Globalization Dvpt Constitutionalism

Embed Size (px)

DESCRIPTION

.

Citation preview

  • Globalization, Development, and Constitutionalism

    in Historical Perspective:

    Lessons from the West on the Rest

    Victoria Tin-bor Hui Assistant Professor

    Department of Political Science University of Illinois

    361 Lincoln Hall 702 South Wright Street

    Urbana, IL 61801 Email: [email protected]

    Prepared for presentation at the 99th Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, Philadelphia, August 28-31, 2003.

  • Victoria Hui 2

    Abstract

    This paper evaluates globalization in the longue dure. Anti-globalization protesters argue that globalization is corrosive of development and human rights. Supporters for globalization respond that, although globalization may have some undesirable side effects in the short-term, it should eventually enrich the poor and empower the underprivileged in the long-term. In the debate about the merits and demerits of globalization, both sides have focused on the impacts of globalization and overlooked the origins of development and human rights. When multinational corporations are blamed for being bed-fellows with authoritarian regimes, it is often overlooked that globalization and the ruler-trader alliance are hardly new phenomena. Rather, both international trade and the resulting ruler-trader alliance have been important aspects of political life for nearly a millennium. Moreover, such developments have not been inherently bad for either human rights or economic development. Capitalism and the so-called European miracle are well-known. But it is often forgotten that the constitutional rights that are so taken for granted in the Western world now were born of concessions which traders and financiers extorted from rulers in the medieval and modern periods.

    Nevertheless, globalization does not have universal effects on development, nor do all

    forms of ruler-trader alliance have salutary effects on constitutionalism. In the early modern period, there was once a growing gap between the successful stories of the Dutch Republic and England/Britain on the one hand and the dismal stories of France and Spain on the other hand. As the successful stories illustrate, ruler-trader coalitions that were embedded with state-society cooperation and with improvement in state capacity were conducive to constitutional as well as economic developments. However, if rulers relied on capital-holders just for easy cash and overlooked to develop cooperative relations with national entrepreneurs or to enhance the states capacity in mobilizing national resources, then the long-term results could well be erosion of both development and constitutionalism. Such divergent trajectories in the early modern West shed important light on the divergent trajectories in the Rest in the post-WWII era. The trade-off between enhancing international competitiveness at the price of making concessions to society on the one hand, and maximizing state autonomy at the price of economic stagnation on the other hand is the same now as then. The developmental paths of the East Asian NICs are reminiscent of those of the Dutch Republic and England/Britain. The lessons from history are that catching up is possible, and that both economic development and constitutional rights are to some extent shaped by state policies. As such, the solution to the widening gap between the haves and the have-nots should be to assist in state-building efforts in the developing world, rather than to stop the unstoppable tides of capitalism and globalization.

  • Victoria Hui 3

    Introduction

    In the midst of the euphoria at the end of the Cold War, many liberals were hopeful that

    the collapse of communism and dictatorship in the Eastern block would soon propel the whole

    world to move toward convergence of capitalism and democracy. The concomitant revolution in

    communication technologies and the economic booms in the early 1990s further added to this

    optimism. However, by the turn of the twenty-first century, it has become obvious that the end

    of history is nowhere in sight.1 In many corners of the globe, authoritarian regimes have

    retained tight grips on power. The collapse of the Soviet Union and the withdrawal of strategic

    support by both superpowers further unleashed waves of ethnic and civil conflicts, generating

    ethnic cleansing and genocide in the former Yugoslavia and Africa. The economic picture has

    not been much better. With the debt crisis in Latin America and the financial crisis in Asia, many

    developing economies have remained as poor as ever if not even poorer. At the same time, the

    conditionality of the International Monetary Funds and the World Bank (which require loan

    recipients to balance budgets, reduce social spendings, privatize public sectors, and liberalize

    financial markets) have simultaneously heightened the developing worlds vulnerability to

    economic downturns and restricted states abilities to provide for their populations.2 It is no

    wonder that in the eyes of some disgruntled critics from the Third World, Western governments

    which claim to promote capitalism and democracy are no more than neo-Bolsheviks who love

    expropriating other people's money, imposing undemocratic and alien rules of economic and

    political conduct and stifling economic freedom.3

    1 Fukuyama 1989. 2 Stiglitz 2002. 3 Cited in Huntington 1993, 40.

  • Victoria Hui 4

    It is not difficult to understand the rage at Seattle in 1999, and Quebec and Genoa in

    2001. However, if democracy and capitalism require that statesmen and businessmen be selfless

    angels, then it is doubtful that either phenomenon would have emerged even in the Western

    world. In the debate about the benefits versus problems of globalization, both sides have focused

    on the impacts of globalization and overlooked the origins of development and constitutionalism.

    I thus examine globalization in the longue dure. I show that the constitutional rights that are so

    taken for granted in the Western world now were born of concessions which traders and

    financiers extorted from rulers in the medieval and modern periods. Faced with constant fiscal

    crises, European rulers one after another turned to traders and financiers for loans and credits. In

    return, such capital-holders were offered public offices and some ad-hoc participation in public

    affairs. To avoid appropriation of private properties and to ensure repayments of sovereign debts,

    traders and financiers gradually pushed representative assemblies to the forefront as guarantors.

    As the revolutionary slogan No representation, no taxation testifies, it was this group of self-

    serving capitalists who brought about the birth of constitutionalism as well as capitalism.

    Nevertheless, not all forms of ruler-trader alliance have salutary effects on development

    and constitutionalism. The anti-globalization camp has rightly pointed out the widening gap in

    both aspects between the West and the Rest. However, there was also once a growing gap

    between the successful stories of the Dutch Republic and England/Britain on the one hand, and

    the dismal stories of France and Spain on the other hand during the early modern period. The

    successful stories illustrate that ruler-trader coalitions that were embedded with state-society

    cooperation and with improvement in state capacity were conducive to constitutional as well as

    economic developments. However, if rulers relied on capital-holders just for easy cash and

    overlooked to develop cooperative relations with national entrepreneurs or to enhance the states

  • Victoria Hui 5

    capacity in mobilizing national resources, then the long-term results could well be erosion of

    both development and constitutionalism.

    The divergent trajectories of European states in the early modern period shed important

    light on the divergent trajectories of developing countries in the post-war era. Whether West or

    Rest, then or now, states have faced the same trade-off between enhancing international

    competitiveness at the price of making concessions to society on the one hand, and maximizing

    state autonomy at the price of economic stagnation on the other hand. The developmental paths

    of the East Asian tigers are reminiscent of those of the Dutch Republic and England/Britain.

    Unfortunately, many rulers of newly independent countries have followed the French-Spanish

    path of relying on international capitalists and ignoring development of state capacity and state-

    society cooperation. Such a course has always been a tempting one, because it accords dictators

    with a high degree of autonomy from societal demands, but at the expense of dragging their

    countries further and further behind in international competition. The lessons from history are

    that catching up is possible; and that both economic development and constitutional rights are to

    some extent a function of state policies. As such, the solution to the widening gap between the

    haves and the have-nots should be to assist in state-building efforts in the developing world, but

    not to stop the unstoppable tides of capitalism and globalization.

    In the following analysis, I will discuss first, processes of globalization from the

    medieval period onward; second, the ruler-trader alliance and the emergence of medieval

    constitutionalism; third, the growing divergence between the Dutch-English trajectory and the

    French-Spanish trajectory in both economic and constitutional developments; and fourth, the

    implications of such historical developments in the West on current developmental problems in

    the Rest.

  • Victoria Hui 6

    Globalization in Historical Perspective

    Globalization or dramatically thickened and widened interdependence networks is

    often seen as a post-Cold War phenomenon. Most notably, breakthroughs in the internet, which

    has facilitated e-commerce, e-trade, and other internet-based transactions, are connecting distant

    markets and distant individuals in manners and at speed unimaginable even several decades ago.

    However, if communication and transportation technologies are seen as the driving force for the

    dramatic widening and thickening of interdependent networks in the current era, then neither

    development is entirely new. As Buzan and Little point out, interaction capacity that is,

    technological capabilities such as caravans, ships, railways, aircraft and shared norms, rules,

    and institutions have always shaped the type and intensity of interaction between political

    entities throughout world history.4

    Although the debate about globalization began as quite historically myopic,5 more and

    more analysts are looking back to the late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries. Just as the

    current wave was unleashed by the internet, the earlier wave was unleashed by the railways, the

    telegraph cable, the telephone, the commercial aircraft, and other innovations made possible by

    the industrial revolution. Most notably, after the first transatlantic telegraph cable was laid down

    in 1866, the entire world was to become connected by telegraph by the turn of the twentieth

    century, allowing communication times to fall from months to minutes.6 Hence, world markets

    were just as highly integrated then as now according to a variety of indicators. First, the openness

    to foreign trade as measured by imports and exports combined as a proportion of GDP was

    4 Buzan and Little 2000, 80. Similarly, Ruggie speaks of dynamic density, or the quantity, velocity, and diversity of transactions. Ruggie 1986, 148. 5 Krasner 1999a, 34. 6 Wolf 2001, 181-182.

