49
How Rules-Oriented Are Accounting Standards? By Paul E. Madsen Assistant Professor Fisher School of Accounting University of Florida [email protected] and Devin Williams Doctoral Student Fisher School of Accounting University of Florida [email protected] Draft as of: 7/2012 We thank Stephen Moehrle for his helpful comments on a predecessor paper. We also thank Charlie Costello for research assistance.

How Rules-Oriented Are Accounting Standards?

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    4

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: How Rules-Oriented Are Accounting Standards?

How Rules-Oriented Are Accounting Standards?

By

Paul E. Madsen Assistant Professor

Fisher School of Accounting University of Florida

[email protected]

and

Devin Williams Doctoral Student

Fisher School of Accounting University of Florida

[email protected]

Draft as of: 7/2012 We thank Stephen Moehrle for his helpful comments on a predecessor paper. We also thank Charlie Costello for research assistance.

Page 2: How Rules-Oriented Are Accounting Standards?

How Rules-Oriented Are Accounting Standards?

ABSTRACT: Recent accounting scandals have prompted an effort to identify features of accounting that may have contributed. One prominent candidate has been the “rules-based,” as opposed to “principles-based,” system of financial reporting standards. But on what basis can the accounting community judge the extent to which its standards are indeed rules-based? In this study, we model the rules-orientation of occupational standards in a large cross-section of U.S. occupations as a means of putting the rules-orientation of accounting standards in context. We find that the standards used by professional auditors are extremely rules-oriented even after controlling for a number of occupational features that theory suggests influence the costs and benefits of constraining worker choices through standardization, especially when it is rules-based. We then examine how the rules-orientation of standards governing specific financial reporting practices changes the dialogue among accounting professionals with respect to that practice. A lower quality dialogue is one of the theorized consequences of increasing rule-boundedness. We find evidence consistent with standard-setters “crowding out” other groups that had previously participated in accounting debates which is especially pronounced when the topic under discussion shifts from a principles-based to a rules-based standard. Keywords: accounting standards; principles-based standards; rules-based standards; principles

versus rules; O*NET; Financial Accounting Standards Board (FASB); Public Company Accounting Oversight Board (PCAOB)

Data Availability: The occupation data in this study are collected and distributed by the U.S.

Department of Labor in the O*NET 4.0 and Occupational Employment Statistics (OES) databases and on the Career One Stop website. Contact the authors for the data collected from the Accountants’ Handbook.

Page 3: How Rules-Oriented Are Accounting Standards?

1

I. INTRODUCTION

Recent accounting scandals have prompted an effort to identify the features of accounting

that may have contributed. One prominent candidate has been the “rules-based,” as opposed to

“principles-based,” system of financial reporting standards in the United States (FASB 2002, SEC

2003, Batson 2003 40, Benston et al. 2006, Ball 2009).1 But on what basis can the accounting

community judge the extent to which its standards are indeed rules-based? Or in other words, to what

extent might one expect U.S. GAAP to be rules-based given the characteristics of the work of

accountants and the institutional, economic, and legal context within which the profession has

developed? Currently, a scientifically robust answer to these questions does not exist. There are very

few systems of auditing and financial reporting standards in the world, and current systems of

standards cannot be considered independent observations because standard-setting organizations

have frequently imitated one another when establishing them. Legitimate counterfactuals against

which to compare the U.S. system of accounting standards are, therefore, scarce (Ball 2008).

Benchmarks discussed in the literature for studying rules- versus principles-based standards include

U.S. standards of the past (Mergenthaler 2009), the national accounting standards of other countries

(Broshko and Li 2006, Bennett et al. 2006), or the standards of the IASB (Shortridge and Myring

2004, Ball 2009). While these comparisons have yielded valuable insights, each approach is limited

by the small numbers of systems of accounting standards available for study and the large number of

potentially confounding variables that are present when making longitudinal or cross-country

comparisons to study them.

In this study we tap a largely unexplored source of variation in standards, which is available

in the cross-section of U.S. occupations, to empirically model the rules-orientation of the standards of

1 Consistent with Madsen (2011) we use Baer’s (1986) definition of standards: “Standards are formalized and codified decision rules that join professional knowledge to action” (Baer 1986, 533). See Section II for more discussion of our definitions of standards and of rules- versus principles-oriented standards.

Page 4: How Rules-Oriented Are Accounting Standards?

2

occupations and the economic, social, and political forces influencing it. The data come primarily

from a U.S. Department of Labor database called O*NET 4.0, which contains data provided by a

team of “occupational analysts” describing the characteristics of the work performed by every

significant U.S. occupation. The strengths of our approach are that the occupations in our sample

share a common institutional, economic, and legal environment reducing the number of potential

confounders; are characterized in the O*NET database by a large set of common variables collected

consistently across occupations, facilitating quantitative cross-sectional comparisons; use standards

whose characteristics differ widely; and each represents a competitively successful occupation which

has survived a long history of competition against other occupations for control of work

“jurisdictions” (Abbott 1988) and whose success is likely partially attributable to the relatively

efficient use of occupational standards (He and Wong 2004, Raisch and Birkinshaw 2008, Uotila et

al. 2009).

Our measure of the rules-orientation of occupational standards comes from an O*NET

variable describing the complexity of the standards workers use to make decisions on their job. We

consider standards which are rated as more complex by O*NET’s occupational analysts to be more

rules-oriented and standards that are rated as simpler to be more principles-oriented.2

Our model generally explains the rules-orientation of U.S. occupational standards well, with

R2 statistics of nearly 88% when the model is estimated on the whole sample of occupations and of

91% when the sample is restricted to include a smaller set of high-status professions.3 There is a

2 The tests in this study follow those in Madsen (2011), which examines the overall level of standardization in financial reporting and the nature of the professional dialogue about financial versus managerial accounting. In contrast to Madsen (2011), our purpose is to study the nature of financial reporting standards (their location on the principles versus rules spectrum after controlling for the perceived importance of standards) rather than the absolute level of accounting standardization. 3 There is no well accepted list of occupations that are considered high status professions. We subjectively selected the following 32 SOC occupations as our sample of high status professions: accountants; actuaries; aerospace engineers; agricultural engineers; airline pilots, copilots, and flight engineers; anesthesiologists; architects, except landscape and naval; auditors; chemical engineers; civil engineers; clergy; commercial pilots; computer hardware engineers; economists; education administrators, postsecondary; electrical engineers; family and general practitioners; financial analysts; financial managers, branch or department; judges, magistrate judges, and

Page 5: How Rules-Oriented Are Accounting Standards?

3

positive and statistically significant association between rules-orientation and the importance of

standards to an occupation’s work, the level of complexity of the occupation’s work, the extent to

which the work of the occupation puts property at risk, the extent to which an occupation performs

inspections or audits of other peoples’ work, and the size of the occupation. Rules-orientation is

negatively associated with the extent to which the occupation manages other workers, the importance

of adaptability on the job, and a measure of the prevalence of state licensing requirements required to

work in the occupation.

Using the model, we estimate a benchmark of the level of rules-orientation one would expect

in the auditing profession, the O*NET occupation whose work is most influenced by financial

reporting and auditing standards, given its characteristics. We find that the observed rules-orientation

of accounting standards is far greater than the benchmark predicted by the model.4 The regression

residual for the auditing profession is among the largest in the sample, falling in the 92nd percentile.

Assuming that the model does not omit variables that are especially critical to explaining the rules-

orientation of accounting standards, this result is consistent with claims that accounting standards are

extremely rules-oriented.

Commentators that are concerned about the rules-orientation of accounting standards argue

that increasingly constraining the choices of accountants and auditors through standardization and

especially rules-oriented standardization has a number of negative consequences that could

potentially contribute to poorer quality financial reports and audits (FASB 2002, Nelson et al. 2002,

SEC 2003, Batson 2003 40, Benston et al. 2006, Ball 2009). One alleged negative consequence of

increasing the standardization of financial reporting and auditing is that it changes the intellectual magistrates; lawyers; mechanical engineers; nuclear engineers; obstetricians and gynecologists; pediatricians, general; personal financial advisors; pharmacists; physicists; registered nurses; surgeons; and treasurers, controllers, and chief financial officers. 4 We interpret regression residuals from our model as a valuable measure of the extent to which an occupation has deviated from the level of rules-orientation that would maximize its competitive efficiency. The concept of competitive efficiency was developed to describe how economic agents compete for scarce resources in imperfect markets and so it differs from the popular concept of allocative efficiency, which is applicable to perfect markets. See Section II for further explanation of competitive efficiency.

Page 6: How Rules-Oriented Are Accounting Standards?

4

climate of the discipline by steering opinion about which topics are worthy of debate and by

crowding non-standard-setter groups out of the public professional dialogue (Baxter 1962, Zeff 1986,

White 2005, Sunder 2010, Madsen 2011). Following our occupation analysis, we test whether the

impact of standardization on the professional dialogue in accounting is especially pronounced for

rules-based standards, which we assume constrain choices more than principles-based standards,

using citations from several editions of a reference manual called the Accountants’ Handbook. The

Accountants’ Handbook is a long-running and popular reference manual that is intended to explain

the essentials of accounting to a broad audience of consumers and producers of accounting

information. We argue that the citations in the Handbook are informative about the extent to which

various interest groups participate in the public dialogue about a given accounting topic.

We define a citation as a mention of a source of information which is not the author. We

begin by identifying several topics for which the primary governing standard shifted from relatively

principles-oriented to relatively rules-oriented (switch topics) and we also identify several topics that

did not undergo such a change (principles-only topics) as a control group. We collect citations from

the sections of the Handbook discussing each switch topic beginning three editions before the switch

and ending three editions after the switch. For principles-only topics, we collect citations from

sections of the Handbook discussing them in every edition from which we collect data for any of the

switch topics.

Consistent with prior research, we find that when we consider our switch and control topics

together, the citations per page to standard-setters generally increased and the citations per page to

non-standard-setters generally declined over time (Madsen 2011). This finding is consistent with the

claim that standard-setters crowd non-standard-setter participants out of the professional dialogue.

When we consider how these trends differed in the switch topics versus the principles-only topics,

we find that both the increase in citations-per-page to standard-setters and the decline in citations-

per-page to non-standard-setters were statistically significantly larger for the switch topics. This

Page 7: How Rules-Oriented Are Accounting Standards?

5

evidence is consistent with rules-based standards having a particularly strong negative impact on the

professional dialogue in accounting.

The results in this study depend on the quality of both the O*NET and Accountants’

Handbook data, and the validity of the model of occupational rules-orientation. O*NET 4.0 is

particularly well suited to making cross-occupation comparisons because the data in it were provided

by objective “occupational analysts” rather than incumbent workers who self-selected into their

occupation.5

Our analysis of the effect of rules-based standards on the professional dialogue in accounting

requires us to identify a set of accounting topics that had once been governed by principles-based

standard but switched to rules-based standards and a set of topics that have been consistently

governed over the sample period by principles-based standards. We used existing literature to guide

our choice of topics to include in each set, but such decisions are inevitably subjective. The

interpretability and generalizability of our results regarding the professional accounting discourse

depend on the quality of these classifications.

Section II discusses theory that is relevant to both the O*NET and the Accountants’

Handbook analysis. Section III discusses the analysis of the O*NET data describing the extent to

which occupational standards are rules-oriented. Section IV presents the study of the impact of

switches from principles-oriented to rules-oriented standards on the professional accounting

dialogue. Section V discusses conclusions.

