125
1 Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU Biofuels Mandate Final Report March 2010 This report has been prepared by: Perrihan Al-Riffai (IFPRI) Betina Dimaranan (IFPRI) David Laborde (IFPRI) ATLASS Consortium Specific Contract No SI2.537.787 implementing Framework Contract No TRADE/07/A2

Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

  • Upload
    phamnhu

  • View
    220

  • Download
    3

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

1

Global Trade and

Environmental Impact Study of the

EU Biofuels Mandate

Final Report

March 2010

This report has been prepared by:

Perrihan Al-Riffai (IFPRI)

Betina Dimaranan (IFPRI)

David Laborde (IFPRI)

ATLASS Consortium

Specific Contract No SI2.537.787

implementing Framework Contract No TRADE/07/A2

Page 2: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

2

DISCLAIMER This study was carried out by the International Food Policy

Institute (IFPRI) for the Directorate General for Trade of the

European Commission. The views expressed in this document

are the authors' and do not necessarily reflect those of the

European Commission or IFPRI.

Page 3: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

3

Table of Contents Executive Summary ............................................................................................................................... 10

1 Introduction................................................................................................................................... 14

2 Review of Recent Studies .............................................................................................................. 17

2.1 Impact on Production, Prices, Trade ..................................................................................... 17

2.2 Modeling Bioenergy .............................................................................................................. 18

2.3 Land Use Modeling................................................................................................................ 21

3 Data and Methodology.................................................................................................................. 27

3.1 Global Data Base ................................................................................................................... 27

3.2 Global Model ......................................................................................................................... 29

3.2.1 Standard MIRAGE Model............................................................................................... 30

3.2.2 Energy Modeling............................................................................................................ 32

3.2.3 Fertilizer modeling......................................................................................................... 33

3.2.4 Modeling of Co-products and Livestock Sectors ........................................................... 34

3.3 Land Use Module................................................................................................................... 36

3.4 GHG Emissions and Marginal ILUC Measurement ................................................................ 37

4 Baseline, Trade Policy Scenarios, and Sensitivity Analysis ............................................................ 39

4.1 Sectoral and Regional Nomenclature.................................................................................... 39

4.2 Baseline Scenario................................................................................................................... 40

4.2.1 Macroeconomic Trends................................................................................................. 40

4.2.2 Technology .................................................................................................................... 41

4.2.3 Trade Policy Assumptions.............................................................................................. 41

4.2.4 Agricultural and Agri-Energy Policies ............................................................................ 43

4.2.5 Other Baseline Evolutions ............................................................................................. 44

4.3 Central and Alternative Trade Policy Scenarios .................................................................... 45

4.4 Sensitivity Analysis Design..................................................................................................... 46

4.4.1 Mandate Policy Targets ................................................................................................. 47

4.4.2 Parameter Uncertainties ............................................................................................... 47

5 Results and Discussion .................................................................................................................. 49

5.1 Production and Trade Impact of Trade Scenarios ................................................................. 49

5.1.1 Biofuel Production and Imports .................................................................................... 50

5.1.2 Agricultural Production ................................................................................................. 52

5.1.3 Fuel and/or Feed? ......................................................................................................... 56

5.2 Land Use Effects .................................................................................................................... 58

5.2.1 Land use......................................................................................................................... 58

5.2.2 Emissions ....................................................................................................................... 61

Page 4: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

4

5.2.3 Crop specific ILUC .......................................................................................................... 64

5.3 Sensitivity Analysis ................................................................................................................ 66

5.3.1 Alternative Mandate Targets ........................................................................................ 66

5.3.2 Land substitution........................................................................................................... 69

5.3.3 Land extension .............................................................................................................. 69

6 Concluding Remarks ...................................................................................................................... 71

6.1 Lessons Learned .................................................................................................................... 71

6.2 Suggestions for Further Research ......................................................................................... 72

7 ANNEXES........................................................................................................................................ 74

8 REFERENCES ................................................................................................................................ 120

LIST of ANNEXES

Annex I. Construction of the Global Biofuels Database ........................................................................ 74

Annex II. Modeling Energy and Agricultural Processes of Production .................................................. 79

Annex III. Final Consumer Energy Demand ........................................................................................... 85

Annex IV. Fertilizer Modeling ................................................................................................................ 87

Annex V. Modeling of Co-Products of Ethanol and Biodiesel ............................................................... 89

Annex VI. Modeling Land Use Expansion .............................................................................................. 91

Annex VII. Measurement of Marginal Indirect Land Use Change ....................................................... 103

Annex VIII: The Role of Technology Pathway...................................................................................... 106

Annex IX: The Role of Land Extension Coefficients ............................................................................. 108

Annex X. Biofuels Policies.................................................................................................................... 109

LIST of TABLES

Table 1 Regional Aggregation................................................................................................................ 39

Table 2. Sectoral Aggregation ............................................................................................................... 40

Table 3 Level and variation of biofuels production (Mio toe and %) .................................................... 50

Table 4. Level and Variation of EU Biofuel Imports, by Origin (Mio toe and %) by 2020...................... 51

Table 5. Main Changes in Crop Production (non EU27) in 2020, 1000t................................................ 53

Table 6. Real Income Impact of European Biofuel Policies, 2020 (Variation / Baseline) ...................... 56

Table 7. Variation of Total Land Used (thousands of km²).................................................................... 60

Table 8 Decomposition of production increase .................................................................................... 61

Table 9. Indirect land use emissions related to biofuels in 2020.......................................................... 62

Table 10 Emissions balance. Annualized figures. CO2 Mto2 eq............................................................ 63

Table 11. Carbon balance sheet ............................................................................................................ 64

Table 12 Marginal Indirect Land Use emissions, gCO2/MJ per annum. 20 years life cycle. ................. 65

Table 13 Marginal Net Emissions by Feedstock. gCO2/Mj. 20 years life cycle. .................................... 66

Table 14 Protein Content of Oil Cakes used for the Modeling.............................................................. 89

Table 15 Energy Content of Feed for Livestock - Metabolizable Energy............................................... 90

Page 5: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

5

Table 16 Share of Land Available for Rainfed Crop Cultivation Computed for the MIRAGE Model (km²)

............................................................................................................................................................... 97

Table 17 Number of cattle head (bovine eq) per square kilometers for main regions ...................... 101

Table 18 Reduction of CO2 associated with different feedstock – Values used in calculations......... 107

Table 19 Land Extension Coefficients.................................................................................................. 108

Table 20 Biofuel Use and Mandates in the European countries (% of energy content)..................... 113

Table 21. Current official targets on share of biofuel in total road-fuel consumption....................... 114

Table 22. Diesel and Biodiesel excise taxes in the European Union ($/liter). ..................................... 115

Table 23. Gasoline and Ethanol excise taxes in the European Union ($/liter). ................................... 115

LIST of FIGURES

Figure 1 Biofuel Feedstock Schematic................................................................................................... 35

Figure 2 EU biodiesel imports by source, Mtoe, in the baseline........................................................... 42

Figure 3 Structure of EU Biofuels Production by Feedstock (2020) ...................................................... 52

Figure 4 Variation of EU Crop Production - 2020 - (volume and percentage) ...................................... 54

Figure 5 Variation of agricultural value-added in 2020 (%) .................................................................. 55

Figure 6 Variation of value-added in livestock sectors in 2020 (%) – MEU_BAU scenario ................... 57

Figure 7 Cropland Extension by Region, 2020, Km2.............................................................................. 59

Figure 8 Source of Cropland Extension by Type of Land....................................................................... 59

Figure 9 Indirect land use emissions and direct savings for different mandate levels, No change in

trade policy............................................................................................................................................ 67

Figure 10 Indirect land use emissions and direct savings for different mandate levels, Free trade

scenario ................................................................................................................................................. 67

Figure 11. Structure of production in the GTAP-E model ..................................................................... 80

Figure 12. Structure of the Capital & Energy Composite in the GTAP-E model .................................... 82

Figure 13. Structure of the Production Process in Agricultural Sectors in the Revised MIRAGE Model83

Figure 14. Demand Structure Adapted for Final Energy Consumption................................................. 85

Figure 15. Possible concave yield functional forms (ymax = 5)............................................................. 88

Figure 16 Land Available for Rainfed Cultivation in Unmanaged Land Area (in km²) ........................... 98

Figure 17. Example of productivity distribution profile for the USA..................................................... 99

Figure 18 Modeling of a Marginal ILUC Shock .................................................................................... 104

Page 6: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

6

LIST of ACRONYMS and ABBREVIATIONS

AEZ Agro-Ecological Zone

Btu British Thermal Unit

CAP Common Agricultural Policy

CARB California Air Resource Board

CEPII Centre d’Etudes Prospectives et d’Informations Internationales

CES Constant Elasticity of Substitution

CET Constant Elasticity of Transformation

CGE Computable General Equilibrium

CIS Commonwealth of Independent States

CO2 Carbon Dioxide

DDA Doha Development Agenda

DDGS Distillers Dried Grains with Solubles

DG Directorate General

EC European Commission

EEA European Environment Agency

EPA Economic Partnership Agreement

EPA (US) Environmental Protection Agency

EU European Union

FAPRI Food and Agricultural Policy Research Institute

FAO Food and Agriculture Organisation of the United Nations

FQD Fuel Quality Directive

GHG Greenhouse Gas

GJ Gigajoule

GTAP Global Trade Analysis Project

HHV High Heating Value

Page 7: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

7

IEA International Energy Agency

IFPRI International Food Policy Research Institute

ILUC Indirect Land Use Change

IMPACT International Model for Policy Analysis of Agricultural Commodities and Trade

IPCC Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change

JRC Joint Research Centre

LCA Life Cycle Analysis

LES Linear Expenditure System

LHV Low Heating Value

MFN Most Favored Nation

MIRAGE Modeling International Relationships in Applied General Equilibrium

MJ Megajoule

MToe Million Tons of Oil Equivalent

N2O Nitrous Oxide

OECD Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development

PE Partial Equilibrium

RED Renewable Energy Directive

RER Renewable Energy Roadmap

RFS Renewable Fuels Standard

SAM Social Accounting Matrix

USA United States of America

Page 8: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

8

UNIT CONVERSION SYSTEM

Ethanol

1 US gallon = 3.78541178 liter

Corn: 1 bushel = .0254 metric ton

Gasoline: US gallon = 115,000 Btu = 121 MJ = 32 MJ/liter (LHV). HHV = 125,000 Btu/gallon = 132

MJ/gallon = 35 MJ/liter

Metric tonne gasoline = 8.53 barrels = 1356 liter = 43.5 GJ/t (LHV); 47.3 GJ/t (HHV)

Metric tonne ethanol = 7.94 petroleum barrels = 1262 liters

Ethanol energy content (LHV) = 11,500 Btu/lb = 75,700 Btu/gallon = 26.7 GJ/t = 21.1 MJ/liter.

Ethanol density (average) = 0.79 g/ml ( = metric tonnes/m3)

Biodiesel

1 m3 de biodiesel = 0,78 tep

Metric tonne biodiesel = 37.8 GJ (33.3 - 35.7 MJ/liter)

Petro-diesel = 130,500 Btu/gallon (34.5 MJ/liter or 42.8 GJ/t)

Petro-diesel density (average) = 0.84 g/ml ( = metric

tonnes/m3)

Vegetable oil density = 0.89 kg/l

Page 9: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

9

Page 10: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

10

Executive Summary

Global demand for biofuels has risen sharply over the last decade, driven initially by oil price hikes

and the need for greater energy security. Support measures were established in many countries in

recognition of the potential of biofuel development in reducing dependence on fossil fuels,

increasing farm revenues, and generating less environmental damage through lower greenhouse gas

(GHG) emissions compared to non-renewable fuel sources. Over the last three years, however,

scepticism about the positive impact of biofuels has escalated as the trade-offs between food, feed,

and fuels and their impact on global agricultural markets became more evident, eventually leading to

the debate over the extent of the role of biofuels in the 2007-08 food price crisis. Furthermore,

several studies have raised serious concerns about the negative environmental impact of the

unintended consequences of biofuel production, particularly the indirect land use change (ILUC)

impact of releasing more carbon emissions as forests and pristine lands are converted to cropland

due to biofuel expansion. This has led to the current debate over whether, and how, the ILUC effects

should be accounted for, along with the direct land use change effects, in evaluating the potential

impact of biofuel policies.

On 23 April 2009, the European Union adopted the Renewable Energy Directive (RED) which included

a 10% target for the use of renewable energy in road transport fuels by 2020. It also established the

environmental sustainability criteria that biofuels consumed in the EU have to comply with. This

includes a minimum rate of direct GHG emission savings (35% in 2009 and rising over time to 50% in

2017) and restrictions on the types of land that may be converted to production of biofuels

feedstock crops. The latter criterion covers direct land use changes only. The revised Fuel Quality

Directive (FQD), adopted at the same time as the RED, includes identical sustainability criteria and

targets a reduction in lifecycle greenhouse gas emissions from fuels consumed in the EU by 6% by

2020. Moreover, the Parliament and Council asked the Commission to examine the question of

indirect land use change (ILUC), including possible measures to avoid this, and report back on this

issue by the end of 2010. In that context, the Commission launched four studies to examine ILUC

issues, including the present study.

The primary objective of this study is to analyse the impact of possible changes in EU biofuels trade

policies on global agricultural production and the environmental performance of the EU biofuel

policy as concretised in the RED. The study pays particular attention to the ILUC effects, and the

associated emissions, of the main feedstocks used for first-generation biofuels production.

This is the only study, out of the four launched by the Commission, that uses a global computable

general equilibrium model (CGE) to estimate the impact of EU biofuels policies, in this case an

Page 11: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

11

extensively modified version of the existing MIRAGE model. Primary among major methodological

innovations introduced in the model is the new modeling of energy demand which allows for

substitutability between different sources of energy, including biofuels. The underlying global Global

Trade Analysis Project (GTAP) database has been extended to separately identify ethanol (with four

subsectors), biodiesel, five additional feedstock crops sectors, four vegetable oils sectors, fertilizers,

and the transport fuel sectors. This extension has been introduced using innovative tools to ensure

the consistency in both value and volume for the sectors of interests. The model was also modified to

account for the co-products generated in the ethanol and biodiesel production processes and their

role as inputs to the livestock sector. Fertilizer modeling was also introduced to allow for substitution

with land under intensive or extensive crop production methods. Finally, another major innovation is

the introduction of a land use module which allows for substitutability between land classes,

classified according to agro-ecological zones (AEZs), and land extension possibilities. We assess the

greenhouse gas emissions (focusing on CO2) associated with direct and indirect land use changes as

generated by the model for the year 2020, and separately quantify the marginal ILUC for each

feedstock crop.

The modelling starts from a baseline scenario that excludes the EU biofuels policies introduced by

the RED. In that baseline, EU biofuels consumption is kept stable between 2009 and 2020, at the

2008 level of a 3.3% share in the mix of biofuels and fossil fuels. This baseline scenario incorporates

the latest forecasts of energy prices by the IEA, and OECD economic growth. It also maintains the EU

anti-dumping levy on biodiesel imports from the US. The baseline takes into account the biofuels

mandates in other economies but we have limited this to a conservative case (5% mandates for

China, Canada, Japan, Australia, New Zealand, Switzerland, Indonesia and Indonesia).

We then introduce a first-generation land-using biofuels share of 5.6% in the overall EU renewable

energy target of 10% for road transport fuels (by 2020) in a central policy scenario, and calculate the

impact of this policy measure on agricultural production, trade, incomes and carbon emissions. The

5.6% figure is obtained by deducting the expected share in 2020 of other renewable road transport

fuels from the 10% target. We also examine the impact of a change in the EU biofuels trade policy

regime, with an elimination of import tariffs, in a full multilateral scenario and in a bilateral scenario

(with the MERCOSUR countries only). Finally, sensitivity analyses are conducted to assess the

robustness of the model results to alternative assumptions about the size of the EU biofuels policy

target and on several parameter settings.

The central policy scenario translates the 5.6% first-generation biofuels mix in road transport fuels in

2020 into an increase in biofuels consumption in the EU by 17.8 Mtoe. The required increase in

biodiesel production is mostly domestic in the EU while the increase in bioethanol production is

Page 12: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

12

mostly concentrated in Brazil. It implies a considerable increase in EU imports of bioethanol, despite

the duties. Brazil's real income increase marginally (+0.06%), and even less so for the EU; all other

regions lose marginally. World cropland increases by 0.07%, showing that there is indeed indirect

land use change associated with the EU biofuels mandate. Direct emission savings from biofuels are

estimated at 18 Mt CO2, additional emissions from ILUC at 5.3 Mt CO2 (mostly in Brazil), resulting in

a global net balance of nearly 13 Mt CO2 savings in a 20 years horizon.

The multilateral and the bilateral trade liberalization scenarios show very similar results, primarily

because Brazil is the main beneficiary in both scenarios. Trade opening is beneficial for the

environment. Elimination of tariffs on biofuels imports, especially for bioethanol, leads to slightly

higher ILUC effects because of land extension outside the EU, especially in Brazil. But direct emissions

are reduced because production and consumption moves towards a more emission-efficient biofuel

(sugar cane ethanol from Brazil). The emissions saving rate is improved and the overall emission

balance is positive in terms of CO2 reduction (between 43 and 47 gCO2 saved by MJ of biofuels). This

effect is based on the assumption that the share of ethanol in EU biofuel consumption can increase

from 19% to the maximum level of 45% by 2020.

The model simulations show that the effect of EU biofuels policies on food prices will remain very

limited, with a maximum price change on the food bundle of +0.5% in Brazil and +0.14% in Europe.

The EU biofuels policy also has no significant real income consequences for the EU, though some

countries may experience a slight decline in real income: -0.11% to -0.18% by 2020 among oil

exporters, and -0.12% for Sub-Saharan Africa, due to a decline in fossil oil prices and a rise in food

prices, respectively.

Analysis of ILUC effects by crop indicates that ethanol, and particularly sugar-based ethanol, will

generate the highest potential gains in terms of net emission savings. For biodiesel, palm oil remains

as efficient as rapeseed oil, even if peatland emissions are taken into account. The model also

indicates that the ILUC emission coefficients could increase with the size of the EU mandate.

Simulations for EU biofuels consumption above 5.6% of road transport fuels show that ILUC

emissions can rapidly increase and erode the environmental sustainability of biofuels.

There are important uncertainties with respect to a number of behavioral parameters in the model.

Still, the main conclusions of the study remain robust with respect to the sensitivity analyses

performed. Yield response and land elasticities play a critical role in the assessment. We have also

confirmed the importance of having a high quality database that links the value and the quantity

matrix to feed the model with technically relevant marginal rates of substitution. .

Page 13: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

13

We conclude by emphasizing critical areas for further research to improve the evidence base for

policy makers.

It is important to investigate the assumptions regarding the 45%/55% ratio between biodiesel and

bioethanol that we use in this study (as a function of vehicle fleet composition) since this strongly

influences the results. It pushes biofuel demand towards bioethanol, where sugar ethanol provides

important net emissions savings and accounts for the strong benefits from trade liberalization..

There is also a critical need to improve the overall quality of data for the EU27 SAM. Considerable

effort was spent on correcting some inconsistencies and updating the GTAP7 database. However, the

quality of the original EU social accounting matrix in the GTAP7 database is poor. Moving to the

latest GTAP7.1 database (released in mid-February 2010) that includes updated EU SAMs could

improve the analysis.

Finally, considerable uncertainty remains regarding the impact of the sustainability criteria on

biofuels markets. The role of certification and the emergence of differentiation in biofuels, feedstock

crops and land prices, based on carbon content and the respect of sustainability criteria, require

more empirical research. More research on the situation and likely evolution of the share of

different production pathways could reduce uncertainties regarding direct emission savings. It would

help to get a better understanding of the actual impact of the sustainability criteria in the EU RED on

emissions and the market for biofuels.

Page 14: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

14

1 Introduction

Global demand for biofuels has risen sharply over the last decade, driven initially by oil price hikes

and the need for greater energy security. Support measures were established in many countries in

recognition of the potential of biofuel development in reducing dependence on fossil fuels,

increasing farm revenues, and generating less environmental damage through lower greenhouse gas

(GHG) emissions compared to non-renewable fuel sources. Over the last three years, however,

scepticism about the positive impact of first-generation biofuels has escalated as the trade-offs

between food, feed, and fuels and their impact on global agricultural markets became more evident,

eventually leading to the debate over the extent of the role of biofuels in the 2007-08 food price

crisis. Furthermore, several studies (e.g. Fargione et al, 2008; Searchinger et al., 2008; RFA, 2008)

have raised serious concerns about the negative environmental impact of the unintended

consequences of first-generation biofuels that are based on feedstock fit for human food

consumption and compete for land use with food crops. The indirect land use change (ILUC) impact

of these biofuel feedstocks could release more carbon emissions as forests and pristine lands are

converted to cropland due to biofuel expansion. This has led to the current debate over whether,

and how, the ILUC effects should be accounted for, along with the direct land use change effects, in

evaluating the potential impact of biofuel policies.

The adoption of targets for the use of biofuels in road transport fuels is a key component of the

European Union's response to achieving its Kyoto targets of GHG emissions. In 2003 the European

Union first set a target of 5.75% biofuels use in all road transport fuels by the end of 2010. The

proposal to adopt a 10% target for a combination of first and second generation biofuels use in road

transport fuels by 2020 was made in the Renewable Energy Roadmap (CEC, 2006) as part of an

overall binding target for renewable energy to represent 20% of the total EU energy mix by the same

date. On 23 April 2009, the European Union adopted the Renewable Energy Directive (RED) which

includes a 10% binding target for renewable energy use in road transport fuels and also establishes

the environmental sustainability criteria for biofuels consumed in the EU (CEC, 2008). A minimum

rate of GHG emission savings (35% in 2009 and rising over time to 50% in 2017), rules for calculating

GHG impact, and restrictions on land where biofuels may be grown are part of the environmental

sustainability scheme that biofuel production must adhere to under the RED. The revised Fuel Quality

Directive (FQD), adopted at the same time as the RED, includes identical sustainability criteria and it

targets a reduction in lifecycle greenhouse gas emissions from fuels consumed in the EU by 6% by

2020. The adoption of the RED includes a requirement for the Commission to report, by 31

December 2010, on the impact of ILUC on GHG emissions and address ways to minimize that impact.

Page 15: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

15

It is against this background that this study seeks to clarify the interactions between different policy

scenarios and their potential impact on global agricultural markets and on the environment,

particularly on GHG emissions from direct and indirect land use change.

This study was commissioned by the Directorate General for Trade of the European Commission (DG

TRADE). The initial objective was to examine the potential economic and environmental impact of

various EU trade policy options with respect to biofuels. However, the model developed for this

purpose was also a very useful contribution to the Commission's impact assessment and report on

ILUC and to possible Commission proposals on the methodology to deal with ILUC under biofuel

production. The objective of the study was thus expanded to analyse the global agricultural

production, trade and environmental impact of the EU biofuel policy as concretised in the RED. The

study pays particular attention to the ILUC effects of the main biofuel feedstocks.

This quantitative analysis of the global economic and environmental impact of biofuel development

is conducted using an extensively modified version of the MIRAGE global computable general

equilibrium model (CGE)1. Primary among major methodological innovations introduced in the model

is the new modeling of energy demand which allows for substitutability between different sources of

energy, including biofuels. This is facilitated by the extension of the underlying global Global Trade

Analysis Project (GTAP) database which separately identifies ethanol with four subsectors, biodiesel,

five additional feedstock crops sectors, four vegetable oils sectors, fertilizers, and the transport fuel

sectors. The model was also modified to account for the co-products generated in the ethanol and

biodiesel production processes and their role as inputs to the livestock sector. Fertilizer modeling

was also introduced to allow for substitution with land under intensive or extensive crop production

methods. Finally, another major innovation is the introduction of a land use module which allows for

substitution between land classes, classified according to Agro-Ecological Zones (AEZs), and land

extension possibilities. We assess the greenhouse gas emissions (focusing on CO2) associated with

direct and indirect land use changes as generated by the model for the year 2020, and separately

quantify the marginal ILUC for each feedstock crop.

The impact of the EU biofuels policy are assessed under alternative trade policy assumptions:

business as usual trade policy; full multilateral trade liberalization in biofuels; and bilateral trade

liberalization between the EU and MERCOSUR. These trade policy alternatives are calculated against

a baseline scenario which incorporates the latest forecasts of energy prices by the IEA and OECD 1 The MIRAGE (Modeling International Relationships in Applied General Equilibrium) model was developed at

the Centre d’Etudes Prospectives et d’Informations Internationales (CEPII). Documentation of the standard

model is available in Bchir et al. (2002) and Decreux and Valin (2007). Model equations for the extensively

modified version developed at IFPRI and used in this study are provided in a separate document as Appendix A.

Page 16: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

16

economic growth. Sensitivity analyses are conducted to assess the robustness of the model results to

alternative assumptions about the size of the EU biofuels policy target, and on several parameter

settings.

A brief review of previous studies that have quantified the potential economic and environmental

impact of biofuel development is provided in the next section of the report. Section 3 includes an

overview of the data development and model development involved in the study. More detailed

discussions of the various components of the methodology are relegated to annexes. The baseline

scenario and alternative trade policy scenarios analyzed in the study, along with the variations

considered for sensitivity analyses, are presented in Section 4. Results and discussions are provided

in Section 5 and concluding remarks are given in Section 6.

Page 17: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

17

2 Review of Recent Studies Although it is a relatively new area of study, research on the impact of policies to promote biofuels

has been particularly intense in recent years. The growing literature reflects the evolution of issues

regarding the impact of biofuel development and support policies on agricultural markets and the

environment. Most quantitative assessments focused initially on the impact of biofuels on

agricultural markets and its contribution to the food price crisis, but more recent studies have

centered on the impact of biofuels on global land use change and greenhouse gas emissions. In this

section of the report, we provide a brief survey of recent studies focusing on the quantitative

assessments of the impact of biofuel support policies on global trade and the environment,

specifically on land use and GHG emissions.

2.1 Impact on Production, Prices, Trade

Much of the early literature on biofuels came out in the mid 2000s and emphasized the potential

benefits of biofuels development in reducing dependence of fossil fuels, providing opportunities for

agricultural and rural development, and reducing environmental damage due to lower greenhouse

gas emissions compared to biofuels. However, concerns about the impact on food security quickly

emerged due to the rising competition between biofuel feedstock crops, food crops, and feed crops,

thereby giving rise to the debate on food versus fuel.

In their review of early work on the economic, environmental, and policy aspects of biofuels,

Rajagopal and Zilberman (2007) found that the current generation of biofuels from food crops is

intensive in land, water, energy and chemical inputs. The authors' synthesis of economic studies

revealed that most models predict that biofuels development will result in higher food prices, a

decline in cereal exports of the United States and European Union, a decline in farm support

programs, an increase in rural jobs, and an ambiguous effect on the livestock sector.

The impact of biofuels on food prices became a hotly debated issue during the food price crisis of

2008. Several researchers sought to quantify the impact of biofuel polices on food prices. Studies

range from back of the envelope calculations, such as those from the JRC (de Santi, 2008) and the

World Bank (Mitchell, 2008) to extensive modeling exercises. In assigning the largest proportion of

the blame on biofuels, Mitchell (2008) concluded that higher energy costs and exchange rate changes

contributed between 25-30% of the rise in food prices, while the other 70-75% was due to biofuels

along with the associated low grain stocks, large land use shifts, speculative activity and export bans.

Although results vary, there is broad agreement from these studies that the price increases are due

to several factors including but by no means restricted to biofuels (Sheeran, 2008, Von Braun, 2008).

Page 18: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

18

In a partial equilibrium exercise using IFPRI's IMPACT model, Rosegrant (2008) also addressed the

question of the extent to which biofuel production contributed to the high food prices in 2008. Based

on a comparison of the simulations of market developments between 2000-2007, with and without

the sudden increase in biofuel production, Rosegrant estimated that biofuel growth accounted for

30% of the food price increases seen in the period. The level varied from 39% for maize to 21% for

rice. A simulation of the future impact of freezing biofuel production at 2007 levels indicated that

maize prices are likely to decline by 6% in 2020 and 14% in 2015.

Based on their review of 25 studies, Abbott et al. (2008) identified three broad sets of forces that

drove up food prices in 2008, namely: the global changes in production and consumption of key

commodities, the depreciation of the dollar, and the growth in the production of biofuels. Even in

their follow-up study after the financial crisis, Abbott et al (2009) found that the key drivers of food

prices remain the same: crop supply and utilization, the exchange rate and world macroeconomic

factors and the agricultural-energy linkage through the biofuels market.

Similarly, in their synthesis of several studies that assessed the impact of biofuels development on

current and projected food prices, Gerber et al. (2009) found that although there are considerable

differences in the methodology and assumptions, and thus in the projection results, the studies

predict some common trends: the EU and US biofuel programs are expected to raise prices of

vegetable oils the most with smaller price increases for corn, wheat and soybean and price declines

for oilseed meals.