  • Victoria Hui 7

    not significantly higher in 1993 than in 1913 for all major capitalist countries except the United

    States.7 Second, foreign direct investment accounted for over 9 percent of global output in 1913

    and this proportion was not surpassed until the early 1990s.8 Third, foreign capital flows relative

    to domestic savings were larger at the start of the twentieth century than at its end.9 Fourth,

    British capital investments abroad averaged 4.6 percent of GDP between 1870 and 1913 and this

    ratio has remained unparalleled in various major economies.10 Fifth, the correlation between

    domestic investment and savings, which measures the extent to which savings remain within one

    country, was lower between 1880 and 1910 than now.11 Sixth, international migration was far

    more prevalent in the late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries when borders were not as

    closed as now.12 In addition, the City of London, whose banks financed large portions of German

    trade, was far more vulnerable to potential disruptions than the City of New York now.13 In

    short, the current wave of globalization is not quantitatively much different from the earlier

    wave.14

    Most historically-oriented analysts are content to trace globalization to the late nineteenth

    century. But if communication and transportation technologies form the driving force for the

    7 Arrighi 1999, 54. Wolf elaborates on this point: In the United Kingdom, for example, exports and imports added up to 57 percent of GDP in 1995 compared to 44 percent in 1910; for France the 1995 proportion was 43 percent against 35 percent in 1910; and for Germany it was 46 percent against 38 percent in the same years. But Japans trade ratio was actually lower in 1995 than it had been in 1910. In fact, among todays five biggest economies, the only one in which trade has a remarkably greater weight in output than it had a century ago is the United States, where the ratio has jumped from 11 percent in 1910 to 24 percent in 1995. Wolf 2001, 180. 8 Arrighi 1999, 54. 9 Charles Wolf 2001. 10 Wolf 2001, 180. 11 Wolf 2001, 180. 12 Krasner 1999b, 39. But immigration in the US may have returned to the pre-1914 level. Mann 1999, 249. 13 Papayoanou 1996.

  • Victoria Hui 8

    widening and thickening of interdependence networks, then we may go further back in history to

    the early centuries of the second millennium. According to North and Thomas, the rise of the

    Western world should ultimately be traced to trade expansion that began in the eleventh

    century.15 Moreover, it is often overlooked that Europe, the initiator of one of the worlds major

    processes of conquest, colonization and cultural transformation was itself the product of

    Europeanization that took place in the period 950-1350.16

    Europe experienced unprecedented economic growth in the eleventh century. Innovations

    in the three-field system and the heavy plow improved agricultural productivity, allowing

    surpluses for trade.17 At the same time, increases in populations brought about large-scale

    migrations. With differences in natural resources and land-to-labor ratios, the opportunity to gain

    from specialization and trade emerged.18 As a result, old Roman towns were revived and new

    towns established, with townsmen building trading networks with surrounding agricultural areas

    and with other towns. Although Europe was hard hit by the Black Death in the fourteenth

    century, the fundamentals for trade had been laid down. When the European economy

    rejuvenated in the Renaissance, Italian cities, led by Venice, stretched their trade routes

    throughout the Mediterranean and reached ever farther along the Atlantic coast on one end and

    Egypt, Asia, and Russia on the other.19 From the last years of the fifteenth century on,

    breakthroughs in shipping technologies and discovery of the New World further set Europe on a

    14 However, the two periods are qualitatively different. While the earlier wave was characterized by a world of unilateral and discretionary policy, the current wave is a world of multilateral and institutionalized policy. Wolf 2001, 184; see also Hobson 1997; Ruggie 1982. 15 North and Thomas 1973. 16 Bartlett 1993, 314, 269. 17 Jones 1988, 54-58, 91; North and Thomas 1973, 41-43; Spruyt 1994, 61. 18 Jones 1988, 90; North and Thomas 1973, 26. 19 North and Thomas 1973, 12.

  • Victoria Hui 9

    course of dramatic commercial expansion, both within the Eurasian continent and between the

    continent and other parts of the world.

    Such increasingly long-distance international trade simultaneously required and

    facilitated the development of international finance. Banks of deposit, which had origins in the

    Roman times, began to emerge in Venice and Genoa in the late twelfth and early thirteenth

    centuries.20 Although international finance suffered retraction in the fourteenth century, its

    revival during the Renaissance was accompanied by improved instruments in mercantile credits,

    bills of exchange, and bills of insurance. Various distinctly modern international banking

    services (including deposits at interest, transferring monies, clearing bills of exchange, floating

    loans, and the like) were gradually developed and expanded in subsequent centuries.21 From the

    sixteenth century on, Europes economic centers gradually shifted from Italy to Antwerp and

    then to Amsterdam. During the ascendance of Amsterdam in the seventeenth century, the first

    market for securities emerged, and the Dutch East India Company became the first global

    corporation financed by shares sold and bought on the securities market.22

    It should be emphasized that big firms of the early modern period were not merely local

    or regional, but global. Following developments in shipping and in discovery of other parts of

    the world, various trading and finance groups had global reach as early as the first decades of the

    sixteenth century. For instance, the Welsers of Augsburg operated in Europe, the Mediterranean

    and Venezuela in 1528. In the heydays of Antwerp, its dominant firm, the Fuggers, controlled

    mines in central Europe and the Alps, had correspondents in Venice, and had branches in

    20 North and Thomas 1973, 54. 21 Kennedy 1987, 69. 22 Pomeranz 1999, 80-81.

  • Victoria Hui 10

    Portugal, Spain, Chile, Fiume, and Dubrovnick.23 Moreover, in such an increasingly integrated

    world, the gold and silver mined in the Americas were circulated not only in Europe, but were

    also shipped to China in exchange for Asian luxurious merchandises.24 Given these

    developments, it is not surprising that Wallerstein argues that capitalism began in the sixteenth

    rather than the nineteenth century.25

    Trade Expansion, the Ruler-Trader Alliance, and the Emergence of Medieval

    Constitutionalism

    I discuss the history of globalization not just for its own sake, but also for its relations to

    economic development and political rights in earlier centuries. Trade expansion that began in the

    eleventh century brought about not just economic growth across Europe, but also the rise of the

    burgher class, the revival of Roman towns, and the emergence of new towns that lied in the

    interstices between feudal lords. This phenomenon significantly enhanced the bargaining power

    of the burgher class and towns.26 The most prosperous cities and towns developed their own

    government and independence from kings and lords alike. Various new-found towns obtained

    written charters from kings who promised townsmen freedoms and immunities in return for

    taxes, weapons, and specialized services.27 Even burghers who came under the formal control of

    23 Krasner 1999a, 221. 24 Pomeranz 1999, 89. 25 Wallerstein calls capitalism proper industrial capitalism, and the early stage agricultural capitalism. What was happening from the sixteenth to the eighteenth centuries is that over a large geographical area going from Poland in the northeast westwards and southwards throughout Europe and including large parts of the Western Hemisphere as well, there grew up a world-economy with a single division of labor within which there was a world market, for which men produced largely agricultural products for sale and profit. I would think the simplest thing to do would be to call this agricultural capitalism. Wallerstein 1974, 399. 26 North and Thomas 1973; Spruyt 1994, chapter 4; Tilly 1990. 27 Downing 1992, 22.

  • Victoria Hui 11

    kings were able to establish themselves as a separate privileged order along with the traditional

    orders of the clergy and the nobility.

    The burghers economic wealth was further translated into political power as geopolitical

    competition stepped up and kings could no longer finance wars out of their traditional sources of

    revenue. As Thomas Ertman puts it, under the pressure of war, the increasingly assertive and

    ambitious rulers of France, the Iberian states, and Sicily were forced to call national

    representative assemblies into being.28 Representative assemblies first appeared sporadically in

    the Iberian kingdoms and Sicily in the late 1100s and early 1200s. They became fully

    institutionalized across the European Christendom cortes in Spain, parlements in France, and

    parliament in England during the period 1250-1350.29 Thus, out of trade expansion in the

    medieval period emerged medieval constitutionalism, or a system of decentralized

    government in which aristocrats, burghers, and clerics were given a voice in the fundamental

    affairs of war, foreign policy, taxation and justice.30

    Nevertheless, it is important to keep in mind that the emergence of a phenomenon and its

    consolidation are quite different matters. Neither continuation of economic growth nor

    maintenance of medieval constitutionalism in subsequent centuries can be taken for granted.31

    For one thing, we cannot presume rulers to be selfless angels who would voluntarily tie their

    own hands in maintaining constitutionalism. As Ruggie puts it, European rulers did not set out

    to weaken their constitutional powers by convening assemblies to raise taxes; they sought only

    28 Ertman 1997, 60. Thus, the revolutionary slogan No representation, no taxation has a medieval origin. 29 Ertman 1997, 68. 30 Downing 1994, 10, 21-22. 31 In the economic sphere, the Black Death wiped out most gains in living standards that were achieved in previous centuries.

  • Victoria Hui 12

    to raise revenues.32 Hence, medieval assemblies were convened only when rulers desired so,

    which means that they might not meet for many decades.

