserved, an

estimation of marginal productivity of family labour from production behaviour is

needed. Assume that there is no difference between the labour of men and women in the

household. The production function for the composite agricultural commodity produced

by the household is specified as

),,( iVADYY (4-12)

where Y is a concave function, D is total labour work for their farm in rice cultivation,

and livestock raising, A is land area, Vi is a vector of all variable inputs. Table 4-5

presents the OLS estimates of the production function.

Page 75: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

57

Table 4-5: Household’s Production Function for Composite Agricultural

Commodity

Variables Coefficient Std. error

Log family labour days D (rice+pig+chicken production) 0.005* 0.006

Log rice cultivation cost 0.162* 0.015

Log livestock cost for feeding and veterinary 0.289* 0.005

Log other fees for farm works 0.071* 0.013

Log total areas of rice cultivation 0.314* 0.010

NE 0.031** 0.013

NW 0.100* 0.019

NCC -0.088* 0.014

SCC -0.104* 0.018

CH 0.092* 0.022

NES -0.029 0.033

MRD 0.025 0.023

Constant 5.189* 0.077

Adjusted R-squared 0.845

Number of observations 3314

*: indicates significance at 1% level, ** at 5% level of confidence

Dependent variable Y is total farm income from rice cultivation, pig and chicken raising ('000 VND)

Based on the results of Table 4-5, the shadow wage rate or agricultural marginal

product of family labour *w is derived using the following expression:

DD

Yw

ˆˆ * (4-13)

where Y denotes the fitted value of farm income derived based on the estimated

coefficients ( j ). D is total family labour and D is the estimated coefficient for

labour. In principle, it would then be possible to use this shadow wage for those

households who do not enter the labour market in the LES demand system. However, as

Page 76: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

58

noted in Chapter 3, if there is an imperfect labour market, production and consumption

decisions of the household are determined simultaneously, and hence the opportunity

cost of labour cannot be considered as exogenous to consumption decisions.

Since the shadow wage is derived from farm income, there is simultaneity among

shadow wage and agricultural production decisions. To control for that, an instrumental

variable set is used in estimation, to break the simultaneity of the shadow wage and

consumption decisions, as follows:

Table 4-6: Instrumental Variables Estimates of Shadow Wage

Variables Description Coefficient Std. error

Log(head edu) Log of head education in levels 0.045*** 0.018

Log(head age) Log of head household age in years 0.005** 0.002

Log(no mem) Log of number of member of the HH 0.035** 0.015

Log(no labour) Log of number of labour of the HH -0.127* 0.019

Exo income Household’s exogenous income (‘000VND) 0.014 0.011

Log(rice price) Log of rice price 0.154*** 0.089

Log(pig price) Log of pig price 0.173* 0.042

Log(chic price) Log of chicken price -0.152 0.122

NE + NW = 1 for North mountainous region -0.538* 0.046

Central + CH = 1 for Central region + central highland -0.352* 0.050

NES +MRD = 1 for the South 0.611* 0.176

Constant 0.767*** 0.410

Number of observations 1022

Adjusted R-squared 0.221

*: indicates significance at 1% level, ** at 5% level, *** at 10% of confidence.

Dependant variable is log of estimated shadow wage

Comparing shadow wages calculated above with those from other research gives us

similar results about estimation of wage determination in households in Vietnam.

Page 77: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

59

Table 4-7: Comparison of Ratio of Instrumental Estimated Shadow Wages to

(Local) Market Wages over Years

Regions 1993* 1998* 2004**

Northern Uplands (NE+NW) 0.20 0.15 0.12

Red River Delta 0.25 0.19 0.16

North Central Coast 0.17 0.15

South Central Coast 0.16 0.19

Central highland 0.13 0.24

0.14

South East 0.20 0.27

Mekong River Delta 0.23 0.29

0.34

*: Calculated by Seshan for dataset VLSS 1993 and VLSS 1998 (Seshan 2005)

**: Calculated from the above estimation for dataset VHLSS 2004

The low ratio of the shadow wage compared with the market wage confirms that there

are limited off-farm job employment opportunities in those households. The results also

show that in the North upland and Central regions, there is a higher labour intensity on-

farm, lower labour productivity, hence lower shadow wages in comparison with the rest

of the country.

4.2.1.2. Estimation of LES Model

Estimation of the LES provided estimates of parameters γi and βi in the demand system

of equations (4-10). As mentioned above, identifying accurate prices for each

commodity group and opportunity cost for each day of labour worked is important for

the estimation of the parameters.

Data about price, or unit value of a commodity, is derived by dividing expenditure by

quantities bought or sold. Price or opportunity cost of each labour day is defined as the

weighted average of the market wage and shadow wage dependent on the amount of

time worked on-farm and off-farm. The price of each day working off-farm is the

labour market wage that households are facing, and the price of on-farm work is defined

by shadow wages above.

Estimation of the LES proceeds under the assumption that the disturbance terms in each

equation are independent and have zero means and uniform variances. The equation of

Page 78: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

60

labour supply was omitted from the system in the estimation to avoid singularity of the

variance-covariance matrix, hence its parameter, β1, was obtained from the restriction

that the marginal budget shares add up to 1.

The estimation of the LES is difficult due to non-linearity in the coefficients γi and βi

which enter in a multiplicative form. Therefore, the technique of Seemingly Unrelated

Regression with an iterative approach is applied to overcome this difficulty. Given

initial estimates of the βi, the remaining parameters were estimated, and then the βi, re-

estimated given these results. This was continued, iteratively, until parameter estimates

converged. Table 4-8 presents parameters of the linear expenditure system for

households in four regions.

Table 4-8: Estimated Parameters of LES of Household

Commodity

group

Coefficient RRD NE+NW Central South

β1* 0.223 0.172 0.133 0.126

Labour supply 206.35

(67.70)

254.35

(93.15)

244.25

(87.09)

252.66

(25.11)

β2 0.308

(36.93)

0.321

(46.46)

0.289

(40.96)

0.294

(17.09)

Main foods

2 61.363

(42.26)

57.799

(41.37)

51.020

(40.69)

48.057

(12.81)

β3 0.334

(34.09)

0.245

(54.91)

0.268

(47.93)

0.252

(21.42)

Other foods

3 -9.07E-14

(-3.84)

3.46E-13

(8.31)

-9.38E-14

(-2.64)

-5.64E-15a

(-0.14)

β4 0.136

(21.02)

0.262

(48.14)

0.310

(48.68)

0.327

(20.75)

Industrial and

Others 4 4.024

(23.10)

-0.404

(-2.00)

-1.009

(-4.75)

-0.254a

(-0.42)

* derived from the restriction that kβ1+β2+β3+β4=1. In calculating β1, k was set at its mean value of

0.682 for RRD, 0.62 for Northern Upland, 0.608 for Central, and 0.665 for the South, with the

implication that the parameters presented in the table are for a representative household in each region.

Numbers in parentheses are t values; a: not statistical significant

Page 79: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

61

All coefficients γi and βi are statistically significant at 1 percent level, except subsistence

quantity γ4 for industrial goods and other expenditures, in the Northern upland is

significant at 5 percent level, and γ3 and γ4 in the South regions are not statistically

significant. See Appendix A4.4 for more detail. The results in Table 4-8 show all βj>0,

meaning that all broad groups of goods and expenditure are considered normal goods.

Some previous studies suggest a negative subsistence quantity indicates that the

household has no commitment for that item, or they do not consuming that item until

they reach a certain level of income (Berges & Casellas 2002, Raper et al. 2002). The

negative subsistence quantities γ4 in the Northern upland and Central region imply,

strictly, that the household has a negative consumption of these items at very low

income. The threshold level of income is estimated as 1.4 million VND/year per capita

in the Northern upland and Central regions, and only 2.59 and 5.55 percent of the

samples, respectively, have income less than this.

Table 4-9 (next page) presents the elasticities of the LES with respect to selected

variables such as prices of commodity groups, wage rate and total income, based on the

assumption that total expenditure for broad groups of commodities and leisure of the

household remains constant as prices change.

All elasticities were calculated at the arithmetic means of independent variables. This

makes the elasticities suitable for applying to a representative household in later

chapters, since all the information and characteristic of the household were built from

average numbers of households in the database.

All own-price elasticities for food, industrial commodities and other expenditures are

similar for all regions and range from -0.56 to -0.73. Due to the zero subsistence

quantity for “other food”, the own price elasticity in all regions for this group is unity.

Elasticities of other food with respect to total expenditure are greater than 1 in all

regions, therefore the other food group can be classified as a luxury. Since the LES

admits a direct estimation of the labour supply function, the elasticity of demand for

leisure was omitted, and replaced by labour supply elasticities. As expected, when the

wage rate increases all households tend to increase labour supplied.

Page 80: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

62

Table 4-9: Elasticities for LES with Respect to Selected Variables, with Total

Expenditure Assumed Exogenous

With respect to

Elasticities Food

price

Other food

price

Industrial

goods

price

Labour

wage

Expenditure

Red River Delta

Food -0.616 0.000 -0.061 -0.470 1.185

Other Food -0.412 -1.000 -0.151 -1.046 2.674

Industrial and Others -0.188 0.000 -0.567 -0.478 1.236

Labour Supply 0.147 0.000 0.050 0.575 -0.864

Northern Upland (NE+NW)

Food -0.601 0.000 -0.061 -0.260 0.871

Other Food -0.602 -1.000 -0.213 -0.789 2.761

Industrial and Others -0.194 0.000 -0.570 -0.251 0.887

Labour Supply 0.313 0.000 0.103 0.406 -1.355

Central

Food -0.575 0.000 -0.069 -0.371 1.079

Other Food -0.508 -1.000 -0.196 -0.935 2.751

Industrial and Others -0.168 0.000 -0.593 -0.305 0.907

Labour Supply 0.226 0.000 0.081 0.559 -1.102

South

Food -0.622 0.000 -0.055 -0.461 1.303

Other Food -0.425 -1.000 -0.146 -1.182 3.281

Industrial and Others -0.123 0.000 -0.735 -0.334 0.929

Labour Supply 0.179 0.000 0.054 0.973 -1.229

4.2.2. Linear Approximately - Almost Ideal Demand System (LA-AIDS) Model

In the second step of estimating the demand function and assessing the effect of

expenditure and price on demand for commodities in the main food group, initially the

AIDS model, proposed by Deaton and Muellbauer (1980) is used.

Page 81: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

63

In the AIDS model, demand is represented by the budget share of each commodity,

while prices and income are expressed in logarithms.

The functional form of the AIDS model can be expressed as follows:

iij

jijii P

Mpw )ln()ln( (4-14)

where

wi is the budget share of a given food commodity

pi is the price of commodity i

i = rice, pork, chicken, fish and prawn, vegetable, and other meats

M is a measure of household welfare, typically per capita income or per capita

expenditure for the main food group

μi is random disturbances with zero mean and constant variance

P is a translog price index, and defined by

lkk l

klk

kk pppP lnln2

1lnln *

0 (4-15)

where k is = 1, …6, l = 1,…,6, and the γij parameters are defined under symmetry as

follows:

jijiijij )(2

1 ** (4-16)

Moschini pointed out that the AIDS model automatically satisfies the aggregation

restriction, and with simple parametric restrictions, homogeneity and symmetry can be

imposed (Moschini 1998). However, the AIDS model may be difficult to estimate

because the price index is not linear in the parameters. In addition, the theory of the

household does not provide any empirically plausible value for α0. Therefore, due to its

simplicity, the Linear Approximate Almost Ideal Demand System (LA-AIDS) with the

Stone index is widely used (Asche & Wessells 1997). The Stone’s price index (P*) is

calculated as follows:

i

ii pwP )ln()ln( * (4-17)

Page 82: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

64

where wi is the budget share among the commodities, and pi is the price of each

individual commodity. The Stone index is an approximation proportional to the

translog, i.e. P=φP* where E(ln(φ))=α0. The LA-AIDS model with the Stone index is

denoted as follows:

**

* )ln()ln( iij

jijii P

Mpw (4-18)

where iiii * and )))(ln()(ln(* Eiii

Since prices are never perfectly collinear, it is widely cited that applying the Stone

index will introduce some measurement error (Moschini 1995). The Stone index does

not satisfy the fundamental property of index numbers because it varies with changes in

the units of measurement for prices. One solution is to ensure that prices are scaled by

their sample mean. Following Moschini’s suggestion, a Laspeyres price index can be

used to overcome measurement error. Specifically, the log-linear analogue of the

Laspeyres price index is obtained by replacing wi with iw , which is a mean budget

share. Hence the Laspeyres price index becomes a geometrically weighted average of

prices:

i

iiL PwP )ln()ln(

Substitution PL into the equation wi with αi *, yields a LA-AIDS model with the

Laspeyers price index as follows:

**** ))ln()(ln()ln( ijjij

jijii pwMpw (4-19)

where j

jjiii pw ))ln(( 0**

Data needed for estimating system (4-19), includes prices and expenditure share of each

individual food in the main food group, were drawn from the VHLSS 2004. With

households that do not purchase food from the market, the price or unit value is derived

by dividing total value of food consumption to consumed quantity. For households that

do not consume one particular commodity, the price of the commodity that household

may have to face, if they want to consume it, is derived from the average price at the

Page 83: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

65

commune or local level. In estimation of LA-AIDS, one equation has to be dropped

(here other meats), and the Seemingly Unrelated Regression technique was used. The

other demand equations were estimated with homogeneity and symmetry restrictions

imposed. Estimated parameters of the LA-AIDS for households with six commodities in

the main food group for four regions are in Appendix A4.3, and the estimated

elasticities derived from the LA-AIDS model are presented in Table 4-10 (next page).

The results show that all goods in the main food group are inelastic in demand, except

pork and other meat in the South region, since their own price elasticity is negative and

less than 1. These commodities are also indicated as necessary goods. In all regions,

other meat is the most sensitive to expenditure change, followed by pork, fish and

chicken, whilst the least sensitive to income are rice and vegetables18, which is

consistent with prior expectations.

18 Except vegetables in the South.

Page 84: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

66

Table 4-10: Uncompensated Elasticity of LA-AIDS Model for Main Food

Commodities

Regions With

respect

to

Rice

quantity

Pork

quantity

Chicken

quantity

Fish

quantity

Vege

quantity

Other

meat

quantity

Price -0.539 -0.565 -0.428 -0.512 -0.138 -0.591

Ppork -0.118 -0.812 -0.006 0.265 0.079 -0.154

Pchicken -0.044 -0.023 -0.550 0.058 -0.120 -0.074

Pfish -0.070 0.097 0.075 -0.879 0.002 -0.023

Pvegetable -0.019 -0.010 -0.125 -0.016 -0.666 0.000

Pother meats -0.020 -0.026 -0.024 0.014 0.041 -0.744

Red

River

Delta

Incomereal 0.810 1.339 1.059 1.069 0.801 1.586

Price -0.833 -0.078 -0.349 -0.389 -0.058 -0.166

Ppork 0.012 -0.778 -0.171 -0.033 -0.126 -0.414

Pchicken -0.054 -0.101 -0.563 0.070 0.168 -0.309

Pfish -0.018 0.007 0.077 -0.925 -0.044 -0.023

Pvegetable -0.029 -0.091 0.106 -0.107 -0.684 0.099

Pother meats 0.011 -0.083 -0.119 -0.011 0.091 -0.660

Northern

upland

(NE+NW)

Incomereal 0.913 1.124 1.019 1.395 0.652 1.473

Price -0.667 -0.232 -0.008 -0.443 -0.077 -1.204

Ppork -0.003 -0.806 -0.314 0.023 -0.139 -0.067

Pchicken 0.020 -0.131 -0.990 0.083 -0.015 -0.053

Pfish -0.074 0.017 0.217 -0.923 -0.019 0.222

Pvegetable 0.003 -0.080 -0.028 -0.023 -0.895 0.186

Pother meats -0.082 -0.009 -0.025 0.083 0.153 -0.572

Central

Incomereal 0.802 1.241 1.147 1.199 0.992 1.489

Price -0.454 -0.409 -0.186 -0.417 -0.447 -0.522

Ppork -0.059 -1.137 -0.216 0.187 0.025 0.407

Pchicken -0.007 -0.115 -0.804 -0.008 0.061 0.086

Pfish -0.144 0.184 -0.028 -0.860 0.155 -0.182

Pvegetable -0.059 -0.009 0.070 0.062 -0.882 -0.030

Pother meats -0.033 0.126 0.073 -0.030 -0.007 -1.093

South

Incomereal 0.756 1.361 1.092 1.065 1.095 1.334

Page 85: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

67

4.3. Summary

This chapter presents results of econometric models for both aspects of household

behaviour: consumption and production. The Cobb-Douglas production function form

was chosen for estimation because of its simple structure and ease of manipulation. The

derivations of inputs demand, profit function and profit-maximised output supply

equations are also presented. Results of OLS estimation for three household production

functions (rice, pig, and chicken) are presented. Hence production elasticities including

elasticities of output, labour demand and profit with respects to output and labour price

are derived.

On the consumption side, a two stage LES-LA-AIDS demand model was chosen

because it is easily derived from a direct utility function, which is needed to represent

the first objective of the household. LES is also very helpful since it assumes

consumption of a broad group of commodities, including leisure, is a linear function of

prices and disposable income. The complexity of a household’s problem in allocating

time between labour working time and leisure can also be solved by LES. With this

demand system, the quantity of commodities consumed are functions of wages, prices

of goods, household characteristics (e.g. number of labourers and dependants) and also

conditions of production, represented by total income. Appling the Seemingly Unrelated

Regression (SUREG) technique, parameters of LES were estimated, hence elasticities

were calculated with the assumption that full income is exogenous, which means the

demand side was not affected by production decisions.

In the second stage of the demand side estimation, a LA-AIDS model was applied to see

the effects of price on household consumption of each individual food in the main food

group, including pork and chicken.

In the next chapter, integrated household models for a representative household of each

region are presented. By linking the two sides (production and consumption) of the

model, the reaction of the household to a signal of price change is presented. Household

behaviour represents both production and consumption elements, including leisure and

labour supply, as part of maximising utility.

Page 86: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

68

CHAPTER 5 : VIETNAMESE HOUSEHOLD MODEL -

INTERACTION OF PRODUCTION AND CONSUMPTION

DECISIONS

In the previous chapter, econometric models were used to estimate parameters of the

functions of consumption, production and utility functions of the household. In this

chapter, a household model representing each region is constructed and the process of

calibrating the model is presented. In this process, the model's elements and

relationships are determined based on the econometric results. Since the representative

household simulation model is built based on integration of three models, some

parameter values needed to be adjusted so that the predicted values for the optimal

solution for the household model match the average observed values of the household

for the base year. Moreover, each region has its own characteristic farming system

activities, so the calibration process allows for additional information, such as the ratio

of raw and industrial feed used in raising livestock, to be incorporated into the model.

Once the model is accepted by validation, it is optimised for each policy scenario. The

whole process is calibrated in Excel, and the utility maximising response to changes in

conditions for the household is determined using Excel solver.

An important feature of the agricultural household model is the household’s responses

to policy changes in both consumption and production. By constructing the integrated

household model, this chapter illustrates changes in household behaviours to a change

in an exogenous variable consisting of both restructuring consumption patterns

attributed to expenditure and consumption substitution effects, and making production

decisions. This gives different results compared with responses of the household to

changes if the household acted only as consumers.

5.1. Calibration of the Model

Calibration and simulation of a model that represents a real world situation is difficult

given the complexity of factors involved. In this section, based on the results of the

econometric model from Chapter 4 and additional information, parameters and data in

Page 87: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

69

the base year are determined. This is an important process since it influences not only

how well the model represents a real situation, but also how useful it is in predicting

policy changes in the future.

5.1.1. The Production Model

In Chapter 4, functional form of the agricultural production function was specified with

a Cobb Douglas (CD) form.

rrrrrice VDAF 321

0

ii

ii

iiii VDGF 321

0 i = pig, chicken

In the econometric models, parameters of the production functions of rice, pig and

chicken were determined. In the calibration process, all elasticity parameters associated

with the input variables were kept, with only technology constants (α0) being adjusted

to make the observed outputs of the average household correspond to fitted output

values from the CD functions. Table 5-1 presents the adjustment of the technological

efficiency parameters in the production functions.

Table 5-1: Calibration of Neutral Technological Efficiency Parameters

In production function of RRD NE+NW Central South

Econometric model 751.48 666.82 561.54 564.27 Rice (α0r)

Calibration 738.98 751.16 566.33 622.35

Econometric model 0.98 0.98 1.08 1.25 Pig (α0p)

Calibration 1.31 1.56 1.57 1.92

Econometric model 0.78 0.82 0.91 1.21 Chicken (α0c)

Calibration 1.23 1.21 1.33 1.86

Since the prices of raw and industrial feed for pig and chicken in each household were

not available, the dependent variable for feed used in the CD is the total value rather

than quantity of feed used. This implies that prices are equal across all farms. In the

representative household model, average price indices of raw feed and industrial feed

Page 88: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

70

from the Vietnamese Institute for Market and Prices database19 are used as the prices

that households face, and the ratio of raw feed and mill feed in raising pig and chicken

from research in IFPRI are used to calculate the quantity of each kind of feed used for

livestock in the model.

Table 5-2: Ratio of Using Raw Feed/Total Feed for Pig and Chicken Raising

(percent)

Ratio of using raw

feed/total feed in

RRD NE+NW Central South

Pig production 0.94 0.95 0.92 0.36

Chicken production 0.64 0.85 0.58 0.26

Source: calculated from database of IFPRI 2001 assuming that the characteristics of the small household

in raising livestock have not changed for years.

Applying the ratio of feed used, production functions of pig and chicken can now be

derived as follows:

095.0171.0584.00 )( pigpigIpigIpigRpigRpigppig VDGpGpF

137.021.046.00 )( chickenchickenIchickenIchickenRchickenRchickencchicken VDGpGpF

where, D is labour requirement, V are variable inputs, and GR, GI are quantities of raw

and industrial feeds, and pR and pI are average price indices of raw and industrial feeds,

respectively. In the simulations, the proportion of raw and industrial feed in total feed is

constant.

5.1.2. The Consumption Model

On the consumption side, all parameters from the estimated econometric demand

functions are used in the household model. To estimate the demand of each food in the

19 In this study, retail prices of some main commodities are obtained from a weekly database representing markets in provinces of Vietnam constructed by the Institute for Market and Prices (under the Ministry of Finance) .

Page 89: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

71

main food group using the LA-AIDS model, the functional form20 outlined in Chapter 4

is used:

**

* )ln()ln( iij

jijii P

Mpw

The constants (αi*) need to be adjusted to let the modelled demand shares equal the

observed ones of the household in the base year. Table 5-3 presents adjustments in

constants of the LA-AIDS model for the purpose of the models’ calibrations.

Table 5-3: Calibration of Constants in LA-AIDS

Regions α*rice α*pork α*chicken α*fish α*vegetable α*othermeat

Original 1.441 -0.369 -0.043 -0.028 0.174 -0.002 RRD

Calibration 1.723 -0.368 -0.034 -0.024 0.184 -0.361

Original 0.899 -0.002 0.042 -0.145 0.276 0.206 NE+NW

Calibration 0.903 -0.006 0.041 -0.134 0.277 0.123

Original 1.331 -0.139 0.017 -0.138 0.081 -0.070 Central

Calibration 1.322 -0.134 0.016 -0.137 0.084 -0.137

Original 1.346 -0.262 0.022 0.005 -0.004 -0.112 South

Calibration 1.339 -0.254 0.025 0.000 -0.006 -0.192

5.1.3. Opportunity Cost of Each Working Day and Exogenous Income in Base

Year

As mentioned in Chapter 4, in estimation of the LES model, defining proper prices for

consumption commodities and opportunity cost of each labour day is necessary to get

appropriate parameters. For a representative household, the opportunity cost of each

labour day in the base year is defined as the weighted average of wages dependent on

time working on-farm and off-farm, and is used as base year’s labour price.

20 Where wi is the budget share of a given food; pi is the price of commodity i; M is a measure of household welfare, typically per capita income or per capita expenditure for main food group; P is the price index, μi is random disturbances.

Page 90: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

72

Note that the standard household model applies the recursive property, where the model

assumes factor markets are complete and the household is a price taker. In the model

simulations in Chapter 7, all prices including labour are considered as exogenous

variables.

As mentioned in Chapter 3, the household maximises its utility with a “full income”

constraint: wTRwLpCqM . This constraint implies total expenditure of

the household (left hand side of the equation) is not greater than total income (right

hand side). Therefore, in calibrating the model in the base year, the sum of any non-

wage, non-farm net other income (R) of the household is calculated as a subtraction

from total expenditure and net farm profit () and the value of the household’s stock of

time (wT).

For the purpose of simulating, it is assumed that the parameters defined in the base

year’s calibration remain constant over time.

5.2. The Interaction of Production and Consumption Decisions

According to the theoretical framework of an agricultural household model, the

household reacts to a change in an exogenous variable, such as the output price of a

commodity the household produces, through price and income effects on consumption

plus a change in production decisions. The change in production decisions is captured

through its influence on on-farm profits and referred to as the profit effect. Since the

model is designed to capture both consumption and production, it yields more realistic

results than an examination of each side individually. To get an indication of the

quantitative significance of the integrated model, the partial household response

elasticity is first derived under the assumption that net farm profit, П, is exogenous,

thereby ignoring the production side of the model. Then the total response elasticity of

the full model is derived by allowing profits to be determined endogenously and

incorporating the production side of the model.

The complete household model consists, on the consumption side, of the demand

functions derived from the first order conditions and the expenditure constraint (3-7).

And on the production side, of the profit function derived from the production functions

and first order profit maximising conditions. Or in terms of the estimated system, the

Page 91: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

73

complete model consists of the demand functions derived directly from the equation

system (4-10).

Totally differentiating the full system of household equations and rewriting allows the

derivation of the set of total response elasticities, giving the proportional change in any

endogenous variable, Z, in response to a proportional change in any exogenous variable,

X. The total response elasticities are written in the form of a sum of component partial

elasticities:

X

XE

E

Z

E

E

Z

Z

X

X

Z

Z

X

X

Z**)constant()variable( (5-1)

or in other notation:

XEZEZXZX ..* (5-2)

where ZX represents the elasticity obtained if farm profits are allowed to change and

*ZX is the elasticity obtained if farm profits are fixed (Barnum & Squire 1979b). This is

the price elasticity of demand. The remaining three terms on the right hand side are

expenditure elasticity of demand, profit elasticity of expenditures and the exogenous

variable elasticity of profits. Note that the profit elasticity of expenditures

E simplifies to П/E from the 'full income' constraint (3-7)

Using the elasticities calculated for production and consumption in Chapter 4, Table 5-4

presents the elasticities of the RRD household with and without the profit effect.

Table 5-4 indicates the significance of integrating production and consumption

decisions by comparing ZX and *ZX . For some commodities, when the price changes it

affects both consumption and production (rice, pig, chicken, and wage of labour). When

farm profits are assumed to remain constant, the own-price effects reduce consumption

of all commodities. For example, when farm profit is assumed to remain constant,

increases in the price of rice, pork and chicken reduce consumption of the main food

group. But when farm profit is allowed to change, the response to price is reduced. This

may be explained by the fact that farm profits increase as these prices rise, and hence

households have more profit and income to cover expenditure.

Page 92: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

74

Table 5-4: Household Response Elasticities with Farm Profit Alternatively

Exogenous and Endogenous in RRD

Elasticities with the consumption quantities/labour supply Variables

Main foods Other foods Industry and others Labour supply

P other foods 9E-17 -1 1E-16 -2.8E-17

P industrial goods -0.053 -0.109 -0.616 0.016

P main foods -0.645 -0.323 -0.180 0.049

P rice *ZX -0.656 -0.329 -0.183 0.049

ZX -0.264 0.476 0.264 -0.072

P pork *ZX -0.675 -0.338 -0.188 0.051

ZX -0.502 0.016 0.009 -0.002

P chicken *ZX -0.657 -0.329 -0.183 0.049

ZX -0.568 -0.147 -0.082 0.022

Labour wage *ZX -0.606 -1.243 -0.691 0.337

ZX 0.832 1.706 0.948 -0.106

Note: *ZX elasticity with exogenous farm profit, ZX elasticity with endogenous farm profit

At the same time, labour supply responds positively to increases in exogenous prices of

commodities. This may be due to increased prices reducing household purchasing

power and forces the household to sell more labour to cover expenditure. The last row

of Table 5-4 shows that an increase in wage results in an increase in consumption of all

foods, industrial commodities and leisure. These changes can be interpreted as more

household income due to wage increases resulting in increased consumption.

For commodities where price changes affect both consumption and production such as

rice, pork, chicken and wage, of the 16 pairs of elasticities shown in Table 5-4, 10 pairs

differ with respect to sign. Once again, this emphasises the need for assessing the

effects of exogenous variables to behaviours of the household in a single model, with

the integration of production and consumption decisions for more accurate results. The

response elasticities of the households in other regions are reported in Appendices A5.1,

A5.2, A5.3.

Page 93: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

75

5.3. Summary

This chapter presents the process of constructing and calibrating representative

household models for each region. All parameters used in the model are taken from the

results of the econometric model in the previous chapter. In addition, some information

defined private characteristics in livestock production of households in each region are

used in the calibration.

By integrating two sides of the model - consumption and production - the response of

households to changes in exogenous variables through standard price and income

effects, and in production reactions, rather than changes in household behaviours of

consumption or production individually is also presented.

The models21 constructed here are considered representative of typical households for

each region, assuming that all households in the region have similar characteristics and

respond to a given change in the same way. A model for each region is constructed for

the base year. The model includes 2 elements: production of rice, pig, and chicken by

the household is represented by Cobb Douglas production functions; and consumption

by the household, represented by three categories:the main food group (which includes

rice, pork, chicken, beef, fish and shrimp, and vegetable), other food group, and

industrial group. the two sides of the model are linked together by a utility function.

Following any impact from the outside, such as price fluctuations, the household would

react by changing both production and consumption activities. On the production side:

the household will choose production level of outputs, and labour supply so that the

household maximises benefit. The benefit from agricultural production plus exogenous

income, known as total income of the household will be used to maximise utility of the

household via consumption of commodities.

In the next chapter, trade liberalisation scenarios and a global trade model will be

examined. Linking the trade and household models allows for analysis of how

households will be affected by changes in trade scenarios.

21 The structure of the model and detail of the model in equation form with the coefficients for each regions are presented in the Appendix A5.4

Page 94: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

76

CHAPTER 6 : VIETNAM’S TRADE LIBERALISATION

AND SIMULATION MODEL

As part of the Doi Moi (renovation) restructuring process, Vietnam has started to

integrate into the world economy. Since then, a series of trade reforms in various forms

of unilateral, bilateral, regional and multilateral liberalisation have occurred. In its

integration process, Vietnam negotiated and signed with more than 100 trade partners.

Among them, a trade agreement with the European Union (EU) was signed in 1992, an

agreement to become an official member of the Association of South East Asia Nations

(ASEAN) in 1995 and a joint ASEAN Free Trade Area (AFTA) in 1996. In 2000

Vietnam entered into a bilateral trade agreement (BTA) with the USA. Becoming the

150th member of the World Trade Organisation (WTO) on 11th January 2007 is an

important milestone in the long process of efforts of Vietnam to integrate into

international markets (Nguyen 2004, Abbott et al. 2007).

Each time a major agreement was reached, Vietnam’s trade with that region expanded,

and these trade agreements were clearly an impetus to ongoing domestic economic

reforms in Vietnam to become a more open economy in the process of integration into

the global economy. Implementation of multilateral and bilateral trade agreements is

likely to provide benefits for the economy and increase welfare for society.

In order to investigate the implications of trade liberalisation on Vietnam, this chapter

applies a multi-country general equilibrium trade model using the Global Trade

Analysis Project (GTAP). Since the final objective of this study is to examine impacts

of trade liberalisation on small livestock households raising pig and chicken, separating

live pig and live chicken from the aggregate livestock sectors in GTAP database is

needed. This is achieved using SplitCom software, a necessary tool for splitting GTAP

commodities into homogeneous and differentiated sub-groups. Scenario simulations of

trade liberalisations are also presented.

Page 95: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

77

6.1. Brief of Vietnam’s Trade Liberalisation Process and Commitments

In 1992 the ASEAN Free Trade Area (AFTA) was established in Singapore with

common targets of improving regional trade of ASEAN, absorbing foreign investment

through setting up one single market, and facilitating ASEAN countries to adapt to

increasingly changing international conditions, especially enhancing regional and

international trade negotiations. The major legal framework for the establishment of

AFTA is the Agreement on Common Effective Preferential Tariff (CEPT) which has

objectives of reducing tariffs and removing all non-tariff barriers. Officially

participating in ASEAN in 1995, Vietnam committed to reduce tariffs according to

CEPT, with the main commitment to reduce import tariffs to 0–5 percent for a wide

range of product groups (Vo 2005):

(a) The Inclusion List (IL) comprises products subject to immediate tariff reduction

ranging from 0–5 percent by 2006 (by 2003 for other ASEAN countries); those

products are neither sensitive nor require high levels of protection, and account for

about 96 percent of total tariff lines in Vietnam;

(b) The Temporary Exclusion List (TEL) comprises those items temporarily not subject

to immediate tariff reduction at the beginning, transferred gradually to the IL; and

(c) The Sensitive List (SL) comprises 89 unprocessed items of agricultural products,

such as eggs, vegetables, rice, prepared meat, sugar, etc. Tariff reduction for these

items, with the final rates ranging from 0–5 percent, started on 1 January 2004, to be

completed by 1 January 2013, except for sugar by 2010.