2.2 Modeling Bioenergy

The economic studies that assess the impact of biofuel production are based either on partial

equilibrium (PE) or computable general equilibrium (CGE) models. These models explain the

relationship between supply, demand, and prices through market clearance using a system of

equilibrium equations. In partial equilibrium models, clearance in the market of a specific good or

sector is obtained assuming that prices and quantities in other markets remain constant, thus

providing better indication of short term response to shocks. PE models often provide a detailed

description of the specific sector of interest but do not account for the impact of expansion in that

sector on other sectors of the economy. Several examples of partial equilibrium models used in the

assessment of the impact of biofuel development include AGLINK/COSIMO, ESIM, FAPRI, and the

IMPACT model. Witzke et al. (2008) provide a review of the methodologies in modeling energy crops

in agricultural sector PE models.

Page 19: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

19

CGE models determine equilibrium by simultaneously taking into account the linkages between all

sectors in the economy. The modeling framework provides an understanding of the impact of

biofuels on the overall economy by accounting for all the feedback mechanisms between biofuels

and other markets, and by capturing factor market impact. As the Gallagher review (RFA, 2008)

points out, CGE models provide a better global assessment, taking linkages in the economy into

account and predicting outcomes that are more representative of medium and long term impact.

Since the present employs a global CGE model, this section focuses on a review of bioenergy

modeling in CGE models.

Kretschmer et al. (2008) classified CGE studies according to three different categories based on the

approach used in integrating bioenergy in CGE models. The implicit approach avoids explicit

modeling of bioenergy production technology and employs an ad-hoc procedure of determining the

quantities of biomass necessary to achieve certain production targets. Classified under this category

is the study of the economy-wide effects of replacing petroleum with biomass in the US using (Dixon

et al. 2007)USAGE, a dynamic CGE model of the US economy. Banse et el. (2008) also used a implicit

approach in introducing biofuels in their extended version of the GTAP-E CGE model. Ethanol is

introduced in a ‘Fuel’ nesting, substituting with vegetable oil, oil, and petroleum products. It is

produced only from crop inputs (sugarcane\beet and cereals) thereby capturing only a part of

ethanol production technology.

The second category identified by Kretschmer et al. (2008) is the latent technology approach that

focuses on production technologies that are existent but not active during the base year of the

model but can become active at a later stage. Information on the inputs and costs structures of the

different types of biofuels are required in modeling latent technologies. Reilly and Paltsev (2007) and

Gurgel, Reilly and Paltsev et al. (2007) employed this approach in looking at the potential land use

implications of a global biofuels development focusing on second generation biofuels . Boeters et al.

(2008) and Kretschmer et al. (2008) both incorporate the European emissions trading scheme (ETS) in

assessing the impact of a 10 percent EU biofuels target.

This study falls under the third category of CGE biofuel studies identified by Kretschmer et al. (2008)

which are studies that actually disaggregate the bioenergy production sectors in the social

accounting matrix (SAM) of the GTAP database, which provides the underlying structure to global

CGE models. Since bioenergy sectors are not explicitly identified in the GTAP database, Taheripour et

al. (2007) introduced ethanol (from aggregated coarse grains and sugarcane) and biodiesel from an

aggregated oilseeds sector. External data on production, cost structure and trade are used to extract

these bioenergy sectors from existing food processing sectors in the 2001 GTAP 6 database.

Bioenergy is modeled through an extended version of the GTAP-E model (Burniaux and Truong,

Page 20: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

20

2002). The applications of this approach include Birur, Hertel, and Tyner (2008) looking at the impact

of biofuels production on the global agricultural market; Hertel, Tyner, and Birur (2008) looking at

the impact of both US and EU biofuel support policies; and Taheripour et al. (2008) which compares

the impact of adding by-products to the results of Hertel et al (2008).

In a recent study, Britz and Hertel (2009) linked the European CAPRI PE model with the GTAP CGE

model to look at the impact of the EU biofuels directive on global markets and on the environment.

Starting from a modified GTAP model that includes a ‘parsimonious summary’ of the regional supply

models of CAPRI, the authors then take the resulting equilibrium price changes from the global

model and apply them to the supply models of CAPRI to obtain highly disaggregated results in terms

of changes in farming practice and their impact in the EU.

The production of biofuels results in several by-products which have potential or existing markets.

Producing ethanol from corn results in a by-product – Dried Distillers Grains with Solubles (DDGS)

which is used as animal feed. Its sale represents 16% of ethanol revenues in the US (Hertel et al.,

2008). Biodiesel production from vegetable oil produces seed meals which can be used as animal

feed. Farrell et al. (2006) pointed out the importance of integrating by-products in assessments of

the energy balance of biofuels. In particular they found that studies which didn’t take by-products

into account concluded that biofuels had a negative energy balance because they failed to take

account of the energy use which the by-products offset.

The increased availability of by-products also have beneficial side effects in other areas of

agriculture. The Commission’s impact assessment of the biofuels mandate pointed out the positive

impact on livestock production in terms of reduced prices for animal feed, with soymeal prices

predicted to fall by 25% and rapemeal by 40% by 2020 (CEC, 2007). In a CGE assessment of the

impact of including biofuel by-products, Taheripour et al. (2008) also found significant differences in

feedstock output and prices depending on whether the existence of by-products is taken into

account. In terms on the land use impact of accounting for by-products, Kampman et al (2008)

estimated that incorporating by-products into the calculations for land requirements of biofuels

reduced the land demand by 10-25%. Croezen and Brouwer (2008) found that scenarios which

include 2G biofuels resulted in substantial reductions of almost half in the amount of avoided land

use. It is clear that the integration of by-products is key to properly estimating changes in prices and

land use, as well as energy balance.

Page 21: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

21

2.3 Land Use Modeling

Although extensive research and literature exists about local drivers of land use changes concerning

deforestation processes, arable land conversion, pasture expansion, and the associated

methodological challenges and development of land-use indicators, the boom in biofuel production

is a recent phenomenon and as such has not yet been included as a factor driving land-use change

(Gnansounou and Panichelli , 2008).

It is clear however, that increased demand for biofuels will have impact on the demand for land and

will result in potentially significant land use changes. The increased demand for land for biofuels is

estimated to be lower than the increased demand for land for food, however estimates vary. Based

on their review of the literature, Kampman et al. (2008) estimated that land for food and feed will

expand between 200-500 Mha by 2020, whereas increased demand for biofuels could result in total

demand of between 73-276 Mha (up from 13.8 Mha today). Eickhout et al. (2008) estimated the land

requirements of the EU’s mandate alone as being between 20-30 Mha. There are high levels of

uncertainty in these estimates as much depends on development of demand, but also on the extent

to which high yield crops (such as sugar cane) are used, the share of second generation biofuels (land

demand is 30-40% less in scenarios with 2G biofuels) and on crop yield. The FAO reported estimates

of the difference between the land required for different sources of first generation biofuels if they

were to replace 25% of global transport needs. This varies from 17% of available land (estimated at

2.5 bn ha) if the source were sugar cane to 200% for soybean (FAO, 2008a).

Many CGE models use the constant elasticity of transformation (CET) approach to capture the

conversion of land to other uses due to the expansion of bioenergy production. Under the CET,

different types of land can be transformed to other uses with the ease of transformation determined

by the elasticity of transformation. Using the WorldScan CGE model to assess the impact of the 10%

EU biofuels target, Boeters et al. (2008) used the CET framework to allow for transformation of

different types of arable land use. The authors assess the sensitivity of the elasticity value of the CET

by allowing for lower and higher-end values of 0.5 and 15, respectively, aside from the default value

of 2. They found that their results for arable land rents and economic welfare are quite robust to the

value to the CET.

Banse et al. (2008) also used the CET approach but employed a 3-level CET nesting structure that

allows for different degrees of land use transformation across types of land use. The third level nest

distinguishes between land in wheat, coarse grains, and oilseeds. This aggregate is distinguished from

land in sugar and pasture in the second level nest. Together, as Field Crops\Pasture, they are

Page 22: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

22

distinguished from Horticulture and Other Crops at the top-level nest. The authors also introduced a

land supply curve which allows for endogenous processes of land conversion and land abandonment.

In their analysis of the impact of implementing biofuels mandate on a global scale, the authors found

that compared to a reference scenario of trade liberalization, the EU’s land use falls by less under

both an EU and global biofuel scenario. All other key regions expand land use under a global biofuels

scenario, in particular Central and South America which increases agricultural land use by almost 10

percentage points compared to the reference scenario. The study also shows, however, that the

majority of the expansion in land use in most regions is due to the liberalization of trade and other

projected changes in the world economy. These are modeled under the reference scenario, where

global agricultural land increases by18% compared to 21% under the global biofuels scenario.

Although biofuels contributes to greater land cultivation it is not, therefore, projected to be the

major driver.

Birur et al. (2008), Hertel et al. (2008) and Taheripour et al. (2008) also employ the CET approach.

These studies use a GTAP-E model adapted to include Agro-Ecological Zones (AEZs). In other words

they take account of the fact that land types differ and substitutability is only possible within limited

zones. Hertel et al. (2008) find substantial impact on land use from the EU and US mandates. In the

US, coarse grains acreage increases by 10% at the expense of other cropland, as well as pasture land

and forests. The biggest global impact are however seen as a result of the boom in oilseeds

production due to EU demand for biodiesel. Here increases range from 11-16% in Latin America, 14%

in SE Asia and Africa and 40% in the EU itself. The model restricts the potential land sources of

increased biomass production to pastureland or forests as it does not take into account idle land.

This tends to over-estimate the impact. The largest impact are for pastureland in Brazil where the

acreage is estimated to reduce by 11%, of which 8% is due to the EU mandate. Reductions in forestry

cover are highest for the EU (-7%), Canada (-6%) and Africa (-3%). The model (like that used in this

study) does not take account of the potential impact of biofuel by-products which the authors

acknowledge to be an important limitation which overestimates the impact of the mandates on corn

and livestock markets. Greenhouse Gas Emissions (ILUC)

A major reason behind the adoption of biofuels is based on the assumption that they are a more

environmentally friendly fuel source, as the GHG emissions associated with their production and use

are lower than those associated with traditional fossil fuels. This assumption is not based on the

GHGs impact from the use of biofuels, as the GHGs emitted from burning them are not noticeably

different to those of other fuels. There is a reduction in certain pollutants, with a possible increase in

others (Worldwatch Institute, 2006). Rather their advantage over fossil fuels is based on the idea that

the production of biofuels absorbs CO2 and therefore offsets large percentages of the future

emissions from using them.

Page 23: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

23

This assumption is far from being universally accepted. Early estimates from the International Energy

Agency indicated that the use of biofuels resulted in net GHG savings – between 20-90% for ethanol

from crops (with most crops in the lower levels. The higher figures are for cellulosic ethanol) and

around 50% for biodiesel from oilseeds (IEA, 2004).

Although the logic for these figures is intuitively attractive, several researchers have pointed out that

such estimates are incomplete as several aspects of the lifecycle and indirect effects of biofuels are

not properly taken into account. Even early, positive analysis of biofuels’ potential, such as that from

the Worldwatch Institute warned that there were limits to its potential benefits. In particular,

biofuels that are produced from low yielding crops, or grown on previous forested or grasslands or

produced using large inputs of fossil fuel, could easily have a negative GHG balance (Worldwatch

Institute, 2006). The fact that biofuel’s GHG balance varies widely depending on these factors is

increasingly taken into account in analyses.

A recent review conducted by the US Government Accounting Office (US GAO, 2009) found that

although there is general consensus on the approach for measuring the direct effects of increased

biofuels production, there is disagreement about assumptions and assessment methods for

estimating the indirect effects of global land-use change. The twelve scientific studies that the GAO

reviewed provided a wide range of estimates on the lifecycle GHG emissions of biofuels relative to

fossil fuels: from a 59 percent reduction to a 93% increase in emissions for conventional corn starch

ethanol, a 113% reduction to a 50 % increase for cellulosic ethanol, and a 41% to 95% reduction for

biodiesel. The differences in assumptions about the agricultural and energy inputs used in biofuel

production and how to allocate the energy used in this production to co-products, such as DDGS,

primarily explain why large differences in the GHG emission estimates among the studies.

One key issue is that producing biofuels requires energy and the assumptions on where that energy

comes from can make a large difference to the calculated relative efficiency of different biofuel

sources. Mortimer et al. (2008) note the large difference between the CO2 emissions in the

production of corn based ethanol in the US and France (0.108 kg eq/MJ compared to 0.049 kg eq/MJ

respectively), which is largely due to the assumption that coal is used for ethanol processing in the

US compared to natural gas in France. Biofuels that use plant waste to fuel their processing, such as

those based on switchgrass and sugarcane are clearly the most efficient.

In their research for the Gallagher Review, Mortimer et al. (2008) provide estimates of the

percentage of GHGs emissions by various sources of biofuels compared to standard fossil fuels. Their

results are fairly consistent with other sources in highlighting the relative efficiency of Brazilian sugar

Page 24: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

24

cane (which generally uses bagasse as the fuel source) and the relative inefficiency of maize which

the study found to be more intensive in GHG emissions than the fuels it seeks to replace.

The above results take into account the ‘credit’ represented by the by-products of the various

processes and the N2O emissions from the soil where the crops are grown. This latter issue is one of

the most contentious and difficult to integrate in relation to the biofuels debate. N2O is a

greenhouse gas which is far more detrimental to global warming than CO2 (296 times according to

Mortimer at al (2008)). For this reason, although emissions are far lower by weight than CO2, they

are potentially very damaging.

A key input to the debate on NO2 emissions and biofuels is a paper by Crutzen et al. (2007). This

paper claims that the manner in which the UN’s Inter-governmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC)

integrates N2O emissions into its assessments underestimates N2O emissions from crops by a factor

of 3 to 5. The paper has been criticized and its accuracy called into question. Mortimer et al. (2008)

have undertaken an exhaustive review of the paper and conclude that while it raises an important

issue ‘…it cannot be regarded as resolving the problems and assisting the objective evaluation of

biofuels.’ (Mortimer et al, 2008, p. 29). For the moment, as their review makes clear, it is impossible

to accurately measure the extent of N2O emissions related to a given biofuel from a given source.

For this reason and due to the complexities of seeking to integrate it in the model, this research does

not seek to assess the indirect effects, related to land use, of biofuels on GHGs other than CO2. But

direct effects related to CO2 and N2O are accounted for as they are incorporated in the coefficients.

The other key issue which has emerged as controversial in recent months is the question of the

‘credit’ attributable to biofuels from the ‘carbon uptake’ of the crops used to produce them. A key

paper in this debate is that by Searchinger et al. (2008). His main point is that earlier assessments of

the carbon impact of biofuels have been biased because they have not taken account of the land use

impact. In short they have counted the carbon benefits of using land for biofuels but not the carbon

costs – the carbon storage and sequestration which is sacrificed when the land is diverted from its

former use (direct GHG effects) or when land is cleared for growing food to replace land which has

been diverted into biofuel production (indirect GHG effects). Searchinger et al. (2008) used the

Greenhouse gases, Regulated Emission and Energy use in Transportation (GREET) model to calculate

the total GHG emissions from various biofuel sources. The model indicates that, without taking into

account land use changes, replacing gasoline by corn-based ethanol reduces GHG emissions by 20%

by 2015. Once they account for land use change, however, the picture changes significantly and they

find that corn based ethanol more than doubles GHG emissions over a 30 year timescale and

increases GHGs for 167 years. On the other end of the spectrum, Brazilian sugarcane production is

estimated by their model to provide GHG savings of 86%. If this sugarcane production converts only

Page 25: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

25

tropical grassland, the payback for GHG emissions would be only 4 years, although this would rise to

45 years if displaced ranches were to convert forest to grazing land.

In their review of the Searchinger paper and the GREET model to assess its applicability to the EU/UK

context, Mortimer et al. (2008) concluded that the model is too US specific to be readily useable

outside that context. The US Department of Energy has itself issued a rebuke criticizing many aspects

of the study, which it considers to also misrepresent the US case, by overestimating corn ethanol

production and making several invalid assumptions (DOE, 2008). Nevertheless the key point which

Searchinger makes – that land use changes and their impact on GHG emissions are key to assessing

the true impact of biofuels - is a valid one which needs to be taken into account in analysis. The

Gallagher review acknowledges this, particularly in its recommendation that policies should seek to

direct biofuels production towards suitable idle land or appropriate wastes and non-food products.

This recommendation is based on a series of calculations on the net impact of the conversion of

various types of land on GHG emissions which concur with the broad conclusions of Searchinger’s

paper (Mortimer et al., 2008). The analysis finds that, apart from the lowest estimate of ethanol from

sugar beet, all current biofuel production on converted UK grasslands would increase GHG emissions,

in some cases emitting twice the level of fossil fuels. The figures calculated for biofuels from overseas

sources are even worse. Of all sources analysed - oil palm in Malaysia, soy biodiesel in Brazil, maize

ethanol in the US and sugar cane ethanol in Brazil - only the latter showed a net saving and the

others showed large net losses, topping 30,000% for biodiesel from soy converted from Brazilian

rainforest.

The calculation for the impact of using fallow land is slightly different, as it assumes that the N2O

emissions which would have been emitted by this land are avoided by its cultivation, thus adding an

additional ‘credit’ to the calculation. The results are generally positive i.e. the production of biofuels

in the UK from fallow land is calculated to emit less GHG than fossil fuels, although the percentage

varies from 88-55%. The figures are similar for biodiesel and ethanol, although they tend to be lower

for the former, especially in the long term and when rotational set-aside land is used.

The JRC report also looked at the issue of land use change and its impact on GHG emissions (de Santi,

2008). They made the point that looking at direct effects alone was probably legitimate when rates of

substitution by biofuel were low and most biofuel feedstock could come from set-aside or other

unused arable land. However the 10% target means that most of the EU biofuel feedstock will be

removed from the world commodity markets either by reduced EU exports or increased EU imports.

They looked at the alternative sources of these extra biofuels and in most cases found significant

negative effects. For example using EU permanent grassland would result in an initial emission of

Page 26: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

26

carbon which would take 20 to 110 (+/- 50%) years to recover through biofuel production. The

carbon losses from drained peat forest, which is used for palm oil production in South East Asia, are

so high that if even 2.4% of the EU’s biodiesel needs are met directly or indirectly by palm oil grown

in peatland all GHG savings from EU biodiesel would be cancelled out. Palm oil is a key alternative to

rapeseed for the food industry, so EU imports are likely to increase once the latter is diverted to

biofuel production. The calculations in the report indicate that the level of EU imports of palm oil

produced on peatland is likely to be considerably higher than 2.4%. Although local regulations could

be set in place to avoid such negative indirect effects, the report is dubious about the potential of

certification schemes to assure sustainability. The report concludes ‘Indirect land use change could

potentially release enough greenhouse gas to negate the savings from conventional EU biofuels.’ (De

Santi, 2008).

Finally a key question which is frequently ignored in the biofuels debate is whether the use of

biomass for biofuels is the most efficient means to use the limited biomass resources at our disposal

to reduce GHGs. A recent JRC report pointed out that while the efficiency of fuel burners for heating

and electricity is 21 almost as high as that of fossil fuels, the energy efficiency of converting biomass

to liquid fuels is only 30-40% (de Santi, 2008). Their cost benefit analysis indicates that the decision

to specifically target GHG reductions in the transport sector reduces the benefits that could be

achieved in other ways. The European Environment Agency has furthermore expressed concern that

diversion of biomass to biofuel will make it difficult for the EU to meet its objectives for renewable

energy sources in energy production (EEA, 2004).

A related point is that support for biofuels is a very expensive means of reducing CO2 emissions. The

OECD has estimated that policy support to biofuels would cost taxpayers and consumers between

$960 and $1 700 per ton of CO2 emissions avoided (OECD, 2008). The exact figures can be debated

as they are based on a series of assumptions and indeed are far higher than the figures used in the

Commission’s impact assessment of the Renewable Energy Directive5 or even the high end estimates

(over €300/ton) referred to in the Economic and Social Committee’s report (EESC, 2008). However

the fundamental point of the OECD work – that reducing CO2 emissions through measures in support

of biofuel production is an expensive option – is a valid one, reiterated both in that report (EESC,

2008) and in the work of the JRC (2007).

Page 27: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

27

3 Data and Methodology

The MIRAGE model2, a computable general equilibrium model originally developed at CEPII for trade

policy analysis, was extensively modified at IFPRI3 in order to address the potential economic and

environmental impact of biofuels policies. The key adaptations to the standard model are the

integration of two main biofuels sectors (ethanol and biodiesel) and biofuel feedstock sectors,

improved modeling of the energy sector, the modeling of co-products and the modeling of fertilizer

use. The land use module which includes the decomposition of land into different land uses, and the

quantification of the environmental impact of direct and indirect land use change (ILUC), was

introduced in the model at the Agro-Ecological Zone (AEZ) level, allowing for infra-national modeling.

The latter feature is particularly valuable for large countries where production patterns and land

availability are quite heterogeneous. The overall architecture of the model has been modified to

allow for various sensitivity analyses, as well as for the computation of marginal ILUC under specific

assumptions. The full set of model equations are provided in a separate document as Appendix A.

Data enhancements, model modifications, and the land use module are discussed in this section of

the report.

3.1 Global Data Base The MIRAGE model relies on the Global Trade Analysis Project (GTAP) database for global, economy-

wide data. The GTAP database combines domestic input-output matrices which provide details on

the intersectoral linkages within each region, and international datasets on macroeconomic

aggregates, bilateral trade, protection, and energy. We started from the latest available database,

GTAP 7, which describes global economic activity for the 2004 reference year in an aggregation of

113 regions and 57 sectors (Narayanan and Walmsley, 2008). The database was then modified to

accommodate the sectoral changes made to the MIRAGE model.

Twenty-three new sectors were carved out of the GTAP sector aggregates -- the liquid biofuels

sectors (an ethanol sector with four feed-stock specific sectors, and a biodiesel sector), major

feedstock sectors (maize, rapeseed, soybeans, sunflower, palm fruit and the related oils), co- and by-

2 Decreux and Valin (2007).

3 The development of the model for this study was undertaken by a joint team of IFPRI researchers and visiting fellow under a larger research framework including Hugo Valin (land use, biofuel mandate, co-products), Antoine Bouet (energy representation) and David Laborde (value chain, trade).

Page 28: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

28

products of distilling and crushing activities, the fertilizer sector, and the transport fuels sector. For

the last two sectors, we split the existing GTAP sectors with the aid of the SplitCom software.4

However, after several tests, we found that limitations of the SplitCom software and the initial data

lead to very unsatisfactory results in our splitting of several feedstock crops, vegetable oils, and

biofuel sectors. We therefore developed an original and specific procedure aiming at providing a

database that is consistent in both values and quantities:

1. Agricultural production value and volume are targeted to match FAO statistics. A world price

matrix for homogenous commodities was constructed in order to be consistent with

international price distortions (transportation costs, tariffs, and export taxes or subsidies);

2. Production technology for new crops is inherited from the parent GTAP sector and the new

sectors are deducted from the parent ones;

3. Vegetal oil sectors are built with a bottom-up approach based on crushing equations. Value

and volume of both oils and meals are consistent with the prices matrix, the physical yields,

and the inputs quantity;

4. Biofuels sectors are built with a bottom-up approach to respect the production costs, input

requirements, production volume, and for the different type of ethanols, the different by-

products. Finally, rates of profits are computed based on the difference between production

costs, subsidies and output prices;

5. For steps 2, 3 and 4, the value of inputs is deducted from the relevant sectors (Other Food,

Vegetal Oils, Chemical products, Fuel) in the original SAM, allowing resources and uses to be

extracted from different sectors if needed (mapping n to n).

6. At each stage, consumption data are adjusted to be consistent with production and trade

flows.

It is important to emphasize that this procedure, even if time consuming and delicate to operate with

so many new sectors, was crucial and differs from a more simplistic approach used in the literature

until now. Indeed, each step allows addressing several issues. For instance, step 1 allows us to have a

more realistic level of production than using the GTAP database that performs production targeting

only for OECD countries, with some flaws, and therefore has an outdated agricultural production 4 SplitCom, a Windows program developed by J. Mark Horridge of the Center for Policy Studies, Monash University, Australia, is specifically designed for introducing new sectors in the GTAP database by splitting existing sectors into two or three sectors. Users are required to supply as much available data on consumption, production technology, trade, and taxes either in US dollar values or as shares information for use in splitting an existing sector. The software allows for each GTAP sector to be split one at a time, each time creating a balanced and consistent database that is suitable for CGE analysis.

Page 29: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

29

structure for many countries. Building a consistent dataset in value and volume – thanks to the price

matrix – is also critical. Targeting only in value often generates inconsistencies in the physical linkage

that thereby leads to erroneous assessments (e.g. wrong yields for extracting vegetal oil). Even more

important is the role of initial prices, and price distortions, in a modeling framework using CES and

CET functions. Indeed, economic models rely on optimality conditions and, in our case, as in all the

CGE literature, our modeling approach leads to equalization of the marginal rate of substitution (CES

case) to relative prices. It means that the physical conversion ratio is bound to the relative prices.

Wrong initial prices, or incorrect price normalization, will lead to convert X units of good i (e.g.

imported ethanol) in Y units of good j (e.g. domestic produced ethanol). In the case of a homogenous

good, we need to have an initial price ratio equal to one and to ensure with a high elasticity of

substitution that this ratio will remain close to one. Otherwise, misleading results appear, e.g. one

ton of palm oil will replace only half a ton of sunflower oil, one ton of imported ethanol can replace

1.5 tons of domestic ethanol, etc. This mechanism may be neglected in many CGE exercises where

the level of aggregation easily explains the imperfect substitution. In the case of this study, however,

we found it imperative to directly address this challenge since we deal with a high level of sector

disaggregation, a high level of substitution (among ethanols produced from different feedstocks,

among vegetal oils, or among imported and domestic production), and with the critical role of

physical linkages, from the crop areas to the energy content of different fuels and meals.

Finally, a flexible procedure is needed (see 5) since some of our new sectors can be constructed from

among several sectors in GTAP. SplitCom allows only a 1-ton disaggregation which is rather

restrictive for the more complex configuration that we face with the data. For instance, Brazilian

ethanol trade data falls under the beverages and tobacco sector while its production is classified

under the chemical products sector. For the vegetal oils, we face similar issues since the value of the

oil is in the “Vegetable Oil” sector but the value of the oil meals are generally under in the food

products sector.

The specific data sources, procedures and assumptions made in the construction of each new sector

are described in Annex I.

3.2 Global Model

Extensive model modifications were done to adapt the MIRAGE trade policy focused CGE model for

an assessment of the trade and environmental impact of biofuels policies. Some of the changes were

already introduced by Bouet et al.(2008) and Valin et al.(2008). In this section, we first provide a brief

description of the standard MIRAGE model. This is followed by the adaptations and innovations

made in the areas of energy modeling, the modeling of co-products of ethanol and biodiesel

Page 30: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

30

production, and the description of fertilizer use. More detailed explanations of the various modeling

changes are provided in the annexes.

3.2.1 Standard MIRAGE Model

The work starts with the MIRAGE model, initially developed at CEPII. This section summarizes the

features of the standard version relevant for this study. MIRAGE is a multisector, multiregion

Computable General Equilibrium Model for trade policy analysis. The model operates in a sequential

dynamic recursive set-up: it is solved for one period, and then all variable values, determined at the

end of a period, are used as the initial values of the next one. Macroeconomic data and social

accounting matrixes, in particular, come from the GTAP 7 database (see Narayanan, 2008), which

describes the world economy in 2004. From the supply side in each sector, the production function is

a Leontief function of value-added and intermediate inputs: one output unit needs for its production

x percent of an aggregate of productive factors (labor, unskilled and skilled; capital; land and natural

resources) and (1 – x) percent of intermediate inputs.5 The intermediate inputs function is an

aggregate CES function of all goods: it means that substitutability exists between two intermediate

goods, depending on the relative prices of these goods. This substitutability is constant and at the

same level for any pair of intermediate goods. Similarly, in the generic version of the model, value-

added is a constant elasticity of substitution (CES) function of unskilled labor, land, natural resources,

and of a CES bundle of skilled labor and capital. This nesting allows the modeler to introduce less

substitutability between capital and skilled labor than between these two and other factors. In other

words, when the relative price of unskilled labor is increased, this factor is replaced by a combination

of capital and skilled labor, which are more complementary.6

Factor endowments are fully employed. The only factor whose supply is constant is natural

resources. Capital supply is modified each year because of depreciation and investment. Growth

rates of labor supply are fixed exogenously. Land supply is endogenous; it depends on the real

remuneration of land. In some countries land is a scarce factor (for example, Japan and the EU), such

5 The fixed-proportion assumption for intermediate inputs and primary factor inputs is especially pertinent to

developed economies, but for some developing economies that are undergoing dramatic economic growth and

structural change, such as China, the substitution between intermediate inputs and primary factor inputs may

be significant.