    More importantly, the ruler-trader alliance forged in the shadow of interlocking political

    and economic competition was a highly uneasy one, which made the consolidation of medieval

    constitutionalism highly uncertain. As Tilly points out:

    Throughout most of the last millennium, European cities and states have carried on a

    series of liaisons dangereuses, love-hate affairs in which each became at once

    indispensable and insufferable to the other [C]apitalists drew indispensable protection

    for their commercial and industrial activity from the specialists in coercion who ran

    states, but rightly feared interference in their money-making and diversion of their

    resources to war, preparation for war, or payment for past wars. States and military men

    depended on capitalists for the financial means to recruit and sustain armed force, yet

    properly worried about the resistance to state power engendered by cities [and] their

    commercial interests... [Capitalists] and states found the grounds for uneasy bargains in

    the exchange of protection for access to capital, but until the nineteenth century such

    bargains remained fragile.33

    In other words, rulers and traders were involved in a simultaneously mutually beneficial and

    mutually suspicious relationship.

    32 Ruggie 1993, 166. See also North and Weingast 1989; Tilly 1990. 33 Tilly 1990, 58-59. Similarly, Spruyt observes that the burghers had two competing preferences. On the one hand, they had a preference for the greatest amount of independence possible On the other hand, a stronger central authority would benefit translocal trade. Protection from robbers, pirates, and demanding feudal barons, as well as reduction in the prolific amount of feudal exactions and tolls, would benefit long-distance trade. Spruyt 1994, 63. Note that Tilly takes a broad definition of capitalists. For him, capital includes any tangible mobile resources, and enforceable claims on such resources. Capitalists, then, are people who specialize in the accumulation, purchase, and sale of capital Through most of history, capitalists have worked chiefly as merchants, entrepreneurs, and financiers, rather than as the direct organizers of production. Tilly 1990, 17.

  • Victoria Hui 13

    In the symbiotic relationship between rulers and traders, the bargain of taxation for

    protection is legendary. Indeed, this bargain is so taken for granted that one of the standard

    definitions of government is an organization that provides protection and justice in return for

    revenue.34 The rationale is that capital-holders would prefer to have rulers provide military

    protection against roving bandits along trade routes than to develop private security on their own.

    As the emerging states increased their territorial size, traders could also enjoy safer travel in

    increasingly larger areas. In addition, capital-holders also needed rulers to create a more

    business-friendly environment, including establishment of a reliable and unified legal framework

    to protect their private properties and to adjudicate disputes among themselves, and

    standardization of currencies and measures to facilitate transactions. In return for these services,

    rulers collected taxes on merchandises and trade activities.35

    But the mutual benefits provided by the ruler-trader alliance ran much deeper than this

    simple caricature of taxation for protection. In earlier times, rulers faced not only external

    enemies, but also internal contestants to the throne. In the face of interlocking internal and

    external rivalries, no ruler who seriously pursued war avoided reliance on capitalists of some

    sort.36 Even when they just wanted to buy off rivals, rulers still needed money. In return for

    ready cash, the nouveaux riches earned not just protection and handsome interests, but also social

    status. The burgher class was originally despised by the clergy and the nobility. Their inability

    to bear arms and their birth marked them inevitably as inferior to the nobility, and their pursuit

    34 North and Thomas 1973, 6. Many rational-choice approaches take a similar definition. 35 North and Thomas 1973; Spruyt 1994. 36 Tilly 1994, 11.

  • Victoria Hui 14

    of profit violated the Churchs proscription against usury.37 Hence, it was not preordained that

    burghers could translate economic wealth into political power.38 However, kings and princes

    who were desperate for cash had to rely on formally independent capitalists for loans, for

    management of revenue-producing enterprises, and for installation and collection of taxes.39 By

    helping political rulers maintain survival or achieve their ambitions, the burgher class not only

    achieved estatization40 on par with the clergy and the nobility, but also became indispensable

    equals to rulers and interacted with them on terms of relative equality.41

    Such mutually beneficial affairs between rulers and burghers, however, were shadowed

    by mutual suspicions right from the beginning. Rulers sought to establish centralize control, but

    found themselves confronted with powerful economic actors whose external relations they

    could never entirely control, and who found it relatively easy to escape with the capital to

    another business site if the rulers demands became unbearable.42 Moreover, the immense

    wealth of the new class had double-edged meanings: Although such wealth provided rulers with

    new resources to subjugate feudal aristocrats and local magnates, it also provided resources for

    its owners to challenge the Crown. On the part of burghers, they had a preference for the

    greatest amount of independence possible43 and lacked confidence that rulers would fully carry

    out the bargain of taxation for protection. As Blockmans observes, [m]onarchies furthered the

    37 Spruyt 1994, 72-74. For the same reason, during the Reformation, the most important converts were merchants and craftsmen who were excluded from political privilege. Philpott 2000, 231. 38 As Gilpin cautions us, [t]he seeming ease with which this aggressive class achieved ascendancy in both domestic and international society in the western world obscures how extraordinary a development this was. Gilpin 1977, 25. 39 Tilly 1990, 29. 40 Downing 1992, 30. 41 Tilly 1990, 130, 60, 30. 42 Tilly 1990, 52. 43 Spruyt 1994, 63.

  • Victoria Hui 15

    development of [commerce] only as long as they were unable to impose their dynastic or

    imperial dreams, which unlimited as they were necessarily exhausted even the most

    flourishing economy.44 As kings were above the law, capital-holders were also worried about

    arbitrary actions, including debt repudiation, debasements, confiscations, expulsions, irregular

    levies, forced loans, judicial murders, and the like.45 For instance, the repudiation of debts by

    Edward III of England in 1339 precipitated a financial crisis in Italy and led to the first clearly

    recognizable business cycle in Europe.46 Nevertheless, the fact that traders and financiers had

    the exit option of escaping to neighboring polities with their movable assets served as an

    implicit rein on arbitrary power.47

    Heightened Fiscal Crises and an Invidious Form of the Ruler-Trader Alliance

    The inherently uneasy relations between rulers and burghers was further strained after the

    modern period dawned at the French invasion of Italy in 1494.48 While technological

    breakthroughs in shipping allowed Italians, Portugese, and Spaniards to expand their trading

    networks to the New World, the concomitant military revolution significantly pushed up the

    costs of war beyond the means of any European rulers. The military revolution refers to not just

    the invention of gunpowder, but also the process whereby small, decentralized, self-equipped

    44 Blockman 1994, 245. North and Thomas also argue that [t]rade and commerce were protected only when their promotion suited the lords and the Crowns interest; frequently they were impeded or hindered for the same reason. North and Thomas 1973, 70. 45 Jones 1988, 93. 46 Krasner 1999a, 129. 47 Jones 1988, 118; also Bates and Lien 1985; Levi 1988, 97-112. 48 According to Levy, the French invasion of Italy at the end of 1494 and the Treaty of Venice in March of 1495 mark the coalescence of the major European states into a truly interdependent system of behavior. Levy 1983, 21. Tilly concurs: We can reasonably date a comprehensive European state system from the French and Spanish invasions of Italy, which greatly expanded the scale of European warmaking, and opened the age of mass mercenary armies. Tilly 1990, 164.

  • Victoria Hui 16

    feudal hosts were replaced by increasingly large, centrally financed and supplied armies that

    equipped themselves with ever more sophisticated and expensive weaponry.49 The combination

    of technologically advanced military weapons and ever larger army size quickly made war so

    fearfully expensive50 that [n]o state in this period could pay immediately for the costs of a

    prolonged conflict.51 Moreover, ordinary revenues were not just insufficient, but they also

    dribbled in small amounts throughout the year and could not therefore provide the large sums

    needed to put an army in the field.52 As before, European rulers turned to capital-holders for

    additional revenues. However, although the ruler-trader alliance had the salutary effects of

    facilitating both economic growth and nascent constitutionalism in the medieval era, an invidious

    form of this alliance had the opposite effects of eroding both development and constitutionalism

    in the early modern period.

    As discussed above, medieval constitutionalism originally emerged when monarchs

    wanted to levy new taxes to pursue war. After the dawn of the early modern period, various

    European rulers did convene representative assemblies to approve new taxes. However,

    representatives were loath to approve dramatic increases in taxes which monarchs claimed were

    demanded by the exigencies of the time. Representatives were also suspicious that kings and

    princes would use the standing armies thus created to establish autocracy. To solve the fiscal

    crises and constitutional strains, various kings tried to subvert representative assemblies. They

    did so by packing estates with supporters, bribing representatives into approving taxes that would

    49 Downing 1992, 10. 50 Kennedy 1987, 65. 51 Kennedy 1987, 72. 52 Kaiser 1990, 20.

  • Victoria Hui 17

    be passed on to the powerless lower classes, or bypassing estates altogether in the name of raison

    detat.53

    In the art of subverting representative assemblies, Charles VII of France was the pioneer

    ahead of other European powers. During the last decades of the Hundred Years War, Charles

    VII originally had a hard time fighting the English king both as a foreign enemy and as a rival

    claimant to the French throne. The turning point occurred in 1428 when the English assaulted

    Orlans. This threat permitted Charles to raise 500,000 livre tournois from the assembly he

    called at Chenon. From then on, the king increasingly treated imposition of taxes as royal

    prerogative which did not require approval. In the face of incessant warfare, the Estates General

    gradually surrendered their constitutional right to approve taxes. The assembly at Orlans in

    1439 became the last national assembly to approve the taille (a direct tax).54 Together with the

    establishment of the Compagnies dOrdonnance the first standing army in Europe in 1445,

    Charles VII thus created a royal monopoly of both coercion and taxation.55

    Frances invasion of Italy in 1494 compelled the Habsburg house to defend its Italian

    possessions, thus kicking off a century-long Spanish-French rivalry. Desperate for new taxes, the

    Emperor of the United Habsburgs Charles V proceeded to subvert the Castilian Estates.56 He did

    so by reducing the Cortes to a single chamber of 36 deputies, then paying the deputies generous

    salaries and expenses, granting to them a lump sum payment each time they voted increases in

    servicios (a direct tax), and allowing them to keep 1.5 percent of newly approved alcabala (a 10

    53 Downing 1992, 10, 14, 74-75. 54 North and Thomas 1973, 120-121. 55 Ertman 1997, 86-87. 56 Through intricate diplomatic marriages by the previous generation, Charles V simultaneously ascended to the crowns of Castile, Aragon, Burgundy, Austria, and the Holy Roman Empire in 1519, and also to the thrones of Hungary and Bohemia in 1526. However, Charles enjoyed de facto control only in Castile.

