I A 2

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 8/14/2019 I A 2

    1/23

    Information and option pricings

    Xin Guo

    IBM T. J. Watson Research Center, P. O. Box 218, Yorktown,

    NY 10598, USA

    Abstract

    How can one relate stock fluctuations and information-based human ac-

    tivities? We present a model of an incomplete market by adjoining the

    Black-Scholes exponential Brownian motion model for stock fluctuations

    with a hidden Markov process, which represents the state of information in

    the investors community. The drift and volatility parameters take differ-

    ent values depending on the state of this hidden Markov process. Standard

    option pricing procedure under this model becomes problematic. Yet, with

    an additional economic assumption, we provide an explicit closed-form for-

    mula for the arbitrage-free price of the European call option. Our model can

    be discretized via a Skorohod imbedding technique. We conclude with an

    example of a simulation of IBM stock, which shows that, not surprisingly,

    information does affect the market.

    AMS classification: 60J65; 60J10;

    Tel: (914) 945 2348; Fax: (914) 945 3434; E-mail: [email protected].

    1

  • 8/14/2019 I A 2

    2/23

    Keywords: Black-Scholes; Hidden Markov processes; Inside information; Ar-

    bitrage; Equivalent martingale measure

    1 Motivation

    We begin our discussion with the classic case of Bre-X, a Canadian gold miningcompany. The mineral company stumbled on what looked like a huge gold cache

    in Indonesia. Consequently, the stock price sky-rocketed for a while. Then, all

    of a sudden, the volatility increased by orders of magnitude due to heavy inside

    tradings. The reason turned out to be that a privileged few were aware of the

    fraudulent gold assays performed by the company. The honeymoon was over and

    the stocks crashed when this news became public (cf. Figure 1, New York Times,

    May 5, 1997). Bre-X perished.

    Figure 1: The rise and fall of Bre-X. (Source: New York Times, May 5, 1997.)

    One of the morals of the story is: volatility increased when there was incom-

    2

  • 8/14/2019 I A 2

    3/23

    plete informationsome people knew that the assays were fraudulent while the

    rest did not. In general, it is reasonable to think that the existence of a one-sided

    group of insiders (in this case short-sellers) will drive the market faster since they

    will always be ready to sell if a buyer appears. They know something (or believe

    they know something) that they think is worth money because others do not know

    what they know (or believe they know).This story well-exemplifies the role of distribution of information in the in-

    vestors community. Information is rarely, if ever shared, simultaneously by ev-

    eryone. It is exactly this time difference that may create an arbitrage opportunity,

    which never exists long. It appears, but is removed immediately once everyone

    gets the information. And this information (or the lack of it) drives human

    activity in the stock market.

    With the view of understanding the stock market better, the obvious question

    arises: Can and how does one link market movement and human activity? This

    would tantamount to modeling stock fluctuations with information. This is the

    theme of our paper.

    A guided road map. Section 2 details the hidden Markov process that models

    stock fluctuations and information changes. Section 3 shows the option pricing

    scheme for our model. Section 4 outlines one possible discretization of our model.

    Section 5 discusses why our model is fundamentally different from other models,

    such as stochastic volatility models. Finally, Section 6 provides some preliminary

    empirical evidence.

    3

  • 8/14/2019 I A 2

    4/23

    2 A hidden Markov model with information

    We incorporate the existence of inside information by modeling the fluctuations

    of a single stock price Xt using an equation of the form

    dXt = Xt( t) dt + Xt( t) dWt (1)

    where ( t) is an additional stochastic process representing the state of information

    in the investor community. ( t) is independent of Wt, the Weiner process. For

    each state i, there is a known drift parameter i and a known volatility parameter

    i. h ( t) ; ( t) i take different values when ( t) is in different states.

    We assume that = ( t) is a Markov process which moves among a few (say,

    2 or 3) states. ( t) = 0 at those times t at which the price change is not abnormal

    and people believe that they are all well-informed in a seemingly complete mar-

    ket; in this state ( t) = 0 ; ( t) = 0. But the process ( t) may take other values

    than zero. ( t) = 1 when there are wild fluctuations in the stock price and peo-

    ple suspect that some individuals or groups have extra information which is not

    circulating among the mass of investors and thus would possibly bring wilder fluc-

    tuations depending on the reaction of the investors. Here, ( t) = 1 ; ( t) = 1.