6 In the generic version, substitution elasticity between unskilled labor, land, natural resources, and the bundle

of capital and skilled labor is 1.1, whereas it is only 0.6 between capital and skilled labor. This structure has

been modified for the present exercise (see 4.2).

Page 31: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

31

that elasticity of supply is low. In others (such as Argentina, Australia, and Brazil), land is abundant

and elasticity is high7.

Skilled labor is the only factor that is perfectly mobile. Installed capital and natural resources are

sector specific. New capital is allocated among sectors according to an investment function. Unskilled

labor is imperfectly mobile between agricultural and nonagricultural sectors according to a constant

elasticity of transformation (CET) function: unskilled labor’s remuneration in agricultural activities is

different from that in nonagricultural activities. This factor is distributed between these two series of

sectors according to the ratio of remunerations. Land is also imperfectly mobile between agricultural

sectors.

In the MIRAGE model there is full employment of labor; more precisely, there is constant aggregate

employment in all countries, combined with wage flexibility. It is quite possible to suppose that total

aggregate employment is variable and that there is unemployment; but this choice greatly increases

the complexity of the model, so that simplifying assumptions have to be made in other areas (such as

the number of countries or sectors). This assumption could amplify the benefits of trade

liberalization for developing countries (see Diao et al. 2005): in full-employment models, increased

demand for labor (from increased activity and exports) leads to higher real wages, such that the

origin of comparative advantage is progressively eroded; but in models with unemployment, real

wages are constant and exports increase much more.

Capital in a given region, whatever its origin, domestic or foreign, is assumed to be obtained by

assembling intermediate inputs according to a specific combination. The capital good is the same

whatever the sector. MIRAGE describes imperfect, as well as perfect, competition. In sectors under

perfect competition, there is no fixed cost, and price equals marginal cost. Imperfect competition is

modeled according to a monopolistic competition framework. It accounts for horizontal product

differentiation linked to product variety. Each firm in sectors under imperfect competition produces

its own unique variety, with a fixed cost expressed as a fixed quantity of output. According to the

Cournot hypothesis, each firm supposes that its decision of production will not affect the production

of other firms. Furthermore, the firms do not expect that their decision of production will affect the

level of domestic demand (which would be what modelers call a “Ford effect”).

The demand side is modeled in each region through a representative agent whose propensity to save

is constant. The rest of the national income is used to purchase final consumption. Preferences

between sectors are represented by a linear expenditure system–constant elasticity of substitution

7 This assumption that applies to the standard model is modified in the version of MIRAGE used in this biofuels

study.

Page 32: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

32

(LES-CES) function. This implies that consumption has a non-unitary income elasticity; when the

consumer’s income is augmented by x percent, the consumption of each good is not systematically

raised by x percent, other things being equal.

The sector sub-utility function used in MIRAGE is a nesting of four CES functions. In this study,

Armington elasticities are drawn from the GTAP 7 database and are assumed to be the same across

regions. But a high value of Armington elasticity, i.e. 10, is assumed for all homogenous sectors

(single crops, single vegetal oils, ethanol). For biodiesel, we assume the same elasticity as that for

other fossil fuels. Macroeconomic closure is obtained by assuming that the sum of the balance of

goods and services and foreign direct investments (FDIs) is constant and equal to its initial value.

3.2.2 Energy Modeling

Most significant of these model modifications is the modeling of the energy sector to introduce

energy products, including biofuels, as components of value-added in the production process.

Following a survey of energy modeling approaches, the MIRAGE model was modified following a top-

down approach, similar to the approach taken with the GTAP-E model (Burniaux and Truong, 2002)

wherein energy demand is derived from the modeling of macroeconomic activity. However, beyond

what is in the GTAP-E model, the MIRAGE model was revised to include a better representation of

agricultural production processes to better capture the potential impact of biofuels development on

agricultural production. The possibility of either intensive or extensive production of crops and

livestock was introduced in the model. The characterization of demand for energy in non-agricultural

sectors, particularly the elasticity of substitution between different energy sources, was also

modified. Further details about the energy modeling developed for this study are in Annex II.

In addition to the extensive modifications made to address the shortcomings of the MIRAGE global

trade model in characterizing the energy sector, modifications were also made in the MIRAGE

demand function for final consumption. The Linear Expenditure System - Constant Elasticity of

Substitution (LES-CES), which captures non-homothetic behaviour in response to changes in income,

was improved through the introduction of new calibration to USDA income and price elasticities

(Seale et al., 2003). For China and India, some complementary information was sourced from FAPRI.

The LES-CES demand structure was further modified to allow for a separate characterization of

demand for fuel relative to demand for other goods. A new CES level is introduced to allow for the

lower elasticity of fuel demand to prices. Further details on this energy demand structure

modification is provided in Annex III.

Page 33: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

33

3.2.3 Fertilizer modeling

Fertilizers are explicitly introduced in the global database and MIRAGE model to capture potential

crop production intensification, using more fertilizers, in response to increased demand for biofuel

feedstock crops. The characterization of the crop production response to prices resulting from

increased bioenergy demand is particularly important. Through improved modeling of fertilizers and

its impact on crop yield, we introduce a better representation of yield response to economic

incentives while taking into account biophysical constraints and saturation effects. The degree of

crop intensification depends on the relative price between land and fertilizers. Further details on the

fertilizer modeling are provided in Annex IV.

In this context, crop yields in the model increase through three channels:

• Exogenous technical progress (see baseline section);

• Endogenous “factor” based intensification: land is combined with more labor and capital;

• Endogenous “fertilizers” (intermediate consumption) based intensification, the mechanism

described above.

The model does not include endogenous technical progress based on private or public research and

development expenditures in response to relative price changes. However, the increase of capital

and labor by unit of land (effect ii) plays a similar role.

3.2.4. Modelling of biofuel sectors

The biodiesel and ethanol sectors are modeled in slightly different ways. Biodiesel production, which

does not produce by-products, uses four kind of vegetal oils (palm oil, soybean oil, sunflower oil and

rapeseed oil) as primary inputs (see Figure 1). These are combined with other inputs (mainly

chemicals and energy) and value-added (capital and labour). Intermediate consumption are modeled

using a CES nested structure with high substitutable (elasticity of substitution equals to 8) assumed

among the vegetal oils. The initial dataset and the calibration of the model were set to allow for an

initial marginal rate of substitution equal to 1 (e.g. one ton of rapeseed oil may be replaced by one

ton of palm oil). The feedstock aggregate is then combined with a bundle comprised of the other

components of intermediate consumption assuming complementarity (with elasticity of substitution

equal to 0.001). As the only output of this sector, biodiesel can be exported or consumed locally. The

share of the different vegetal oils is given by initial data but evolve endogenously through the CES

aggregate. However, in this framework, a country that does not produce biodiesel initially will never

produce biodiesel and if a biodiesel sector in one country does not initially use a type of vegetal oil as

feedstock, it will never switch to such feedstock.For the ethanol sector, we first model four

Page 34: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

34

subsectors, each using only one of the following as specific feedstock -- wheat, sugar cane, sugar

beet, or maize. This main input is combined with other production inputs and value-added assuming

complementarity. Each subsector produces a specific by-product (DDGS with different properties and

prices), except for the sugarcane-based ethanol sector, as well as the main output ethanol. These

different types of ethanol are blended into one homogenous good that is exported or consumed

locally. In addition, we allow for Central America and Caribbean regions the possibility to use

imported ethanol for Brazil as an input into their own ethanol production sector.8 Each type of DDGS

is also directly traded or consumed by local livestock industries. It is important to emphasize that no

other DDGS production is modeled outside of the production of ethanol. It means that the size of

DDGS market is more restricted in the model than in the real world and will be totally dependent on

the evolution of the ethanol production sectors. It is quite different from the production of meals

wherein the vegetal oil production process itself generates oilcakes. Since the biodiesel sector is a

limited destination for the overall vegetal oil sectors, the effects of biodiesel policies are much more

limited on these markets.

3.2.4 Modeling of Co-products and Livestock Sectors

Co-products of the biofuels industry, such as Dried Distillers Grains with Solubles (DDGS), soy meal,

and rapeseed meal, are used as substitutes for feedgrains in livestock production. It is therefore

recognized that in assessing the impact of biofuels development on agricultural markets, co-products

should be taken into account since they could lessen the unfavorable impact of biofuels: they reduce

the need of land reallocation/extension to replace the crops displaced from the feed and food

sectors to bio-energy production. Biofuel co-products are also recognized for their role in potentially

mitigating the land use impact of biofuels as demand for feedgrains are reduced. Kampman et al.

(2008) estimated that incorporating by-products into the calculations for land requirements of

biofuels reduced land demand by 10-25%.

Accounting for co-products was only recently introduced in CGE assessments of the impact of

biofuels development. Taheripour et al. (2008) analysed the impact of including biofuel by-products

(DDGS) in an analysis based on the GTAP CGE model. They found significant differences in feedstock

output and prices depending on whether the existence of by-products is taken into account.

Inclusion of co-products has become a prerequisite to the modeling of biofuel policy impact.

8 The consumption of other inputs are corrected from the share of imported ethanol used in the processing of

domestic ethanol under the assumption that transformation of processing of imported ethanol is performed at

a low cost. However, only the existence of tariff preferences on the US and EU markets justify these indirect

exports from Brazil.

Page 35: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

35

Significant efforts have been made in the US Environmental Protection Agency and the California Air

Resource Board (CARB) assessments of indirect land use impact to take co-products into account at

the US level (DDGS from corn ethanol production).

Figure 1 Biofuel Feedstock Schematic

*Only for Central America and Caribbean regions to represent the re-export channel of Brazilian ethanol in the region. Note: Other inputs and Value added are not displayed here.

Page 36: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

36

Co-products play a different role in the ethanol and in the biodiesel production pathways. For

ethanol, distillers grains and sugar beet pulp are low value materials that are not profitable without

the benefits from ethanol sale (the share of ethanol by-products in total production value is below

20%). On the other hand, the production of oilseed meals is at the heart of oilseed market dynamics

in biodiesel production. Oil and meals are co-products that can be valued independently and the

demand for one of them directly affects the price of the other. This difference in treatment of co-

products of ethanol and biodiesel production is reflected in the modeling of co-products introduced

in this study. For ethanol, co-products are represented as a fixed proportion of ethanol production,

with the shares based on cost shares data for co-products for selected ethanol feedstocks in the USA

and EU. For biodiesel, we consider as co-products the oilcakes\meals that are produced in the

crushing of oilseeds to produce vegetable oils that are then processed for biodiesel production. We

rely on cost share information for oilcakes in the vegetable oil production process. Co-products are

then introduced in the model as substitutes for feedgrains in livestock production. Substitution

between oilcakes, based on the protein content of the different oilcakes, is first introduced. The

composite of oilcakes is then introduced as substitute for animal feed and DDGS as feed inputs to the

livestock sector based on their energy content. However, we do not model the co-products of the

biodiesel trans-esterification process, i.e. glycerol and similar products that can be used as additives

to the feeding process.

With the introduction of co-products in the model, the modeling of livestock production was also

significantly modified to allow for intensification through substitution of livestock feed, including

ethanol and biodiesel co-products, with land. This is treated using a similar approach to our modeling

of crop intensification through substitution of fertilizer for land, and is assessed as an alternative case

in the sensitivity analyses. Further details on the modeling of co-products are given in Annex V.

3.3 Land Use Module

To capture the interactions between biofuels production and land use change, we introduce a

decomposition of land use and land use change dynamics. Land resources are differentiated between

different agro-environmental zones (AEZ). The possibility of extension in total land supply to take

into account the role of marginal land is also introduced. The modeling of land use change captures

both the substitution effect involved in changing the existing land allocation to different crops and

economic uses, and the expansion effect of using more arable land for cultivation. Detailed

documentation of the land use module including data on AEZs and land use change modeling are

Page 37: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

37

available in Annex VI. Land extension takes place at the AEZ level allowing capturing different

behaviour across different regions of large countries (e.g. Brazil).

To determine in which biotope cropland occurs, we follow the marginal land extension coefficients

computed by Winrock International for the US EPA, wherein the extent of land use change over the

period 2001 to 2004 was determined using remote sensing analysis. For Brazil, these coefficients are

defined at the AEZ level to capture that deforestation occurs in specific regions. This feature is

particularly important since sectoral distribution will lead to different deforestation behaviour: for

instance, soya crops are closer to the deforestation frontier than sugar cane plantations. Although

the historical trends for land use change are followed in the baseline, changes in land use allocation

in the scenarios come from the endogenous response to prices through the substitution effects.

Therefore, historical land use changes do not affect the distribution of land under economic use

across their alternative uses (cropland, pasture, managed forest).

We also introduce a mechanism for expansion or retraction of pasture land in response to changes in

demand for cattle. Alternative assumptions regarding the links between demand for cattle and for

pastureland and for the possibility of intensification are accommodated in the revised modeling of

land use expansion and discussed in Annex VI.

3.4 GHG Emissions and Marginal ILUC Measurement

A critical component of this study is the assessment of the of balance in CO2 emissions between (a)

direct emission savings induced by the production and use of biofuels and (b) possible increases in

emissions as a result of indirect land use changes (ILUC) induced by biofuels production.

Direct emissions savings for each region, are calculated primarily using the typical direct emission

coefficients for various production pathways as specified in the EU Renewable Energy Directive (see

in Annex VII). Additional sources were used for the relevant emissions coefficients data for other

regions (EPA, 2009). We also perform sensitivity analysis on these values. The values of these

coefficients are critical to the determination of direct emission savings and the net emissions effects

of biofuels. We do not model each production pathway separately in the model but calculate an

average composition of the biofuels production sector. Data on that composition remain sparse

however; consequently the current average composition of production capacity in the industry

remains uncertain as well. Moreover, there are major uncertainties with regard to (a) the future

weight of each of these production pathways in total production and (b) the possibility for

substitution between different pathways to comply with the sustainability criteria defined in the RED.

As a result, major uncertainties remain regarding the direct emission savings in the biofuels industry.

Page 38: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

38

We use the consumption approach to allocate direct emission savings: the emission credit is given to

the country that consumes the biofuels, not to the producer country. In this we follow the RED

directive even though this may appear to be in contradiction with the UNFCCC and Kyoto Protocol

emission accounting rules that allocate credits for reductions to the producer country.

In calculating the GHG emissions from indirect land use change, the study considered emissions from

(a) converting forest to other types of land, (b) emissions associated with the cultivation of new land

and (c) below-ground carbon stocks of grasslands and meadows. We rely on IPCC coefficients for

these different ecosystems. We also include two different treatments. For the EU, the carbon stock

of forest is limited to 50% of the value for a mature forest. It is considered that no primary forest will

be affected by the land extension in the EU and only the areas recently concerned by afforestation

will be impacted.

For Indonesia and Malaysia, we include in addition to the carbon stocks (above and below ground),

the emissions from peatlands converted to palm tree plantations. We assume a marginal coefficient

of extension of palm tree plantations on peatlands of 10% for Malaysia and 27% for Indonesia, based

on statistics provided by Wetlands International9. We use two sets of emissions coefficients for

peatlands, from IPCC – AFOLU and from Couwenberg (2009), since the literature displays a wide

range of coefficients (from 5 to 40 tonnes of CO2 by hectare). Recent trends emphasize the

underestimation of past values.

In this study, we compute the overall effect of the mandate using average ILUC, as well as marginal

ILUC (the effect of an additional unit of biofuels). The two notions differ from each other due to the

non-linearity of marginal ILUC in the model.10

We estimate the marginal ILUC effects for each feedstock, measured in tons of CO2 emissions per

metric ton and per Giga Joule of biofuel, resulting from a marginal extra demand of 106 GJ, i.e.

around 0.1% of the consumption level at this stage, applied to the EU mandate level. Further details

are provided in Annex VII.

9 http://wetlands.org/.

10 The distinction between the concept of average (mean) and marginal ILUC is discussed in Tipper et al. (2009).

Page 39: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

39

4 Baseline, Trade Policy Scenarios, and Sensitivity Analysis

This section provides a description of the baseline scenarios, the alternative trade policy scenarios,

and the sensitivity analyses conducted on some parameters used in the model. The baseline scenario

provides a characterization of growth of the global economy up to 2020 but without the biofuels

policy scenarios of interest in the study. We then introduce the EU biofuels mandate as a policy

scenario and examine the resulting changes compared to the baseline scenario. We also introduce

alternative trade policy scenarios around this EU biofuels mandate scenario impact. Moreover, since

the values of some parameters used in the model are uncertain, sensitivity analyses are performed

by simulating the policy scenarios using alternative values of key parameters.

4.1 Sectoral and Regional Nomenclature

Even if the database has been developed at a detailed level (57 sectors and 35 regions), it is not

practical to run the scenarios at this highly detailed level due to the much larger size of this model

(now twice the number of equations/variables than the normal MIRAGE model) and the modeling of

land extension at the detailed AEZ level. Focusing on the sectors and regions of interest in this study

on biofuels and agricultural production and trade from an EU point of view, we limit the size of our

aggregation to the main players (11 regions) and 43 sectors. Details are provided in Table 1 and 2.

The sectoral disaggregation covers agricultural feedstock crops and processing sectors, energy

sectors and other sectors that also use agricultural inputs.

Table 1 Regional Aggregation

Region Description Brazil Brazil CAMCarib Central America and Caribbean countries China China CIS CIS countries (inc. Ukraine) EU27 European Union (27 members) IndoMalay Indonesia and Malaysia LAC Other Latin America countries (inc. Argentina) RoOECD Rest of OECD (inc. Canada & Australia) RoW Rest of the World SSA Sub Saharan Africa USA United States of America

Page 40: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

40

Table 2. Sectoral Aggregation

Sector Description Sector Description Sector Description Rice Rice SoybnOil Soy Oil EthanolW Ethanol - Wheat Wheat Wheat SunOil Sunflower Oil Biodiesel Biodiesel Maize Maize OthFood Other Food sectors Manuf Other Manufacturing

activities PalmFruit Palm Fruit MeatDairy Meat and Dairy

products WoodPaper Wood and Paper

Rapeseed Rapeseed Sugar Sugar Fuel Fuel Soybeans Soybeans Forestry Forestry PetrNoFuel Petroleum products,

except fuel Sunflower Sunflower Fishing Fishing Fertiliz Fertilizers OthOilSds Other oilseeds Coal Coal ElecGas Electricity and Gas VegFruits Vegetable &

Fruits Oil Oil Construction Construction

OthCrop Other crops Gas Gas PrivServ Private services Sugar_cb Sugar beet or

cane OthMin Other minerals RoadTrans Road Transportation

Cattle Cattle Ethanol Ethanol - Main sector

AirSeaTran Air & Sea transportation

OthAnim Other animals (inc. hogs and poultry)

EthanolC Ethanol - Sugar Cane PubServ Public services

PalmOil Palm Oil EthanolB Ethanol - Sugar Beet RpSdOil Rapeseed Oil EthanolM Ethanol - Maize

4.2 Baseline Scenario

It is important to emphasize that the underlying GTAP database is first updated from the 2004 data

reference year to 2008 through a simulation that uses external macroeconomic variables (GDP,

population, labor force) over that period, as well as by targeting observed biofuel production and

consumption data for 2008. Endogenous variables (mandate) are used to reach these levels. After

2009, we let the model evolve freely in the baseline except for the macroeconomic variables and oil

prices that are still targeted.

An exhaustive description of the baseline scenario is provided in the Excel workbook that

accompanies this report: Details_baseline_CentralScenario.xlsx.

4.2.1 Macroeconomic Trends

The baseline scenario reflects recent International Energy Agency forecasts (2008) with oil prices

reaching $120 a barrel in 2030 current prices. Economic growth projections, now taking into account

the effects of the economic crisis, have also been updated with projections data from the World

Page 41: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

41

Economic Outlook (April 2009) of the International Monetary Fund. In this context, EU consumption

of energy for road transportation is estimated to reach 316 Mtoe in 2020. This figure is in line with

the latest projections of DG ENER. However, this number may appear too high when new EU policies

aimed a reducing energy consumption are taken into account.

4.2.2 Technology

The average total factor productivity (TFP) in the economy is computed endogenously to reach the

real GDP target in the baseline.

In agriculture, we introduce country and sector specific TFP rates based on estimates from Ludena et

al. (2006). It is important to note that no exogenous growth in palm tree yield is assumed due to the

lack of data at our disposal. Therefore, compared to other crops, palm oil tends to suffer from a

disadvantage in the baseline. Yields in the palm fruit sector can only increase through an endogenous

process (intensification). (See table B9 of the Baseline Excel workbook for details). We do not assume

changes in the yield of the crushing, distilling and biofuel production activities.

It is important to notice that these projections assume very low exogenous productivity increases in

EU agriculture, both when comparing agriculture to other sectors in the EU and also comparing EU

agriculture to its main competitors (up to +5% only for main crops in the EU whereas yields increase

by more than 30% in Brazil). This assumption is based on Ludena et al. (2006) but leads to losses of

competitiveness of EU agriculture in the baseline and will have adverse consequences on

endogenous yield growth. Indeed, since agricultural sectors are below EU average in terms of

productivity growth, capital will tend avoid these sectors as expected returns are higher in other

sectors. Less capital accumulation leads to low yield increases through factor intensification.

4.2.3 Trade Policy Assumptions

The baseline scenario leaves the trade policies that were in place by end 2008 unchanged. The

Economic Partnership Agreements (EPAs) between the EU and the ACP countries, negotiated in 2008,

are implemented either as ratified interim agreements or a complete EPA (e.g. with CARICOM),

depending on the status of the agreement. Negotiations on trade agreements that were not finalized

by end 2008 are not included: the Doha Development Agenda, an EU-ASEAN agreement and an EU-

Ukraine agreement.

The baseline scenario includes the full ad-valorem equivalent (AVE around 48%) of the prevailing EU

MFN duty on EU bioethanol imports from countries that do not benefit from bilateral or unilateral

(GSP) preferential schemes. In reality, this is likely to be an overestimate of the effective AVE.

Page 42: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

42

Significant quantities of bioethanol are imported under temporary suspensions of duties and, in the

form of denatured ethanol, as chemical products for which a lower duty applies. In the absence of a

specific EU tariff line for bioethanol, there are no trade statistics available that permit us to estimate

the effective trade-weighted tariff on bioethanol.

Another critical trade policy measure that we incorporate in the baseline scenario are the anti-

dumping duties that the EU imposed on US exports of biodiesel in March 2009. Over the last few

years, the US has emerged as the major biodiesel exporter to the EU (with more than 80% of market

share among all exporters), supplying about 19% of the EU domestic market for biodiesel. However,

due to the tax credit given to the US blenders, and the splash’n dash practice, the EU initiated anti-

dumping measures and countervailing duties in March 2009. This contingent protection has reduced

US biodiesel exports to the EU to negligible quantities. Allegedly, some of these US exports may now

have been replaced partially by exports from Indonesia and Malaysia and Argentina and growing

trade flows from Canada.11 In the model, the bulk of the adjustment to the antidumping duty is

achieved through increased in EU biodiesel production (based on EU produced and imported

feedstocks). Figure 2 shows the change in EU imports in 2008 and 2020.

Figure 2 EU biodiesel imports by source, Mtoe, in the baseline

Source: Authors’ calculations

11 These flows can be re-exported US production and in some cases, double splash’n go has been detected (tax

credit in the US then in Canada).

Page 43: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

43

4.2.4 Agricultural and Agri-Energy Policies

For the EU, we implement two policy elements in the baseline:

i. The sugar reform market;

ii. The end of the land set-aside policy.

These two assumptions have overall limited effects in the baseline. First, we remove the land set-

aside constraint by 2008 (full use of EU land). The main effect is to lead to a fall in EU yields from

2007 to 2020 by an average of 10 percent. This result is quite strong and will be translated into a

proportional fall in land prices. Indeed, we force EU farmers to use all set-aside land (10% of the

overall croplands in our baseline) when overall demand for crops will not change during the same

period. Therefore, EU production will not change when the harvested area will increase by 10% and

yield decreases. Since the relative price between land and fertilizers determines the use of fertilizers

in this model, another yield-depressing effect appears: lower land prices reduce intensification

behaviour and yield. The effects are differentiated between crops depending on existing tensions on

markets during the period in the baseline: stronger for crops with low demand (other crops -15%),

weaker for crops with high demand (-5%). The combination of this with our assumptions on EU

agricultural productivity (Section 4.2.2) leads to the decline in EU yields in the baseline. This is a

crude modelling solution for land set-aside and it should be improved. In particular, forcing farmers

to use all the land set-aside has a strong mechanical effect. In reality, it appears that these lands have

lower yields than average and that only a share of it has been used in 2008, even during crop price

surges.

Second, since we do not explicitly model the existing sugar policy tool, we mimic the sugar market

reform by reducing the EU MFN tariff to reproduce the price decrease. Overall, the EU sugar

production decrease by 5% between 2008 and 2020 when the world production increases by 47%.

The effects of the reform are slightly absorbed by the ethanol industry since the sugar-beet ethanol

industry is the most resilient in the baseline (see next paragraph for the evolution of the biofuels

sector in the baseline).

In the baseline, no additional EU bioenergy mandate is implemented. The status-quo is assumed to

prevail until 2020, with biofuel blending levels not exceeding the 3.3% level in 2008. The previous EU

target of 5.75% blending is not implemented. We do this to capture the impact of the EU mandate

against a baseline where biofuel use remains at the 2008 blending levels (3.3%). It implies that EU

consumption reach 9.75 Mtoe in 2020 with a 90% share for biodiesel. At the same time, production

increases by 22% while imports fall by 68% with the exclusion of the US from the market (see Figure

Page 44: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

44

2). Interestingly, EU production of bioethanol falls by 20% under the pressure of foreign competitors

(Brazil). Indeed it appears that the EU has no dynamic comparative advantage in this sector, contrary

to biodiesel.

This result is quite strong and has several explanations. First, the relative price of cereals compared

to sugar cane/sugar beet increases. This is due mainly to the evolution of world demand and the role

of cereals in cattle feeding but also demand from agribusiness sectors (flours etc.). This price gap

leads to a loss of competitiveness of EU ethanol (except for sugar beet). Second, as discussed

previously, EU yields will progress – exogenously and endogenously - very slowly compared to Brazil.

In addition, the land constraint is tighter in the EU than in Brazil. We have also a clear dichotomy

between EU and Brazil agricultural supplies since in the former land is scarce and intensification

already high, when in the latter both extensive and intensive growth appear to be very easy. This

undermines the overall competitiveness of EU ethanol. Last, we have a CGE effect: with the loss of

competitiveness of the EU ethanol sector, capital accumulation will slow, other sectors being more

attractive, and the ethanol sectors will shrink in the EU.

Since there are already strong political commitments in place in these countries, we implement the

US and Brazilian biofuel targets in the baseline.12 The US mandate will lead to the consumption of 40

Mtoe of ethanol by 2020. The US production of ethanol will increase by 128% in twelve years while

the US biodiesel sectors will expand by 193% (but will represent only 12% of the ethanol sector).

With the Brazilian blending target fixed at 24.4% over the period, its ethanol production rises by

139%. We also include a 5% mandate for Indonesia, Malaysia, Rest of OECD and China. This

assumption is aimed to maintain a minimal consumption target in these countries in the baseline and

in the scenarios. It is important to take other countries' bioenergy consumption targets into account

since they affect the amount of foreign feedstock and biofuels production that the EU will be able to

import and thus the future domestic production in the EU.

4.2.5 Other Baseline Evolutions

As described previously, oil prices follow trends proposed by IEA in the recent World Energy Outlook

with an oil price stable at $83.8 a barrel by 2010 and increasing slowly up to $96.4 in 2015, and $109

in 2020 (values are given in 2004 constant dollars). Oil production is forecast to experience

constraints with an increase of only 32% on the period 2010-2020.

Demand for all crops increases only marginally (+27% in world production) over the same period. The

highest increases in demand are for palm fruit (60%) and for sugar cane, sugar beet and soybeans 12 A survey of biofuels policies in the EU, US and Brazil is provided in Annex X.

Page 45: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

45

sectors (+47%). Demand for cereals faces limited increases (about 20% for both wheat and maize).

These figures are above the FAO-Aglink projections and are mainly driven by a relatively inelastic

demand for agricultural products by other sectors (services, agri-business, chemistry) and are

intrinsic to the CGE exercise. This forecast is based on the assumption that no major changes occur in

the diet of the world population.

Given these forecasted changes, cropland expansion is expected to be 1 Mios of km2 between 2008

and 2020 (+9% for crops), with substantial expansion in Brazil (+36%) and Africa (+22%). In Europe,

the cropland surface will increase by 5% between 2008 and 2020.