  • Victoria Hui 18

    percent sales tax) and millones (a tax on foodstuffs).57 As a result, although the Cortes led a

    national revolt against Charles in the late 1510s, from 1520s onwards they loyally voted ever

    larger sums in taxes for the emperors wars.58 Unfortunately, Charles subversion of the Cortes

    not just eroded medieval constitutionalism, but also retarded economic development that was

    reviving elsewhere in Europe. The new taxes granted preferential rates and even complete

    exemptions to the privileged, but tended to hit at trade, the exchange of goods and the poor,59

    with the result of destroying Spains economy in the long-term.60

    The fiscal problems did not end there. As even dramatic increases in tax revenues were

    insufficient to meet skyrocketing costs of war, both France and the United Habsburgs soon

    resorted to a variety of expedients that were easy in the short term but disastrous for the long-

    term good.61 Increasingly, they contracted loans and credits with Italian and German bankers,

    and sold public offices to the highest bidders. But such ready cash came at a high price not just

    because rulers had to pay high interest rates, but also because they signed away both the yield

    and the administration of these revenues for years on end.62 While sovereign debts had begun in

    the thirteenth century,63 they assumed much higher salience in the sixteenth century. Bankers

    learned from widespread sovereign defaults in earlier centuries that there was simply no effective

    57 Ertman 1997, 112-116. 58 Ertman 1997, 112-116. 59 Kennedy 1987, 53. 60 There was also the problem of the Mesta or shephards guild in Castile. The Crown had earlier granted the Mesta the right to drive their sheep across Spain in their accustomed manner. This means that no land owner could have exclusive rights to his property and so there were few incentives to engage in arable agriculture and much less to improve it. North and Thomas 1973, 130. However, as it was relatively easy to tax the Mesta, the Spanish king not only did not change this policy, but even outlawed farmers own efforts at enclosures. The result was widespread discontent and depopulation. North and Thomas 1973, 4-5. 61 Kennedy 1987, 54. 62 Kaiser 1990, 20. 63 Blockmans 1994, 244.

  • Victoria Hui 19

    means to enforce repayments because kings were above the law. Bankers thus demanded a high

    risk premium in the form of higher interest rates.64 In France, Francis I (1515-1547) began to

    borrow from Parisian businessmen at interest rates of 12-16 percent per annum.65 In Spain, the

    annual interest charge for juros (interest-bearing government bonds) consumed 36.6 percent of

    the Crowns total ordinary revenue in 1522.66 This interest payment climbed to 65 percent of

    ordinary revenue in 1543,67 then to 103.9 percent by 1560.68 From then onward, the income from

    nearly all of the Crowns most reliable and predictable taxes were pledged to bond holders.69

    As the amounts of sovereign debts quickly exceeded the kings abilities to repay, bankers

    became increasingly reluctant to lend even at handsome interest rates. French and Habsburg

    rulers thus gradually transferred control over future sources of revenues into the hands of

    creditors. Successive Spanish kings contracted asientos which pledged as collaterals shiploads of

    gold and silver from the New World.70 In France, Henry I and II launched the sale of rentes and

    guaranteed interest payments by signing over to lenders the right to income streams from pieces

    of property (land or building). This means that, until reimbursement, the Crown had in fact

    permanently alienated the revenue source against which the interest payments were guaranteed.71

    In addition to contracting loans, French kings and Habsburg emperors also put up public

    offices for sale. As Shultz and Weingast explain, [a]lthough an absolute monarch could not be

    64 Shultz and Weingast 2000, 13. 65 Ertman 1997, 97. 66 Ertman 1997, 116. 67 Kennedy 1987, 54. 68 Ertman 1997, 116. 69 Ertman 1997, 116. 70 Ertman 1997, 117. Although the United Habsburgs seemed to be blessed with such an external source, the empire was also more burdened with the need to defend a far-flung empire. 71 Ertman 1997, 98-99.

  • Victoria Hui 20

    trusted or forced to pay back a loan, granting offices was a way to ensure that lenders would

    receive compensation.72 Francis I first created 20 new positions in the Parlement of Paris in

    1522. Henry II then established an entirely new system of courts in 1552, and later the alternatif

    or the practice of sharing an office between two holders in 1554.73 Louis XIVs ministers even

    created a host of entirely absurd offices, including official burial announcer, barrel roller, and

    wall and room inspector.74 Bidders continued to be forthcoming because even absurd offices

    carried exemptions from taxes and other privileges. Such massive sale of public offices gradually

    led to the formation of corporate bodies of lenders who advanced cash to the Crown in exchange

    for the right to levy a tax, to administer justice, to enforce laws, and to enjoy exemption from

    taxes and other privileges.75 Similarly, in Spanish Castile, the royal court sold many whole

    villages and towns into private hands, so that only about 30 percent of the territory of Castile

    remained under royal authority in the late 1500s.76 A natural consequence of venality of public

    offices was corruption of public finance. As each official could take his cut before passing

    public revenues to a higher level,77 there were huge discrepancies between the amount of taxes

    paid and the revenues that actually reached the courts. For instance, in France in 1752, the

    overhead on a total revenue of 270 million livres amounted to 40.2 million, or nearly 15

    percent.78

    72 Shultz and Weingast 2000, 31. 73 Ertman 1997, 100-101. 74 Ertman 1997, 136. 75 Shultz and Weingast 2000, 30. 76 Ertman 1997, 119. 77 Kennedy 1987, 82. 78 Riley 1986, 60.

  • Victoria Hui 21

    Overall, the French and Spanish responses to heightened fiscal crises in the early modern

    period involved not just erosion of medieval constitutionalism, but also retardation of economic

    development in the long-term. The fiscal expedients they pursued only generated a vicious cycle

    leading to ever-escalating fiscal crises: the more the crowns ordinary income became alienated,

    the more desperate was its search for extraordinary revenues and new taxes;79 the more offices

    were sold and the more loans were contracted, the more difficult it became to relinquish sold

    offices and contracted loans. At various moments of acute desperation, the French court and the

    Habsburg house also repudiated debts, debased their currencies, and declared bankruptcies,

    thereby further hurting both the courts credit-worthiness and economic activities.80 Equally

    ominous, the privatization of public finance turned the ruler-burgher alliance into an invidious

    one. The emerging bourgeoisie who could potentially have played a progressive role in the

    transition from the medieval to the modern were thus feudalized and made weak, craven, and

    spineless.81

    An Alternative Form of Ruler-Trader Alliance Which Promoted Development and

    Consolidated Constitutionalism

    The patron-client relations between rulers and traders in the French-Spanish trajectory

    should resonate with various dismal stories in many corners of the world today. But there was an

    alternative trajectory tracked by the United Provinces/Dutch Republic and then England/Britain.

    Compared with the large and resourceful United Habsburgs/Habsburg Spain and Bourbon

    France, the Dutch Republic and England were puny. Although the center of commerce gradually

    79 Kennedy 1987, 54. 80 The Spanish Crown declared bankruptcies in 1557, 1575, 1596, 1607, 1627, and 1647, with grave impacts on the long-term credit market. North and Thomas 1973, 141.