II. THEORY

In this study we employ theory for two purposes. The first is to identify occupational

characteristics that might be expected to explain the extent to which occupational standards evolve

toward the rules or principles end of the standards continuum. The second is to identify a testable

5 We discuss this further in the O*NET data section. See http://www.onetcenter.org/reports/AnalystProc.html for more information on O*NET’s occupational analysts.

Page 8: How Rules-Oriented Are Accounting Standards?

6

implication of deviations from the level of rules-orientation predicted by the model. In this section,

we discuss some general theory on occupations and efficiency. We leave the theoretical discussions

of occupational characteristics and their expected association with rules-orientation to Section III and

the discussion of the consequences of deviations from predicted levels of rules-orientation to Section

IV.

Following Madsen (2011), we use Baer’s (1986) definition of standards: “Standards are

formalized and codified decision rules that join professional knowledge to action” (Baer 1986, 533).

This definition is broad and encompasses the pronouncements of formal standard-setting bodies like

the FASB and PCAOB, but also encompasses decision rules with labels like laws, regulations, or

guidelines that have been formalized in national or state law or that are only present in firm specific

practice guides. We conceive of standards existing on a continuum with “rules” at one end and

“principles” at the other and assume that standards toward the rules end of the spectrum constrain

behavior more than standards at the principles end. We follow prior literature, especially

Mergenthaler (2009) and Kohlbeck and Warfield (2010), in defining standards as rules-based when

they have bright-line thresholds, scope and legacy exceptions, large volumes of implementation

guidance, and a high level of detail, and as principles-based when they are concise, have few

exceptions or internal inconsistencies, limited implementation guidance, and few bright-lines (see

also SEC (2003)). In the occupational context, the principle of nonmaleficence from medical ethics,

“first do no harm” (Smith 2005) is an example of a standard near the “principles” end of the

rules/principles continuum, while the 2007 California Building Code for Masonry6 is an example of a

standard near the “rules” end of the spectrum.

In order to model the rules-orientation of occupational standards, we require theories to

identify occupational features that are likely associated with the relative costs and benefits of using

rules-oriented standards. This requires us to specify a theory of standard-setting which considers the 6 Available at: http://www.rumford.com/code/2007CBCCh21A.pdf.

Page 9: How Rules-Oriented Are Accounting Standards?

7

forces influencing standard-setter decisions to make standards more or less rules-oriented. We reject

the view that accounting standard-setters could effectively promote the public interest, even if it was

their sole goal to do so. They are constrained from doing so by a lack of information about the social

consequences of their decisions (Sunder 1988, Watts and Zimmerman 1986; FASB 1991; Meeks and

Swann 2009), by the difficulty of specifying a broadly acceptable definition of social welfare

(Buchanan and Tullock 1962, Sunder 1988), and by the threat of political intervention in standard-

setting if their decisions are sufficiently repugnant to any constituent group (Zeff 2002, 2005; Kothari

et al. 2010). Rather, we view accounting standard-setters as political agents whose role is primarily to

manage conflicts among constituent groups and between constituents and supervisory government

agencies by making socially acceptable, rather than the most socially efficient, choices (Horngren

1972, Zeff 1978, Sunder 1988, McLeay et al. 2004 p. 286, Kothari et al. 2010). We assume that

members of the occupation whose work is subject to a given set of standards have significant power

to influence the nature of the standards and that they use this power to improve their competitive

positions relative to one another and relative to other occupations with overlapping skill sets

(Buchanan and Tullock 1962, Arrow 1963, Olson 1965, Stigler 1971, Mahoney 2003, Kleiner 2006,

Kothari et al. 2010).

Given competition between occupations for jurisdictional control, workers in occupations

have incentives to pursue institutional innovations that enhance the competitive fitness of the

occupation.7 Effective use of standards is one potential means of enhancing occupational competitive

efficiency. Occupational standardization likely involves a number of tradeoffs. The management 7 The sociology literature views occupations as social groups that are more or less cohesive and have gained control of areas of economic activity, which have been called work “jurisdictions” (Larson 1977, Abbott 1988, Macdonald 1995). The jurisdictions controlled by any given occupation overlap at the margins with the jurisdictions controlled by occupations with similar skills. For example, the knowledge and skills of engineers and accountants working in manufacturing firms overlapped during the early 20th century and the two occupations battled for control of the work jurisdiction that is now called cost accounting (Abbott 1988). Workers in occupations benefit if demand for the work of the occupation increases, whether through growth in the size of jurisdictions it controls or growth in the number of jurisdictions it controls. It is in this sense that they are in perpetual competition with one another, with successful occupations growing in size and income and unsuccessful occupations shrinking or disappearing (Abbott 1988, MacDonald 1995).

Page 10: How Rules-Oriented Are Accounting Standards?

8

literature on “exploration” versus “exploitation” suggests that, while standardization can increase

operational efficiency in the short run, this comes at the cost of a lower rate of radical innovation,

which can threaten organizational survival in the long-run (March 1991, Benner and Tushman 2002,

He and Wong 2004, Cole and Matsumiya 2007, Raisch and Birkinshaw 2008, Uotila et al. 2009). In

addition, occupational standardization can add value by increasing the consistency with which the

occupation’s services are delivered (Abbott 1988, Freidson 2001, Meeks and Swann 2009), but this

comes at the cost of replacing expert judgment with a routinized “check the box” mentality (Baxter

1962, 1979; Jamal et al. 2005; Sunder 2005, 2010).

Given the poor information environment in which they operate, standard-setters are likely

unable to manage these tradeoffs in a manner that maximizes social welfare. Rather, the best they can

hope to do is arrive at “competitively efficient” solutions through trial and error experimentation

combined with competition to sort the effective from the ineffective solutions (Alchian 1950, Hayek

1968). Competitive efficiency is an idea that was developed by economists interested in “imperfect

markets” which are characterized by uncertainties, asymmetric information, barriers to entry and exit,

market power, and unequal access to technology (Alchian 1950, North 1990, Kohn 2004).

Competitively efficient behavior can be defined as the application by agents in competition for scarce

resources of the set of known strategies that most effectively enhance the survival prospects of their

users in the existing competitive environment. While allocative efficiency involves finding a global

maximum along an objective function, competitive efficiency cannot be said to do so. Competitive

efficiency applies to situations where there is too little information to maximize an objective function

and the problem agents face is primarily one of effective adaptation to unpredictable changes in

circumstances rather than effective allocation of a set of known resources to a set of known

consumers of resources (Alchian 1950, Hayek 1968, Kling 2007). While the characteristics of U.S.

stock markets approximate those of perfect markets and so can be effectively understood using

concepts like allocative efficiency, the characteristics of the market for occupational standards often

Page 11: How Rules-Oriented Are Accounting Standards?

9

deviate from perfect market assumptions and so are better understood using the concept of

competitive efficiency.

Competitive success is the reward enjoyed by occupations that manage the tradeoffs of

standardization in a competitively efficient manner, but there are barriers to identifying competitively

efficient solutions that can prevent an occupation from doing so. These include the presence of

entrenched special interest groups that benefit from the status quo and resist change and

anticompetitive legal protections that prevent the discovery and correction of deviations from

competitive efficiency (North 1990, 2005; Kleiner 2006). Because occupations do not inevitably

arrive at competitively efficient levels of rules-orientation, we do not assume that all occupations

have arrived at a competitively efficient “equilibrium” level of rules-orientation. But we assume that,

because of competition among occupations, the rules-orientation of the standards of an average

occupation in our sample is approximately competitively efficient.

III. RULES-ORIENTATION OF OCCUPATIONAL STANDARDS

In this section, we develop and estimate a model of the rules-orientation of occupational

standards. This section begins with a discussion of theory linking occupational characteristics to

likely costs and benefits of rules-oriented occupational standards. We then discuss our data, methods,

and results from the O*NET analysis.

Theory of Occupational Standards

Madsen (2011) develops a model of the overall level of occupational standardization and

estimates it using the O*NET 12.0 database. Our model is a modified and expanded version of the

Madsen (2011) model. Following Madsen (2011), we expect that the complexity of occupational

work, the extent to which the work of the occupation puts people or property at risk of harm, the

importance of adaptability, the extent to which the occupation is professionalized, and the presence

Page 12: How Rules-Oriented Are Accounting Standards?

10

of network externalities will explain variation in the extent of the rule-boundedness of occupational

standards (which is increasing in the level of rules-orientation).8

One proposed benefit of occupational standards is that they routinize complex tasks, enabling

non-experts to perform them more like an expert would (Larson 1977, Brunsson and Jacobsson 2000,

Meeks and Swann 2009). If they can do this, workers may be able to provide complex services at a

lower cost or higher quality by standardizing the task. We, therefore, expect that occupations that

perform complex tasks will use standards and that those standards will tend toward the rules end of

the rules/principles continuum.

Theory from accounting suggests that occupational standards can be used to defend auditor’s

decisions when an audit firm is sued (Healy and Palepu 2001, Schipper 2003, Healy 2003, Watts

2003, Benston et al. 2006, Bratton 2007). If standards are indeed effective tools for defending

workers against litigation costs, workers in occupations that put people or property at risk might be

expected to demand more standards and standards that are more detailed. For this reason, we expect a

positive association between the extent to which the work of an occupation puts people or property at

risk and the degree to which their standards are rules-oriented.

Standardization brings with it a number of potential benefits but many of its potential costs

come from its effect on adaptability. Standards can reduce the rate of innovation by reducing

variation in practice (Benner and Tushman 2002, Cole and Matsumiya 2007) or lock an occupation

into practices that may be competitively efficient today but will not be in the future if the competitive

environment changes (Farrell and Saloner 1985, Meeks and Swann 2009). Workers in occupations

that experience high levels of environmental uncertainty may, therefore, resist standardization in an

8 We expect that the relationship between complexity and rules-orientation will be positive in situations that do not involve strategic interaction between opposing sets of agents. If the job is complex because it involves strategic interactions, we expect a negative association between complexity and rules-orientation. In our tests, we control for the extent to which the occupation performs inspection or auditing services because these services are strategic in nature. Because we believe that this controls for strategic complexity, we predict a positive coefficient on our complexity measure. We discuss our inspection variable further below.

Page 13: How Rules-Oriented Are Accounting Standards?

11

effort to retain the flexibility to adapt to change. For this reason we expect a negative association

between the environmental uncertainty experienced by an occupation and the degree of occupational

standardization, which we assume is increasing in the rules-orientation of standards.

The literature on the sociology of professions describes how occupations transform

themselves into high-status professions through a coordinated set of initiatives, like controlling

occupational entry and education and lobbying for legislation that limits a work jurisdiction to

licensed workers, which together are called a “professional project” (Larson 1977, Macdonald 1995,

Kleiner 2006). An increase in occupational standards can be a consequence of the pursuit by an

occupation of professional status because standards publicly display occupational knowledge and

could enhance occupational prestige (Abbott 1988, Lee 1995), and because standards are one tool

professions use to exercise control over their members (Abbott 1988, Friedson 2001). We, therefore,

expect a positive association between the extent of professionalization and the extent to which

occupational standards are rules-oriented.