4.3 Central and Alternative Trade Policy Scenarios

Against this baseline scenario, we evaluate the impact of three different trade policy scenarios. In the

central scenario, we introduce a biofuels policy shock that assumes that the EU will consume 17.76

Mtoe of bioethanol and biodiesel by 2020 in order to achieve the mandate target of 10% renewable

energy in road transport fuels. This figure is taken from an intermediate biofuels demand scenario by

DG ENER, based on the PRIMES model, that combines various renewable energy sources, including

second generation biofuels and increased use of electric cars powered by renewable electricity.

Furthermore, the model uses a target ratio for 2020 of 55% ethanol and 45% biodiesel, based on DG

AGRI projections.13

However, the current baseline does not include new projections for total road transport fuel

consumption in the EU in 2020, taking into account new EU energy and emission policy initiatives.

For this reason, we stick to the existing PRIMES figure of 316 Mtoe by 2020, and derive a biofuels

incorporation ratio of 5.6%14. As a result, the denominator of that ratio is probably too high. We do

however test the sensitivity of the outcomes for other values of this ratio (see below 4.4.1)

The mandate target is achieved in the model by mandatory regulation (explicit biofuels mix

constraints build into the supply of road transport fuels) and not by means of explicit subsidies or tax

credits.

13 “Impact Assessment of the Renewable Energy Roadmap - March 2007”, DG AGRI, AGRI G-2/WM D(2007).

These targets are still very close to the latest estimates of the JRC ISPRA. The ratio of bioethanol to biodiesel is

largely determined by the car fleet composition. Diesel cars cannot use petrol, and vice versa. We assume that

the fleet composition is exogenous to the model and not influenced by EU biofuels policies.

14 Note that this estimated 5.6% target for biofuels in 2020 is actually below the previous target of 5.75% for

2012. These 5.6% include land-using first-generation biofuels only. Non land-using first generation biofuels

such as recycled waste oil and animal fats are not included.

Page 46: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

46

Our trade policy scenarios are:

• MEU_BAU: Implementation of the EU biofuels mandate of achieving 5.6% consumption of

ethanol and of biodiesel in 2020 under a Business as Usual trade policy assumption;

• MEU_FT: Implementation of the EU biofuels mandate of achieving 5.6% consumption of

ethanol and of biodiesel in 2020 with the assumption of full, multilateral, trade liberalization

in biofuels. Contingent protection on US biodiesel remains;

• MEU_MCS: Implementation of the EU biofuels mandate of achieving 5.6% consumption of

ethanol and of biodiesel in 2020 with the assumption of EU bilateral trade liberalization with

MERCOSUR.

Two important points regarding the trade policy scenarios have to be emphasized. First, the size of

the mandate is not excessive since it will require an increase in EU demand of biofuels by 70% and an

8% increase of world production/consumption of biofuels. The limited size of the shock explains the

magnitude of our results in the next section. Due to the potential non-linearity in our analytical

framework (see section 5.2.3), this policy design will also explain the relatively low per unit cost (CO2

and economic inefficiency) of such a mandate. Second, the initial ad valorem equivalent (AVE) MFN

tariff on EU imports that we use, about 50%, appears to be an upper bound to more recent estimates

(25%-30%).15 Combined with the high Armington trade elasticity assumed for this product to

represent a more homogeneous good, the effects of trade liberalization will be very strong, and may

be overestimated.

4.4 Sensitivity Analysis Design

Assessing the impact of biofuel policies and the ILUC coefficients – the focus of this study – is quite

challenging due to a lot of uncertainties. We can group them into two categories: mandate policy

targets and varying parameter settings. We assess the robustness of our central case results by

performing sensitivity analysis on these different dimensions. A third set of sensitivity analyses

regarding modeling assumptions is performed on two issues and reported in relevant annexes: the

modeling of fertilizers (Annex IV) and the interaction between pasture and crop lands (Annex VI).

15 Please note that the estimation of the EU AVE on ethanol is complicated by two main difficulities: (i)

identification of the relevant unit value on imports, and (2) identification of the tariff line actually used by

Member States to import ethanol for biofuel production.

Page 47: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

47

4.4.1 Mandate Policy Targets

The overall size of the biofuels policies should matter in quantifying the economic and environmental

impact of the policy. Due to decreasing marginal productivity, we expect that applying the same

marginal change on a low or high level of biofuel demand and supply can play a very different role.

The goal of this analysis is to check if (average and marginal) ILUC is constant or increasing with the

total demand for biofuels.

Since the overall ambition of the EU mandate is an important question, we look at different values

for the mandate: 4.6%, 5.6%, 6.6%, 7.6% and 8.6%, equivalent to 14.5 Mtoe, 17.8 Mtoe, 20.7 Mtoe,

23.9 Mtoe and 27 Mtoe of biofuels consumption, respectively.

4.4.2 Parameter Uncertainties

It is important to underline that the values of some key parameters in the model are still subject to

considerable uncertainty. It is therefore important to assess the role of alternative values in

determining the robustness of the results.

Land and fertilizer substitution – Due to uncertainty about the values of elasticity of substitution

between land and fertilizers, sensitivity analysis (is done by looking at the impact of using twice the

land/fertilizer substitution elasticity in the base case.16 Increasing the elasticity should help the

farmers to intensify their production more easily and will limit the pressure for new lands.

In addition, in Annex IV, we also analyze the consequences of alternative modeling of fertilizers.

Land substitution – Due to uncertainty about the value of the elasticity of land substitution across

agricultural production, i.e. how easily land can be shifted from one crop to another, we investigate

two cases:

• Elasticity of land substitution between crops are doubled;

• Elasticity of land substitution between crops and pasture are doubled.

The last section of Annex VI provides a discussion of the role of the interaction between croplands

and pasture in our modeling and describes three variations on how pasture land area is affected by

increased demand for livestock. In the simulations in this report, we use the mode P=1 wherein

increased demand for livestock could lead to intensification in some regions, thereby affecting the

amount of land that is substituted between the livestock and crop sectors.

16 The basic value has been calibrated based on detailed elasticity information extracted from the IMPACT

model (Rosegrant et al. 2008)

Page 48: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

48

Land use extension – Due to uncertainty about the value of elasticity of the land extension supply

curve, i.e. how new land are converted to agricultural uses when the rental price of land increases,

we conduct sensitivity analysis by varying the value of the land extension elasticity. Our main

estimates are based on Barr, et al. (2010) for the US and Brazil and on the OECD. Current values

assume much more flexibility in Brazil and a land extension elasticity in Brazil that is 5 times higher

than in the US or in the EU. We look at two specific scenarios:

• We increase the land extension elasticity in Indonesia and Malaysia to reach the level for

Brazil;

• We reduce by half the land extension elasticity in Brazil (which could be the case if Brazil

manages to enforce its preservation program).

Other parameters that may be critical to te overall assessment of the emissions effects of the biofuel

mandates are: the choice of direct emissions savings and the coefficients of land use extensions.

Since different set of values are available and are based on different methodological choices, we

discuss them in Annex IX.

Technology Pathway – In the assessment of the direct GHG emissions from different biofuel

feedstocks used by major biofuels producers, we rely on a set of direct emissions coefficients that are

sourced from the EU RED Directive, or from the literature. The values are employed in the central

scenario. These values, as well as the results of a sensitivity analysis on these values are discussed in

Annex VIII.

It is important to keep in mind that alternative technology pathways are used in an ad-hoc method

(per unit coefficient) and do not lead to a modification of the sectoral technology used in the model.

We expect that the better the technology (higher reduction coefficients) the better the net CO2

balance effect.

Page 49: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

49

5 Results and Discussion

In this section, we present the results of the central scenario along with alternative trade policy

scenarios, focusing first on the potential impact on production and trade under these policies and

then on the land use and environmental impact in terms of GHG emissions from direct and indirect

land use changes. Included in this assessment of environmental impact is the calculation of marginal

crop-specific ILUC change, which is an important focus of this study. The final sub-section presents

the results of several sensitivity analyses that are designed to assess the robustness of the results to

changes in the mandate policy and some parameter values. The full set of results indicators

calculated for the scenarios are available in the Detailed_scenario_results.xlsx.

5.1 Production and Trade Impact of Trade Scenarios

In this section we examine the impact of two policy scenarios:

First, the European mandate scenario seeks to achieve the EU policy objective of at least 5.6%

biofuels consumption in transport fuels in 2020 by imposing that bio/fossil fuel mix on all fuels sold in

the EU. In that case, the consumer bears most of the cost of any fuel price increases at the pump. It is

compared to the baseline situation where no mandate is implemented. The mandate is implemented

progressively and in a linear fashion from 2010 to 2020. It is applied on each type of biofuel and no

blending over 5.6% is allowed for biofuels in either gasoline or diesel. No change in trade policies are

considered (scenario MEU_BAU).

Second, the trade liberalization scenario consists of reaching the same objective through a more

market-based approach, by lowering the consumer price of biofuels in order to stimulate

consumption. This is achieved, in a first scenario, by the full liberalization of biofuels sectors (scenario

MEU_FT). A second scenario consists in a liberalization of biofuels trade between MERCOSUR

countries and the EU (scenario MEU_MCS). We do not present in the report the detailed figures for

the EU-Mercosur scenario since it leads to result very similar to the multilateral liberalization.

We evaluate the effects of these policy scenarios on several key elements - biofuel production,

biofuel imports, crop production, agricultural value-added, variation of land use by sector, variation

of total land use, variation of the intensification index for cultivation ($ of fertilizer used by ha), direct

emissions reduction related to biofuels, and indirect emissions related to indirect land use change

effect.

Page 50: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

50

5.1.1 Biofuel Production and Imports

Table 3 illustrates the impact of the various scenarios on biofuel production. The two first columns in

Table 3 provide the level of ethanol production in 2008 and in 2020 in the baseline (without policy

shocks – column Ref). The next columns give the level and variation of production in 2020 implied by

the two scenarios with variation being a comparison with the baseline. The same table organization

is kept throughout all the report unless indicated otherwise.

Table 3 Level and variation of biofuels production (Mio toe and %)

REF MEU_BAU MEU_FT

Lev Lev Var Lev Var

Biodiesel Brazil 0.36 0.37 1.81% 0.37 2.92%

Biodiesel China 0.23 0.23 -0.72% 0.23 -0.76%

Biodiesel EU27 8.15 9.04 10.92% 9.07 11.27%

Biodiesel IndoMalay 3.58 3.65 2.06% 3.65 2.07%

Biodiesel LAC 0.45 0.48 5.91% 0.48 6.10%

Biodiesel RoOECD 3.24 3.24 -0.01% 3.24 0.12%

Biodiesel USA 3.46 3.45 -0.18% 3.46 -0.03%

Biodiesel World 19.46 20.45 5.08% 20.49 5.30%

Ethanol Brazil 28.51 32.78 14.97% 34.36 20.50%

Ethanol CAMCarib 7.25 7.45 2.64% 7.19 -0.89%

Ethanol China 10.81 10.83 0.18% 10.83 0.16%

Ethanol EU27 0.84 2.17 156.89% 0.44 -48.23%

Ethanol LAC 0.69 0.69 0.95% 0.70 2.21%

Ethanol RoOECD 5.66 5.78 2.03% 5.84 3.03%

Ethanol RoW 1.51 1.50 -0.54% 1.50 -0.49%

Ethanol USA 29.10 29.57 1.64% 29.72 2.14%

Ethanol World 84.38 90.77 7.58% 90.57 7.34%

Source: Authors’ calculations

The mandate scenarios and trade liberalization scenario have very contrasting effects on biofuel

production in the European Union. In 2020 ethanol production increases by 157% in the EU under an

EU mandate scenario, while the competition coming from increased imports in a trade liberalization

scenario would mean a decrease by -48% in case of full liberalization scenario. The removal of tariffs

on ethanol would be followed by a surge in European imports of this product (they are multiplied by

6.8 by 2020 – see Table 4) under trade liberalization scenario. As previously mentioned, since the

baseline tariff may be overestimated (by a factor of 1.5), the effects of trade liberalization simulated

here may also be overstated.

As can be expected, the European mandate increases overseas production of ethanol by less than

when it is coupled with trade liberalization. The greatest impact are seen in the two largest

producers, the US and Brazil. In particular, Brazilian ethanol production is increased by 5.8 Mios toe

Page 51: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

51

(+20%)in 2020 under the trade liberalization scenario, while it is increased by +4.3 Mios toe (15%)

under a European mandate. Effects on US production are more limited US (+2.14% with trade

liberalization). US exports to the EU do not increase significantly (they remain a tiny fraction of the

market) but they need to replace displaced Brazil exports. However, the free trade scenario leads to

a strong preference erosion for the Central America and Caribbean region (-83%).

Table 4. Level and Variation of EU Biofuel Imports, by Origin (Mio toe and %) by 2020

REF MEU_BAU MEU_FT

Lev Lev Var Lev Var

Biodiesel Brazil 0.00 0.00 6.21% 0.00 5.49%

Biodiesel China 0.00 0.00 14.45% 0.00 14.59%

Biodiesel IndoMalay 0.44 0.51 15.29% 0.51 15.46%

Biodiesel LAC 0.19 0.22 15.69% 0.22 16.04%

Biodiesel RoOECD 0.00 0.00 12.92% 0.00 82.07%

Biodiesel USA 0.00 0.00 11.78% 0.00 12.10%

Biodiesel World 0.64 0.74 15.40% 0.74 15.79%

Ethanol Brazil 0.92 5.53 502.82% 7.56 724.32%

Ethanol CAMCarib 0.04 0.27 517.35% 0.01 -83.48%

Ethanol USA 0.00 0.01 546.96% 0.00 111.89%

Ethanol World 0.96 5.82 503.58% 7.57 685.98%

Source: Authors’ calculations

Figure 3 shows EU production of biofuels in 2020 broken down by feedstock crops. The ranking

among feedstocks by share of productionin 2008 is not modified since the impact of trade

liberalization for the biodiesel sector is weak and the effects of the mandate are very limited. We see

only a slight expansion of the share of palm oil in EU biodiesel production17 and a contraction of the

share of rapeseed oil. It shows that palm oil is marginally more competitive and with a larger

mandate (and a stronger demand of biodiesel), we can expect a larger use of palm oil. This is also

true for soya (from 32% to 33%). It is important to keep in mind that with the antidumping and

countervailing duties applied in the baseline, the significant share of US soya-based biodiesel was

already eliminated in the baseline.

For the ethanol sectors, the evolution of the feedstock structure of EU production is stronger. When

the demand for EU ethanol is high (no trade liberalization), most of the production expansion will be

based on sugar beet (from 41% to 45% of EU ethanol production). Symmetrically, with trade

liberalization, this feedstock will be marginally the most affected ( from 41% to 37%).

17 This is in addition to the increase in biodiesel imports.

Page 52: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

52

Figure 3 Structure of EU Biofuels Production by Feedstock (2020)

Source: Authors’ calculations

5.1.2 Agricultural Production

These various policy scenarios have significant impact on crop production, particularly on feedstocks

needed for the production of ethanol and biodiesel. This is particularly true for rapeseed and sugar

cane-sugar beet. For example, while the production of sugar cane-sugar beet is increased under the

MEU_BAU scenario (+3.8% in 2020 with +9.7% for Brazil –sugar cane, see Table 5, and +9.3% for the

EU –sugar beet, see Figure 4), this increase is much more significant in the case of trade liberalization

(+4.9% under the MEU_FT scenario with +15% for Brazil –sugar cane, and a decrease of -2.4% for the

EU –sugar beet).

Page 53: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

53

Table 5. Main Changes in Crop Production (non EU27) in 2020, 1000t

Crops Region REF MEU_BAU MEU_FT Lev Lev Var Lev Var

Sugar_cb Brazil 913385 1001556.15 9.65% 1045492.08 14.46%

Rapeseed CIS 571 583.00 2.06% 583.42 2.13%

PalmFruit Brazil 3117 3196.06 2.53% 3181.86 2.07%

Rapeseed Brazil 151 153.15 1.59% 152.85 1.39%

Rapeseed SSA 108 108.87 1.10% 108.89 1.12%

Sunflower Brazil 153 155.23 1.24% 154.91 1.03%

Rapeseed RoOECD 13848 13969.92 0.88% 13975.74 0.92%

Soybeans RoOECD 3999 4020.98 0.54% 4025.62 0.66%

Sunflower USA 2142 2155.86 0.64% 2156.20 0.65%

Soybeans CIS 1129 1134.41 0.46% 1135.71 0.58%

Soybeans LAC 77981 78349.47 0.47% 78428.70 0.57%

Sunflower LAC 5883 5916.54 0.57% 5916.34 0.57%

Rapeseed LAC 141 142.09 0.52% 142.10 0.53%

OthCrop Brazil 9090 9034.08 -0.61% 9002.90 -0.96%

Wheat IndoMalay 1 0.55 -5.92% 0.55 -6.81%

Source: Authors’ calculations

These policy scenarios have a substantial impact on the European production of agricultural crops

(Figure 4). As a result of the development of ethanol and biodiesel, the European production of crops

used in these processes of production is increased in 2020: rapeseeds, sugar beet, wheat, maize,

soybeans and sunflower.

The production of various agricultural crops competes for common scarce productive resources (like

land). On the one hand the production of agricultural commodities for non-food purposes can have

negative consequences on other agricultural commodities through increased price of this common

resource (this effect should be limited by the presence of co-products in the analysis). On the other,

demand for food is inelastic and there should be some substitution effects in demand that could

positively affect the production of other agricultural crops. Production of other crops (rice, vegetable

and fruit) can be negatively affected but the phenomenon is limited.

Page 54: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

54

Figure 4 Variation of EU Crop Production - 2020 - (volume and percentage)

Source: Authors’ calculations

Figure 5 illustrates how agricultural value-added could be affected by these different scenarios. The

potential impact of both policies on agricultural value-added is positive in almost all

countries/regions throughout the world, in particular in the three countries/regions shown on Figure

5: Brazil, Indonesia and Malaysia, the EU and the US. These policies create more activity in the

Page 55: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

55

agricultural sector and the impact is worldwide. While the mandate is more positive for European

agricultural value-added than for Brazil and the US, the impact is larger for the US and Brazil.

Figure 5 Variation of agricultural value-added in 2020 (%)

Source: Authors’ calculations

These gains in agricultural value-added have to be compared with the cost to consumers (consumers

are negatively affected in the EU) in order to derive a net economic benefit/loss. This is done through

the calculation of welfare effects of European policies not only for the EU but also for other

countries/regions as shown in Table 6. The two policies have minimal effects on other

countries/regions welfare, except for Brazil which benefits from significant improvement in their

terms of trade thanks to their exporting status of oilseeds for biodiesel and sugar cane. As far as the

European Union is concerned both policies are neutral: in that sense the increase in agricultural

added value observed on Figure 5, is offset by negative impact of both policies on consumers’ surplus

and public receipts.

Page 56: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

56

Table 6. Real Income Impact of European Biofuel Policies, 2020 (Variation / Baseline)

REF MEU_BAU MEU_FT

Lev Lev Var Lev Var

Brazil 856 857 0.06% 857 0.08%

CAMCarib 444 444 -0.01% 444 -0.02%

China 4593 4592 0.00% 4592 -0.01%

CIS 1093 1091 -0.18% 1091 -0.17%

EU27 15182 15184 0.01% 15182 0.00%

IndoMalay 564 564 -0.02% 564 -0.03%

LAC 1605 1604 -0.05% 1604 -0.06%

RoOECD 8590 8589 -0.01% 8588 -0.01%

RoW 5639 5633 -0.11% 5633 -0.11%

SSA 912 911 -0.12% 911 -0.12%

USA 15219 15218 0.00% 15218 -0.01% World 54697 54687 -0.02% 54684 -0.02%

Source: Authors’ calculations

5.1.3 Fuel and/or Feed?

As mentioned earlier the production of biofuels also produces several by-products for which there is

current or potential demand: Dried Distillers Grains with Solubles (DDGS) obtained from the

production of ethanol and which is used as animal feed, and oilcakes (animal feeds) from biodiesel

production. When accounting for by-products, biofuels development should lead to less pressure on

food markets and in particular on markets for animals feeds. The increased availability of these by-

products should have beneficial side effects in other areas of agriculture. A biofuel mandate could

potentially lead to a positive impact on livestock production in terms of reduced prices for animal

feed.

The model used in this analysis includes by-products and illustrates how the development of biofuels

production can clearly contribute to the consumption of biofuels by-products in cattle and “other

animal” sectors. Price of meals will decrease by 0.9% to 1%, with the strongest reduction in rapeseed

cakes. In the DDGS market, the expansion in supply will lead to more substantial price changes (as

much as -45% for beet pulp in Europe) in the scenario without trade liberalization. This strong result

is related to the strong bias of the mandate towards ethanol production and the fact that the initial

DDGS market is very small. Since DDGS in the EU only goes to the domestic market in our model, and

since new trade flows cannot be generated in our framework, all the initial DDGS production is linked

Page 57: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

57

to biofuel ethanol plants.18 At the opposite end, when trade liberalization is implemented, EU

ethanol production, as well as co-products production, is sharply reduced. Since sugarcane ethanol is

not associated with a by-product in our model, the market is depleted and prices go up. With weak

substitution effects, the meal prices will decrease less (changes reduced by one-tenth).

The augmentation of consumption of co-products is driven by more availability of DDGS and oilcakes,

of which prices are reduced thanks to the EU mandate.

As illustrated in Figure 6, this is beneficial for the value-added in livestock sectors particularly in the

European Union where the reduction of prices of these intermediate commodities are more

significant than elsewhere: the value-added in the cattle sector will increase by almost 0.08% while

the one for the “Other Animals” sector will be augmented by 0.07%. The results are also positive for

value-added in the same sectors of the US. Globally the value-added in the cattle sector throughout

the world is augment by 0.04% (0.03% as far as the “Other animal” sector is concerned). In Brazil, on

the other hand, the livestock sector will suffer from land competition with the different crops (-0.07%

of pasture land, see Table 7) and a rising price of soya and other feedstocks .

Figure 6 Variation of value-added in livestock sectors in 2020 (%) – MEU_BAU scenario

Source: Authors’ calculations

18 It will be interesting to change the elasticity of substitution between DDGS and other energy feed to see if

the strong results remain.

Page 58: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

58

5.2 Land Use Effects

5.2.1 Land use

Changes in crop production, particularly due to the increased demand for feedstock crops used as

inputs in biofuels, will have different implications on the expected patterns of land use under the

mandates and trade liberalization scenarios.

Table 7 indicates the variation in land use by type of land which could be expected from these policy

scenarios. The amount of cropland is significantly affected in Brazil (+0.54% without trade

liberalization, +0.77% with trade liberalization, see Figure 7). This result is due to the combination of

the demand for ethanol (sugar cane) and oilseeds (soya) and the high elasticity of land extension for

this country. However, due to the AEZ level modeling of land extension, it appears that primary

forest are not the main source (see Figure 8 and Table 7) of new land for sugar cane production but

Savannah/Grassland (South East of Brazil). The other regions that are mostly affected are the EU, the

CIS region, the rest of Latin America and Indonesia-Malaysia. However, since land extension is more

difficult in these regions (lower elasticity of land extension), the effect is limited.

Globally the mandate increases cropland use by 0.07% in 2020 and by 0.08% under the trade

liberalization scenario, with slightly more encroachment into areas reserved for forest. The land use

changes under the two policy scenarios have implications on CO2 emissions and these are discussed

in the next section.

Page 59: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

59

Figure 7 Cropland Extension by Region, 2020, Km2

Source: Authors’ calculations

Figure 8 Source of Cropland Extension by Type of Land19

Source: Authors’ calculations

19 These results are based on estimates of past behavior on deforestation in Brazil and we do not consider new preservation

policies in the central scenario.

Page 60: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

60

Table 7. Variation of Total Land Used (thousands of km²)

2020 2020 2020 2020 2020 REF MEU_BAU MEU_FT Lev Lev Var Lev Var Cropland Brazil 888.60 893.41 0.54% 895.46 0.77%Forest_total Brazil 4391.84 4391.05 -0.02% 4390.78 -0.02%Pasture Brazil 1371.17 1370.49 -0.05% 1370.21 -0.07%SavnGrasslnd Brazil 1838.39 1835.61 -0.15% 1834.35 -0.22%Cropland China 1421.29 1421.37 0.01% 1421.37 0.01%Forest_total China 2112.52 2112.45 0.00% 2112.45 0.00%Pasture China 1083.30 1083.30 0.00% 1083.30 0.00%SavnGrasslnd China 1927.67 1927.67 0.00% 1927.67 0.00%Cropland EU27 1004.03 1004.81 0.08% 1004.49 0.05%Forest_total EU27 1449.27 1449.00 -0.02% 1449.11 -0.01%Pasture EU27 617.18 617.17 0.00% 617.18 0.00%SavnGrasslnd EU27 205.20 205.20 0.00% 205.20 0.00%Cropland IndoMalay 344.41 344.55 0.04% 344.55 0.04%Forest_total IndoMalay 867.13 867.04 -0.01% 867.04 -0.01%Pasture IndoMalay 34.05 34.02 -0.08% 34.02 -0.08%SavnGrasslnd IndoMalay 138.54 138.54 0.00% 138.54 0.00%Cropland LAC 397.51 397.91 0.10% 397.92 0.10%Forest_total LAC 3294.18 3294.07 0.00% 3294.07 0.00%Pasture LAC 794.01 794.07 0.01% 794.07 0.01%SavnGrasslnd LAC 2213.70 2213.70 0.00% 2213.70 0.00%Cropland World 12425.91 12434.11 0.07% 12435.66 0.08%Forest_total World 37704.94 37703.17 0.00% 37703.05 0.00%Pasture World 10870.45 10869.46 -0.01% 10869.26 -0.01%SavnGrasslnd World 29860.28 29857.50 -0.01% 29856.25 -0.01%Source: Authors’ calculations

Note: The land category “Other” is not displayed on the table.

An interesting question which is related to the expansion of cropland is the relative decomposition of

production increase between yield changes and extensive land use. Table 8 provides such a

decomposition at the world level for each crop. For instance, in the pure mandate case, the world

increase of 0.91% of rapeseed production is achieved by increasing land by 0.54% and by increased

use of new capital and labour per Ha (0.34%); intensification of fertilizer used plays only a minor role.

At the other hand, we see that for wheat the production increase is achieved completely by

intensification, through increased use of fertilizers and through factor intensification.

Page 61: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

61

Table 8 Decomposition of production increase

MEU_BAU MEU_FT Yield Yield Land

use Total Yield Yield Land

use Total

Factors increase

Fertilis-er

Change Production

increase

Factors increase

Fertilis-er

Change Production

Increa-se

Rapeseed 0.32% 0.04% 0.54% 0.90% 0.34% 0.02% 0.61% 0.97%PalmFruit 0.10% 0.21% 0.31% 0.10% 0.20% 0.30%Maize 0.04% 0.03% 0.01% 0.08% 0.03% 0.03% -0.01% 0.05%OthCrop 0.01% 0.00% 0.00% 0.01% 0.02% 0.02% -0.01% 0.03%OthOilSds 0.01% 0.01% -0.03% -0.01% 0.01% 0.02% -0.03% 0.00%Rice 0.00% 0.00% 0.00% 0.00% 0.00% 0.00% 0.00% 0.00%Soybeans 0.04% 0.06% 0.12% 0.22% 0.05% 0.07% 0.15% 0.27%Sugar_cb 0.66% 0.54% 2.67% 3.87% 0.62% 0.37% 3.98% 4.97%Sunflower 0.11% -0.10% 0.37% 0.38% 0.11% -0.10% 0.39% 0.40%VegFruits 0.00% 0.05% -0.06% -0.01% 0.00% 0.05% -0.06% -0.01%Wheat 0.06% 0.05% 0.00% 0.11% 0.00% 0.04% -0.09% -0.05%Source: Authors’ calculations 5.2.2 Emissions

As displayed in Table 9, the sum of land use related emissions implied by the European mandate is

107 million tons of CO2 equivalent in 2020 without trade liberalization and 118 million with

elimination of MFN duties on biodiesel and ethanol. Even without trade liberalization, most of the

emissions effects (between 50% and 60% of world emissions) are concentrated in Brazil where these

are driven by demand for sugar and soybeans. However, we see that emissions related to

deforestation represent just a share (between half and one third) of Brazilian emissions. Modeling

the land extension at the AEZ level shows that forest is less impacted than other biotopes (grassland)

due to the extension of sugar protection. Without trade liberalization the EU is the second region in

terms of direct emissions (nearly 10.63 Mios tCO2eq). Trade liberalization allows the EU to cut its

direct emissions by 40% but the CIS and Brazil will emit much more. Taking peatlands into account

plays a minor role in the broad picture (up to 1.1% in the case were largest emissions figures are

used). But if we compare these additional figures to the other CO2 emissions of Indonesia and

Malaysia, we see that these figures can add 25% to overall emissions of this region, acknowledging

the fact that it remains a minor supplier for the EU (less than 10% of EU biodiesel consumption when

we add biodiesel imports and palm oil imports) and that the mandate target implies limit increase in

biodiesel consumption.

