1
Hedging by Sequential Regression in Discrete Market Models Sarah Boese 1 , Tracy Cui 2 , Sam Johnston 3 , Gianmarco Molino 4 , Oleksii Mostovyi 4 1 Vassar College, 2 Carnegie Mellon University, 3 Willamette University, 4 University of Connecticut The authors have been supported by the National Science Foundation under grant No. DMS-1659643. Hedging by Sequential Regression in Discrete Market Models Sarah Boese 1 , Tracy Cui 2 , Sam Johnston 3 , Gianmarco Molino 4 , Oleksii Mostovyi 4 1 Vassar College, 2 Carnegie Mellon University, 3 Willamette University, 4 University of Connecticut The authors have been supported by the National Science Foundation under grant No. DMS-1659643. Overview The field of mathematical finance has long been concerned with the fair valuation of derivative securities. The no-arbitrage pricing approach, summarized in [1], uses the idea of replicating strategies to find fair prices in a simplified complete market example. This approach, however, has sharp limitations when conditions of market incompleteness are introduced. There is an extensive literature on optimal hedging in incomplete markets. We consider optimal hedging in the discrete time case. Following [2], [3], and [4], we apply the sequential regression approach to option hedging. We examine the question of equivalence of hedging strategies in the binomial case, and the question of stability of sequential regression under model perturbations. Binomial Model We introduce the binomial asset pricing model as presented in [1]. The binomial model consists of two components: A risk-free money market asset with constant interest r . A risky stock asset whose initial value is S 0 and whose value at each time period is determined by a coin flip(not necessarily fair). Given heads, the stock value will increase by an upfactor u. Given tails, the stock value will decrease by a downfactor d. S uS dS u 2 S S d 2 S Fig. 1: Example of a 2-period Binomial Model Given this market, we define the wealth process for a small investor in the market as follows: X n+1 = (1 + r )(X n - ϑ n S n )+ ϑ n S n+1 , where X n represents the wealth the investor has at time n and ϑ n represents the number of stocks held at time n. Let V N be a random variable of the coin flips (ω 1 ,...,ω N ) and define the stochastic process (V n ) 0nN such that V n (ω 1 ,...,ω n )= 1 (1 + r ) N -n ˜ E[V N | ω 1 ,...,ω n ], where ˜ E is the conditional expected value under risk-neutral probabilities. The bino- mial model represents a complete market, where there must exist a unique risk-neutral probability under which discounted option values are martingales. I.e. V 0 = 1 (1 + r ) N ˜ E[V N ]. We can also derive the following formula for ϑ n from the wealth process above: ϑ n (ω n )= V n+1 (ω 1 ,...,ω n ,H ) - V n+1 (ω 1 ,...,ω n ,T ) S n+1 (ω 1 ,...,ω n ,H ) - S n+1 (ω 1 ,...,ω n ,T ). (1) We hereby refer to this method as backward recursion, and we note that it provides a unique and exact hedging strategy. F ¨ ollmer-Schweizer Decomposition While the method of backward recursion provides an optimal hedging strategy for the binomial model, we aim to obtain a more general method of optimal hedging. We first reframe our problem as: min ξ Θ E[(V N - V 0 - G T (ξ )) 2 ] where Θ is the set of all predictable processes ξ such that ξ k ΔS k ∈L 2 (P ) and G(ξ ) := k j =1 ξ j ΔS j . In our particular application, V N represents the payoff the investor must pay at time N , V 0 is the initial price of the option, or the initial capital available to the investor, and G T (ξ ) is the gains the investor makes in trade. The problem is now one of minimizing net square loss, equivalent to the problems posed in [2]–[4]. If certain nondegeneracy conditions hold, we can decompose the wealth process into its almost- surely unique Doob Decomposition to obtain the discrete F¨ ollmer-Schweizer Decomposition : V N = V 0 + N -1 X j =0 ξ j ΔS j +1 + L N , where ξ n := Cov(V N - N -1 j =n+1 ξ j ΔS j +1 , ΔS n+1 |F n ) Var(ΔS n+1 |F n ) for n =0, ..., N, (2) where ΔS n = S n - S n-1 is the change in the stock price at time n, and L N is a martingale with initial value 0. This hedging method is known as sequential regression. Theorem. Under the binomial model, the hedging strategy (ϑ n ) 0nN -1 in (1) is equivalent to the hedging strategy (ξ n ) 0nN -1 in (2). Trinomial Model While the binomial model is often used as an introductory tool, most models used in practice exhibit incompleteness, that is the inability to hedge exactly. An example of an incomplete market is the trinomial model. Similar to the binomial model, we have a risky asset and a risk-free asset, and the value of the risky asset at each time step is determined by a small set of outcomes. This time, we have three possible outcomes for the coin flip instead of two. That is, along with the possibility of an increase by a factor of u and decrease by a factor of d, we allow for the possibility that the stock price does not change between two consecutive time steps. S uS S dS u 2 S uS S dS d 2 S Fig. 2: Example of a 2-period Trinomial Model If we attempt to apply backward recursion to determine a hedging strategy for the trinomial model, we obtain an overdetermined system with no solution. Thus in the trinomial model we must use the more general strategy of sequential regression to find an optimal hedging strategy. Market Stability We now subject the pricing model to market perturbations. We shift our focus to the change in price of the risky asset at each time step, defined by the process S n ) 1nN , which can be decomposed as ΔS n = λΔt + σ ΔW where λ and σ are constants describing the market, Δt is a process representing the change in time, and ΔW is a martingale with initial expectation 0 representing hedging error. Then, a market perturbation can be represented, for some ε, λ 0 0 R, as ΔS ε n =(λ + ελ 0 t +(σ + εσ 0 W It is of interest to consider whether the sequential regression is stable under such perturbations; if it is not, then our predictions for asset valuation can not be consid- ered accurate once too much error is present in our assumed values for ε, λ, and σ . Similar questions of stability were considered in a continuous time setting in [5] and [6]. Fig. 3: Behavior of the Trinomial Model Under Market Perturbations Theorem. In the discrete time setting, the perturbed hedge ξ ε converges asymp- totically to ξ 0 , that is ξ ε - ξ 0 ε ε0 ---→ C where C is a constant dependent on market parameters. References [1] S. Shreve, Stochastic calculus for finance i: The binomial asset pricing model. Springer Science & Business Media, Nov. 6, 2012, 197 pp., Google-Books-ID: zXhCAAAAQBAJ, isbn: 978-0-387-22527-2. [2] H. F¨ ollmer and M. Schweizer, Hedging by sequential regression: An introduction to the mathe- matics of option trading,ASTIN Bulletin: The Journal of the IAA, vol. 18, no. 2, pp. 147–160, Nov. 1988, issn: 0515-0361, 1783-1350. doi: 10.2143/AST.18.2.2014948. [3] M. Schweizer, Variance-optimal hedging in discrete time,Mathematics of OR, vol. 20, no. 1, pp. 1–32, Feb. 1, 1995, issn: 0364-765X. doi: 10.1287/moor.20.1.1. [4] S. Goutte, N. Oudjane, and F. Russo, Variance optimal hedging for discrete time processes with independent increments. application to electricity markets,ARXIV:1205.4089 [math, q- fin], May 18, 2012. arXiv: 1205.4089. [5] O. Mostovyi and M. S ˆ ırbu, Sensitivity analysis of the utility maximisation problem with respect to model perturbations,Finance and Stochastics, vol. 23, no. 3, pp. 595–640, 2019. [6] O. Mostovyi, Asymptotic analysis of the expected utility maximization problem with respect to perturbations of the num´ eraire,ARXIV:1805.11427 [math], May 27, 2018. arXiv: 1805.11427.