Standardization is a means of increasing uniformity, which is particularly valuable in the

presence of network externalities, or situations in which a product or service becomes more valuable

as it is used by larger numbers of people. We control for occupation size as a means of controlling

for the magnitude of network effects (Katz and Shapiro 1985, Farrell et al. 1992, Dye and Sunder

2001, Healy 2003, Jamal et al. 2003, Meeks and Swann 2009). We expect a positive association

between the potential value of network effects to an occupation and the rules-orientation of

occupational standards.

In addition to these occupational features, which we expect to be associated with rules-

orientation following Madsen (2011), we add two new predictions. We expect that the rules-

orientation of occupational standards will be positively associated with the level of occupational

compensation and negatively associated with the degree to which an occupation performs inspection

work.

Page 14: How Rules-Oriented Are Accounting Standards?

12

In addition to pursuing licensing requirements, occupations with professional power may use

it to artificially limit the entry of new workers to reduce competition and increase compensation

(Routh 1965, Kleiner 2006).9 Therefore, in addition to licensing requirements, we control for

compensation as a means of better capturing the extent to which an occupation is professionalized.

Madsen (2011) finds a positive association between the degree of occupational

standardization and the complexity of occupational work but his prediction with respect to the

complexity variable is non-directional because, while standardization can potentially enable a non-

expert to perform difficult tasks more like an expert, it may not do so in strategic situations. In

strategic situations, a non-expert applying a rules-oriented standard could likely be easily

outmaneuvered by a strategic opponent that is an expert and is not constrained by a detailed standard.

Transaction structuring is an example of this problem (Nelson et al. 2002). We expect that strategic

interactions in the occupational context are especially likely in occupations that perform inspection

services. We, therefore, expect that occupations that perform inspections of the work of another

person or group will be less likely to use rules-based standards than occupations that do not perform

inspections.

In the next section, we discuss our occupation data and how we use it to operationalize the

theoretical constructs we expect will explain the rules-orientation of occupational standards.

Occupation Data and Methods

Our occupations data come primarily from a dataset collected by the U.S. Department of

Labor called O*NET 4.0 which was released in 2002. We use the 4.0 version of the database because

it was the last in which the data were collected from “occupational analysts” rather than incumbent

workers in the occupations. While occupational analysts likely have knowledge about a job that is

more shallow than workers on the job, their advantages are that they did not self-select into the

9 For example, not all medical doctors are board certified, but the rigors of medical school ensure the supply of qualified graduates is limited.

Page 15: How Rules-Oriented Are Accounting Standards?

13

occupations they describe and they provide ratings for multiple occupations with which they are

familiar with the likely consequence that the data they provide are more comparable across

occupations than those provided by incumbent workers. Occupational analysts were employees of the

O*NET project who were hired because they were experts in fields such as industrial and

organizational psychology, vocational psychology, human resources, or industrial relations. They

were required to have two or more years of work experience and at least two years of graduate

education in their respective fields.

O*NET 4.0 contains data describing 900 occupations which are defined according to the

Standard Occupation Classification (SOC) of the U.S. federal government.10 We restrict the sample

to the subset of O*NET occupations that do not have missing values for any of our required variables

leaving 643 occupations.

The dependent variable in our tests is the rules-orientation of occupational standards. O*NET

asked occupational analysts to rate both the level of importance and the level of complexity of the

skill “evaluating information to determine if it complies with standards” for each of the jobs in the

database. The full text of the standardization questions from the O*NET “Work Activities”

questionnaire is displayed in Figure 1. In part B of the question, analysts are asked to assess the

“level” (which is a term used in O*NET to denote the level of complexity) of the skill required to

perform the job. We label the analyst ratings of the level of importance of this skill “importance of

standards” and the level of complexity “rules-orientation of standards.” Madsen (2011) shows that in

the O*NET 12.0 database, the values for the importance and rules-orientation of standards are highly

correlated. In O*NET 4.0, their correlation is 0.75 (p = 0.00). In our tests, to isolate the rules-

orientation of occupational standards from the importance of standards, we control for the

importance of standards in all regressions. As a result, our measure of rules-orientation is increasing

10 See http://www.bls.gov/soc/ for more information on the SOC system.

Page 16: How Rules-Oriented Are Accounting Standards?

14

in the complexity of occupational standards after controlling for the importance of occupational

standards.

Figure 2 shows a scatter-plot of O*NET occupations with their rules-orientation (defined as

the complexity of occupational standards that is not explained by the importance of occupational

standards) on the y-axis and their occupation group (SOC code) on the x-axis. Occupations above the

horizontal line marking zero use standards that are more rules-oriented than average while

occupations below it use standards that are more principles-oriented than average. Several

occupations with extreme values and their occupational groups (two-digit SOC code title) are

labeled. Figure 1 shows that there is considerable variation in occupational rules-orientation.

Auditors’ level of rules-orientation is among the highest in the sample along with judges, nuclear

engineers, and nuclear medicine technologists. Office and administrative support occupations tend to

have standards that are particularly principles-oriented. While the data in Figure 2 are informative

about the variation in rules-orientation present in the sample, they are not informative about whether

these values are likely near a competitively efficient level. In the remainder of this section, we

construct and estimate an empirical model of the rules-orientation of occupational standards in order

to identify deviations from the levels of rules-orientation that would be expected given occupations’

characteristics.

O*NET contains variables describing the work of occupations in detail but does not contain

variables expressly measuring most of our constructs of interest. Our approach when this is the case

is to identify O*NET variables that we expect are highly correlated with our construct of interest and

factor analyze them to identify unobserved factors that best explain the shared variance in the

O*NET variables.11 We take the factor scores calculated from factors with eigenvalues greater than

one as the operationalizations of our constructs.

11 An alternative approach would be to use principal components analysis rather than factor analysis. Principal components analysis is a method that is similar to factor analysis in that it is useful for reducing the dimensionality

Page 17: How Rules-Oriented Are Accounting Standards?

15

Theory suggests that the complexity of tasks performed by an occupation is likely to be

positively associated with rules-orientation. There is not a single O*NET variable measuring job

complexity. We identify seven O*NET variables that we expect are highly correlated with job

complexity. They are the complexity of information analyzed, the complexity of problem solving, the

complexity of decisions made and problems solved, the complexity of consultation and advice

provided, the complexity of information that is interpreted, the complexity of judgments and

decisions, and the training required for the job. Our measure of the degree to which the work of an

occupation puts people at risk, which we expect is positively associated with rules-orientation, is

based on three variables: the extent to which workers are responsible for the health and safety of

others, the importance of knowledge of public safety and security, and a measure we construct from

several O*NET variables measuring occupational exposure to hazards like heights and radiation.

O*NET has two measures that we expect are highly correlated with the degree to which the work of

an occupation puts property at risk, which we expect are positively associated with rules-orientation.

These are the potential seriousness of an error committed on the job and the extent to which workers

are responsible for work outcomes.

We construct a measure of the importance of adaptability, which we expect to be negatively

associated with rules-orientation, from six O*NET variables. These are the importance of updating

and using relevant knowledge and the complexity of active learning, of coordinating and adjusting

actions in relation to others’ actions, of thinking creatively, of idea fluency, and of original thought.

O*NET has a search feature on its website that enables one to search all O*NET occupation titles

and job descriptions for keywords. This search feature returns a list of occupations along with a

of a dataset and identifies latent “principal components” that explain variation in the input variables. The approaches differ in that factor analysis explains the shared variance of the input variables while principal components analysis explains the total variance of the input variables. O*NET 4.0 was not intended to measure many of our constructs of interest and, therefore, the variables we use as inputs are noisy proxies for them. Because factor analysis ignores variance that is idiosyncratic and focuses instead on variance that is shared across input variables, we expect that it will produce factors that measure our constructs of interest with less noise than principle components analysis.

Page 18: How Rules-Oriented Are Accounting Standards?

16

“relevance score” that indicates the extent to which the term is relevant to each occupation. To

construct our measure of the extent to which an occupation performs inspection work, we perform a

number of keyword searches on the most recent O*NET database (16.0) and record the relevance

scores returned for each occupation. The terms we search are audit, inspect, examiner, examine,

investigate, verify, review, and check. Our measure of the extent to which an occupation performs an

inspection role is constructed from a factor analysis of the relevance scores from these eight keyword

searches. Our measure of compensation comes from a question in the O*NET values questionnaire

asking how much workers in the occupation value high levels of compensation relative to their peers.

State licensing is a variable between 0 and 5 which is a count of the number of U.S. states that

require a license to work in an occupation rounded to the nearest unit of 10. These data were

collected from the Career One Stop website in 2010.12 Finally, occupation size is the log of an

estimate of the number of people working in an occupation. It is collected from the Occupational

Employment Statistics database of the U.S. Department of Labor.

The results of the factor analyses which produce our complexity, risk of physical harm,

importance of adaptation, and inspection role variables are displayed in Table 1. We estimate them

using the iterated principal factor method.13 Panel A shows the factors produced by the factor

analyses, their eigenvalues, and the proportion of the shared variance in the input variables they

explain. The factor analyses for each of our constructs each produce a single factor with an

eigenvalue greater than one. We take this factor as our measure of each construct. Table 1 Panel B

shows the factor loadings for each input variable which can be interpreted as the correlation of the

input variable with the factor. It shows that the complexity factor is most strongly associated with the

12 See http://www.acinet.org/licensedoccupations/lois_state.asp?nodeid=16&by=occ. 13 In addition to the iterated principal factors estimation method, we use orthogonal quartimax rotation to ensure maximization of the variance of the factor loadings in each variable. Before rotation, one factor is retained from each factor analysis as only one factor retained an eigenvalue greater than one (latent root method). In addition, all variables loaded heavily on the retained factor. With rotation, only one factor was retained and the loadings on that factor were not significantly different from the prior-to-rotation loadings. The changes were marginal and did not affect the analysis. The reported factor loadings are unrotated for ease of interpretation and replication.

Page 19: How Rules-Oriented Are Accounting Standards?

17

analyzing data, complex problem solving, and making decisions variables. The legal risk physical

factor is most strongly associated with the responsible for others’ health and safety variable. The

adaptation factor is most strongly associated with the fluency of ideas input variable. And the

inspection factor is most strongly associated with the relevance scores for the search term “examine.”

Table 2 shows descriptive statistics for each of the variables we use in our rules-orientation

regression as well as the value for the auditing profession and the location of the auditor value in the

distribution of all occupations expressed in percentile terms. It shows that the auditing profession has

among the highest values in the sample for rules-orientation (99.5th percentile), importance of

standards (97.5th percentile), job complexity (96.7th percentile), inspection role (98.4th percentile),

and state licensing requirements (99.8th percentile). The only variable we examine for which the

auditing profession is below average is the extent to which their work exposes people to physical

harm (21.3rd percentile).

Results

Univariate correlations among our variables are shown in Table 3. The univariate correlations

between the dependent and independent variables are all positive, which is contrary to expectations

in the cases of the adaptation and inspection variables. 14

Table 4 shows the results of an OLS regression estimation of our model of the rules-

orientation of occupational standards. We cluster errors by two-digit SOC code (22 groups) to correct

for possible correlation of the residuals across similar occupations. Importance of standards, job

complexity, consequence of error, and occupation size are all significantly positively associated with

rules-orientation, consistent with expectations.15 The coefficient on legal risk physical is also

14 Table 3 also shows that some of the independent variables are highly correlated, raising concerns about the risk of multicolinearity in our multivariate tests. In our multivariate analysis below, we compute variance inflation factors (VIFs) to determine presence of extreme multicollinearity. All of the VIFs are well below the “rule of thumb” cutoff of for individual variables of 10 (Baum 2006).14 The mean VIF is 2.63. 15 As a sensitivity analysis, we ran the model without the occupation size variable, which comes from the OES rather than the O*NET variable and may be measured with error. The results did not qualitatively differ from the original

Page 20: How Rules-Oriented Are Accounting Standards?

