Hicks Hansen Islm

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 8/7/2019 Hicks Hansen Islm

    1/13

    The Hicks-Hansen

    IS-LM Model

    Roy Harrod (1937), James Meade (1937) and Oskar Lange (1938) had attempted to express the main

    relationships of Keynes's theory as equations in order to elucidate the interrelationships between the

    theory of effective demand and the theory of liquidity preference. In a similar effort, John Hicks, in his

    famous 1937 Econometrica article, "Mr Keynes and the Classics: A suggested interpretation", drew two

    curves, "SI-LL" to illustrate these relationships. These curves have since become famously known as the

    IS-LM model and were popularized by a now-converted Alvin Hansen (1949, 1953). The IS-LM model has

    remained one of the most formidable pieces of pedagogic machinery and, as far as back-of-the-

    envelope diagrammatic reasoning is concerned, one of the most efficient ever devised in economics. It is

    not, however, without substantial problems, both as an internally consistent model or as a

    representation of Keynes's theory.

    The crucial feature of the Keynesian system Hicks and Hansen concentrated on when formulating the

    simple IS-LM is the interaction between the real and monetary markets. From the real market, one

    extracts the level of income (Y) and from the money market, one obtains the interest rate (r). These

    variables, in turn, affect elements in the other market - in the simplest version, income affects money

    demand and interest affects investment. This interaction clearly violates the "classical dichotomy" and,

    as we shall see, it also does not support the neutrality of money. Financial-real interaction is the core of

    the IS-LM version of Keynes's theory - therefore, Hicks (1937) concluded with perfect Walrasian

    instincts, it is necessary to solve for the money and real markets simultaneously.

    However, many Keynesians, such as Pasinetti (1974), have argued that Keynes's system should be

    thought of "block recursively" or "sequentially" and thus should not be solved simultaneously.

    Specifically, it can be argued that the Keynesian system ought to be seen as a sequence of alternating

    "asset market" and "goods market" decisions - the interest rate being first determined by a portfolio

    decision in the financial markets and only thereafter determining investment, output and employment

    in the real market which then feeds back into another portfolio decision, etc. This criticism is

    noteworthy because the portfolio (LM) decision is made in the context of a stock constraint whereas the

    real market decisions (IS) is made in a flow constraint. Furthermore, as Richard Kahn (1984) and Joan

    Robinson (1973, 1978, 1979) emphasized later, the simultaneous equation method of the IS-LM, by

    eliminating sequential time, also eliminates the time-dependent concepts which they saw as

    fundamental to Keynes's theory - such as uncertainty, expectations, speculation and animal spirits. As

    John Hicks (1980, 1988) himself notes in his recantation, these different time references for IS and LM

    makes the simultaneous IS-LM model incongruous (see also Leijonhufvud, 1968, 1983; Davidson, 1992).

  • 8/7/2019 Hicks Hansen Islm

    2/13

    The following construction of the IS-LM ignores these problems and is built on the original Hicks-Hansen

    presentations. The best place to begin is perhaps the very familiar income-expenditure diagram - the

    "Keynesian cross" - which Paul Samuelson (1948), Abba Lerner (1951) and Alvin Hansen (1953) made

    popular. Let total planned expenditures - i.e. "aggregate demand" - be:

    Yd = C + I + G

    where C is planned consumption, I is planned investment and G is planned government spending (and

    we are ignoring the foreign sector). If there is goods-market equilibrium, then aggregate demand must

    equal aggregate supply:

    Yd = Y

    where Y is income (or output or aggregate supply). Now, income is either consumed, saved or taxed

    away, thus we can decompose Y into:

    Y = C + S + T

    where the terms follow their traditional definitions (S is savings, T is taxes). Consequently, at equilibrium

    C + I + G = C + S + T or, simply, assuming a balanced government budget (so G = T), then the equilibrium

    condition Yd = Y can be written equivalently as:

    I = S

    thus planned investment equals planned savings.

    The equilibrium level of output is potentially any level up to the full employment level. Which level of

    output actually happens to be the equilibrium depends entirely upon aggregate demand - hence

    aggregate demand is the primary determinant of the equilibrium level of output. This is indisputably the

  • 8/7/2019 Hicks Hansen Islm

    3/13

    central message of Keynes's theory: given any level of aggregate demand, producers will try to meet

    that demand and thus aggregate output will rise or fall to equate the given aggregate demand.