    1 may be larger or smaller than 0 depending on the nature of inside information,

    therefore this state may divide into two extra states where informed investors be-lieve the company will prosper or decline. Furthermore, some inside groups may

    actually be misled and the model could include a state which would indicate that

    there is a group of investors who erroneously believe that the companys fortunes

    are going to change for the positive, and another state for the negative. More

    generally, one can use the state space S = f 0 ; 1; 2; : : : ; Ng for ( t) to model more

    complex information structures.

    4

  • 8/14/2019 I A 2

    5/23

    If we assume that the s are distinct then it is no loss of generality to assume

    that ( t) is actually observable, since the local quadratic variation of Xt in any

    small interval to the left of t will yield ( t) exactly. (For details, see McKean,

    1969.) Hence, even ifX( t) is not Markovian, h X( t) ; ( t) i is jointly so.

    It is conceivable that sometimes insiders will try to manipulate their buying

    and selling in such a way that the existence of such information is not detectablefrom the change of volatilities, namely s are identical. The problem of de-

    tecting the state change of ( t) when s remain unchanged appears to be hard

    to solve mathematically. It is plausible that change in information distribution,

    hence predictability, manifests itself in the diffusion coefficient in the form of

    both stochastic volatility and drift.

    A two-state model. For ease of exposition, we focus on the two-state case, inwhich ( t) alternates between 0 and 1 such that

    ( t) =

    8

    >

    :

    0 ; when the market seems complete, and

    1 ; when some people have (or believe they have) inside information;

    (2)

    where 0 6= 1.

    Suppose, further, that each piece of information flow is a random process Yi,

    and Y1;

    Y2; : : : ;

    Yn being i.i.d processes, then their super-imposed process (underminor technical restrictions) is Poisson. Therefore, let i denote the rate of leaving

    state i, i the time of leaving state i, then

    P( i > t) = e it

    ; i = 0 ; 1 (3)

    The memoryless property of this process is plausible in that, from a practical

    standpoint, the information flow be identified more easily otherwise.

    5

  • 8/14/2019 I A 2

    6/23

    3 Option pricings and arbitrage

    3.1 Completing the marketnew securities COS

    It is easy to see that the model is not complete, according to Harrison and Pliska

    (1981), Harrison and Kreps (1979), because of the additional process ( t) . In

    other words, ( t) is a bounded adapted process with respect to the -algebra Ft

    generated by Xt (denoted as FX), but is not adapted to the -algebra generated by

    Wt (written as FW).

    One way (by D. Duffie) to complete the market is as follows: at each time t,

    there is a market for a security that pays one unit of account (say, a dollar) at the

    next time ( t) = inff u > t ( u ) 6= ( t) g that the Markov chain ( t) changes state.

    That contract then becomes worthless (i.e., has no future dividends), and a new

    contract is issued that pays at the next change of state, and so on. Under natural

    pricing, this will complete the market, and provide unique arbitrage-free prices to

    the hedge options on the underlying risk asset. (For reference, see Harrison and

    Pliska, 1981).

    One can think of this as an insurance contract that compensates its holder for

    any losses that occur when the next state change occurs. Of course, if one wants

    to hedge a given deterministic loss C at the next state change, one holds C of the

    current change-of-state (COS) contracts.

    3.2 Pricing and no arbitrage

    As an assumption analogous to the assumption of the pricing of the underlying

    risky stock, it is natural to propose that the current COS contract trade for a

    6

  • 8/14/2019 I A 2

    7/23

    price of

    V( t) = E

    e r+ k( ( t) ) ] ( ( t) t)

    Ft

    ; (4)

    where k: f 0; 1 g ! is given, and can be thought of as a risk-premium coefficient.

    More precisely, the current COS contract price is

    V(

    t) =

    J(

    (

    t) ) ;

    (5)

    J( i) =( i)

    r+ k( i ) + ( i ); (6)

    recalling that ( ( t) ) is the intensity of the point process N that counts changes of

    state.

    One the other hand, It can be shown (Harrison and Kreps (1979), Harrison

    and Pliska (1981)) that the absence of arbitrage is effectively the same as the

    existence of a probability measure Q, equivalent to P, under which the price of

    any derivative is the expected discounted value of its future cash flow.

    Given such a measure Q, we must therefore have

    V( t) = EQ

    e r( ( t) t)

    Ft

    ;

    (7)

    where EQ denotes expectation under Q. The price of the current COS security is

    of course zero after the next change of state.