18

positive, as predicted, but is not statistically significant. Also consistent with predictions, we find that

adaptation is significantly negatively associated with rules-orientation.

Three of our variables have coefficients that are large but have signs that are opposite of

predictions. These are responsibility for outcomes and state licensing, for which we expected a

positive sign but find a negative sign, and inspection, for which we expected a negative sign but find

a positive sign.16

The model’s high R2 (0.88) shows that the cross-sectional variation in the sample is

explained well by the model. Errors from the estimation of the model are differences between the

model’s predicted levels of rules-orientation and rules-orientation as reported by the occupational

analysts. Table 5 shows the regression errors for a selection of accounting related occupations (panel

A) and professions (panel B). The rows showing the auditing profession are bolded to highlight them.

We emphasize the results for auditors because this is the O*NET occupation whose work is most

directly affected by auditing and financial reporting standards. O*NET’s definition of auditors

explains that they “analyze data to detect...non-compliance with laws, regulations, and management

policies,” “prepare detailed reports on audit findings,” “inspect account books and accounting

model with one exception. The responsible for outcomes variable that was significant at the 0.05 level in the original model became significant at the 0.10 level with a p-value of 0.052. All else remained qualitatively identical. 16 We speculate that responsibility for outcomes may have a negative association with rules-orientation due to the latitude needed by workers with significant responsibility to accomplish their intended objectives. For example, the occupation with the highest score for the responsible for outcomes variable is “Sales Manager,” a job that likely requires adaptability and creativity in response to customer demands. State licensing is negatively associated with rules-orientation, against expectation, possibly because of the increasing prevalence of state licensing requirements, even in jobs that are not traditionally considered professions. For example, the Career One Stop website shows that to work in the “hairdressers, hairstylists, and cosmetologists,” “bus drivers,” or “interior designers” occupations requires a license in many states. These are not traditionally considered professions. The unexpected result for state licensing could be a consequence of the fact that the proliferation of state licensing requirements means that occupational licensing is not a strong indicator of professionalization. The coefficient on the inspection variable had a positive sign when we expected a negative sign. This is perhaps a mechanical consequence of the O*NET definitions of our variables. Inspection occupations apply not only the standards of their own profession but also the rules and standards of those occupations that they inspect. In addition, as a practical matter, the occupation being inspected deals with standards as only a portion of their occupation whereas the same standards capture virtually all of the attention of an inspector of that occupation. Thus, when answering an O*NET question regarding the complexity of rules and standards, an analyst may be more likely to rank an inspection-performing occupation higher than the occupation it inspects because of this compounding of occupational standards across two occupations.

Page 21: How Rules-Oriented Are Accounting Standards?

19

systems for...use of accepted accounting procedures,” and “confer with company officials about

financial and regulatory matters,” all of which are functions that are likely directly impacted by

financial reporting or auditing standards.

Table 5, panel A shows that, of our five selected accounting occupations, three have extreme

positive errors, suggesting that their occupational standards are far more rules-oriented than the

model’s predictions. The accounting occupations with extreme positive errors are tax preparers (99th

percentile), auditors (92.5th percentile), and bookkeeping, accounting, and auditing clerks (88th

percentile). Table 5, panel B shows that of the 32 professions we study, auditors have the fifth largest

regression error. Other professions with exceptionally large positive errors are Judges, nuclear

engineers, and chemical engineers. Professions with exceptionally large negative errors, indicating

far less rules-orientation (or, equivalently, greater principles-orientation) than expected include

economists, financial advisors, and pharmacists.

Our analysis suggests that the work of auditors is governed by standards that are far more

rules-oriented than one might expect given the profession’s characteristics. In the next section, we

explore one of the possible consequences of deviating from a competitively efficient level of rules-

orientation, changes in the nature of the professional dialogue.

IV. PRINCIPLES, RULES AND THE PROFESSIONAL ACCOUNTING DIALOGUE

In this section, we examine how the professional dialogue in accounting changes over time

for topics governed by principles-based standards (principles-only topics) as compared to topics

governed by standards that switch from principles-based to rules-based (switch topics). We begin by

discussing the theory linking the rules-orientation of accounting standards to the accounting dialogue.

We then explain the data and methods and conclude the section by discussing results.

Theory

Page 22: How Rules-Oriented Are Accounting Standards?

20

Concerns about the impact of standardization on the intellectual vitality of the accounting

discipline date back to at least the beginning of the 20th century (Uniformity 1906) and persist today

(Sunder 2010) but statistical tests of these claims are rare. Baxter (1962) argues that the presence of a

powerful standard-setting authority in a field, whether or not it is benevolent, inevitably reduces the

scope and intensity of intellectual inquiry in the field with the result that “the stream of new ideas

dries up...criticism loses its edge, and ideas are not put to a stern test” (Baxter 1962, 421). This is

consistent with Zeff (1986), which shows that the advocacy writing of the large audit firms declined

following the empowerment of the FASB, perhaps because of its greater authority to determine

which accounting practices have “substantial authoritative support.” We predict, consistent with

Baxter (1962) and Zeff (1986) that as standard-setters increasingly exercise their authority, they will

increasingly dominate accounting debates. Because we assume that rules-based standards by their

nature constrain behavior more than principles-based standards, we expect that Baxter’s (1962)

theory is especially applicable to them.

Data and Methods

Madsen (2011) tests Baxter’s (1962) theory that standardization, regardless of the level of

rules-orientation, narrows the accounting dialogue using citations from an accounting reference

manual called the Accountants’ Handbook. In this section, we present a refinement of the Madsen

(2011) approach that is intended to examine our prediction that Baxter’s (1962) argument is

especially applicable to accounting topics governed by rules-based standards.

The Accountants’ Handbook is an accounting reference manual that is intended for a broad

audience of accountants and financial statement users. It was first published in 1923 and most

recently published in 2012 (12th edition). It is attractive for use in characterizing the nature of

accounting discourse and its relationship to accounting standards because it has been repeatedly

updated over the time during which accounting standards emerged and it has passed the “market test”

by remaining in print. We, therefore, assume that it provides useful snapshots of the nature of the

Page 23: How Rules-Oriented Are Accounting Standards?

21

accounting discourse through time. It has also used a somewhat stable set of chapters and sections

which facilitates time-series comparisons of data collected from them. Table 6 shows some

descriptive information about the editions of the Handbook that are used in this study.

We examined accounting standards applicable to a number of accounting topics to identify a

set of principles-only topics and a set of switch topics which are sufficiently covered by the

Accountants Handbook. The control topics we identified are inventory valuation, intangible asset

accounting, and accounting for bad debt. These three topics have been governed by general

principles rather than rules-based standards. As an example of the principles-based control group, the

current guidance for the accounting for bad debt expense for receivables is contained in the

Accounting Standards Codification topic 310, and is as follows:

ASC 310-10-35-8 Subtopic 450-20 requires recognition of a loss when both of the following conditions are met: a. Information available before the financial statements are issued or are available to be issued (as discussed in Section 855-10-25) indicates that it is probable that an asset has been impaired at the date of the financial statements. b. The amount of the loss can be reasonably estimated. ASC 310-10-35-9 Losses from uncollectible receivables shall be accrued when both of the preceding conditions are met. Those conditions may be considered in relation to individual receivables or in relation to groups of similar types of receivables. If the conditions are met, accrual shall be made even though the particular receivables that are uncollectible may not be identifiable.

The principles-orientation of this standard can be seen when compared to the rules-based standards

governing our switch topics, which are hedge accounting (switching between 1994 and 1998 with

SFASs 119 and 133), accounting for income taxes (switching in 1987 with SFAS 96), accounting for

pensions (switching in 1985 with SFAS 87), and lease accounting (switching in 1976 with SFAS 13).

Lease accounting has traditionally been the most prominent example of rules-based accounting.

Appendix A quotes the standards for lease accounting under APB 5 (principles-based) and also FAS

13 (rules-based) to illustrate the difference in rule-orientation between the two standards.

Page 24: How Rules-Oriented Are Accounting Standards?

22

Madsen (2011) finds that the citations from financial accounting topics in the Handbook

become increasingly dominated by standard-setters while concurrently the citations to non-standard-

setter groups become less frequent, consistent with Baxter (1962) and Zeff (1986). This trend is not

apparent in managerial accounting topics suggesting that the cause is not something that is general to

all of accounting but is peculiar to financial accounting. In this study, we more closely examine

financial accounting topics to see whether the rules-orientation of the standard governing them is

predictably associated with the rate of the changes in citations documented in Madsen (2011).

Specifically, we test whether the increase in standard-setter citations and the decline in citations to

non-standard-setters have been larger in switch topics than in control topics.

To conduct our tests, we begin by collecting citations from the Handbooks’ discussions of

our switch topics from three editions prior to the switch to a rules-based standard and three editions

after the switch and for the control topics from each edition from which we coded any switch topic

data. Table 7 shows our control and switch topics and the Handbook editions from which we

collected citations data for each of them. Where possible, we collected citations from 10 randomly

selected pages discussing a given topic in a given Handbook edition. We require that selected pages

be at least three quarters text. For many of our topics, these pages were together in a single

Handbook chapter dedicated to discussing our topic. When this is the case, Table 7 shows the

relevant chapter number. In other cases, the pages were not collected in one chapter but were spread

over many chapters. In these cases, we use the Handbooks’ indices to identify pages and subsections

which discuss our topics. For these cases, Table 7 lists the word “index” instead of a chapter number.

The notes to Table 7 list our search terms. If there were more than 10 such pages, we randomly select

10 of them to code. Where there were fewer than 10 pages discussing one of our topics, we collect

data from every page or subsection discussing the given topic in the given Handbook edition and

record the number of lines of text making up the coded page or subsection. The result is a list of

Page 25: How Rules-Oriented Are Accounting Standards?

23

citations hand collected from our control and switch topics along with the number of pages or

proportion of pages from which they were collected.17

Then, using the line counts, we adjust our citation counts, which are on a “citations-per-line”

basis for some topics and a “citations-per-page” basis for others, to be consistently on a “citations per

page” basis. The number of words on an average page of the Handbook differs from edition to

edition. The final step is to adjust all citations-per-page values to be in terms of 3rd edition pages so

that they are comparable across editions with different page lengths.

At the end of this process, we have a list of citations-per-page for each of our Handbook

edition/accounting topic pairs. We take these citations and group them into two groups: standard-

setters, which includes citations to the CAP, APB, and FASB, and non-standard-setters which

includes all other citations which were to specific individual experts, journal articles, books, AAA,

AIA, AICPA, NACA, and regulators like the SEC and IRS. There is some ambiguity in this

classification exercise because the AICPA has been the parent to financial accounting standard-

setting organizations (the CAP and APB) and the audit standard-setter. The SEC also issues standard-

like rules. In robustness tests, we include citations to the AICPA and SEC in our standard-setters

category. We discuss the results of the robustness tests in the results section.