  • Victoria Hui 22

    shifted from the Mediterranean to the Atlantic from the early sixteenth century on, the

    subsequent rise of these countries was not at all obvious at the beginning.82

    Indeed, the Netherlands was under Habsburg rule during the reigns of Charles V and

    Philip II. It is paradoxical that, although Charles V resorted to dubious expedients which

    simultaneously eroded the Cortes and impeded the economy in Castile, he laid down fiscal

    institutions which both facilitated economic growth and strengthened the provincial States

    (provincial assemblies) and States-General (an assembly of representatives from different

    provinces) in the Habsburg Netherlands. Charles authority was more tenuous in the Netherlands

    than in Castile, because he acquired the former from Burgundy by indirect inheritance through

    dynastic marriages. He thus engaged in more bargaining than coercion in the far-away

    possessions. To secure loans from wealthy Dutch burghers, the emperor shifted the responsibility

    for debt collection and repayment from the Habsburg regent in Belgium to the provincial States

    in 1515.83 On top of the fiscal institutions laid down by Charles, Dutch merchants further

    adopted and adapted various credit instruments that had been developed by the Italians, including

    bills of exchange, demand notes, deposit certificates, and the bonds of states and towns. As a

    result, the Low Countries reaped full benefits from the dramatic expansion of international trade

    and international finance in the sixteenth century. Antwerp soon came to dominate Europes

    business transactions, and the Dutch provinces became the jewels of the Habsburg Empire,

    furnishing the Crown with the bulk of its revenues.84

    81 Hirschman 1992, 130. 82 For instance, Portugal had tried to divert the Mediterranean trade by military force but failed. The Dutch later succeeded not by violence, but by price competition resulting from more efficiency in both ships and economic organization. North and Thomas 1973, 112. 83 Shultz and Weingast 2000, 30. 84 North and Thomas 1973, 134.

  • Victoria Hui 23

    Charles Vs policy in the Netherlands was more or less in line with that of the preceding

    Burgundian house, allowing a high degree of autonomy and extracting only reasonable amounts

    of taxation. This changed, however, under Philip II (1556-1598). Faced with ever-escalating

    fiscal crises, Philip decided to squeeze the Dutch harder by coercion. As Downing puts it, the

    Spanish governor, the Duke of Alva, set about castilianizing the land: taxes were forced through

    the States; the States-General was dismantled; and opponents were arrested and summarily tried

    by Alvas Council of Blood.85 The Dutch revolted. Over night, Philip lost the bulk of his

    ordinary revenues and even had to divert other resources to suppress the revolt. On the other

    hand, the States-General and the efficient fiscal institutions which Charles had fostered allowed

    the United Provinces to have sufficient political unity and financial resources to fight an

    intermittent war of independence. Although Antwerp was sacked, it was quickly replaced by the

    even more magnificent rise of Amsterdam. With the wealthiest economy of the time, the tiny

    United Provinces not only repelled the bankrupt Habsburgs, but also established a trading empire

    connecting Europe to Asia. The Dutch Republic gained Spanish recognition for its independence

    in 1648.86

    In the course of the Dutch war of independence, England was dragged into the War of

    Armada (1585-1604) with Habsburg Spain, thereby diverting Spanish pressure on the United

    Provinces. After the Dutch Republic gained independence, the two countries in turn became

    entangled in three naval wars in 1652-54, 1665-67, and 1672-74. It is worth noting that England

    looked more like Habsburg Spain and Bourbon France than the Dutch Republic at the time. In

    the early sixteenth century, England had pursued the most desperate of expedients: the sale of

    85 Downing 1992, 216. 86 The Dutch gained formal recognition from Spain in the Treaty of Mnster in January 1648. Note that this was a bilateral treaty and was not part of the Peace of Westphalia later in the same year. Osiander 2001, 268.

  • Victoria Hui 24

    religious properties at low rates, the seizure of the estates of nobles on trumped-up charges,

    repeated forced loans, the great debasement of the coinage, and finally the recourse to the

    Fuggers and other foreign bankers.87 Hence, by the reign of Charles I, the English state had

    become a kind of parasite, extracting resources from the productive sectors of the nation and

    redistributing them among a small political class with access to power, offices, and contracts.88

    During the Second Anglo-Dutch War, English defenses had deteriorated to the point where the

    Dutch were able to sail up to the Thames and burn the great naval dockyard at Chatham in

    1667.89

    Nevertheless, such humiliation also triggered a thorough review of corrupt practices in

    the Navy and other government departments. Sir George Downing, who had been ambassador to

    the Hague, sought to introduce Dutch institutions, most notably the public credit system. The

    public credit system was so called because the Crown would directly borrow from the general

    public rather than from financiers. To fully implement this policy, England needed an efficient,

    centralized administration. First, the English Crown established the Treasury as the master

    department over all other departments in 1679 and the Bank of England in 1694. Second, the

    court abolished tax farming in customs tax, excise tax and hearth tax in 1671-84. At the same

    time, it built up the efficiency and probity of the chief revenue-collecting (excise, customs, and

    land tax) agencies and of main spending departments (most notably the army and navy). Third,

    venality was replaced by meritocracy in the whole government structure civil and military.

    While venality pitted officials private interests against a countrys national interest, meritocracy

    87 Kennedy 1987, 60. 88 Ertman 1997, 184. 89 Ertman 1997, 194.

  • Victoria Hui 25

    could bring social and private rates of return into closer parity.90 In addition to administrative

    and fiscal efficiency, the public credit system also required guarantees to investors that only a

    representative assembly could provide.91 The Parliament thus came to the forefront of this

    operation, with market forces and informed public opinion providing additional scrutiny.92 This

    system came to maturity during the subsequent War of the Spanish Succession: Every year

    Parliament voted supply of between 4 and 6 million pounds to prosecute the war, and every year

    the general public advanced to the government the full amount of supply voted in cash in

    exchange for Treasury Orders secured on the tax funds If for any reason the price of Treasury

    Orders or departmental bills fell below par, the Bank of England stood ready to intervene at the

    Treasurys request to prop up the market.93 In short, the public credit system provided a long-

    term solution to the perennial problem of how to come up with large amounts of ready cash in

    time of war without having to rely on such expedients as high-interest loans and sale of offices.

    With an unprecedented ability to mobilize national resources, Britain soon took over the

    preeminence of the Dutch Republic in the economic sphere,94 and Bourbon France in the military

    sphere in the eighteenth century.

    Britains ascendance over France was a surprise to contemporaries, because Frances

    population was three times as big and its economy twice as large. But money formed the sinews

    90 North and Thomas 1973, 2. To North and Thomas, this is the most important factor that defines efficient administration. Of course, meritocracy did not stamp out venality in one stroke. Britains ruling class continued to be dominated by the landed aristocracy well into the twentieth century. Nevertheless, the principle of meritocracy did help to make sure that it was the more competent among the aristocracy who enjoyed the power to rule. 91 Ertman 1997, 225. 92 Ertman 1997, 218. 93 Ertman 1997, 218. 94 North and Thomas emphasize that the Netherlands did not really decline. It is simply that the center of the economic stage shifts to England. North and Thomas 1973, 145.

  • Victoria Hui 26

    of power95 in the modern period, so that superior finance96 could be translated into superior

    military strength. After the administrative-fiscal reforms, the British state could levy higher taxes

    on its citizens and secure higher credits at lower interest rates. The following figures are

    illustrative. While Frenchmen paid about 8.1 livres per capita in annual taxes in the first quarter

    of the eighteenth century, Englishmen paid 17.6 livres. By the 1780s, Frenchmen paid 17 livres

    per capita, but Englishmen paid 46 livres.97 While the French courts ratios of public spending to

    national output were 8.7 percent and 10.3 percent in 1689-1699 and 1702-1715 respectively, the

    British government could lift public expenditure from 4.2 percent in 1687, to 11.4 percent in the

    1690s, and then to 14 percent the 1700s.98 Moreover, with superior access to credits, Britain

    could sustain larger and longer wars well in excess of normal receipts without exhausting its

    economy.99 In the average war year, Britains military spending amounted to 1-1.5 years worth

    of revenue, while Frances comparable figure was 0.5-0.8. During the Seven Years War, Britain

    outspent France by 40 percent, but it was France which went to the brink of bankruptcy.100 In

    addition, while Britains credits took the form of perpetual redeemable securities and at the low

    interest rates of 3-4 percent in the period 1689-1815, France had to rely on amortizing loans at 2

    percentage points higher.101 As the British-French rivalry intensified in the eighteenth century,

    France witnessed three major episodes of defaults. The centuries-old fiscal problems eventually

    culminated in the fateful calling of the Estates General in 1789.

    95 Brewer 1989. 96 Shultz and Weingast 2000, 22. 97 Brewer 1989, 89. 98 Ertman 1997, 134. 99 Shultz and Weingast 2000, 3-4, 47-48. 100 Shultz and Weingast 2000, 25-26. 101 Brewer 1989, 133; Ertman 1997, 141; Shultz and Weingast 2000, 24.

  • Victoria Hui 27

    Ruler-Trader Alliance, State Capacity, Development, and Constitutionalism

    The French-Spanish and Dutch-English trajectories may now be examined together. In

    the face of growing fiscal crises brought on by increasingly larger armies and increasingly

    expensive weapons, rulers could mobilize additional revenues (1) by seeking approval and

    guarantee from representative assemblies, or (2) by circumventing assemblies and turning to

    bankers, financiers, and other wealthy individuals. Rulers had to bargain with capital-holders in

    both scenarios, but the institutional settings in which the ruler-trader alliance occurred were very

    different, with dramatic consequences. In France and Spain, the invidious ruler-trader alliance

    subverted medieval constitutionalism, feudalized the emerging bourgeoisie, retarded economic

    growth, and eroded military strength. In contrast, in the Dutch Republic and England/Britain, the

    alliance between rulers and the emerging bourgeoisie not only enhanced military and economic

    competitiveness, but also consolidated constitutionalism.