    Figure 1 - The Keynesian Cross of Income-Expenditure

    The computation of the equilibrium output level is actually a quite simple result of the Kahn-Keynes

    "multiplier". Letting consumption be a linear function of current income:

    C = C0 + cY

    where c is the marginal propensity to consume (MPC) so 0 < c < 1, and C0 is autonomous consumption.

    Assuming, in turn, that investment demand and government spending are exogenous, (i.e. I = I0 and G =

    G0), then aggregate demand becomes:

    Yd = C0 + cY + I0 + G0

    which is shown in Figure 1 as the aggregate demand function, Yd. Note that the slope of this curve is the

    marginal propensity to consume (c) and because 0 < c < 1, the aggregate demand function Yd is flatter

    than the 45 line. The vertical intercept is merely the collection of autonomous terms, A0 = [C0 + I0 +

    G0].

    Obviously, in equilibrium, it must be that Y = Yd. Thus, solving for equilibrium output, Y*:

    Y* = [C0 + I0 + G0]/(1-c)

  • 8/7/2019 Hicks Hansen Islm

    4/13

    so the equilibrium level of output is some multiple of the autonomous terms (C0 + I0 + G0), where the

    term 1/(1-c) is the Kahn-Keynes "multiplier". The equilibrium level of output, Y*, is shown in Figure 1 as

    the point where the aggregate demand function intersects the 45 line.

    The basic reasoning behind the Kahn-Keynes multiplier is the idea that expenditure (by people, firms or

    government) will generate income for somebody and that subsequently some of this income will be

    consumed and thus generate more expenditure which will in turn generate more income and thus more

    expenditure, etc. Thus, if autonomous expenditure is C0+I0+G0, then this will be someone's income;

    thus consumption increases by c(C0+I0+G0), which, in turn, is also an increase in someone's income and

    thus consumption increases again by c(c(C0+I0+G0), and so on through successive rounds. Thus, the

    total income generated by an initial autonomous level of expenditure C0+I0+G0 will be:

    Y* = (C0+I0+G0) + c(C0+I0+G0) + c2(C0+I0+G0) + c3(C0+I0+G0) + ...

    However, this geometric progression is not eternal: this is a convergent series because the marginal

    propensity to consume is a fraction. In other words, note that as 0 < c < 1, then this is equal to

    Y* = [C0+I0+G0](1 + c + c2 + c3 + ....) = (1/(1-c))[C0+I0+G0]

    as the sum of an infinite geometric progression (1 + c + c2 + c3 + ....) is merely 1/(1-c) (which is greater

    than 1). Thus, the initial autonomous expenditures [C0+I0+G0] have generated [C0+I0+G0]/(1-c) of

    income in the economy as a whole after the multiplier works itself out.

    Naturally, there is also a disequilibrium dynamic underlying the system implied the Kahn-Keynes

    "multiplier" process. Specifically, the dynamic of the multiplier argues that output responds to excess

    demand for goods:

    dY/dt = (Yd - Y)

  • 8/7/2019 Hicks Hansen Islm

    5/13

    where > 0, so output increases if there is excess demand for goods (Yd > Y or I > S) and output

    decreases if there is excess supply of goods (Yd < Y or I < S). This is very different from the Neoclassical

    macromodel which argued that it was interest rates that cleared the goods market.

    Now, we noted earlier, following Lerner (1938, 1939, 1944), that actual savings always equals actual

    investment, thus we must remind ourselves that the I and S denoted here refer only to planned levels of

    investment and savings. To see why, assume that output is at a position to the left of Y* in Figure 1, such

    as Y1. At this point, output Y1 is given, thus, by extension, S is fixed. However, obviously, at this point,

    aggregate demand exceeds aggregate supply, Yd > Y (equivalent to I > S). How can Lerner be correct?

    Easily. Note that as there is excess demand for goods thus there must be unplanned depletion of firms'

    inventories - which implies, in turn, that there is unplanned disinvestment. This unplanned

    disinvestment is the difference between planned investment and planned savings - i.e. the interval at Y1

    between the two curves, Yd and the 45 line. Thus, although planned investment exceeds planned

    savings, actual investment (planned investment minus unplanned disinvestment) is equal to actual

    savings. The multiplier dynamic, then, proposes that as firms see their inventories deplete unexpectedly,

    they take this as a signal of excess demand for their goods and consequently increase production -

    thereby raising output back up to Y*.