It also required the elimination of non-tariff barriers22 for most products originating

from other ASEAN members by 2006. However, AFTA allows member countries to

exclude some commodities from tariff reduction under CEPT in order to protect

national security, social morality, human lives and health. The commodities are put in a

group named General Exclusion List (GEL), with a requirement that these items are

also categorised as an exception under the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade

22 According to the CEPT Agreement, non-tariff barriers that create quantitative restrictions on imports need to be removed after the tariff imposed on these imported products are reduced to less than 20 percent. Other non-tariff barriers applied to those products need to be removed within the next 5 years, but in any case not later than 2006.

Page 96: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

78

(GATT) and other international commitments. Other items are excluded for different

reasons, such as guiding the consumers (tobacco and alcoholic drink), market control

(petroleum) or protection (un-manufactured tobacco), etc.

Since 2003 when CEPT/AFTA entered its final implementation phase. ASEAN leaders

decided to prioritise 11 sectors to speed up regional integration. Vietnam is actively

involved in some sectors including agriculture, fishery, textile, electronics, wood based

products and tourism (Vu & Nguyen 2005). In accordance with the program, in 2010 all

these sectors shall be liberalised for free flow of trade and investment throughout the

region. Beyond that target, these industries will become fully integrated both in terms of

trade, investment and technical aspects.

ASEAN agreed to expand the regional trade border by negotiating with other trade

partners. In November 2002, a new stage of cooperation between China in the post-

WTO accession era and dynamic ASEAN economies started by signing a framework

agreement on comprehensive economic cooperation between ASEAN and China. The

major goal of the agreement is to create an ASEAN-China Free Trade Area (ACFTA) in

2010, with the exception of Cambodia, Lao, Myanmar and Vietnam (CLMV) who will

join in 2015. The main content of the tariff negotiations under ACFTA covers: Early

Harvest Program (EHP), General Exclusion List (GEL), Sensitive List (SL) and Normal

List (NL). In particular, the EHP concerns all products in Chapters from 1 to 8 at the 8/9

digit level (Harmonize System - HS Code) which mainly covers agricultural products

and fish. Tariff reduction is scheduled for Vietnam from 2004 to 2008 with tariff rates

needing to be gradually reduced to 0 percent by 2008. Non-tariff barriers and safeguard

measures must comply with WTO disciplines (Vu & Nguyen 2005).

ASEAN also started negotiations with India and Japan in 2003, with Korea, Australia

and New Zealand in 2004 to establish free trade areas with these partners. ASEAN and

Japan agreed on the general pattern for Closer Economic Partnership (CEP) in 2012,

and 2015 for CLMV. However, unlike the ASEAN-China model of negotiation and

liberalisation commitment, this agreement is based on a bilateral Economic Partnership

Agreement (EPA) between Japan and each individual ASEAN country. Since then,

Japan has had five official talks with five ASEAN dialogue partners on EPA including

Thailand, the Philippines, Malaysia, Indonesia and Singapore. For the rest of ASEAN,

Page 97: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

79

Japan has had limited consultations. ASEAN also started trade talks with Korea

covering three areas for liberalisation, namely trade in goods, trade in services and

investment. In 2004, the parties agreed on the objective to liberalise 80 percent of tariff

lines by 2009 (Vu & Nguyen 2005). Although these free trade agreements are still in the

process of being negotiated, and the scope of commitments have not yet been

determined fully, dialogues between ASEAN with other trade partners in the Pacific

Asia region are moving forward to the target of full liberalisation.

Simultaneously while taking part in the regional free trade agreements, Vietnam

negotiated and signed bilateral trade agreements (BTA) with other partners. The textile

trade agreement with the European Community in 1992 constituted one of its first trade

deals with a Western partner. The cooperation was followed by a broader cooperation

agreement in 1995, which granted Vietnam most favoured nation treatment in its trade

relations with the EU. The negotiation continued in 2004, when Vietnam was

negotiating to join the World Trade Organisation (WTO). With an agreement on market

access signed in December 2004, the European Union lifted all quantitative restrictions

for Vietnamese textiles. In return, Vietnam agreed to open its market further in a

number of areas of interest to the EU (Vo 2005).

After many rounds of negotiation, on 13 July 2000, Vietnam and the USA officially

signed a bilateral trade agreement, towards trade normalisation. The agreement was the

most comprehensive agreement ever signed by either Vietnam or the USA. The

agreement was prepared on the basis of WTO principles and regulations, especially

those relating to intellectual property and services trade23. In terms of trading goods,

USA committed to reduce the average rate of import tariffs on Vietnamese goods from

40 percent to 3 percent. In turn, Vietnam would also reduce import tariff rates on

agricultural and industrial products from the United States within two to seven years,

gradually removing all non-tariff measures, according to WTO standards. Clauses on

intellectual property and service trade were negotiated in BTA, based on the principles

and regulations under the WTO legal framework (Vo 2005).

23 The Agreement contains 63 articles and 14 appendixes with seven chapters, namely, (I) Trade in Goods; (II) Intellectual Property Rights; (III) Trade in Services; (IV) Development of Investment Relation; (V) Business Facilitation; (VI) Transparency-Related Provisions and Right to Appeal; and (VII) General Articles.

Page 98: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

80

At the time of joining ASEAN in 1995, Vietnam formally began its WTO accession

talks. In 12 years of negotiation, Vietnam’s accession was undertaken through both

multilateral and bilateral channels. On the multilateral side, the working party

composed of 63 WTO member countries, organised dozens of meeting sessions to deal

with multilateral issues. Vietnam responded to more than 2000 questions from working

party members for transparency purposes relating to import licensing procedures,

sanitary and phytosanitary, technical trade barriers, intellectual property rights, etc

(Nguyen 2004). On the bilateral side, Vietnam negotiated with 20 countries/regions

including the USA, EU, China, Japan, India, Korea and Australia. The bilateral

negotiations mostly dealt with market access concession for goods and commitments in

the service sectors.

To be a member of WTO, Vietnam needs to conform to various WTO rules and

obligations, such as the Agreement on Agriculture24 (AoA), Sanitary and Phytosanitary

(SPS), Agreement on Technical Barriers to Trade (TBT), Agreement on Trade-Related

Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPs), and other regulations related to state

trading enterprises (STEs), etc. The purpose of implementing these agreements is to

avoid distortion of trade and production.

Becoming the 150th member of WTO in January 2007, Vietnam has committed to

comply with WTO requirements since acceding. Particularly, Vietnam accepts as

binding its ceiling import tariff at an average rate of 17.4 percent for 10 600 tariff lines,

which decrease gradually to an average rate of 13.4 percent within 5 to 7 years. The

average of the current applied rate for agricultural products of 23.5 percent would

reduce to 20.9 percent within 5 to 7 years25. Regarding non-tariff measures, Vietnam

also commits to abolish export subsidies and domestic supports, except subsidies that

do not create obstacles to trade and is allowed by WTO. At the same time, all non-tariff

measures are transformed into tariffs or, in other words, tariffication. Other

commitments on service trading, STEs, TRIPs will also be implemented (MARD 2005).

24 The purpose of the agreement is to curb the policies that have, on a global level, created distortion in agriculture production and trade. This includes three categories namely market access restrictions, domestic support and export subsidies. The main contents of AoA are converting all non-tariff-barriers (NTBs) to trade into tariff equivalents, lowering import tariffs, gradually decreasing domestic support and export subsidy. 25 While the average committed agricultural tariffs of recently acceding members is only 19.8 percent, and of China, a recent WTO member, is 15 percent.

Page 99: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

81

6.2. Trade Liberalisation in GTAP Model

6.2.1. Previous studies on Vietnam trade liberalisation

The previous section dealt with the process of trade liberalisation of Vietnam. It was

believed that joining multilateral and bilateral trade agreements would bring substantial

benefits to the Vietnam economy, by increasing efficient investment, technology

progress, and the ability to access cheaper and better quality goods and services.

However, it may affect the sensitive and infant sectors of the economy, since they have

to face fierce competition from foreign firms. To quantify the total effects to the

economy and stake holders in trade liberalisation, people often apply computable

general equilibrium (CGE) models.

There are number of such studies that assess the economy wide effects of Vietnam’s

trade liberalisation. Nguyen Chan and Tran Kim Dung (2001) used a CGE model to

evaluate the impact of trade liberalization for Vietnam as a small open/ price-taking

economy. By categorizing 97 sectors identified in the 1996 Vietnam I/O table into 33

production sectors (17 for domestic sale and 16 for export), the authors analysed the

effects of trade and tariff reforms on export.

Pham Lan Huong (2000) used a CGE model to study the effect of trade liberalization on

Vietnam’s economy. She found that removing tariffs eventually lead to a depreciation

of VND, which means an increase in competitiveness. Improvement in the

competitiveness will translate into an expansion in exports and consequently increased

output in the economy. She also estimated that under the context of tariff removal and

trade reforms, aggregate employment is expanded. And because of expansion of

employment, i.e. an increase in the demand for labour, household nominal income

increases although it may differ among household groups (Pham 2000).

Using a multi-sector, dynamic applied general equilibrium model and the Initial Offer

by Vietnam, Roland-Holst et al (2002) presented a set of assessments of the long-term

economic effects of Vietnam’s accession to the WTO. The study indicated that, while

WTO accession is essential to economic development and fuller participation in the

global economy, it is only a partial step towards realizing Vietnam’s economic

potential. They calibrated five different scenarios for Vietnam’s economy during the

Page 100: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

82

period 2000-2020. The first scenario calibrates the Vietnam’s economy for this period

based upon the Business as Usual trends for productivity growth. This scenario is

viewed as the baseline for the dynamic counterfactuals of five different types. The other

four scenarios include the country joining the WTO and conforming to its commitments

but the domestic economy is not reformed; the country joins the WTO and implements

the agreed offers; the country signs the BTA with the US; and the capital market is

liberalized (Holst et al. 2002).

Another CGE model of trade, GTAP, which involves basic accounting relations that

track the value flows through the global data base, has been used with some previous

applications to Vietnam.

In 2001, Le Quoc Phuong used the GTAP to assess the economic impacts of the process

of Vietnam’s integration. Based on the arguments that Vietnam is integrating into the

world economy at different level, Phuong proposes four scenarios for his assessments.

These scenarios include: Vietnam’s unilateral integration; Vietnam joining AFTA;

Vietnam’s following the requirements of APEC; and global liberal trade. He found that

economic integration does have positive impacts on the Vietnam’s economy (Le 2001).

Nguyen Tien Dung and Misuo Ezaki (2005) link a global CGE model with a GTAP

2001 I-O database with a focus on international relations. The model includes 10

industries and 11 countries or regions. They found that regional economic integration

generally has positive economic impacts. The integration is not only welfare enhancing,

but also leads to a less unequal income-distribution. The research also predict that

household consumption and income rise significantly as a consequence of liberalization,

and the poor and rural groups benefit more than the rich. Moreover, the removal of

tariffs in trading partners provides Vietnam with greater market access, and exports rise

in all simulations (Nguyen & Ezaki 2005).

In 2005, Dimaranan et al. used GTAP to analyse liberalisation of tariffs and textile

export quotas. Dimaranan used the same GTAP I-O data as Nguyen and Ezaki (2005),

but aggregated into 22 sectors and 12 regions, and the research focused on industries

rather than households. (Dimaranan et al. 2005).

Page 101: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

83

Recently, David Vanzetti and Pham Lan Huong (2006) provide the most recent CGE

impact assessment of the WTO accession on the Vietnamese economy. Six scenarios

are simulated in the GTAP 6 model: Unilateral, bilateral, harmonized, bilateral,

regional, multilateral liberalization, and free trade. Similar to Dimaranan et al. (2005),

they predict only limited gains in the agriculture and resource sectors, but large effects

on the textiles and apparel sectors. All scenarios, with the exception of harmonization,

lead to an increase in exports. The largest sectoral effects are in textiles and apparel. In

other sectors, chemicals show large percentage gains from a relatively low base. Growth

in these sectors pulls resources out of agriculture, and exports fall in several agricultural

sectors. The model also predicts that Vietnam can obtain most of the potential gains

from trade reform from unilateral liberalization (Vanzetti & Pham 2006).

To assess the impact of trade liberalisation on the livestock sector in Vietnam, Nin et al.

(2003) use a micro/macro approach that combines the GTAP general equilibrium model

with a simple micro model to measure expected impacts of trade liberalization on a

representative sample of Vietnam’s livestock producers. The results show that the

impact of trade liberalization on Vietnam’s livestock production tends to be small but in

general a more open Vietnamese economy would result in a deterioration of the trade

balance of livestock products. In spite of this, trade liberalization would benefit poor

livestock producers by increasing livestock prices relative to production costs, in

particular feed costs, and by increasing non-agricultural income (Nin et al. 2003).

Apart from using a CGE model, which provides a framework for economy-wide

analyses, and taking into account existing relations among the different sectors, factor

markets, households and the government, some researchers take a partial approach in

analysing impacts of trade liberalisation to specific sectors. It ignores feedback links

among markets and activities and relies instead on in-depth knowledge of specific

sectors and the economic actors who participate in them. There have been a number of

studies following this approach, including research on the impact of trade liberalisation

on some sectors such as rice (Oxfam 2001) or livestock in Vietnam (AusAid 2004).

Page 102: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

84

6.2.2. GTAP database

In this research, GTAP, with its focus on worldwide trade policy is used, as it takes

advantage of the CGE model structure, in that it offers a consistent economy-wide

framework for analyse trade policies. The purpose is to analyse trade liberalisations,

both bilateral and multilateral trade agreements between Vietnam and other countries.

Since the latest version and most recent database include data for Vietnam, the

Vietnamese economy with all its factor and activity flows is represented in the model.

GTAP was initially developed in 1992 at Purdue University in the USA. It is a standard

Computable General Equilibrium (CGE) model based on the neoclassical theory of firm

and household behaviour assuming perfect competition, rational and utility optimising

behaviour. It is designed to be a multi-region, general equilibrium model with bilateral

trade flows between all regions and linkages between economies and between sectors

within an economy. The model uses the Armington approach where products are

differentiated by origin and assumed to substitute imperfectly for one another forming a

composite import aggregate that substitutes imperfectly for domestically produced

goods. Primary factors (land, unskilled labour, skilled labour, capital and natural

resources) are substitutable but are used as a composite in fixed proportions to

intermediate inputs (Hertel & Tsigas 1997).

Simulations are undertaken using the GTAP version 6.2 database, released in November

2003. The database has 96 countries and regions, 57 sectors, and includes tariffs, export

subsidies and taxes, subsidies on outputs and inputs such as capital, labour and land that

represented the world economy in 2001 (Dimaranan 2006). It is possible within the

GTAP model to define the required level of aggregation. For this study, in the

region/country aggregation, the objective is to split the ASEAN countries as much as

possible to distinguish the economic effects of trade liberalisation and highlight

important regional economic relations. Other important trade partners of Vietnam, such

as the USA, Japan, China, Korea, and Australia are detailed. Meanwhile, countries with

similar economic conditions such as European countries, or some developed countries

are aggregated together. African and Latin American countries are also grouped

together, since Vietnam has quite limited trade with them. Table 6-1 presents the final

aggregation for 20 countries and regions from the GTAP database for this study.

Page 103: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

85

Table 6-1: GTAP Regional Concordance

No New region Old countries/regions

1 USA United States of America

2 EU25 (European Union 25)

Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, United Kingdom, Greece, Ireland, Italy, Luxembourg, Netherlands, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, Cyprus, Czech Republic, Hungary, Malta, Poland, Slovakia, Slovenia, Estonia, Latvia, Lithuania

3 JPN Japan

4 CHN China, Hong Kong

5 VNM Vietnam

6 IDN Indonesia

7 MYS Malaysia

8 PHL Philippines

9 THA Thailand

10 KOR Korea

11 IND India

12 XEA (Rest of East Asia)

Taiwan, Rest of East Asia

13 XSE (Rest of South East Asia)

Cambodia, Singapore, Rest of Southeast Asia

14 XSA (Rest of South Asia)

Bangladesh, Pakistan, Sri Lanka, Rest of South Asia

15 AUS Australia

16 ODV (Other developed countries)

New Zealand, Canada, Rest of North America, Switzerland, Rest of EFTA

17 LAM (Latin America)

Mexico, Bolivia, Colombia, Ecuador, Peru, Venezuela, Argentina, Brazil, Chile, Paraguay, Uruguay, Rest of South America, Central America, Rest of Free Trade Area of Americas, Rest of the Caribbean

18 AFR (Africa) Egypt, Morocco, Tunisia, Rest of North Africa, Botswana, South Africa, Rest of South African Customs, Malawi, Mauritius, Mozambique, Tanzania, Zambia, Zimbabwe, Rest of Southern African Development Community, Madagascar, Nigeria, Senegal, Uganda, Rest of Sub-Saharan Africa

19 CEE (Central and East Europe)

Rest of Europe, Albania, Bulgaria, Croatia, Romania

20 ROW (Rest of the world)

Rest of Oceania, Russian Federation, Rest of Former Soviet Union, Turkey, Iran, Islamic Republic of, Rest of Middle East

Source: Aggregate from GTAP v 6.2

Page 104: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

86

GTAP includes 57 sectors, covering all industries and commodities of the economy.

This can be classified into three broad sectors, namely, food and agriculture,

manufactures, and services. Food and agriculture includes 20 sectors, such as rice,

vegetables, fruit, cereal, livestock and meat products, etc., which together comprise 8

percent of world sales value. The 22 manufacturing sectors contribute 31 percent, and

the high-value services sectors comprise 61 percent of world sales value (Dimaranan

2006). For the purpose of this research, these 57 sectors are firstly aggregated into 18

commodity groups, with 7 in agricultural and food commodities and 11 in

manufacturing and services.

Since the study is interested in the impacts of trade liberalisation on small households

who raise pig and chicken as the main source of income, an examination of how trade

liberalisation affects the individual pig and chicken sectors at a national level is

necessary, and the impact of price changes of these two commodities to the household

production at the micro level is considered. Disaggregation of pork and poultry in the

meat products group is also needed, however separating pork and poultry is too

complicated since the required data on bilateral trade is not available in some countries,

so they remain aggregated in one group. The software SplitCom is used to separate live

pig and poultry sectors from the livestock group used in the standard GTAP framework,

the method of which is described below.

6.2.3. Using SplitCom and Introducing New Sectors into GTAP Database

Generating new sectors for live pig and live chicken to introduce into GTAP database is

based on extracting data from the sources of UN Comtrade, International Statistics,

WITS, FAOStat, and SAMs of countries, and using the SplitCom program, developed

by Mark Horridge, Centre of Policy Studies (Monash University) in 2005. The process

takes the following steps:

Step 1: Aggregating 18 sectors and 20 regions/countries from 57 individual sectors and

96 countries of GTAP version 6.2. The sectoral aggregation attempts to split sectors

with significant protection, such as textiles and apparel, manufactures, and electronics,

while grouping some sectors with similar characteristics in production and approximate

protection level together. In the initial aggregation, of the 11 sectors belonging to

Page 105: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

87

manufacturing and services, four are process sectors that provide inputs from

agriculture.

Step 2: Applying SplitCom to disaggregate the live animals sector into three new

sectors: live pig, live poultry and live other. The program works with three sub-folders:

Input, Work, and Output. The original GTAP database and its associated files

(basedata.har, default.prn, and sets.har) are copied into an input folder. The files

SplitSec.har and UserWgt.har are created automatically by SplitCom, once the

commands of creating new split and new database are set up. However, in the primary

action, SplitCom weights the three new commodities equally, and the user needs to

supply the desired weights by adding new headers26 TWGT, RWGT, CWGT, and

XWGT to the userwgt.har file. To do this, data on bilateral trade between

countries/regions in 2001 are taken from UN Comtrade, International Statistics, and

WITS. Data on production and consumption of pig, chicken and other animals comes

from FAOStat, and Social Accounting Matrices (SAMs) of various countries27; and

assumptions are made that some countries with similar economic conditions have

similar production activity. Hence, SplitCom is used with updated userwgt.har file to

get the final split. Finally, the new expanded GTAP database is stored in the Output

folder of the SplitCom, ready for loading to run the GTAP model.

The database is now disaggregated into 20 commodity groups (Table 6-2).

26 These headers are found in the file named nuweght.har in the work folder of the SplitCom. These headers are originally designed to introduce user weights for sales, costs, self uses and trade data into SplitCom. 27 SAMs of countries are used from source of International Food Policy Research Institute (IFPRI)

Page 106: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

88

Table 6-2: GTAP Sectoral Concordance

No New sector Old sectors

1 RIC (Paddy and processed rice) Paddy rice; Processed rice

2 VF (Vegetable and fruit) Vegetables, fruit, nuts

3 OCR (Other crops) Wheat; Cereal grains nec; Sugar cane, sugar beet; Plant-based fibres; Crops nec; Sugar

4 LivePig

5 LivePoultry

6 LiveOther

Live pig, poultry, cattle, sheep, goats, horses; Animal products nec; Wool, silk-worm cocoons

7 OMT (Pork, poultry, other meats) Meat products nec

8 CMT (Beef and sheep meats) Meat: cattle, sheep, goats, horses

9 FSH (Fishing) Fishing

10 OSO (Oilseed and vegetable oil) Oil seeds; Vegetable oils and fats

11 OFD (Processed food) Food products nec

12 B_T (Beverages and tobacco) Beverages and tobacco products

13 MLK (Milk and dairy products) Raw milk; Dairy products

14 RES (Natural res, petroleum product)

Forestry; Coal; Oil; Gas; Minerals nec; Petroleum, coal products

15 CRP (Chemicals, rubber, plastic) Chemicals, rubber and plastic products

16 TXT (Textile and apparel) Textiles; Wearing apparel; Leather products

17 MAN (Manufactures) Wood products; Paper products, publishing; Mineral products nec; Ferrous metals; Metals nec; Metal products; Motor vehicles and parts; Transport equipment nec; Machinery and equipment nec; Manufactures nec

18 ELE (Electronic) Electronic equipment

19 TCN (Transport, communication) Transport nec; Sea transport; Air transport; Communication

20 SVC (Services) Electricity; Gas manufacture, distribution; Water; Construction; Trade; Financial services nec; Insurance; Business services nec; Recreation and other services; PubAdmin/Defence/Health/Educat; Dwellings

Source: aggregate from GTAP v 6.2 and disaggregate new sectors using SplitCom

Page 107: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

89

6.2.4. Trade Scenarios of Trade Liberalisation Simulation

In this study, several scenarios are explored using the GTAP model:

(1) Unilateral Vietnam trade liberalisation; Vietnam completely removes all of its trade

taxes.

(2) Vietnam and all other ASEAN countries fully eliminate all tariff and subsidies, and

apply a free trade area in ASEAN. The trade barriers among other countries stay the

same.

(3) Extension of AFTA by expanding free trade area to include Japan, Korea and China.

In this scenario, China is a competitor of many ASEAN economies, with its large, low-

cost labour force, and it may have some impacts for adjustment in the economies of

ASEAN in general and Vietnam in particular.

Bilateral trade agreements are relatively easy to negotiate but are of limited value if the

two economies are similar. For developing countries, agreements with large developed

countries were generally considered the most beneficial. Two agreement options were

investigated:

(4) Between Vietnam and the USA

(5) Between Vietnam and EU.

The reasons for choosing USA and EU is that both are large economies; the USA has

the potential to export maize and soybean to Vietnam which may affect the livestock

sector, and both USA and EU are large trade partners of Vietnam in apparel and textile

trading, which can absorb more labour from rural areas once they have opportunity to

develop.

Multilateral liberalisation refers to a potential WTO agreement. To simplify the analysis

the sixth scenario is:

(6) A 50 percent reduction in tariffs, exports subsidies and domestic support for all

regions.

Page 108: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

90

(7) Full global liberalisation, without any trade barriers among countries that indicate

the potential gains from trade liberalisation and the opportunity cost of not liberalising

fully.

Even though the simulations in these scenarios do not fully describe real trade

liberalisation, they help to provide a closer representation of prospects that Vietnam has

to face in the near future, when all regulations of the agreements are confirmed.

Table 6-3: Alternative Trade Scenarios28

Scenarios Title Change in tariffs

(1) Unilateral Vietnam unilateral trade

liberalisation

VNM exempts 100% of import tax

for all countries

(2) AFTA Free trade area in ASEAN ASEAN countries exempt 100%

import tax to each others

(3) AFTA+3 Free trade area in ASEAN

plus China, Japan and Korea

ASEAN countries and JPN, KOR,

CHN exempt 100% import tax to

each others

(4) VNM-USA Bilateral trade between VNM

and USA

VNM and USA exempt 100% on

trade between two countries

(5) VNM-EU Bilateral trade between VNM

and EU

VNM and EU25 exempt 100% on

trade between two regions

(6) Multilateral Multilateral trade

liberalisation

All countries exempt 50% of import

tax to the others

(7) Global Free trade over the world No import tax over the world

6.3. Simulations with Different Modifications of GTAP Closures

The simulation model is based on the GTAP database version 6.2, aggregated into 20

regions and 20 commodities, with all macroeconomic, trade and protection data

referring to the common reference year of 2001, which is the most updated version at

the time of this study. The standard model is a comparative static model. Therefore, if

28 Implementing the detail and complexity of actual trade policy within a model requires a number of simplifying assumptions to be made i.e. rules of origin introduce considerable complexity, and representation of details of tariff schedules. However, the representation of trade policy used here is deemed sufficient to give an insight into the overall impact of liberalization.

Page 109: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

91

all markets in the multi-region model are balanced (market-clearing condition), all firms

earn zero profit (zero-profit condition) and all households are on their budget constraint

line, then global savings must equal global investment and with this Walras’ Law is

satisfied. It implies that equilibrium is obtained for a system of n equations if n-1

equations are solved (Hertel & Tsigas 1997). When an exogenous shock is introduced,

the model works out a new equilibrium in all markets and determines new values for the

endogenous variables (Francois et al. 2003). The default solution method for the GTAP

model is Gragg’s method where the model is solved several times with an increasingly

fine grid until convergence is achieved.

Due to the introduction of new sectors of live pig, live poultry and other live animals to

the GTAP database, import tariffs for these commodities need to be adjusted to align

with the real situation. The changes to the tariffs contained in the database were

implemented as a 'pre-experiment' using 'Alter tax'29. Then, the updated post-simulation

database is used as a starting point for our subsequent policy experiments. Table 6-4

presents outputs and trade data of sectors of Vietnam in base year.

One of the questions that often arises when using a comparative static model is how to

“close” the model. Since the study tries to link a trade GTAP model at macro level with

a household model at a micro level, where labour allocation and wages are important

factors affecting welfare and behaviour of the household, the labour issue is especially

considered.

In the GTAP model, relating to labour market closure, the two most common

alternatives involve either assuming flexible wages and full employment or fixed real

wages and unemployment. However, GTAP also gives users a wide range of closure

options. In this study, the GTAP model is applied with some different closures for the

labour market.

29 Altertax runs a simulation that shocks tax rates to their desired value. It uses a special closure and a special parameter file to ensure that the rate-changing simulation leaves other cost and sales shares as little changed as possible.

Page 110: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

92

Table 6-4: Vietnam’s Output and Trade Flows, 2001 (mill. USD)

Sector Output Export Import

Paddy and processed rice 6467 374 17

Vegetable and fruit 1902 257 71

Other crops 1541 810 225

Live Pig 881 2 5

LivePoultry 434 0 7

LiveOther 545 62 29

Pork, poultry, and other meats 168 33 20

Beef and sheep meats 22 0 7

Fishing 1541 49 6

Oilseed and vegetable oil 93 45 90

Processed food 2895 1365 374

Beverages and tobacco 1222 22 395

Milk and dairy products 241 2 239

Natural res, petroleum product 3703 2346 1692

Chemical, rubber, plastic 2938 495 2796

Textile and apparel 7994 4746 1848

Manufactures 10203 2313 6780

Electronic 528 446 1002

Transport, communication 2143 534 2546

Services 26763 1552 6997

Total 72223 15453 25145

Source: GTAP v.6.2

The first implication of the factor market clearing conditions (Closure A), an

assumption of an archetypal free market model is specified, with full employment and

Page 111: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

93

full factor mobility in all factor markets. This is the standard closure, which is often

applied in the GTAP model.

Since there is an acknowledgement of unemployment in the world, the presumption of

full employment in all economies is questionable. The second alternative assumption on

the labour market (Closure B), in which excess supplies of unskilled labour in

developing countries exist, but other factors are still fully mobilised, is made. When

there is unemployment, the real wage is held constant and the supply of unskilled labour

adjusts following a policy shock.

The different assumptions on the employment situation will result in different values for

employment, wages, and prices, and thus different final welfare results, an assumption

on the level of unemployment needs to be considered if possible. The Closure C is made

based on an assumption that there is an unemployment situation that exists in Vietnam,

but the unskilled labour supply is not unlimited, and at some point real wages rise.

In the next section, the implications of alternative labour market clearing conditions are

investigated and the results of trade liberalisation scenarios presented.

6.3.1 Closure A - Standard GTAP Closure

Closure A is often used in simulations of the GTAP model. In the standard process,

prices, quantities of all non-endowment commodities, and regional incomes are

endogenous variables, conversely, policy variables, technical change variables, and

population are exogenous variables to the model.

In this closure, labour supply in all markets is fixed exogenously and, according to the

profit-maximising behaviour of the productive sector, labour demand is determined.

Since the fundamental property of a neoclassical general equilibrium model is the

concept of flow equilibrium in product and factor markets, labour demand is derived

endogenously as a function of output price and the wage, and is equalised to labour

supply. This is a fundamental requirement for market clearing. In the labour market the

variable responsible for equilibrating is the average wage rate which varies in order to

achieve economy-wide full employment. In that context, the labour market in Vietnam

can be illustrated as in Figure 6-1. The economy-wide supply of labour is fixed at L*.

Assume that there is a policy shock, which makes the demand for labour increase from

Page 112: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

94

D1 to D2, hence the equilibrium in the labour market will move from L1 to L2, and the

price of labour will increase from P1 to P2.

Figure 6-1: Labour Market under GTAP Standard Closure - Closure A

The results of the GTAP simulations are presented in broad categories, such as

production, price, trade, and welfare effects, etc. Table 6-5 provides an overview of the

output effects of the various scenarios with simulations under Closure A.

Significant adjustments in production are observed following trade liberalisation. In

most scenarios, rice, pig and poultry outputs increase, or at least stay the same30.

Textile, electronic, and service sectors experience positive production effects31.

Meanwhile, manufacturing, meats and processed food sectors reduce production. Of

interest is the difference in the impacts of Unilateral and Regional or Multilateral

scenarios on production. In the Unilateral scenario there is no expansion in export

markets, as countries other than Vietnam do not reduce their tariffs. Most sectors

contract. With liberalisation in AFTA there is an increase in Vietnamese production of

oilseeds (OSO) whereas EU liberalisation led to an increase in Vietnamese production

of livestock. This contributes to a limited flow of labour into electronics and services.

30 Except paddy sector in Unilateral scenario, and live pig and live poultry in AFTA. 31 Except case of Electronic under the VNM-EU scenario.

D2

D1

L1

L2

S PL

QL

P2

P1

0 L*

Page 113: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

95

Table 6-5: Initial Values (mill.USD) and Percentage Changes in Vietnamese Outputs under Alternative GTAP Scenarios* with Closure A

Sector Initial output

Unilateral

(1)

AFTA

(2)

AFTA+3 (3)

VNM-USA (4)

VNM-EU (5)

Multilateral (6)

Global

(7)

Paddy and processed rice 6467 -2 6 6 0 0 1 4

Vegetable and fruit 1902 -3 -2 -3 -1 -1 -1 -3

Other crops 1541 -5 -6 -14 -1 -6 -9 -18

Live Pig 881 0 -1 1 0 2 2 3

Live Poultry 434 0 -1 0 0 2 1 2

Live Other 545 -3 -3 -6 0 -2 -3 -6

Pork, poultry, other meats 168 -13 -10 -21 -1 -9 -10 -27

Beef and sheep meats 22 -6 -1 -6 -2 0 -3 -10

Fishing 1541 -2 -1 -2 0 -1 -1 -4

Oilseed and vegetable oil 93 -17 37 27 -2 -9 -7 -6

Processed food 2895 -6 -1 -10 -1 -5 -8 -18

Beverages and tobacco 1222 -22 -18 -20 0 0 -9 -21

Milk and dairy products 241 -26 -5 -6 -1 -4 -12 -24

Natural res, petrol product 3703 -5 -1 -8 -1 -4 -4 -10

Chemical, rubber, plastic 2938 -10 -4 28 -1 -7 0 14

Textile and apparel 7994 32 1 12 6 27 19 42

Manufactures 10203 -17 0 -18 -2 -8 -10 -24

Electronic 528 41 19 22 0 -6 11 19

Transport, communication 2143 -1 -1 -5 -1 -5 -2 -6

Services 26763 4 1 3 0 1 2 3

Source: GTAP simulations; * Definition of trade liberalisation scenarios in all following tables and figures are as stated in Table 6-3 above.