Results

Table 8 shows the average citations per page for each edition/topic pair. For example, hedge

accounting in the 6th edition (1981) averaged 2.33 citations per page to non-standard-setter groups.

Table 8 is separated into Panel A, which shows the citations per page to non-standard-setter groups

and Panel B, which lists the citations per page to standard-setters. Each panel is also separated into

the switch topics (the switch occurs after the underlined number in the table and before the number

just below it) and principles-only topics. An increase in citations to standard-setters without a 17 An independent coder with no knowledge of this study’s predictions coded about 10% of the pages we coded to determine the reliability of our data collection process. The independent coder recorded the same citations as we did in 88% of cases.

Page 26: How Rules-Oriented Are Accounting Standards?

24

corresponding decrease to non-standard-setter groups would indicate that standard setters are getting

more attention without crowding others out. An increase in citations to standard-setters with a

corresponding decline in citations to non-standard-setter groups would suggest that standard-setters

are crowding others out of the dialogue, reducing the breadth of accounting discourse.

In Table 8, the final two columns show the average citations-per-page for switch topics and

principles-only topics. These two columns show that over time there were declines in the citations-

per-page to non-standard-setters and increases in citations-per-page to standard-setters in both switch

and principles-only topics. It is not immediately apparent from Table 8 whether these trends were

stronger in switch topics than in non-switch topics.

We make statistical comparisons of the magnitude of the decline in citations-per-page to non-

standard-setters and the increase in citations-per-page to standard-setters in the switch versus

principles-only topics in Table 9.18 These statistical tests are informative about whether the finding

that standard-setters crowd other participants out of the professional accounting dialogue is more

pronounced in topics that switched to a rules-based standard. Table 9 differs from Table 8 in that it

aligns the switch topics in event time and shows values for each edition/topic pair for the switch

topics only. The values in Table 9 represent the difference between the citations-per-page in each

switch topic and the average citations-per-page in the principles-only topics from the same time-

period. For example, in Table 9 Panel A, the value at t-3 for hedge accounting is 1.23 which

represents the citations-per-page to non-standard-setters in the hedge section of the 6th edition of the

Handbook (2.33) less the average citations-per-page to non-standard-setters in the principles-only

sections of the 6th edition (1.10).

18 The first row of Table 8, representing the 3rd edition, has switch topic data from only the lease topic. The 3rd edition of the Handbook contained only one tenth of one page discussing leases and that passage contained only one citation (to an accounting expert). When we adjust the citations data to be on a citations-per-page basis, this single citation is inflated by a factor of 10. Because it is based on so little data, we drop the lease observation from the 3rd edition in our statistical tests in Table 9.

Page 27: How Rules-Oriented Are Accounting Standards?

25

The last column in Table 9 shows the average of the differences before the switch to a rules-

based standard and after the switch. Table 9 Panel A shows that before the switch, the sections

discussing switch topics contained, on average, 0.28 more citations-per-page to non-standard-setters

than did the discussions of principles-only topics. But this changed after the switch to a rules-based

standard. After the switch, the discussions from the switch topics contained on average 0.37 fewer

citations-per-page to non-standard-setters than the discussions in the principles-only sections. This

represents a decline in citations-per-page to non-standard-setters that was greater by 0.65 citations-

per-page in switch topics than in non-switch topics. This is evidence that the decline in citations-per-

page to non-standard-setters was larger for accounting topics that switched to a rules-based standard

than for topics that were consistently governed by a principles-based standard. A t-test taking each of

the edition/switch topic observations from Table 9 as observations shows that this faster decline in

switch topics was statistically significant at the p = 0.05 level.19

Table 9 Panel B shows that before the switch to rules-based standards, the switch topics

contained, on average, 0.89 more citations-per-page to standard-setters than the principles-only

topics. The magnitude of this difference grew after the switch to a rules-based standard to 1.83

citations-per-page. The increase in the size of the difference amounts to 0.94 citations-per-page

which is statistically significant at the p = 0.05 level. This is evidence that the trend toward more

citations-per-page to standard-setters was stronger in the discussions of switch topics than in

discussions of principles-only topics. Together, the results in Table 9 are consistent with our

prediction that the “crowding out” effect of standardization on participants in the accounting

discourse is particularly strong when standards are rules-based.

In robustness test, we repeat these tests after reclassifying the AICPA and SEC into the

standard-setters group. The result is that the decline in citations-per-page to non-standard-setters and

the increase in citations-per-page to standard-setters become slightly less different in the switch and 19 We use unpaired t-tests assuming unequal variances in Table 9 Panels A and B.

Page 28: How Rules-Oriented Are Accounting Standards?

26

principles-only topics than they were in our main tests. This can be interpreted as a weakening of our

result that the crowding out effect is stronger for rules-based than for principles-based standards. The

increase in citations to standard-setters was greater in switch topics than in principles-only topics by

0.64 citations-per-page (p = 0.05) and the decline in citations to non-standard-setters was greater in

switch topics than in principles-only topics by 0.35 (p = 0.11).

The results in this section are consistent with previous findings that in financial accounting,

the influence of standard-setters in the dialogue among professional accountants has increased over

time while concurrently the participation of non-standard-setter groups has declined (Madsen 2011).

This is consistent with standard-setters crowding other participants out of the professional dialogue

concerning financial accounting. Our results further suggest that this trend was stronger for financial

accounting topics that were governed by rules-based, rather than principles-based standards.

V. CONCLUSIONS

The claim that U.S. GAAP has become excessively rules-based and would improve if it were

to become more principles-based has recently received significant attention from accounting

regulators and researchers (FASB 2002, SEC 2003, Batson 2003 40, Benston et al. 2006, Ball 2009).

But such claims are inevitably based on scant evidence because of the scarcity of counterfactuals

against which to compare U.S. GAAP (Ball 2008). Another consequence so the scarcity of

counterfactuals is that the consequences of an extremely rules-based U.S. GAAP are not well

understood.

In this study, we first use the cross-section of U.S. occupations to put the rules-orientation of

financial reporting and auditing standards in perspective. We show that the rules-orientation of

occupational standards is a function of observable occupational characteristics including the

importance of standards to an occupation’s work, the complexity of the work, the extent to which the

occupation puts people or property at risk, the importance of adaptability on the job, the extent to

Page 29: How Rules-Oriented Are Accounting Standards?

27

which the occupation is professionalized, whether they inspect others’ work, and occupation size. We

then show that the rules-orientation of the standards used by auditors is extremely high, even after

controlling for the characteristics of the auditing profession that likely influence the costs and

benefits of rules-oriented standards. This is consistent with the claim that U.S. GAAP is extremely

rules-oriented.

We then examine one potential consequence of rules-based standards, that they crowd non-

standard-setter participants out of the professional discourse about financial accounting with

distinctive potency. We test this claim using citations from several editions of a long popular

accounting reference manual called the Accountants’ Handbook. We collect citations from topics

which were consistently governed by principles-based standards and from sections that came to be

governed by rules-based standards and study how the citations changed in these sections over time.

In all of our sections, whether they were governed by principles- or rules-based standards, we find

that the influence of standard-setters steadily increased while the participation of non-standard-setter

groups steadily declined, consistent with standard-setters crowding other participants out of the

accounting dialogue. We then show that these trends were stronger for accounting topics that

switched to a rules-based standard, suggesting that the crowding out effect is particularly strong

when standards are rules-based.

There is a well recognized scarcity of research evaluating the quality of accounting’s

regulatory institutions. We do not have good answers to even some of the most basic questions about

them. Why is financial reporting regulated (Healy and Palepu 2001, Kothari et al. 2010)? What are

the costs and benefits of financial reporting regulation (Leuz and Wysocki 2008)? How do the

benefits of financial reporting regulation compare to the costs (Beyer et al. 2010)? These questions,

and many others, remain unanswered even after more than 70 years of federal disclosure regulation.

A primary reason for our ignorance is that world does not produce easily exploitable natural

experiments that we can use to discover the answers. “What does he know of England who only

Page 30: How Rules-Oriented Are Accounting Standards?

28

England knows?”20 Or in other words, evaluation of anything requires that it be compared against

something else. But every option for comparison that has been identified by researchers interested in

accounting regulators has critical limitations (Ball 2008).

In this study we evaluate accounting standard-setters using a source of variation that has

received very little attention in the accounting literature, the cross-section of U.S. occupations. This

research setting, like the others, has limitations. Occupations differ. The differences are critically

important because they constitute variation, and researchers need variation to learn from data. But

one must carefully account for the effects of ancillary differences between occupations in order to

isolate the effects of the differences of interest. The cross-section of occupations has distinctive

strengths. The characteristics of the occupations have been carefully, and fairly exhaustively,

quantified. These data are publicly available. U.S. occupations have all developed under the same

national institutions, facing a similar cultural, legal, and economic environment, but are also subject

to widely varying regulatory systems. These features make the cross-section of U.S. occupations a

valuable source of counterfactual worlds against which to compare the existing accounting regulatory

system.

The present study corroborates the finding in Madsen (2011) that accounting standards are

extreme relative to the standards of other occupations. It also shows that this extremity could have

important detrimental long-term consequences. Why are accounting standards extreme? Is there a

benefit that offsets the costs? These are puzzles for future research. Research exploiting the variation

available in the cross-section of U.S. occupations will likely be a profitable source of answers.

20 This is an idiom that has been attributed to Kipling and Shakespeare but of which I have been unable to find the original source.

Page 31: How Rules-Oriented Are Accounting Standards?

29

Appendix A Example of Switch from Principles-Based to Rules-Based

Lease Accounting

RULES-BASED – FAS 13 (Nov. 1976)

FAS 13 p7. ...If at its inception (as defined in paragraph 5(b)) a lease meets one or more of the following four criteria, the lease shall be classified as a capital lease by the lessee. Otherwise, it shall be classified as an operating lease…. A. The lease transfers ownership of the property to the lessee by the end of the lease term b. The lease contains a bargain purchase option... c. The lease term (as defined in paragraph 5(f)) is equal to 75 percent or more of the estimated economic life of the leased property... d. The present value at the beginning of the lease term of the minimum lease payments....equals or exceeds 90 percent of the excess of the fair value of the leased property

PRINCIPLES-BASED – APB 5 (Sept. 1964) APB 5 10. ...The presence...of either of the two following conditions will usually establish that a lease should be considered to be in substance a purchase: a. The initial term is materially less than the useful life of the property, and the lessee has the option to renew the lease for the remaining useful life of the property at substantially less than the fair rental value; or b. The lessee has the right, during or at the expiration of the lease, to acquire the property at a price which at the inception of the lease appears to be substantially less than the probable fair value of the property at the time or times of permitted acquisition by the lessee. 11. ...the existence... of one or more circumstances such as those shown below tend to indicate that the lease arrangement is in substance a purchase and should be accounted for as such. a. The property was acquired by the lessor to meet the special needs of the lessee and will probably be usable only for that purpose and only by the lessee. b. The term of the lease corresponds substantially to the estimated useful life of the property, and the lessee is obligated to pay costs such as taxes, insurance, and maintenance, which are usually considered incidental to ownership. c. The lessee has guaranteed the obligations of the lessor with respect to the property leased. d. The lessee has treated the lease as a purchase for tax purposes.

Page 32: How Rules-Oriented Are Accounting Standards?