    Under Q, the counting process N has intensity of the form Q ( ( t) ) , Solving

    the expression, we get V( t) = JQ ( ( t) ) , where

    JQ ( i) =Q ( i)

    r+ Q ( i)(8)

    Of course, J = JQ, and therefore

    Q ( i ) =r( i)

    r+ k( i )(9)

    7

  • 8/14/2019 I A 2

    8/23

    The same exercise applied to the underlying risky-asset implies that its price pro-

    cess S must have the form

    dS ( t) = ( r d( t) ) S ( t) dt + St( t) dBQ

    ; (10)

    where BQ is a standard Brownian motion under Q.

    Now the usual techniques from Harrison and Kreps (1979) and Harrison and

    Pliska (1981) can be applied to get complete market and unique pricing for any

    derivatives with appropriate square-integrable cash flows.

    Theorem 1 Given Eq. (10), COS, and a riskless interest rate r, the arbitrage free

    price of a European call option with expiration date T and strike price K is:

    Vi ( T; K; r) = EQ e rT

    ( XT K)+ ( 0 ) = i (11)

    = e

    rT

    Z

    0

    Z T

    0y( ln ( y + K) ; m( t) ; v( t) ) fi ( t; T) dtdy; (12)

    where ( x; m( t) ; v( t) ) is the normal density function with expectation m ( t) and

    variance v( t) , and

    f0 ( t; T) = e 1Te( 1 0 ) t

    T t

    01t 1 = 2J

    1 2 ( 01T t + 01T2

    )

    1= 2

    + 0J0 2 ( 01T t + 01T2

    )

    1=

    2

    ; (13)

    f1(

    t;

    T) =

    e 0T

    e( 0 1 ) t

    T t

    01 t1

    =

    2

    J 1

    2(

    01T t+

    01T2

    )

    1=

    2

    + 1J0 2 ( 01T t + 01T2

    )

    1=

    2

    ; (14)

    m( t) = ( d1 d0 1 = 2 ( 20

    21 ) ) t + ( r d1 1= 2

    21 ) T; (15)

    v( t) = ( 20 21 ) t +

    21T; (16)

    8

  • 8/14/2019 I A 2

    9/23

    where Ja ( z) is the Bessel function such that (cf. Oberhettinger and Badii, 1973)

    Ja ( z) =

    1

    2z

    a

    n= 0

    (

    1)

    n( z= 2 ) 2n

    n!( a + n + 1 ); (17)

    Ya( z) = cot( a ) Ja ( z) csc ( a) J a ( z) (18)

    In particular, when 0 = 1 ; 1 = 0, we have fi ( t; T) = t T, and therefore above

    the equations reduce to the classical Black-Scholes formula for European options.

    The key idea is to calculate the probability distribution function of a telegraph

    process. This was obtained independently and earlier by Di Masi et. al. (1994).

    Our Laplace transform based approach is entierly different. The details of our

    proof are given in Appendix A.

    Comparing Eq. (10) with a geometric Brownian motion process with drift r

    and variance , d( t) is of special interest to us. A careful examination reveals

    that this very extra term d( t) differentiates our model from the standard stochastic

    volatility and Markov volatility models, in that it invalidates the martingale pricing

    approach. Moreover, it provides us a way to understand the flow of the infor-

    mation. The drift differs from the riskless interest rate r by d1 d0 when there is

    some information flow and hence the arbitrage opportunity emerges. It also sug-

    gests the difference between the case of pure noise (i.e., 0 6= 1 ; d0 = d1) and

    the case when there may exist an inside information (i.e., 0

    6= 1

    ; d1

    6= d0

    ).

    4 A discretization of the CRR type

    To facilitate numerical simulations, we present one way of discretizing our con-

    tinuous market model along the vein of Cox, Ross, and Rubinstein (Cox, Ross,

    and Rubinstein, 1979). It is worth pointing out that this methodology applies also

    9

  • 8/14/2019 I A 2

    10/23

    to the general case where the the hidden Markov process ( t) takes more than

    two states, i.e., the state space can be S = f 0 ; 1; : : : ; Ng , when, for example, more

    complex information patterns can be imposed.

    Suppose the time interval 0; t is divided into n sub-intervals such that t = nh.