Page 114: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

96

A more obvious effect on Vietnam of trade liberalisation is the change in trade flows.

Two sectors with a positive change in production, textiles and electronics, also show an

increase in exports in all scenarios. These sectors are export oriented. Textile exports

are 60 percent of production and electronics 85 percent. As with output, the increase in

trade is greatest with unilateral liberalisation. Trade increases are driven by domestic

reforms rather than improved market access. In the livestock sector, initial trade in pigs

and poultry is minimal. Unilateral liberalisation generates increases in exports of

livestock but the other scenarios do not, even though livestock production increases in

all scenarios. This implies that other countries source their supplies from elsewhere as a

result of lower costs of production in response to tariff changes (see Appendix A6.1 for

more detailed information about changes in exports across scenarios in Closure A).

In the model closure used here there is no requirement for an individual country that

import value must equate to export value. Any increase in trade deficit would be

accommodated by capital inflows. The removal of tariffs leads, as expected, to

significant increases in imports (see Appendix A6.2). The most notable exception is

livestock, where the initial tariffs are quite low, 5 percent for pigs and poultry. In this

sector, imports exceed exports. There is a big increase in processed meat consumption,

but much of this includes the “LiveOther” category. There is significant variation across

the scenarios, with the AFTA+3 and the globalisation scenario most important. This

shows the importance of China, on Vietnam’s doorstep.

Due to taxes and subsidies, there are different prices on different market levels, which

are called “price wedges” (Daude 2004). These tax instruments drive a wedge between

prices of producer, trader and consumer. When policy scenarios are implemented in

GTAP, new prices and quantities are calculated, through the inter-relationship between

supply and demand, to ensure the model is in equilibrium. For the purpose of analysing

the impacts of these policies on the households, the resulting price changes for

commodities and production factors are used in the simulation analysis of the household

model in the next chapter. Table 6-6 presents price changes of some commodities and

factors in Vietnam’s market through scenarios with Closure A. Details of price changes

for consumption commodities are in Appendix A6.3.

Page 115: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

97

Table 6-6: Price Changes in the Vietnamese Market under Alternative GTAP

Scenarios with Closure A (percentage)

Factors/

Commodities

Uni-lateral

(1)

AFTA

(2)

AFTA +3

(3)

VNM-USA (4)

VNM-EU (5)

Multi-lateral

(6)

Global

(7)

Land -5.59 5.23 11.48 -0.39 1.26 1.6 6.67

Unskilled labour 9.15 3.21 13.56 1.3 6.52 7.17 17.66

Skilled labour 11.73 3.49 15.29 1.45 7.14 8.44 20.17

Capital 9.64 3.03 13 1.38 6.75 7.25 17.67

Natural Resources -14.1 -3.7 -18.95 -1.9 -9.07 -11.21 -26.88

Paddy and processed rice

1.78 3.65 9.82 0.54 3.58 3.71 9.99

Vegetable and fruit 0.41 2.4 9.39 0.22 3.22 3.37 9.18

Other crops 0.44 1.01 4.82 0.28 2.19 1.12 4.23

Live Pig -0.17 2.03 7.97 0.36 3.64 2.89 7.63

Live Poultry -3.31 2.09 7.64 0.04 2.98 2.01 5.73

Live Other 0.5 0.92 5.61 0.26 3.36 2.08 5.71

Pork, poultry, other meats

1.1 1.52 6.59 0.45 3.41 2.77 7.09

Beef and sheep meats

-2.62 0.85 3.78 -0.51 3.32 1.07 2.39

Fishing -1.71 0.01 0.79 0.53 2.65 0.03 -0.43

Oilseed and vegetable oil

-0.32 6.78 12.56 0.44 2.77 2.55 8.52

Processed food -0.36 0.66 4.11 0.42 2.95 1.47 3.81

Beverages and tobacco

-2.72 -2 0.74 0.49 2.86 0.37 1.57

Milk and dairy products

-3.56 -0.16 2.36 0.23 2.49 -0.11 0.56

Natural res, petrol product

-0.34 0.25 -0.04 0.06 0.42 0.03 0.41

Chemical, rubber, plastic

1.29 0.65 4.09 0.58 2.99 1.97 5.18

Textile and apparel -6.77 -0.38 -3.15 -0.11 1.45 -2.12 -4.2

Manufactures -1.61 -0.05 0.67 0.48 2.52 0.6 1.8

Electronic -4.61 -2.39 -2.31 0.02 0.71 -1.45 -2.56

Transport, communication

0.61 0.63 2.79 0.55 3.18 1.64 4.66

Services 2.19 0.97 4.91 0.74 3.78 2.78 7

Source: GTAP simulations

Page 116: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

98

Since the closure fixed the supply of labour as exogenous, in all scenario simulations,

wages of both unskilled and skilled labour increase, with the biggest changes at 17.66

and 20.17 percent respectively, if full globalisation happens.

6.3.2 Closure B - Non Standard Closure in Labour Market

This closure is made based on an assumption that there is significant unemployment in

developing and less developed countries such as Asia, Africa, and some of Latin

America where the unemployed account for approximately one-third of the world’s

unemployment rate (Kurzweil 2002) and poor people are always willing to work, even

at a wage level lower than the current market price. Therefore, in this closure, real

wages for unskilled labour in all those countries are fixed, and labour supply is taken to

be endogenous. Then the labour market of a developing country can be illustrated

through the following figure.

Figure 6-2: Labour Market of a Developing Country under GTAP Closure B

With this non-standard closure of labour, the real price of labour is fixed at P* and at

that wage there is unlimited labour supply. Assume that economic integration of one

country increases trade in goods or services with others. It may lead to stimulation of

production through increased exports and thus at the same time increase demand for

workers in the country from D1 to D2, hence the equilibrium in labour market moves

from L1 to L2, and labour supply increases from Q1 to Q2. This allows the unemployed

or underemployed to sell additional labour should there be demand for unskilled labour

in intensive goods and services sectors. Table 6-7 presents changes in outputs and

unskilled labour through scenario simulations under Closure B.

S

D1

D2

P*

PL

QL 0 Q1 Q2

L1 L2

Page 117: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

99

Table 6-7: Changes in the Vietnamese Outputs and Unskilled Labour under

Alternative GTAP Scenarios with Closure B (percentage)

Sector

Uni-

lateral

(1)

AFTA

(2)

AFTA

+3

(3)

VNM-

USA

(4)

VNM

-EU

(5)

Multi-

lateral

(6)

Global

(7)

Unskilled labour (%) 17.97 5.84 18.27 1.43 6.06 10.13 24.7

Paddy and processed rice 1 7 10 0 1 3 8

Vegetable and fruit -1 -2 0 0 0 0 0

Other crops -2 -5 -11 -1 -5 -7 -14

Live Pig 7 2 8 1 5 6 12

Live Poultry 6 1 6 1 4 5 10

Live Other 5 0 2 0 0 2 5

Pork, poultry, other meats -8 -8 -16 -1 -7 -7 -22

Beef and sheep meats -1 0 -2 -1 1 -1 -5

Fishing 2 1 2 0 1 1 2

Oilseed and vegetable oil -12 39 34 -1 -7 -4 1

Processed food -5 -1 -8 -1 -5 -7 -16

Beverages and tobacco -17 -16 -16 0 2 -6 -15

Milk and dairy products -17 -2 6 0 0 -5 -11

Natural res, petrol product -2 0 -5 -1 -3 -2 -6

Chemical, rubber, plastic 1 0 45 0 -3 7 35

Textile and apparel 46 4 24 7 32 26 61

Manufactures -8 3 -10 -1 -5 -5 -13

Electronic 54 23 35 0 -3 17 37

Transport, communication 6 1 2 0 -3 2 3

Services 11 3 11 1 4 6 14

Source: GTAP simulations

Page 118: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

100

The tendency for production adjustments in all simulations of trade liberalisation under

Closure B are similar to that under Closure A. Rice and livestock sectors increase in

most simulations. Two export-oriented sectors - textiles and electronics - also increase

production under alternative scenarios. However, absolute change values of simulations

under Closure B are larger in comparison with those under Closure A. The changes in

trade balance are detailed in the Appendix A6.4. Trade surplus only happens for rice,

textile and electronic sectors; meanwhile, due to the reduction of taxes, the trade deficit

happens in almost all other sectors. Changes in market prices are reported in Table 6-8.

Table 6-8: Price Changes in the Vietnamese Market under the Alternative GTAP

Scenarios with Closure B (percentage)

Factors/ Commodities Uni-

lateral

(1)

AFTA

(2)

AFTA

+3

(3)

VNM-

USA

(4)

VNM

-EU

(5)

Multi-

lateral

(6)

Global

(7)

Land 6 9.36 24.97 0.61 5.62 8.81 24.6

Unskilled labour -3.5 -1.03 0.29 0.24 2 -0.23 -0.01

Skilled labour 14.32 4.5 18.17 1.71 8.21 10.07 23.9

Capital 13.01 4.25 16.7 1.68 8.04 9.27 22.6

Natural Resources 2.64 2.25 -1.15 -0.47 -3 -0.47 -2.99

Paddy and processed

rice

1 3.43 9.2 0.49 3.37 3.34 9.2

Vegetable and fruit 0.81 2.62 10.19 0.27 3.47 3.79 10.3

Other crops 0.16 0.94 4.6 0.27 2.13 1 3.9

Live Pig 1.57 2.71 10.34 0.52 4.39 4.12 10.8

Live Poultry 4.35 4.83 16.72 0.7 5.92 6.85 17.9

Live Other -4.02 -0.57 0.94 -0.11 1.78 -0.52 -0.48

Pork, poultry, other

meats

0.7 1.48 6.53 0.44 3.37 2.7 7.01

Beef and sheep meats -1.58 1.27 5.21 -0.41 3.78 1.82 4.31

Fishing 2.56 1.51 5.54 0.9 4.29 2.67 5.56

Page 119: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

101

Table 6-8: Price Changes in the Vietnamese Market under the Alternative GTAP

Scenarios with Closure B (percentage) - continous

Factors/ Commodities Uni-

lateral

(1)

AFTA

(2)

AFTA

+3

(3)

VNM-

USA

(4)

VNM

-EU

(5)

Multi-

lateral

(6)

Global

(7)

Oilseed and vegetable

oil

-1.38 6.5 11.66 0.37 2.44 2.02 7.27

Processed food -0.06 0.83 4.59 0.47 3.14 1.74 4.35

Beverages and tobacco -4.4 -2.51 -0.94 0.36 2.3 -0.57 -0.72

Milk and dairy products -5.16 -0.68 0.69 0.1 1.93 -1.03 -1.63

Natural res, petrol

product

-0.39 0.32 0.01 0.06 0.43 0.26 0.8

Chemical, rubber,

plastic

-0.67 0.04 2.09 0.43 2.34 0.89 2.49

Textile and apparel -8 -0.8 -4.42 -0.21 1.02 -2.84 -5.9

Manufactures -2.98 -0.47 -0.72 0.38 2.07 -0.16 -0.08

Electronic -5.62 -2.74 -3.4 -0.06 0.38 -2.05 -4.05

Transport,

communication

-0.81 0.25 1.42 0.46 2.75 0.95 2.81

Services 0.16 0.36 2.86 0.59 3.14 1.67 4.18

Source: GTAP simulations

In all scenarios, live pig and live poultry show increased market prices and, as a result

of splitting the sectors, the increases are different between pig and poultry. Comparing

changes in wages of unskilled labour under alternative scenarios with application to

Closures A and B, the simulation results are significantly different. Labour wage

increases fastest under Closure A, where labour supply is fixed, and is almost

unchanged, or slightly fluctuates around zero, under Closure B. These changes in wages

may seem counterintuitive, since the closure fixes real wage as exogenous and makes

labour supply endogenous. However, note that this applies to real prices and wages. In

the simulation, real wages are maintained, but nominal wages may change as other

Page 120: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

102

prices in the system alter, and this is reflected in the above results. Changes in prices of

consumption commodities are shown in Table 6-9.

Table 6-9: Price Changes of Consumption Commodities under Alternative GTAP

Scenarios with Closure B (percentage)

Commodities Uni-lateral

(1)

AFTA

(2)

AFTA +3 (3)

VNM-USA (4)

VNM-EU (5)

Multi-lateral

(6)

Global

(7)

Paddy and processed rice 0.98 3.43 9.17 0.49 3.37 3.33 9.17

Vegetable and fruit -0.19 2.35 9.15 -0.01 3.35 3.24 8.96

Other crops -2.78 -0.52 2.04 0.07 1.5 -0.31 0.5

Live Pig 1.56 2.7 10.29 0.52 4.37 4.09 10.8

Live Poultry 4.26 4.75 16.55 0.69 5.84 6.76 17.7

Live Other -3.89 -0.63 0.57 -0.11 1.6 -0.67 -0.91

Pork, poultry, other meats -2.12 -0.41 3.64 0.1 2.3 1.24 2.23

Beef and sheep meats -1.6 1.26 5.19 -0.42 3.78 1.81 4.27

Fishing 2.5 1.5 5.5 0.87 4.27 2.64 5.48

Oilseed and vegetable oil -14.9 -13.42 -12.72 -0.04 0.57 -6.3 -14.0

Processed food -6.17 -0.92 0.81 -0.14 1.35 -1.68 -3.73

Beverages and tobacco -23.26 -18.25 -20.27 0.04 0.74 -9.63 -21.2

Milk and dairy products -11.33 -1.68 -1.09 -0.4 0.7 -4.07 -8.34

Natural res, petrol product -7.19 -1.09 -6.79 -0.24 -0.15 -3.26 -6.8

Chemical, rubber, plastic -3.15 -0.83 -0.71 0.13 0.72 -1.04 -1.88

Textile and apparel -15.13 -1.8 -10.82 -0.84 -0.55 -6.62 -14.5

Manufactures -8.56 -1.9 -6.66 0.13 0.81 -3.1 -7.04

Electronic -8.53 -4.65 -6.58 -0.47 -1.29 -4.03 -8.46

Transport, communication -0.25 0.1 0.32 0.14 0.82 0.18 0.59

Services 0.11 0.27 2.01 0.43 2.26 1.15 2.85

Source: GTAP simulations

Page 121: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

103

6.3.3 Closure C - Modified Non-Standard Closure

In Closure C the wage of unskilled labour in all developing countries, except Vietnam,

is fixed. It is assumed that there is a limit on the maximum increase in unskilled labour

in Vietnam of R percent. If a trade liberalisation scenario results in a simulated increase

in labour of R percent, then the increase in labour is fixed at R percent and wages rise to

get the market in equilibrium. The reason for doing so is based on an assumption that

there is an unemployment situation in Vietnam and the unemployed are willing to work

at the current wage level, however, the number cannot increase over the total number of

unemployed of the society. Hence, the market for unskilled labour in Vietnam is

illustrated in Figure 6-3.

Figure 6-3: Unskilled Labour Market in Vietnam under Closure C

When labour demand is lower than Q1(1+R%), equilibrium of the labour market is at L1,

where Q1 unskilled labour is willing to work at wage level P*, as is the case for Closure

B. Labour would agree to work at the current market price until labour supply reaches

Q1(1+R%), after which, if demand for labour increases the new equilibrium on the

market would be L2, where the new wage is P2, higher than the current wage.

6.3.3.1. Estimation of R

Applying Closure B, fixing wages of unskilled labour in all developing countries, and

allowing labour demand in Vietnam to increase in all scenario simulations led to a

maximum increase in demand of approximately 25 percent, if global liberalisation

QL

D2

D1

L1

L2

P*

P2

PL

Q1(1+R%) 0

S

Q1

Page 122: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

104

happens (Table 6-7). However, the issue is whether or not society can supply that much

labour at the current wage.

Statistics from Vietnam’s General Statistics Office show that in 200132, the

unemployment rate in Vietnam’s urban areas was 6.28 percent, and under-employment

in the rural areas was 25.74 percent (GSO 2008). However, to move to complete full

employment is impossible. “Full employment” has come to mean an unemployment rate

close to 6 percent; it would be difficult to reduce unemployment below this rate, even in

a highly developed economy (Baumol & Blinder 1988). Based on that argument, with

about 64 percent of the population working in rural areas (2001), increases in the labour

force supplied to the economy is about 12 percent33 at the current wage. Assuming that

the ideal solution is that about 12 percent of the population can find a job (limitations of

information accession, transportation, skill, etc., are no obstacle). With that assumption,

Closure C now fixes the maximum increase in labour supply of Vietnam at 12 percent.

When the demand for labour increases over that level, wages would increase since the

elasticity of labour supply is perfectly inelastic (Figure 6-3).

In this study, a rate of 12 percent more than the baseline labour supply is chosen as the

upper limit of the change in unskilled labour supply (R) in Vietnam at the current wage.

This means scenarios (1) (3) and (7) above need to be resolved using Closure C, as all

have increases in labour exceeding 12 percent (see Table 6-7). With closure C, fixing

the potential increase in unskilled labour supply in Vietnam at 112 percent compared to

the baseline, and allowing the wage of labour to vary34, changes in market prices under

trade scenario simulations are found in Table 6-10.

Scenarios (1), (3) and (7) have market wage increases of 0.31, 4.44, and 8.23 percent

respectively, corresponding with increases in labour demand over 12 percent in the

three scenarios with Closure B (see Table 6-7).

32 The study is based on reports of unemployment and underemployment in year 2001 to match with the economy situation of the base year in the GTAP model. 33 Assume that unemployment rate cannot go lower than 6 percent and unemployed people are prepared to work at the current wage level, the maximum labour can absorb into labour market = 100% - %labour in work - 6% limited = 0.64* (25.74% - 6%) + 0.36*(6.28% - 6%) = 12.73%. 34 For other developing countries and LDCs, wages of unskilled labour are fixed, as in Closure B

Page 123: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

105

Table 6-10: Percentage Changes in Vietnamese Market Prices under Alternative

GTAP Scenarios with Closure C (R=12%)

Factors/ Commodities Uni-

lateral

(1)

AFTA

(2)

AFTA

+3

(3)

VNM-

USA

(4)

VNM-

EU

(5)

Multi-

lateral

(6)

Global

(7)

Land 2.26 9.36 20.5 0.61 5.62 8.81 15.7

Unskilled labour 0.31 -1.03 4.44 0.24 2 -0.23 8.23

Skilled labour 13.54 4.5 17.3 1.71 8.21 10.07 22.2

Capital 11.97 4.25 15.54 1.68 8.04 9.27 20.2

Natural Resources -2.88 2.25 -7.09 -0.47 -3 -0.47 -14.3

Paddy and processed rice 1.23 3.43 9.39 0.49 3.37 3.34 9.54

Vegetable and fruit 0.63 2.62 9.89 0.27 3.47 3.79 9.69

Other crops 0.22 0.94 4.65 0.27 2.13 1 4.01

Live Pig 0.95 2.71 9.5 0.52 4.39 4.12 9.14

Live Poultry 1.84 4.83 13.66 0.7 5.92 6.85 11.8

Live Other -2.67 -0.57 2.4 -0.11 1.78 -0.52 2.41

Pork, poultry, other meats 0.78 1.48 6.51 0.44 3.37 2.7 6.96

Beef and sheep meats -1.94 1.27 4.72 -0.41 3.78 1.82 3.31

Fishing 1.06 1.51 3.84 0.9 4.29 2.67 2.36

Oilseed and vegetable oil -1.06 6.5 11.97 0.37 2.44 2.02 7.9

Processed food -0.19 0.83 4.4 0.47 3.14 1.74 4.02

Beverages and tobacco -3.87 -2.51 -0.39 0.36 2.3 -0.57 0.38

Milk and dairy products -4.66 -0.68 1.23 0.1 1.93 -1.03 -0.59

Natural res, petrol product -0.38 0.32 0.02 0.06 0.43 0.26 0.84

Chemical, rubber, plastic -0.04 0.04 2.75 0.43 2.34 0.89 3.82

Textile and apparel -7.61 -0.8 -4 -0.21 1.02 -2.84 -5.07

Manufactures -2.54 -0.47 -0.26 0.38 2.07 -0.16 0.86

Electronic -5.3 -2.74 -3.06 -0.06 0.38 -2.05 -3.36

Transport, communication -0.34 0.25 1.91 0.46 2.75 0.95 3.81

Services 0.81 0.36 3.56 0.59 3.14 1.67 5.58

Source: GTAP simulations

Page 124: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

106

Market prices of agricultural products under alternative scenarios have similar change

tendencies between application of Closures B and C. Prices of rice, live pig and live

chicken all increase under scenario simulations with both Closure B and C. This may be

an incentive for households to produce more. However, there is little difference in

absolute change values between the two closures. The price of rice increases more, but

live pig and chicken increase less in Closure C under scenarios (1), (3), and (7)

compared with the change levels in Closure B. This is attributed to changes in labour

supply in the economy. Market price changes in scenarios (2), (4), (5), and (6) under

Closure C have the same results as with Closure B, due to the constraints on increases in

unskilled labour demand is not being binding, with predicted increases lower than 12

percent.

Table 6-11 presents changes in the price of consumption commodities that have a direct

impact on consumption behaviour of the household. Compared with Closure B (Table

6-9), Closure C has similar changes in consumption prices (Table 6-11). However,

under scenarios (1), (3), and (7), consumers face slightly higher prices for rice

consumption, but less change for pork, chicken meat and beef.

Other results for changes in the output and trade of Vietnam at the macro level with

Closure C are reported in Appendices A6.6 - A6.8.

Page 125: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

107

Table 6-11: Percentage Change in Consumption Commodity Price under

Alternative GTAP Scenarios with Closure C (R=12%)

Commodities Uni-

lateral

(1)

AFTA

(2)

AFTA

+3

(3)

VNM-

USA

(4)

VNM

-EU

(5)

Multi-

lateral

(6)

Global

(7)

Paddy and processed rice 1.21 3.43 9.36 0.49 3.37 3.33 9.51

Vegetable and fruit -0.36 2.35 8.86 -0.01 3.35 3.24 8.35

Other crops -2.74 -0.52 2.08 0.07 1.5 -0.31 0.57

Live Pig 0.94 2.7 9.46 0.52 4.37 4.09 9.09

Live Poultry 1.78 4.75 13.54 0.69 5.84 6.76 11.6

Live Other -2.67 -0.63 1.88 -0.11 1.6 -0.67 1.66

Pork, poultry, other meats -2.06 -0.41 3.62 0.1 2.3 1.24 2.19

Beef and sheep meats -1.96 1.26 4.7 -0.42 3.78 1.81 3.28

Fishing 1 1.5 3.81 0.87 4.27 2.64 2.31

Oilseed and vegetable oil -14.85 -13.42 -12.68 -0.04 0.57 -6.3 -13.9

Processed food -6.26 -0.92 0.68 -0.14 1.35 -1.68 -3.95

Beverages and tobacco -23.01 -18.25 -20 0.04 0.74 -9.63 -20.7

Milk and dairy products -11.15 -1.68 -0.86 -0.4 0.7 -4.07 -7.98

Natural res, petrol product -7.2 -1.09 -6.79 -0.24 -0.15 -3.26 -6.8

Chemical, rubber, plastic -2.89 -0.83 -0.43 0.13 0.72 -1.04 -1.37

Textile and apparel -14.95 -1.8 -10.63 -0.84 -0.55 -6.62 -14.1

Manufactures -8.34 -1.9 -6.43 0.13 0.81 -3.1 -6.59

Electronic -8.51 -4.65 -6.56 -0.47 -1.29 -4.03 -8.43

Transport, communication -0.11 0.1 0.47 0.14 0.82 0.18 0.88

Services 0.59 0.27 2.5 0.43 2.26 1.15 3.84

Source: GTAP simulations

Page 126: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

108

6.3.4 Alternative Labour Assumptions and Real Wages

An interesting finding is the difference in the simulated changes in real wages for the

seven trade scenarios, using different assumptions about the possible expansion in

labour supply. In order to graphically present these differences, the GTAP model was

run with different closures based on the different levels of unskilled labour supply in

Vietnam (with the value of R% varying over 0, 8, 12 percent, to unlimited supply in

Closure B). Note that these are real wages, that is, the market wage deflated by the

consumer price index (CPI), and hence changes at a 12 percent change in unskilled

labour are different to changes in market wage reported in Table 6-10. The assumption

within GTAP under Closure C is that it is the real wage that remains constant.

0

4

8

12

16

20

0 4 8 12 16 20 24 28Maximum possible increase in labour supply (%)

perc

enta

ge c

hang

e of

rea

l wag

e co

mpa

re

with

bas

elin

e

Uni AFTA AFTA+3 VNM-USA VNM-EU Multi Glob

Figure 6-4: Changes in Real Wages under Scenario Simulations with Different Possible

Maximum Labour Supplies

Source: GTAP simulations

If there is zero expansion in possible labour (equivalent to Closure A) then Figure 6-4

shows increases in real wages ranging from 1.02 to 16.89 percent. If there are potential

increases in labour supply then the change in real wages fall but remains positive as

long as the labour constraint is binding (Closure C). Once the maximum possible labour

increase exceeds the increase in labour demand induced by a liberalisation scenario,

then the constraint is not binding, and real wages do not change (Closure B). The figure

shows the maximum change in labour supply at the point of transition from Closure C

to B for each scenario. At the maximum level of labour change used in this study (12

Page 127: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

109

percent) only scenarios (1), (3) and (7) hit the constraint and have increased real wages.

One advantage of the figure is that it identifies the simulated increase in real wages for

any level of labour constraint, for each scenario.

6.3.5 Changes of Vietnam’s Welfare under Alternative Closures

The results of the GTAP simulations are presented in some broad categories. The

previous section presented changes in production, price, and trade of Vietnam through

scenario simulations under alternative closures. Another important indicator is the

welfare effect of trade liberalisation on the country at the macro level. In the GTAP

model, the welfare indicator summarises policy changes by incorporating changes in

consumption, production, price and trade flows, and is measured using equivalent

variation35 (EV) in income.

Figure 6-5 presents the changes of Vietnam’s welfare in trade simulation scenarios

under different closures. It shows significant improvement in welfare under different

closures, but with some variations.

0

1000

2000

3000

4000

Unilateral AFTA AFTA+3 VNM-USA VNM-EU Multilateral Global

Scenarios

mil.

US

D

closure A closure B closure C

Figure 6-5: Changes in Welfare under Alternative Trade Scenarios with Different

Closures

Source: GTAP simulations

With Closures B and C, creating more jobs and improving the employment situation or

unemployment threats in specific sectors under trade liberalisation scenarios enhance 35 EV represents the money-metric equivalent to the utility change brought about by a change in prices. It measures the amount of money needed to be taken away from the consumer before the price change to leave her as well off as she would be after the change in prices.

Page 128: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

110

welfare gains of Vietnam. Different welfare changes under scenarios (1), (3) and (7)

between Closure B and C are due to the binding upper limit of unskilled labour supply.

Under scenarios (2), (4), (5), and (6), there are no differences in welfare, since demands

for unskilled labour do not reach the limiting 12 percent increase. This improvement in

welfare is attributed to a significant contribution of job creation for unskilled labourers

(Table 6-12). Further analysis of the basis for the differences in welfare is conducted in

the following chapter.

Table 6-12: Number of Jobs Created for Unskilled Labour and its Contribution to

Total Social Welfare in Vietnam under Trade Scenarios (percentage)

Number of jobs for unskilled labour

created compare with baseline

Contribution to total social

welfare

Scenarios

Closure B Closure C Closure B Closure C

Unilateral 17.97 12 20.37 13.79

AFTA 5.84 5.84 6.63 6.63

AFTA+3 18.27 12 20.76 13.78

VNM-USA 1.43 1.43 1.63 1.63

VNM-EU 6.06 6.06 6.89 6.89

Multilateral 10.13 10.13 11.5 11.5

Global 24.71 12 28.05 14.05

Source: GTAP simulations

Choosing the closure of the GTAP model has a significant effect on defining the scope

and changes of economies in general and of commodity/factor prices in particular.

However, it should be kept in mind that simulations are based on a database that

incorporates pre-existing distortions and these interact with policy shocks and produce

second-best effects. Another important point is to interpret numbers with an appropriate

attitude as certain numbers should not be taken literally, but they suggest certain

directions e.g. big returns to simulated policies (Daude 2004).

Page 129: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

111

6.4. Summary

This chapter briefly presents progress in Vietnam and its main commitments in its

integration into the world economy. Even though some negotiations are still in progress,

prospects of near future trade liberalisation and its impacts on the economy are needed.

The computable general equilibrium model has been used widely to investigate the

implications of trade liberalisation in the world, and in some sectors in Vietnam,

previously. The current research uses the multi-country trade model GTAP to assess the

impacts of trade liberalisation at the national level and to household level. Trade

agreements between Vietnam and trade partners are very complicated, with variation

between fields. Presenting all agreements in a model simulation is not possible;

however, simulation scenarios are designed to represent real situations closely.

Since the study is interested in impacts of trade liberalisation on households raising pigs

and poultry, three new sectors of live pig, poultry and other animals were introduced to

the GTAP database using SplitCom software. This means price signals of these

commodities are better captured, hence reactions in household behaviours to the

changes are expected to be measured more accurately when linking trade and household

models together.

The labour market issue in the GTAP model is also considered. Acknowledgment of the

employment and underemployment situation in the process of liberalisation has an

important role in policy simulation, especially in the case of developing countries in

general and Vietnam in particular. This helps the model to be more useful in analysing

economic impacts of policy changes, since it presents a more accurate situation of

resource allocation and use of endowments. In this study, Closure C is chosen based on

the unemployment and under employment situation in Vietnam. With this closure, the

Vietnamese labour force can increase labour supply to the economy by 1.12 times in

comparison with the baseline, without causing any wage increase. After that point,

when the demand for labour increases, wages would increase according to the normal

rules of closure.

Regarding impacts of trade liberalisation on Vietnam at the macro level, the largest

benefit would be if full liberalisation happens. The voluntary trade liberalisation of

Page 130: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

112

Vietnam in a unilateral liberalisation would benefit itself without negotiating with

others. However, market access benefits are limited because other countries do not open

their markets.

For the purpose of assessing impacts of trade liberalisation on the household, the next

chapter links GTAP results with household models to examine how small livestock

households react to price changes induced by trade liberalisation.

Page 131: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

113

CHAPTER 7 : IMPACTS OF TRADE LIBERALISATION

ON SMALL LIVESTOCK HOUSEHOLDS - LINKAGES

BETWEEN TRADE AND HOUSEHOLD MODELS

The previous chapter presented the trade liberalisation process of Vietnam and

simulated impacts at the national level using the GTAP model. In this chapter, to

examine impacts of trade liberalisation on Vietnam’s small household livestock sector,

price changes of trade scenarios from simulations of the GTAP model are linked with

the household model from Chapter 5. Changes in household welfare and responses to

price signals in terms of substitution between commodities in consumption and

production, and labour allocation in the household, are reported. However, the analysis

only examines one-way effects of trade liberalisation on households, and not their

influence on trade. Therefore, feedback from households to the international system is

not considered. Policy conclusions on opportunities and threats from trade liberalisation

for small livestock producers under alternative assumed liberalisation scenarios and

labour market conditions are also presented.

7.1. Price Changes in the Trade Scenario Simulations

The impacts of trade liberalisation on Vietnam’s welfare, production, and trade at a

national level, were reported in the previous chapter. This chapter uses price changes for

both consumption and production as a result of trade liberalisation scenarios of the

GTAP macro model to assess impacts at the household level. To determine

liberalisation effects on consumption and production, as well as reactions in labour

allocation, certain assumptions are made to align different sectors or commodities of

GTAP with those in the household model.

Changes in consumption prices (pp) from trade scenario simulations in the GTAP

model are matched with the consumption side in the household model. Consumption

commodities at the household level are more detailed than aggregated sectors in the

GTAP macro level, however commodities in both models are aggregated into groups

which can be matched as best as possible. In the main food group, rice consumption

Page 132: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

114

corresponds to the GTAP categories of processed rice and paddy rice (RIC),

consumption of fruits and vegetables are directly comparable with the fruit and

vegetable sector (VF), fish and shrimp consumption at the household level match the

fishing group (FSH), pork and chicken meat connect to OMT (pork and poultry meats)

and other meats correspond to CMT (group of beef, sheep, and other meats),

respectively in the GTAP. All other foods in the household model are summarised as

one common commodity namely “other food”, which matches various processed foods

in the GTAP model under oilseed and vegetable oil (OSO), processed food (OFD),

beverages and tobacco (B_T), and milk and dairy products (MLK). Household

consumption of all industrial commodities such as clothing, electronic equipment or

other expenditures on services, for example eating out, are grouped together to match

categories of textile and apparel (TXT), manufacture goods (MAN), electronic (ELE),

transport and communication (TCN) and services (SVC). Price changes in broad groups

such as “other food” or “industrial and other expenditures” in the household model are

therefore calculated as weighted changes in prices of corresponding commodities in the

GTAP model.