30

Appendix B Citation Definition

In general, a citation is coded when the author of the handbook references an external source of information (source of information other than the writer). Citations generally appear in 3 types.

1. Citation to a specific source. Examples include, “SFAS No. 109 allows partial recognition…” This would be coded as a citation to the FASB (Standard-setter). Another example would be a citation to The Wall Street Journal; this would be coded as a citation to a non-standard setting body.

2. Citation to a general source. Examples include, “The AICPA’s position on this topic has been…”, which would be coded as a citation to the AICPA (non-standard setter). Also, “…which matches current costs with sales, according to some writers, will tend to…” “Some writers” would be coded as a citation to non-standard setters.

3. An indirect citation to a specific source. Examples include, “as defined in the lease classification criteria.” This would be a citation to the FASB (standard-setting body) as it indirectly cites FAS 13’s capital lease criteria. Another example occurred when a paragraph mentions “the standard indicates” wherein the context a specific standards was being discussed. This would be coded according to the body which set the standard being discussed. There were very few of these types of citations.

Citation rules: 1. Only one instance of a specific citation was recorded if it appeared multiple times in the same

paragraph. For example, if APB Opinion No. 5 was referred to twice in one paragraph, only one citation would be recorded. On the other hand, if APB Opinion No. 5 and APB Opinion No. 7 were both referred to in one paragraph, two separate citations would be recorded.

2. As page numbers were selected to code, only the first full citation on a page was recorded. If a citation began on a non-selected page and finished on a selected page, it was not recorded.

3. If a citation contained an additional citation, only the first, or parent, citation was recorded.

Page 33: How Rules-Oriented Are Accounting Standards?

31

REFERENCES

Abbott, A. (1988). The System of Professions: An Essay on the Division of Expert Labor. Chicago, IL, US: University of Chicago Press.

Alchian, A. (1950). Uncertainty, evolution, and economic theory. Journal of Political Economy 58 (3): 211-221.

Arrow, K. J. (1963). Uncertainty and the welfare economics of medical care. The American Economic Review 53 (5): 941-973.

Batson, N. 2004. Final report of Neal Batson, court-appointed examiner, in Re: Enron Corp., et al., debtors, United States Bankruptcy Court, Southern District of New York.

Baer, W. (1986). Expertise and professional standards. Work and occupations 13 (4): 532-552.

Baum, C. (2006). An Introduction to Modern Econometrics Using Stata. College State, TX, US: Stata Press.

Baxter, W. T. (1962). Recommendations on accounting theory. Studies in Accounting Theory. London, UK: Sweet and Maxwell Limited.

Baxter, W. T. (1979). Accounitng standards: Boon or curse? The Saxe Lectures in Accounting, February 13, City University of New York.

Bennett, B., M. Bradbury, and H. Prangnell. (2006). Rules, principles and judgments in accounting standards. Abacus 42 (2): 189–204.

Benner, M. J. and M. Tushman. (2002). Process management and technological innovation: A longitudinal study of the photography and paint industries. Administrative Science Quarterly, 47 (4): 676-707.

Benston, G. J., M. Bromwich, and A. Wagenhofer. (2006). Principles- versus rules-based accounting standards: the FASB's standard setting strategy. Abacus 42 (2): 165–188.

Ball, R. (2008). What is the actual economic role of financial reporting? Accounting Horizons 22 (4): 427-432.

Ball, R. (2009). Market and political/regulatory perspectives on the recent accounting scandals. Journal of Accounting Research 47 (2): 277–323

Bratton, W. W. (2007). Private standards, public governance: A new look at the Financial Accounting Standards Board. Boston College Law Review 48 (1): 5-53.

Broshko, E. B., and K. Li. 2006. Playing by the rules: Comparing principles-based and rules-based corporate governance in Canada and the U.S. Canadian Investment Review (Winter): 18-23.

Brunsson, N. and B. Jacobsson. 2000. A World of Standards. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.

Page 34: How Rules-Oriented Are Accounting Standards?

32

Buchanan, J. M., and G. Tullock. 1962. The Calculus of Consent: Logical Foundations of a Constitutional Democracy. Ann Arbor, MI, US: The University of Michigan Press.

Carmichael, D. R., Lilien, S. B., and M. Mellman (eds.). 1991. Accountants’ Handbook (7th ed.). New York: The Ronald Press Company.

Carmichael, D. R., Lilien, S. B., and M. Mellman (eds.). 1996. Accountants’ Handbook (8th ed.). New York: The Ronald Press Company.

Carmichael, D. R., Lilien, S. B., and M. Mellman (eds.). 1999. Accountants’ Handbook (9th ed.). New York: The Ronald Press Company.

Carmichael, D. R., and P. H. Rosenfield (eds.). 2003. Accountants’ Handbook (10th ed.). New York: The Ronald Press Company.

Carmichael, D. R., Whittington, O. R., and L. Graham (eds.). 2007. Accountants’ Handbook (11th ed.). New York: The Ronald Press Company.

Cole, R. E. and T. Matsumiya. (2007). Too much of a good thing? Quality as an impediment to innovation. California Management Review 50 (1): 77-93.

Dye, R. A. and S. Sunder. (2001). Why not allow FASB and IASB standards to compete in the US? Accounting Horizons 15 (3): 257-271.

Farrell, J. and G. Saloner. (1985). Standardization, compatibility, and innovation. The RAND Journal of Economics 16 (1): 70-83.

Farrell, J., C. Shapiro, R. R. Nelson, and R. G. Noll. (1992). Standard setting in high-definition

television. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity: Microeconomics: 1-93

Financial Accounting Standards Board. (1991). Special Report: Benefits, costs, and consequences of financial accounting standards. Norwalk, CT, US: FASB.

Financial Accounting Standards Board. (2002). Principles-based approach to standard setting. The FASB Report, (November 27).

Friedson, E. (2001). Professionalism: The Third Logic. Chicago, IL., US: University of Chicago Press.

Hayek, F. A. translated by M. S. Snow. 1968. Competition as a discovery procedure. Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics 5 (3): 9-23.

He, Z. and P. Wong. (2004). Exploration vs. exploitation: An empirical test of the ambidexterity hypothesis. Organization Science 15 (4): 481-494.

Healy, P. M. (2003). Discussion of privacy in e-commerce: Development of reporting standards, disclosure, and assurance services in an unregulated market. Journal of Accounting Research 41 (2): 311–315.

Page 35: How Rules-Oriented Are Accounting Standards?

33

Healy, P. M. and K. G. Palepu. (2001). Information asymmetry, corporate disclosure, and the capital markets: A review of the empirical disclosure literature. Journal of Accounting and Economics 31 (1-3): 405-440.

Horngren, C. T. 1972. Accounting principles: Private or public sector? Journal of Accountancy 1972 (5): 37-41.

Jamal, K., Maier, M., and S. Sunder. 2005. Enforced standards versus evolution by general acceptance: A comparative study of e-commerce privacy disclosure and practice in the United States and the United Kingdom. Journal of Accounting Research 43 (1): 73-96.

Katz, M. L., and C. Shapiro. 1985. Network externalities, competition, and compatibility. The American Economic Review 75 (3): 424-440.

Kohlbeck, M., and T. Warfield. 2010. Accounting standard attributes and accounting quality: Discussion and analysis. Research in Accounting Regulation 22 (2): 59-70.

Kohn, M. 2004. Value and exchange. Cato Journal 24 (3): 303-339.

Kothari, S. P., Ramanna, K., and D. J. Skinner. 2010. Implications for GAAP from analysis of positive research in accounting. Journal of Accounting and Economics 50 (2-3): 246-286.

Kleiner, M. M. 2006. Licensing Occupations: Ensuring Quality or Restricting Competition. Kalamazoo, MI: W.E. Upjohn Institute for Employment Research.

Kling, A. 2007. Adaptation and the Economy. TCSDaily (June 19).

Larson, M. S. 1977. The Rise of Professionalism: A Sociological Analysis. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.

Lee, T. 1995. The professionalization of accountancy: A history of protecting the public in a self-interested way. Accounting, Auditing and Accountability Journal 8 (4): 48–69.

Macdonald, K. M. 1995. The Sociology of the Professions. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage Publications Ltd.

Madsen, P. E. 2011. How standardized is accounting? The Accounting Review 86 (5): 1679-1708.

Mahoney, P. G. 2003. The origins of the blue-sky laws: A test of competing hypotheses. Journal of Law and Economics 46 (1): 229-251.

March, J. G. 1991. Exploration and exploitation in organizational learning. Organizational Science 2 (1): 71–87.

McLeay, S., Ordelheide, D., and S. Young. 2004. Constituent lobbying and its impact on the development of financial reporting regulations: Evidence from Germany in Leuz, C., Pfaff, D., and A. Hopwood (eds.) The Economics and Politics of Accounting. Oxford, U.K.: Oxford University Press.

Page 36: How Rules-Oriented Are Accounting Standards?

34

Meeks, G., and P. Swann. 2009. Accounting standards and the economics of standards. Accounting and Business Research 39 (3): 191-210.

Mergenthaler, R. D. 2009. Principles-based versus rules-based standards and earnings management. Working Paper.

Nelson, M. W., Elliott, J. A., and R. L. Tarpley. 2002. Evidence from auditors about managers’ and auditors’ earnings management decisions. The Accounting Review 77 (Supplement): 175-202

North, D. C. 1990. Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press.

North, D. C. 2005. Understanding the Process of Economic Change. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

Olson, M. 1965. The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups. Boston, MA: Harvard University Press.

Paton, W. A. (ed.). 1943. Accountants’ Handbook (3rd ed.). New York: The Ronald Press Company.

Raisch, S., and J. Birkinshaw. 2008. Organizational ambidexterity: Antecedents, outcomes, and moderators. Journal of Management 34 (4): 375-409.

Routh, G. 1965. Occupation and pay in Great Britain 1906-1960. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press.

Schipper, K. 2003. Principles-based accounting standards. Accounting Horizons 17 (1): 61-72.

Securities and Exchange Commission. 2003. Study pursuant to section 108(d) of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act of 2002 on the adoption by the United States Financial Reporting System of a principles-based accounting system. http://www.sec.gov/news/studies/principlesbasedstand.htm.

Seidler, L. J., and D. R. Carmichael (eds.). 1981. Accountants’ Handbook (6th ed.). New York: The Ronald Press Company.

Shortridge, R. T., and M. Myring. 2004. Defining principles-based accounting standards. The CPA Journal (August). http://www.nysscpa.org/cpajournal/2004/804/essentials/p34.htm.

Smith, C. M. 2005. Origin and uses of primum non nocere – above all, do no harm! The Journal of Clinical Pharmacology 45 (4): 371-377.

Stigler, G. J. 1971. The theory of economic regulation. The Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science 2 (1): 3-21.

Sunder, S. 1988. Political economy of accounting standards. Journal of Accounting Literature 7: 31-41.

Page 37: How Rules-Oriented Are Accounting Standards?

35

Sunder, S. 2005. Minding our manners: Accounting as social norms. The British Accounting Review 37 (4): 367-387

Sunder, S. 2010. Adverse effects of uniform written reporting standards on accounting practice, education, and research. Journal of Accounting and Public Policy 29 (2): 99-114.

Uotila, J., Maula, M., Keil, T., and S. A. Zahra. 2009. Exploration, exploitation and financial performance: Analysis of S&P 500 corporations. Strategic Management Journal 30 (2): 221-231.