    Let X = ( Xk) where Sk is a price at time kh, and define:

    Xkk

    = ( Xk; k) = ( X( kh ) ; ( kh ) ) ; (19)

    then the following recurrence is obtained,

    ( Xn ; ( n ) ) = ( ( n ) ( n 1 ) )n ( Xn 1 ; ( n 1) ) ; (20)

    where i jn are i.i.d random variables taking values uj with probability pj ( i 1 j +

    ( 1 ) i 1 j e ih ) and 1= uj with probability ( 1 pj ) ( i 1 j + ( 1)i 1 j e ih ) re-

    spectively (i;

    j=

    0;

    1), where

    ai = e ih

    ; ui = ei

    p

    h; pi =

    ih + ip

    h 0 52i h

    2ip

    h(21)

    By the memoryless property of i ; ( Xkk

    ) ; i = 0 ; 1 is a Markov chain. More pre-

    cisely, the Markov chain f Xg = ( Xnn ) with initial state X0 = x is a random walk

    on the set Ex = f xur r = 0m + 1n ; m; n 2 Z; u = e

    p

    hg .

    Intuitively Eq. (20) provides the right discretization and indeed it can be

    proved.

    Theorem 2 Xkk

    converges in distribution to Xt as given in Eq. (1) when h ! 0.

    To prove that Xn ! X in distribution, it is equivalent to show the convergence

    E f( Xn ) ! E f( X) for each bounded and continuous function f( ) . Using standard

    techniques (cf. Billingsley, 1968; Kurtz, 1985; Kushner and Huang, 1984; Skoro-

    hod, 1956), we define new processes Xn and X, the piecewise linear interpolation

    10

  • 8/14/2019 I A 2

    11/23

    ofXn and X. Via a Skorohod imbedding technique, we prove that Xn converges to

    X with probability one, hence the convergence in distribution of Xn to X.

    Proof Sketch: [of Theorem 2] The key here is to calculate the characteristic func-

    tions ofYt = lnXt and Y( n )

    n , (cf. Feller, 1971) where

    Yt = Y0 +

    Z t

    0(

    1

    22 ) ds +

    Z t

    0dWs ; (22)

    Y( n)n = Y

    ( n 1 )n 1 j

    p

    h ; ( j = 0; 1) (23)

    Without loss of generality, let Y( 0 )

    0 = 0, let

    fj ( t) = E E eicYt ( 0) = j

    = E eR t

    0 ic ic12

    2

    12 c

    22ds ( 0) = j ; (24)

    then starting from time 0, between time 0 and h, either (

    h) 6=

    (

    0) =

    j with prob-ability 1 e jh, or ( h) = ( 0 ) = j with probability e jh and the process starts

    afresh because of the memoryless property of the exponential function. Therefore

    we have

    fj ( t) = e jheh ( icj ic

    12

    2j

    12 c

    22j ) fj ( t h) + jh f1 j ( t) + o ( h ) (25)

    By Taylors expansion, we have

    fj ( t) = 1 + ( icj ic122j 12

    c22j j ) h + o ( h) fj ( t) f0

    j ( t) h + o ( h )

    + jh f1

    j ( t) ; (26)

    thus f0 and f1 satisfy first order system of ODEs

    8

    >

    :

    f00 ( t) = ( ic0 ic12

    20

    12 c

    220 0 ) f0 ( t) + 0f1 ( t)

    f01 ( t) = ( ic1 ic1221

    12 c

    221 1 ) f1 ( t) + 1f0 ( t) ;

    (27)

    11

  • 8/14/2019 I A 2

    12/23

    with initial conditions fj ( 0) = 1; f0

    j ( 0) = icj 12 ic

    2j

    12 c

    22j ; ( j = 0 ; 1 ) . This

    system is stable and has a unique solution for any fixed c.

    On the other hand, let Ynn = lnXnn as defined in Eq. (23), and let

    fj k = E E eicYk ( 0 ) = j ; ( j = 0 ; 1 ) ; 0 k n (28)

    Then, we have

    f0 k = E E eicY

    kk ( 0) = 0

    = E ( eicY( k 1

    k 1+ ic0

    p

    hp0 + eicY

    ( k 1k 1

    ic0p

    h( 1 p0 ) ) e

    0h ( 1 ) = 0

    + ( 1 e 0h ) ( eicY

    ( k 1k 1

    + ic1p

    hp1 + eicY

    ( 1

    k 1 ic1

    p

    h( 1 p1 ) ) ( 1 ) = 1

    = f0 k 1 eic0

    p

    h 0hp0 + ( 1 p0 ) e

    ic0p

    h 0h

    + 0h f1 k 1 eic1

    p

    hp1 + e ic1

    p

    h( 1 p1 )

    =

    f0 k 1

    eic0

    p

    h 0h

    p0+ (

    1

    p0)

    e ic0

    p

    h 0h+

    0h f1 k 1

    = f0 k 1 f0 n 1h0 1= 2f0 n 1c220h + ( 0 1= 2

    20 ) ich f0 k 1

    + 0h f1 k 1 + o( h) (29)