    How do we account for the divergent trajectories? First, England was fortunate that the

    Parliament was better able to resist the blandishments of ambitious rulers102 than the Cortes in

    Spain or the Parlements in France. The English Parliament was territorially-based, whereby

    privileged classes sat together in an upper house and representatives from localities sat in the

    lower house. In contrast, the estate-based assemblies in France and Spain were divided into

    separate chambers with each composed of one privileged group: the nobility, the clergy, or the

    burghers. Ertman argues that estate-based assemblies were far more vulnerable to divide-and-

    rule tactics, while territorially-based assemblies facilitated collective actions against the

    encroachment of the Crown.103 England was also fortunate that it was less entangled with

    102 Ertman 1997, 21. 103 Ertman 1997, 21-22.

  • Victoria Hui 28

    continental warfare than Spain or France in the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries. With less

    severe fiscal crises, England had fewer sold offices and smaller amounts of debts to redeem

    when it decided to pursue reforms.104 By the time England did become entangled with France

    when William of Orange became king of both England and the Dutch Republic, the weak foreign

    king was so committed to resist France that he was willing to yield to a united, reformist

    Parliament. After the Glorious Revolution, all matters of war and peace and taxation had to be

    jointly decided by the Crown in Parliament.

    The superiority of the ruler-trader alliance in constitutional settings also rested with the

    simultaneous building of state capacity. State capacity refers to the human and material

    resources the state can mobilize for is purposes and the effectiveness with which it can achieve

    its goals.105 It has become a clich to say that absolute rulers in Europe were not really absolute.

    Indeed, [t]he doctrine of the absolute right of monarchs was a theoretical claim of weak rulers

    for a far-off utopia they hoped to establish.106 For most of the early modern period, various

    European states had small and ineffective bureaucracies, armed forces they did not control very

    well, and all sorts of strong local authorities and overlapping jurisdictions.107 England suffered

    from the same problems in the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries. But the Treasury established

    in the reform era enabled Britain to become the first major European state to keep full accounts

    of total government revenue and expenditure.108 Moreover, Englands reform package replaced

    intermediate power-holders with centrally appointed officials. While reliance on tax farmers and

    104 Brewer 1989, 69-70. 105 Wong 1997, 82. 106 Wallerstein 1999, 23. 107 Wallerstein 1999, 23. 108 Brewer 1989, 129.

  • Victoria Hui 29

    venal officials set serious limits on the quantity of resources rulers could extract from the

    ambient economy,109 use of centrally appointed administrators allowed the central government

    to identify potential tax bases, to assess tax liabilities in accordance with specific activities, and

    to effectively collect revenues at the local level.

    The symbiosis between constitutionalism and state capacity may also be analyzed in light

    of the evolving literature on state strength. In the early round of scholarship to bring the state

    back in,110 state strength was taken to mean the states ability to formulate interests and policies

    on its own, independent of and even against the will of resistant societal interests.111 This

    unidimensional view has been replaced by a multidimensional conception which differentiates

    state autonomy from state capacity, and despotic power from infrastructural capacity.112 While

    state autonomy and despotic power refer to rulers ability to act against societal interests, state

    capacity in general and infrastructural capacity in particular refer to the ability to mobilize

    resources and to deploy them effectively. As Barkey and Parikh put it, [s]tates with despotic

    power are often characterized as strong, but their levels of autonomy and capacity are highly

    variable. By contrast, states with infrastructural power enhance their capacities to carry out their

    goals.113 Hence, although the English state was weak vis--vis the Parliament, it had a

    tremendous capacity for extracting considerable sums in taxation and loans.114 In contrast, the

    109 Tilly 1990, 104. 110 Evans, Rueschemeyer and Skocopol 1985. 111 Krasner 1984. 112 Katznelson 1992; Mann 1988. 113 Barkey and Parikh 1991, 526. 114 Barkey and Parikh 1991, 529.

  • Victoria Hui 30

    French state had a more conventional, despotic kind of power but it had very limited capacity to

    mobilize resources from its populace.115

    The multidimensional conception of the state also provides insight for the type of state-

    society relations that best enhances state capacity. While the despotic power of the state is in

    zero-sum conflict with society, the infrastructural power of the state is best achieved by state-

    society cooperation. Constitutionalism was traditionally seen as a standoff between a would-be

    despot and parliamentary opposition.116 But theorists of the state now speak of state-society

    synergy,117 state-society partnership,118 and mutual empowerment of state and society.119

    As Hobson puts it, state power is enhanced when the state co-operates with, and embeds itself

    in, strong social power.120 In the image of the Crown-in-Parliament, the state-in-society

    perspective now views constitutionalism as state-society partnership in the joint pursuit of

    national interests.121

    If economic development, constitutional rights, and even military capabilities are heavily

    shaped by state capacity and state-society cooperation, then it is possible though by no means

    easy for those that lagged behind to catch up. Thus, the United Provinces/Dutch Republic was

    able to catch up with Italian city-states in the sixteenth century. England was able to catch up

    with the Dutch Republic in the economic sphere and with France in the military sphere in the

    eighteenth century. Even more dramatically, France was able to catch up with Britains military

    115 Barkey and Parikh 1991, 529. 116 Downing 1992, 54. 117 Evans 1997, 81. 118 Unger 1987, 170. 119 Wang 1999, 234. 120 Hobson 2002, 74. 121 See Migdal et al. 1994.

  • Victoria Hui 31

    prowess after the French Revolution. After revolutionaries overthrew centuries-old expedients

    and installed unprecedented direct rule,122 France could engage in near total mobilization by

    imposing national taxation and universal national conscription.123 Napoleonic France came very

    close to dominating the European continent. Britain eventually defeated France only with the

    assistance of allies.

    Lessons from the West on the Rest

    Smith, Solinger and Topik argue that, by beginning with the history of globalization, we

    are better able to appreciate the situations and dilemmas of states in the world today, as well as

    the forces that have shaped them over time.124 Can we draw any lessons from the Western

    world in the medieval and modern period on the Rest in the contemporary era? The contrasting

    trajectories of France and Spain on the one hand and the Dutch Republic and England on the

    other hand have important implications for economic growth and constitutional rights in

    developing countries. In the early stage of the post-colonial era, there was an optimism that all

    developing countries should sooner or later share the fruits of both economic and political

    modernization. However, that did not happen in most parts of the world. Instead, growing trade

    expansion in the post-WWII era only accentuated the gap between the West and the Rest. In the

    late 1960s and 1970s, Latin American scholars thus propounded the theory of development of

    122 As Tilly observes, no European state made a serious attempt to institute direct rule from top to bottom until the era of the French Revolution. Tilly 1990, 25. More or less simultaneously [the revolutionaries] recast the French map into a nested system of departments, districts, cantons, and communes, while sending out reprsentants en mission to forward revolutionary reorganization. They installed direct rule. Tilly 1990,109. 123 In response, Britain introduced the income tax (which was repealed after the Napoleonic Wars) but not yet direct rule. 124 Smith, Solinger and Topik 1999, 10.

  • Victoria Hui 32

    underdevelopment, arguing that underdevelopment in the periphery was the necessary

    corollary of development in the West.125

    The dependency theory, however, was soon shattered by the East Asian miracle.126

    After Japans miraculous127 rise to become the worlds second largest economy, four East Asian

    newly industrialized countries (NICs) Taiwan, South Korea, Hong Kong, and Singapore also

    witnessed phenomenal economic growth in the 1980s. Like the literature on the European

    miracle,128 the literature on the East Asian miracle has little patience with the pessimism of

    the dependency school or the cynicism of anti-globalization critics. Indeed, scholars of East

    Asian political economy emphasize that catching up is possible and that economic development

    is a function of state policies.129 Although the task of catching up has become increasingly

    difficult because late developers face increasingly large-scale markets and high entry costs,

    success is still possible if the state mobilizes national resources, builds efficient institutions, and

    support infant industries in the national pursuit of the developmental project.

    While scholars of both the East Asian miracle and the European miracle agree on the

    possibility of catching up, they tend to diverge on the relationship between development and

    constitutionalism. Constitutionalism now means more than just checks on the king; it refers to

    democratic elections with free and fair multiparty contests, human rights and freedom of

    125 Wallerstein 1974, 392. 126 The World Banks 1992 report coins the success of the East Asian NICs as the East Asian miracle. World Bank 1992. 127 Johnson 1982. 128 Jones 1988. 129 It is typically argued that the East Asian NICs have been more successful than Latin American economies because the former have pursued export-led growth while the latter pursued the import-substitution policy. See Haggard 1990.