Hedging by Sequential Regression in Discrete Market Models · Fig. 3: Behavior of the Trinomial Model Under Market Perturbations Theorem. In the discrete time setting, the perturbed

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    0

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Hedging by Sequential Regression in Discrete Market Models · Fig. 3: Behavior of the Trinomial Model Under Market Perturbations Theorem. In the discrete time setting, the perturbed

Hedging by Sequential Regression in Discrete Market Models

Sarah Boese1, Tracy Cui2, Sam Johnston3, Gianmarco Molino4, Oleksii Mostovyi4

1Vassar College, 2Carnegie Mellon University, 3Willamette University, 4University of ConnecticutThe authors have been supported by the National Science Foundation under grant No. DMS-1659643.

Hedging by Sequential Regression in Discrete Market Models

Sarah Boese1, Tracy Cui2, Sam Johnston3, Gianmarco Molino4, Oleksii Mostovyi4

1Vassar College, 2Carnegie Mellon University, 3Willamette University, 4University of ConnecticutThe authors have been supported by the National Science Foundation under grant No. DMS-1659643.

Overview

The field of mathematical finance has long been concerned with the fair valuationof derivative securities. The no-arbitrage pricing approach, summarized in [1], usesthe idea of replicating strategies to find fair prices in a simplified complete marketexample. This approach, however, has sharp limitations when conditions of marketincompleteness are introduced. There is an extensive literature on optimal hedging inincomplete markets. We consider optimal hedging in the discrete time case. Following[2], [3], and [4], we apply the sequential regression approach to option hedging. Weexamine the question of equivalence of hedging strategies in the binomial case, andthe question of stability of sequential regression under model perturbations.

Binomial Model

We introduce the binomial asset pricing model as presented in [1]. The binomialmodel consists of two components:• A risk-free money market asset with constant interest r.

• A risky stock asset whose initial value is S0 and whose value at each time periodis determined by a “coin flip” (not necessarily fair). Given heads, the stock valuewill increase by an upfactor u. Given tails, the stock value will decrease by adownfactor d.

S

uS

dS

u2S

S

d2S

Fig. 1: Example of a 2-period Binomial Model

Given this market, we define the wealth process for a small investor in the market asfollows:

Xn+1 = (1 + r)(Xn − ϑnSn) + ϑnSn+1,

where Xn represents the wealth the investor has at time n and ϑn represents thenumber of stocks held at time n.Let VN be a random variable of the coin flips (ω1, . . . , ωN ) and define the stochasticprocess (Vn)0≤n≤N such that

Vn(ω1, . . . , ωn) =1

(1 + r)N−nE[VN | ω1, . . . , ωn],

where E is the conditional expected value under risk-neutral probabilities. The bino-mial model represents a complete market, where there must exist a unique risk-neutralprobability under which discounted option values are martingales. I.e.

V0 =1

(1 + r)NE[VN ].

We can also derive the following formula for ϑn from the wealth process above:

ϑn(ωn) =Vn+1(ω1, . . . , ωn, H)− Vn+1(ω1, . . . , ωn, T )

Sn+1(ω1, . . . , ωn, H)− Sn+1(ω1, . . . , ωn, T ).(1)

We hereby refer to this method as backward recursion, and we note that it providesa unique and exact hedging strategy.

Follmer-Schweizer Decomposition

While the method of backward recursion provides an optimal hedging strategy for the binomialmodel, we aim to obtain a more general method of optimal hedging. We first reframe our problemas:

minξ∈Θ

E[(VN − V0 −GT (ξ))2]

where Θ is the set of all predictable processes ξ such that ξk∆Sk ∈ L2(P ) and G(ξ) :=∑kj=1 ξj∆Sj. In our particular application, VN represents the payoff the investor must pay at

time N , V0 is the initial price of the option, or the initial capital available to the investor, andGT (ξ) is the gains the investor makes in trade. The problem is now one of minimizing net squareloss, equivalent to the problems posed in [2]–[4].If certain nondegeneracy conditions hold, we can decompose the wealth process into its almost-surely unique Doob Decomposition to obtain the discrete Follmer-Schweizer Decomposition:

VN = V0 +

N−1∑j=0

ξj∆Sj+1 + LN ,

where

ξn :=Cov(VN −

∑N−1j=n+1 ξj∆Sj+1,∆Sn+1 | Fn)

Var(∆Sn+1 | Fn)for n = 0, ..., N, (2)

where ∆Sn = Sn − Sn−1 is the change in the stock price at time n, and LN is a martingalewith initial value 0. This hedging method is known as sequential regression.