    We can see the same thing for the other side: suppose actual output is to the right of Y*, for instance, at

    Y2 in Figure 1. In this case, Yd < Y or planned I is less than planned S - or, quite simply, there is

    unplanned inventory investment as excess goods supply accumulate on inventory shelves. Firms take

    this as a signal to cut back output - and therefore Y is reduced to Y*. Thus, the Keynesian multiplier

    dynamic implies that output (Y) does all the adjusting in response to disequilibrium in the goodsmarkets.

    [Alternatively, the interim difference between aggregate demand and supply can be regarded as

    representing unplanned or forced savings and dissavings rather than unplanned inventory decumulation

    and accumulation respectively. Such a characterization, reminiscent of the earlier Wicksellian literature

    (e.g. Hayek, 1931), would imply that it is consumers expenditure plans, and not necessarily those of

    firms, which are contradicted in disequilbrium. The resulting multiplier dynamic would not be affected

    by such an interpretation, although it may seem less natural.]

    We have noted that we can determine the equilibrium level of output, Y* once we know what the

    marginal propensity to consume (c) is and what the autonomous terms C0, I0 and G0 are. However, this

    is a heavily stripped version of the model and these terms ought to be a bit more detailed. For instance,

    consumption can be defined as:

  • 8/7/2019 Hicks Hansen Islm

    6/13

    C = C0 + c(Y - TX)

    where C0 is autonomous consumption, c is the marginal propensity to consume out of current

    disposable income, where disposable income is defined as actual income Y minus taxes, TX, which in

    turn, can be defined as TX = TX0 - TR0 + tY where TX0 are autonomous taxes (e.g. excise taxes), TR0 are

    net government transfer payments (e.g. unemployment benefits) and t (where 0 < t < 1) is the marginal

    tax rate so that tY reflects income taxes. In this case, consumption becomes:

    C = C0 + c((1-t)Y - TX0 + TR0)

    which is a bit richer than our earlier expression for the consumption function.

    The more interesting change in the model is in the description of the investment demand function.

    Specifically, assume that investment is a negative function of interest rates, r, so that investment

    demand becomes:

    I = I0 + I(r)

    where Ir < 0 and I0 is autonomous investment. Note that, written thus, investment is a negative function

    of only one interest rate - this is already a Hicksian modification of the original story. Continuing to

    assume that G = G0 is completely autonomous, total planned expenditures are now:

    Yd = C0 + c((1-t)Y - TX0 + TR0) + I0 + I(r) + G0

    Thus, in equilibrium, Y = Yd and thus solving for equilibrium output Y*:

    Y* = [C0 + c(TR0 - TX0) + I0 + G0 + I(r)]/(1-c(1-t))

  • 8/7/2019 Hicks Hansen Islm

    7/13

    or letting A0 denote all the autonomous terms, i.e. A0 = [C0 + c(TR0 - TX0) + I0 + G0 + I(r)], which will be

    the intercept of our Yd curve, then it follows that:

    Y* = A0/(1-c(1-t))

    where 1/(1-c(1-t)) is the new multiplier. Of course, 0 < (1-c(1-t)) < 1 thus the aggregate demand function

    has still a flatter slope than the 45 line, thus there will be an intersection which will yield us

    equilibrium Y*.

    We could have made this richer by adding a foreign sector and thereby including autonomous

    export/import terms and a marginal propensity to import into the multiplier term, but the lesson we

    believe is clear at this point: whatever we wish to include in the set of autonomous terms or into the

    multiplier in order to increase "realism", there is an equilibrium level of output Y* that is determinate

    and a multiplier dynamic that ensures that it is stable.

    The most important result of this exercise is that Y* corresponds to an equilibrium output level, where I

    = S, but which may or may not imply full employment. Y* is just one of a continuum of possible output

    levels. In Figure 1, full employment is noted by YF which is definitely higher than Y* but, contrary to the

    Neoclassical model, there are no inherent mechanisms to drive the equilibrium level of output to the full

    employment level. The economy will therefore be sustained at an "underemployment equilibrium".