    By linear interpolation, it is not hard to see that when h ! 0, there exists fj

    which satisfies

    f00 ( t) = ( ic0 1

    2ic20

    1

    2c220 0 ) f0 ( t) + 0f1 ( t) (30)

    Similarly, we have

    f01 ( t) = ( ic1 1

    2ic21

    1

    2c221 1 ) f1 ( t) + 1f0 ( t) (31)

    and initial conditions fj ( 0 ) = 1 ; f0

    j ( 0 ) = icj 12 ic

    2j

    12 c

    22j. Therefore, by

    the uniqueness of the solution to the ODE Eq. (27), fi = fi . Hence Theorem 2

    follows immediately.

    12

  • 8/14/2019 I A 2

    13/23

    5 Our model vs. other models

    There has been extensive work on modeling stock fluctuations with stochastic

    volatility (cf. Anderson, 1996; Hull and White, 1987; Stein, 1991; Wiggins,

    1987), Markov volatility (Di Masi et. al. 1994), and uncertain volatility (Avel-

    laneda, Levy, and Paras, 1995). Many efforts have been made to study financial

    markets with different information levels among investors (cf. Duffie and Huang,

    1986; Ross, 1989; Anderson, 1996; Karatzas and Pikovsky, 1996; Guilaume et.

    al., 1997; Grorud and Pontier, 1998; Imkeller and Weisz, 1999). Especially, Kyle

    (1985) considered a dynamic model of inside trading with sequential auctions, in

    which the informational content of prices and the values of private information

    to an insider are examined. Lo and Wang (1993) used Ornstein-Uhlenbeck (O-

    U) processes in their adjustment to the Black-Scholes model (Black and Scholes,

    1973; Merton 1973) to induce the drift term via option formula.

    Our model vs. stochastic volatility. It is worth pointing out that the model

    we propose here is fundamentally different from various models with stochastic

    volatility or uncertain volatility. This is because the drift ( t) is also driven by the

    hidden Markov process ( t) , which, in consequence, changes the option pricing

    methodology.

    Our model vs. Markov volatility. The work of Di Masi et. al. (1994) on

    Markov volatility emphasizes more on aspects of hedging strategies than of op-

    tion pricing issues. Moreover, they seemed to have overlooked the fact that the

    martingale pricing approach would not be applicable for the general case when

    the drift term is non-zero, therefore their pricing procedure would be flawed.

    13

  • 8/14/2019 I A 2

    14/23

    Our model vs. O-U processes. O-U processes have the nice property that when

    the price goes too negative, the drift term will pull it back, which makes eco-

    nomic sense. It is however known to probabilists that O-U process is a rescaled

    Brownian motion; therefore it does have its limitations to adjusting the Black-

    Scholes model. Moreover, for tractability reasons, the model proposed by Lo and

    Wang (1993) assumes a fixed volatility.In our model, the information component is reflected in both the drift and

    volatility term. Therefore, not surprisingly, the option pricing formula is function-

    ally dependent on the drift. Moreover, unlike the trending O-U processes which

    are Markovian, in our model while X( t) is not Markovian, h X( t) ; ( t) i is jointly

    so. It provides a simple and feasible way to connect historical data and current sit-

    uation. Furthermore, it captures our earlier intuition that the market never exists

    independently of the information distribution.

    Remark. An anticipated criticism comes from the usage of the term inside in-

    formation, perhaps due to its not-so-glorious image in our (hopefully) efficient

    market. It is, therefore, worth pointing out that inside information is merely a

    convenient way to describe the hidden Markov process ( t) , which is driven by

    some market force, and can be interpreted in a broader way to reflect the noise

    exemplified by d( t) , that goes beyond the Black-Scholes and other standard mod-

    els.

    For pricings of other types of hedge options such as perpetual lookback op-

    tions, Russian options, perpetual American options, interested readers are referred

    to (Guo, 1999).

    14

  • 8/14/2019 I A 2

    15/23

    6 Empirical results and conclusions

    We conclude our paper with an example borrowed from the ongoing empirical

    study with Ed. Pednault at IBM (Guo and Pednault, 2000). Figure 6 illustrates

    our notion of information structure that is present in the IBM stock price.

    Figure 2: IBM stock price.