Similarly, inputs and outputs of a household’s production are suitably related to

subsumed sectors in the GTAP model. Changes in market price (pm) of commodities

from trade scenario simulations in the GTAP model are used in the household model.

For example, price changes for chemical fertiliser and pesticides for rice cultivation are

limited to average price changes of the chemical, rubber, and plastic (CRP) group in the

GTAP.

One of the main inputs of livestock production is feed. According to statistics, in

Vietnam feed often accounts for 65 to 70 percent of the total cost of raising livestock in

small households (IFPRI 2001, Lapar et al. 2003, Nguyen & Tran 2005). To

disaggregate industrial feed as an individual sector in the GTAP model is not possible,

so to estimate price changes in livestock feed due to trade liberalisation, an assumption

on feed contents is needed36. Hence, changes in the price of raw and industrial feeds for

36 Industrial feed for chicken often contains 60 percent maize, 20 percent soybean, 5 percent fish, and 15 percent other ingredients. Industrial feed for pig often includes 40 percent maize, 15 percent soybean, 7 percent meat and milled bone, 5 percent fish, 10 percent rice bran, and 23 percent other ingredients. Different kinds of feed have different ingredients; these numbers are an estimate based on author’s interview with feed livestock companies in Vietnam, in August 2007, during a CARD project (Collaboration for Agricultural and Rural Development Program) namely 'Developing a Strategy for

Page 133: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

115

raising livestock are calculated based on changes in prices of feed ingredients such as

maize, soybean, milled bone, fish and others, all subgroups in GTAP. Table 7-1

presents the aggregation and/or splitting sector/commodities available in GTAP to be

matched with those of the household model.

Table 7-1: Matching between GTAP Sectors and Endowments in this Study and

their Concordance with Commodities and Goods in Vietnam’s Household Models

In household model Matched GTAP sectors and factors

Rice, Paddy, and Seeding RIC: Paddy and processed rice

Live pig Live Pig

Live chicken Live Poultry

Chemical fertiliser and

Pesticide

CRP: Chemical, rubber, plastic

Pork and chicken meat OMT: Pork and poultry meats

Fish FSH: Fishing

Vegetable and fruit VF: Vegetable and fruit

Other meats CMT: Beef, sheep, and other meats

Other foods OSO: Oilseed and vegetable oil, OFD: Processed food,

B_T: Beverages and tobacco, MLK: Milk and dairy products

Industrial commodities

and other expenditures

TXT: Textile and apparel, MAN: Manufactures, ELE:

Electronic, TCN: Transport, communication, SVC:Services

Labour UnSkLab: Unskilled Labour

In the household model, as mentioned in Chapter 3, total land for production is assumed

to be fixed, therefore changes in land prices due to trade liberalisation are assumed to

have no effect on production behaviour of the household. Other production factors such

as capital and natural resources are also assumed to have no impact on decision making

of the household in production. In order to simplify the model, labour in the household

is categorised as unskilled and assumed to be equivalent to unskilled labour in the Enhancing the Competitiveness of Rural Small and Medium Enterprises in the Agro-Food Chain: the Case of Animal Feed' 030/06VIE. Raw feed is assumed to include 50 percent rice bran and 50 percent vegetables.

Page 134: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

116

GTAP model. In fact, this assumption is probably close to the truth: most agricultural

labour receives a low wage irrespective of education level.

7.2. Price and Wage Transmission

Four household models are constructed in this study to represent households in four

different regions: (1) Red River Delta, one of two main important deltas in the country

with favourable conditions for rice cultivation, however land cultivation is limited and

population density is the highest; (2) Northern Uplands (includes North East (NE) and

North West (NW)), where agricultural production is limited by ecological and economic

conditions; (3) the Centre, including North Central Coast, South Central Coast and

Central Highland; and (4) the South, including Mekong River Delta and North East

South, is similar to the Red River Delta, where urbanisation and industrialisation have

recently expanded very quickly. The South also has the highest commercialisation of

rice and livestock production. Different agro-ecological areas with different economic

conditions may affect the farming system and activities of the household in production

in different ways due to trade liberalisation.

Simulation results of trade liberalisation in the GTAP model only generate average

price changes of consumption commodities and production inputs/outputs at the

national level. However, it is possible that these national changes will translate into

differences in price changes of those commodities/inputs in different regions. This

section analyses differences in price transmission of some commodities/inputs between

each region from the simple average price at the national level.

Data used in this study include monthly prices of main commodities from 24 provinces

and cities in Vietnam, such as rice, paddy rice, live pig, live chicken, beef, maize,

soybean, cassava, orange, tomato and fertiliser. Data were collected by the Vietnamese

Institute for Market and Prices from 1997 to 2006 (120 observations) for all

commodities except rice, pig, beef and fertiliser which were collected from 2001 to

2004 (48 observations). The average price in the Red River Delta is calculated from five

provinces: Ninh Binh, Ha Tay, Hung Yen, Hai Duong and Ha Noi; Northern Uplands

(NE+NW) from six markets: Bac Giang, Thai Nguyen, Yen Bai, Tuyen Quang, Lai

Chau, and Son La; the Central region from six provinces: Thanh Hoa, Nghe An, Hue,

Da Nang, Quang Ngai, Dac Lac; and the South from seven markets including Dong Nai,

Page 135: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

117

Ba Ria, Binh Duong, Tien Giang, Ben Tre, Can Tho, and Ho Chi Minh city. The

average price at national level is calculated from all 24 provinces.

A simple econometric method for measuring price integration is used. The functions

take the functional forms as follows:

iiiri Pp loglog

where

Pi is average price of ith commodity at national level

rip is price of ith commodity at region r, which includes RRD, NE+NW, the Central,

and the South

i include rice, paddy rice, live pig, live chicken, beef, maize, soybean, cassava, orange,

tomato and fertiliser.

This is the simplest way to measure spatial price relationships between two markets and

the transmission coefficients, βi are interpreted as a measure of how closely price

movements of a commodity at different markets are linked (Luu 2003).

The regression results show that the coefficients βi of most commodities in the four

regions fluctuate around 1 (range 0.712 to 1.33). However, testing the result shows 28

of the 44 coefficients are not significantly different from 1 at 95 percent confidence

level. Another five coefficients are different within 10 percent between regional and

national price (see Appendix A7.1). The results also show that there is no consistent

pattern of transmission of price for any region. In order to simplify the calculation, the

study assumes that if the price of a commodity changes by 1 percent at national level,

the price at regional market level also changes approximately by 1 percent.37

A similar question arises for changes in labour wages at the regional and national levels.

Since there is no annual labour and salary survey, time series data of labour wages in

Vietnam are not available. The main information sources are surveys on Vietnam living

standards - one in 1998 (VLSS 1998) and two other recent household living standard 37 The impacts of trade liberalization at the domestic level will obviously be affected by assumptions about the degree of price transmission. However, given the relatively weak statistical evidence for deviations from unity, that is applied here. Further research on identifying more precise estimates of price transmission in Vietnam are warranted.

Page 136: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

118

surveys in 2002 and 2004 (VHLSS 2002 and 2004). Table 7-2 presents average wages

and annual growth rate of wages in the four regions.

Table 7-2: Average Wage of Labour at Current Price and Annual Growth Rate

Average wage ('000 VND) Annual growth rate of wage (%)Region

1998 2002 2004 1998–2002 2002–2004

RRD 411.58 652.96 773.70 1.122 1.089

NE+NW 367.82 642.90 728.37 1.150 1.064

Central 366.14 515.99 661.07 1.090 1.132

South 561.77 729.46 872.00 1.067 1.093

Whole country 481.07 666.97 791.79 1.085 1.090

Source: calculation based on data of VLSS1998, VHLSS 2002, and VHLSS2004

Table 7-2 shows similarities in annual growth rates of wages between each region and

national level over time. Assuming from 1998 to 2004 there were some macro policies

as well as changes in the economy that impacted on labour wage levels across the whole

country then it can be concluded that a change in labour wages will be approximately

the same in all regions of the country.

Therefore, changes in commodity prices and labour wages due to trade liberalisation

would be applied to all regional household models at the same percentage changes as

predicted by the GTAP national model.

7.3. Impacts of Trade Liberalisation on Households

Having generated price changes for trade liberalisation scenarios from the GTAP model,

and linking them to the household model, this section analyses how a household

responds to trade scenarios by changes in behaviour. Changes in commodity and factor

markets affect household welfare because adjustments are transmitted through changes

in production, consumption, and labour allocation, hence changes in utility.

Changes in prices are drawn from simulations of the GTAP model, using Closure C,

where the maximum increase in unskilled labour supply in Vietnam is fixed at 12

Page 137: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

119

percent. Hence, a trade scenario can absorb labour up to a level equal to 112 percent of

the baseline without causing a wage increase, but wage increases occur when labour

demand goes beyond that point.

In calculating welfare impacts on the household using the household model, a measure

of compensating variation (CV) in income is applied. That is, the amount of money

which, when taken away from the household after price and income changes, leaves the

household with the same utility as before the change (Varian 1996):

000101 ,, upeupeYYCV

where: Y1 is income after the price change from p0 to p1, Y0 is baseline income and

expenditure function e(p,u) is the minimum income necessary to reach the level of

utility u at given price p.

Table 7-3 summarises the change in utility (measured by compensating variation) for

each region for each scenario. The results show that the biggest changes in welfare in

three of the regions occur under scenario 7, global liberalisation, although the NE+NW

are similarly affected by both this and scenario 3, an expanded AFTA arrangement.

Table 7-3: Welfare Changes in Households in Different Regions under Alternative

Liberalisations Compare with Baseline (percentage)

Welfare

change of

household

Uni-

lateral

(1)

AFTA

(2)

AFTA

+3

(3)

VNM-

USA

(4)

VNM-

EU

(5)

Multi-

lateral

(6)

Global

(7)

RRD 6.41 4.63 13.82 0.3 -0.12 3.26 19.13

NE+NW 5.90 -0.03 12.18 -- 4.76 5.62 11.56

Central 6.11 4.22 11.86 -- 3.36 3.50 15.80

South 6.85 7.29 19.56 -- 5.06 6.78 22.31

Source: Household model simulation

-- Negligible price changes due to trade liberalisation predicted, welfare change can be considered equal

to zero

Page 138: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

120

The change in welfare of the household in the South in each scenario is always the

biggest, in (7), its welfare increases by 22 percent compared with the baseline, with a

CV of about 3 million VND.

Underlying each simulation is a large number of changes in specific commodity

production and demand. It is not possible to review, in detail, this information for all

regions, for all trade scenarios. Therefore, the South model is used as an example for a

more detailed analysis of the changes that occur in production, consumption and labour

as a result of the global liberalization. Later in the chapter, more general overviews of

the changes that occur in all regions are presented.

7.3.1. Impacts of Global Trade Liberalisation on Households in the South

On the production side, in response to increases in market output prices, the household

in the South increases agricultural production under the global trade scenario. Figure 7-

1 shows increases of about 7 and 10 percent in pig and chicken production, respectively,

compared with the base year, when live pig and chicken prices increase by 9 and 11.8

percent, respectively.

0

10

20

30

Rice Pig Chicken

quan

tity

(kg)

0%

4%

8%

12%

16%

Change in production quantity

Change in production compare w ith base year (%)

Change of output price compare w ith base year (%)

Figure 7-1: Changes in Agricultural Production of Household in the South under

Global Trade Scenario

Source: Household model simulation

Rice production, with the highest increase in quantity, has a very small increase in

percentage terms compared with the base year: 0.43 percent. This can be explained by

Page 139: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

121

the limited possibility for expansion in land for rice cultivation, and productivity of rice

production may have already reached its upper bound.

0.5

1.0

1.5

2.0

2.5

3.0

Rice Pig Chicken

Rat

io o

f ch

ange

s in

out

put

pric

es

and

inpu

t pr

ices

-4%

0%

4%

8%

12%

Out

put

chan

ges

com

pare

with

ba

selin

e

Ratio o f changes o f P output/P raw feed Ratio o f changes of P output/P industrial feed

Ratio o f changes o f P output/wage Ratio o f changes of P output/P chemical inputs

Output change compare with baseline(%)

Figure 7-2: Changes in Relative Prices of Outputs and Inputs and Changes in

Agricultural Production of Household in the South under Global Trade Scenario

Source: Household model simulation

As stated in Chapter 6, the global trade scenario creates changes in market prices of all

commodities and factors. The Figure 7-2 illustrates the reaction of household

agricultural production activities to price changes. Since an increase in output price is

faster than that of input prices, using inputs are relatively cheaper compared with the

baseline. In livestock production, inputs such as feed are cheaper in comparison with

pre-liberalisation. For rice cultivation, using both chemical fertiliser and pesticides are

also less costly in the global scenario. This indicates why the household has incentives

to expand production of rice and livestock products under the simulation.

Thanks to the expansion in agricultural production as well as increases in output prices,

under the scenario, the household in the South increases their profit for rice and

livestock production by 14 and 30 percent, respectively (Figure 7-3).

Page 140: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

122

Figure 7-3: Changes in Profit of Agricultural Production of Household in the South

under Global Trade Scenario

Source: Household model simulation

The increase in prices of all outputs and relative decrease in prices of inputs help the

household to expand agricultural production, hence increase farm profit. At the same

time, increased labour wages under the global scenario enrich the household in terms of

full income, and help cover the bigger cash expenditure they incur, and longer leisure

time.

-100

0

100

200

300

400

Food qty Other food qty Industry and others Leisure day

kg/u

nit/

day

-15%

-10%

-5%

0%

5%

10%

Ow n price effect Cross price effect

Income effect Total change in consumption

Price change compare w ith baseline (%)

Figure 7-4: Disaggregate Effects of Price and Income to Changes in Consumption of

Household in the South under Global Trade Scenario Compared with Baseline

(percentage)

Source: Household model simulation and calculation based on LES elasticities in Chapter 6

Page 141: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

123

In the simulation, prices of groups of “main food” and “industrial commodities”

increase at 5.6 and 1.4 percent, and labour wage increases by 8.23 percent compared

with the pre-simulation period. As expected, own price effects make consumption of

these groups decrease. However, due to the availability of more income from the

expansion of agricultural production and the value of farm labour, income effects

dominate and help increase consumption of all broad groups of commodity under the

scenario.

Changes in consumption due to own-prices and income effects in the “main food” group

including rice, pig, chicken meat, fish, vegetable and other meat are shown in Table 7-4.

Conforming to the theory of demand, when prices of all individual commodities

increase under the simulation, consumption of each commodity decrease by 1.43, 0.82,

0.58, 0.66, 2.44 and 1.19 kg for rice, pork, chicken, fish, vegetable and other meats,

respectively. Nevertheless, increased cash income of the household allows allocation of

more funds for “main food” group consumption. This large income effect not only

prevents reduced consumption of each commodity, but also increases total quantity of

individual commodities. This explains why the household consumes more, even though

the commodities become more expensive in the trade liberalisation scenario.

Opportunities for consuming all commodities as well as leisure, at the same time

expanding agricultural production of the farm under the scenario of global trade,

significantly increase welfare of the household by 22 percent compared with the

baseline.

Page 142: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

124

Table 7-4: Disaggregated Changes in Main Food Consumption Quantity of Household in the South due to Price and Expenditure Effects

under Global Trade Scenario (kg)

Effects of changes in price of Change in

Consumption

Quantity of

Rice

Pig

Chicken

Fish

Vegetable

Other meat

Due to

effects of

expenditure

Total change

(kg)

Rice -1.43 -0.04 -0.01 -0.11 -0.16 -0.04 6.68 4.89

Pig -1.29 -0.82 -0.08 0.14 -0.02 0.14 12.02 10.09

Chicken -0.58 -0.16 -0.58 -0.02 0.19 0.08 9.64 8.57

Fish -1.31 0.14 -0.01 -0.66 0.17 -0.03 9.40 7.7

Vegetable -1.41 0.02 0.04 0.12 -2.44 -0.01 9.67 5.99

Other meat -1.64 0.29 0.06 -0.14 -0.08 -1.19 11.79 9.09

Expenditure and price changes compared to baseline (%)

9.51

2.19

2.19

2.31

8.35

3.28

26.70

Source: calculation based on household model simulation and LA-AIDS elasticities in Chapter 6

Page 143: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

125

7.3.2. Impacts of Global Trade Liberalisation on Households in Different Regions

The following section analyses the effects of each trade scenario on households in the

regions to compare changes in welfare and different reactions of households in

production and consumption within each trade liberalisation context.

With changes in prices of agricultural inputs and outputs under the global trade

scenario, households in the four regions increase farm profit. The household in the RRD

has the largest increase of more than 30 percent followed by the Central and the South.

The household in NE+NW has a limited change of 10 percent.

-20%

-10%

0%

10%

20%

30%

40%

RRD NE+NW the Central the South

Region

chan

ge c

ompa

re w

ith b

asel

ine

Rice Pig Chicken Farm profit

Figure 7-5: Changes in Output Production and Farm Profit of Households in Different

Regions under Global Trade Scenario

Source: Household model simulation

Rice outputs only increase at limited rates in the Central and South regions while in the

other regions, households tend to reduce rice production. Almost all households expand

livestock production by about 5 to 10 percent in pig and chicken output compared with

the baseline. In the NE+NW, chicken production reduces by 12 percent compared with

the baseline, even though the household in this area is confronted with the same price

changes as households in other regions. This may be due to the different method of

chicken production, manifested by the high proportion of raw feed in total chicken feed

(85 percent). Hence, with a price change in raw feed under the simulation of about 10

percent and industrial feed of 4.7 percent, obviously the household in NE+NW faces

higher prices for chicken feed, the main input for production.

Page 144: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

126

Table 7-5: Ratio of Raw Feed and Price Change of Feed in Different Households

(percent)

RRD NE+NW Central South

Ratio of raw feed in total chicken feed 64 85 57.9 25.6

Price change of chicken feed* under

global trade scenario

6.79

8.05

6.39

5.47

Source: Household model simulation

* change in price of combination feed (based on ratio of raw and industrial feeds) in each region

With pig production, the household in the North mountainous area (NE+NW) uses a

similar technique to other households in other regions, in terms of raw feed in total

feed38. Therefore, with the same impacts of price change in all regions, households have

similar changes in production. However, since the household in the NE+NW area

restricts its rice and chicken production under the simulation, some resources are now

used to produce more pig, leading to higher total farm income. It should be noted that,

compared with other areas, the percentage increase in pig production of the NE+NW

household is quite large; however with modest output in the baseline, the absolute

change in pig output is only 46 kg. A similar situation occurs for chicken production,

with a 2.3 kg reduction in chicken production equating to approximately 12 percent of

total chicken output of the household.

On the consumption side, households in the RRD, NE+NW and the Central region have

similar reactions to the household in the South, with increased consumption in all broad

group of commodities and expenditures, even though prices of the “main food” group

and “industrial goods” are higher than the baseline. This is because of the strength of

income effects in the household. Under the simulation, the price of the “other food”

group decreases by nearly 13 percent, hence its own-price effect combined with the

income effect drives big changes in consumption of this group of commodities in all

regions.

38 The ratio of using raw feed in total feed for pig in the regions are around 92-95 percent, except the household in the South, which is more commercially oriented which, uses only 36.4 percent raw feed for pig production.

Page 145: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

127

0%

10%

20%

30%

40%

RRD NE+NW the Central the South

regionch

ange

com

pare

with

bas

elin

e

Main foods Other foods Industrial goods & others

Figure 7-6: Changes in Consumption Quantities of Households in Different Regions

under Global Trade Scenario

Source: Household model simulation

In all regions, when more funds are available to allocate for “main food” consumption,

households increase consumption particularly pork, chicken, other meats, fish and

prawn. This sounds quite sensible since small household producers are often not rich

consumers.

-4%

0%

4%

8%

12%

RRD NE+NW the Central the South

region

chan

ge c

ompa

re w

ith b

asel

ine

Rice Pork Chicken Fish-shrimp Vegetable Other meat

Figure 7-7: Changes in Main Food Consumption of Households in Different Regions

under Global Trade Scenario

Source: Household model simulation

Inside the “main food” group, meat is still considered a luxury food compared with

other foods such as rice and vegetables. The expenditure elasticities of all meats range

Page 146: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

128

from 1.1 to 1.5 in all regions, meanwhile the elasticities of rice and vegetables vary

between 0.6 to 0.8. Therefore, when income increases, expansion of rice and vegetable

consumption is quite limited compared with meat consumption. For households in

NE+NW, consumption of rice and vegetables do not increase as per the other regions

but decrease, as the income effect could not cover the negative effects of price

increases.

One factor contributing to increased welfare of households under the global trade

scenario is changes in time allocation of the household. Households in all regions chose

more leisure and less work than in the pre-simulation period.

Table 7-6: Changes in Labour Allocation of Households in Different Regions under

Global Trade Scenario Compared with Baseline (percentage)

RRD NE+NW Central South

Leisure 1.57 0.45 1.05 2.40

Labour supply -1.64 -0.35 -0.75 -1.69

Days working on-farm 3.03 84.42 3.87 3.55

Days working off-farm -2.16 -10.83 -1.25 -2.83

Source: Household model simulation

Relatively, the number of leisure days in households increase by about 1 to 3 percent.

These changes in leisure allow households to increase their utility by about 2 to 4.5

percent compared with the baseline. In order to have more leisure, households chose to

work less off-farm, while at the same time increasing work on-farm. The latter is driven

by the increased demand for farm labour, due to expansion of livestock production, as

mentioned above. For the household in the north mountainous area (NE+NW), as pig

production expanded by 27 percent, the number of days working on-farm increases by 2

man months in comparison with the baseline.

7.3.3. Impacts of Unilateral Trade Liberalisation on Households in Different

Regions

With the unilateral trade scenario, Vietnam reduces taxes for all imported commodities.

This allows Vietnam some benefit without negotiating with others, by reallocating

Page 147: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

129

resources more efficiently. Unilaterally decreasing taxes has a marginal impact on many

prices of commodities in agricultural sectors, prices of outputs and production inputs:

about 1 percent compared with the baseline. Inside households, the reallocation of

resources for a more efficient production combination also happens. The household re-

structures agricultural production on-farm to gain more farm profit. Pig and chicken

production increases in almost all regions under this scenario. In RRD, rice production

reduces slightly and livestock production increase. Expansion of all pig, chicken and

rice production occurs in households in NE+NW and the South. In the Central region,

the household slightly reduces pig production, while increasing production of rice and

chicken.

-3%

-1%

1%

3%

5%

RRD NE+NW the Central the South

region

change c

om

pare

with

base

line

Rice Pig Chicken Farm profit

Figure 7-8: Changes in Agricultural Production of Households in Different Regions

under the Unilateral Trade Scenario

Source: Household model simulation

Restructuring farm production under the scenario helps households increase farm profit,

hence have more cash income for expenditure. Table 7-7 presents changes in

consumption of the households under the simulation. Price and income effects are

negligible in household consumption of “main food” and “industrial goods”.

Meanwhile, due to the impact of the trade scenario, the price of “other food” decreases

by 15 percent compared with the baseline: this price effect, along with the income effect

helps households in all regions to increase “other food” consumption by about 20

percent.

Page 148: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

130

Table 7-7: Changes in Price and Consumption Quantity of Households in Different

Regions under the Unilateral Trade Scenario (percentage)

RRD NE+NW Central South

Change in “main food” price -0.32 0.02 0.63 1.26

Change in ”main food” quantity 1.71 1.60 1.38 1.95

Change in “other food” price -15.22 -15.22 -15.22 -15.22

Change in “other food” quantity 19.69 19.83 19.62 20.28

Change in price of “industrial and

other expenditures” group

-1.40

-1.40

-1.40

-1.40

Change in quantity of “industrial

goods and others”

1.74

3.13

3.07

3.46

Source: Household model simulation

In the main food group, rice and fish have higher prices, with all other individual

commodities having slightly lower prices, about 1 to 2 percent cheaper in comparison

with pre-simulation. Figure 7-9 shows that in all regions, households consume cheaper

commodities more and less rice and fish.

-3

-2

-1

0

1

2

3

4

RRD NE+NW the Central the South

region

chan

ge c

ompa

re w

ith b

asel

ine

(%)

Rice Pork Chicken Fish-shrimp Vegetable Other meats

Figure 7-9: Changes in Food Consumption of Households in Different Regions under

Unilateral Trade Scenario (percentage)

Source: Household model simulation

In general, by changing production and consumption behaviours, households in all

regions increase welfare under the unilateral trade scenario. Welfare of households

Page 149: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

131

increases by 6 - 7 percent due to impacts of trade liberalisation, with the value of

welfare change in terms of money ranging from 600 000 to 900 000 VND per

household per year, depending on agro-ecological areas (see Appendix A7.2a).

Apart from changes in behaviour in production and consumption, time and labour

allocation inside the households also affects changes in welfare. The NE+NW and the

South are two regions which expand farm work, at about 1 percent compared with the

baseline. In comparison, households in RRD and the Central regions reduce the number

of working days on-farm, and work more off-farm. However, the deciding factor that

makes the household better off in terms of utility is the reduction in number of days of

labour supply and increased leisure days in all regions. It should be noted that behaviour

change of the household in commodity consumption and labour supply is decided by the

assumption made in the household model. With the application of the LES, whenever

households become richer and have more income available, they consume more of both

commodities and leisure.

Table 7-8: Changes in Time Allocation of Households in Different Regions under

Unilateral Trade Scenario Compare with Baseline (percentage)

RRD NE+NW Central South

Leisure 0.20 0.41 0.26 0.46

Labour supply -0.21 -0.31 -0.19 -0.32

Days working on-farm -3.08 1.25 -2.73 1.08

Days working off-farm 0.10 -0.51 0.09 -0.63

Source: Household model simulation

7.3.4 Impacts of Regional AFTA to Households in Different Regions

Under the simulation of free trade in the ASEAN region, the price of agricultural

outputs of pig, chicken and rice all increase by 3 to 5 percent. That leads to a household

response to increase farm production in most regions. Households in RRD, the Central,

and the South show similar reactions to price changes by expanding farm production of

rice, pig and chicken. As a result, farm profit in these regions increases by 8 to 14

percent in comparison with pre-simulation.

Page 150: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

132

Table 7-9: Changes in Production Outputs and Total Farm Profit of Households in

Different Regions under AFTA Compare with Baseline (kg)

RRD NE+NW Central South

Rice output change 4.05 -107.94 16.39 35.32

Pig output change 4.99 41.02 4.24 13.33

Chicken output change 1.83 -3.95 1.82 4.47

Total farm profit change (%) 14.10 -3.48 11.66 8.25

Source: Household model simulation

Response of the household in NE+NW is similar with that under global trade

liberalisation, since the price of chicken feed becomes relatively more expensive than in

other regions, and the household reduces chicken production. The ecological conditions

for rice cultivation are not competitive in the mountainous area, which drives the

household to concentrate more resources on pig production.

-4%

2%

8%

14%

20%

RRD NE+NW the Central the South

region

chan

ge c

ompa

re w

ith b

asel

ine

Main foods Other foods Industrial goods & others

Figure 7-10: Changes in Quantity Consumption of Households in Different Regions

under AFTA in Comparison with Baseline (percentage)

Source: Household model simulation

On the consumption side, prices of the broad group of “other food” commodities, and

“industrial goods” reduce by 9.85 and 0.09 percent, respectively, under the simulation.

This leads to increased consumption of those groups in all regions. The increased level

of consumption of the “other food” group in the NE+NW is lower than other regions,

Page 151: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

133

and at the same time consumption of industrial commodities reduces by 2 percent. This

is due to decreased farm profits in the household. Under the scenario, prices of the

“main food” group (weighted prices for individual foods (rice, pork, chicken, etc.) in

each region) increase by 1.1 to 2.8 percent. However, since households in the RRD, the

Central and the South have higher profits from farm production, they spend more,

irrespective of the slight increase in prices.

Inside the “main food” group, price increases of rice, fish, vegetable and other meats

lead to a decrease in consumption quantities of those individual commodities in all

regions. However, allocation of more funds for the “main food” group expenditure of

the household in the South compared with those in other regions cause negligible

changes in consumption of rice, fish and other meats in the household. As a result of

trade liberalisation, consumption prices of both pork and chicken are reduced by 0.41

percent. These price effects, combined with increased expenditure, increase pork and

chicken consumption in the South in the simulation.

-5%

-3%

-1%

1%

3%

5%

RRD NE+NW the Central the South

region

chan

ge c

ompa

re w

ith b

asel

ine

Rice Pork Chicken Fish-shrimp Vegetable Other meats

Figure 7-11: Changes in Food Consumption of Households in Different Regions under

AFTA in Comparison with Baseline (percentage)

Source: Household model simulation

Under the AFTA simulation, the household in the South has the biggest welfare

increase of more than 7 percent compared with the baseline. The households in RRD

and the Central increase welfare by more than 4 percent, while the household in the

northern upland (NE+NW) seems unaffected by trade liberalisation in terms of total

welfare (see Appendix A.7.2b). Changes in time allocation of households’ members are

Page 152: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

134

shown in Table 7-10, with number of days of leisure increasing in all regions except

NE+NW. More labour is allocated to on-farm work, and less to off-farm work to meet

requirements from increasing agricultural production of households under the scenario.

Table 7-10: Changes in Time Allocation of Households in Different Regions under

AFTA Trade Scenario Compare with Baseline (days)

RRD NE+NW Central South

Leisure 2.45 -1.73 2.63 6.68

Days working on-farm 3.87 71.32 3.41 6.88

Days working off-farm -6.32 -69.59 -6.04 -13.56

Source: Household model simulation

7.3.5 Impacts of Expansion of the Regional AFTA (ASEAN plus China, Korea and

Japan) to Households in Different Regions

In the last chapter, results of the GTAP model showed that expansion of the regional

free trade area, ASEAN, to include China, Korea and Japan creates the second largest

increase in welfare for Vietnam in general. In the household model, the simulation also

shows that households in all regions of the country under the scenario are better off in

terms of welfare, with the biggest change in the South, where welfare of the household

is improved by 20 percent compared with the baseline. In the other three regions,

welfare increases by around 10 percent (see Appendix A7.2c).

Increases in output prices in the market of 10 to 13 percent are good incentives for

households to expand farm production. In all regions, livestock production and rice

cultivation increase, improving total farm profits of households by 20 to nearly 40

percent compared with the baseline.

With improvements in farm profits, households have more cash income available for

consumption. Consumption of all goods and commodities increases in terms of quantity

over all regions. Inside the “main food” group, due to more funds being allocated,

consumption of almost all individual foods increase under the simulation, even though

the increase in prices lead to negative effects on consumption (see Appendix A7.3a and

b for more detail).

Page 153: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

135

-10%

0%

10%

20%

30%

40%

50%

RRD NE+NW the Central the South

regionch

ange

com

pare

with

bas

elin

e

Rice Pig Chicken Farm profit

Figure 7-12: Changes in Production of Households in Different Regions under

AFTA+3

Source: Household model simulation

Expansion of farm production requires more labour on-farm. As a consequence all

households increase labour on-farm by approximately 10 percent, and decrease off-farm

days by 2 to 4 percent compared with the base, depending on region (see summary

Table 7-15).

7.3.6 Impacts of Bilateral Trade Liberalisation with the United State on

Households

Bilateral trade liberalisation between Vietnam and the United States has almost no

impact on consumption prices or output and input prices in Vietnam. Table 7-11

presents price changes under the simulation used in the optimisation of the household

model.

Facing negligible changes in prices, households in all regions except the RRD, do not

respond with changes in production and consumption. Welfare of the household in RRD

changes by only 0.3 percent (see Appendix A7.5a for more detail). As a result, further

details are not discussed here.

Page 154: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

136

Table 7-11: Changes in Prices of Consumption Commodities and Production

Inputs and Outputs in Vietnam under Bilateral Trade Liberalisation with USA

(percentage)

Production side Price

change

Consumption side Price

change

Rice and Paddy seedling 0.49 Rice 0.49

Live Pig 0.52 Pork meat 0.10

Live Chicken 0.70 Chicken meat 0.10

Raw feed for pig 0.38 Fish and prawn 0.87

Industrial feed for pig 0.40 Vegetable and fruit -0.01

Raw feed for chicken 0.38 Other meats -0.42

Industrial feed for chicken 0.35 Industrial goods and others 0.28

Chemical fertiliser and pesticides 0.43 Other food group -0.07

Unskilled labour 0.24

Source: GTAP simulation

7.3.7 Impacts of Bilateral Trade with EU and Multilateral Trade Liberalisation on

Households in Different Regions

The simulation results of these two trade liberalisations in the GTAP model show

similar trends in changes in prices of consumption commodities as well as prices of

outputs and inputs of agricultural production. Therefore, reactions of households to the

changes are similar. With higher prices of agricultural outputs under the simulations,

households have incentives to increase farm production (Figures 7-13 and 7-14).