Page 62: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

62

Table 9. Indirect land use emissions related to biofuels in 2020

(Mios tCO2eq - extra emissions are positive values)

5.6% EU Mandate 5.6% EU Mandate + Full trade liberalization on biofuels

Forest Biomass

change

Organic Carbon in

Mineral Soil

Total land use

emissions

Forest Biomass

change

Organic Carbon in

Mineral Soil

Total land use emissions

Brazil 23.97 33.33 57.30 28.50 46.02 74.52

CAMCarib 0.52 0.52 0.22 0.22 China 1.57 0.65 2.22 1.43 0.60 2.03 CIS 3.18 5.08 8.26 2.91 4.52 7.43 EU27 3.03 7.60 10.63 1.80 4.50 6.30

IndoMalay 3.39 1.53 4.92 3.38 1.53 4.90 LAC 2.63 3.58 6.21 2.71 3.70 6.41 RoOECD 1.08 2.47 3.55 0.87 2.34 3.22 RoW 1.20 0.94 2.14 0.88 0.71 1.59

SSA 1.49 4.50 5.99 1.36 4.04 5.41 USA 1.88 2.89 4.76 2.24 3.47 5.71 World 43.41 63.09 107.50 46.07 71.66 117.74 Additional MtCo2 emissions from peatlands IPCC method 0.17 Values are indentical in both scenarios at 0.01 MtCO2eq Couwenberg(2009): 1.38 Source: Authors’ calculations

As shown in Table 10, the sum of direct emissions reductions20 generated by the substitution of

fossile fuel by biofuels and implied by a European liberalization of trade in ethanol and biodiesel is

slightly higher: -21 million tons of CO2 equivalent in 2020 under the trade liberalization scenario

instead of-18 Mios. This result is driven by the increased use of sugar cane ethanol that is the most

efficient feedstock. The net emissions balance (land use emissions minus direct emission savings) is

positive and slightly larger under the liberalization case than under the pure mandate scenario. Even

if the liberalization leads to more emissions through indirect land use effects, using efficient

imported biofuels delivers a net missions reduction in a 20 year period.

20 Each MJ of fossil fuel is assumed to generate 25gr of carbon, i.e. about 92 gr. of CO2.

Page 63: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

63

Table 10 Emissions balance. Annualized figures. CO2 Mto2 eq.

MEU_BAU MEU_FTA Direct

emissions Land use

changeTotal

emissionsDirect

emissionsLand use

change Total

emissionsBrazil -0.05 2.87 2.82 -0.06 3.73 3.67CAMCarib -0.32 0.03 -0.29 0.24 0.01 0.25China -0.02 0.11 0.09 -0.02 0.10 0.08CIS 0.00 0.41 0.41 0.00 0.37 0.37EU27 -18.36 0.53 -17.83 -21.24 0.31 -20.93IndoMalay -0.01 0.25 0.24 -0.01 0.25 0.24LAC 0.01 0.31 0.32 0.01 0.32 0.33RoOECD 0.12 0.18 0.30 0.21 0.16 0.37RoW 0.02 0.11 0.13 0.02 0.08 0.10SSA 0.00 0.30 0.30 0.00 0.27 0.27USA 0.45 0.24 0.69 0.72 0.29 1.01World -18.17 5.33 -12.84 -20.11 5.89 -14.22Source: Authors’ calculations Note: Land use emissions column is based on Table 9 figures divided by 20 (years). The emissions credit is attributed to the country that consumes the biofuel. Additional peat lands emissions are not included in this table.

Table 11 displays the carbon balance sheet of the 5.6% mandate under our different scenarios. The

upper part of the table displays the total carbon release (from forest biomass and soil contents) due

to the change in land use during the 2008-2020 period following the implementation of the mandate.

The lower part shows average ILUC effect computed with our model equal to the sum of carbon

release from forest biomass and soil carbon content. All annual coefficients take the stock value of

the upper table and divides them by 20 years and divided by the increase in EU consumption of

biofuels. The average ILUC computed here is between 17.7 gCO2eq/Mj (no trade liberalization) and

19.5 gCO2eq/Mj (with trade liberalization).The net emission balance on a 20-year period is about -

42.82gCO2/MJ if the mandate is not associated with an open trade policy and slightly more under

trade liberalization (-46.93 gCO2/MJ). These coefficients are average values since they are based on

the full mandate increase (from 3.3% to 5.6%) and takes into consideration all the direct and indirect

effects in the CGE framework in terms of income and substitution effects. But they do not include

CO2 variations not related directly to the biofuel policies (such as the income effect on the steel

industry).

Page 64: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

64

Table 11. Carbon balance sheet

2020 2020 2020 REF MEU_BAU MEU_FTTotal carbon release from forest biomass (MtCO2eq) 43.41 46.07Total carbon release from organic carbon in mineral soil (MtCO2eq) 63.09 71.66EU Consumption of biofuel in 2020 (million GJ) 443 743 746Annual carbon release from forest biomass (gCO2eq/MJ) 7.23 7.61Annual carbon release from organic carbon in mineral soil (gCO2eq/MJ) 10.50 11.84Annual direct savings (gCO2/MJ) -60.55 -66.38Total emission balance on a 20 years period (gCO2/MJ) -42.82 -46.93

Source: Authors’ calculations

5.2.3 Crop specific ILUC

Applying the method described in Annex VII, we can also compute the marginal ILUC coefficient for

each crop. In this case, we investigate the marginal effect of the 5.6% mandate by increasing the

demand for biofuel in the EU27 by a marginal amount of 1 million GJ in the 2020 (about 0.1% of the

EU consumption level in 2020) situation and allowing the corresponding increase in biofuel (domestic

or imported) production to come from one feedstock only. We compute the marginal effect for each

feedstock at the end of the mandate in 2020. Table 12 displays the coefficient of emissions from land

use changes for the eight feedstocks, for ethanol – without constraint on the feedstocks - and

biodiesel. Figures are provided with and without the peatland effects. Concerning the later, we use a

simple average of the IPCC and Couwenberg coefficients.

Results show that sugarcane and sugarbeet, with the lowest marginal ILUC, are the most efficient

feedstocks in terms of land use under the mandate scenario. The average ethanol coefficients from

these two feedstocks are between 16 and 19 gCO2/Mj with a life cycle of 20 years. For wheat and

sugar beet, under trade liberalization the ILUC effect increased. Since the EU will always outsource is

supply of sugar cane ethanol in Brazil, the trade liberalization scenario has a very limited effect on

the sugar cane coefficient.

Concerning biodiesel, even if peat land emissions are considered, palm oil is the most efficient

feedstock, although still at a level three times above the emission levels for sugar cane ethanol. Palm

oil appears as an efficient feedstock and can compete with crops for two reasons: it produces co-

products, even in limited quantity and has a very high oil yield (up to six times the rapeseed yield by

hectare). The average biodiesel coefficients (between 54gCO2/Mj and 58gCO2/Mj) are between

Page 65: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

65

rapeseed oil and the soybean oil. The latter is the most costly biodiesel in terms of ILUC since the

soya market puts a lot of pressure on land extension in Brazil.

Table 12 Marginal Indirect Land Use emissions, gCO2/MJ per annum. 20 years life cycle.

MEU_BAU MEU_FT

Without Peatland effects

With Peatland effect

Without Peatland effect

With Peatland effect

Ethanol 17.74 17.74 19.16 19.18

Ethanol SugarBeet 16.07 16.08 65.48 65.47

Ethanol SugarCane 17.78 17.78 18.86 18.86

Ethanol Maize 54.11 54.12 79.10 79.15

Ethanol Wheat 37.26 37.27 16.04 16.12

Biodiesel 58.67 59.78 54.69 55.76

Palm Oil 46.40 50.13 44.63 48.31

Rapeseed Oil 53.01 53.68 50.60 51.24

Soybean Oil 74.51 75.40 67.01 67.86

Sunflower Oil 59.87 60.53 56.27 56.89

Source: Authors’ calculations Note:The marginal coefficient is computed in 2020 after the implementation of the 5.6% mandate.

Compared to the average ILUC coefficients reported in Table 11, the figures in Table 12 are slightly

different. We can provide two explanations. First, we are dealing with marginal coefficients that are

expected to be above the average due to the decreasing marginal productivity embedded in the

model (see next section). Second, as previously discussed, the mandate is mainly driven by an

increased consumption of ethanol. As shown in the production figures, this ethanol will be produced

from sugar cane (imports) and sugar beet, the most efficient feedstock in terms of land use.

The marginal ILUC effects reported in Table 12 combine with direct emissions reductions to generate

the net emissions balance reported in Table 13. Sugar cane, Sugar beet and Wheat ethanol will

generate marginal net emissions savings (negative emissions) under both the 5.6% mandate and the

trade liberalization scenario, with the strongest effect for Sugar cane. For biodiesel, only palm oil will

generate emission savings.21

21 Under the central assumption here that palm oil direct savings coefficient is 61%.

Page 66: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

66

Table 13 Marginal Net Emissions by Feedstock. gCO2/Mj. 20 years life cycle.

MEU_BAU

MEU_FT

Without Peatland effects

With Peatland effect

Without Peatland effect

With Peatland effect

Ethanol -49.69 -49.68 -53.55 -53.53

Ethanol Sugar Beet -35.86 -35.85 21.84 21.83

Ethanol SugarCane -53.95 -53.95 -55.53 -55.53

Ethanol Maize 3.64 3.65 62.82 62.87

Ethanol Wheat -7.00 -6.99 -5.02 -4.95

Biodiesel 5.95 7.06 3.63 4.70

Palm Oil -21.98 -18.25 -22.43 -18.76

Rapeseed Oil 8.76 9.42 7.42 8.06

Soybean Oil 24.07 24.96 18.95 19.80

Sunflower Oil 8.73 9.38 7.74 8.37

Source: Authors’ calculations Note: Negative figures represent an emission reduction, positive values represent an emission increase.

5.3 Sensitivity Analysis

This section discusses two aspect of the sensitive analysis done in this study:

• The policy target;

• The value of key parameters.

On the later issue, we only study alternative cases but a richer and systematic analysis should be

performed in future research.

5.3.1 Alternative Mandate Targets

We compute the average ILUC of the mandate for five levels of mandatory blending in the EU: 4.6%,

5.6%, 6.6%, 7.6% and 8.6% for the two main trade scenarios: status quo (Figure 9) and trade

liberalization (Figure 10).

As expected, the direct emission saving coefficient is reduced as the level of the mandate increases.

Greater pressure for biofuel production from a higher target results in increasing use of less efficient

feedstock. Similarly, starting with trade liberalization and a low mandate, the EU will import primarily

sugar cane ethanol and with the increasing pressure on this feedstock, domestic sources of ethanol

will become more attractive and the biofuel mix will become less efficient in terms of direct savings.

Page 67: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

67

Figure 9 Indirect land use emissions and direct savings for different mandate levels, No change in trade policy

T

Source: Authors’ calculations Note: Negative figures represent an emission reduction, positive values represent an emission increase.

Figure 10 Indirect land use emissions and direct savings for different mandate levels, Free trade

scenario

Source: Authors’ calculations Note: Negative figures represent an emission reduction, positive values represent an emission increase.

Concerning the ILUC emissions, we see a net increase of the adverse effects of the biofuel demands

on land use as the level of the mandate increases. A 4.6% mandate could be achieved without

Page 68: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

68

noticeable land use impact, however any level above this point starts to generate emissions. Moving

from 4.6 to 6.6 % will increase sharply the average emissions to reach 25gCo2/Mj. A 8.6% mandate

without trade liberalization will cut by nearly half of the emissions savings under the 4.6% mandate.

However, the total emissions balance remains positive for all the level of the mandate considered

here.

A key issue in this research is the question of whether the non-linear ILUC is just a feature of the

model or whether it also reflects an underlying reality. First, the evolution of the size of the mandate

leads to an evolution in the biofuel mix: no additional biodiesel is needed at 4.6% when about 5Mtoe

of biodiesel is required by a 8.6% mandate. Since biodiesel is less emissions friendly, the average

effect deteriorates. Second, nonlinearity of the ILUC effect can be expected from the modeling

framework. Several mechanisms contribute to this effect:

• The capacity to substitute one type of land for another: it is represented by the concavity of

the CET function in the land use module. The marginal productivity of one hectare moving

from one sector to another is declining quickly with the low elasticity used. The first unit of

land planted to barley can be transformed “easily” to wheat for instance, but this marginal

transformation ratio is deteriorating. From the modeling point of view, the CET framework is

not totally satisfactory but it remains the mainstream approach in the literature. However,

how can we explain in the reality that farmers continue to have diversified productions, even

if the price of one commodity dominates the other. Even when the wheat price is high, not

all land in Europe is not shifted to wheat. There are many possible reasons for this: desire of

diversification from farmers, real differences in land quality for the different crops, short

term perception vs long term perception etc. Overall, they will lead to the same

consequences: if farmers shift “some” units of land to the expanding crops easily, they will

not do it in a linear way. They will stop converting eventually, and if they want to produce

more of one crop, they will go for “new” land, while keeping their other production at a

certain level. It means that substitution is non linear and that there is more pressure on new

land with the increase in magnitude of demand from biofuels. A similar mechanism applies to

pasture and forest that is converted to cropland. There is limited substitution (and non

linearity due to the CET effect). It represents the fact that (a) pasture and forestry land

converted to cropland have decreasing marginal productivity, (b) there are institutional

factors that could hinder the conversion of these lands to cropland.

• The rigidity of other sectors to reduce part of their own consumption of feedstocks. The

capacity of other sectors, and final consumers, to reduce their consumption level of

feedstocks is also non linear (and represented by CES function). If they can initially forego a

Page 69: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

69

few units easily (e.g. Palm oil by cosmetic industry), their marginal propensity to do so

declines quickly (=their marginal cost to do it increase). In a symmetric way, the absorption

capacity for co-products by the livestock sector is disputable. Is it linear or not? In the model,

it is not. But it seems also that in the “real” word, people argue about the limit in DDGS, or

meals (at least one type of meal) in the animal feed.

• The saturation effect on fertilizers.

• The below-average productivity assumed for new units of land.

Every model is an abstraction of reality but should, at the same time, represent the essential features

and behavior of that reality as correctly as possible. The non-linear features in this model are widely

used in most biofuels models and indeed in most (agro-)economic models. There is sound economic

rationale behind these behavioral assumptions. Abandoning decreasing returns would go against

economic logic and common sense. On the other hand, it is difficult to estimate how strong these

decreasing returns effects should be. The available empirical evidence is limited and often very

different estimates for key parameters are available. There are two options here: extensive

sensitivity analysis on key parameters (which we do below) and collecting more robust empirical

evidence. The latter is outside the scope of this research project and may take many years to

complete.

5.3.2 Land substitution

Both sensitivity analyses (doubling the elasticity of substitution between crops, and alternatively, the

elasticity of substitution between cropland and pasture) have very similar results. Emissions are

reduced by 10% on average. Marginal ILUC is reduced by 30% since this parameter plays a key role in

defining the marginal productivity profile for the crops.

5.3.3 Land extension

If we apply Brazil's land extension elasticity to Indonesia and Malaysia, i.e. 0.10 instead of 0.05, the

ILUC effects will be stronger in this region. Emissions increase by about 4 millions of CO2eq and the

marginal ILUC of palm oil increases by 10%, reaching the same level as for rapeseed oil.

If land extension elasticity in Brazil is reduced by half, global ILUC emissions are reduced by one-third

and the total emissions balance improves. Brazilian exports to the EU are not significantly affected

since land is taken from other sectors and production becomes more intensive.

Page 70: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

70

Page 71: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

71

6 Concluding Remarks

This section summarizes our main findings and then provides some recommendations for future

research.

6.1 Lessons Learned

The main lesson learned is that ILUC does indeed have an important effect on the environmental

sustainability of biofuels. However, the size of the additional EU 2020 mandate, under current

assumptions regarding the future evolution of renewable energy use in road transport, is sufficiently

small (5.6% of road transport fuels in 2020) and does not threaten the environmental viability of

biofuels. If the underlying assumptions should change however, either because the mandated

quantities turn out to be higher and/or because the model assumptions and parameters need to be

revised, there is a real risk that ILUC could undermine the environmental viability of biofuels. Non-

linear effects, in terms of biofuels volumes and behavioural parameters, pose a risk.

At the same time, this biofuels modeling project has demonstrated how the current limits to data

availability create significant uncertainty regarding the outcomes predicted by these policy

simulations. The model represents a state of the art simulation of the real world, but more data

collection work will be required to reduce this margin of uncertainty.

In terms of trade policy, the main result is that biofuels trade liberalization would lead to slightly

more ILUC effects through deforestation outside the EU (especially in Brazil). But this is compensated

by the use of a more efficient biofuel (sugar cane ethanol) that improves emissions savings and

results in animproved CO2 emission balance. At the same time such an effect can take place only if

we assume that the share of ethanol in total biofuel consumption can increase drastically from 19%

to 45% by 2020.

Effects on food prices will remain limited (maximum +0.5% in Brazil, +0.14% in Europe). Although EU

biofuel policy has no significant real income consequences for the EU, some countries may

experience small negative effects, particularly oil exporters (-0.11% to -0.18% of real income by 2020)

and Sub-saharan Africa (-0.12%) due to the fall in oil prices and rise in food prices, respectively.

Analysis of ILUC by crop indicates that ethanol, and particularly sugar-based ethanol, will generate

the highest potential gains in terms of net emissions savings. For biodiesel, palm oil is the efficient

feedstock in terms of CO2 emissions, even if peatland emissions are taken into account.

From a methodological point of view, our study confirmed that yield response and land substitution

elasticities play a critical role in our assessment. The potential non-linearity of ILUC coefficients was

Page 72: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

72

also demonstrated. However, our main conclusions remain robust to the sensitivity analyses

performed at this stage. We have also confirmed the importance of having a high quality database

with the need of linking the value and the quantity matrix to feed the model with marginal rates of

substitution that are relevant. In terms of policy design, taking into account the biofuels mandates in

other economies was important to limit the capacity of the EU to absorb foreign production.

However, we have limited our analysis to a conservative case (5% mandates for China, Canada,

Japan, Australia, New Zealand, Switzerland, Indonesia and Indonesia) and a stronger constraint may

lead to higher ILUC impact.

Even more important is the role of the mix between ethanol and biodiesel. Depending on the

flexibility allowed for the ratio between the two biofuels, land use effects and trade policy effects can

be very different.

6.2 Suggestions for Further Research

Based on our analysis, we can underline a few directions for future research.

First, due to strong impact of the non linearity on our results, assessing the relevance of this behavior

is critical. On one hand, new modeling approach should be introduced to as an alternative to the CET

framework of land reallocation. Modeling explicit conversion costs (fixed costs) will allow explaining

the short term low elasticity of substitution existing in the literature and will be compatible with

stronger marginal productivity (no yield decrease) in the long run. As biofuel policies are expected to

be long term policies, this later approach seems reasonable. At the same time, more econometric

work is needed to estimate the behavior of EU farmers in the short and long run, in particular in the

context of the more market-oriented CAP. Similarly, assessing the relevance of the assumption on

decreasing marginal productivity of new land plays an important role here.

Second, our modeling of land extension at the AEZ level allows for the consideration of different

extension coefficients for different regions within a country. With this feature, it will be beneficial to

have access to more detailed data for an extended set of countries (beyond Brazil).

Third, different assumptions on the mix between biodiesel and ethanol should be studied.

Fourth, the role of certifications, the emergence of differentiated biofuels, crops and land prices

based on their “carbon” contents, and direct savings coefficients, should be studied to understand to

which extent minimum requirements in the EU legislation impact the market.

Fifth, the modeling of endogenous yield increases, based on research and development activities

may be useful to limit the land use effects.

Page 73: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

73

Sixth, more critical is the need to improve the overall quality of data for the EU27. In this exercise,

aside from introducing new sectors in the database, considerable effort was spent in correcting some

inconsistencies and upgrading the GTAP7 database. However, the quality of the original social

accounting matrix for the EU in the GTAP7 is very weak and some strange intersectoral linkages

remain. Moving to the latest GTAP7.1 (recently released in mid-February 2010) that includes updated

EU SAMs based on the JRC AgroSams and benefiting from the CAPRI input/outputs information

appears to be a strong requirement to provide a accurate analysis for the European Union,

particularly in looking at domestic policies.

Seventh, a higher level of geographical disaggregation is needed to gain a better understanding of

land use effects, e.g. having Canada and Australia in one region leads to an important loss of

information in terms of production allocation and elasticity of supply, but also of the carbon content

of different biotopes.

Page 74: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

74

7 ANNEXES

Annex I. Construction of the Global Biofuels Database

External data for 2004 on production, trade, tariffs and processing costs of the new sectors,

especially for ethanol and biodiesel, for use in splitting these sectors from GTAP sectors were

compiled from published sources, FAO stats and from the BACI databases. The primary feedstock

crops used in the production of liquid biofuels in the major producing countries were identified from

available literature. The input-output relationships in each biofuels producing country in the GTAP

database were then examined to determine the feedstock processing sector from which the new

ethanol and biodiesel sectors could be extracted. Since the global database is comprised of national

social accounting matrices (SAMs) which are from different years of data, some of which reflect

outdated agricultural production relationships, the global database was adjusted using agricultural

input-output relationships developed from FAO data22.

The database has been developed on a mix 2004 and 2007 data to ensure enough maturity in the

biofuels sector (especially trade pattern)

Ethanol

Data on ethanol production for 2004 and 2007, in millions of gallons, were obtained from industry

statistics provided by the Renewable Fuels Association for annual ethanol production by country.23

The data covers 33 individual countries plus a sum for “other countries”. Producer costs structure are

extracted from OECD (2008) from which data on ethanol processing costs for the major ethanol

producers (USA, Brazil, EU) were compiled. Bilateral trade for ethanol byproduct in 2004 and 2007

was obtained from the reconciled BACI trade database which is developed and maintained at CEPII.

Depending on the country, the ethanol sector was carved out either from the sugar (SGR) sector, the

other food products (OFD) sector, or the chemicals, rubber and plastics (CRP) sector and then

aggregated to create one ethanol sector. Ethanol producers were first classified according to the

primary feedstock crops used in production. The input-output accounts in the GTAP database were

then examined for each ethanol producer to determine which processing sector used a large

proportion of the feedstock as intermediate input. This is then the processing sector that is split to

create the ethanol sector in that country. For example, a large share of sugarcane production in

22 The food and agricultural input-output database is documented in Peterson (2008).

23 See: http://www.ethanolrfa.org/industry/statistics/#EIO citing F.O. Licht. Renewable Fuels Association, Homegrown for

the Homeland: Industry Outlook 2005, (Washington, DC: 2005), p. 14.

Page 75: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

75

Brazil goes to an established sugar ethanol processing sector, which is incorporated in GTAP’s

chemicals, rubber and plastic (CRP) sector in the Brazilian I-O table. Thus CRP is the sector that was

split in Brazil to extract the sugar ethanol sector. However, similar analysis indicated that it was the

sugar processing (SGR) sector that should be split in other sugar ethanol producing countries in Latin

America. Production of grain-based ethanol in the United States, Canada and in the European Union

was introduced in the data by splitting the other food products (OFD) sector where wheat and cereal

grain processing takes place.

Total consumption of ethanol in each region was computed from the data on production, total

exports and total imports. Ethanol was assumed to go directly to final household consumption and

not as an intermediate input into production. Production cost data in terms of the share of

feedstock, energy and other processing costs were used to construct technology matrices for

ethanol. These vary by country depending on the primary feedstock used in production.

In details, each feedstock is the only agricultural inputs of a sub ethanol sectors. Each ethanol sectors

will produce ethanol and and a coproduct (DDGS) except the sugar cane sector. They all share the

same techonology (intermediate consumptions, labor) except the sugar cane sector that is less

energy intensive (cogeneration).

All the sub-ethanol sectors sell their liquid ethanol to a supra ethanol sector that collects the

different varieties and provide its output to final consumers, intermediate consumption for the road

transportation sector and to export markets.

The international trade of ethanol is classified in the Harmonized System (HS) under HS6 codes

220710 and 220720 which cover undenatured and denatured ethyl alcohol, respectively. Since it is

difficult from trade information to know the exact use of ethanol (agrifood, industry or biofuel), we

prefer to rely on trade figures from F.O. Litch. Although ethanol production from different feedstocks

is introduced by splitting the appropriate food processing sectors (SGR, OFD, CRP), as guided by the

input-output relationships for each region, ethanol trade is actually classified under trade of the

GTAP beverages and tobacco (B_T) sector. It is the B_T sector that we split to take bilateral ethanol

trade and tariff information into account.

Concerning the EU tariff on ethanol, we assume an average ad valorem equivalent of 50%. However,

the effective AVE is difficult to compute since tariffs on the two types of ethanol are significantly

different and the mix difficult to define. In addition, some Member States are not applying the

specific tariffs of 220710 and 220720 but a lower one considering ethanol for biofuel as a non-

agricultural, chemical input.

Page 76: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

76

Biodiesel

Data on biodiesel production in the European Union, in million tons, were obtained from published

statistics of the European Biodiesel Board.24 Biodiesel production data for non-EU countries for 2004

was estimated based on 2007 production data for these countries, obtained from F.O. Licht25,

deflated using 2004-2007 biodiesel production average growth rate for the EU. The volume data

were converted to US$ millions using 2004 price data. Information on biodiesel processing costs was

obtained from the OECD (2006). The international trade of biodiesel is classified in under the HS 3824

position, mainly under 382490. Once again this product includes non fuel-related imports that make

difficult any direct use. Therefore, we combine HS6 trade flows from BACI, 8- or 10- digit trade flows

from the US and the EU trade data and rescale flows to match F.O. Licht estimates.

The biodiesel industry is created from the CRP sector in GTAP and relevant feedstocks are extracted

from the OFD and CRP sectors depending on the initial IO links. The technology of the sector (share

costs) is based on OECD (2008) report without any significant difference across countries, except for

the nature of the feedstock (type of vegetal oil) used.

Maize

The most important feedstock crops for biofuel production have to be treated separately in the

database in order to more accurately assess the impact of biofuels expansion on feedstock

production, prices and on land use. Wheat and sugarcane\sugar beet are both separate sectors in the

GTAP database. Maize (corn), however, is classified under the GTAP cereal grains sector which

include crops that are not used as feedstock in biofuels production. The GTAP cereal grains (GRO)

sector was split to create the maize (MAIZ) and other cereal grains (OGRO) sectors. Maize production

volume and price data for 2004, as well as production data for other cereals (barley, buckwheat,

canary seeds, fonio, millet, mixed grains, oats, and cereal grains, nes) were compiled from FAO

Production Statistics.26 This allowed us to compute the shares of maize production to total cereal

grains production in each country. Similarly, bilateral trade data from the BACI trade database for

maize and for the GTAP GRO sector allowed us to compute trade shares for maize trade to total GRO

trade for each bilateral trade flow. We then used the production shares information and trade shares

24 Available online at: http://www.ebb-eu. org/stats.php.

25 As cited in OECD (2008).

26 Available online at: http://faostat.fao.org/site/567/default.aspx.

Page 77: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

77

information to split the GRO sector into MAIZ and OGRO. We assume that the production technology

for MAIZ and OGRO in each country are the same as those used for the original sector, GRO.

Oilseed crops (Palm nut, Rapeseed, Soybeans, Sunflower Seed)

For oilseeds, we compile 2004 production volume and prices data from FAO Production Statistics for

the oilseed crops that are significant feedstocks for biodiesel production (palm nut, rapeseed,

soybeans, sunflower seed) as well as for other oilseed crops. Bilateral trade data for oilseeds used in

biodiesel, as well for the GTAP OSD sector, were obtained from the BACI trade database.

The different oilseeds are extracted from the OSD sector proportionally to their production value. No

technology differences are assumed across them. In several cases, the OSD sector in GTAP was too

small to accommodate production value estimated based on FAO statistics. In this case, we extract

resources from the OCR (other crops) sector.

Vegetable Oils (Palm oil, Rapeseed oil, Soybeans oil , Sunflower Seed Oil)

For vegetable oils, we compile 2004 production volume and prices data from FAO Production

Statistics for the vegetable oils that are used for biodiesel production (palm oil, rapeseed oil, soybean

oil, sunflower seed oil) as well as for other oilseed crops. Bilateral trade data for oilseeds used in

biodiesel, as well for the GTAP OSD sector, were obtained from the BACI trade database. In addition

to the oils value, we add the co-products value in each subsector. Each subsector technology is

defined on the relevant crushing technology where only one oilseed is used to produce one type of

vegetal oil.