    There are many immediate questions that spring to our mind. We recognize

    that it is not completely realistic to assume that 0 6= 1. We believe, however,

    the assumption that information structure is closely related to fluctuations in drift

    and volatilities stands to reason, while the mathematical tractability is retained. It

    is also far from clear how drift and volatility are intrinsically related with respect

    to change in information distribution. This question requires further investigation

    15

  • 8/14/2019 I A 2

    16/23

    and statisticians and experimental economists might be able to provide possible

    answers. There are also cases in which the emergence of inside information will

    have a certain delay time, such that ( t) and ( t) will be generated by different

    processes ( t) and 0 ( t) . It will be interesting to study these models. Furthermore,

    another direction is to model the actions investors undertake upon receiving new

    information.It is worth pointing out that our option pricing approach relies heavily on a

    rather strong economic assumption: the existence of a COS contract. It is not clear

    how feasible this assumption is. This brings up a even more basic question: is

    there a better way to incorporate information distribution into stock fluctuations?

    Indeed, a simple model like ours, whose primary goal is to capture the real-

    ity in stock market without sacrificing tractability, has already gone beyond the

    boundary of the general framework of martingale approach. Therefore, we feel

    that our model may serve as little acorn from which great oaks could grow.

    Acknowledgements

    This model was jointly developed with Larry Shepp. He deserves special thanks

    for motivating me to pursue it further. Darrell Duffie, Dan Ocone, and Michael

    Harrison made valuable suggestions to improving both the content and presenta-

    tion of this paper. Ed. Pednault provided me with Figure 6. Part of this work was

    supported by DIMACS. I thank the hospitality of the University of California at

    Berkeley.

    16

  • 8/14/2019 I A 2

    17/23

    References

    Anderson, T. G, 1996, Return volatilityand trading volume: an information flow interpre-

    tation of stochastic volatility, Journal of Finance, 51, 169204.

    Avellaneda, M., Levy, P., and Paras, A., 1995, Pricing and hedging derivative securities in

    markets with uncertain volatilities, Applied Mathematical Finance, 2, 7388.

    Back, K., 1992, Insider trading in continuous time, Review of Financial Studies 5, 387

    409.

    Bachelier, L., 1900, Theorie de la Speculation Annales Scientifiques de LEcole Normale

    Superieure, 3d ser., 17, 2188.

    Ball, C. A., 1993, A review of stochastic volatility models with applications to option

    pricing, Financial Markets, Institutions and Instruments 2, 5569.

    Billingsley, P., 1968, Convergence of Probability Measures (Wiley, New York).

    Black, F. and Scholes, M., 1973, The pricing of options and corporate liabilities, Journalof Political Economy 81, 637654.

    Cox, J., Ross, S., and Rubinstein, M., 1979, Option pricing, a simplified approach, Journal

    of Financial Economics 7, 229263.

    Delbaen, F. and Schachermayer, W., 1994, A general version of the fundamental theorem

    of asset pricing, Mathematique Annales, 463520.

    Di Masi, G. B., Yu, M., Kabanov, and Runggaldier, W. J., 1994, Mean-variance hedging

    of options on stocks with Markov volatility, Theory of Probability and Its Applications

    39, 173181.

    Duffie, D., and Huang, C. F., 1986, Multiperiod security markets with differential infor-

    mation, Journal of Mathematical Economics 15, 283303.

    Feller, W., 1971, An Introduction to Probability Theory and Its Applications, Vol. 2 (John

    Wiley & Sons).

    Follmer, H., and Schweizer, M., 1990, Hedging of contingent claims under incomplete

    17

  • 8/14/2019 I A 2

    18/23

    market, in: M. H. A. Davis and R. J. Elliott, eds., Applied Stochastic Analysis, Stochastic

    Monographs, Vol. 5, (London, Gordon and Breach) 389414.

    Grorud, A., and Pontier, M., 1998, Insider trading in a continuous time market model,

    International Journal of Theoretical and Applied Finance 1, 331347.

    Guilaume, D. M., Dacorogna, M., Dave, R., Muller, U., Olsen, R., and Pictet, P., 1997,

    From the birds eye to the microscope, a survey of stylized facts of the intra-daily foreign

    exchange market, Finance and Stochastics 1, 95129.

    Guo, X, 1999, Inside Information and Stock Fluctuations. Ph.D. dissertation, Department

    of Mathematics, Rutgers University.

    Guo, X., and Pednault, E., 2000, Identifying the states of a hidden Markov model of stock

    price fluctuations, Manuscript.

    Harrison, M., and Kreps, D., 1979, Martingales and arbitrage in multiperiod securities

    markets, Journal of Economics Theory 20, 381408.