In both optimisations, livestock production is improved in terms of quantity in all

regions. Rice production is not expanded in the household in the South under the

bilateral trade simulation, and decreases slightly in the RRD household under the

multilateral one.

Page 155: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

137

0%

5%

10%

15%

20%

RRD NE+NW the Central the Southregion

chan

ge c

ompa

re w

ith b

asel

ine

Rice Pig Chicken Farm profit

-5%

0%

5%

10%

15%

20%

RRD NE+NW the Central the South

region

chan

ge c

ompa

re w

ith b

asel

ine

Rice Pig Chicken Farm profit

Figure 7-13: Changes in Production of

Households in Different Regions under

Scenario of Bilateral Trade Liberalisation

with EU

Source: Household model simulation

Figure 7-14: Changes in Production of

Households in Different Regions under

Multilateral Trade Scenario

The same trends in consumption of households under the scenarios are also presented.

The “other food” group has the biggest increase in terms of consumption quantity. The

increase under the bilateral trade scenario is due to the positive effect of income, which

dominates over the negative own price effect39, and consumption increase under the

multilateral simulation due to a combination of income and own-price effects (Figures

7-15 and 7-16)40.

-1%

1%

3%

5%

7%

RRD NE+NW the Central the South

region

chan

ge c

ompa

re w

ith b

asel

ine

Main foods Other foods Industrial goods and others

Figure 7-15: Changes in Consumption of

Households in Different Regions under

Scenario of Bilateral Trade Liberalisation

with EU

Source: Household model simulation

0%

4%

8%

12%

16%

RRD NE+NW the Central the South

region

chan

ge c

ompa

re w

ith b

asel

ine

Main foods Other foods Industrial goods and others

Figure 7-16: Changes in Consumption of

Households in Different Regions under

Multilateral Trade Scenario

39 Under the bilateral scenario, the price of the “other food” group increase by 0.97 percent in comparison with baseline. 40 Price of the “other food” group decreases by 5.95 percent in the multilateral trade liberalisation.

Page 156: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

138

Funds allocated for the “main food” group in both scenarios increase by about 1-2

percent compared with the baseline. That is why consumption of each individual

commodity in the “main food” group increases by a maximum of 3 percent. In both

cases of liberalisation, the consumption quantity of each commodity in the “main food”

of the household in RRD reduces, since the price of each food group expenditures

increase insignificantly. This is also the case for the household in the Central region

under the multilateral scenario (Figures 7-17 and 7-18).

-2%

-1%

0%

1%

2%

3%

4%

RRD NE+NW the Central the South

region

chan

ge c

ompa

re w

ith b

asel

ine

Rice Pork Chicken Fish-shrimp Vegetable Other meats

-2%

-1%

0%

1%

2%

3%

4%

RRD NE+NW the Central the South

region

chan

ge c

ompa

re w

ith b

asel

ine

Rice Pork Chicken Fish-shrimp Vegetable Other meats

Figure 7-17: Changes in Main Food

Consumption of Households in Different

Regions under Scenario of Bilateral Trade

Liberalisation with EU

Source: Household model simulation

Figure 7-18: Changes in Main Food

Consumption of Households in Different

Regions under Multilateral Trade Scenario

The combination of reactions in production and consumption of households under the

two simulations make them better off in terms of welfare in all cases, apart from RRD

household under bilateral trade liberalisation with the European Union where there is a

small decline (see Appendices A7.2d and e)

In both scenarios, households have similar tendencies in using their time and in

allocation to work. Table 7-12 shows slight increases in leisure time. Due to the

requirements for an expansion in farm production, on-farm work of household members

increases in all regions, especially in RRD under the bilateral trade agreement, at the

same time a reduction in days worked off-farm is reported.

Page 157: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

139

Table 7-12: Changes in Time Allocation of Households in Different Regions under

Alternative Liberalisations (percentage)

RRD NE+NW Central South Changes in

compare with

baseline VNM-

EU

Multi-

lateral

VNM-

EU

Multi-

lateral

VNM-

EU

Multi-

lateral

VNM-

EU

Multi-

lateral

Leisure 0.09 0.37 1.20 1.45 0.61 0.58 1.03 1.42

Labour supply -0.09 -0.39 -0.92 -1.11 -0.43 -0.41 -0.72 -1.00

On-farm work 52.87 5.98 5.11 7.87 4.02 6.46 3.87 5.99

Off-farm work -5.96 -1.10 -1.67 -2.22 -0.92 -1.16 -1.72 -2.52

Source: Household model simulation

7.4. Impacts of Trade Scenarios, Opportunities and Threats in Each

Region

The section above analyses in detail reactions of households to price and wage changes

due to trade liberalisations. In this section, the benefits and losses indicated in each of

the scenarios simulated are presented. Opportunities and threats to households from

changes in production and consumption are mentioned. Alternative specifications of

assumptions relating to the labour markets in the global general equilibrium model,

which lead to different simulation results for welfares levels and reactions of

households under the trade liberalisations, are also discussed.

In general, the results from alternative liberalisation scenarios in all regions show that

Vietnam’s small households in the livestock sector would benefit from trade

liberalisation. Table 7-13 presents the summary of welfare changes in households under

alternative scenarios.

The largest benefit that households have is when full trade liberalisation occurs over the

world and the second largest is when ASEAN expands its regional free trade agreement

to include Japan, China and Korea. The results are slightly different in the NE+NW,

where the biggest change in welfare occurs with the AFTA+3 scenario followed by

global trade liberalisation.

Page 158: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

140

Table 7-13: Welfare Changes of Households in Different Regions under

Alternative Liberalisations Compared with Baseline (percentage)

Welfare change

of the household

Uni-

lateral

(1)

AFTA

(2)

AFTA

+3

(3)

VNM-

EU

(5)

Multi-

lateral

(6)

Global

(7)

RRD 6.41 4.63 13.82 -0.12 3.26 19.13

NE+NW 5.90 -0.03 12.18 4.76 5.62 11.56

Central 6.11 4.22 11.86 3.36 3.50 15.80

South 6.85 7.29 19.56 5.06 6.78 22.31

Source: Household model simulation

Welfare changes under VNM-USA (4) simulation were omitted since the scenario only made a negligible

change in RDD (0.3%) and had no impacts on the other regions.

The households in almost all regions do not show any response to bilateral trade

liberalisation with the United States, as it leads to very small price changes. Bilateral

trade liberalisation with the European Union also had an insignificant impact on

households in the RRD. Meanwhile liberalisation increases welfare of the other three

regions by 4.76, 3.36, and 5.06 percent in NE+NW, the Central, and the South,

respectively.

Unilateral trade liberalisation of Vietnam increases welfare in households in all regions

equally, by around 6 percent compared with the baseline. All other trade scenarios help

households in Vietnam.

On the production side, trade liberalisation scenarios increase prices of agricultural

outputs, with the biggest increases under AFTA+3 and global liberalisations. As a

result, households in all regions have a tendency to increase livestock production.

Chicken production increases in almost all scenarios with rates ranging from 5 to 10

percent over the regions. Unilateral trade liberalisation in Vietnam seems to have little

impact on changes in behaviour of households in raising chickens. Meanwhile the

expanded AFTA increases chicken output over the country. Pig production also expands

under alternative scenarios, with the rate up to 10 percent higher than the baseline. In

the NE+NW area, pig output in particular increases in the scenarios of AFTA and global

Page 159: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

141

trade liberalisation, meanwhile production of chickens and rice are narrowed (see Table

7-14).

Table 7-14: Production Changes of the Households in Different Regions under

Alternative Liberalisations Compared with Baseline (percentage)

Production Changes in

the Households

Uni-

lateral

(1)

AFTA

(2)

AFTA

+3

(3)

VNM-

EU

(5)

Multi-

lateral

(6)

Global

(7)

Rice -2.25 0.15 -0.89 2.57 -1.23 -1.71

Pig 2.11 2.96 4.27 5.44 5.42 7.19

RRD

Chicken 1.34 9.79 42.83 11.77 16.93 5.39

Rice 0.34 -3.82 1.93 1.47 2.00 -4.28

Pig 0.67 24.31 7.73 2.80 3.21 26.95

NE+NW

Chicken 1.41 -15.85 11.06 4.51 6.99 -12.80

Rice 1.93 0.76 1.19 0.72 0.54 0.87

Pig -2.26 2.73 7.00 2.71 3.17 5.51

Central

Chicken 1.84 5.92 14.95 5.39 7.81 10.11

Rice 0.18 0.59 0.73 0.03 0.38 0.43

Pig 0.64 3.84 9.57 3.96 4.36 7.00

South

Chicken 1.91 7.64 16.36 4.39 9.45 10.57

Source: Household model simulation

Benefits from expanding farm production as well as an increase in the value of working

time of households gives more cash income to purchase more goods and commodities

under all trade scenarios (see Appendix A7.6). “Other food” consumption increases

significantly every time households have more available income. Price decreases in this

group of commodities under the scenarios, especially the 10 percent reduction in

AFTA+3 and the global trade scenario, also cause increased consumption. Consumption

of “main foods” and “industrial goods” increase under trade liberalisations, albeit at

modest levels.

Page 160: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

142

For the “main foods” group, households consume more under AFTA+3 and global trade

scenarios in all regions. Pork, chicken and other meats are consumed more as soon as

households have available income. The household in the South consume more

individual foods in all scenarios, since their income effects are large enough to dominate

the opposite own-price effects. On the other hand, the RRD household reduces food

consumption in most simulations, except under scenarios of expanded AFTA and global

liberalisation (see Appendix A7.7).

Table 7-15: Changes of Time Allocation of Households in Different Regions under

Alternative Liberalisations Compared with Baseline (percentage)

Changes in Time

Allocation of

Households

Uni-

lateral

(1)

AFTA

(2)

AFTA

+3

(3)

VNM-

EU

(5)

Multi-

lateral

(6)

Global

(7)

leisure 0.11 0.09 0.75 0.05 0.20 0.82

days on-farm -3.08 0.14 10.05 52.87 5.98 3.03

RRD

days off-farm 0.10 -0.24 -2.77 -5.96 -1.10 -2.16

leisure 0.17 -0.06 0.79 0.50 0.60 0.19

days on-farm 1.25 2.52 10.12 5.11 7.87 84.42

NE+NW

days off-farm -0.51 -2.46 -2.89 -1.67 -2.22 -10.83

leisure 0.10 0.12 0.47 0.23 0.22 0.39

days on-farm -2.73 0.16 9.89 4.02 6.46 3.87

Central

days off-farm 0.09 -0.28 -2.06 -0.92 -1.16 -1.25

leisure 0.20 0.62 1.31 0.45 0.62 1.05

days on-farm 1.08 5.73 8.77 3.87 5.99 3.55

South

days off-farm -0.63 -2.47 -4.48 -1.72 -2.52 -2.83

Source: Household model simulation

One of the most important impacts of trade liberalisations on households is the way they

reallocate time between leisure, working on-farm and off-farm. With the application of

Closure C in all regions, households have a tendency to increase working days on-farm,

diminish off-farm days under trade scenarios, except the unilateral liberalisation. Labour

Page 161: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

143

allocation between on-farm and off-farm is driven by demand by of the household for

increased farm production, when market prices of agricultural outputs become higher

under the impact of trade liberalisations.

In bilateral trade between Vietnam and the European Union for the RRD, and global

trade liberalisation for NE+NW, the expansion of farm production increases days

worked on-farm by more than 50 and 80 percent, respectively, compared with the

baseline, which limits the time that household labour could be devoted to off-farm jobs.

In all trade scenarios, households chose to increase leisure time. This is attributed to

increased household income. Since the household model applies LES in defining the

household’s utility, the household would choose less work and more leisure every time

they have more available income. The change in time allocation under trade

liberalisation helps households to improve welfare, with the increase in leisure

contributing about 20 to 25 percent of total welfare gained under the scenarios (see

Appendix A7.5).

In the previous chapter, at the national level under scenario simulations, the number of

jobs for unskilled labour increased (Table 6-12). In Appendix A7.11, the change in

unskilled labour jobs in sectors at the national level is reported, showing that labour in

live pig and live poultry sectors increase under simulations compared with baseline.

However, labour in the aggregate OMT sector, which produces pork and poultry meat

decreases in all trade liberalisation scenarios. It is therefore difficult to conclude at the

national level, whether jobs created in the livestock sector increase or not. Meanwhile,

the household model reports a decrease in labour supply from small household livestock

producers, therefore the increase in labour at national level can be attributed to increases

from labour in other sectors such as rice production, textile, electronic or service sectors

(see Appendix A7.11). The increase in labour in the livestock sector at national level (if

there is any) may come from commercial households and bigger scale producers or by

joining of landless labourers.

In the GTAP model simulations, the restructure of the economy due to effects of trade

liberalisation lead to changes in supply, demand and wages in the labour market.

However, the assumption about possible labour market expansion, or in other words, the

binding labour constraint, makes the change in wages more significant in some

Page 162: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

144

scenarios. This leads to different impacts on household’s welfare under the context of

trade liberalisation. This is illustrated by the following comparison of household welfare

and behaviour in labour allocation, when households are faced with alternative labour

markets.

Table 7-16 shows the changes in wages of unskilled labour under trade scenarios with

two alternative assumptions of the labour market. In Closure A, the supply of labour is

fixed as exogenous, therefore labour wages increase when the demand for labour

increase. The assumption in Closure C is that Vietnam’s unskilled labour market has

potential to supply labour up to 112 percent compared to the baseline under trade

scenarios, without causing increased labour wages, then allowing labour wages to vary

when demand increases over that limit.

Table 7-16: Change Unskilled Labour Wage under Alternative GTAP Scenarios

with Different Assumptions of Labour Market (percentage)

Changes of

Unskilled Labour

Wages

Uni-

lateral

(1)

AFTA

(2)

AFTA

+3

(3)

VNM-

USA

(4)

VNM-

EU

(5)

Multi-

lateral

(6)

Global

(7)

Closure A 9.15 3.21 13.56 1.3 6.52 7.17 17.66

Closure C (R=12%) 0.31 -1.03 4.44 0.24 2.00 -0.23 8.23

Source: GTAP simulations

Clearly Closure A leads to higher wage levels. The differences in the changes of wages

as well as other input and output prices give different welfare changes under the trade

simulations.

Figure 7-19 presents changes in welfare of households in the South if alternative

assumptions on the labour markets are applied. Similar presentations for other regions

are in Appendix A7.10.

Page 163: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

145

0

1000

2000

3000

4000

Unilateral AFTA AFTA+3 VNM-EU Multilateral Global

scenarioch

ange

com

pare

with

bas

elin

e (0

00V

ND

)Welfare change w ith Closure C Welfare change w ith Closure A

Figure 7-19: Welfare Changes of the South Household under Alternative Scenarios

with Different Assumptions of Labour Market

Source: Household model simulation

Fixing labour supply in the economy (Closure A) lead to increased wage in all scenarios

(Table 7-16) which is partly attributed to increased welfare of the household under

Closure A compared with Closure C. An obvious source of the differences is changes in

the household’s labour allocation (Figure 7-20)

Figure 7-20: Changes in Labour Allocation of Household in the South under

Alternative Scenarios with Different Assumptions on Labour Market

Source: Household model simulations

With Closure A, household labour can earn higher wages compared with Closure C.

Since agricultural output prices are not increasing as fast, the high wage pulls labour

Page 164: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

146

from their farm. The household chooses to reduce agricultural production, and work off-

farm more for more cash income. Similar results in other regions are presented in

Appendix A7.9.

7.5. Summary

By linking the simulation results of the GTAP model with a household model, this

chapter examines how small livestock households react to changes in economic

policies, especially in the context of trade liberalisation. Analytical results allow one to

see how household behaviour changes when they are both consumers and producers,

taking into account how income changes (from profit, via production) influence

consumption to give a more accurate assessment.

Since four household models are constructed to represent four different agro-ecology

regions over the country, question remains whether or not there are differences in price

transmission between regional markets. A simple method of bivariate correlation

coefficients to measure price integration is applied, concluding that there are

approximately equal changes of prices and wages in all regions.

Regarding impacts of trade liberalisation on the household, the results from different

liberalisation scenarios run with Closure C, show that Vietnam’s small households in

the livestock sector would benefit from most trade liberalisations. The largest benefit for

households is if full trade liberalisation occurs over the world. Households do not seem

to have significant gains from bilateral trade liberalisation with the USA. Meanwhile

unilateral trade can help households increase their welfare.

On the production side, households tend to increase livestock production under trade

liberalisation scenarios, while rice production does not change much in output. Since

land expansion for cultivation is limited, productivity in rice is limited to increases in

variable inputs (given the assumption within the model that rice is the only extensive

land use).

On the consumption side, since more cash income is available under the trade scenarios,

households purchase more goods and commodities, and in particular increase

consumption of the “other food” group.

Page 165: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

147

Welfare of the household is dominated by the effect of the household’s labour decision

(working or taking leisure), rather than increases in production profit and consumption

only. Under all trade scenarios, households increase their leisure, at the same time

working more on-farm to meet requirements of labour increase due to the expansion of

agricultural production, despite increases in off-farm wages.

The comparative illustration at the end of the chapter shows the importance of the

assumption made with respect to the national labour market in the GTAP model.

Closure C in the GTAP model is chosen in this study based on the unemployment and

under employment situation in many developing countries, and Vietnam. Even though

Closure A is often used in trade liberalisation simulations, applying that closure in this

study may lead to imprecise results, since the higher wage increase under trade

liberalisations would pull them out of on-farm work, instead of expanding the

production.

Page 166: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

148

CHAPTER 8 : CONCLUSIONS

This study analysed the impacts of trade liberalisation on small livestock households in

Vietnam, using a multi-country general equilibrium model (GTAP) at the macro level,

linked with a household model at the micro level. The modelling process was

implemented in three steps:

1. Build a representative household model for each of four regions: RRD, North

mountainous area (NE+NW), Central, and South.

2. Simulate the effects of trade liberalisation scenarios on commodity and input prices,

using the GTAP model, after implementing SplitCom to disaggregate live pig and live

poultry from the general livestock group.

3. Take the simulated prices from the trade model and use them in the household model,

and optimise the household model to investigate household changes in welfare,

production and consumption, as well as in time allocation behaviours under the price

changes that the trade liberalisation scenarios imply.

8.1. Summary, Conclusions, and Policy Implications

The following summary, conclusions, and policy implications are drawn from the study:

Households involved in livestock production in Vietnam are mainly characterised by

small-scale production, not specialised in livestock activities, but raising livestock is

often considered a secondary activity combined with others such as cultivation. Small-

scale production, based on the traditional livestock husbandry method, is very popular

throughout the country. Though constrained by poor access to markets, very low scale

operations, poor access to improved genetics and high-quality forage and concentrated

feeds, and poor animal husbandry and animal nutrition, the smallholder sector supplies

the majority of meat in the market, and raising livestock is an important source of

household cash income.

Page 167: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

149

In building the model at the micro level, a recursive household model with

characteristics of a semi-commercial family farm was constructed. In undertaking this,

some assumptions were made: the household is a price-taker in all markets and all

markets exist; commodities are assumed homogeneous, including labour; the total stock

of land and labour are treated as given; issues relating to intertemporal allocation and

risk are omitted. In the model, the role of the labour market is of particular importance.

The labour market was assumed to be an active market, where family and hired labour

are perfect substitutes and face the same wage rates regardless of whether they work on-

or off-farm.

The household was assumed to produce only three agricultural commodities: rice, pigs

and chicken. They consume rice, pork, chicken in the main food group, “other foods” as

well as “industrial goods” bought through the market. For each output produced by the

household, a CD production function was estimated. Consumption decisions were

specified using the LES for demand estimation of broad groups (including leisure), and

LA-AIDS for individual commodity demand in the “main food” group. Two aspects of

production and consumption were then linked together through farm profit.

Household behaviour in consumption and production are driven by elasticities, which

are taken from estimated econometric models. The results showed livestock raising

activities are very responsive to changes in output prices. The labour demand for

livestock production was also very responsive to changes in labour wages. The results

are broadly in agreement with those from previous studies of other countries in similar

conditions. On the consumption side, elasticities from the LES showed that the “other

foods” group are classified as a luxury.

Building the household model for each representative small livestock household was the

main contribution of the study. A recursive model with both consumption and

production linked together allows a more accurate assessment of the determinants of

household consumption, since the household’s response to a change in an exogenous

variable such as a commodity price consists of both restructuring of consumption

patterns attributed to expenditure and consumption substitution effects, and making

production decisions which will influence income. Choosing the LES functional form,

which is easily derived from a direct utility function, is very helpful since it allows one

Page 168: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

150

to assess consumption demand of broad groups of commodities, including leisure, and

also help solving the complexity of problems in households allocating time between

work and leisure.

At the macro level, several scenarios for trade liberalisation in Vietnam including

unilateral, bilateral, regional, multilateral and fully global liberalisations were explored

in the GTAP model. All simulation scenarios were constructed so as to describe as

closely as possible the rules and regulations required by trade agreements for all trade

partners, including Vietnam.

One important step in applying the GTAP model was the disaggregation of livestock

into new sectors for live pig, poultry and other animals using SplitCom software. By

disaggregating the group into its different components, price signals of the separate

commodities were better captured, particularly since changes in prices of live pig and

poultry were different in all trade liberalisation scenarios, and the study was interested

in impacts of trade liberalisation on households who raise pigs and poultry.

In implementing the GTAP model, the labour market issue was also considered since it

has a very significant influence on simulated changes of social welfare and household

behaviour. In the GTAP, three different closures relating to the labour market were

explored: (1) a standard closure (Closure A) with the assumption of full employment

utilisation and full factor mobility in all factor markets; (2) in Closure B, where

unemployment exists, real wages were held constant and the supply of unskilled labour

adjusted following the policy change; and (3) in Closure C, unemployment also exists,

but the supply of unskilled labour is not unlimited. With trade liberalisations, Vietnam

can supply unskilled labour up to a maximum 112 percent compared with the baseline,

without causing any increase in wages, but if demand for labour increases beyond that

point, wages must increase to clear the market. In this study, Closure C was chosen as

the base situation, as it is believed to be a better representation of the Vietnamese

situation in resource allocation and usage of endowments. There were some sensitivity

results reported for Closures A and B, since implementing different closures in the

GTAP model showed significantly different effects in defining the scope and changes of

commodity/factor prices.

Page 169: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

151

At the national level, the results of the trade liberalisation simulations in the GTAP

model show that Vietnam can get the largest benefit if full liberalisation occurs. The

expansion of the ASEAN free trade area to include China, Korea and Japan brings the

second largest welfare increase to the society. The voluntary trade liberalisation of

Vietnam in a unilateral liberalisation would generate some benefit without the need for

negotiating with others. However, the market access benefits are limited because other

countries do not open their markets. A bilateral trade agreement with USA does not

bring much benefit to the country as a whole, but has a positive impact on the textiles

sector41

All trade scenario simulations increased production in rice and livestock sectors. Some

export-oriented sectors, such as textiles and electronics also increased production under

most of the alternative scenarios. And since most of the output of these sectors is

exported, the sectors also increased exports in all scenarios. Trade liberalisation also led

to significant increases in imports for all commodities.

By linking simulated prices of the GTAP model with the household model, the results

of the simulations showed that Vietnam’s small households in the livestock sector

would benefit from almost all trade liberalisations. The largest benefit was generated by

full liberalisation - by comparison there was almost no gain from bilateral trade

liberalisation with the USA. Meanwhile, in line with the macro-economic level results

from GTAP, unilateral trade liberalisation led to increases in household welfare.

For the small households of the livestock sector, output prices of rice, pig and chicken

increased under trade scenarios - an incentive for households to produce more on-farm

thereby increasing farm profit and cash flow. At the same time, by removing import

taxes, inputs for production and consumption goods were relatively cheaper compared

with the baseline. This effect was particularly noticeable for the “'other food”

consumption, with the increase in consumption ranging from 10 to 30 percent.

Producing more agricultural products also required households to devote more labour

41 However, it should be noticed that since the base year of the simulation in GTAP is 2001, these conclusions may be affected by trade situation in that period of time. For example, the possibility of trade between Vietnam with the United States in agricultural goods was limited because of diplomatic relationships between two countries were only just normalised after a long period of time. If database of the model is upgraded, says to GTAP version 7 (with base year data of 2004), the conclusion may be different. This is one of the study limitations, which will be returned to later in the chapter.

Page 170: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

152

time for on-farm work in almost all trade scenarios. There are also some benefits to

households due to trade liberalisation, which are not captured by the model but which

should be recognised. Households who are producers can exploit opportunities of

productivity-enhancement by easier access to improved production technologies.

One of the important issues contributing to increases in household welfare is the

decision of the household on time allocation. In almost all scenarios, the household

decided to take more leisure. This contributed about one quarter of the household’s total

welfare increases in the trade liberalisations.

The decision of the household in time allocation was driven by the type of utility

function chosen. By applying the LES, the household chose to work less and take more

leisure every time they had more income available. Since full income is defined by the

sum of non-farm income, net other income, a farm’s profits, and the value of the

household’s stock of time (wT), increased wage rates under trade scenarios made

households feel more wealthy, hence they spent more time for leisure than work.

Choosing an appropriate assumption about possible labour market expansion in the

general equilibrium trade model is very important. Assumptions about whether wages

or labour supply changes to clear markets have important implications for wages

simulated by the model. The study compared decisions of the household on labour

allocation under alternative trade scenarios with Closure A and Closure C. Assuming

full utilisation of labour at the national level, labour wages under Closure A were much

higher than that under Closure C, where the economy supplied up to 12 percent more

unemployment to the labour force. Higher wages under Closure A made the household

wealthier, in terms of full income, resulting in the household choosing more leisure time

by working less compared with that under Closure C. At the same time, since

agricultural output prices are not high enough, farm production does not promise

increased benefits, so higher wages pull out more household labour from their farm

under Closure A. The household chooses to reduce agricultural production, and work

more off-farm. This illustrates that choosing Closure C is appropriate, since it represents

Vietnam’s economy more precisely with wage increases due to trade liberalisations at a

more suitable level, that wouldn’t draw household labour away from on-farm work to

an excessive degree.

Page 171: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

153

In summary, the research shows that Vietnam’s small households in the livestock sector

would benefit from almost all trade liberalisation simulation scenarios. What

implications do these results have for policy? We can envision that in the long run

Vietnam will keep moving towards a more open economy. The household seem

continuously get benefits, which are derived from an increase in livestock output prices

relative to production costs. The availability of improved production technologies for

production could contribute to increase competitiveness and income of the household in

a globalised economy. As experienced in other countries, which follow liberalisation,

increased specialization in production and trade with income growth and increasing

urbanization is happened. Higher labour costs, including for unskilled labour and

opportunities in the manufacture sector will act as pull factors attracting workers from

agricultural household, which promises a possible increase of non-agricultural income

of the household. Certainly, as the past experience showed, this transition is not

necessarily smooth.

In that context, developing enabling policies to help small households to better exploit

the opportunities that globalisation presents is not an easy exercise for the government.

Given Vietnam’s current policy is oriented to increasing market orientation in livestock

production, with a focus toward the development of industrial livestock production

system, how can the government facilitate and support the small household? Since

liberalisation leads to a tightening of the link between domestic and world markets, it is

desirable for government to have a policy to strength other sectors such as industry or

service, or the export sector, to generate jobs and absorb labour from the small

household/ agricultural sector, before exposing small households to a fiercer

competition with large-scale producers in the domestic economy and others in the

world. The alternative option of facilitating more productive smallholder production

systems through adoption of productivity-enhancing technologies may be more

beneficial, equitable, and sustainable in the long run.

8.2. Limitations of the Study and Potentials for Further Study

Constructing a household model was a major contribution to this study. With the

principle of maximising household utility in response to changes in external factors,

reactions of the household to production, consumption and time allocation are easily

Page 172: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

154

captured. This capability is the power of the household model in assessing impacts of a

number of policy issues on the household, such as government intervention to input and

output prices, restrictions on exports or imports, decisions about subsidisation, etc. In

the context of urbanisation and industrialisation, migration or capacity of the industrial

zones in absorbing labour may impact households in terms of welfare which can be

assessed using the model.

The household model was constructed using a recursive form, in which the household

decision making process is divided into two separate stages. The benefit of the model is

through its treatment of the profit effect on consumption: the two sides of production

and consumption are linked, and then the reaction of the household to an external factor

change is captured more precisely. However, the model has some disadvantages itself.

Some assumptions made in the model, such as the household is a price-taker in all

markets and all markets exist and are perfect and commodities are homogeneous,

including labour, are not always suitable. In some cases, these assumptions may be

violated, for example in the situation of under- or unemployment in the agricultural

sector in the slack season. Therefore an extension to the model allowing for incomplete

markets may be useful. In particular, in the labour market, where there may be different

wages for on- and off-farm work, or limits to obtaining work may be good options for

future research.

The household model in the study is often used for assessment in the short run, since

some factors are fixed under the model. It was assumed that cultivation land area was

fixed, technology of agricultural production did not change, savings and exogenous

income of the household were also unchanged, but in the long term the above factors

may vary and be endogenous. Therefore relaxing these assumptions may be good

applications for future modelling. In this study, the impact of risk was not included.

However, the issue of risk, which may vary under alternative liberalisation scenarios,

may also influence production decisions, so extending the model to include risk issues

is another potential area of study.

In the study, LES and LA-AIDS models were used for the demand side, and Cobb

Douglas models were applied for production functions. These choices were based on

suitability for inclusion in the household model, and their ability to be solved in that

Page 173: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

155

context. However, choice of functional forms for the econometric models may change

policy conclusions. For example, an assumption of the LES model implies the

household will consume more leisure as soon as they become wealthy, which is partly

defined by the value of total stock of time. This may not be strictly true, especially for

very poor households. Therefore a study that allows different values for labour wages

and 'cost' for leisure would be helpful. The choice of functional forms applied in the

model may be a useful area to explore further in development and application of the

household model.

To assess possible impacts of trade liberalisation on the household, a trade model at the

macro level was linked with the micro household model. Matching perfectly an

aggregate model such as GTAP with a household model is always difficult. In this

study, in order to match sectors, commodities as well as inputs and factors between the

models, some simplifying assumptions were made. Disaggregating the live pig and

poultry sectors as separate activities within the GTAP database was implemented using

SplitCom. Splitting commodities requires massive supporting data sets. If possible,

further work on the appropriate level of aggregation of commodities in GTAP for the

purpose of this research would be useful. The “SplitCom technology” is also a potential

application for trade liberalisation research using the GTAP model.

Choosing the closure rule in GTAP is required, and has significant implications for

simulated changes in the economy. In this study, several closures were used to compare

the sensitivity of results. Identifying a closure which is most suitable for the Vietnamese

situation is not straightforward. Assuming a maximum level of labour increase in

Vietnam of 12 percent was supported by some macro-economic data, however other

closures may also need to be explored in future research. Currently, the only variable

that was changed was labour, but there may be other variables, such as the treatment of

trade balances that could also be explored. Since the GTAP model applied in this

research is a static model, it cannot capture ongoing changes of the policy. The static

model only allows assessment at a point in time, , which does not allow a consideration

of the time path between equilibria to be considered.. Research with a dynamic GTAP,

which is available now, would be more ideal for future studies of this nature.

Page 174: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

156

In conclusion, applying the GTAP model at the macro level and linking it with

household models at the micro level, the study met the objective of the study: to assess

impacts of globalisation and trade liberalisation on small households in the Vietnam

livestock sector. The study showed the welfare of the households is improved under the

trade scenarios. However, the results depend significantly upon assumptions made in

the models. The assumptions made about the operation of the labour market (both at the

aggregate level within GTAP, and on household decisions about work/leisure) are most

important. Acknowledgement of advantages as well as understanding of the limitations

of the models are necessary for further and deeper studies in the future.

Page 175: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

157

APPENDICES

A3.1: Recursive Model Matrix

The annex is verbatim drawn from Singh, Squire and Strauss, 1986 to give more detail on how

the household model is separated between revenue and expenditure.

A household utility function is assumed to exist:

),.....,( 1 LXXUU i =1, …., (A3.1-1)

Where Xi is vector of commodity i consumption for different members of the household, XL

denotes leisure time.

Its utility is maximised subject to a budget constraint:

L

iii XpY

1

(A3.1-2)

Where Y is the household’s full income and pi’s are commodity prices (pL is wage rate):

RLpVqQqTpY L

N

iii

M

jjjL

11

(A3.1-3)

Where:

T= time endowment

Qj = output, j= 1,…,M

Vi = non-labour variable inputs, i=1,….,N

L = labour demand

qj = price of Qj

pi = price of Vi

R = exogenous income

It is assumed that L is labour demanded by household both family and hired, and they are

perfect substitutes.