    Furthermore, note that any changes in any of the autonomous terms (e.g. C0, TX0, TR0, I0, I(r), G0) will

    lead to a change in A0 and consequently a change in the intercept of the Yd line - and consequently the

    resulting equilibrium level of output, Y*. It is thus easy to visualize that fiscal policy variables, such as

    government spending (G0), autonomous taxes (TX0), government transfers (TR0) or (via a slightly

    different channel) the income tax rate (t) will affect the equilibrium level of output, Y*. Thus, equilibrium

    is policy-effective: government can, by means of increasing spending and transfers or reducing taxes,

    increase the equilibrium level of output Y*. Thus, Keynesian propositions about the government using

    expenditure and tax policy to assist the economy by pushing equilibrium output Y* to the fullemployment level YF - part of what Abba Lerner (1943, 1944) called "functional finance" - are obvious

    here.

    Naturally, government fiscal policy variables are not the only things included in the intercept A0:

    autonomous consumption (C0) and investment terms (I0, I(r)) also affect the equilibrium level of output.

  • 8/7/2019 Hicks Hansen Islm

    8/13

    Keynes was particularly interested in investment - "that flighty bird" - and how it helped determine the

    equilibrium level of output and how that could be changed. Specifically, note that investment is a

    function of the interest rate, r - thus our model is not exactly "closed" because we have said nothing

    about how the interest rate, r, is determined. Now, the relationship between interest and investment is

    via the "marginal efficiency of investment" or MEI - as Lerner (1944) appropriately rebaptized it.

    Essentially, we can think of the MEI curve as downward-sloping: as investment increases, the marginal

    efficiency of investment collapses. Firms, Keynes proposed, will invest until the MEI is equal to a given

    rate of interest. Thus, the lower the rate of interest, the greater the amount of investment and vice-

    versa, thus I(r) is such that dI/dr < 0.

    Thus, we can begin to set out Hicks's "IS" curve - the equilibrium locus which captures the relationship

    between interest rate and output. As interest rate rises, I(r) falls and consequently so does Yd - thus, the

    equilibrium level of output, Y* declines. Thus, as we see in the Figure 3, the IS curve is downward

    sloping: high r is related with low equilibrium output Y* while low r is related with high Y*. This is an

    equilibrium locus and not a curve - any point on the curve represent goods market equilibrium, where

    aggregate demand equals aggregate supply. Points off the curve represent disequilibrium points. For

    instance, at a given r, we obtain a particular Y* so that if output is actually greater than Y* (Y > Y*) the

    multiplier dynamic implies that it must fall towards the locus. Similarly, if Y < Y* at a given r, then output

    must rise towards Y* and thus towards the locus. Thus, points to the left of the IS curve represent points

    where there is "excess demand" for goods whereas points to the right of the IS curve situations of

    "excess supply" of goods. The horizontal directional arrows shown in Figure 3 summarize the multiplier

    dynamic.

    We can immediately see that a rise in government spending (G), a rise in transfers (TR0), a decline in

    taxes (TX0, t), an increase in autonomous investment (I0) or an increase in autonomous consumption

    (C0) or the propensity to consume (c) all lead to a rightward shift in the IS curve. The opposite cases

    imply a leftward shift. Now, given:

    Y* = [C0 + c(TR0 - TX0) + I0 + G0 + I(r)]/(1-c(1-t))

    then by totally differentiation with respect to r and Y, we can note that

    dr/dY = (1-c(1-t))/Ir

  • 8/7/2019 Hicks Hansen Islm

    9/13

    denotes the slope of the IS curve. Thus the lower the income sensitivity of expenditure (the lower the

    marginal propensity to consume and the higher the income tax rate) and the lower the interest

    sensitivity of investment, then the steeper the IS curve. Conversely, a high income sensitivity (i.e. a high

    multiplier) and a high interest sensitivity of investment imply a flatter IS curve.

    However, we have still to determine the rate of interest - this is where Keynes's theory of liquidity

    preference comes in. As he writes:

    "The rate of interest at any time, being the reward for parting with liquidity, is a measure of the

    unwillingness of those who possess money to part with their liquid control over it. The rate of interest is

    not the "price" which brings into equilibrium the demand for resources to invest with the readiness to

    abstain from present consumption. It is the "price" which equilibrates the desire to hold wealth in the

    form of cash with the available quantity of cash"

    (Keynes, 1936: p.167)

    What this means is that people possess a portfolio of assets for which they try to find the "right"

    liquidity mix. For simplicity, it is assumed to contain only two assets: money (which yields nothing but is

    highly liquid) and "bonds" (which yield interest but are illiquid). If the rate of interest were zero, nobody

    would hold bonds in their portfolios - for the liquidity provided by the money would be far superior.