    Harrison, M. and Pliska, S., 1981, Martingales and stochastic integrals in the theory of

    continuous trading, Stochastic Processes and Their Applications 11, 215260.

    Hull, J. and White, A., 1987, The pricing of options on assets with stochastic volatility,

    Journal of Finance 2, 281300.

    Kurtz, T., 1985, Approximation of Population Processes (CBMSNSF Regional Confer-

    ence Series in Applied Mathematics 36, Society for Industrial and Applied Mathematics

    (SIAM)).

    Jacod, J. and Shiryaev, A. N., 1997, Local martingale and the fundamental asset pricing

    theorems in the discrete-time case, Labo de probabilities 453, 216.

    Karatzas, I., and Pikovsky, I., 1996, Anticipative portfolio optimization, Advances in Ap-

    plied Probability 28, 10951122.

    Kushner, H. J. and Huang, H., 1984, On the weak convergence of a sequence of general

    stochastic differential equations to a diffusion, SIAM Journal of Applied Mathematics 40,

    528541.

    18

  • 8/14/2019 I A 2

    19/23

    Kyle, A., 1985, Continuous auctions and insider trading, Econometrica 53, 13151335.

    Naik, V., 1993, Option valuation and hedging strategies with jumps in the volatility of

    asset return, Journal of Finance 48(5), 1969-1984.

    Pages, H., 1987, Optimal Consumption and Portfolio When Markets Are Incomplete,

    Ph.D. dissertation, Department of Economics, Massachusetts Institute of Technology.

    Ross, S. A., 1989, Information and volatility, the no-arbitrage martingale approach to

    timing and resolution irrelevancy, Journal of Finance 44, 18.

    Samuelson, P., 1973, Mathematics of speculative price (with an appendix on continuous-

    time speculative processes by Merton, R. C.), SIAM Review 15, 142.

    Skorohod, A. V., 1956, Limit theorem for stochastic processes, Theory of Probability and

    Its Applications 1, 262290.

    Stein, E. M., and Stein, C. J., 1991, Stock prices distribution with stochastic volatility, an

    analytic approach, Review of Financial Studies 4, 727752.

    Wiggins, J. B., 1987, Option values under stochastic volatility. Theory and empirical

    evidence, Journal of Financial Economics 19, 351372.

    A Proof of Theorem 1

    Since the arbitrage price of the European option is the discounted expected value

    ofXt under the equivalent martingale measure Q, we have

    Vi ( T; K; r) = EQ e rT

    ( XT K)+ ( 0) = i (32)

    Recalling that

    Xt = X( 0 ) exp(

    Z t

    0( r d( s ) 1= 2

    2( s ) ) ds +

    Z t

    0( s ) dW

    s ) ; (33)

    19

  • 8/14/2019 I A 2

    20/23

    the key point is to calculate the instantaneous distribution of X( T) . Now let Yt =

    lnXt, then

    Yt = Y( 0 ) +

    Z t

    0( r d( s ) 1= 2

    2( s ) ) ds +

    Z t

    0( s ) dW

    s (34)

    If we consider the probability distribution function fi ( t; T) , where fi ( t; T) is the

    probability distribution function of Ti, (Ti being the total time between 0 and T

    during which ( t) = 0, starting from state i), then by the well-known property of

    conditional expectations, we have

    Vi ( T; K; r) = E e rT

    ( XT K)+ ( 0) = i

    = e rTE E ( XT K)+ Ti ( 0) = i

    = e rTEi E ( XT K)+ Ti F ( 0) = i

    =

    e rT

    Z

    0

    Z T

    0 y(

    ln(

    y+

    K)

    x;

    m(

    t) ;

    v(

    t) )

    fi(

    t;

    T)

    dydt;

    (35)

    where x = X( 0) , ( x; m( t) ; v ( t) ) is the normal density function with expectation

    m( t) and variance v( t) .