An implicit function is applied:

0),.......,,,,........,,,.......,( 0111 KKLVVQQG NM (A3.1-4)

Where Ki’s are fixed inputs.

Page 176: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

158

To see that the model is recursive, comparative statistics are examined. Let the household

consume three commodities: leisure, XL, industry goods purchased on the market, Xm, and an

agricultural good produced by the household, Xa. The household uses labour, L, other variable

inputs, V, and fixed input K to produce Qa to consume at home and Qc to sell on the market. The

Lagrangian is written as:

),,,,(]

)([),,(

KVLQQGXpXpXpR

VqLpQpQqTpXXXU

acmmLLaa

vLaaccLamL

(A3.1-5)

The first-order conditions are:

0

LLL

pUX

(A3.1-6)

0

mmm

pUX

0

aaa

pUX

0)()(

RXpVqXQpQqLXTp mmvaaaccLL

01

ccc

GqQ

01

aaa

GpQ

01

LL GpL

01

Vv GqV

0),,,,(

KVLQQG ac

Totally differentiating (A3.1-6), have (A3.1-7)

Page 177: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

159

000000

0000

0000

0000

0000

000000

00000

00000

00000

v

L

a

c

a

m

L

a

c

a

m

L

vLac

vvvvLvavc

LLvLLLaLc

aavaLaaac

ccvcLcacc

amL

aaaamaL

mmammmL

LLaLmLL

dp

dp

dp

dq

dp

dp

dp

d

dV

dL

dQ

dQ

d

dX

dX

dX

GGGG

GGGGG

GGGGG

GGGGG

GGGGG

ppp

pUUU

pUUU

pUUU

(A3.1-7)

where dKGVdqdqQdRdpXQdpXdpLXT kvccaaammLL )()(

when differentiating the budget constraint we have substituted

)( dVGdLGdQGdQG vLaacc

for dVqdLpdQpdQq vLaacc

This equals dKGk

since G(.)=0.

This system of equations is block diagonal, as seen from (A3.1-7). The first set of equations,

upper left block of the matrix, gives the solution for commodity demands and marginal utility of

full income. The second set, the lower right one, gives the solution for output supplies, variable

input demands, and the associated multiplier. The assumptions concerning utility and

production functions ensure that second-order conditions are met. Hence, the consumption

decisions are partially determined by the outcome of production decisions. However,

consumption decisions have no impact on production decisions (Singh et al. 1986)

Page 178: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

160

A4.1. OLS Estimation of Production Functions

A4.1-1: OLS Estimation of Rice Production Function

Region RRD is omitted

Source SS df MS Number of obs. = 3995

Model 2529.5133 8 316.189163 F(8, 3986) = 2736.94

Residual 460.487984 3986 0.115526338 Prob > F = 0.0000

Total 2990.00129 3994 0.748623257 R-squared = 0.8460

Adj R-squared = 0.8457

Root MSE = 0.33989

Rice output Coefficient Std. error t P> | t | [95% Conf. Interval]

Area 0.609834 0.014437 42.24 0.000 0.58153 0.638138

Seed 0.047518 0.007981 5.95 0.000 0.031871 0.063166

Chemical fertiliser 0.22347 0.009149 24.42 0.000 0.205532 0.241408

Pesticide 0.054194 0.006030 8.99 0.000 0.042373 0.066016

Labor 0.058637 0.005828 10.06 0.000 0.047211 0.070064

NE + NW -0.11952 0.015533 -7.69 0.000 -0.14998 -0.08907

The Central -0.29136 0.014538 -20.04 0.000 -0.31986 -0.26285

The South -0.2865 0.024463 -11.71 0.000 -0.33447 -0.23854

Constant 6.62204 0.072516 91.32 0.000 6.479869 6.764211

Rice output = total output of rice cultivation raising/year (kg)

Area= total areas of rice cultivation/year (ha)

Seed = total rice used as seeding/year (kg)

Chemical fertiliser = total chemical fertiliser used/year (kg)

Pesticide = total pesticide and herbicide used/year (bottle)

Labour = Total day working for chicken raising/year (man-days)

Other costs = total other cost for production ('000 VND)

Page 179: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

161

A4.1-2. OLS Estimation of Pig Production Function

Region RRD, NE+NW are omitted

Source SS df MS Number of obs. = 3191

Model 2197.96921 5 439.593841 F(5, 3185) = 2218.69

Residual 631.051269 3185 0.198132266 Prob. > F = 0.0000

Total 2829.02048 3190 0.886840275 R-squared = 0.7769

Adj. R-squared = 0.7766

Root MSE = 0.44512

Pig output Coefficient Std. error t P> | t | [95% Conf. Interval]

Feed 0.5844212 0.0106976 54.63 0.000 0.5634462 0.6053961

Labor 0.1714647 0.010323 16.61 0.000 0.1512243 0.1917052

Veterinary+ others 0.0946292 0.0106225 8.91 0.000 0.0738016 0.1154568

The Central 0.0967256 0.0172795 5.60 0.000 0.0628455 0.1306057

The South 0.246214 0.0326408 7.54 0.000 0.1822149 0.3102131

Constant -0.0242914 0.0545676 -0.45 0.656 -0.1312825 0.0826997

Pig output = total output of pig raising/year (kg)

Feed = total cost of feeding pig/year ('000 VND)

Labour = Total day working for pig raising/year (man-days)

Other costs = total other cost for production ('000 VND)

Page 180: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

162

A4.1-3. OLS Estimation of Chicken Production Function

Region RRD is omitted

Source S df MS Number of obs. = 1959

Model 837.416308 6 139.569385 F(6, 1952) = 924.45

Residual 294.705857 1952 0.150976361 Prob. > F = 0.0000

Total 1132.12217 1958 0.578203353 R-squared = 0.7397

Adj. R-squared = 0.7389

Root MSE = 0.38856

Chicken output Coefficient Std. error t P> | t | [95% Conf. Interval]

Feed 0.460 0.012 38.700 0.000 0.436 0.483

Labor 0.210 0.010 20.820 0.000 0.190 0.229

Veterinary+ others 0.137 0.011 12.560 0.000 0.116 0.159

NE+NW 0.048 0.024 2.030 0.043 0.002 0.094

The Central 0.158 0.024 6.460 0.000 0.110 0.206

The South 0.440 0.049 8.930 0.000 0.344 0.537

Constant -0.251 0.055 -4.560 0.000 -0.359 -0.143

Chicken output = total output of chicken raising/year (kg)

Feed = total cost of feeding chicken/year ('000 VND)

Labour = Total day working for chicken raising/year (man-days)

Other costs = total other cost for production ('000 VND)

Page 181: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

163

A4.2. Estimation Shadow Wage of Labour

A4.2-1. Calculate Marginal Product of Labour from Production Function

Source SS df MS Number of obs. = 3314

Model 1159.58383 12 96.6319862 F(12, 3301) = 1504.01

Residual 212.08832 3301 0.064249718 Prob > F = 0.0000

Total 1371.67215 3313 0.414027212 R-squared = 0.8454

Adj R-squared = 0.8448

Root MSE = 0.25348

Income Coefficient Std. error t P> | t | [95% Conf. Interval]

Labour 0.049815 0.006339 7.86 0.000 0.037386 0.062244

Rice cultivation cost 0.162491 0.014545 11.17 0.000 0.133974 0.191008

Livestock cost 0.289491 0.004632 62.50 0.000 0.280409 0.298573

Other fees 0.070952 0.013116 5.41 0.000 0.045235 0.096668

Area 0.313744 0.009501 33.02 0.000 0.295116 0.332373

NE 0.031253 0.013215 2.37 0.018 0.005343 0.057163

NW 0.100236 0.019494 5.14 0.000 0.062014 0.138457

NCC -0.08841 0.013999 -6.32 0.000 -0.11586 -0.06096

SCC -0.10361 0.017589 -5.89 0.000 -0.1381 -0.06913

CH 0.091724 0.022322 4.11 0.000 0.047958 0.13549

NES -0.0289 0.03318 -0.87 0.384 -0.09396 0.036156

MRD 0.024851 0.022931 1.08 0.279 -0.02011 0.06981

Constant 5.188956 0.077439 67.01 0.000 5.037123 5.34079

Income = total farm income from rice cultivation, pig and chicken raising ('000 VND)

Cost of rice = total cost for rice cultivation ('000 VND)

Livestock cost = total cost for feeding and veterinary ('000 VND)

Labour = total day working for rice cultivation + pig, chicken raising/year (man-days)

Other fees = total fees for farm works/year ('000 VND)

Area= total areas of rice cultivation/year (ha)

Page 182: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

164

A4.2-2. Using Instrumental Variables for Estimation of Shadow Wage

Source SS df MS Number of obs. = 1022

Model 96.552277 11 8.77747973 F( 11, 1010) = 27.29

Residual 324.81811 1010 0.321602089 Prob > F = 0.0000

Total 421.370387 1021 0.412703611 R-squared = 0.2291

Adj R-squared = 0.2207

Root MSE = 0.5671

Shadow wage Coefficient Std. error t P> | t | [95% Conf. Interval]

Head edu 0.044846 0.018125 2.47 0.014 0.015007 0.074686

Head age 0.005095 0.001873 2.72 0.007 0.002011 0.008179

No mem 0.035177 0.015068 2.33 0.020 0.01037 0.059985

No labor -0.12694 0.018594 -6.83 0.000 -0.15756 -0.09633

Exo income 0.014297 0.010719 1.33 0.183 -0.00335 0.031943

Rice price 0.153528 0.08859 1.73 0.083 0.007677 0.29938

Pig price 0.173112 0.042222 4.10 0.000 0.1036 0.242625

Chic price -0.15215 0.122458 -1.24 0.214 -0.35376 0.049459

NE + NW -0.53810 0.045793 -11.75 0.000 -0.61349 -0.46271

The Central -0.35212 0.049609 -7.10 0.000 -0.43380 -0.27045

The South 0.610628 0.175814 3.47 0.001 0.321176 0.900081

Constant 0.766624 0.410344 1.87 0.062 0.091048 1.44220

Shadow wage = (Income-hat *_b[Labour])/Labour

Head edu = education level of head household

Head age = age of head household

No mem = no of member in the household

No labour = no of labour in the household

Exo income = total exogenous income of the household

Rice price = price of rice ('000 VND/kg)

Pig price = price of pork ('000 VND/kg)

Chic price = price of chicken ('000 VND/kg)

Page 183: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

165

A4.3. Results of LA-AIDS Models

A4.3-1. LA - AIDS Model in RRD

Iteration 1: tolerance = .00616148

Iteration 2: tolerance = .00009929

Iteration 3: tolerance = 1.644e-06

Iteration 4: tolerance = 2.675e-08

Seemingly unrelated regression, iterated

Equation Obs Parms RMSE 'R-sq' chi2 P

Rice 913 6 0.119509 0.149 162.12 0.0000

Pork 913 6 0.08901 0.106 122.09 0.0000

Chicken 913 6 0.047949 0.0272 28.15 0.0001

Fish 913 6 0.063733 0.0192 29.09 0.0001

Vegetable 913 6 0.033437 0.0683 73.80 0.0000

Coefficient Std. error t P>| t| [95% Conf. Interval]

Rice qty

Rice price 0.185345 0.023026 8.05 0.000 0.140214 0.230475

Pork price -0.07996 0.014382 -5.56 0.000 -0.10815 -0.05177

Chic price -0.02951 0.009122 -3.24 0.001 -0.04739 -0.01163

Fish price -0.04475 0.009314 -4.80 0.000 -0.063 -0.02649

Vege price -0.01593 0.005687 -2.80 0.005 -0.02708 -0.00479

Othmeat price -0.01519 0.007147 -2.13 0.034 -0.0292 -0.00119

Real income -0.09708 0.010781 -9.00 0.000 -0.11821 -0.07595

Constant 1.404675 0.07929 17.72 0.000 1.249271 1.56008

Pork qty

Rice price -0.07996 0.014382 -5.56 0.000 -0.10815 -0.05177

Pork price 0.052484 0.013692 3.83 0.000 0.025649 0.079319

Chic price 0.000453 0.006735 0.07 0.946 -0.01275 0.013652

Fish price 0.026245 0.006913 3.80 0.000 0.012695 0.039794

Vege price 0.002591 0.004448 0.58 0.560 -0.00613 0.01131

Othmeat price -0.00181 0.005315 -0.34 0.733 -0.01223 0.008606

Real income 0.069049 0.008026 8.60 0.000 0.053319 0.084779

Constant -0.36941 0.059246 -6.24 0.000 -0.48553 -0.25329

Page 184: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

166

Coefficient Std. error t P>| t| [95% Conf. Interval]

Chic qty

Rice price -0.02951 0.009122 -3.24 0.001 -0.04739 -0.01163

Pork price 0.000453 0.006735 0.07 0.946 -0.01275 0.013652

Chic price 0.033656 0.008017 4.20 0.000 0.017942 0.049369

Fish price 0.005932 0.004649 1.28 0.202 -0.00318 0.015044

Vege price -0.00896 0.003501 -2.56 0.011 -0.01582 -0.0021

Othmeat price -0.00157 0.004192 -0.37 0.708 -0.00979 0.006646

Real income 0.004358 0.004334 1.01 0.315 -0.00414 0.012852

Constant -0.03448 0.033142 -1.04 0.298 -0.09944 0.030477

Fish qty

Rice price -0.04475 0.009314 -4.80 0.000 -0.063 -0.02649

Pork price 0.026245 0.006913 3.80 0.000 0.012695 0.039794

Chic price 0.005932 0.004649 1.28 0.202 -0.00318 0.015044

Fish price 0.012005 0.006779 1.77 0.077 -0.00128 0.025292

Vege price -0.00109 0.003079 -0.35 0.724 -0.00712 0.004946

Othmeat price 0.001656 0.003693 0.45 0.654 -0.00558 0.008895

Real income 0.006473 0.005757 1.12 0.261 -0.00481 0.017757

Constant -0.0254 0.040694 -0.62 0.532 -0.10516 0.054357

Vege qty

Rice price -0.01593 0.005687 -2.80 0.005 -0.02708 -0.00479

Pork price 0.002591 0.004448 0.58 0.560 -0.00613 0.01131

Chic price -0.00896 0.003501 -2.56 0.011 -0.01582 -0.0021

Fish price -0.00109 0.003079 -0.35 0.724 -0.00712 0.004946

Vege price 0.021349 0.003117 6.85 0.000 0.015239 0.027459

Othmeat price 0.002041 0.002623 0.78 0.436 -0.0031 0.007182

Real income -0.01321 0.003019 -4.38 0.000 -0.01912 -0.00729

Constant 0.184329 0.022606 8.15 0.000 0.140022 0.228635

Page 185: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

167

* Uncompensated Elasticities in RRD

Rice

price

Pork

price

Chic

price

Fish

price

Vege

price

Othmeat

price

Real

income

Rice qty -0.53934 -0.11804 -0.04378 -0.06989 -0.0186 -0.01992 0.809563

Pork qty -0.56494 -0.81158 -0.02287 0.09693 -0.00981 -0.02647 1.338731

Chic qty -0.42839 -0.00588 -0.54998 0.074559 -0.12486 -0.02427 1.05883

Fish qty -0.51154 0.265362 0.058049 -0.87866 -0.01617 0.014048 1.068919

Vege qty -0.13841 0.079482 -0.12007 0.00228 -0.6656 0.041025 0.801302

Othmeat qty -0.59122 -0.15427 -0.07365 -0.02312 0.000388 -0.74381 1.585686

* Compensated Elasticties in RRD

Rice

price

Pork

price

Chic

price

Fish

price

Vege

price

Othmeat

price

Rice qty -0.12664 0.04699 0.016182 0.006147 0.035213 0.022112

Pork qty 0.117512 -0.53869 0.076291 0.222674 0.079176 0.043032

Chic qty 0.111372 0.209956 -0.47156 0.174012 -0.05449 0.030702

Fish qty 0.033363 0.483257 0.137224 -0.77826 0.054873 0.069542

Vege qty 0.270067 0.242823 -0.06072 0.077544 -0.61234 0.082626

Othmeat qty 0.217121 0.168963 0.043803 0.125817 0.105783 -0.66149

A4.3-2. LA - AIDS Model in NE+NW

Iteration 1: tolerance = .05016562

Iteration 2: tolerance = .00269992

Iteration 3: tolerance = .0001371

Iteration 4: tolerance = 7.660e-06

Iteration 5: tolerance = 4.202e-07

Seemingly unrelated regression, iterated

Equation Obs Parms RMSE 'R-sq' chi2 P

Rice 996 6 0.132031 0.0247 40.41 0.0000

Pork 996 6 0.087304 0.0369 35.10 0.0000

Chicken 996 6 0.056136 0.0327 37.63 0.0000

Fish 996 6 0.056747 0.0421 43.99 0.0000

Vegetable 996 6 0.048459 0.0645 94.29 0.0000

Page 186: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

168

Coefficient Std. error t P>| t| [95% Conf. Interval]

Rice qty

Rice price 0.063509 0.02129 2.98 0.003 0.021782 0.105236

Pork price -0.00237 0.013293 -0.18 0.858 -0.02842 0.023682

Chic price -0.03304 0.009416 -3.51 0.000 -0.0515 -0.01459

Fish price -0.01281 0.007595 -1.69 0.092 -0.02769 0.002077

Vege price -0.01891 0.006687 -2.83 0.005 -0.03201 -0.0058

Othmeat price 0.00362 0.006229 0.58 0.561 -0.00859 0.015828

Real income -0.04585 0.011078 -4.14 0.000 -0.06756 -0.02414

Constant 0.899446 0.082064 10.96 0.000 0.738605 1.060288

Pork qty

Rice price -0.00237 0.013293 -0.18 0.858 -0.02842 0.023682

Pork price 0.045083 0.013429 3.36 0.001 0.018763 0.071403

Chic price -0.01631 0.007787 -2.09 0.036 -0.03157 -0.00105

Fish price 0.002802 0.006103 0.46 0.646 -0.00916 0.014764

Vege price -0.01491 0.005225 -2.85 0.004 -0.02515 -0.00467

Othmeat price -0.01429 0.005219 -2.74 0.006 -0.02452 -0.00406

Real income 0.022747 0.007329 3.10 0.002 0.008383 0.03711

Constant -0.00232 0.05522 -0.04 0.966 -0.11055 0.105907

Chic qty

Rice price -0.03304 0.009416 -3.51 0.000 -0.05150 -0.01459

Pork price -0.01631 0.007787 -2.09 0.036 -0.03157 -0.00105

Chic price 0.042696 0.009766 4.37 0.000 0.023556 0.061836

Fish price 0.007656 0.004806 1.59 0.111 -0.00176 0.017076

Vege price 0.010509 0.004117 2.55 0.011 0.002439 0.018578

Othmeat price -0.01151 0.004642 -2.48 0.013 -0.02061 -0.00241

Real income 0.001838 0.004715 0.39 0.697 -0.0074 0.011079

Constant 0.042374 0.036591 1.16 0.247 -0.02934 0.114091

Fish qty

Rice price -0.01281 0.007595 -1.69 0.092 -0.02769 0.002077

Pork price 0.002802 0.006103 0.46 0.646 -0.00916 0.014764

Chic price 0.007656 0.004806 1.59 0.111 -0.00176 0.017076

Fish price 0.007229 0.005339 1.35 0.176 -0.00324 0.017694

Page 187: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

169

Coefficient Std. error t P>| t| [95% Conf. Interval]

Vege price -0.00535 0.003335 -1.60 0.109 -0.01189 0.001188

Othmeat price 0.000469 0.003328 0.14 0.888 -0.00605 0.006993

Real income 0.027894 0.004763 5.86 0.000 0.018559 0.037228

Constant -0.15087 0.034723 -4.34 0.000 -0.21892 -0.08281

Vege qty

Rice price -0.01891 0.006687 -2.83 0.005 -0.03201 -0.0058

Pork price -0.01491 0.005225 -2.85 0.004 -0.02515 -0.00467

Chic price 0.010509 0.004117 2.55 0.011 0.002439 0.018578

Fish price -0.00535 0.003335 -1.60 0.109 -0.01189 0.001188

Vege price 0.022695 0.004033 5.63 0.000 0.014791 0.030599

Othmeat price 0.005965 0.002816 2.12 0.034 0.000446 0.011483

Real income -0.0273 0.004068 -6.71 0.000 -0.03527 -0.01933

Constant 0.276218 0.029883 9.24 0.000 0.217648 0.334788

* Uncompensated Elasticities in NE+NW

Rice

price

Pork

price

Chic

price

Fish

price

Vege

price

Othmeat

price

Real

income

Rice qty -0.83341 0.011517 -0.05433 -0.0182 -0.0291 0.010691 0.91283

Pork qty -0.07799 -0.77751 -0.10077 0.006509 -0.09082 -0.08315 1.123735

Chic qty -0.34942 -0.17107 -0.56314 0.077335 0.106491 -0.11907 1.018885

Fish qty -0.38931 -0.03295 0.070006 -0.92548 -0.10682 -0.01062 1.395164

Vege qty -0.05792 -0.12594 0.16762 -0.04357 -0.68376 0.091128 0.652442

Othmeat qty -0.16602 -0.41408 -0.30943 -0.02265 0.099349 -0.66028 1.473126

* Compensated Elasticties in NE+NW

Rice

price

Pork

price

Chic

price

Fish

price

Vege

price

Othmeat

price

Rice qty -0.35325 0.179327 0.034512 0.046238 0.042596 0.050576

Pork qty 0.513117 -0.57093 0.008594 0.085831 -0.00256 -0.03405

Chic qty 0.186528 0.016233 -0.46398 0.149255 0.186518 -0.07455

Fish qty 0.344566 0.223534 0.20579 -0.82700 0.002763 0.050345

Vege qty 0.28527 -0.00600 0.231118 0.002483 -0.63251 0.119636

Othmeat qty 0.608864 -0.14327 -0.16606 0.081331 0.215052 -0.59592

Page 188: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

170

A4.3-3. LA - AIDS Model in the Central

Iteration 1: tolerance = .0275376

Iteration 2: tolerance = .00080431

Iteration 3: tolerance = .00003048

Iteration 4: tolerance = 1.043e-06

Iteration 5: tolerance = 3.363e-08

Seemingly unrelated regression, iterated

Equation Obs Parms RMSE 'R-sq' chi2 P

Rice 1005 6 0.1246 0.1098 170.68 0.0000

Pork 1005 6 0.077306 0.0426 65.22 0.0000

Chicken 1005 6 0.04528 0.0173 27.84 0.0001

Fish 1005 6 0.082862 0.0448 67.94 0.0000

Vegetable 1005 6 0.037377 0.0187 38.32 0.0000

Coefficient Std. error t P>| t| [95% Conf. Interval]

Rice qty

Rice price 0.118058 0.018912 6.24 0.000 0.080992 0.155125

Pork price -0.01699 0.010928 -1.55 0.120 -0.03841 0.00443

Chic price 0.004175 0.007077 0.59 0.555 -0.0097 0.018045

Fish price -0.05309 0.008832 -6.01 0.000 -0.0704 -0.03578

Vege price -0.00569 0.004754 -1.20 0.232 -0.015 0.003631

Othmeat price -0.04647 0.00665 -6.99 0.000 -0.0595 -0.03344

Real income -0.10077 0.010307 -9.78 0.000 -0.12097 -0.08056

Constant 1.330537 0.076552 17.38 0.000 1.180499 1.480575

Pork qty

Rice price -0.01699 0.010928 -1.55 0.120 -0.03841 0.00443

Pork price 0.036052 0.010067 3.58 0.000 0.01632 0.055784

Chic price -0.01805 0.005291 -3.41 0.001 -0.02842 -0.00768

Fish price 0.008412 0.005775 1.46 0.145 -0.00291 0.019732

Vege price -0.00984 0.003513 -2.80 0.005 -0.01673 -0.00296

Othmeat price 0.000416 0.004884 0.09 0.932 -0.00916 0.009988

Real income 0.037492 0.006398 5.86 0.000 0.024953 0.050031

Constant -0.13892 0.047294 -2.94 0.003 -0.23161 -0.04623

Page 189: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

171

Coefficient Std. error t P>| t| [95% Conf. Interval]

Chic qty

Rice price 0.004175 0.007077 0.59 0.555 -0.0097 0.018045

Pork price -0.01805 0.005291 -3.41 0.001 -0.02842 -0.00768

Chic price 0.001201 0.006431 0.19 0.852 -0.0114 0.013805

Fish price 0.014858 0.003799 3.91 0.000 0.007413 0.022304

Vege price -0.00108 0.002543 -0.43 0.671 -0.00607 0.003903

Othmeat price -0.00111 0.004007 -0.28 0.782 -0.00896 0.006747

Real income 0.009131 0.003751 2.43 0.015 0.00178 0.016482

Constant 0.016924 0.028846 0.59 0.557 -0.03961 0.07346

Fish qty

Rice price -0.05309 0.008832 -6.01 0.000 -0.0704 -0.03578

Pork price 0.008412 0.005775 1.46 0.145 -0.00291 0.019732

Chic price 0.014858 0.003799 3.91 0.000 0.007413 0.022304

Fish price 0.016749 0.007235 2.31 0.021 0.002568 0.030929

Vege price -0.0014 0.002808 -0.50 0.618 -0.0069 0.004103

Othmeat price 0.014468 0.003634 3.98 0.000 0.007346 0.02159

Real income 0.030928 0.006863 4.51 0.000 0.017478 0.044378

Constant -0.13847 0.048212 -2.87 0.004 -0.23296 -0.04398

Vege qty

Rice price -0.00569 0.004754 -1.20 0.232 -0.01500 0.003631

Pork price -0.00984 0.003513 -2.80 0.005 -0.01673 -0.00296

Chic price -0.00108 0.002543 -0.43 0.671 -0.00607 0.003903

Fish price -0.0014 0.002808 -0.50 0.618 -0.00690 0.004103

Vege price 0.007306 0.00242 3.02 0.003 0.002562 0.012050

Othmeat price 0.010707 0.002382 4.50 0.000 0.006039 0.015376

Real income -0.00055 0.003093 -0.18 0.859 -0.00661 0.005512

Constant 0.080924 0.022458 3.60 0.000 0.036907 0.12494

Page 190: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

172

* Uncompensated Elasticities in the Central

Rice

price

Pork

price

Chic

price

Fish

price

Vege

price

Othmeat

price

Real

income

Rice qty -0.66714 -0.00261 0.020477 -0.0736 0.002692 -0.08173 0.801899

Pork qty -0.23198 -0.80556 -0.13104 0.016657 -0.08022 -0.00905 1.241195

Chic qty -0.00758 -0.31432 -0.98974 0.217022 -0.02779 -0.02504 1.147434

Fish qty -0.4431 0.023209 0.083336 -0.92309 -0.02296 0.083471 1.199135

Vege qty -0.07721 -0.13937 -0.01496 -0.01877 -0.89512 0.153289 0.992135

Othmeat qty -1.20426 -0.06742 -0.05302 0.221618 0.185968 -0.57163 1.488747

* Compensated Elasticties in the Central

Rice

price

Pork

price

Chic

price

Fish

price

Vege

price

Othmeat

price

Rice qty -0.25924 0.122044 0.070139 0.050945 0.058846 -0.04273

Pork qty 0.39937 -0.61263 -0.05417 0.209429 0.006691 0.051304

Chic qty 0.576078 -0.13596 -0.91867 0.395231 0.052564 0.03076

Fish qty 0.166851 0.209606 0.157599 -0.73685 0.061012 0.141782

Vege qty 0.427451 0.014853 0.046488 0.135318 -0.82564 0.201534

Othmeat qty -0.44699 0.163998 0.039175 0.452837 0.290218 -0.49924

A4.3-4. LA - AIDS Model in the South

Iteration 1: tolerance = .04020703

Iteration 2: tolerance = .0019823

Iteration 3: tolerance = .00009177

Iteration 4: tolerance = 5.330e-06

Iteration 5: tolerance = 2.912e-07

Seemingly unrelated regression, iterated

Equation Obs Parms RMSE 'R-sq' chi2 P

Rice 192 6 0.117078 0.2077 48.89 0.0000

Pork 192 6 0.091636 0.1108 22.40 0.0010

Chicken 192 6 0.053138 0.0134 1.98 0.9219

Fish 192 6 0.101117 0.0138 27.95 0.0001

Vegetable 192 6 0.041957 0.0431 10.21 0.1161

Page 191: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

173

Coefficient Std. error t P>| t| [95% Conf. Interval]

Rice qty

Rice price 0.187111 0.042787 4.37 0.000 0.103251 0.270971

Pork price -0.04138 0.028961 -1.43 0.153 -0.09814 0.015382

Chic price -0.01054 0.019748 -0.53 0.594 -0.04924 0.028169

Fish price -0.0828 0.018066 -4.58 0.000 -0.11821 -0.04739

Vege price -0.03323 0.01298 -2.56 0.010 -0.05867 -0.00779

Othmeat price -0.01917 0.015679 -1.22 0.222 -0.0499 0.011564

Real income -0.1031 0.022811 -4.52 0.000 -0.14781 -0.05839

Constant 1.346043 0.172254 7.81 0.000 1.008432 1.683655

Pork qty

Rice price -0.04138 0.028961 -1.43 0.153 -0.09814 0.015382

Pork price -0.01269 0.032205 -0.39 0.694 -0.07581 0.050435

Chic price -0.01444 0.018206 -0.79 0.428 -0.05012 0.021242

Fish price 0.042018 0.014651 2.87 0.004 0.013301 0.070734

Vege price 0.003302 0.011597 0.28 0.776 -0.01943 0.026032

Othmeat price 0.023188 0.014503 1.6 0.110 -0.00524 0.051614

Real income 0.058188 0.017891 3.25 0.001 0.023122 0.093253

Constant -0.26176 0.131823 -1.99 0.047 -0.52013 -0.00339

Chic qty

Rice price -0.01054 0.019748 -0.53 0.594 -0.04924 0.028169

Pork price -0.01444 0.018206 -0.79 0.428 -0.05012 0.021242

Chic price 0.014543 0.021251 0.68 0.494 -0.02711 0.056194

Fish price -0.00064 0.008867 -0.07 0.942 -0.01802 0.016737

Vege price 0.005548 0.008817 0.63 0.529 -0.01173 0.022829

Othmeat price 0.005526 0.011759 0.47 0.638 -0.01752 0.028573

Real income 0.006575 0.010445 0.63 0.529 -0.0139 0.027047

Constant 0.021993 0.079054 0.28 0.781 -0.13295 0.176935

Fish qty

Rice price -0.0828 0.018066 -4.58 0.000 -0.11821 -0.04739

Pork price 0.042018 0.014651 2.87 0.004 0.013301 0.070734

Chic price -0.00064 0.008867 -0.07 0.942 -0.01802 0.016737

Fish price 0.032738 0.017202 1.90 0.057 -0.00098 0.066453

Page 192: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

174

Coefficient Std. error t P>| t| [95% Conf. Interval]

Vege price 0.014273 0.006723 2.12 0.034 0.001095 0.027451

Othmeat price -0.00559 0.007545 -0.74 0.459 -0.02037 0.009201

Real income 0.013734 0.019659 0.70 0.485 -0.0248 0.052265

Constant 0.005239 0.135223 0.04 0.969 -0.25979 0.27027

Vege qty

Rice price -0.03323 0.01298 -2.56 0.010 -0.05867 -0.00779

Pork price 0.003302 0.011597 0.28 0.776 -0.01943 0.026032

Chic price 0.005548 0.008817 0.63 0.529 -0.01173 0.022829

Fish price 0.014273 0.006723 2.12 0.034 0.001095 0.027451

Vege price 0.010253 0.008116 1.26 0.206 -0.00565 0.02616

Othmeat price -0.00015 0.007204 -0.02 0.983 -0.01427 0.013969

Real income 0.007769 0.008269 0.94 0.347 -0.00844 0.023976

Constant -0.00395 0.059786 -0.07 0.947 -0.12113 0.113225

* Uncompensated Elasticities in the South

Rice

price

Pork

price

Chic

price

Fish

price

Vege

price

Othmeat

price

Real

income

Rice qty -0.45413 -0.05856 -0.00745 -0.1441 -0.05871 -0.03307 0.756024

Pork qty -0.40894 -1.13682 -0.11536 0.183828 -0.00898 0.125583 1.360699

Chic qty -0.18583 -0.21635 -0.8036 -0.02845 0.06994 0.072508 1.091769

Fish qty -0.41704 0.187339 -0.00765 -0.85964 0.061902 -0.02955 1.064642

Vege qty -0.44721 0.025089 0.061142 0.154617 -0.88217 -0.00663 1.095165

Othmeat qty -0.52205 0.406654 0.085809 -0.18201 -0.03028 -1.09255 1.334426

* Compensated Elasticties in the South

Rice

price

Pork

price

Chic

price

Fish

price

Vege

price

Othmeat

price

Rice qty -0.13464 0.063397 0.046719 0.016523 0.003012 0.004988

Pork qty 0.166073 -0.91732 -0.01787 0.472922 0.102102 0.194086

Chic qty 0.275546 -0.04022 -0.72537 0.20351 0.159069 0.127471

Fish qty 0.032865 0.359087 0.068632 -0.63345 0.148816 0.02405

Vege qty 0.015591 0.20176 0.139611 0.387296 -0.79277 0.048507

Othmeat qty 0.041867 0.621923 0.181421 0.101498 0.078659 -1.02537

Page 193: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

175

A4.4. Results of LES Models

A4.4-1. LES Model in RRD

Iteration 1: tolerance = .0166451 Iteration 2: tolerance = .00343 Iteration 3: tolerance = .00052913 Iteration 4: tolerance = .0000844 Iteration 5: tolerance = .00001439 Iteration 6: tolerance = 3.337e-06 Iteration 7: tolerance = 7.574e-07 Seemingly unrelated regression, iterated