  • Victoria Hui 33

    expression, and the rule of law.130 Specialists of East Asia argue that such Western-style

    democracy and human rights are not suitable to Asian culture and may even be harmful for

    development.131 In this view, the global market presents a hard choice between economic

    development and constitutional rights. East Asian experts argue that the so-called

    developmental state should be authoritarian because the developmental project involves high

    extraction and short-term sacrifices for societal actors.132 As Haggard explains, [s]ince

    authoritarian political arrangements give political elites autonomy from distributionist pressures,

    they increase the governments ability to extract resources, provide public goods, and impose the

    short-term costs associated with efficient economic adjustment. Weak legislatures that limit the

    representative role of parties, the corporatist organization of interest groups, and recourse to

    coercion in the face of resistance should all expand governments freedom to maneuver on

    economic policy.133 This argument is squarely at odds with the European experience that it was

    constitutional Britain, rather than absolutist France, which could extract higher rates of taxation,

    surpassed France in military competition, and kicked off the industrial revolution. The

    developmental thesis often points to Germany, which caught up with Britain in the late twentieth

    century by pursuing ruthless state-led industrialization. But Germany is hardly representative of

    the European experience.134 Ertman, who studies all countries in the European Christendom,

    observes that, if the European past holds one overriding lesson for todays state-builders, it

    130 Davis 2002, 5. 131 Haggard 1990; Kausikan 1997. 132 Johnson 1982. See also Deyo 1987; Woo-Cummings 1999. 133 Haggard 1990, 13. 134 Germany was quite a different story apart from both the French-Spanish and Dutch-English trajectories. In the early modern period, geographical Germany constituted the Holy Roman Empire. After the Thirty Years War, the Peace of Westphalia restored constitutional checks and balances within the empire. The levels of state capacity

  • Victoria Hui 34

    would be this: it is the combination of a strong center and strong, participatory localities

    which, over the long run, will best permit states to balance the demands of infrastructural

    expansion, political participation, economic growth, and geopolitical competition.135

    Although the early literature on the East Asian miracle was disconnected with the

    Western experience, more and more scholars of East Asia have over time turned to the literature

    on state-society relations to challenge the claim that the developmental state must be

    authoritarian. For instance, Friedman argues that [a] strong state is not an authoritarian or

    parasitic state. A strong state is one with the capacity to formulate, legitimate, and implement

    crucial policies.136 Among the four East Asian NICs, South Korea and Taiwan underwent

    successful transitions to democracy in the 1990s. Like the Dutch-English model, these states now

    enjoy both development and constitutionalism. Asian economies were hard hit by the Asian

    financial crisis, but those that are more democratic have been more resilient.137

    What about the rest of the Rest? It is worrisome that South America and Central

    America now risk becoming another Africa.138 Various Latin American economies are again on

    the verge of another financial crisis. Argentinas economy has already collapsed. But Argentina

    is not alone, most of Latin America, in particular, Uruguay, Paraguay, Bolivia, Colombia,

    Venezuela are as badly off or worse.139 The current problems are, to some extent, a legacy of

    varied across autonomous principalities, highest in Brandenburg-Prussia but lower in others. Osiander 2001, 269-277. 135 Ertman 1997, 324. 136 Friedman1999, 247. 137 Emmerson 1998; Haggard 2000. 138 Kristof 2002. 139 Ibid.

  • Victoria Hui 35

    easy credits in the 1970s and debt crises in the 1980s.140 As the French and Spanish experiences

    illustrate, it is very difficult to get out of the vicious cycle of unsustainable debts. Africa is in

    even worse shape. The World Banks World Development Report points out that state failure in

    sub-Saharan Africa has reached crisis proportions as the state has failed to deliver even such

    fundamental public goods as property rights, roads, and basic health and education.141 Not

    surprisingly, such [f]ailed states, disorderly states, weak states, and corrupt states are shunned

    as the black holes of the global economic system.142

    To some extent, the worst cases in the contemporary Rest are similar to the worst case in

    the early modern West, Spain. The United Habsburgs enjoyed access to treasures from the New

    World and payments from the rich Netherlands and Italian city-states (Naples and Milan). At the

    empires height, Spain itself (mostly Castile) provided only about 10 percent of the empires

    revenues. While such enviable external sources helped to explain Habsburg power under Charles

    V, they equally explained its decline from Philip II on. The availability of easy cash meant that

    Charles had no need to engage in the difficult tasks of building up administrative capacity or

    mobilizing support from the productive sectors of the empire. However, when the Dutch

    provinces revolted, and when the influx of bullion leveled off at the end of the sixteenth century

    and then declined precipitously from the 1630s onward, Habsburg Spain was constantly on the

    verge of bankruptcy.143 Similarly, in the developing world, the worst cases now often appeared

    to be the most blessed at the moment of independence they were either richly endowed with oil

    or other precious minerals, or strategically located and enjoyed handsome foreign aids. With

    140 Frieden 1991. 141 Cited in Krasner 1999a, 145. 142 Wolf 2001, 191. 143 North and Thomas 1973, 128-131.

  • Victoria Hui 36

    such easy sources of revenues, rulers of these newly independent states did not have to extract

    taxation from their populations and did not have to bargain with societal actors. They could

    therefore enjoy high degrees of state autonomy and despotic power. However, when economic

    crises hit, or when demand for their minerals plummet, or when their natural resources dry up,

    these states have little viability to survive. Even in oil-rich countries where resources seem

    inexhaustible and the global demand robust, rulers often exercise despotic power with little state

    capacity.

    If different states East and West, now and then could achieve development and

    constitutionalism, then it is difficult to agree with anti-globalization protestors to place all the

    blame of such dismal conditions on the West. At the same time, advocates for globalization

    should understand that catching up is a daunting process, requiring extraordinary efforts if not

    revolutionary changes and extraordinary luck. Failed states are unlikely to be able to pick up

    such extraordinary efforts on their own. The World Bank has taken steps to rebuild state

    effectiveness through an overhaul of public institutions, reasserting the rule of law, and credible

    checks on abuse of state power.144 Even the IMF, whose original mandate was merely to

    maintain international balance-of-payments stability, has moved toward structural reforms to

    build up administrative capacity necessary for sustainable economic development. These state-

    building efforts should be intensified. It may be said that World Bank and IMF conditionality has

    made indebted states more vulnerable to the exigencies of the international market, thereby

    generating further disruptions rather than promoting growth.145 These Bretton Woods institutions

    have acknowledged that some of their earlier conditions were excessive. But the more

    144 Cited in Krasner 1999a, 145. 145 Stigliz 2002.

  • Victoria Hui 37

    fundamental problem is probably not liberalization per se, but weak administrative capacity and

    regulatory oversight that have made debtor countries so vulnerable to economic downturns.146 As

    Evans puts it, high stateness is a critical competitive advantage in a globalized economy.147

    From this perspective, it may be more useful to see the globalized market as a realm of

    opportunity into which [states] can dip in order to push through reforms.148 In the long-run,

    the winners will be those whose government and society are resilient enough to withstand the

    shocks and surprises that the fast-changing global economy inevitably brings.149 It may be

    further argued that any efforts by international institutions to engage in state-building would

    violate state sovereignty. It is important not to overlook that Spanish and French rulers were once

    far more vulnerable to international financiers. The lesson from history is that debtors are

    inevitably at the mercy of creditors150 -- the only way to break out of dependence on external

    actors is to build up state capacity and to depend on societal actors.

    Concluding Remarks

    This paper evaluates globalization in the longue dure, analyzing not only its impacts on

    development and constitutionalism, but also its origins and evolution over time. I have discussed

    processes of globalization from the medieval period onward, the resultant ruler-trader alliance,

    and the emergence of medieval constitutionalism. It is often overlooked that constitutionalism as

    well as capitalism were brought about by self-serving capital-holders who are denounced by anti-

    146 Eichengreen 2002. 147 Evans 1997, 68. 148 Hobson 2002, 75. 149 Plattner 1999, 168. 150 As Mann puts it, Restructuring is now extreme across much of [Latin American] region, virtually eliminating macroeconomic planning and trimming welfare states. But this may result less from transnationalism than from the power conferred on finance capital and its major institutions by the burden of debt. Mann 1999, 247.

  • Victoria Hui 38

    globalization protestors.151 However, not all forms of ruler-trader alliance have salutary effects.

    The divergence between the Dutch-English trajectory and the French-Spanish trajectory in terms

    of both economic and constitutional developments is instructive. While the former achieved

    international competitiveness at the price of making concessions to society, the latter maximized

    despotic power at the price of economic stagnation and constitutional erosion. To achieve

    simultaneous economic growth and constitutional rights, the ruler-trader alliance should be

    embedded with state-society partnership and with state capacity. In short, the challenge of

    globalization is the same now and then, Rest and West. Just as European states had to build up

    state capacity in the early modern period, developing countries have faced the same daunting

    task in the post-WWII era.

    151 While the self-serving bourgeoisie should be credited for the emergence of constitutionalism, they played no progressive role in the expansion of constitutionalism. Capitalists pushed for their own inclusion in state affairs, but they were very reluctant to extend the franchise to the lower classes. See Rueschemeyer, Stephens and Stephens 1992.

  • Victoria Hui 39

    Bibliography

    Arrighi, Giovanni. 1999. Globalization, State Sovereignty, and the Endless Accumulation of Capital, in David A. Smith, Dorothy J. Solinger, and Steven C. Topik, eds., States and Sovereignty in the Global Economy, New York: Routledge, 53-73.

    Blockmans, Wim P. 1994. Voracious States and Obstructing Cities: An Aspect of State Formation in Preindustrial Europe, in Charles Tilly and Wim Blockmans, eds., Cities and The Rise of States in Europe AD 1000 to 1800, Boulder, Colarado: Westview Press, 218-250.