Uniformity in railway accounting. 1906. Editorial. Journal of Accountancy 3 (1): 36-38.

Watts, R. L. 2003. Conservatism in accounting, Part I: Explanations and implications. Accounting Horizons 17 (3): 207–221.

Watts, R., and J. Zimmerman. 1986. Positive Accounting Theory. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall.

White, L. H. 2005. The Federal Reserve system’s influence on research in monetary economics. Econ. Journal Watch 2 (2): 325-354.

Wixon, R. (ed.). 1956. Accountants’ Handbook (4th ed.). New York: The Ronald Press Company.

Wixon, R., Kell, W. G., and N. M. Bedford (eds.). 1970. Accountants’ Handbook (5th ed.). New York: The Ronald Press Company.

Zeff, S. A. 1978. The rise of “economic consequences.” The Journal of Accountancy 146 (6): 56-63.

Zeff, S. A. 1986. Big eight firms and the accounting literature: The falloff in advocacy writing. Journal of Accounting, Auditing, and Finance 1 (2): 131-154.

Zeff, S. A. 2002. “Political” lobbying on proposed standards: A challenge to the IASB. Accounting Horizons 16 (1): 43-54.

Zeff, S. A. 2005. The evolution of U.S. GAAP. The CPA Journal 75 (1): 18-27.

Page 38: How Rules-Oriented Are Accounting Standards?

36

FIGURE 1 O*NET Question That Is the Source of the Standardization Measures

This figure shows the full text of the O*NET question from which data on the importance of standards and the rules-orientation of standards (level of complexity) are collected.

Page 39: How Rules-Oriented Are Accounting Standards?

37

FIGURE 2 Rules-Orientation of O*NET Occupations Organized by Occupation Group

Each dot represents an occupation from the O*NET 4.0 database. The y-axis shows the rules-orientation of occupational standards which is the portion of the complexity of occupational standards that is not explained by the importance of occupational standards.

Page 40: How Rules-Oriented Are Accounting Standards?

38

TABLE 1 Results of Factor Analysis to Create Proxies for Complexity, Physical Legal Risk, Adaptation,

and Inspection Panel A: Factors and Eigenvalues a Construct Factor Eigenvalue Proportion Explained Cumulative Explained Complexity 1 5.94 0.94 0.94 2 0.19 0.03 0.97 3 0.11 0.02 0.99 4 0.05 0.01 0.99 5 0.03 0.00 1.00 6 0.01 0.00 1.00 7 -0.00 0.00 1.00 Legal Risk Physical 1 1.52 0.94 0.94 2 0.09 0.06 1.00 3 -0.00 -0.00 1.00 Adaptation 1 4.44 0.91 0.91 2 0.27 0.06 0.97 3 0.13 0.03 0.99 4 0.03 0.01 1.00 5 0.00 0.00 1.00 6 -0.00 0.00 1.00 Inspection 1 2.53 0.63 0.63 2 0.59 0.15 0.77 3 0.51 0.13 0.90 4 0.22 0.05 0.95 5 0.11 0.03 0.98 6 0.07 0.02 1.00 7 0.00 0.00 1.00 8 -0.00 -0.00 1.00

Page 41: How Rules-Oriented Are Accounting Standards?

39

TABLE 1 (continued) Results of Factor Analysis to Create Proxies for Complexity, Physical Legal Risk, Adaptation,

and Inspection Panel B: Variable Loadings on Factors b Legal Risk Variable Complexity Physical Adaptation Inspection Analyzing data or information 0.95 Complex Problem Solving 0.95 Making Decisions and Solving Problems 0.95 Provide Consultation and Advice to Others 0.92 Interpreting the Meaning of Information for Others 0.90 Judgment and Decision Making 0.90 Training 0.83 Responsible for Others' Health and Safety 0.92 Knowledge of public safety and security 0.67 Physical harm 0.48 Fluency of ideas 0.96 Originality of thought 0.90 Active Learning 0.88 Thinking Creatively 0.85 Updating and Using Relevant Knowledge 0.77 Coordination and adjusting actions in relation to others' actions. 0.73 O*NET Relevance Search - "Examine" 0.93 O*NET Relevance Search - "Examiner" 0.88 O*NET Relevance Search - "Investigate" 0.43 O*NET Relevance Search - "Review" 0.40 O*NET Relevance Search - "Audit" 0.35 O*NET Relevance Search - "Inspect" 0.33 O*NET Relevance Search - "Verify" 0.33 O*NET Relevance Search - "Check" 0.16 a Eigenvalues in Panel A are taken from unconstrained, unrotated factor analyses. b Factor Loadings are taken from factor analyses constrained to one factor. This table shows results from factor analyzing variables from the O*NET 4.0 database maintained by the U.S. Department of Labor (DOL). The unit of analysis is the occupation. Factor analysis is performed using the iterated principal factors method. Training is labeled “Job Zone” in O*NET. Physical Harm is a variable we construct by taking the maximum value across the following O*NET variables which all measure occupational exposure to various hazards: very hot temperatures, very cold temperatures, extremely bright or inadequate lighting conditions, sounds and noise levels that are distracting and uncomfortable, whole body vibration, hazardous equipment, hazardous conditions, high places, diseases or infection, radiation, and contaminants. Variables labeled “O*NET Relevance Search” are scores for each occupation of the relevance of a given search term provided by the O*NET website in searches of the O*NET 16.0 database.

Page 42: How Rules-Oriented Are Accounting Standards?

40

TABLE 2 Descriptive Statistics, Values, and Rankings for Auditors

Auditors Variable Description Mean Median Min Max n Value Percentile Rules-Orientation 2.63 2.50 0.16 6.83 643 5.50 99.5% Importance of Standards 3.02 3.00 1.00 5.00 643 4.33 97.5% Complexity 0.00 -0.15 -1.71 2.28 643 1.89 96.7% Legal Risk Physical 0.00 -0.21 -1.23 2.73 643 -0.83 21.3% Consequence of Error 2.86 2.78 1.33 4.87 643 3.67 86.5% Responsibility for Outcomes 1.86 1.63 1.00 4.00 643 2.54 82.9% Adaptation 0.00 -0.12 -1.95 2.56 643 0.79 73.9% Compensation 3.10 3.12 1.62 4.62 643 3.75 91.3% Inspection 0.00 -0.31 -0.49 7.89 643 3.92 98.4% State Licensing 1.19 1.00 0.00 5.00 643 5.00 99.8% Occupation Size 10.74 10.72 6.49 15.19 643 12.98 92.1% The sample comes from the O*NET database maintained by the U.S. Department of Labor (DOL). The unit of analysis is the occupation. Rules-Orientation is a measure of the level of complexity of occupational standards. Importance of Standards is a measure of the importance of evaluating information to determine if it complies with standards to the work of the occupation. Complexity is a measure of the complexity of an occupation’s work. Legal Risk Physical is a measure of the extent to which the work of the occupation puts people at risk of physical injury. Consequence of Error measures the severity of a worker’s mistake if not readily correctable. Responsibility for Outcomes measures how responsible the worker is for outcomes and results of other workers. Adaptation is the measure of the need for innovation and adaptability on the job. Compensation is a measured of the extent to which workers in an occupation value receiving high levels of compensation relative to other occupations. Inspection is a measure of the extent to which an occupation performs inspection or audit tasks. State Licensing is a measure of the number of states that require a license to work in a given occupation (in units of ten). Occupation Size is the log of the number of workers in the occupation. The columns labeled “Auditors” show the value of each variable for auditors and the percentile location of that value among all occupations in the sample where 100th percentile is the largest value in the sample.

Page 43: How Rules-Oriented Are Accounting Standards?

41

TABLE 3 Correlations between Variables in Rules-Orientation Regression

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 1. Rules-Orientation 2. Importance of 0.75 Standards 0.00 3. Complexity 0.83 0.46 0.00 0.00 4. Legal Risk Physical 0.10 0.04 0.11 0.01 0.26 0.01 5. Consequence of Error 0.42 0.32 0.37 0.59 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 6. Responsibility for 0.44 0.29 0.57 0.31 0.39 Outcomes 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 7. Adaptation 0.68 0.39 0.90 0.12 0.31 0.63 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 8. Compensation 0.52 0.31 0.60 0.12 0.48 0.46 0.57 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 9. Inspection 0.29 0.31 0.12 -0.01 0.11 -0.03 0.00 0.04 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.76 0.00 0.53 0.92 0.32 10. State Licensing 0.27 0.13 0.34 0.28 0.28 0.18 0.27 0.30 0.07 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.06 11. Occupation Size 0.01 0.12 -0.08 -0.08 -0.03 -0.03 -0.05 -0.17 0.04 0.19 0.80 0.00 0.04 0.03 0.42 0.42 0.22 0.00 0.29 0.00 Reported coefficients are Pearson correlations. Spearman correlation coefficients are not reported because they are virtually identical to the reported Pearson correlations. Italicized rows are p-values. The sample comes from the O*NET database maintained by the U.S. Department of Labor (DOL). The unit of analysis is the occupation. Rules-Orientation is a measure of the level of complexity of occupational standards. Importance of Standards is a measure of the importance of evaluating information to determine if it complies with standards to the work of the occupation. Complexity is a measure of the complexity of an occupation’s work. Legal Risk Physical is a measure of the extent to which the work of the occupation puts people at risk of physical injury. Consequence of Error measures the severity of a worker’s mistake if not readily correctable. Responsibility for Outcomes measures how responsible the worker is for outcomes and results of other workers. Adaptation is the measure of the need for innovation and adaptability on the job. Compensation is a measured of the extent to which workers in an occupation value receiving high levels of compensation relative to other occupations. Inspection is a measure of the extent to which an occupation performs inspection or audit tasks. State Licensing is a measure of the number of states that require a license to work in a given occupation (in units of ten). Occupation Size is the log of the number of workers in the occupation.

Page 44: How Rules-Oriented Are Accounting Standards?

42

TABLE 4 Regression Explaining the Rules-Orientation of Occupational Standards

Variable Predicted Sign Coefficient Estimates Importance of Standards + 0.597*** Complexity + 0.854*** Legal Risk Physical + 0.019 Consequence of Error + 0.069** Responsibility for Outcomes + -0.073†† Adaptation - -0.236*** Inspection - 0.049†† Compensation + 0.063 State Licensing + -0.026†† Occupation Size + 0.018** Constant 0.415 R2 0.879 Observations 643 ** and *** Represent statistical significance at the p = 0.05, and 0.01 levels, respectively. †† represents statistical significance of the variable but with a sign opposite the predicted sign. P-values are one-tailed for all variables. The sample comes from the O*NET database maintained by the U.S. Department of Labor (DOL). The unit of analysis is the occupation. Rules-Orientation is the dependent variable and is a measure of the level of complexity of occupational standards. Importance of Standards is a measure of the importance of evaluating information to determine if it complies with standards to the work of the occupation. Complexity is a measure of the complexity of an occupation’s work. Legal Risk Physical is a measure of the extent to which the work of the occupation puts people at risk of physical injury. Consequence of Error measures the severity of a worker’s mistake if not readily correctable. Responsibility for Outcomes measures how responsible the worker is for outcomes and results of other workers. Adaptation is the measure of the need for innovation and adaptability on the job. Compensation is a measured of the extent to which workers in an occupation value receiving high levels of compensation relative to other occupations. Inspection is a measure of the extent to which an occupation performs inspection or audit tasks. State Licensing is a measure of the number of states that require a license to work in a given occupation (in units of ten). Occupation Size is the log of the number of workers in the occupation. Occupations in O*NET 4.0 are organized according to the SOC occupation classification system. Similar occupations in the SOC are grouped together in two-digit SOC codes. We cluster errors by two-digit SOC code to control for possible correlation of the errors terms across similar occupations.