Equation Obs Parms RMSE 'R-sq' chi2 P

Main food 1028 4 364.2532 0.9046 10606.20 0.000

Other food 1028 4 448.8232 0.6768 9701.01 0.000

Industry 1028 4 303.4447 0.7621 9745.03 0.000

Coefficient Std. error t P>| t| [95% Conf. Interval]

Main food

Gamma food 60.468 1.445 41.830 0.000 57.634 63.301

Beta food 0.310 0.008 37.650 0.000 0.294 0.327

Gamma bar 204.535 2.958 69.140 0.000 198.737 210.333

Gamma othfood 0.000 0.000 -2.840 0.005 0.000 0.000

Gamma indust 3.537 0.174 20.300 0.000 3.195 3.878

Other food

Gamma othfood 0.000 0.000 -4.830 0.000 0.000 0.000

Beta othfood 0.332 0.010 34.620 0.000 0.313 0.350

Gamma bar 204.535 2.958 69.140 0.000 198.737 210.333

Gamma food 60.468 1.445 41.830 0.000 57.634 63.301

Gamma indust 3.537 0.174 20.300 0.000 3.195 3.878

Indust

Gamma indust 3.537 0.174 20.300 0.000 3.195 3.878

Beta indust 0.149 0.007 22.820 0.000 0.136 0.161

Gamma bar 204.535 2.958 69.140 0.000 198.737 210.333

Gamma food 60.468 1.445 41.830 0.000 57.634 63.301

Gamma othfood (dropped)

Page 194: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

176

A4.4-2. LES Model in NE+NW

Iteration 1: tolerance = .442507 Iteration 2: tolerance = .02771702 Iteration 3: tolerance = .00203137 Iteration 4: tolerance = .00016556 Iteration 5: tolerance = .00001456 Iteration 6: tolerance = 1.354e-06 Iteration 7: tolerance = 1.305e-07 Seemingly unrelated regression, iterated

Equation Obs Parms RMSE 'R-sq' chi2 P

Main food 1222 4 304.5923 0.9374 23255.78 0.000

Other food 1222 4 238.3234 0.8226 16699.72 0.000

Industry 1222 4 254.1319 0.8479 17236.36 0.000

Coefficient Std. error t P>| t| [95% Conf. Interval]

Main food

Gamma food 57.799 1.397 41.370 0.000 55.061 60.537

Beta food 0.321 0.007 46.460 0.000 0.307 0.334

Gamma bar 254.350 2.730 93.150 0.000 248.999 259.702

Gamma othfood 0.000 0.000 -2.800 0.005 0.000 0.000

Gamma indust -0.404 0.202 -2.000 0.046 -0.799 -0.008

Other food

Gamma othfood 0.000 0.000 8.310 0.000 0.000 0.000

Beta othfood 0.245 0.004 54.910 0.000 0.236 0.254

Gamma bar 254.350 2.730 93.150 0.000 248.999 259.702

Gamma food 57.799 1.397 41.370 0.000 55.061 60.537

Gamma indust -0.404 0.202 -2.000 0.046 -0.799 -0.008

Indust

Gamma indust -0.404 0.202 -2.000 0.046 -0.799 -0.008

Beta indust 0.262 0.005 48.140 0.000 0.251 0.273

Gamma bar 254.350 2.730 93.150 0.000 248.999 259.702

Gamma food 57.799 1.397 41.370 0.000 55.061 60.537

Gamma othfood (dropped)

Page 195: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

177

A4.4-3. LES Model in the Central

Iteration 1: tolerance = .6732174 Iteration 2: tolerance = .04393632 Iteration 3: tolerance = .00471102 Iteration 4: tolerance = .00053876 Iteration 5: tolerance = .00006323 Iteration 6: tolerance = 7.536e-06 Iteration 7: tolerance = 9.066e-07 Seemingly unrelated regression, iterated

Equation Obs Parms RMSE 'R-sq' chi2 P

Main food 1252 4 289.8065 0.9258 18920.63 0.000

Other food 1252 4 263.4267 0.8166 14426.39 0.000

Industry 1252 4 272.7707 0.8479 15118.56 0.000

Coefficient Std. error t P>| t| [95% Conf. Interval]

Main food

Gamma food 51.020 1.254 40.690 0.000 48.562 53.477

Beta food 0.289 0.007 40.960 0.000 0.275 0.303

Gamma bar 244.249 2.805 87.090 0.000 238.752 249.745

Gamma othfood 0.000 0.000 1.900 0.058 0.000 0.000

Gamma indust -1.009 0.213 -4.750 0.000 -1.425 -0.592

Other food

Gamma othfood 0.000 0.000 -2.640 0.008 0.000 0.000

Beta othfood 0.268 0.006 47.930 0.000 0.257 0.279

Gamma bar 244.249 2.805 87.090 0.000 238.752 249.745

Gamma food 51.020 1.254 40.690 0.000 48.562 53.477

Gamma indust -1.009 0.213 -4.750 0.000 -1.425 -0.592

Indust

Gamma indust -1.009 0.213 -4.750 0.000 -1.425 -0.592

Beta indust 0.310 0.006 48.680 0.000 0.298 0.323

Gamma bar 244.249 2.805 87.090 0.000 238.752 249.745

Gamma food 51.020 1.254 40.690 0.000 48.562 53.477

Gamma othfood (dropped)

Page 196: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

178

A4.4-4. LES Model in the South

Iteration 1: tolerance = .6650812 Iteration 2: tolerance = .3609569 Iteration 3: tolerance = .08167922 Iteration 4: tolerance = .01609599 Iteration 5: tolerance = .00372692 Iteration 6: tolerance = .00092618 Iteration 7: tolerance = .00023766 Iteration 8: tolerance = .00006185 Iteration 9: tolerance = .0000162 Iteration 10: tolerance = 4.253e-06 Iteration 11: tolerance = 1.118e-06 Iteration 12: tolerance = 2.940e-07 Seemingly unrelated regression, iterated

Equation Obs Parms RMSE 'R-sq' chi2 P

Main food 224 4 377.4217 0.9223 2795.28 0.000

Other food 224 4 324.3866 0.8076 1860.86 0.000

Industry 224 4 403.193 0.8347 1985.05 0.000

Coefficient Std. error t P>| t| [95% Conf. Interval]

Main food

Gamma food 48.057 3.751 12.810 0.000 40.705 55.408

Beta food 0.294 0.017 17.090 0.000 0.261 0.328

Gamma bar 252.658 10.061 25.110 0.000 232.939 272.377

Gamma othfood 0.000 0.000 1.170 0.240 0.000 0.000

Gamma indust -0.254 0.601 -0.420 0.672 -1.432 0.924

Other food

Gamma othfood 0.000 0.000 -0.140 0.887 0.000 0.000

Beta othfood 0.252 0.012 21.420 0.000 0.229 0.276

Gamma bar 252.658 10.061 25.110 0.000 232.939 272.377

Gamma food 48.057 3.751 12.810 0.000 40.705 55.408

Gamma indust -0.254 0.601 -0.420 0.672 -1.432 0.924

Indust

Gamma indust -0.254 0.601 -0.420 0.672 -1.432 0.924

Beta indust 0.327 0.016 20.750 0.000 0.297 0.358

Gamma bar 252.658 10.061 25.110 0.000 232.939 272.377

Gamma food 48.057 3.751 12.810 0.000 40.705 55.408

Gamma othfood (dropped)

Page 197: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

179

A5.1: Household Response Elasticities with Farm Profit Alternatively Exogenous

and Endogenous in NE+NW

Elasticities with consumption quantities/labour supply Variables

Main foods Other foods Industry and others Labour supply

P other foods -3E-16 -1 -7E-16 1.2E-16

P industrial goods 0.006 0.011 -1.033 -0.002

P main foods -0.661 -0.320 -0.335 0.059

P rice *ZX -0.672 -0.326 -0.341 0.060

ZX -0.355 0.307 0.321 -0.056

P pork *ZX -0.685 -0.332 -0.347 0.061

ZX -0.049 0.940 0.982 -0.173

P chicken *ZX -0.677 -0.328 -0.343 0.060

ZX -0.096 0.832 0.869 -0.153

Labour wage *ZX -0.231 -0.463 -0.483 0.269

ZX 0.555 1.108 1.158 -0.020

A5.2: Household Response Elasticities with Farm Profit Alternatively Exogenous

and Endogenous in the Central

Elasticities with consumption quantities/labour supply Variables

Main foods Other foods Industry and others Labour supply

P other foods 1E-16 -1 2E-16 -2.7E-17

P industrial goods 0.014 0.028 -1.068 -0.004

P main foods -0.658 -0.268 -0.294 0.035

P rice *ZX -0.669 -0.272 -0.299 0.036

ZX -0.622 -0.181 -0.199 0.024

P pork *ZX -0.683 -0.278 -0.305 0.037

ZX -0.748 -0.402 -0.442 0.053

P chicken *ZX -0.670 -0.272 -0.299 0.036

ZX -0.501 0.052 0.057 -0.007

Labour wage *ZX -0.275 -0.529 -0.581 0.202

ZX 0.591 1.137 1.249 -0.018

Page 198: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

180

A5.3: Household Response Elasticities with Farm Profit Alternatively Exogenous

and Endogenous in the South

Elasticities with consumption quantities/labour supply Variables

Main foods Other foods Industry and others Labour supply

P other foods 6E-18 -1 1E-17 -1.4E-18

P industrial goods 0.003 0.005 -1.011 -0.001

P main foods -0.706 -0.2107 -0.2141 0.030

P rice *ZX -0.714 -0.213 -0.217 0.031

ZX 0.942 2.628 2.669 -0.376

P pork *ZX -0.734 -0.219 -0.223 0.031

ZX 1.542 3.684 3.742 -0.527

P chicken *ZX -0.717 -0.214 -0.217 0.031

ZX 0.994 2.722 2.764 -0.389

Labour wage *ZX -0.248 -0.426 -0.433 0.204

ZX 0.585 1.003 1.019 0.000

Page 199: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

181

A5.4: Model structure and equation forms for each regions using in the household model Framework of the household model:

The detail of the model in equation form for each region: 1. Production functions:

058.0223.0048.0059.061.0)( 98.738 pesticidefertilizerseedRRDrice VVVDAF

058.0223.0048.0059.061.0

)( 16.751 pesticidefertilizerseedNWNErice VVVDAF

058.0223.0048.0059.061.0

)( 33.566 pesticidefertilizerseedCentralrice VVVDAF

058.0223.0048.0059.061.0

)( 35.622 pesticidefertilizerseedSouthrice VVVDAF

Page 200: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

182

095.00171.584.0

)( 31.1 pigpigpigRRDpig VDGF

095.00171.584.0

)( 56.1 pigpigpigNWNEpig VDGF

095.00171.584.0

)( 57.1 pigpigpigCentralpig VDGF

095.00171.584.0

)( 92.1 pigpigpigSouthpig VDGF

137.021.0.46.0

)( 23.1 chickenchickenchickenRRDchicken VDGF

137.021.0.46.0

)( 21.1 chickenchickenchickenNWNEchicken VDGF

137.021.0.46.0

)( 33.1 chickenchickenchickenCentralchicken VDGF

137.021.0.46.0

)( 86.1 chickenchickenchickenSouthchicken VDGF

in which A: land cultivation for rice production D: labour requirement V: variable inputs G: feed for pig or chicken 2. Utility functions – LES (of each individual people in the household):

)024.4ln(136.0)ln(334.0)363.61ln(308.0)35.206ln(071.0)35.206ln(152.0 mccsu ofdfdRRD

)ln(262.0)ln(245.0)8.57ln(321.0)35.254ln(065.0)35.254ln(107.0 mccsu ofdfdNWNE

Page 201: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

183

)ln(31.0)ln(268.0)020.51ln(289.0)25.244ln(052.0)25.244ln(081.0 mccsu ofdfdCentral

)ln(327.0)ln(252.0)057.48ln(294.0)66.252ln(042.0)66.252ln(084.0 mccsu ofdfdSouth

in which:

s is the quantity of time supplied to work activities

cfd is per capita consumption of main food group of commodity Cfd,

cofd is per capita consumption of commodity group of other foods Cofd,

m is per capita consumption of industrial goods and other expenditure M

3. Demand for main food group of the household:

)ln()ln(*

*

P

Mpw i

jjijii

)ln(097.0)ln(015.0)ln(016.0)ln(045.0)ln(029.0)ln(079.0)ln(185.0404.1*)(

RRD

RRDothmeatvegefishchicporkriceRRDrice

P

Mppppppw

)ln(069.0)ln(0018.0)ln(0026.0)ln(0026.0)ln(0005.0)ln(052.0)ln(08.0369.0*)(

RRD

RRDothmeatvegefishchicporkriceRRDpork

P

Mppppppw

)ln(0044.0)ln(0016.0)ln(009.0)ln(006.0)ln(034.0)ln(0005.0)ln(029.0034.0*)(

RRD

RRDothmeatvegefishchicporkriceRRDchicken

P

Mppppppw

)ln(0065.0)ln(0017.0)ln(0011.0)ln(012.0)ln(006.0)ln(026.0)ln(045.0025.0*)(

RRD

RRDothmeatvegefishchicporkriceRRDfish

P

Mppppppw

)ln(0132.0)ln(0020.0)ln(021.0)ln(0012.0)ln(009.0)ln(0026.0)ln(016.0184.0*)(

RRD

RRDothmeatvegefishchicporkriceRRDvege

P

Mppppppw

Page 202: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

184

)ln(030.0)ln(015.0)ln(0020.0)ln(0017.0)ln(0016.0)ln(0018.0)ln(015.0159.0*)(

RRD

RRDothmeatvegefishchicporkriceRRDothmeat

P

Mppppppw

)ln(046.0)ln(0036.0)ln(019.0)ln(013.0)ln(033.0)ln(0024.0)ln(064.0899.0*)(

NWNE

NWNEothmeatvegefishchicporkriceNWNErice

P

Mppppppw

)ln(023.0)ln(014.0)ln(0149.0)ln(0028.0)ln(0163.0)ln(045.0)ln(024.0002.0*)(

NWNE

NWNEothmeatvegefishchicporkriceNWNEpork

P

Mppppppw

)ln(0018.0)ln(0115.0)ln(0105.0)ln(007.0)ln(043.0)ln(0163.0)ln(033.0042.0*)(

NWNE

NWNEothmeatvegefishchicporkriceNWNEchicken

P

Mppppppw

)ln(0279.0)ln(0005.0)ln(0053.0)ln(072.0)ln(0076.0)ln(0028.0)ln(013.0151.0*)(

NWNE

NWNEothmeatvegefishchicporkriceNWNEfish

P

Mppppppw

)ln(0273.0)ln(0059.0)ln(0227.0)ln(0053.0)ln(0105.0)ln(0149.0)ln(019.0276.0*)(

NWNE

NWNEothmeatvegefishchicporkriceNWNEvege

P

Mppppppw

)ln(020.0)ln(016.0)ln(0059.0)ln(0005.0)ln(0115.0)ln(0142.0)ln(0036.0065.0*)(

NWNE

NWNEothmeatvegefishchicporkriceNWNEothmeat

P

Mppppppw

)ln(1.0)ln(046.0)ln(0057.0)ln(053.0)ln(0042.0)ln(019.0)ln(1181.0331.1*)(

Central

CentralothmeatvegefishchicporkriceCentralrice

P

Mppppppw

)ln(037.0)ln(0004.0)ln(0098.0)ln(0084.0)ln(0181.0)ln(036.0)ln(017.0139.0*)(

Central

CentralothmeatvegefishchicporkriceCentralpork

P

Mppppppw

)ln(0091.0)ln(0011.0)ln(0011.0)ln(015.0)ln(0012.0)ln(018.0)ln(042.0017.0*)(

Central

CentralothmeatvegefishchicporkriceCentralchicken

P

Mppppppw

)ln(031.0)ln(0147.0)ln(0014.0)ln(017.0)ln(015.0)ln(0084.0)ln(053.0138.0*)(

Central

CentralothmeatvegefishchicporkriceCentralfish

P

Mppppppw

)ln(0006.0)ln(0107.0)ln(0073.0)ln(0014.0)ln(0019.0)ln(0098.0)ln(0057.0081.0*)(

Central

CentralothmeatvegefishchicporkriceCentralvege

P

Mppppppw

)ln(024.0)ln(022.0)ln(0107.0)ln(0145.0)ln(0011.0)ln(0004.0)ln(046.0151.0*)(

Central

CentralothmeatvegefishchicporkriceCentralothmeat

P

Mppppppw

)ln(103.0)ln(019.0)ln(033.0)ln(083.0)ln(0105.0)ln(041.0)ln(187.0346.1*)(

South

SouthothmeatvegefishchicporkriceSouthrice

P

Mppppppw

Page 203: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

185

)ln(058.0)ln(023.0)ln(0033.0)ln(042.0)ln(0144.0)ln(017.0)ln(041.0262.0*)(

South

SouthothmeatvegefishchicporkriceSouthpork

P

Mppppppw

)ln(0065.0)ln(0055.0)ln(0056.0)ln(0006.0)ln(0145.0)ln(0144.0)ln(0105.0022.0*)(

South

SouthothmeatvegefishchicporkriceSouthchicken

P

Mppppppw

)ln(014.0)ln(0056.0)ln(014.0)ln(0033.0)ln(0006.0)ln(042.0)ln(083.00052.0*)(

South

SouthothmeatvegefishchicporkriceSouthfish

P

Mppppppw

)ln(0078.0)ln(0002.0)ln(0102.0)ln(0142.0)ln(0056.0)ln(0033.0)ln(033.00039.0*)(

South

SouthothmeatvegefishchicporkriceSouthvege

P

Mppppppw

)ln(017.0)ln(0038.0)ln(0002.0)ln(0056.0)ln(0055.0)ln(023.0)ln(019.01076.0*)(

South

SouthothmeatvegefishchicporkriceSouthothmeat

P

Mppppppw ii

in which

wi: budget share of a given food commodity pi: the price of commodity i i = rice, pork, chicken, fish and prawn, vegetable, and other meats M: household expenditure P: price index

Page 204: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

186

A6.1: Initial Values and Percentage Changes in Vietnamese Exports from Alternative Scenarios with Closure A

Sector Initial exports

(mill.USD)

Unilateral

(1)

AFTA

(2)

AFTA+3

(3)

VNM-USA

(4)

VNM-EU

(5)

Multilateral

(6)

Global

(7)

Paddy and processed rice 374 -8 57 65 -2 -4 12 42

Vegetable and fruit 257 -1 -7 7 -1 -10 4 10

Other crops 810 -2 -5 -18 -2 -10 -13 -24

Live Pig 2 1 -8 -2 -1 -13 -5 -13

LivePoultry 0 15 1 -17 0 -11 -4 -10

LiveOther 62 -2 -5 -17 0 -10 -3 -7

Pork, poultry, other meats 33 -9 -12 -45 0 -22 -20 -45

Beef and sheep meats 0 22 -6 -28 4 -22 2 15

Fishing 49 3 1 2 0 -5 2 7

Oilseed and vegetable oil 45 2 115 102 -2 -13 7 34

Processed food 1365 1 2 -12 -1 -7 -8 -19

Beverages and tobacco 22 6 12 19 0 6 8 19

Milk and dairy products 2 29 -1 278 73 -16 37 222

Natural res, petrol product 2346 3 -1 -1 -1 -4 0 -3

Chemical, rubber, plastic 495 -8 -1 194 -3 -16 28 140

Textile and apparel 4746 63 4 33 10 38 35 81

Manufactures 2313 11 20 10 -3 -12 2 0

Electronic 446 49 23 28 0 -5 14 26

Transport, communication 534 -2 -2 -7 -1 -8 -3 -8

Services 1552 -8 -4 -17 -3 -13 -11 -24

Source: GTAP simulation

Page 205: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

187

A6.2: Initial Values and Percentage Changes in Vietnamese Imports from Alternative Scenarios with Closure A

Sector Initial imports

(mill.USD)

Unilateral

(1)

AFTA

(2)

AFTA+3

(3)

VNM-USA

(4)

VNM-EU

(5)

Multilateral

(6)

Global

(7)

Paddy and processed rice 17 70 26 118 2 13 44 130

Vegetable and fruit 71 48 13 47 15 7 25 62

Other crops 225 17 6 16 2 6 8 21

Live Pig 5 2 1 11 1 5 6 13

LivePoultry 7 -2 3 3 0 5 3 4

LiveOther 29 3 2 12 1 6 6 16

Pork, poultry, other meats 20 69 47 66 9 27 33 104

Beef and sheep meats 7 9 2 4 4 -7 -1 5

Fishing 6 9 1 2 7 3 4 7

Oilseed and vegetable oil 90 14 23 28 1 3 10 25

Processed food 374 39 13 25 5 13 21 49

Beverages and tobacco 395 51 47 55 1 7 22 59

Milk and dairy products 239 19 4 11 3 7 12 26

Natural res, petrol product 1692 7 2 8 0 0 4 8

Chemical, rubber, plastic 2796 10 3 19 1 7 9 24

Textile and apparel 1848 78 11 57 11 37 41 101

Manufactures 6780 25 10 26 2 7 13 30

Electronic 1002 11 7 7 0 0 3 6

Transport, communication 2546 1 0 2 1 4 2 5

Services 6997 5 2 10 1 7 6 15

Source: GTAP simulation

Page 206: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

188

A6.3: Price Changes of Consumption Commodities under Alternative GTAP Scenarios with Closure A (percentage)

Commodities Unilateral

(1)

AFTA

(2)

AFTA+3

(3)

VNM-USA

(4)

VNM-EU

(5)

Multilateral

(6)

Global

(7)

Paddy and processed rice 1.77 3.64 9.79 0.54 3.58 3.7 9.96

Vegetable and fruit -0.58 2.15 8.38 -0.05 3.11 2.84 7.87

Other crops -2.6 -0.47 2.19 0.08 1.54 -0.22 0.72

Live Pig -0.18 2.02 7.93 0.36 3.62 2.87 7.59

Live Poultry -3.3 2.05 7.59 0.03 2.94 1.98 5.68

Live Other 0.17 0.71 4.73 0.23 3.02 1.66 4.58

Pork, poultry, other meats -1.83 -0.38 3.67 0.11 2.33 1.3 2.25

Beef and sheep meats -2.64 0.84 3.77 -0.52 3.33 1.07 2.36

Fishing -1.75 0.01 0.78 0.51 2.64 0.01 -0.47

Oilseed and vegetable oil -14.74 -13.31 -12.49 -0.02 0.65 -6.14 -13.76

Processed food -6.37 -1.05 0.46 -0.17 1.21 -1.88 -4.1

Beverages and tobacco -22.46 -18 -19.47 0.12 1.08 -9.12 -20.15

Milk and dairy products -10.77 -1.45 -0.39 -0.34 0.94 -3.71 -7.62

Natural res, petrol product -7.2 -1.16 -6.92 -0.24 -0.16 -3.5 -7.27

Chemical, rubber, plastic -2.35 -0.56 0.12 0.19 0.99 -0.58 -0.85

Textile and apparel -14.59 -1.54 -10.21 -0.78 -0.31 -6.23 -13.71

Manufactures -7.88 -1.64 -5.95 0.2 1.08 -2.66 -6.07

Electronic -8.47 -4.56 -6.42 -0.47 -1.27 -3.95 -8.27

Transport, communication 0.18 0.21 0.73 0.17 0.95 0.37 1.1

Services 1.58 0.71 3.47 0.54 2.72 1.95 4.85

Source: GTAP simulation

Page 207: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

189

A6.4: Changes of Trade Balance under Alternative GTAP Scenarios with Closure B (mill. USD)

Sectors Unilateral

(1)

AFTA

(2)

AFTA+3

(3)

VNM-USA

(4)

VNM-EU

(5)

Multilateral

(6)

Global

(7)

Paddy and processed rice -25 232 297 -5 -2 57 199

Vegetable and fruit -45 -24 -2 -13 -25 -3 -10

Other crops -57 -50 -164 -15 -82 -115 -235

Live Pig -1 0 -1 0 -1 -1 -2

Live Poultry -1 -1 -2 0 -1 -1 -2

Live Other 7 -1 -3 0 -4 3 7

Pork, poultry, other meats -17 -13 -29 -2 -13 -13 -37

Beef and sheep meats -1 0 -1 0 0 0 -1

Fishing -2 -1 -2 0 -2 0 0

Oilseed and vegetable oil -15 37 30 -2 -9 -6 -4

Processed food -170 -23 -232 -25 -124 -187 -449

Beverages and tobacco -224 -193 -242 -7 -34 -96 -265

Milk and dairy products -61 -15 -34 -6 -31 -40 -89

Natural res, petrol product -189 -94 -287 -27 -115 -135 -328

Chemical, rubber, plastic -450 -123 428 -64 -311 -161 -13

Textile and apparel 1388 48 621 275 1337 948 2112

Manufactures -1719 -284 -1783 -182 -826 -965 -2358

Electronic 44 8 4 -7 -33 1 -2

Transport, communication -175 -66 -241 -39 -198 -156 -361

Services -617 -234 -1103 -154 -772 -683 -1598

Source: GTAP simulation

Page 208: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

190

A6.5: Price Changes of Consumption Commodities under Alternative GTAP Scenarios with Closure B (percentage)

Commodities Unilateral

(1)

AFTA

(2)

AFTA+3

(3)

VNM-USA

(4)

VNM-EU

(5)

Multilateral

(6)

Global

(7)

Paddy and processed rice 0.98 3.43 9.17 0.49 3.37 3.33 9.17

Vegetable and fruit -0.19 2.35 9.15 -0.01 3.35 3.24 8.96

Other crops -2.78 -0.52 2.04 0.07 1.5 -0.31 0.5

Live Pig 1.56 2.7 10.29 0.52 4.37 4.09 10.8

Live Poultry 4.26 4.75 16.55 0.69 5.84 6.76 17.7

Live Other -3.89 -0.63 0.57 -0.11 1.6 -0.67 -0.91

Pork, poultry, other meats -2.12 -0.41 3.64 0.1 2.3 1.24 2.23

Beef and sheep meats -1.6 1.26 5.19 -0.42 3.78 1.81 4.27

Fishing 2.5 1.5 5.5 0.87 4.27 2.64 5.48

Oilseed and vegetable oil -14.9 -13.42 -12.72 -0.04 0.57 -6.3 -14.04

Processed food -6.17 -0.92 0.81 -0.14 1.35 -1.68 -3.73

Beverages and tobacco -23.26 -18.25 -20.27 0.04 0.74 -9.63 -21.22

Milk and dairy products -11.33 -1.68 -1.09 -0.4 0.7 -4.07 -8.34

Natural res, petrol product -7.19 -1.09 -6.79 -0.24 -0.15 -3.26 -6.8

Chemical, rubber, plastic -3.15 -0.83 -0.71 0.13 0.72 -1.04 -1.88

Textile and apparel -15.13 -1.8 -10.82 -0.84 -0.55 -6.62 -14.46

Manufactures -8.56 -1.9 -6.66 0.13 0.81 -3.1 -7.04

Electronic -8.53 -4.65 -6.58 -0.47 -1.29 -4.03 -8.46

Transport, communication -0.25 0.1 0.32 0.14 0.82 0.18 0.59

Services 0.11 0.27 2.01 0.43 2.26 1.15 2.85

Source: GTAP simulation

Page 209: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

191

A6.6: Percentage Changes in Vietnamese Outputs under Alternative GTAP Scenarios with Closure C (R=12%)

Sector Unilateral

(1)

AFTA

(2)

AFTA+3

(3)

VNM-USA

(4)

VNM-EU

(5)

Multilateral

(6)

Global

(7)

Paddy and processed rice 0 7 9 0 1 3 6

Vegetable and fruit -2 -2 -1 0 0 0 -1

Other crops -3 -5 -12 -1 -5 -7 -16

Live Pig 5 2 6 1 5 6 8

Live Poultry 4 1 4 1 4 5 6

Live Other 2 0 -1 0 0 2 -1

Pork, poultry, other meats -9 -8 -18 -1 -7 -7 -24

Beef and sheep meats -3 0 -3 -1 1 -1 -7

Fishing 1 1 1 0 1 1 -1

Oilseed and vegetable oil -13 39 32 -1 -7 -4 -2

Processed food -5 -1 -9 -1 -5 -7 -17

Beverages and tobacco -19 -16 -17 0 2 -6 -18

Milk and dairy products -20 -2 2 0 0 -5 -17

Natural res, petrol product -3 0 -6 -1 -3 -2 -8

Chemical, rubber, plastic -3 0 39 0 -3 7 25

Textile and apparel 41 4 19 7 32 26 51

Manufactures -11 3 -13 -1 -5 -5 -18

Electronic 50 23 30 0 -3 17 28

Transport, communication 4 1 0 0 -3 2 -2

Services 9 3 8 1 4 6 9

Source: GTAP simulation

Page 210: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

192

A6.7: Percentage Changes in Vietnamese Exports from Alternative Scenarios with Closure C (R=12%)

Sector Unilateral

(1)

AFTA

(2)

AFTA+3

(3)

VNM-USA

(4)

VNM-EU

(5)

Multilateral

(6)

Global

(7)

Paddy and processed rice -6 58 68 -2 -3 13 44

Vegetable and fruit -2 -8 6 -1 -10 3 9

Other crops -1 -5 -17 -1 -10 -12 -23

Live Pig -4 -10 -7 -2 -15 -8 -15

LivePoultry -7 -9 -33 -3 -21 -20 -27

LiveOther 11 0 -6 1 -5 8 6

Pork, poultry, other meats -6 -11 -45 0 -22 -19 -43

Beef and sheep meats 16 -9 -33 3 -24 -3 8

Fishing -2 -2 -4 -1 -8 -2 3

Oilseed and vegetable oil 6 118 109 -2 -12 10 39

Processed food 1 1 -12 -1 -8 -9 -20

Beverages and tobacco 9 14 22 1 7 11 23

Milk and dairy products 40 3 311 75 -13 46 251

Natural res, petrol product 4 -1 0 -1 -4 0 -1

Chemical, rubber, plastic 0 3 219 -2 -12 38 164

Textile and apparel 74 7 41 10 42 41 90

Manufactures 19 23 17 -2 -10 7 7

Electronic 59 27 37 1 -3 21 36

Transport, communication 1 -1 -4 -1 -7 -1 -6

Services -3 -1 -13 -2 -11 -7 -20

Source: GTAP simulation

Page 211: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

193

A6.8: Percentage Changes in Vietnamese Imports from Alternative Scenarios with Closure C (R=12%)

Sector Unilateral

(1)

AFTA

(2)

AFTA+3

(3)

VNM-USA

(4)

VNM-EU

(5)

Multilateral

(6)

Global

(7)

Paddy and processed rice 71 26 120 2 14 44 131

Vegetable and fruit 54 15 53 16 9 29 69

Other crops 21 8 20 2 8 11 25

Live Pig 8 4 18 1 9 12 21

LivePoultry 9 9 16 2 11 13 17

LiveOther 3 2 12 1 6 7 16

Pork, poultry, other meats 73 50 72 10 30 37 111

Beef and sheep meats 14 4 9 5 -5 3 10

Fishing 17 4 8 7 6 10 13

Oilseed and vegetable oil 18 25 33 1 5 13 29

Processed food 44 15 29 5 15 24 55

Beverages and tobacco 55 49 59 2 9 25 63

Milk and dairy products 24 6 15 3 9 16 31

Natural res, petrol product 13 5 13 1 2 8 14

Chemical, rubber, plastic 15 5 24 2 9 13 29

Textile and apparel 87 14 64 11 40 46 109

Manufactures 30 12 30 2 10 17 35

Electronic 17 10 12 1 2 8 12

Transport, communication 5 2 7 1 6 6 10

Services 7 3 13 2 9 9 18

Source: GTAP simulation

Page 212: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

194

A7.1: Estimated Parameters on Price Interrelation between Regions and National

Level for Some Main Commodities

Commodity Red River Delta NE+NW The Central The South

Rice 1.083515

(-1.47)

1.206036

(-2.48)**

0.89411138

(0.96)