    Barkey, Karen, and Sunita Parikh. 1991. Comparative Perspectives on the State, Annual Review of Sociology 17, 523-549.

    Buzan, Barry, and Richard Little. 2000. International Systems in World History: Remaking the Study of International Relations, Oxford University Press.

    Bartlett, Robert. 1993. The Making of Europe: Conquest, Colonization and Cultural Change 950-1350, Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Brewer, John. 1989. The Sinews of Power: War, Money and the English State, 1688-1783, New York: Alfred A. Knopf.

    Davis, Michael D. 2002. Developmental Paths for East Asia: Constitutionalism and State Reform. Paper presented at the 98th Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, August 29-September 1, Boston.

    Deyo, Frederic C., ed. 1987. The Political Economy of the New Asian Industrialism, Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

    Eichengreen, Barry. The Globalization Wars: An Economist Reports from the Frontline. Foreign Affairs 81, 4, Jul/Aug2002, 157-164.

    Emmerson, Donald. 1998. Americanizing Asia? Foreign Affairs, May/June ?? Ertman, Thomas. 1997. Birth of the Leviathan: Building States and Regimes in Medieval and

    Early Modern Europe, New York: Cambridge University Press. Evans, Peter B. 1995. Embedded Autonomy: States and Industrial Transformation, Princeton:

    Princeton University Press. Evans, Peter, B. 1997. The Eclipse of the State? Reflections on Stateness in an Era of

    Globalization, World Politics 50, 1, 62-87. Evans, Peter B., Dietrich Rueschemeyer and Theda Skocopol, eds. 1985. Bringing the State Back

    In, New York: Cambridge University Press. Frieden, Jeffrey A. 1991. Debt, Development, and Democracy: Modern Political Economy and

    Latin America, 1965-1985, Princeton: Princeton University Press. Friedman ?? 1999b. Globalization and Sovereignty, in David A. Smith, Dorothy J. Solinger,

    and Steven C. Topik, eds., States and Sovereignty in the Global Economy, New York: Routledge, ??

    Fukuyama, Francis. 1989. The End of History, The National Interest 16, Summer, 3-18. Gilpin, Robert. War and Change in World Politics, New York: Cambridge University Press,

    1981. Haggard, Stephen. 1990. Pathways from the Periphery: The Politics of Growth in the Newly

    Industrialized Countries. Ithaca: Cornell University Press. Haggard, Stephen. 2000. The Politics of the Asian Financial Crisis. Journal of Democracy April

    (April, 2000): ??

  • Victoria Hui 40

    Helleiner, Eric. 1999. Sovereignty, Territoriality, and the Globalization of Finance, in David A. Smith, Dorothy J. Solinger, and Steven C. Topik, eds., States and Sovereignty in the Global Economy, New York: Routledge, 138-157.

    Hirschman, Albert. 1970. Exit, Voice and Loyalty: Responses to Decline in Firms, Organizations, and States, Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Hirschman, Albert. 1992. Rival Views of Market Society and Other Recent Essays, Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Hobson, John M. 1997. The Wealth of States. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Hobson, John M. 2002. The Two Waves of Weberian Historical Sociology in International

    Relations, in Historical Sociology of International Relations, edited by Stephen Hobden and John M. Hobson, New York: Cambridge University Press, 63-81.

    Huntington, Samuel. 1993. The Clash of Civilizations? Foreign Affairs, Summer, 22-49. Jackson, Robert H., and Carl G. Roseberg. 1982. Why Africas Weak States Persist: The

    Empirical and the Juridical in Statehood, World Politics 35, 1, October, 1-24. Johnson, Chalmers. 1982. MITI and the Japanese Miracle: The Growth of Industrial Policy,

    1925-1975. Stanford: Stanford University Press. Jones, Eric L. 1988 [1981]. The European Miracle: Environments, Economies, and Geopolitics

    in the History of Europe and Asia, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Kaiser, David. 1990. Politics and War: European Conflict from Philip II to Hitler, Cambridge:

    Harvard University Press. Kang, David C. 2002. Bad Loans to Good Friends: Money Politics and the Developmental State

    in South Korea. International Organization 56, 1, Winter, 177-207. Katznelson, Ira. 1992. The State to the Rescue? Political Science and History Reconnect,

    Social Research 59, 4, Winter, 719-737. Kausikan, Bilahari. 1997. Governance That Works. Journal of Democracy 8 Kennedy, Paul. 1987. The Rise and Fall of the Great Powers: Economic Change and Military

    Conflict from 1500 to 2000, New York: Random House. Krasner, Stephen D. 1984. Approaches to the State: Alternative Conceptions and Historical

    Dynamics, Comparative Politics 16, Jan., 223-246. Krasner, Stephen D. 1999a. Sovereignty: Organized Hypocrisy, Princeton: Princeton University

    Press Krasner, Stephen D. 1999b. Globalization and Sovereignty, in David A. Smith, Dorothy J.

    Solinger, and Steven C. Topik, eds., States and Sovereignty in the Global Economy, New York: Routledge, 34-52.

    Kristof, Nicholas D. 2002. The Next Africa? The New York Times, December 10; available at http://query.nytimes.com/search/articlepage.html?res=9E07E2DF173AF933A25751C1A9649C8B63.

    Levi, Margaret 1997. Consent, Dissent, and Patriotism, New York: Cambridge University Press. Levy, Jack. 1983. War in the Modern Great Power System, 1495-1975, Lexington: University

    Press of Kentucky. Mann, Michael. 1988. States, War and Capitalism, Oxford: Blackwell. Mann, Michael. 1999. Has Globalization Ended the Rise and Rise of the Nation State? in T. V.

    Paul and John A. Hall, eds., International Order and the Future of World Politics, New York: Cambridge University Press, 237-261.

    McAdam, Doug, Sidney Tarrow, and Charles Tilly. 2001. Dynamics of Contention, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

  • Victoria Hui 41

    MacIntyre, Andrew. 2001. Institutions and Investors: The Politics of the Economic Crisis in Southeast Asia. International Organization 55, 81-122.

    Migdal, Joel S., Atul Kohli, Vivien Shue, eds. 1994. State Power and Social Forces: Domination and Transformation in the Third World, New York: Cambridge University Press.

    North, Douglass, and Robert Paul Thomas. 1973. The Rise of the Western World: A New Economic History, New York: Cambridge University Press.

    North, Douglass C., and Barry Weingast. 1989. Constitutions and Commitment: The Evolution of Institutions Governing Public Choice in Seventeenth Century England, Journal of Economic History 49, Dec., 803-832.

    Osiander, Andreas. 2001. Sovereignty, International Relations, and the Westphalian Myth, International Organization 55, 2, Spring, 251-287.

    Papayoanou, Paul A. 1996. "Interdependence, Institutions, and the Balance of Power." International Security 20, Spring, 42-76.

    Pempel, T. J., ed. 1999. The Politics of the Asian Economic Crisis. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

    Philpott, Daniel. 2000. The Religious Roots of Modern International Relations, World Politics 52, Jan., 206-245.

    Philpott, Daniel. 2001. Usurping the Sovereignty of Sovereignty? World Politics 53, January, 297-324.

    Plattner, Marc F. 1999. Exploring Globalization. Journal of Democracy 10, 4, 166-170. Pomeranz, Kenneth. 1999. Two Worlds of Trade, Two Worlds of Empire: European State-

    Making and Industrialization in a Chinese Mirror, in David A. Smith, Dorothy J. Solinger, and Steven C. Topik, eds., States and Sovereignty in the Global Economy, New York: Routledge.

    Riley, James C. 1986. The Seven Years War and the Old Regime in France. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Rueschemeyer, Dietrich, ?? Stephens and ?? Stephens. 1992. Capitalist Development and Democracy. Cambridge: Polity Press.

    Ruggie, John G. 1982. International Regimes, Transactions and Change: Embedded Liberalism in the Post-War Economic Order. International Organization 36, 2, Spring, 379-415.

    Ruggie, John G. 1993. Territoriality and Beyond: Problematizing Modernity in International Relations. International Organization 47, 1, Winter, 139-174.

    Schultz, Kenneth A., and Barry R. Weingast. Forthcoming. The Democratic Advantage: Institutional Foundations of Financial Power in International Competition, International Organization.

    Schumpeter, Joseph. 1972 [reprint of 1919]. The Sociology of Imperialisms. New York: Meridian.

    Smith, David A., Dorothy J. Solinger, and Steven C. Topik. 1999. Introduction, in David A. Smith, Dorothy J. Solinger, and Steven C. Topik, eds., States and Sovereignty in the Global Economy, New York: Routledge, 1-19.

    Spruyt, Hendrik. 1994. The Sovereign State and Its Competitors, Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Stiglitz, Joseph 2002. Globalization and Its Discontents, New York: W. W. Norton. Tilly, Charles. 1992 [1990]. Coercion, Capital, and European States, AD 990-1992, Oxford:

    Blackwell.

  • Victoria Hui 42

    Tilly, Charles. 1994. Entanglements of European Cities