Page 45: How Rules-Oriented Are Accounting Standards?

43

TABLE 5 Regression Residuals for Selections of Occupations

Panel A: Selection of Accounting Occupations Rules- Occupation Orientation Prediction Error Error Rank N Error %ile Tax Preparers 3.50 2.63 0.87 6 643 99.1% Auditors 5.50 5.01 0.49 48 643 92.5% Bookkeeping, Accounting, 3.66 3.27 0.39 78 643 87.9% and Auditing Clerks Accountants 4.50 4.49 0.01 300 643 53.3% Tax Examiners, Collectors, 4.33 4.55 -0.22 488 643 24.1% and Revenue Agents Panel B: Selection of Professions Rules- Occupation Orientation Prediction Error Error Rank N Error %ile Top 7 out of 32 Professions Ranked by Error Judges, Magistrate 6.83 5.16 1.67 1 643 99.8% Judges, and Magistrates Nuclear Engineers 6.00 4.99 1.02 5 643 99.2% Chemical Engineers 4.83 4.22 0.61 32 643 95.0% Physicists 5.16 4.55 0.60 33 643 94.9% Auditors 5.50 5.01 0.49 48 643 92.5% Electrical Engineers 4.60 4.18 0.42 68 643 89.4% Actuaries 4.83 4.43 0.40 76 643 88.2% Aerospace Engineers 5.16 4.84 0.32 117 643 81.8% Bottom 7 out of 32 Professions Ranked by Error Architects 4.00 4.11 -0.11 412 643 35.9% Surgeons 4.40 4.52 -0.12 425 643 33.9% Registered Nurses 3.58 3.78 -0.20 479 643 25.5% Clergy 2.66 2.91 -0.25 509 643 20.8% Anesthesiologists 4.00 4.28 -0.28 516 643 19.8% Pharmacists 3.66 3.99 -0.33 536 643 16.6% Personal Financial Advisors3.00 3.39 -0.39 560 643 12.9% Economists 1.66 3.08 -1.42 643 643 0% This table shows the rules-orientation of a selection of occupations as estimated by O*NET’s occupational analysts, the rules-orientation predicted for each occupation by our model of occupational rules-orientation (an estimate of the competitively efficient level), the difference between these two values (the regression error) and where this regression error falls in the whole sample of 643 regression errors. Regression errors that are among the largest in the sample are near the 100th percentile while errors that are among the smallest (most negative) in the sample are near the 0th percentile.

Page 46: How Rules-Oriented Are Accounting Standards?

44

TABLE 6 Descriptive Information about the Accountants’ Handbook

Edition Year Editor(s) Contributors % Ph.D. % CPA or CA Total Pages 3 1943 W. A. Paton 89 39%† -† 1505 4 1956 Rufus Wixon 30 67% 80% 1541 Walter G. Kell 5 1970 Rufus Wixon 50 72% 74% 1523 Walter G. Kell Norton M. Bedford 6 1981 Lee J. Seidler 57 30% 75% 2068 D. R. Carmichael 7 1991 D. R. Carmichael 56 21% 82% 1378 Steven B. Lilien Martin Mellman 8 1996 D. R. Carmichael 71 21% 90% 1723^ Steven B. Lilien Martin Mellman 9 1999 D. R. Carmichael 67 12% 91% 1735 Steven B. Lilien Martin Mellman 10 2003 D. R. Carmichael 64 20% 88% 1828 Paul H. Rosenfield 11 2007 D. R. Carmichael 69 20% 87% 1799 O. Ray Whittington Lynford Graham † Because the 3rd edition does not list contributors' degrees and designations, I count the number of contributors described as "Professor" or "Dean" as contributors with Ph.D.s. I was unable to count the number of CPAs or CAs for this edition. ^ Our copy of the eighth edition was spiral bound and was missing Section 4, a section that was not needed for our data collection. To produce an estimate of the total pages in the eighth edition, I assumed that Section 4 was 42 pages long, the average length of the other sections of the eighth edition. Some of the information in this table comes from Madsen (2011).

Page 47: How Rules-Oriented Are Accounting Standards?

45

TABLE 7 Switch and Control Topics and Their Location in the Handbooks from Which Data Were Collected

Switch Topics Control Topics Inventory Edition Year Tax Leases Hedge Pensions Valuation Intangibles Bad Debt 3 1943 index 10 15 index 4 1956 27 index index 12 19 index 5 1970 index index index 12 19 index 6 1981 13 26 index 27 18 23 index 7 1991 17 16 index 26 13 15 index 8 1996 18 17 20 32 14 16 index 9 1999 19 21 32 15 17 index 10 2003 24 18 20 index 11 2007 26 20 22 index The values in this table describe from where in each Handbook’s we collected citations. The top of the table shows seven accounting topics for which we collected data. The first four, tax, leases, hedge accounting, and pension accounting, are topics that are governed by standards that we consider to have switched from principles-based to rules-based. For “switch” topics, we collected data from three editions of the Handbook prior to the switch (ending with the edition whose value is underlined for a particular topic) and three editions of the Handbook after the switch. The final three topics, inventory valuation, intangibles, and bad debt, are accounting topics that were governed by a principles-based standard over the entire sample period. We collected data from “principles-only” topics for every edition in which we collected data for any switch topic. Numbers in the table represent the number of the Handbook section that discusses the topic. The word “index” in the table means that there was not a whole Handbook section dedicated to the topic so we identified relevant pages by searching the index. For the tax topic, our search terms were “taxes” and “income taxes.” For the leases topic, our search terms were “leases”, ”leasehold”, and “leases and leasing”. For the hedge accounting topic our search terms were “hedging”, “futures contracts”, forward exchange contracts”, and “hedges”. For the pensions topic, our search terms were “pension plans”. For the bad debt topic our search terms were “uncollectible accounts” and “uncollectibles”. For each index term used we focused only on those references to financial reporting matters. For example, personal income tax items were not searched.

Page 48: How Rules-Oriented Are Accounting Standards?

46

TABLE 8 Citations per Page to Non-Standard-Setters and Standard-Setters

Panel A: Non-Standard-Setter Groups (Experts, Profession, and Regulators) Switch Topics Principles-Only Topics Average Average Edition Hedge Tax Pension Lease Inventory Intangibles Bad Debt Switch Principles 3 10.00 3.20 2.30 2.90 10.00 2.80 4 1.18 1.96 1.36 1.82 3.00 2.50 1.50 2.44 5 3.38 2.40 1.97 1.08 2.25 2.37 2.58 1.90 6 2.33 1.18 3.55 0.97 1.29 1.08 0.93 2.01 1.10 7 0.88 0.92 0.28 0.09 0.64 1.28 1.18 0.54 1.03 8 1.32 1.32 0.96 0.00 1.49 1.32 0.56 0.90 1.12 9 1.93 0.96 0.88 0.88 1.32 1.11 1.26 1.10 10 0.09 2.26 0.87 0.56 0.09 1.23 11 0.09 0.96 1.14 0.53 0.09 0.88 Average 1.11 1.49 1.67 2.40 1.51 1.62 1.40 Panel B: Standard-Setters (CAP, APB, and FASB) Switch Topics Principles-Only Topics Average Average Edition Hedge Tax Pension Lease Inventory Intangibles Bad Debt Switch Principles 3 0.00 0.10 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.03 4 0.00 0.87 2.27 0.55 0.09 0.00 1.05 0.21 5 0.68 2.00 0.77 0.59 0.39 0.17 1.15 0.38 6 1.00 4.41 2.04 3.33 0.22 3.76 0.47 2.70 1.48 7 1.76 3.85 3.58 1.38 1.19 2.84 0.59 2.64 1.54 8 3.77 5.61 4.12 4.91 1.23 3.60 1.11 4.61 1.98 9 2.37 4.04 3.86 0.96 3.25 1.11 3.42 1.77 10 3.48 1.48 3.48 1.11 3.48 2.02 11 2.89 1.58 3.51 1.05 2.89 2.05 Average 2.55 3.10 2.75 2.11 0.88 2.32 0.62 Data are collected from editions of the Accountants’ Handbook. Values are citations-per-page to non-standard-setter groups (panel A) and standard-setters (panel B). Data are displayed for four topics which were once governed by a principles-based standard but switched to a rules-based standard. These “switch topics” include hedge accounting, tax accounting, pension accounting, and lease accounting. Values in the table come from three editions of the Handbook prior to the switch and three editions after the switch. The transition from principles- to rules-based standard occurs between the underlined value and the value beneath it. We also display data for three topics which were governed by standards that remained principles-based over the sample period. These were inventory accounting, accounting for intangibles, and accounting for bad debts. The table shows average citations-per-page for each accounting topic (in the bottom row) and average citations-per-page over time separately for the switch topics and principles-only topics (last two columns).

Page 49: How Rules-Oriented Are Accounting Standards?

47

TABLE 9 Citations per Page in Switch Topics less Citations per Page in Principles-Only Topics

Panel A: Differences in Citations per Page to Non-Standard-Setters Event Time Hedge Tax Pension Lease Average Diff. Pre/Post Average Diff. t-3 1.23 -1.26 -0.48 ^ -0.17 t-2 -0.15 1.48 0.50 -1.08 0.19 t-1 0.19 0.08 2.45 0.06 0.70 0.28 t+1 0.83 -0.12 -0.76 -0.13 -0.04 t+2 -1.14 0.19 -0.16 -0.94 -0.51 t+3 -0.79 -0.14 -0.22 -1.12 -0.57 -0.37 Post-Switch Average Difference less Pre-Switch Average Difference -0.65** Panel B: Differences in Citations per Page to Standard-Setters Event Time Hedge Tax Pension Lease Average Diff. Pre/Post Average Diff. t-3 -0.48 -0.21 0.66 ^ -0.01 t-2 0.22 0.29 1.62 2.06 1.05 t-1 1.79 2.93 0.56 0.39 1.42 0.89 t+1 0.59 2.31 2.04 1.85 1.70 t+2 1.46 3.64 2.14 -0.17 1.77 t+3 0.85 2.26 2.09 2.93 2.03 1.83 Post-Switch Average Difference less Pre-Switch Average Difference 0.94** ^ These values were based on a single passage equal in length to one tenth of one page in the Handbook. They were excluded from the statistical tests because they were based on so little data. Data come from editions of the Accountants’ Handbook. Column labels are accounting topics which were governed by principles-based standards but switched to rules-based standards. Values represent the difference between the citations-per-page in each switch topic and the citations-per-page in a set of topics that remained principles-based over the sample period (inventory accounting, accounting for intangible assets, and bad debt accounting). Average differences are shows for each year in event time (t-3 to t+3) and for the periods before the switch (t-3 to t-1) and the periods after the switch (t+1 to t+3) separately. At the bottom of each panel is the difference between the differences. It shows whether the change in the citations-per-page in the switch topics was different than the change in the principles-only topics.