Fertilizer

Fertilizers are part of the large CRP sector in GTAP. A separate treatment of fertilizers is necessary to

more adequately assess the implications of biofuels expansion on the interactions between fertilizers

and land in crop production. The production values for 2004 for nitrogen, phosphate and potash

fertilizers were obtained from production and prices data from the FAO Resource Statistics and from

published data.27 Bilateral trade data for fertilizers and for the GTAP CRP sector were obtained from

the BACI database. Tariff data were obtained from the 2004 MAcMap database. The fertilizer

production values and trade shares information were used to split the CRP sector into FERT and

CRPN. We adapt an average production technology for fertilizers based on the detailed US input-

27 FAO fertilizer production data available online at: http://faostat.fao.org/site/575/default.aspx. Price data obtained were

from: http://www.farmdoc.uiuc.edu/manage/newsletters/fefo08_13/fefo08_13.html

Page 78: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

78

output table and we assume that fertilizers are used only as an intermediate input in the crop

production sectors.

Transport Fuel

Fuels used for transport are part of GTAP’s petroleum and coal sector (P_C). A separate treatment of

transport fuels is necessary to provide a better assessment of the likely substitution between

transport biofuels and transport fuels from fossil fuels. Data on the value of consumption of fossil

fuels28 was used along with trade data to obtain the value of transport fuel production by country.

Bilateral trade data and tariffs for transport fuel were obtained from the BACI and MAcMap

databases, respectively. The transport fuel production values and trade shares information were

used to split the P_C sector into TP_C and OP_C. We assume that the production technologies for

TP_C and OP_C in each country are the same as those for the original sector, P_C. However, we

assume that in contrast to OP_C, TP_C is the main fuel product comprising 90 percent of fuels used

as intermediate input in the GTAP transport sectors (land, water and air transport) and in final

household demand. TP_C and OP_C are equally split as fuel inputs used in the production of all other

sectors.

28 From national fuel consumption data reported in (Metschies) International Fuel Prices 2005, 4th edition, available at:

http://www.international-fuel-prices.com.

Page 79: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

79

Annex II. Modeling Energy and Agricultural Processes of Production

The MIRAGE model has been expanded to address its shortcomings in the energy sector and thus

better adapt it to the specific needs of the study. It has been undertaken following a literature

review. This review reveals the existence of two main approaches to energy modeling in the

literature.

The “top-down” approach focuses on the modeling of macroeconomic activity and international

trade and derives energy demand from the activity implied by this modeling. Burniaux and Truong

(2002) for example develop an energy version of the GTAP model (the GTAP-E model) and use it to

study the impact of alternative implementations of the Kyoto Protocol on welfare and terms of trade

in eight regions of the world.

A bottom-up approach places a lot of emphasis on the technical description of the energy sector and

provides a more realistic and detailed modeling of energy efficiency. It selects the most efficient

process of energy production corresponding to a certain level of energy demand. For example the

MEGABARE model (ABARE, 1996) makes use of the technology bundle approach which introduces

substitutability between different technologies (for example between the electric arc furnace and

the basic oxygen furnace in the steel industry) while the use of a specific technology implies a

Leontief combination of primary factors and intermediate consumption.

Although this kind of approach is much more difficult to implement on a large scale, it provides very

interesting elements. For example the substitutability of capital and energy depends on whether the

model is used in a short or long term perspective. Following an energy price increase, in the short

term energy and capital are complementary while in the long term a new technology could be

adopted which utilizes more capital and less energy. Attention needs to be paid to this aspect. Finally

it is possible to envisage combining the two approaches. The CETM model for example (Rutherford et

al., 1997) manages to combine the top-down and bottom-up approach. In this model, a partial

equilibrium model of the energy sector is developed and linked to a general equilibrium model

through energy price and quantity variables.

The bottom-up approach is obviously much more realistic but at the same time it is very demanding

in terms of both data and behavioral parameters. In addition, it has been shown that the top-down

approach provides a better assessment of economic agents’ actual responses to changes in prices. As

this project focuses on the potential impact of biofuel mandates on world prices, exports and imports

Page 80: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

80

of energy and agricultural commodities and worldwide changes in land use, a top-down approach

appears to be much more suitable for the purpose of this study.

The GTAP-E model is a typical example of the top-down approach to modeling (Figure 11). The model

introduces complementarity between intermediate consumption and a composite of Value-Added

and Energy. It is worth noting that intermediate consumption does not include energy inputs

(gas/oil/coal/electricity/petroleum products), although it includes energy feedstock.

The details of the Value-Added and Energy composite are represented in Figure 12Figure 11. This

modeling approach has four main advantages. Firstly inside the energy composite, the demands for

each source of energy (electricity/coal/gas/oil/petroleum products) can have different degrees of

substitutability. In particular demand for gas, oil and petroleum products are relatively substitutable

while demand of each of these three energy sources is only moderately substitutable with coal and

electricity. Secondly in the standard GTAP model, as well as in the standard MIRAGE model capital is

as substitutable with energy as skilled labor due to the inclusion of all energy inputs in the

intermediate consumption branch of the nesting. In the GTAP-E model the inclusion of energy inputs

in the Value Added branch of the nesting allows for the differentiation of substitutabilities. Thirdly

this representation can account for the fact that investment in capital may reduce the demand for

energy and that the intensity of this relation can vary by sector.

Figure 11. Structure of production in the GTAP-E model

Page 81: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

81

Fourthly this representation of productive process can take into account both a short-term

complementarity between capital and energy and a long-term substitutability. Both the GTAP and

the MIRAGE models are based on the ‘Putty-Clay hypothesis’ which holds that old capital is sector-

specific while new capital is mobile. Thus following an increase in energy price the substitution

between capital and energy is rather limited, as in the short term most of the capital is sector

specific. However, in the long run, if the price shock is permanent, the degree of substitution is much

larger. Thus the GTAP-E model takes into account both the rigidity in energy use in the short term

and its flexibility in the long term. While the GTAP-E model represents a major progression in terms

of energy modeling we do think that it is not fully satisfactory in this case, for several reasons.

Firstly a key issue of the debate around the development of a biofuels sector and its impact on food

prices and CO2 emissions is what the literature calls the ‘indirect land use effect’. In other words

because the allocation of land to the production of agricultural feedstock for non-food purpose

decreases food supply, it exerts pressure on agricultural prices. This has a tendency to encourage an

increase in land supply, either from forest or livestock utilization and this change in itself contributes

to increased CO2 emission. One decisive element in this mechanism is how increased agricultural

prices translate into increases in land supply. In fact, faced with higher demand farmers can either

chose a more extensive production process (increased land supply under a constant yield) or a more

intensive production process (increased yield under a constant land supply). The modeling of

agricultural processes has to take this mechanism into account. This is the reason why we adopt a

new nesting, as illustrated in Figure 13.

In agricultural sectors, the output is a Leontief combination of a “modified Value Added” and a

“Modified Intermediate Consumption”. We use the term ‘modified’ as from the Value Added side it

incorporates all primary factors, plus the energy products, plus other products like fertilizers and

animal feedstock. From the intermediate consumption side it does not incorporate all commodities

used as intermediate consumption in the production process. This “Modified Value Added” is a

combination of two composites taking into account the traditional MIRAGE assumptions on the

elasticity of substitution, which is 1.1 in this case. The first one is a composite of land and either

animal feedstock in livestock sectors or fertilizers in crops sectors. It enables the key issue of choice

between intensive and extensive production processes to be tackled. The elasticity of substitution for

this CES function varies between 0.1 and 2 according to the GTAP database, except for Northern

countries for which the default elasticity is fixed to 0.1.

Page 82: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

82

Figure 12. Structure of the Capital & Energy Composite in the GTAP-E model

The other composite is a combination of the standard MIRAGE approach and the GTAP-E approach:

• It incorporates a capital-energy composite according to which investment in capital can

reduce the demand for energy;

• As only new capital is mobile, the degree of substitutability between capital and energy is

greater in the long term;

• In Figure 13, under the Capital-energy composite we incorporate the nesting illustrated in

Figure 12 which incorporates different degrees of substitutability between

coal/oil/gas/electricity/petroleum products.

• Skilled labor and the capital-energy composite are rather complementary while both can be

substituted for unskilled labor.

Page 83: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

83

Figure 13. Structure of the Production Process in Agricultural Sectors in the Revised MIRAGE Model

The paper by Burniaux and Truong (2002) was the inspiration for the elasticities of substitution of the

different CES nesting levels described above. Between energy and electricity, it is set at 1.1, between

energy and coal it is 0.5, and between fuel oil and gas it is 1.1. Based on estimates from Okagawa and

Ban (2008) - (EUKLEMS estimates), the elasticity of substitution between capital and energy is 0.2 in

Industry, 0.3 in services and 0.03 in agriculture.

Finally it is worth noting that a distinctive feature of this new version of MIRAGE is in the grouping of

intermediate consumptions into agricultural inputs/ industrial inputs/services inputs. This introduces

greater substitutability within sectors, for example substitution is higher between industrial inputs

(substitution elasticity of 0.6), than between industrial and services inputs (substitution elasticity of

0.1). At the lowest level of demand for each intermediate, firms can compare prices of domestic and

foreign inputs and as far as foreign inputs are concerned, the prices of inputs coming from different

regions. In non-agricultural sectors demand for energy exhibits specific features which are

incorporated as follows:

• In transportation sectors (Road transport and Air and Sea Transport) the demand for fuel

which is a CES composite of fossil fuel, ethanol and biodiesel, is rigidified. The modified Value

Page 84: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

84

Added is a CES composite with very low substitution elasticity (0.1) between the usual

composite (unskilled labor and a second composite which is a CES of skilled labor and a

capital and energy composite) and fuel which is a CES composite with high elasticity of

substitution (1.5) of ethanol, biodiesel and fossil fuel.

• In sectors which produce petroleum products, intermediate consumption of oil has been

rigidified. The modified intermediate consumption is a CES composite (with low elasticity,

0.1) of a composite of agricultural commodities, a composite of industrial products, a

composite of services and a composite of energy products which is a CES function (with low

elasticity) of oil, fuel (composite of ethanol, biodiesel, and fossil fuel with high elasticity, 1.5)

and of petroleum products other than fossil fuel. The share of oil in this last composite is by

far the biggest one. This implies that when demand for petroleum products increases,

demand for oil increases by nearly as much.

• In the gas distribution sector the demand for gas has been rigidified. It has been introduced

at the first level under the “modified intermediate consumption” composite, at the same

level as agricultural inputs, industrial inputs and services inputs. This CES composite is

introduced with a very low elasticity of substitution (0.1).

• In all other industrial sectors we keep the production process illustrated in Figure 4, except

that there is no land composite and that fuel is introduced in the intermediate consumption

of industrial products.

Page 85: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

85

Annex III. Final Consumer Energy Demand

Introduction of a new CES level for energy demand

Because a LES-CES calibration is more efficient for respecting income elasticity values rather than

price elasticity ones, it appeared relevant to better set the demand function in order to reflect the

low elasticity of energy demand to prices. That is why we introduced a third level in the demand

structure by setting an additional LES-CES function at the first level. The overall demand structure, as

shown in Figure 14, is therefore:

• A first LES-CES for energy treatment: note that in this first stage, income elasticities for this

function will be assumed to be one, i.e. minimum shares will be set to zero, and the function

will follow a CES behavior.

• A second LES-CES function for all other goods. This function is calibrated thanks to a specific

program that has been adjusted in order to take into account the presence of the first LES-

CES.

• A CES function in order to represent highly substitutable goods.

Figure 14. Demand Structure Adapted for Final Energy Consumption

Page 86: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

86

The direct price elasticity of fuel for transportation is calibrated at - 0.45 to reproduce the right

evolution of the EU fuel demand for transportation. It corresponds to an intermediate value in the

literature.

Page 87: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

87

Annex IV. Fertilizer Modeling

A logistic function for modeling fertilizer effect

Modeling fertilizers is a delicate task since a simple CES assumption cannot be used to represent the

impact of fertilizers on crop yield. Indeed, increasing fertilizer use could allow an increase in yields in

the short run. However, some saturation can occur and some countries cannot get higher yield

through fertilizers because of an already intensive use of them (Kumar and Goh, 2000).

We choose here to represent yield reaction to fertilizer as a logistic function. The most general

logistic functional form would be probably the most appropriate to describe how yield reacts

because it can be very precisely calibrated on biophysical data. The general form of such a function is

the following:

where f is the level of fertilizer input per ha, ymin the potential mimimum yield attainable (bottom

asymptote), ymax is the maximum yield attainable (top asymptote), y0 is the yield where the

maximum efficiency is reached (inflexion point), and a is a parameter giving the maximum efficiency

level.

However, in a CGE framework, this representation is quite complex to implement. Indeed, this

function is not convex and therefore does not guarantee the uniqueness of a solution. Second, this

function is delicate to calibrate because it incorporates many coefficients which require biophysical

information that are not available for every region. As a consequence, we decided to use a simplified

yield representation of this function. In order to ensure that the convexity is preserved, we assume

y0 > ymax-ymin\2. A set of available functions are displayed in Figure 15.

These functions therefore allow for the modeling of different levels of fertilizer saturation,

and different levels of response to an increase in fertilizer levels.

Page 88: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

88

Figure 15. Possible concave yield functional forms (ymax = 5)

Source: Authors’ calculations

Detailed parameters of the function are available upon request.

In a comparison of our logistic approach and a more traditional CES function between land and

fertilizer wherein the CES elasticity was calibrated to be comparable with the logistic elasticity at the

initial point, it appears that the differences are generally minimal (less than 4% on overall ILUC).

Page 89: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

89

Annex V. Modeling of Co-Products of Ethanol and Biodiesel

On the supply side, meals are produced by the vegetal oil sectors and we calibrate quantity and value

based on a representative crushing equation for each sector. Yields are assumed to be identical

across countries and do not change overtime. They are oilseed specific. No by-products (glycerol) of

biodiesel is considered.

For the ethanol sectors, DDGS are introduced for all sectors except the Sugar cane based industry.

For the latter, we only assume that bagasse will generate an income of 6% of the production cost but

the market is not represented explicitly.

The substitution patterns between the different feeds are different depending on their nutritional

content. Oil cakes are appreciated for their protein content (Table 14) and used as a food

complement to ordinary rations of cereals and DDGS, for which the caloric content is more relevant.

We therefore introduced two substitution degrees, based on different expressions of feed volume:

• Oil cakes: the first level of substitution describes substitution between oil cakes on the basis

of their protein content. In order to ensure a consistent substitution, the different values of

cakes where converted into protein volume, using the shares displayed inTable 15Error!

Reference source not found.. The default value for elasticity of substitution used at this level

is 5 which implies a very high substitution.

Table 14 Protein Content of Oil Cakes used for the Modeling

Protein content per ton

Rapeseed cake 38%

Soybean cake 45%

Palm kernel cake 20%

Sunflower cake 39%

Source: Authors’ calculations

• Feed, grains and DDGS input: the second level of substitution includes the aggregate of oil

cakes in substitution with other types of feed and grains and with DDGS. At this level, all

inputs are expressed in their energy content (see Table 15 showing energy content in

metabolizable energy, taken from Board on Agriculture and Renewable Resources,

Commission on Natural Resources, National Research Council (1982)). For oil cakes, an

average energy content is computed from the initial composition of oil cakes for each

country and livestock sector.

Page 90: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

90

Table 15 Energy Content of Feed for Livestock - Metabolizable Energy

Feed Livestock Mcal/t Note Rice Cattle 2.42 rice bran - ruminant Rice OthAnim 2.59 poultry 2.11 - swine 3.07 Wheat Cattle 3.08 wheat grain - ruminant Wheat OthAnim 3.13 poultry 3.02 - swine 3.25 Maize Cattle 3.03 grain - ruminant Maize OthAnim 3.34 poultry 3.38 - swine 3.3 VegFruits cattle 0.74 potato, tubers, fresh VegFruits OthAnim 0.76 poultry 0.71 - swine 0.82 OthCrop Cattle 2.9 barley, grain - ruminant OthCrop OthAnim 2.51 poultry 2.51 - swine 2.91 Rapeseed Cattle 0.33 fresh, early bloom Rapeseed OthAnim 0.29 Derived from meal value Soybeans Cattle 0.64 fresh, dough stage Soybeans OthAnim 0.54 Derived from meal value Sunflower Cattle 1.36 Sunflower, seed meal not hulled - ruminant Sunflower OthAnim 1.68 poultry 1.54 swine 1.81 SoybnCake Cattle 2.94 Soy meal 0.44 - Ruminant SoybnCake OthAnim 2.52 Poultry 2.22 - Swine 2.82 RpSdCake Cattle 2.66 Rapeseed meal prepressed - Ruminant

RpSdCake OthAnim 2.3 Extrapolated from Rapeseed summer values Poultry 2 - Swine 2.61

PalmKCake Cattle 3.1 239 kcal / MJ; source: FAO* PalmKCake OthAnim 2.5 Extrapolated - should not show in the data SunflowerCakel Cattle 2.27 Sunflower meal withou hulls, sol ext - Ruminant SunflowerCakel OthAnim 2.36 Poultry 2.08 - Swine 2.65 http://www.fao.org/ag/AGP/agpc/doc/Proceedings/manado/chap25.htm

Page 91: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

91

Annex VI. Modeling Land Use Expansion

The mechanism of land use expansion in the revised MIRAGE is based on theoretical foundation that

is supported by the literature on this issue, but at the same time was designed to be simple enough

for modeling purposes. The representation explained in this Annex has been introduced in some

previous works (Bouet et al., 2007 and Valin et al., 2008). This note explains the mechanism in play in

as much detail as possible.

1 – Modeling land use expansion: a normative approach

The first important idea is that this representation of land use is based on the principle that an

increase in the price of land used for economic activity leads to conversion of new land. Since

MIRAGE is an economic model, agents are assumed to follow an optimization behaviour. Therefore,

the rationale of agents in the model is completely different from the rationale presented in Fargione

et al. (2008) where the assessment is conducted by assuming that a producer arbitrarily plants

his\her crops on a new area of land, the type of which remains to be determined. As in the case of

most CGE models that rely on neoclassical assumptions, a producer in MIRAGE only reacts to prices

and no other rationality constraint is taken into account. Land use conversion is consequently driven

by price changes.It is also important to consider that, from the econometric point of view, the

relationship between deforestation and cropland expansion is not yet fully understood. These

phenomena are quite complex, and most of them depend on the combination of various factors

which includes prices and others. Furthermore, due to the lack of robust estimates, field specialists

and geographic economists are very reluctant to propose aggregated elasticities of prices variations

with respect to land expansion variation. Some scientists also stress that deforestation is impossible

to model (most studies about land use expansion concerns deforestation for understandable

reasons, but of course, this seems to be applicable to other). Geist and Lambin (2001) provide a very

good insight on this complex issue.

With the background given above, , a few assumptions were made for this analysis:

- Strong evidence relying on geographical analysis (even if it does not guarantee any causality

linkage), supports the fact that international markets and price incentives affect land use

decisions (see Morton et al., 2006 for geographical analysis, Ghimire et al., 2001). And it is

straightforward to infer that there is a positive correlation between land expansion and the

price level.

Page 92: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

92

- The elasticities of land expansion are usually lower than the elasticities of land use

substitution,

- Furthermore, if yield increases are capped and demand is rigid, deforestation will occur to

furnish the corresponding supply whatever the value of the elasticity. But we do not know at

what price.

However, we do not know the magnitude of the elasticities of land expansion. There are no robust

estimates from the econometric literature because of the complexity of the linkage and the highly

fragmented data available for land use in deforested regions, the lack of a continuous time series on

local prices, and more importantly, land rent, when they exist. More importantly, if we assume for

each region such an elasticity, we do not know the variation of this elasticity across regions and we

do not know its sensitivity to specific crop prices. For example, how much does deforestation in

Indonesia react to price of palm oil in comparison to deforestation in the Amazon with respect to

price of beef or soybeans?

One can therefore understand the difficulty of the task of estimating indirect land use change of

biofuels. Linking crop price changes to land use changes is a much more complex exercise than the

assessment of the contribution of biofuels to the2008 food price crisis (wherein no land expansion is

considered since it is a short term phenomena). And yet several quantitative analyses of the food

price crisis produced a wide range of estimates. A practical way to address such an issue is as follows:

- We implement in the model with the mechanisms we know, i.e. the positive correlation

between prices and land use expansion;

- We base our elasticities on working assumptions, respecting the constraints stated above

(lower than substitution elasticities but high enough to support the fact that cropland and

other managed land expansion is driven in part by demand for land products)

- We perform sensitivity analysis around these values. Values close to the substitution value

will mean that producers are indifferent between expanding their production by replacing

their production and using new land. A very low elasticity indicates that the producer will not

expand much (protected areas of natural land). A land expansion elasticity higher than the

substitution elasticities will mean that there is little competition for managed land because

producers can expand at little cost in new areas.

- We choose to adopt a neutral normative assumption concerning elasticities across regions

and crops, which means that we assume that each producer, whatever his production type

or his region, reacts the same way to a price change.

Page 93: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

93

Even if this approach is weak in terms of support of econometric evidence, it corresponds to the

most heuristic representation that we can incorporate in an economic model to represent this

complex phenomenon.

2 –Land Use Substitution

The details of this mechanism has been documented above. What is however important to keep in

mind is that a distinction is made between two types of land: managed land, which has an economic

return, and unmanaged land which is represented without any economic value.

Managed land includes in the default mode (mode P=0, P standing for “Pasture”):

- Cropland (cultivated land including permanent crops land and set aside land).

- Pastureland

- Managed forest

These different types of land are substitutes for each other. They are represented in the model in the

form of economic rental values and the representative land owner can choose to allocate the land-

productivity (homogenous to land rent values at initial year and defined as land surface adjusted by a

productivity index) between land use with different substitution levels.

When demand for a crop increases, prices for the crop go up, and more land is allocated to this crop.

This land is taken from other uses (pasture and managed forest) with respect to the respective prices

of these two other categories. In the standard specifications, the price of pasture land is directly

affected by the demand for cattle products (beef meat and dairy). Forest prices are affected by the

demand for raw wood products. The magnitude of substitution follows the Constant Elasticity of

Transformation (CET) specification:

where L1 and L2 are hectares-productivity associated with two different land uses and PL1 and

PL2 are their respective prices. A is a calibration constant and σ is the elasticity of

transformation.

If the elasticity of transformation is high, the possibility for land replacement within managed land

will allow for low prices for the increased demand for crops and aggregated cropland price will not

increase significantly. But if transformation possibilities inside managed land are smaller (for

instance, simultaneous demand for competing products on the land market; a very homogenous use

of the managed land; or very small elasticity of transformation), then cropland prices will rise in

response to the increased demand. Land use expansion will occur in response to the price increase.

Page 94: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

94

3 - Land Use Extension

The mechanism for land use expansion in each region and each AEZ can be represented with the

simple equation below:

Where

is managed land expansion into unmanaged land in region r and AEZ z: this land is

allocated to cropland

is the exogenous land evolution trend in AEZ z and region r based on historical

data

is the average price of managed land for region r and AEZ z,

is the reference price of managed land in the baseline for the region r

is an elasticity of land expansion

is the area of land available for rain-fed crops in region r and AEZ z and not already in

use

This relation has the following properties:

- In the initial year, MANAGED_LANDZini = MANAGED_LANDZtExo and therefore LANDEXT = 0

- In dynamic evolution, land expansion corresponds to the exogenous trend based on historical

trends.

- Around the initial point, LANDEXTZ is small in the exponent; therefore, land expansion

elasticity equals

- When price of cropland increases, LANDEXTZ increases and MANAGED_LAND expands. In this

framework, only demand of new land for crops is considered. Therefore, it is the price of

cropland that determines the expansion and the associated natural land uptake is attributed

to cropland.

- When LANDEXTZ increases, becomes smaller and the

elasticity of land expansion is reduced by this factor. This means that price increases need to

Page 95: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

95

be more and more important to allow expansion, reflecting the fact that land expansion

becomes harder when as more available land is used up. If this elasticity gets close to zero,

land expansion becomes indeed impossible.

Implicitly, this equation defines what other studies have referred to as a “land supply curve”. Land

supply curves are often calibrated on physical values (such as productivity displayed in Figure 17).

However, this does not really increase their robustness because the most significant indicator is the

expansion elasticity at the starting point, which depends more on behavioral factors than on

biophysical factors (even if biophysical factors can explain a part of the behavior).

In the revised MIRAGE model, the default value for land expansion has been set at the level of

substitution value between managed forest and cropland-pasture aggregate in the substitution tree

(between 0.05 and 0.1 varying by region). However, sensitivity analyses are critical on account of the

uncertainty on this parameter.

4 – A Database on Land Available at the AEZ Level

In order to use a proxy for land available for rain fed crops at the AEZ level, we computed our own

estimates by decomposing IIASA databases following the procedure outlined below:

1) Each region is associated with a reference macro region which has similar geophysical

characteristics. It is then assumed that available land distribution ratio across LGP will be

close.

2) The land distribution ratio of the LGP are distributed across AEZ (it means it is distributed

across climatic zones). For this the key of distribution is a geometric mean of cropland and

total land.

3) The land distribution ratio obtained are applied to the land available in the country.

4) The land available obtained is compared to land under cultivation at the AEZ x country level.

When land available is less than cropland area, three cases are considered:

a. If the total of land available is less than the total cropland for the aggregate region,

then cropland is considered fixed and no expansion will be possible in the region.

b. If the total of land available – cropland is positive and twice larger for the sum of the

positive terms than the sum of the negative terms, then one redistributes the

negative terms, i.e. one considers that AEZs where there is less land available than

cropland are computation biases. The gap is then redistributed across regions where

land available is higher than cropland. The key used for AEZ distribution is land

available – cropland.

Page 96: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

96

c. If the total of land available – cropland is positive but less than twice larger for the

sum of the positive terms than the sum of the negative terms, then one consider that

the data available does not allow a correct distribution of available land and no

redistribution is done. Land expansion is enabled but only for AEZs where land

available – cropland > 0.

5) Once all land available is distributed across AEZ and larger than cropland, a last step is to

check that this land_available does not exceed AEZ area of land with soil (i.e. total productive

land > land available for crop). For AEZs where this condition is not respected, the extra land

available is distributed among other AEZs using the land distribution ratio as a key of

distribution.

Therefore, the database obtained respects the following criteria:

- All land available in regions summed across AEZ matches national data from IIASA on land

available for crops;

- In each AEZ, land available is equal or greater than cropland. If equal, no expansion is

considered in the AEZ (and no decrease of cropland).

- In each AEZ, land available is less than the total quantity of productive land.

- Available land distribution across AEZ follows the distribution of the macro region mapped

with the region considered.

Applied to the aggregation of 10 regions, the distribution is displayed in

Table 16 and

Page 97: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

97

Figure 16.

Table 16 Share of Land Available for Rainfed Crop Cultivation Computed for the MIRAGE Model (km²)

RoOECD China RoW IndoMalay USA LAC Brazil CAMCarib EU27 World

AEZ1 297 1,077 1,374

AEZ2 45,883 97,840 2,227 145,950

AEZ3 19,502 998,449 19,659 100,983 1,138,593

AEZ4 30,267 16 115,237 12,250 68,796 462,927 11,377 700,870

AEZ5 45,407 284 32,734 158,354 848,911 5,285 1,090,975

AEZ6 81,214 579,105 1,544,057 67,731 2,272,107

AEZ7 5,833 298 1,242 7,373

AEZ8 68,838 16,227 157,856 207,758 73,444 8,574 532,697

AEZ9 731 709,365 108,956 87,212 33,521 939,785

AEZ10 46,740 283 24,478 80,139 2,675 39,079 193,394

AEZ11 80,196 6,450 50,422 65,656 608 36,979 240,311

AEZ12 42,983 1,827 35,634 150,950 173,797 1,399 13,814 420,404

AEZ13 28 104 8,605 8,737

AEZ14 2,471 415,007 91,014 8,379 6,103 522,974

AEZ15 2,973 1,547,775 42,379 6,221 1,599,348

AEZ16 3,215 2,145 1,830 738 4,699 12,627

AEZ17 541 323 864

AEZ18 1,056 1,056

TOTAL 470,944 34,132 4,078,761 44,984 536,901 1,305,897 3,133,958 85,792 138,070 9,829,439

Page 98: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

98

Figure 16 Land Available for Rainfed Cultivation in Unmanaged Land Area (in km²)

Source: Computed from IIASA databases to obtain AEZ distribution and using symmetric assumptions on the

share of available land under managed pasture and forest and the share of land not under management.