    However, in order to convince people to "part from liquidity", bonds offer a rate of interest. The greater

    the rate of interest, the greater the enticement to move away from money and hold bonds instead.

    Although the issue of expected and actual rates of interest (and a multiplicity of these) is an issue that

    was papered over by Hicks (1937), the gist of the story can be captured by recognizing that money

    demand can be written:

    Md = L(r, Y)

    where Lr < 0 and LY > 0, thus as interest rate rises, the demand for money falls (as people prefer to buy

    interest-bearing bonds) while as output rises people demand more money (as people need money to

    conduct more transactions). The dependence of money demand on income is a crucial relation -

    originally mentioned but suppressed by Keynes, and then resurrected by Hicks and Hansen. In contrast,

    the supply of money is written as:

  • 8/7/2019 Hicks Hansen Islm

    10/13

    Ms = M/p

    where M is the nominal money supply which is regarded as exogenously determined and the price level,

    p, for the moment will be left unexplained. For money market equilibrium, then Md = Ms, or:

    L(r, Y) = M/p

    The money market equilibrium is shown in Figure 2.

    Figure 2 - Money Market with Liquidity Preference

    Obviously, the interest rate brings the money market into equilibrium, but how is that possible? We

    learn in regular microeconomics that the market for apples is cleared by the price of apples - how then is

    the market for money cleared by the price on another good, i.e. bonds? To understand this, let us notethat Keynes implied was the existence of a portfolio stock constraint, which can heuristically be set out

    as follows:

    (Md - Ms) + (Bd - Bs) = 0

    where the total demand for wealth is Md + Bd and the total supply of wealth is Ms + Ms. By assuming

    Walras's Law for stocks, a crucial assumption, then this equation will hold true at all times. Now, Keynes

    claimed that the rate of interest is determined by the supply and demand for bonds. But if interest rate

    clears the bond market (so Bd = Bs) then we see that necessarily Md = Ms, the money market clears -

    thus we can also say (as Keynes did repeatedly) that interest rates are determined by the supply and

    demand for money. In view of the Walras's Law stock constraint, bond market equilibrium and money

    market equilibrium are, indeed, one and the same thing.

  • 8/7/2019 Hicks Hansen Islm

    11/13

    If interest rates are too high so that bond demand exceeds bond supply (Bd > Bs), we can see that, via

    this stock constraint, this translates necessarily into Md < Ms, i.e. an excess supply of money. We can

    see how this is depicted in Figure 2 when we consider r1 > r*. The portfolio dynamics are simple supply-

    and-demand logic: if there is excess demand for bonds, then the price of bonds will rise, which means

    that the rate of interest on bonds will fall - thus r1 declines towards r*. Similarly, the opposite case is

    also true: when interest is below r* (at, say, r2), then bond supply exceeds bond demand by regular logic

    - but then, by the stock constraint, this implies that there must be excess demand for money. The

    dynamics also apply: when there is excess bond supply, then the price of bonds falls and thus the

    interest rate on bonds rises - so we move from r2 back up to r*. Thus, all this is captured in the money-

    market diagram alone. Thus, by recognizing this Walras' Law relationship implied by the portfolio

    allocation of wealth, we can claim that interest rate on bonds is determined in the money market, even

    though the details of the story are told in the bond market. For more thoughts on this matter, see our

    review of Keynes's General Theory.

    Now, recall that Md = L(r, Y), thus money demand is also a function of output, Y. When output rises, the

    money demand curve will thus rise and therefore the equilibrium level of interest rates, r*, will also rise.

    Consequently, following Hicks (1937), we can derive an "LM" curve as the equilibrium locus which

    relates output levels to equilibrium levels of interest. As we see in Figure 3, this is a positive relationship,

    thus the LM is upward sloping. Keep in mind the important fact that LM represents money market

    equilibrium, thus M/p = L(r, Y) anywhere along the LM curve. Any point off the LM curve will denote a

    money-market disequilibrium. Specifically, at a given rate of output, if r is too high, then by the

    dynamics proposed earlier apply: if r > r*, then there is excess money supply and r declines; whereas if r

    < r*, then there is excess money demand and r increases. Thus, all points above the LM curve denote

    situations of excess money supply whereas all points below the LM curve are situations of excess moneydemand. Thus, the vertical directional arrows in Figure 3 denote the dynamics implied by the financial

    markets.