Theorem. Under the binomial model, the hedging strategy (ϑn)0≤n≤N−1 in (1) is equivalentto the hedging strategy (ξn)0≤n≤N−1 in (2).

Trinomial Model

While the binomial model is often used as an introductory tool, most models used in practiceexhibit incompleteness, that is the inability to hedge exactly. An example of an incompletemarket is the trinomial model. Similar to the binomial model, we have a risky asset and arisk-free asset, and the value of the risky asset at each time step is determined by a small set ofoutcomes. This time, we have three possible outcomes for the coin flip instead of two. That is,along with the possibility of an increase by a factor of u and decrease by a factor of d, we allowfor the possibility that the stock price does not change between two consecutive time steps.

S

uS

S

dS

u2S

uS

S

dS

d2S

Fig. 2: Example of a 2-period Trinomial Model

If we attempt to apply backward recursion to determine a hedging strategy for the trinomialmodel, we obtain an overdetermined system with no solution. Thus in the trinomial model wemust use the more general strategy of sequential regression to find an optimal hedging strategy.

Market Stability

We now subject the pricing model to market perturbations. We shift our focusto the change in price of the risky asset at each time step, defined by the process(∆Sn)1≤n≤N , which can be decomposed as

∆Sn = λ∆t + σ∆W

where λ and σ are constants describing the market, ∆t is a process representingthe change in time, and ∆W is a martingale with initial expectation 0 representinghedging error. Then, a market perturbation can be represented, for some ε, λ′, σ′ ∈R, as

∆Sεn = (λ + ελ′)∆t + (σ + εσ′)∆W

It is of interest to consider whether the sequential regression is stable under suchperturbations; if it is not, then our predictions for asset valuation can not be consid-ered accurate once too much error is present in our assumed values for ε, λ, and σ.Similar questions of stability were considered in a continuous time setting in [5] and[6].

Fig. 3: Behavior of the Trinomial Model Under Market Perturbations

Theorem. In the discrete time setting, the perturbed hedge ξε converges asymp-totically to ξ0, that is

ξε − ξ0

ε

ε→0−−−→ C

where C is a constant dependent on market parameters.

References

[1] S. Shreve, Stochastic calculus for finance i: The binomial asset pricing model. SpringerScience & Business Media, Nov. 6, 2012, 197 pp., Google-Books-ID: zXhCAAAAQBAJ, isbn:978-0-387-22527-2.

[2] H. Follmer and M. Schweizer, “Hedging by sequential regression: An introduction to the mathe-matics of option trading,” ASTIN Bulletin: The Journal of the IAA, vol. 18, no. 2, pp. 147–160,Nov. 1988, issn: 0515-0361, 1783-1350. doi: 10.2143/AST.18.2.2014948.

[3] M. Schweizer, “Variance-optimal hedging in discrete time,” Mathematics of OR, vol. 20, no. 1,pp. 1–32, Feb. 1, 1995, issn: 0364-765X. doi: 10.1287/moor.20.1.1.

[4] S. Goutte, N. Oudjane, and F. Russo, “Variance optimal hedging for discrete time processeswith independent increments. application to electricity markets,” ARXIV:1205.4089 [math, q-fin], May 18, 2012. arXiv: 1205.4089.

[5] O. Mostovyi and M. Sırbu, “Sensitivity analysis of the utility maximisation problem with respectto model perturbations,” Finance and Stochastics, vol. 23, no. 3, pp. 595–640, 2019.

[6] O. Mostovyi, “Asymptotic analysis of the expected utility maximization problem with respect toperturbations of the numeraire,” ARXIV:1805.11427 [math], May 27, 2018. arXiv: 1805.11427.