5 - Marginal Productivity of New Land from Expansion

The variable LANDEXTZ is not a land-productivity as in the CET structure. That is why it is necessary to

attribute a productivity factor to the new land converted to make it homogenous with the land

already in use. A first approach was to multiply the area of land by the marginal productivity of land

with respect to mean land productivity. Figure 17 shows the distribution curve that is used in the

model in order to compute the marginal yield to apply. An index of average yield for cropland is

computed by integrating the curve between the origin and the yellow dot and dividing by the x-axis

value of the yellow dot. The marginal yield for expansion is then obtained by dividing the marginal

productivity of managed land by the average productivity of cropland (this indicator is referred to as

“yield elasticity to land expansion” in the GTAP/CARB study).

However, we have relied on a much simpler approach in the final study. We assume that marginal

land productivity in all regions is half the existing average productivity and will not change. This ratio

is increased to 75% for Brazil. It is important to keep in mind that this assumption remains strong and

recent research seems to show that recent marginal land extension were taking place on land with at

least average level yields.

Page 99: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

99

Figure 17. Example of productivity distribution profile for the USA.

Note : Y axis is a relative index of potential productivity for a 0.5 x 0.5 degree grid cell in the IMAGE

model. X axis represents the productive land (cultivation potential > 0) and is normalized from 0 to

1. Black dots (thick line) represent the initial data of the distribution, sorted from the highest value

to the lowest value, on a 0.5 x 0.5 degree grid cell basis. The thin line represents the interpolation

curve defined as an 11th degree polynomial function, and interpolation points are represented with

black cross. The yellow circle represents the marginal position of arable land use expansion, under

the assumption that the most productive land is used for cropland. The red point represents the

marginal position of agricultural land expansion (cropland, pasture and managed forest) under the

assumption that the most productive land is used for this category. When managed land expand,

we consider that the marginal value to consider is the latter.

6 - Allocation of Land Expansion Between other Uses in the Model

Once land expansion is computed in the model, the difficult task of allocating it between the

different types of unmanaged land remains. In the revised MIRAGE model, because we rely primarily

on FAO data, only three different types of unmanaged land are distinguished:

- Primary forests

- Savannah and Grassland: this category is mixed with Pastureland into the reference

“Meadows and Pastures” under FAO nomenclature. With the Monfreda-Ramankutty-Foley

(2007) database that we use to distinguish the AEZ in managed land, we can disentangle

Page 100: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

100

these categories, assuming that Pastureland is associated with an economic use, whereas

Grassland and Savannah are not.

- Other land (shrubland, mountains, deserts, urbanized areas).

We then allocate the expansion following a coefficient for each land use type. This coefficient

corresponds to the proportion of the land use type which is converted to cropland when 1 ha of

cropland expansion occurs.

We use coefficients from the Winrock database (EPA RIA, Feb 2010) for countries for which this data

is available. These coefficients are estimated by remote sensing analysis and are supposed to

specifically correspond to the effect of cropland expansion. For Brazil, these coefficients are AEZ

specific and thus allows us to accurately reproduce the heterogeneity of expansion distribution

between AEZs. For other regions, we compute the distribution at the AEZ level with the national

distribution keys and we eventually adjust using cross entropy if some land use types are not

available in a specific AEZ. Therefore, the national distribution is conserved whatever the specific

repartition at the AEZ level.

It should be noted that in some regions managed land expansion can be a managed land retraction. If

so, we use the same coefficient to allocate the new land between land use, except for primary forest

that cannot be recovered by afforestation in that case. Primary forest is therefore replaced by

plantation forest.

7 - Pasture and Managed Forest Retroaction

Representation of cropland expansion into other land uses differ a lot across models depending on

the transformation possibilities between cropland, pasture and forest land. In computable general

equilibrium models (like GTAP used for CARB), the representation of land rent for cattle and forest is

such that demand for these new sectors affects land use. But in many partial equilibrium models that

do not represent demand for these types of good, (for instance the FAPRI model used by EPA for

countries other than the US29, AGLINK or other models without representation of cattle land), this

feedback effect is not represented. This is an important issue since the effect of the pasture sector on

land use can be a large source of uncertainty in results, as long as new demand for cattle is

associated with new demand for land (which seems to be the case in some areas of the Brazil

deforestation frontier). For example, some income effect in large and poor areas like Africa can have

29 The FASOM model used in the EPA assessment of biofuel carbon emissions and compute the ILUC effect

represent US cattle and US forest. It can therefore represent the effect of land requirements of these sectors.

Page 101: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

101

a significant land use effect via a drop in demand for meat following an increase in food prices due to

biofuels.

In order to test the influence of the retroaction of these sectors to biofuel policies, we considered

several variations in the modeling to better control the possible assumptions:

- The first mode (P=0) is the GTAP assumption, where all pasture land is allocated to the

production function of cattle. All pasture land is assumed to be used efficiently so that

increased demand for cattle products will require an expansion of pasture land. This

assumption is clearly not realistic for some regions, where cattle intensification is possible.

- One variant (P=1), which is used in our central scenario, relaxes the P=0 assumption by

allowing for cattle intensification using an intensification index. At the present time, this

index is computed in a very simple way: it only corresponds to the number of cattle heads

(expressed by bovine equivalent, using weight of animals as an indicator of their feed intake)

by hectare (see Table 17). This indicator could be refined to take into account the

heterogeneity of productivity of grassland, which however cannot be done easily with a non-

spatially explicit model. From this index of cattle density, we impose a level above which no

intensification is possible. For countries where no intensification is possible, we attribute all

pasture to the cattle production function. But for countries where cattle density is below the

cap, we attribute only a share of the total pasture, which corresponds to the area on which

the cattle would reach the intensification limit value. Because only a share of pastureland is

related to production, this design lowers the effect of new demand of cattle.

Table 17 Number of cattle head (bovine eq) per square kilometers for main regions

Region Cattle head eq per km2Rest of OECD countries 31China 53Rest of World 35Indonesia & Malaysia 577South Asia 790USA 44Other Latin America countries 60Brazil 118Central America and Carribeans 109EU27 168

Source: FAOSTAT (2009)

Page 102: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

102

- A second variant (P=2) is closer to the assumption in some partial equilibrium models. We

assume that intensification is possible for cattle (and also for forest), and we remove these

land types from the substitution tree. This means that there is no retroaction from

pastureland or from forest land on cropland in the model. Technically, this is done by

assuming that these sectors do not remunerate land but instead remunerate a fixed natural

resource that is not substitutable with land. Doing so, substitution can only occur within

cropland, between crop types. In this design, “managed land” area is reduced to cropland

and expansion occurs in more land types than before. It can expand in:

o Pastureland

o Managed forest

o Primary forests

o Savannah and Grassland

o Other land (shrubland, mountains, deserts, urbanized areas).

The share of pastureland and managed land affected by land use demand from cropland is no

longer distributed endogenously with respect to demand of cattle and wood but

exogenously, using fixed coefficients (more likely, Winrock coefficients).

All these mechanisms allow us to explore the different dimensions of potential impact of biofuel

policies on land use change. In turn, computing land use change allows us to compute the associated

GHG emissions. However, the detailed description of all these different linkages is done mainly for

explanatory purpose because of all uncertainties on the addressed phenomena, as already discussed

in the introduction of this annex.

Page 103: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

103

Annex VII. Measurement of Marginal Indirect Land Use Change

The indirect land use change effects from the use of different biofuel feedstock to produce an

additional 106 GJ of biofuels in the EU is computed in terms of CO2 emissions from the equilibrium

state reached under the mandate in 2020. Marginal ILUC are computed on a selection of different

scenarios for 8 different biofuel feedstock:

- Wheat

- Corn

- Sugar beet

- Sugar cane

- Rapeseed oil

- Soybean oil

- Palm oil

- Sunflower oil

The computation starts from the equilibrium state reached under the mandate in 2020. A small shock

of an extra incorporation commitment of 106 GJ is applied to the EU mandate of the level selected

(4.6%, 5.6%, 6.6%, 7.6%, or 8.6%). For this shock, the level of intermediate consumption of all

feedstock, except the one studied, is fixed for biofuel production in all regions. The extra demand of

EU for biofuel is consequently met by an extra production of biofuel with this feedstock only. This

production can be supplied domestically or come from other regions if some production capacities

exist in these other regions. This mechanism is illustrated in Figure 18.

In addition, the demand of regions other than EU for biofuel is maintained constant during the shock

to ensure that at constant production volume a country does not divert its exports and domestic

oriented production of biofuel, used with other feedstock, to exports to the EU. Similarly, trade in

biofuel to non-EU markets are considered unchanged during the marginal shock. Consequently, the

supply of biofuels across the world only varies by the extra use of the selected feedstock and this

extra production is sent to the EU for incorporation in transportation fuel. This modeling enables the

computation of the land use change effects related to the marginal shock on feedstock.

Page 104: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

104

EU Biofuel demand: x% mandate in 2020+ 106 GJ extra demand in feedstock 2

Domestic biofuelproduction

Foreign biofuelproduction

ExportsForeign

consumption

Feedstock 1

Feedstock 2

Feedstock 3

Feedstock 1

Feedstock 2

Feedstock 3

Domestic land Foreign land

Figure 18 Modeling of a Marginal ILUC Shock

Land use change emissions, expressed as gCO2/MJ and gCO2/t of biofuel, are computed from the

land use change in the model using IPCC Tier 1 methodology. Two types of emissions are considered:

- Emissions from biomass lost by deforestation: when an area of forest is converted into

cropland or grassland, the carbon content above ground and below ground is considered

released into the atmosphere. These emissions are accounted for as a stock variation and as

an annual loss on a period of amortization of twenty years (no discounting coefficient is

applied).

- Emissions from release of carbon in mineral soil: cultivation of new land under several

management practices is considered releasing carbon on an annual basis for a period of

twenty years. This carbon release is accounted for on an annual basis.

This modeling enables the comparison of the indirect land use effect with direct effects, which can be

measured with a detailed description of sector specificities. Land use change effects are also

computed by the model. The indicators which are computed are:

1) Feedstock saving per annum - Prod EU (gCO2eq / MJ and kgCO2eq / t)

Emissions Prod EU (biofuel) = Production variation (biofuel) * EU Emission factor (biofuel)

2) Feedstock saving per annum - Conso EU (gCO2eq / MJ and kgCO2eq / t)

These emissions correspond to savings from the extra world production consumed in the EU.

It is therefore computed as:

Emissions Conso EU (biofuel)

Page 105: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

105

= EU production for domestic demand (biofuel)* EU emission factor (biofuel)

+ Imports (biofuel) * Exporter emission factor (biofuel).

3) Feedstock saving per annum - Conso World (gCO2eq / MJ and kgCO2eq / t)

This indicator provides the total carbon savings for the feedstock selected at the world level,

as a consequence of the EU increase in demand. It incorporates the values from 3) but also

takes into account change in consumption of other countries affected by the EU mandate. It

is simply computed as:

Emissions Conso World (biofuel) = SumRegions [Production region (biofuel) * Region emission

factor (biofuel)]

4) Carbon payback time from 2020 (Conso EU)

Carbon payback time is computed in reference to the second direct emission indicator (2 =

Conso EU). This period of time is computed as:

Carbon payback = Land use change initial emissions (1)

/ Annual emissions savings - Conso EU (3)

The coefficients of direct GHG emissions reduction used for different biofuels feedstock in different

regions are given in the next section.

Page 106: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

106

Annex VIII: The Role of Technology Pathway

This study uses coefficients of direct GHG emissions reduction for different biofuels feedstock in

different regions, as reported in Table 18. The Set 1 values are employed in the model and the Set 2

values are considered for sensitivity analysis.

These values have no direct impact in our modeling exercise since they are only used in an ad-hoc

manner to compute the net emissions effects. They have no influence in the outcome of the

simulations. Their choice is highly debatable since they should refer to future technological paths and

different methods of estimation of the direct saving effects have been discussed in the literature. We

show in this annex the consequences of alternative values on the net emissions computations.

Final users of this research report can easily use alternative values for direct savings and combine

them with our ILUC computations to determine final net values to ensure their compatibility with

policy targets. An important debate is to determine if we should consider technological pathways

that do not match the minimum requirements of the EU legislation. The answer is not

straightforward since in each country we can have a mix of heterogeneous production processes with

different levels of energy intensity. Even if the EU manages to enforce specific standards for the

biofuels sold in its market, substitution can occur: “clean” producers will shift their production to the

EU market, and may collect a price premium, and the other producers will supply other markets. Due

to this potential substitution effects, the EU demand of high standard biofuels may still lead to the

expansion of low energy efficient suppliers, leading to contrasted effects on the environment.

However, to which extent this mechanism will take place is unclear. Our model assumes only one

average technology in each country. Future research will demonstrate if we see dual markets for

biofuels emerge (high standard vs low standard) and how the sector reacts to certification processes,

and for the later, if they are enforceable.

Page 107: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

107

Table 18 Reduction of CO2 associated with different feedstock – Values used in calculations

Feedstock Set 1 Set 2 Source (Set 1)

Wheat (EU) -45% -53% EU Dir (2009)

Wheat (Other) -32% -50% EU Dir (2009)

Maize (EU) -56% -56% EU Dir (2009)

Maize (USA)* -46% -69% EPA (2009)

Maize (Other)** -29% -29% FAO (2008)

Sugar Beet -61% -61% EU Dir (2009)

Sugar Cane -71% -71% EU Dir (2009)

Soya -40% -50% EU Dir (2009)

Rapeseed -45% -50% EU Dir (2009)

Palm Oil -36% -62% EU Dir (2009)

Sunflower -58% -58% EU Dir (2009)

Sources: European Council, (2009). Directive of the European Parliament and of the Council on the promotion of the use of

energy from renewable sources, EPA assessment, JEC estimates (substitution method).

* EPA (2009) Draft Regulatory Impact Analysis: Changes to Renewable Fuel Standard Program

** FAO (2008),The State of Food and Agriculture

Sensitivity analysis: Alternative CO2 direct savings figures

As previously discussed, looking at alternative direct savings coefficients has different

interpretations. On one hand, we can consider that our capacity to measure efficiently these

coefficients today is delicate, in particular if we consider if we assume technologies implemented in

2020. On the other hand, it also represents how the country-level mix of different technologies for a

biofuel will evolve with time. Since we rely on average coefficient in each country, looking for higher

saving coefficients in absolute level will represent the increase of the share of energy-efficient

producers (plants powered by gas or cogeneration) and the decrease of less efficient producers (e.g.

coal powered plants). Using the set 2 instead of the set 1 does not change the main picture. Direct

savings are improved slightly but the main difference is between the two trade scenarios. Indeed,

trade liberalization leads to a decline in EU ethanol production, in particular wheat based ethanol

and increase the share of sugar cane ethanol in EU consumption. Since the set 2 increases direct

savings of wheat ethanol, the gap between the two scenarios is slightly reduced. Finally, the set 2

improves the net emissions of the palm oil and make it the most attractive vegetal oil (under a

median assumption concerning peat land emissions).

Page 108: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

108

Annex IX: The Role of Land Extension Coefficients

The choice of extension coefficients plays a critical role in the CO2 emissions related to the ILUC.

Indeed, they distribute the increase (or decrease) of agricultural land over the different ecosystems.

With each ecosystem being associated with different CO2 contents, the distribution of the land

extension across them defines the CO2 emissions related to the ILUC. Put differently, for the same

amount of “new” land requested by agriculture, the emissions outcome may vary largely just due to

the value of these coefficients. In this report, we use coefficients computed by Winrock International

for the US EPA as reported in Table 19.

Table 19 Land Extension Coefficients

ForestManaged ForestPrimary Other Pasture Savannah & Grassland

Argentina 16.4% 0.0% 24.7% 35.6% 23.3% Brazil 0.5% 16.3% 11.2% 23.5% 48.5% CAMCarib 0.0% 30.4% 10.7% 16.1% 42.9% Canada 1.4% 7.8% 42.5% 32.2% 16.1% China 5.6% 2.2% 27.3% 39.0% 26.0% CIS 3.7% 5.6% 33.3% 30.7% 26.7% EU27 8.4% 0.4% 23.5% 36.8% 30.9% IndoMalay 3.2% 51.7% 7.0% 7.0% 31.0% LAC 17.8% 10.8% 14.3% 23.4% 33.8% Oceania 9.0% 0.0% 32.6% 36.0% 22.5% RoOECD 14.6% 0.0% 18.8% 20.8% 45.8% RoW 3.4% 3.7% 36.9% 39.3% 16.7% SEasia 1.1% 20.4% 21.5% 23.1% 33.8% SouthAfrica 1.1% 5.1% 28.4% 43.2% 22.2% SouthAsia 12.7% 0.0% 32.4% 31.0% 23.9% SSA 0.1% 13.0% 16.7% 28.6% 41.7% USA 5.4% 2.5% 21.1% 47.4% 23.7%

Source: EPA (2010) based on Winrock International computations Note: For Brazil, the model used AEZ specific coefficients. Figures in the table are simple average of the AEZ values.

Page 109: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

109

Annex X. Biofuels Policies

EU Biofuel Policies

The European Biofuel policy is quite complex because it is driven not only by the Biofuel Directive,

but also by others directives and regulations related to Energy, Fuels Quality, Agriculture and Trade

Policies.

The Biofuel Directive30 introduces some constraints on the substitution requirements of fossil fuels

by biofuels. The main goal of this policy is to reduce greenhouse gas emissions particularly in

transportation and to lessen dependence on fossil fuels by diversifying energy sources, especially

towards environmentally friendly technologies. For this purpose, this Directive prescribes several

mandates for biofuel blending with current fuels at different dates. The first objective was, for each

EU member to have a 2% market share for biofuels in 2005, then 5.75% in 2010. With the recent

Renewable Energy Directive, a target of (at least) 10% in 2020 was added.

In order to help EU members with the implementation of the previous Directive, the Energy Tax

Directive authorises the EU countries to introduce some tax reductions and exemptions for

biofuels.31 The application of both directives differs from one EU country to another. Austria,

Belgium, Germany and Luxembourg have obtained the best results in response to the targets of the

Biofuels Directive. They have reached a 2.5 to 2.75 % market share for biofuels. Moreover, other

developing EU members have also attained the 2005-target: Slovenia (2.5% in 2006), Latvia (2.75% in

2006), Greece (2% in 2005 and 2006) and the Czech Republic (3.7% in 2005 and 1.78% in 2006).

However, some other EU members have not yet fulfilled their biofuel commitments, despite various

incentives (e.g. United Kingdom, Malta, Cyprus, etc.). For instance, the United Kingdom, although it

has not applied any energy tax reduction/exemption, has favouring production subsidies and capital

grants for biofuel projects. Austria, Germany and France have all taken similar approaches, reducing

or exempting biofuel production from taxes imposed on mineral oils, depending on the biofuel type

(e.g. ethanol or biodiesel) and the level of blending (i.e. Austria exempts 100% tax for pure biodiesel

but only slightly reduces this tax for 5%-ethanol gasoline).

The Common Agricultural Policy also plays an important role in encouraging biofuels production.

Since the 2003-CAP Reform, the supply of energy crops has benefited from direct payments and

decoupled support without any set-aside obligation and without any loss of income support.

30 Directive 2003/30/EC of 8 May 2003 concerning biofuel promotion for transport use.

31 Energy Tax Directive 2003/96/EC of 27 October 2003.

Page 110: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

110

Moreover, these energy crops also benefit from a premium over the price received by producers and

following the Common Market Organisation regulation, sugar beet production for ethanol is

exempted from production quotas.

EU trade policies also affect domestic biofuel production as well as reducing export opportunities

and production incentives for foreign biofuel producers (e.g. USA, Brazil, Indonesia, Malaysia, etc.).

The Most Favourite Nation (MFN) duty for biodiesel is 6.5%, while for ethanol tariff barriers are

higher (€19.2 /hectolitre for the HS6 code 220710 and €10.2 / hectolitre for the code 220720). Even

if tariffs for biodiesel were to be reduced, trade would still have to face more restrictive non-tariff

barriers (NTBs) in the form of quality and environmental standards, which already mostly affect

developing country exporters.

Nevertheless, some European partners already benefit from a duty-free access for biofuels under the

Everything But Arms Initiative, the Cotonou Agreement, the Euro-Med Agreements and the

Generalised System of Preferences Plus. Many ethanol exporters, such as Guatemala, South Africa

and Zimbabwe, use this free access opportunity. However, most ethanol imports come from Brazil

and Pakistan under the ordinary European GSP without any preference for either since 2006.

Concerning European biofuel exports, the EU has a preferential access for ethanol in Norway through

tariff-rate quotas (i.e. 164 thousand hectolitres for the code 220710 and 14.34 thousand hectolitres

for 220720).

Trade liberalisation for biofuels is a contentious issue in the multilateral negotiation of the Doha

Round (being relevant both to discussions on agricultural trade liberalisation and trade and

environment) as well as in the bi-lateral negotiations between the EU and the Mercosur countries.

Clearly key countries, products and interests are common to both.

Brazilian Biofuel Policies

Ethanol policies have been implemented in Brazil since the mid-70s and today blending obligations

for ethanol are up to 20-25% for gasoline. More recently, Brazil has introduced biodiesel blending

targets of 2% in 2008 and 5% in 2013, similar to the EU’s.

In order to reach these obligations, Brazilian federal and state governments grant tax

reductions/exemptions. The level of advantage varies on the basis of the size of the agro-producers

and the level of development of each Brazilian region.

The Common External Tariff (CET) of Mercosur also protects domestic biofuel production, with

ethanol duties of 20% and biodiesel 14%. These tariffs could be eliminated or significantly reduced

under the Doha and/or the EU-Mercosur negotiations. Furthermore, no non-tariff barriers constrain

Brazilian imports of biofuels (e.g. no TRQ on biofuels in Mercosur).

Page 111: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

111

Another important explanatory factor in the growth of the ethanol sector in Brazil is the role of

foreign investment. Most recent investments come from Europe and the United States. They not

only concern distillation plants but also sugar cane production. The competitive prices of raw

materials and the high level of integration in the process explain the lower costs for ethanol

production in Brazil and the motivation of the foreign investors.

US Biofuel Policies

In the USA, as in Brazil, Biofuels policies date back to the 70s. However they are as complex as those

of the EU because fiscal incentives and mandates vary from one state to another and differ from

federal ones. The Energy Tax Act of 1978 introduces tax exemption and subsidies for the blending of

ethanol in gasoline. In contrast, biodiesel subsides are more recent, they were introduced in 1998

with the Conservation Reauthorization Act.

Concerning mandates on biofuels consumption, they were instigated by the Energy Policy Act of

2005 at the federal level, although obligations for biofuel use existed at the state level (e.g.

Minnesota introduced a mandate on biofuels before the federal government, which it increased to

20% in 2013). This 2005 Act sets the objective of the purchasing of 4 billion gallons of biofuels in 2006

and 7.5 billion gallons in 2012.

The current biofuels policies in the USA consist of three main tools output-linked measures, support

for input factors and consumption subsidies. Tariffs and mandates benefit biofuels producers

through price support. Tariffs on ethanol (24% in equivalent ad valorem) are higher than biodiesel

(1% in equivalent ad valorem) which limit imports especially from Brazil. Moreover, producers

benefit from tax credits based on biofuels blend into fuels. The Volumetric Ethanol Excise Tax Credit

(VEETC) and the Volumetric Biodiesel Excise Tax Credit (VBETC) provide the single largest subsidies to

biofuels, although there are additional subsidies linked to biofuel outputs.32

Investments in biofuels also receive financial support from the government, as a kind of capital

subsidies. Support is also provided for labor and land used in biofuel production in some states (e.g.

Washington). Input subsidies are another important element in biofuel support in the USA. US

ethanol production overwhelmingly uses corn which is one of the most heavily subsidized crops in

the country. In contrast, soybeans, which are the main feedstock used for biodiesel production in the

USA, are not very subsidized in the USA, which means that prices are not inflated and production is

less attractive for farmers. Finally, indirect biofuel consumption is also supported by the federal

32 E.g. a federal small producer tax credit - equivalent to a 10% tax credit per gallon on the first 15 million

gallons produced -, blenders’ credits, supplier tax refunds and other subsidies at the state level

Page 112: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

112

government through investment in infrastructure for transport, storage and distribution (Koplow,

2006; Koplow, 2007).

Modeling Biofuel Policies

In order to calibrate the model and to run the different simulation scenarios for the European biofuel

policies, we need to build a “policy” data set and to identify some technical requirements to be

incorporated into the model.

Obligations in Substitution Requirements for Biofuels

The EU members are required to report to the Commission on their implementation of biofuel

policies. Considering the development disparities, the implementation of these policies is largely

developed in larger countries such as France, Germany or Austria and not in small countries such as

Malta and Cyprus. However, the EU mandate for the share of biofuel in fossil fuel according to their

energy content is compulsory for all countries. Only 5 of 27 EU members have reached the 5% target

for 2005. One year later this number had doubled and today it shows a positive trend.

Using the national reports to the European Commission relating each country’s biofuel policies, we

have built a new database that contains the real percentage of biofuels in fuels according to their

energy content (from 2003 to 2006) and the national and European targets for the years up to 2020.

For a better use of this database, we differentiate between biodiesel and ethanol with details of how

much these percentages in energy content terms represent in percentage of the final product (by

volume), in order to have better information for the model calibration.

Table 20 shows detailed information about the past application of the biofuels mandates for the

European Union since 2003 and the prospective application and targets up to 2020.

Page 113: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

113

Table 20 Biofuel Use and Mandates in the European countries (% of energy content)

Countries GTAP Consumption

weight

2003 2004 2006 2007 2008 2009

use EU target use (*) EU target use (*) EU mandate

Austria 0,015 0,06 1,28 2,5 2 2,5 4,3 5,75 5,75 5,75 5,75 10 10

Belgium 0,028 0 1 2 2 2,75 3,5 4,25 5 5,75 5,75 10 10

Bulgaria 0,003 0 0 0 2 0 0 0 0 0 5,75 0 10

Cyprus 0,001 0 0,5 1 2 1 1 2 2 2 5,75 10 10

Czeck Republic 0,012 1,12 2,41 3,7 2 1,78 1,63 2,45 2,71 3,27 5,75 10 10

Germany 0,2 1,18 2,54 3,9 2 2 5,75 7,15 7,88 8,6 5,75 10 10

Danemark 0,009 0,17 0,24 0,27 2 0,39 1,73 3,07 4,41 5,75 5,75 10 10

Spain 0,079 0,76 1,38 2 2 3,34 4,62 6 7,26 8,66 5,75 10 10

Estonia 0,001 0 0,1 0,2 2 2 2,13 2,25 2,38 2,5 5,75 10 10

Finland 0,005 0,1 0,1 0,1 2 1,75 3,37 5,05 6,63 8,35 5,75 10 10

France 0,176 0,68 1,34 2 2 1,75 3,5 5,75 6,25 7 5,75 10 10

Great Britain 0,16 0,03 0,3 0,3 2 0,73 1,15 2 2,8 3,5 5,75 10 10

Greece 0,012 0 0,35 0,7 2 2,5 3 4 5 5,75 5,75 10 10

Hungary 0,012 0 0,4 0,6 2 1,63 2,66 3,69 4,72 5,75 5,75 10 10

Ireland 0,006 0 0,03 0,06 2 1,14 1,75 2,24 4,18 6,12 5,75 10 10

Italy 0,129 0,5 0,75 1 2 2 2 3 4 5 5,75 10 10

Lituania 0,002 0 1 2 2 2,75 3,5 4,25 5 5,75 5,75 10 10

Luxembourg 0,002 0 0 0 2 2,75 2,75 2,75 2,75 5,75 5,75 10 10

Latvia 0,002 0,21 1,11 2 2 2,75 3,5 4,25 5 5,75 5,75 10 10

Malta 0 0 0,15 0,3 2 1,92 3,5 5,15 6,7 8,38 5,75 10 10

Netherdlands 0,027 0,03 1,02 2 2 2 2 2,94 3,88 5,75 5,75 10 10

Poland 0,03 0,49 0,5 0,5 2 1,5 2,3 3,16 4,03 5,75 5,75 10 10

Portugal 0,022 0 1 2 2 2 3 5,75 5,75 5,75 5,75 10 10

Romania 0,006 0 0 0 2 0 0 0 0 0 5,75 0 10

Slovakia 0,006 0,14 1,07 2 2 2,5 3,2 4 4,9 5,75 5,75 10 10

Slovenia 0,003 0 0 0 2 1,2 2 3 4 5 5,75 10 10

Sweden 0,019 1,33 2,17 3 2 3,55 4,1 4,65 5,2 5,75 5,75 10 10

EU27 0,54 1,2 1,81 2 1,8 3,18 4,47 5,21 6,05 5,75 9,59 10

20202005 2010

Source: Source: Cepii's calculations based on European Commission - National Reports

Notes: (*) calculated based on national targets and mandates

National incorporation rates will need to be aggregated at the EU27 level in order to be used with

the model aggregation, first in the baseline up to 2007 and then in scenarios up to 2020.