0.7123662

(5.69)*

Paddy 0.958295

(1.87)

0.99446

(0.29)

0.985169

(0.74)

1.093085

(-3.03)*

Pig 0.9678404

(0.66)

1.334515

(-7.95)*

0.9001949

(2.95)*

0.9679933

(0.52)

Chicken 1.060107

(-3.68)*

1.086309

(-5.54)*

0.849838

(6.16)*

1.029625

(-1.44)

Beef .9649945

(0.90)

1.04176

(-1.24)

0.9984677

(0.06)

1.079186

(-1.61)

Maize 0.958644

(0.78)

0.801897

(4.64)*

1.204399

(-6.06)*

1.02281

(-0.38)

Soybean 0.979604

(0.81)

0.987675

(0.53)

0.847164

(8.64)*

1.139757

(-7.22)*

Cassava 1.163563

(-2.63)*

1.094039

(-1.78)

0.731602

(8.48)*

0.997324

(0.06)

Orange 1.156382

(-2.95)*

1.018733

(-0.33)

0.928677

(1.47)

0.91281

(1.65)

Tomato 0.996818

(-0.04)

1.092844

(-1.55)

0.955616

(0.53)

1.031711

(-0.87)

Chemical fertiliser 1.027977

(-1.55)

1.036671

(-1.73)

1.005628

(-0.69)

0.9123972

(3.41)*

*: indicates significant different from 1 at 1% level, ** at 5% level of confidence

Numbers in parentheses are t values for testing of divergence of parameter from 1

Page 213: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

195

A7.2: Welfare Changes of Households in Different Regions under Alternative

Trade Scenarios

A7.2a: Welfare Changes of Households in Different Regions under Unilateral Trade Scenario

0

200

400

600

800

1000

RRD NE+NW the Central the South

region

000V

ND

5.0%

6.0%

7.0%

chan

ge c

ompa

re w

ith

base

line

A7.2b: Welfare Changes of Households in Different Regions under AFTA Scenario

-200

0

200

400

600

800

1000

1200

RRD NE+NW the Central the South

region

000V

ND

-1%

1%

3%

5%

7%

chan

ge c

ompa

re w

ith

base

line

A7.2c: Welfare Changes of Households in Different Regions under AFTA+3 Scenario

0

500

1000

1500

2000

2500

3000

RRD NE+NW the Central the Southregion

000V

ND

0%

5%

10%

15%

20%

25%ch

ange

com

pare

with

ba

selin

e

A7.2d: Welfare Changes of Households in Different Regions under VNM-EU Scenario

-200

0

200

400

600

800

RRD NE+NW the Central the South

region

000V

ND

-2%

0%

2%

4%

6%

chan

ge c

ompa

re w

ith

base

line

A7.2e: Welfare Changes of Households in Different Regions under Multilateral Scenario

0

200

400

600

800

1000

RRD NE+NW the Central the Southregion

000V

ND

0%

2%

4%

6%

8%

chan

ge c

ompa

re w

ith

base

line

A7.2g: Welfare Changes of Households in Different Regions under Global Scenario

0

500

1000

1500

2000

2500

3000

3500

RRD NE+NW the Central the Southregion

000V

ND

0%

5%

10%

15%

20%

25%

chan

ge c

ompa

re w

ith

base

line

Source: Household model simulation

Note: Bar graph: change in welfare in terms of value compare with baseline ('000 VND)

Line graph: percentage change of welfare compare with baseline

Page 214: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

196

A.7.3 Changes in Consumption of Households under AFTA+3 Scenario

A7.3a: Changes in Consumption of Households in Different Regions under AFTA+3

Scenario

0%

5%

10%

15%

20%

25%

30%

RRD NE+NW the Central the South

region

chan

ge c

ompa

re w

ith b

asel

ine

Main food Oth foods Ind & oth exp

A7.3b: Changes in Main Food Consumption Quantity of Households in Different Regions

under AFTA+3 Scenario

-2%

0%

2%

4%

6%

8%

10%

RRD NE+NW the Central the South

region

chan

ge c

ompa

re w

ith b

asel

ine

Rice Pork Chicken Fish-shrimp Vegetable Other meats

Page 215: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

197

A7.4: Production Changes of Households under Alternative Scenarios

Production Changes in RRD Households under Alternative Scenarios

-20%

-10%

0%

10%

20%

30%

40%

50%

Uni AFTA AFTA+3 VNM-USA VNM-EU Multi Glob

scenario

chan

ge c

ompa

re w

ith b

asel

ine

Rice Pig Chicken

Production Changes in NE+NW Household under Alternative Scenarios

-20%

-10%

0%

10%

20%

30%

uni AFTA AFTA+3 VNM-EU Multi Glob

scenario

chan

ge c

ompa

re w

ith b

asel

ine

Rice Pig Chicken

Production Changes in the Central Household under Alternative Scenarios

-4%

0%

4%

8%

12%

16%

uni AFTA AFTA+3 VNM-EU Multi Glob

scenario

chan

ge c

ompa

re w

ith b

asel

ine

Rice Pig Chicken

Production Changes in the South Household under Alternative Scenarios

0%

4%

8%

12%

16%

20%

uni AFTA AFTA+3 VNM-EU Multi Glob

scenario

chan

ge c

ompa

re w

ith b

asel

ine

Rice Pig Chicken

Page 216: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

198

A7.5: Welfare Changes of Households under Alternative Scenarios

Welfare Change in RRD Household under Alternative Scenarios

-2%

2%

6%

10%

14%

18%

22%

Unilateral AFTA AFTA+3 VNM-USA VNM-EU Multilateral Global

scenario

cha

ng

e c

om

pa

re w

ith b

ase

line

Welfare change compare w ith baseline (%) Welfare change due to leisure change (%)

Welfare Change in NE+NW Household under Alternative Scenarios

-2%

2%

6%

10%

14%

Unilateral AFTA AFTA+3 VNM-EU Multilateral Global

scenario

chan

ge c

ompa

re w

ith b

asel

ine

Welfare change compare w ith baseline (%) Welfare change due to leisure change (%)

Welfare Change in the Central Household under Alternative Scenarios

0%

4%

8%

12%

16%

20%

Unilateral AFTA AFTA+3 VNM-EU Multilateral Global

scenario

chan

ge c

ompa

re w

ith b

asel

ine

Welfare change compare w ith baseline (%) Welfare change due to leisure change (%)

Welfare Change in the South Household under Alternative Scenarios

0%

5%

10%

15%

20%

25%

Unilateral AFTA AFTA+3 VNM-EU Multilateral Global

scenario

chan

ge c

ompa

re w

ith

base

line

Welfare change compare w ith baseline (%) Welfare change due to leisure change (%)

Page 217: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

199

A7.6: Changes in Consumption Quantities of Households under Alternative Scenarios

Consumption Change in RRD Household under Alternative Scenarios

-10%

0%

10%

20%

30%

40%

Unilateral AFTA AFTA+3 VNM-USA VNM-EU Multilateral Global

scenario

chan

ge c

ompa

re w

ith

base

line

Main foods Other foods Industrial goods & others

Consumption Change in NE+NW Household under Alternative Scenarios

-10%

0%

10%

20%

30%

Unilateral AFTA AFTA+3 VNM-EU Multilateral Global

scenario

chan

ge c

ompa

re w

ith

base

line

Main foods Other foods Industrial goods & others

Consumption Change in the Central Household under Alternative Scenarios

0%

10%

20%

30%

Unilateral AFTA AFTA+3 VNM-EU Multilateral Globalscenario

chan

ge c

ompa

re w

ith

base

line

Main foods Other foods Industrial goods & others

Consumption Change in the South Household under Alternative Scenarios

0%

10%

20%

30%

40%

Unilateral AFTA AFTA+3 VNM-EU Multilateral Global

scenario

chan

ge c

ompa

re w

ith

base

line

Main foods Other foods Industrial goods & others

Page 218: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

200

A7.7: Changes in Main Food Consumptions of Households under Alternative Scenarios

Main Food Consumption Changes in RRD Household under Alternative Scenarios

-3%

1%

5%

9%

Unilateral AFTA AFTA+3 VNM-USA VNM-EU Multilateral Global

scenario

chan

ge c

ompa

re w

ith

base

line

Rice Pork Chicken Fish-shrimp Vegetable Other meats

Main Food Consumption Changes in NE+NW Household under Alternative Scenarios

-6%

-4%

-2%

0%

2%

4%

6%

Unilateral AFTA AFTA+3 VNM-EU Multilateral Global

scenario

chan

ge c

ompa

re w

ith

base

line

Rice Pork Chicken Fish-shrimp Vegetable Other meats

Main Food Consumption Changes in the Central Household under Alternative Scenarios

-4%

-2%

0%

2%

4%

6%

8%

Unilateral AFTA AFTA+3 VNM-EU Multilateral Global

scenario

chan

ge c

ompa

re w

ith

base

line

Rice Pork Chicken Fish-shrimp Vegetable Other meats

Main Food Consumption Changes in the South Household under Alternative Scenarios

-4%

0%

4%

8%

12%

Unilateral AFTA AFTA+3 VNM-EU Multilateral Global

scenario

chan

ge c

ompa

re w

ith

base

line

Rice Pork Chicken Fish-shrimp Vegetable Other meats

Page 219: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

201

A7.8: Changes in Time Allocation of Households under Alternative Scenarios

Time Allocation Changes in RRD Household under Alternative Scenrios

-20%

0%

20%

40%

60%

Uni AFTA AFTA+3 VNM-USA VNM-EU Multi Glob

scenario

chan

ge c

ompa

re w

ith

base

line

leisure day onfarm day off-farm

Time Allocation Changes in NE+NW Household under Alternative Scenarios

-20%

0%

20%

40%

60%

80%

100%

Unilateral AFTA AFTA+3 VNM-EU Multilateral Global

scenario

chan

ge c

ompa

re w

ith

base

line

leisure day onfarm day off-farm

Time Allocation in the Central Household under Alternative Scenarios

-4%

0%

4%

8%

12%

Unilateral AFTA AFTA+3 VNM-EU Multilateral Global

scenario

chan

ge c

ompa

re w

ith

base

line

leisure day onfarm day off-farm

Time Allocation Change in the South Household under Alternative Scenarios

-8%

-4%

0%

4%

8%

12%

Unilateral AFTA AFTA+3 VNM-EU Multilateral Global

scenario

chan

ge c

ompa

re w

ith

base

line

leisure day onfarm day off-farm

Page 220: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

202

A7.9: Changes in Labour Allocation of Households under Alternative Scenarios with Different Assumptions on Labour Market

Labour Allocation Changes of RRD Household under Alternative Scenarios with Different Assumptions on Labour Market

-40%

-20%

0%

20%

40%

60%

Uni AFTA AFTA+3 VNM-EU Multi Glob

scenario

chan

ge c

ompa

re w

ith

base

line

day onfarm w ith Closure C day onfarm w ith Closure A

day off-farm w ith Closure C day off-farm w ith Closure A

Labour Allocation Changes in NE+NW Household under Alternative Scenarios with Different Assumptions on Labour

Market

-20%

0%

20%

40%

60%

80%

100%

Unilateral AFTA AFTA+3 VNM-EU Multilateral Global

scenario

chan

ge c

ompa

re w

ith

base

line

day onfarm w ith Closure C day onfarm w ith Closure A

day off-farm w ith Closure C day off-farm w ith Closure A

Labour Allocation Changes in the Central Household under Alternative Scenarios with Different Assumptions on Labour

Market

-15%

-10%

-5%

0%

5%

10%

15%

Unilateral AFTA AFTA+3 VNM-EU Multilateral Global

scenario

chan

ge c

ompa

re

with

bas

elin

e

day onfarm w ith Closure C day onfarm w ith Closure A

day off-farm w ith Closure C day off-farm w ith Closure A

Labour Allocation Changes in the South Household under Alternative Scenarios with Different Assumptions on

Labour Market

-10%

-5%

0%

5%

10%

Unilateral AFTA AFTA+3 VNM-EU Multilateral Global

scenario

chan

ge c

ompa

re w

ith

base

line

day onfarm w ith Closure C day onfarm w ith Closure A

day off-farm w ith Closure C day off-farm w ith Closure A

Page 221: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

203

A7.10: Welfare Changes in Households under Alternative Scenarios with Different Assumptions on Labour Market

Welfare Change in RRD Household under Alternative Scenarios with Different Assumptions on Labour Market

0

1000

2000

3000

Uni AFTA AFTA+3 VNM-EU Multi Globscenario

chan

ge c

ompa

re w

ith

base

line

(000

VN

D)

Welfare change w ith Closure C Welfare change w ith Closure A

Welfare Change in NE+NW Household under Alternative Scenarios with Different Assumptions on Labour Market

0

1000

2000

3000

Unilateral AFTA AFTA+3 VNM-EU Multilateral Globalsecenario

chan

ge c

ompa

re w

ith b

asel

ine

(000

VN

D)

Welfare change w ith Closure C Welfare change w ith Closure A

Welfare Change in the Central Household under Alternative with Different Assumptions on Labour Market

0

500

1000

1500

2000

2500

Unilateral AFTA AFTA+3 VNM-EU Multilateral Global

scenario

chan

ge c

ompa

re w

ith

base

line

(000

VN

D)

Welfare change w ith Closure C Welfare change w ith Closure A

Welfare Change in the South Household under Alternative Scenarios with Different Assumptions on Labour Market

0

1000

2000

3000

4000

Unilateral AFTA AFTA+3 VNM-EU Multilateral Global

scenario

chan

ge c

ompa

re w

ith b

asel

ine

(000

VN

D)

Welfare change w ith Closure C Welfare change w ith Closure A

Page 222: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

204

A7.11: Percentage Changes in Unskilled Labour Demand in Sectors from Alternative Scenarios with Closure C (R=12%) (percentage)

Sector Unilateral

(1)

AFTA

(2)

AFTA+3

(3)

VNM-USA

(4)

VNM-EU

(5)

Multilateral

(6)

Global

(7)

Paddy and processed rice 1.53 10.11 13.79 0.34 2.44 5.94 9.36

Vegetable and fruit -1.31 -0.6 0.7 -0.36 0.07 1.43 -0.56

Other crops -2.82 -4.1 -11.65 -0.66 -4.65 -6.67 -16.69

Live Pig 5.63 3.08 8.6 1.25 5.88 8 9.61

LivePoultry 5.34 2.93 8.01 1.2 5.52 7.81 8.53

LiveOther 2.37 -0.09 -0.5 0.48 0.46 2.23 -0.41

Pork, poultry, other meats -5.84 -6.33 -14.5 -0.46 -5.3 -4.45 -20.92

Beef and sheep meats 2.92 2.86 2.3 -0.6 4.29 3.8 -2.32

Fishing 2.06 1.79 1.83 0.48 1.77 2.35 -1.05

Oilseed and vegetable oil -12.95 49.14 42.21 -1.01 -6.85 -1.62 0.45

Processed food 3.25 3.16 -1.46 0.29 -0.35 -0.03 -9.63

Beverages and tobacco -13.1 -13.42 -11.9 1.22 5.33 -0.6 -12.33

Milk and dairy products -16.49 0.37 6.11 0.34 2.41 -1.84 -13.76

Natural res, petrol product -3.04 0.05 -6.64 -0.66 -3.59 -1.96 -9.11

Chemical, rubber, plastic 5.23 3.71 49.49 0.63 1.28 13.75 34.14

Textile and apparel 53.1 7.99 28.63 7.89 37.26 34.2 62.55

Manufactures -3.42 7.16 -5.55 0.19 -0.25 1.77 -11.37

Electronic 61.6 27.47 39.77 1.2 0.61 24.83 38.14

Transport, communication 16.12 6.37 10.53 1.13 3.27 11.69 9.51

Services 19.54 7.93 17.92 2.06 8.72 14.88 18.97

Source: GTAP simulation

Page 223: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

205

REFERENCES

Abbott, M. & Ashenfelter, O. 1976, ‘Labour Supply, Commodity Demand and the

Allocation of Time’, Review of Economics Studies, vol. 63, no.135, pp. 389–412.

Abbott, P., Bentzen, J. & Tarp, F. 2007, Vietnam’s Accession to the WTO: Lessons from

Past Trade Agreements, Disscussion paper, Department of Economics, University of

Copenhagen, Denmark.

Akter, S., Jabbar, M.A. & Ehui, S.K. 2003, Competitiveness and Efficiency in Poultry and

Pig Production in Vietnam, ILRI, Kenya.

AusAid. 2004, The impact of trade liberalization on livestock sector in Vietnam. Hanoi,

December 2004. Mimeograph.

Asche, F. & Wessells, C.R. 1997, ‘On Price Indices in the Almost Ideal Demand System’,

American Journal of Agricultural Economics, vol. 79, pp.1182–1185.

Barnum, H.N. & Squire, L. 1979a, A Model of an Agricultural Household: Theory and

Evident, published for the World Bank, The John Hopkins University Press, Baltimore and

London.

Barnum, H.N. & Squire, L. 1979b, ‘An Econometric Application of the Theory of the

Farm-Household’, Journal of Development Economics, vol. 6, pp. 79–102.

Baumal, W.J. & Blinder, A.S. 1988, Economics Principles and Policy, 4th edition, Harcourt

Brace Jovanovich Publishers.

Becker, G. 1965, ‘A Theory of the Allocation of Time’, Economic Journal, vol. 75, pp.

493–517.

Becker, G. 1991, A Treatise on the Family, Harvard University Press.

Benjamin, D. 1992, ‘Household Composition, Labour Markets, and Labour Demand:

Testing for Separation in Agricultural Household Models’, Econometrica, vol.60, pp. 287–

322.

Berges, M.E. & Casellas, K.S. 2002, A Demand System Analysis of Food for Poor and

Non-poor Households: The Case of Argentina, Mal del Plata University, Argentina.

Page 224: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

206

Braverman, A. & Hammer, J.S. 1986, ‘Multi-Market Analysis of Agricultural Pricing

Policies in Senegal’, in Agricultural Household Models: Extensions, Applications, and

Policy, eds. I. Singh, L. Squire & J. Strauss, the Johns Hopkins University Press, Baltimore

and London, pp. 233–254.

Castella, J.C. & Dang, D.Q (eds.) 2002, Doi moi in the Mountains: Land Use Changes and

Farmers Livelihood Strategies in Bac Kan Province, Vietnam, The Agricultural Publishing

House, Hanoi, Vietnam.

Chen, S. & Ravallion, M. 2002, ‘Household Welfare Impacts of China’s Accession to the

WTO’, Paper presentated at the Fourth Asia Development Forum Trade and Poverty

Reduction, Seoul, Korea, 3-5 Nov 2002.

Daude, S. 2004, ‘The Doha Development Round and its Poverty Implications for a WTO

Accession Candidate: The Case of Vietnam’, 7th Annual Conference on Global Economic

Analysis, Available from: <www.gtap.org>. [14 Sep 2007]

Deaton A. & Muellbauer, J. 1980, Economics and Consumer Behaviour, Cambridge

University Press.

Deolalikar, A.B. & Vijverberg, W. 1987, ‘A Test of the Heterogeneity of Family and Hired

Labour in Asian Agriculture’, Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, vol.49, pp. 291–

305.

Dimaranan, B.V. (ed.) 2006, Global Trade, Assistance, and Production: The GTAP 6

Database, Center for Global Trade Analysis, Purdue University. Available from:

<https://www.gtap.agecon.purdue.edu/databases/v6/v6_doco.asp>. [18 Jan 2007]

Dimaranan, B., Le. T. D, & Martin, W. 2005, Potential Economic Impacts of Merchandise

Trade Liberalization under Viet Nam’s Accession to the WTO, GTAP Resource # 1777,

GTAP Resource Centre, Purdue University.

Dinh, X.T., Nguyen, T.T. & Tran, C.T. 2006, Pork and Poultry Markets in Vietnam, Hanoi,

Vietnam.

Edmeades, S., Smale, M., Renkow, M. & Phaneuf, D. 2004, Variety Demand within the

Framework of an Agricultural Household Model with Attributes: the Case of Bananas in

Uganda, EPTD Discussion Paper No. 125, IFPRI, Washington D.C, USA

Page 225: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

207

Ellis, F. 1988, Peasant Economics: Farm Households and Agrarian Development,

Cambridge University Press.

FAO. 2005, FAO Statistical Year Book 2004, [Online], Available from:

<http://www.fao.org/statistics/yearbook> [20 Oct 2007]

FAOStat. (2008). [Online], Available from: <http://faostat.fao.org/site/345/default.aspx> [4

Sep 2008]

Francois, J., Meijl, H. V. & Tongeren, F.V. 2003, Trade Liberalisation and Developing

Countries under the Doha Round, Discussion Paper Series No. 4032, London, Centre for

Economic Policy Research (CEPR), UK.

GSO. (2008). [Online], Available from:

http://www.gso.gov.vn/default.aspx?tabid=430&idmid=3>. [28 Aug 2008]

GSO. 2004, Survey Guidance for Vietnam Household Living Standard Survey 2004 [in

Vietnamese], Ha Noi, Vietnam

GSO. Agricultral Census 1994 (Database), Ha Noi, Vietnam

GSO. Agricultural Census 2001 (Database), Ha Noi, Vietnam

GSO. Agricultural Census 2006 (Database), Ha Noi, Vietnam

GSO. Review: 'Today Index Price', Price and Trade Department, Hanoi, Vietnam

GSO. Vietnam Household Living Standard Survey 2002 (Database), Ha Noi, Vietnam

GSO. Vietnam Household Living Standard Survey 2004 (Database), Ha Noi, Vietnam

GSO. Vietnam Household Living Standard Survey 2006 (Database), Ha Noi, Vietnam

GSO. Vietnam Living Standard Survey 1998 (Database), Ha Noi, Vietnam

GTAP Model 6.2. (2007). [Online], Available from:

https://www.gtap.agecon.purdue.edu/models/current.asp>. [20 May 2007]

Haughton, J. 1985, ‘Farm Price Responsiveness and the Choice of Functional Form: An

Application to Rice Cultivation in West Malaysia’, Journal of Development Economics,

Vol. 24, pp. 203–233.

Page 226: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

208

Hertel, T.W. & Tsigas, M.E. (eds.) 1997, Global Trade Analysis: Modelling and

Applications, Cambridge University Press, New York.

Hertzler, G. & MacAulay, T.G. 2000, ‘Modelling Farm Households in a Spatial Context:

Vietnamese Agriculture’, Paper presented at the 44th Annual Conference of the Australian

Agricultural and Resource Economics Society, Sydney, 23-25th Jan 2000.

Holst, D.R. 2004, ‘CGE Methods for Poverty Incidence Analysis: An Application to

Vietnam’s WTO Accession’, Paper presented at the 7th Annual Conference on Global

Economic Analysis, 17-19th Jun 2004, Washington D.C., USA.

IFPRI. 2001, Policy Option for Using Livestock to Promote Rural Income Diversification

and Growth in Vietnam, Hanoi, Vietnam.

IMF. (2008). [Online], Available from: <http://indexmundi.com/commodities>. [12 Sep

2008].

Jacoby, H. 1992, ‘Productivity of Men and Women and the Sexual Division of Labour in

Peasant Agriculture of the Peruvian Sierra’, Journal of Development Economics, vol. 37,

pp. 265–287.

Jacoby, H. 1993, ‘Shadow Wages and Peasant Family Labour Supply: An Econometric

Application to the Peruvian Sierra’, Review of Economic Studies, vol. 60, pp. 903–921.

Janvry, A.D., Sadoulet, E. & Davis, B. 1995, ‘NAFTA’s Impact on Mexico: Rural

Household – Level Effects’, American Journal of Agricultural Economics, vol. 77,

pp.1283-1291

Jensen, H.T. & Tarp, F. 2005, ‘Trade Liberalisation and Spatial Inequality: a

Methodological Innovation in a Vietnamese Perspective’, Review of Development

Economics, vol.9, pp. 69-86

Justino, P. & Litchfield, J. 2002, Poverty Dynamics in Rural Vietnam: Winners and Losers

During Reform, Poverty Research Unit, University of Sussex, UK.

Kumar, D.S. & Ramasamy, C. 2003, ‘Modelling Household Economy of Agro-forestry

Based Resource Poor Farmers: A Case of Silvipastoral System’, Indian Journal of

Agricultural Economics, vol. 58, pp.669-694

Page 227: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

209

Kurzweil, M. 2002, The Need for a 'Complete' Labour Market in CGE Modelling, GTAP

Working Paper. Available from: <www.gtap.org>. [14 Sep 2007]

Lapar, M.L., Vu, T.B. & Ehui, S. 2003, Identifying Barriers to Entry to Livestock Input and

Output Markets in Southeast Asia, Livestock Information, Sector Analysis and Policy

Branch, FAO, Rome.

Le, Q. P, 2001, ‘Vietnam’s International Economic Integration: An Assessment and

Implications’, in Vietnam’s Economy Entering XXI Century, eds. D.C. Pham, & N. B.Tran,

Hanoi.

Leod, A.M., Morgan, N., Prakash, A., & Hinrichs, J. 2005, Economic and Social Impacts of

Avian Influenza, FAO Emergency Centre for Transboundary Animal Diseases Operations

(ECTAD), FAO, Rome.

Lopez, R.E. 1986, ‘Structural Models of the Farm Household that Allow for Interdependent

Utility and Profit Maximization Decisions’, in Agricultural Household Models: Extensions,

Applications, and Policy, eds. I. Singh, L. Squire, & J. Strauss, The Johns Hopkins

University Press, Baltimore and London, pp. 306–326.

Luu, T.D.H. 2003, Rice Market in the Mekong River Delta, Vietnam: a Market Integration

Analysis, CAS Discussion Paper No.40.

MacAulay, T.G., Hertzler, G. & Marsh, S.P. 2001, ‘Modelling Vietnamese Households: A

Simple Economic Model of a Village’, Paper presented at the 45th Annual Conference of the

Australian Agricultural and Resource Economics Society, Adelaide, 23-25th Jan 2001.

MARD. 2005, Roadmap on International Economic Integration of Vietnam’s Agriculture,

Research Paper, Vietnam.

MARD. 2007, Animal Husbandry Strategy to 2020, Hanoi, Vietnam.

Mellor, J. 1963, ‘The Use and Productivity of Farm Labor in Early Stages of Agricultural

Development’, Journal of Farm Economics, vol.45, pp.517-34

Menon, M., Perali, F. & Rosati, F. 2005, The Shadow Wage of Child Labour: An

Application to Nepal, Research Paper under Project Understanding Children's Work, ILO -

WB - UNICEF

Page 228: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

210

Mincer, J. 1963, ‘Market Prices, Opportunity Costs, and Income Effects’, in Measurement

in Economics: Studies in Mathematical Economics and Econometrics in Memory of Yehada

Grunfeld, eds. C. Christ et al., Stanford University Press, Stanford.

Moschini, G. 1995, ‘Units of Measurement and the Stone Index in Demand System’,

American Journal of Agricultural Economics, vol. 77, pp. 63–68.

Moschini, G. 1998, ‘The Semi Flexible Almost Ideal Demand System’, European

Economics Review, vol. 42, pp. 346–364.

Nakajima, C. 1986, Subjective equilibrium theory of the farm household, Elsevier,

Amsterdam, New York.

Nguyen, C. & Tran, K. D. 2001, ‘Development of CGE Model to Evaluate Tariff Policy in

Vietnam’, Paper presented at the final dissemination seminar of the MIMAP Vietnam

Modeling Project, 30 August 2001, Hanoi.

Nguyen, T. 2004, The Poverty Impact of Doha: Vietnam, Department for International

Development, Overseas Development Institute, London.

Nguyen, T.D. & Ezaki, M. 2005, ‘Regional Economic Integration and its Impacts on

Growth, Poverty and Income Distribution: the Case of Vietnam’, The Applied Regional

Science Conference, Blackwell Publishing Asia Pty. Ltd.

Nguyen, T.S. & Tran, D.T. 2005, Research on Comparative Advantages of Some

Commodities as Inputs for Industrial Feed Processing in Vietnam [in Vietnamese], Hanoi

Agricultural University, Vietnam.

Nin, A., Lapar, M.L & Ehui, S. 2003, ‘Globalisation, Trade Liberalisation and Poverty

Alleviation in Southeast Asia: the Case of the Livestock Sector in Vietnam’, Paper presented

at the 6th Annual Conference on Global Economic Analysis, 12-14th Jun 2003, the Hague,

the Netherlands.

Oxfam. 2001, Rice for the Poor and Trade Liberalization in Vietnam, Final Draft Report,

Oxfam. [Online] Available from:

<http://www.maketradefair.com/en/assets/english/VietnamRiceResearch2001Final.pdf>

[15 Sep 2009]

Page 229: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

211

Pham, L. H. 2000, Impacts of Trade and Investment Policy on Income Distribution in

Vietnam Using a general Equilibrium Framework, Unpublished Ph. D. Thesis, ANU,

Canberra

Quazi, R.M. 1992, Consumption Behaviour of Agricultural Households in Rural

Bangladesh, Prairie View A&M University, Texas, USA.

Raper, K.C., Wanzala, M.N. & Nayga R.M. 2002, ‘Food Expenditures and Household

Demographic Composition in the US: a Demand Systems Approach’, Applied Economics,

vol. 34, pp. 981–992.

Schnepf, R. & Senauer, B. 1989, Estimation of an Agricultural Household Model for

Southern Minnesota Farms, Staff Papers Series of Department of Agricultural and Applied

Economics, University of Minnesota.

Sen, A. K. 1966, ‘Peasants and Dualism with or without Surplus Labor’, Journal of

Political Economy, vol. 74, pp. 425-50

Seshan, G. 2005, The Impact of Trade Liberalisation on Household Welfare in Vietnam,

Word bank Policy Research Working Paper 3541.

Singh, I., Squire, L. & Strauss, J. (eds.) 1986, Agricultural Household Models: Extensions,

Applications, and Policy, the Johns Hopkins University Press, Baltimore and London.

Skoufias, E. 1994, ‘Using Shadow Wages to Estimate Labour Supply of Agricultural

Households’, American Journal of Agricultural Economics, vol.76, no.2, pp. 215–227.

Stone, J.R.N. 1954, ‘Linear Expenditure Systems and Demand Analysis: An Application to

the Pattern of British Demand’, Economics Journal, vol.64, no.1, pp. 511–527.

Strauss, J. 1984, ‘Joint Determination of Food Consumption and Production in Rural Sierra

Leone’, Journal of Development Economics, vol. 14, pp. 77–103.

Taffesse, A.S. 1999, An Economic Model of the Ethiopian Farm Household, The Centre for

the Study of African Economies Working Paper Series, Paper 110.

Thorner, D., B. Kerblay, and R.E.F. Smith. 1966. Chayanov on the Theory of Peasant

Economy, Homewood, IL: Richard D. Irwin.

Page 230: IMPACTS OF GLOBLISATION AND TRADE LIBERALISATION ON … · Thang, Nguyen Thi Bich Ngoc, Dang Lan Huong, Phan Nguyen Trung Khanh, Tran Thanh Nhan, Bui Thu Ha, Tran Doc Lap, Nguyen

212

UNSD. ComTrade (Database), [Online] Available from <http://comtrade.un.org/>. [Nov

2007]

Vanzetti, D. & Pham L.H. 2006, ‘Vietnam’s Trade Policy Dilemmas’, Paper presentated at

the 9th Annual Conference on Global Economic Analysis, 15-17th Jun 2006, Addis Ababa,

Ethiopia

Varian, H.R. 1996, Intermediate Microeconomics: A Modern Approach, University of

California at Berkeley, W.W.Norton & Company, New York, London.

VietTrade. Trademap Vietnam: the Statistics for International Business Development

(Database), [Online] Available from <http://www.trademap.net/vietnam/login.htm>. [Nov

2007]

Vo, T.T. 2005, ‘Vietnam’s Trade Liberalisation and International Economic Integration:

Evolution, Problems and Challenges’, ASEAN Economic Bulletin, vol.22, no.1, pp.75–91.

Vu, T. 2003, The Political Economy of Pro-Poor Livestock Policy Making in Vietnam,

PPLPI Working Paper No. 5, FAO, Rome

Vu, T.B & Nguyen, N.S. 2005, Impacts of FTAs on Food Security: Vietnam’s Case Study,

Hanoi, Vietnam

World Bank. 2000, Macroeconomic Update for Vietnam. East Asia Brief. [Online],

Available from: <http://www.worldbank.org/eap> [2 Sep 2008]

World Bank. 2005, The cost of avian influenza in Vietnam, Hanoi, Vietnam. [Online]

Available from: <http://go.worldbank.org/SXJV7V2B60> [12 Sep 2008]

World Bank. World Integrated Trade Solutions (Database), [Online] Availabe from:

<http://wits.worldbank.org/witsnet/StartUp/Wits_Information.aspx>. [Nov 2007]

WTO. International Trade and Tariff Data (Database), [Online] Available from:

<http://www.wto.org/english/res_e/statis_e/statis_e.htm>. [Nov 2007].