    Clearly, we have:

    m( t) = ( d1 d0 1 = 2 ( 20

    21 ) ) t + ( r d1 1= 2

    21 ) T; (36)

    v( t) = ( 20 21 ) t +

    21T; (37)

    and

    ( x; m( t) ; v( t) ) =1

    p

    2v( t)exp(

    ( x m( t) ) 2

    2v( t)) (38)

    Now the key is to calculate fi ( t; T) . Notice that

    fi ( t; T) dt = P(

    Z T

    0

    0( s ) ds 2 dt) ; (39)

    20

  • 8/14/2019 I A 2

    21/23

    and let

    i ( r; T) = E e r

    R T0 0 ( s ) ds ( 0 ) = i

    =

    Z

    0e rtfi ( t; T) dt

    = Lr( fi ( ; T) ) ; (40)

    then we have

    i ( r; T) = e

    rTe iTi 0 + e iT1 i 0

    +

    Z T

    0e iui1

    i ( T u) e rui 0 du ; (41)

    i.e.,

    0 ( r; T) = e rTe 0T +

    Z T

    0e 0u01 ( T u ) e

    rudu ; (42)

    1(

    r;

    T) =

    e 1T

    +

    Z T

    0 e 1u

    10(

    T

    u)

    du (43)

    Taking Laplace transforms on both sides, and writing

    Ls ( i ( r; ) ) = Ls Lr( fi ( ; T) ) ( r; )

    =

    Z

    0e sTi ( r; T) dT

    = i ( r; s) ; (44)

    then

    0 ( r; s) =1

    r+ s + 0+

    0r+ s + 0

    1 ( r; s) (45)

    1 ( r; s) =1

    s + 1+

    1s + 1

    0 ( r; s) (46)

    Solving these equations, we obtain:

    0 ( r; s) =s + 0 + 1

    s2 + s1 + s0 + rs + r1(47)

    21

  • 8/14/2019 I A 2

    22/23

    Taking the inverse Laplace transform on Eq. (47) with respect to ryields

    L 1r ( 0 ( r; s) ) ( w; ) = ( 1 +0

    s + 1) exp(

    s( s + 0 + 1 )

    s + 1w)

    = exp( sw s0

    s + 1w)

    +

    0s + 1

    exp( sw s0

    s + 1w) (48)

    By a well-known property of the Laplace transform, effectively we can first take

    the Laplace inverse transform of the above formula with respect to s (the conver-

    gence of the integrand is obvious) and obtain

    L 1s ( L 1r ( 0 ( r; s) ) ) ( w; ) ( ; v)

    = L 1s (s + 0 + 1

    s + 1exp(

    s( s + 0 + 1 )

    s + 1w) ) ( ; v)

    = L 1

    s

    ( exp( s( s + 0 + 1 )

    s + 1w)

    +

    0s + 1

    exp(

    s( s + 0 + 1 )

    s + 1w) ) ( ; v)

    = e 1ve( 1 0 ) wL 1s ( e ws +

    01ws

    +

    0s

    e ws +01w

    s) ( ; v) (49)

    Recall that

    L 1s ( e

    as) ( v) = ( v a) ; (50)

    and that if

    L 1s ( g( s) ) ( v) = f( v) ; (51)

    then

    L 1s ( s 2c 1g ( s + b = s) ) ( v) =

    Z v

    0f( u) ( v u ) = ( bu) cJ2c 2( buv bu

    2)

    1 = 2 du ;

    (52)

    22

  • 8/14/2019 I A 2

    23/23

    where Ja ( z) s are Bessel functions as given in Eqs. (17), and (18).

    Therefore we have (for w v):

    L 1s (s + 0 + 1

    s + 0exp(

    s( s + 0 + 1 )

    s + 1w) ) ( ; v)

    = e 1ve( 1 0 ) w (

    Z v

    0( u w)

    ( v u)

    01u 1 = 2J

    1 2 ( 01uv + 01u2

    )

    1= 2 du

    + 0

    Z v

    0( u w) J0 2( 01uv + 01u

    2)

    1=

    2 du )

    = e 1ve( 1 0 ) w ( v w

    01w 1= 2J

    1 2( 01wv + 01w2

    )

    1= 2

    + 0J0 2 ( 01wv + 01w2

    )

    1=

    2) (53)

    Thus we obtain f0 ( w; v) , the distribution function ofT0, such that

    f0 ( w; v) = L

    1s ( L

    1r ( 0 ( r; s) ( w; ) ) ( ; v) )

    = e 1ve( 1 0 ) w ( v w

    01w1 = 2J

    1 2( 01wv + 01w2

    )

    1 = 2

    + 0J0 2 ( 01wv + 01w2

    )

    1=

    2) (54)

    Similarly we have:

    f1 ( w; v) = e 0ve( 0 1 ) (

    v w

    01w21

    =

    2J

    1 2 ( 01wv + 01w2

    )

    1=

    2

    + 1J0 2 ( 01wv + 01w2

    )

    1 = 2) ;

    (55)

    Now the theorem is immediate.

    23