    It is obvious that the LM shifts on the basis of many parameters. An increase in the nominal money

    supply M, a decrease in prices p, a decrease in the bond supply Bs, an decrease in money demand Md or

    an increase in bond demand, Bd, all lead to a rightward shift in the LM curve. The opposite of any of

    these leads to a leftward shift in the LM. Totally differentiating the equilibrium locus:

    d(M/p) = Lrdr + LYdY

    so as d(M/p) = 0, then, the slope of the LM curve is:

  • 8/7/2019 Hicks Hansen Islm

    12/13

    dr/dY = -LY/Lr

    where LY is the income sensitivity of money demand and Lr is the interest sensitivity of money demand.

    Thus, if LY is high and Lr is low, we get a steep LM curve. If LY is low and Lr high, then we get a very flat

    LM curve. What Hicks (1937) called the "liquidity trap" assumes an extreme case of the latter.

    In Figure 3, we superimpose the IS and LM curves to generate the IS-LM diagram. Immediately we can

    notice that the only point in the diagram where both goods markets and money markets are in

    equilibrium is at point E, where r = r* and Y = Y*. This is the equilibrium level of output and interest

    where both goods and money markets clear. By examining the directional arrows implied by the goods

    market multiplier and the money market financial dynamics, we can notice immediately that equilibrium

    E is stable as all trajectories tend towards it sooner or later (the IS curve, of course, is nothing but the

    isokine for dY/dt = 0 and the LM curve being the isokine for dr/dt = 0 - thus the dynamics are easy toderive).

    Figure 3 - Hicks-Hansen IS-LM Model

    It might be worthwhile reminding ourselves what the disequilibrium quadrants (denoted in Figure 3 by I-

    IV) imply:

    Quadrant I: excess supply of goods, excess demand for money

    Quadrant II: excess demand for goods, excess demand for money

    Quadrant III: excess demand for goods, excess supply of money

    Quadrant IV: excess supply of goods, excess supply of money

    Immediately we can begin seeing some implied problems. As Hicks (1980) later carefully noted, one

    cannot really superimpose a stock equilibrium over a flow equilibrium because their time references are

    different. To see this, we must realize that any point on the LM curve implies a stock equilibrium - thus,

    by definition, the demand for wealth equals the supply of wealth. But recall that planned savings

  • 8/7/2019 Hicks Hansen Islm

    13/13

    translate into additional demand for wealth while planned investment translate into additional supply of

    wealth. Consequently, how is it ever logically possible, then, to be on the LM curve but not on the IS

    curve? In other words, by imposing stock constraint at all times, it can never be that the flow constraint

    is in disequilibrium - thus planned I = S at all times as well. Other familiar problems re-emerge here: does

    not Keynes's theory of liquidity preference hinge on at least two interest rates, the future expected rate

    and the current rate? Where are these?

    These are just a few of the many difficulties implied by an IS-LM depiction of the Keynesian model.

    However, as a pedagogic, back-of-the-envelope device, IS-LM is supremely efficient. We can see this

    mechanically. Increases in autonomous effective demand variables (C0, I0, G0, TR0, -TX0 etc.) all lead to

    rightward-shifts in the IS curve and consequently a new equilibrium at a higher level of output and

    interest. Increases in money supply, falls in the general price level, lower money demand, etc. all lead to

    a rightward shift in the LM curve and thus a higher level of output and lower level of interest. Notice

    also that the relative efficacy of fiscal policy (via IS) and monetary policy (via LM) depend crucially on the

    slopes of the IS and LM curves - and thus on the presumed interest and income sensitivities of money

    demand, investment, consumption and other expenditure categories. A relatively steep LM curve and

    flat IS curve imply that monetary policy is highly effective whereas the converse case of a relatively flat

    LM curve and steep IS cure imply that fiscal policy is highly effective.

    The manifold stories which can be told via the Hicks-Hansen IS-LM diagram almost permits one to

    overlook the logical and theoretical difficulties that underlie it. However, as is evident in the work of

    many prominent Keynesian economists - such as Abba Lerner (1944, 1951, 1952), Tibor Scitovsky (1940),

    Sidney Weintraub (1958, 1959, 1961, 1965) and Paul Davidson (1972, 1994) - who never used thisapparatus, the IS-LM model is neither the only, nor the most faithful, nor the most coherent tool in

    which to express Keynes's General Theory - but it might very well be the simplest.