In the baseline scenario, we also need to take into account the mandates for biofuel blending in

other important countries, such as Brazil and the United States. According to the IEA databases and

ACG (2005), Brazilian bio-ethanol consumption ratio between 2005 and 2010 should increase and,

according to the forecast, lead to about a 40% increase in production. Today Brazil blends between

20-25% of bio-ethanol with gasoline. Since 2005, the Brazilian government has been trying to repeat

their ethanol policy with biodiesel and new mandatory targets for biodiesel blending have been set

for 2008, increasing up to 2013 (see Table 21). For the United States, some mandatory incorporation

has also been ruled out.

Page 114: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

114

Table 21. Current official targets on share of biofuel in total road-fuel consumption

Countries Official Targets Year Products

India 5% In near future BiofuelsJapan 500 million litres 2010

China 15% 2020 total renewable fuelsThailand 2% 2010 Biofuels

Brazil 20-25% 2006 Ethanol40% increase in production 2005-2010 Ethanol

2% 2008 biodiesel5% 2013 biodiesel

Indonesia 2% of total fuels 2010 biodiesel (palm oil)5% of total fuels 2025 biodiesel (palm oil)

Malaysia 5% In near future biodiesel (palm oil)USA 2.78% 2006 Ethanol

Canada 3.5% 2010 Ethanol

Source: IEA database; ACG (2005); USDA Brazil report (2007); IFQC Biofuels Center (2006).

The modeling of the mandates requires firstly splitting the petroleum and coal product sector (p_c)

from the GTAP database into the petroleum and coal sectors (p_c_fuels and p_c_others). This aspect

was essential to introducing the consumption obligations for fuels in the transport sector.

Secondly, even if the biofuel demand without mandate is calibrated assuming a CES function, the

introduction of the mandate implies removing substitution possibilities and using a Leontief

structure. As a consequence, for our different mandate scenarios, we will impose fixed shares

between each biofuel and fossil-fuels. Moreover, we interpret the blending requirement for each

biofuel in a different way, which means that the mandate is global but rather there is a specific

mandate modeling by biofuel type.

Tax Incentives for Biofuels

The implementation of biofuel consumption mandates is coupled with other support measures.

Each European country can chose their policy tools independently in order to facilitate and

encourage biofuel consumption. More specifically, each European member state can grant tax

reductions/exemptions on biofuel production or consumption in order to reach the European

mandatory consumption target. However, there is no prescription for implementing these tax

incentives (e.g. type of biofuels, blending level, taxes, investment grants, etc.), and each member

state can design its own policy in line with its tax system and the national context. This discretionary

implementation of tax incentives makes it harder to represent the total biofuel support at the

European level.

Page 115: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

115

National reports of each Member State detail national taxes/subsidies support at the production

and consumption level and these can be used to build a database for implementing the baseline and

different scenarios in our model. Once the EU database on different biofuels support measures was

completed, we calculated an equivalent ad valorem tax/subsidy on consumption, to get an estimate

of the effect of support measures at the European level.

Table 22. Diesel and Biodiesel excise taxes in the European Union ($/liter).

GTAP Consumption weight 2005 2006 2007 2005 2006 2007 2005 2006 2007

AUT 0,015 0,371 0,368 0,368 0,397 0,409 0,403 -0,025 -0,041 -0,035

BEL 0,028 0,407 0,423 0,407 0,000 0,459 0,202 0,407 -0,036 0,204BGR 0,003

CYP 0,001CZE 0,012 0,411 0,435 0,435 0,384 0,409 0,411 0,027 0,026 0,025

DEU 0,200 0,583 0,583 0,583 0,583 0,508 0,000 0,000 0,074 0,583DNK 0,009 0,502 0,501 0,501 0,037 0,434 0,440 0,464 0,067 0,061ESP 0,079 0,365 0,365 0,374 0,335 0,335 0,335 0,030 0,030 0,040

EST 0,001FIN 0,005 0,396 0,396 0,396 0,000 0,000 0,396 0,396 0,396 0,000

FRA 0,176 0,517 0,517 0,531 0,409 0,409 0,310 0,108 0,108 0,221GBR 0,160 0,304 0,304 0,342 0,000 0,000 0,322 0,304 0,304 0,020

GRC 0,012 0,859 0,857 0,879 0,397 0,360 0,358 0,462 0,497 0,521HUN 0,012 0,409 0,399 0,399 0,422 0,422 0,422 -0,012 -0,022 -0,022

IRL 0,006 0,456 0,456 0,456 0,459 0,459 0,456 -0,002 -0,002 0,000ITA 0,129 0,506 0,512 0,516 0,471 0,512 0,474 0,035 0,000 0,042

LTU 0,002LUX 0,002 0,339 0,345 0,360 0,057 0,062 0,000 0,281 0,283 0,360

LVA 0,002MLT 0,000

NLD 0,027 0,453 0,453 0,460 0,000 0,384 0,378 0,453 0,068 0,082POL 0,030 0,320 0,362 0,363 0,000 0,310 0,322 0,320 0,052 0,041

PRT 0,022 0,386 0,389 0,451 0,000 0,000 0,000 0,386 0,389 0,451ROM 0,006

SKV 0,006 0,466 0,482 0,482 0,434 0,434 0,476 0,032 0,048 0,006SLK 0,003

SWE 0,019 0,472 0,491 0,498 0,459 0,484 0,484 0,013 0,007 0,015EU27 0,439 0,442 0,454 0,311 0,338 0,260 0,128 0,105 0,193

Diesel tax 2004 dollar/liter

Biodiesel tax exemption 2004

dollar/literBiodiesel tax 2004

dollar/liter

Source: CEPII's calculations based on European Environment Agency, OECD (for diesel tax) and Biofuels at what cost? EU,

IISD (for biofuels tax exemptions).

Table 23. Gasoline and Ethanol excise taxes in the European Union ($/liter).

Page 116: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

116

GTAP Consumption weight 2005 2006 2007 2005 2006 2007 2005 2006 2007

AUT 0,015 0,517 0,517 0,517 0,533 0,533 0,552 -0,016 -0,016 -0,035

BEL 0,028 0,682 0,734 0,734 0,000 0,732 0,438 0,682 0,002 0,296BGR 0,003

CYP 0,001CZE 0,012 0,489 0,518 0,518 0,372 0,037 0,037 0,117 0,481 0,481

DEU 0,200 0,812 0,812 0,812 0,806 0,806 0,123 0,006 0,006 0,690DNK 0,009 0,672 0,677 0,677 0,347 0,347 0,000 0,325 0,330 0,677ESP 0,079 0,491 0,491 0,491 0,459 0,459 0,461 0,032 0,032 0,030

EST 0,001FIN 0,005 0,729 0,729 0,729 0,000 0,000 0,000 0,729 0,729 0,729

FRA 0,176 0,730 0,730 0,753 0,471 0,471 0,409 0,259 0,259 0,343GBR 0,160 0,367 0,367 0,410 0,000 0,000 0,000 0,367 0,367 0,410

GRC 0,012 0,859 0,857 0,879 0,347 0,347 0,358 0,512 0,510 0,521HUN 0,012 0,498 0,486 0,486 0,508 0,508 0,513 -0,011 -0,022 -0,027

IRL 0,006 0,549 0,549 0,549 0,546 0,546 0,549 0,004 0,004 0,000ITA 0,129 0,686 0,699 0,699 0,000 0,000 0,000 0,686 0,699 0,699

LTU 0,002LUX 0,002 0,548 0,548 0,573 0,097 0,099 0,000 0,451 0,449 0,573

LVA 0,002MLT 0,000

NLD 0,027 0,826 0,828 0,842 0,000 0,620 0,626 0,826 0,208 0,216POL 0,030 0,429 0,444 0,525 0,000 0,459 0,484 0,429 -0,015 0,041

PRT 0,022 0,670 0,692 0,723 0,000 0,000 0,000 0,670 0,692 0,723ROM 0,006

SKV 0,006 0,498 0,516 0,516 0,459 0,459 0,461 0,039 0,057 0,055SLK 0,003

SWE 0,019 0,660 0,668 0,678 0,682 0,682 0,657 -0,022 -0,014 0,021EU27 0,605 0,610 0,625 0,325 0,372 0,214 0,280 0,238 0,411

Gasoline tax 2004 dollar/liter

Ethanol tax exemption 2004

dollar/literEthanol tax 2004

dollar/liter

Source: CEPII's calculations based on European Environment Agency, OECD (for fuel tax) and Biofuels at what cost? EU, IISD

(for biofuels tax exemptions).

In the European Union other incentives do exist, but since excise tax exemption represents more

than 60% of biofuel fiscal policy incentive we will run our scenarios based on this consumption

tax/subsidy.

In the case of Brazil, there are many different consumption and production incentives. Production

incentives for oilseed production include tax reductions and exemptions, especially federal taxes

whose reduction level depends on the agriculture type and on the production regions (e.g. only

subsistence agriculture from the North are exempted from federal taxes, while large agricultural

producers from the South only benefit from a 32% tax reduction). Each biofuel project also benefits

Page 117: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

117

from loan assistance and there are also some tax reductions at the industrial level. Brazilian states

also apply different tax incentives on consumption (e.g. 12% tax for biofuels and between 12-17%

for fossil-fuels). There are also price control policies for biofuels as well as other policies to motivate

the use of flex-fuel vehicles. Since it is important to introduce Brazilian supports into the baseline, it

will be necessary to have a national measure taking into account these differences across states.

Agricultural Policy

Since the 2003 CAP reform, decoupled policies have been applied to EU energy crops without any

loss of income and without the initial restrictions due to set-aside obligations. Moreover, the

production of energy crops benefits from a premium of €45 / hectare with a maximum of 1.5 million

hectares. Biofuels production in the European Union is also encouraged by the special provision

included in the CAP for agricultural inputs.

Concerning sugar beet for ethanol production, the CAP exempts this part of the supply from

production quotas. This last policy is part of the last Common Market Organisation sugar reform.

Production quota exemptions for sugar and premiums on energy crops have to be taken into account

in modeling EU biofuel support. The sectoral split between energy crops and food crops could be

important to implementing these policies.

Focus on some Biofuels policies considered in the Baseline scenario

For the baseline scenario we introduce the current biofuel policies in the EU27, the USA and Brazil

into the model. These countries mandate a target blend ratio for the percentage of biofuels, which

should be incorporated into fossil fuels. In order to reach their objectives these countries

simultaneously implement various fiscal aids and grants, which are incorporated into the model.

In the EU27, policy in this area is decided at Member State level. Biofuel blend targets are therefore

compulsory for some countries, but not all. Today, only nine of the twenty-seven European countries

have set a mandatory requirement for biofuel blend ratios. They couple these obligations with fiscal

incentives, which also vary from one country to another. Most of them involve total or partial

reductions in excise-tax on biofuel blended transport fuels or tax-free biofuel quotas. Others also

include output or input subsidies, the latter supported by the Common Agricultural Policy (CAP).

Finally, there are some countries that provide investment grants to biofuel development projects,

such as flex-fuels cars or biofuel distribution infrastructure.

The heterogeneity in the European biofuels’ policy makes it difficult to simulate scenarios at the EU

level. For that reason we have introduced some assumptions into the simulations. In the case of the

baseline scenario, we have introduced the EU targets for biofuel use (at least 2% in 2005 and 3.3% in

Page 118: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

118

2008). At the country level, some countries, but by no means all, have reached the 2005 target. We

construct our baseline scenario for the level of biofuels blending with fossil fuels on the basis of the

mean (consumption weighted) development in blending shares at the EU27 level.

We modeled the excise-tax reduction by calculating the mean (consumption weighted) values for

each year since 2004 at the EU27 level. For instance, in 2004 the average excise-tax credit was $0.578

per liter of biodiesel and $0.634 per liter of ethanol. In 2007 the tax credit for biodiesel was slightly

lower ($0.544 per liter) while that for ethanol was slightly higher ($0.649 per liter) (Kutas et. al,

2007). For model calibration and for the baseline scenario we use the tax excise credit data from the

existing literature because the values are very incomplete for the moment and in addition they are

lower than those in other key papers. Although, as indicated above, there are several other more

marginal policy measures which impact on the biofuel market and which could have been considered

(energy crop payment, set-aside payment and market price support), we only model the excise-tax

credit because it represent more than 60% of the total effective support for biofuels provided in the

EU. The CAP is also modeled, but without taking into account certain detailed policies related to

biofuels (e.g. the “no production quota” for sugar beet). Other key policies including biofuel trade

protection are also considered and the mandate mechanism is explicitly modeled.

In the USA, both a federal mandate and state-level targets or mandates for biofuel blends exist. The

federal objective is that 15.2 billion liters (equivalent to 2.78% of gasoline consumption) should be

consumed in 2006 and 28.4 billion liters (equivalent to 5.2%) by 2012. At state level, these objectives

may vary. For instance, Iowa State has set a target of 10% by 2009 and 25% by 2020. This is one of

the highest targets in the USA, where targets do not generally exceed 20%. According to

AgraFNP(2008) the ethanol industry is lobbying for a higher level of blending - up to 12 or 13%.

However, so far levels have remained lower, so we only introduce a mandate of 10% for biofuel

blending in the baseline.

Subsidies are an important policy tool. Since 2004 the federal and state governments replaced fuel-

tax exemption for biofuels with volumetric subsidies or/and consumption mandates. At the federal

level the volumetric excise-tax credit for ethanol is $0.135 per liter and for biodiesel it is $0.26433.

Direct production subsidies are also significant. There is a federal small producer tax credit of $0.026

per liter and subsidies to support biofuel production of $0.05 per liter provided at the state level.

Although there are other indirect support measures related to agricultural inputs or capital grants, 33 Volumetric biodiesel excise-tax credit distinguishes two different products and thus subsidies: biodiesel

derived from waste oil, which benefits from 0.132 US dollar per liter and biodiesel derived from agricultural

fats and oils which receives 0.264 US dollars per liter. In our baseline scenario, we assume the second case

since we do not have detailed information to model second generation biofuels.

Page 119: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

119

we only consider the above policies support in the baseline scenario, since they together represent

more than 65% of total biofuels support in the USA ( Koplow, 2006; Koplow, 2007).

The third country we consider in the baseline is Brazil, where we also introduce detailed information

about mandates and fiscal aids in the model. Historically Brazil has imposed a mandate for ethanol

consumption, which presently varies between 20 and 25% depending on the ethanol price. The

government officially launched the Biodiesel Program in 2004 and in 2005 the new law (LEI N°11097)

authorized the voluntary blending of biodiesel with petrol diesel for the first 3 years, moving towards

a mandatory target of 2% for biodiesel blending by 2008 and 5% by 2013 (Methanol Institute et. al,

2006).

Mandates in Brazil are therefore differentiated by biofuel type although our modeling does not

include this distinction. In our baseline scenario however, we take the Brazilian ethanol mandate as

representing the biofuel mandate. This is a realistic simplification given the predominance of ethanol

(in the matrix, the biodiesel sector is currently almost nonexistent in Brazil). In modeling the fiscal

support to biofuels, the excise tax reduction is the most significant element. For ethanol the excise

tax levied is 67% lower than that applied to gasoline. Decomposing the ethanol excise tax credit by

source we find that, in 2007, the federal element was $0.135 per liter and the Sao Paulo state part

$0.224 per liter. The excise tax reduction for biodiesel was fairly stable over the 2004-2007 period.

Initially it was $0.0973 per liter while at the time of writing it has increased slightly to $0.0992 per

liter. Other tax exemptions linked to the type of feedstock and the feedstock origin also exist, but

they are minor compared to the excise-tax credit (Jank et.al, 2007; FAO, 2008b).

Page 120: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

120

8 REFERENCES

ABARE (1996), “The MEGABARE Model: Interim Documentation”, Canberra

Abbott P., C. Hurt, and W. Tyner (2008). "What's Driving Food Prices? " Farm Foundation Issue Report.

Abbott, P., C. Hurt, and W. Tyner (2009). "What's Driving Food Prices? March 2009 Update," Farm Foundation Issue Report.

AgraFNP (2008), ‘Biofuels Brazil’, November 18, issue N°41.

Banse, M, van Meijl, H and G. Woltjer. (2008) "The Impact of First and Second Generation Biofuels on Global Agricultural Production, Trade and Land Use", GTAP Conference Paper, June 2008. https://www.gtap.agecon.purdue.edu/resources/download/3693.pdf

Barr, K., B. Babcock, M. Carriquiry, A. Nasser, and L. Harfuch (2010). "Agricultural Land Elasticities in the United States and Brazil", Center for Agricultural and Rural Development, Working Paper 10-WP 505, February 2010.

Bchir, H., Y. Decreux, J-L Guerin, and S. Jean (2002). "MIRAGE, a Computable General Equilibrium Model for Trade Policy Analysis," CEPII Working Paper No 2002-17. France. December 2002. Available at : http://www.cepii.fr/anglaisgraph/workpap/pdf/2002/wp02-17.pdf

Birur, Dileep & Hertel, Thomas & Tyner, Wally, 2008. "Impact of Biofuel Production on World Agricultural Markets: A Computable General Equilibrium Analysis," GTAP Working Papers 2413, Center for Global Trade Analysis, Department of Agricultural Economics, Purdue University.

Board on Agriculture and Renewable Resources, Commission on Natural Resources, National Research Council (1982). United States-Canadian tables of feed composition : nutritional data for United States and Canadian feeds, Subcommittee on Feed Composition, Committee on Animal Nutrition, Washington, DC.

Boeters, S., P. Veenendaal, N. van Leeuwen, and H. Rojas-Romagoza. (2008). "The Potential for Biofuels Alongside the EU-ETS," CPB Netherlands Bureau for Economic Analysis. Paper presented at the GTAP Conference in Helsinki, June 2008. See: https://www.gtap.agecon.purdue.edu/resources/download/3871.pdf

Bouet, A., L. Curran, Dimaranan, B., Ramos, M.P., and H. Valin,(2008). “Biofuels: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study”. Report for DG Trade. ATLASS Consortium.

Bouët, A., Y. Decreux, L. Fontagné, S. Jean, and D. Laborde (2008). Assessing Applied Protection Across the World. Review of International Economics. 16(5), 850-863.

Britz, W. and T. Hertel (2009). "Impacts of EU Biofuels Directives on Global Markets and EU Environmental Quality: An Integrated PE, Global CGE analysis," Agric. Ecosyst. Environ. (2009), doi:10.1016/j.agee.2009.11.003.

Burniaux, J. M. and T.P. Truong (2002). "GTAP-E: An Energy-Environment Version of the GTAP Model," GTAP Technical Paper No 16, Center for Global Trade Analysis, Purdue University, West Lafayette, IN.

Commission of the European Communities (CEC) (2008). Proposal for a Directive of the European Parliament and of the Council on the Promotion of the Use of Energy from Renewable Sources. Commission of the European Communities, Brussels.

Commission of the European Communities (CEC) (2007). The Impact of a Minimum 10% Obligation for Biofuel Use in the EU-27 in 2020 on Agricultural Markets. Note to File, DG Agriculture, 30/04/07.

Page 121: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

121

Commission of the European Communities (CEC) (2006). Renewable Energy Roadmap. COM(2006) 848, Commission of the European Communities, Brussels.

Commission of the European Communities (CEC) (2003). Directive 2003/30/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council on the Promotion of the Use of Biofuels or other Renewable Fuels for Transport. Official Journal L 123, 17.5.2003, Brussels.

Couwenberg, J. (2009). "Emission Factors for Managed Peat Soils: An Analysis of IPCC Default Values," Wetlands International, Produced for the UNFCCC meetings in Bonn, June 2009.

Croezen, H. and F. Brouwer. (2008). Estimating Indirect Land Use Impacts from By-Products Utilization - A Report to the Renewable Fuels Agency. Published on www.renewablefuelsagency.org, CE Delft, Delft, Netherlands.

Crutzen, P. J., A.R. Mosier, K. A. Smith, and W. Winiwarter. (2007). N20 release from Agro-Biofuel Production Negates Global Warming Reductions by Replacing Fossil Fuels. Atmospheric Chemistry and Physics Discussions, 7, p. 11191-11205.

Decreux, Y. and H. Valin. (2007). MIRAGE : Updated Version of the Model for Trade Policy Analysis: Focus on Agriculture and Dynamics.’ CEPII Working Paper, N°2007-15, October 2007. [Online] Available at : http://www.cepii.fr/anglaisgraph/workpap/pdf/2007/wp07-15.pdf

De Santi, G. (2008). Biofuels in the European Context: Facts and Uncertainties. Joint Research Centre (JRC), Petten, the Netherlands.

Diao, X., E. Diaz-Bonilla, S. Robinson, and D. Orden. (2005). Tell Me Where It Hurts, An’ I’ll Tell You Who To Call: Industrialized Countries’ Agricultural Policies And Developing Countries. IFPRI Discussion Paper 84. Washington, D.C.: International Food Policy Research Institute.

Dixon, P.B., S. Osborne & M.T. Rimmer (2007). The Economy-wide Effects in the United States of Replacing Crude Petroleum with Biomass. Energy and Environment 18(6): 709-722.

DOE (2008). DOE Actively Engaged in Investigating the Role of Biofuels in Greenhouse Gas Emissions from Indirect Land Use Change. see: http://www1.eere.energy.gov/biomass/pdfs/obp_science_response_web.pdf

Eickhout, B. (2008). “The Local And Global Consequences of the EU Renewable Directive for Biofuels.”, Netherlands Environmental Assessment Agency, at: http://www.rivm.nl/bibliotheek/rapporten/500143001.pdf

EPA. (2009). “Draft Regulatory Impact Analysis: Changes to Renewable Fuel Standard Program.”

European Biodiesel Board. Website: http://www.ebb-eu.org/stats.php

European Council (2009). “Directive 2009/30/Ec of the European Parliament and of The Council.” 23 April 2009. [Online] Available from: http://www.r-e-a.net/document-library/thirdparty/rea-and-fqd-documents/FQD_090605_Directive_200930EC_OJ.pdf

European Environment Agency (2004). Transport Biofuels: Exploring Links with the Energy and Agricultural Sectors. EEA briefing 04, European Environment Agency, Copenhagen.

Fargione, F, J. Hill, D. Tilman, S. Polasky, and P. Hawthorne (2008), “Land Clearing and the Biofuel Carbon Debt. Science 319.

Farrell, A. E., R.J. Plevin, B.T. Turner, A.D. Jones, M. O’Hare M. and D.M. Kammen (2006). “Ethanol Can Contribute to Energy and Environmental Goals.” Science, 311, 27/01/06.

F.O. Licht. Renewable Fuels Association (2005) “Homegrown for the Homeland: Industry Outlook 2005”, (Washington, DC: 2005), p. 14.

Page 122: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

122

F.O. Licht’s (2008). “World Ethanol and Biofuel Report.” Various Issues. [Online] Available from: http://www.agra-net.com/portal2/puboptions.jsp?Option=archive&pubid=ag072

Food and Agricultural Organization of the United Nations (2008a). Climate Change and Food Security – A Framework Document. Food and Agriculture Organization, Rome.

Food and Agricultural Organization of the United Nations (FAO) Fertilizer Production Data. [Online] Available from: http://faostat.fao.org/site/575/default.aspx.

Food and Agricultural Organization of the United Nations (FAO) Fertilizer Price Data. [Online] Available from: http://www.farmdoc.uiuc.edu/manage/newsletters/fefo08_13/fefo08_13.html

Food and Agricultural Organization of the United Nations (FAO) Production Statistics: [Online] Available from: http://faostat.fao.org/site/339/default.aspx.

Food and Agricultural Organization of the United Nations (FAO) Supply and Utilisation Accounts (SUA) . [Online] Available from:: http://faostat.fao.org/site/354/default.aspx.

Food and Agricultural Organization of the United Nations (FAO) (2008b). “The State Of Food and Agriculture. Biofuels: Prospects, Risks and Opportunities.” FAO-UN, Rome, pp.138.

Gaulier, G. et al. (2008). "BACI: A World Database of International Trade Analysis at the Product-level", CEPII Working Paper, 2008.

Geist H. J., and E.F. Lambin (2001). “What Drives Tropical Deforestation? A Meta-Analysis of Proximate and Underlying Causes of Deforestation Based on Subnational Case Study Evidence.” LUCC Report Series; 4.

Gerber, N., M. van Eckert, and T. Breuer (2009). "Biofuels and Food Prices: A Review of Recent and Projected Impacts," RIO 9 - World Climate & Energy Event, Rio de Janeiro, Brazil, 17-19 March 2009.

Ghimire, K. B., L. Solon, and L. Barraclough (2001). “Agricultural Expansion and Tropical Deforestation: Poverty, International Trade and Land Us.”. United Nations. Research Institute for Social Development.

Gnansounou, E. and L. Panichelli. (2008). "Background document," Workshop on Biofuels and Land Use Change, São Paulo, Brazil, 20-21 November 2008.

Gurgel, A., J.M. Reilly and S. Paltsev (2007).”Potential Land Use Implications of a Global Biofuels Industry.” Journal of Agricultural & Food Industrial Organization, 5.

Hertel, T., W. Tyner, and D.K. Birur (2008). “Biofuels For All? Understanding The Global Impacts Of Multinational Mandates.” GTAP Conference Paper, Helsinki, June 2008.

Hertel, T., S. Rose, and R. Tol. (2008). “Land Use in Computable General Equilibrium Models: An Overview.” GTAP Technical Paper.

Horridge, J.M. (2005). SplitCom: “Programs to Disaggregate a GTAP Sector.” Centre of Policy Studies, Monash University, Melbourne, Australia. http://www.monash.edu.au/policy/SplitCom.htm

International Energy Agency (2009). “World Energy Outlook – 2009.”

International Energy Agency (2004). “Biofuels For Transport – An International Perspective.” InternationalEnergy Agency, Paris.

International Energy Agency (2008). “Energy Technology Perspectives.” 2008. International Energy Agency, see: http://www.iea.org/textbase/npsum//ETP2008SUM.pdf

International Monetary Fund. (April 2009). World Economic Outlook. Washington DC.

Page 123: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

123

Jank, M., G. Kutas, L. do Amaral and A. Nassar (2007). “EU and US Policies on Biofuels: Potential Impacts on Developing Countries.” The German Marshal Fund of the United States, Washington, DC .

Kampman, B, F. Brouwer and B. Schepers. (2008). “Agricultural Land Availability and Demand In 2020, Report to the Renewable Fuels Agency.” published on www.renewablefuelsagency.org, CE Delft, elft;, The Netherlands.

Koplow, D. (2007). “Biofuels: At What Cost? Government Support for Ethanol And Biodiesel in the United States: 2007 Update,” Technical report, International Institute for Sustainable Development.

Koplow, D. (2006). “Biofuels: At What Cost? Government Support for Ethanol and Biodiesel in the United States, Technical Report.” International Institute for Sustainable Development, 45.

Kretschmer, B. and S. Peterson (2008). "Integrating Bioenergy into Computable General Equilibrium Models -- A Survey," Kiel Working Paper No. 1473.

Kumar, K., and K. M. Goh (2000). "Crop Residues and Management Practices: Effects on Soil Quality, Soil Nitrogen, Crop Yield and Nitrogen Recovery." Advances in Agronomy. Ed. Donald Sparks. San Diego, CA: Academic P, 2000. 198-279.

Kutas, G., C. Lindberg and R. Steenblik (2007). “Biofuels: at What Cost? Government Support for Ethanol and Biodiesel in the European Union.” Technical report, International Institute for Sustainable Development.

Ludena, C., T. Hertel, P. Preckel, K. Foster, and A. Nin Pratt (2006). ‘Productivity Growth and Convergence in Crop, Ruminant and Non-Ruminant Production: Measurement and Forecasts.’ GTAP Working Paper No. 35. [Online] Available from: https://www.gtap.agecon.purdue.edu/resources/download/2900.pdf.

Metschies, Gerhard, (2005). ‘ International Fuel Prices. ‘4th Edition. Federal Ministry of Economic Development, Eschborn, Germany 2005.

Methanol Institute &International Fuel Quality Center (2006). “A Biodiesel Primer: Market & Public Policy Developments, Quality, Standards & Handling.” April, pp.31.

Mitchell, D. (2008). “A Note on Rising Food Prices.” World Bank, Washington DC.

Monfreda, C., N. Ramankutty and T. Hertel. (2007), 'Global Agricultural Land Use Data for Climate Change Analysis', GTAP Technical Paper.

Mortimer, N. D, Ashley, A, Evans, A, Hunter, A. T, and V.L. Shaw. (2008). “Support for the Review of Indirect Effects of Biofuels.” Northe energy, Stocksfield, UK, published on www.renewablefuelsagency.org

Morton, D. C., R.S. DeFries, Y.E. Shimabukuro, L.O. Anderson, E. Arai, F. del Bon Espirito-Santo, R. Freitas, and J. Morisette (2006). “Cropland Expansion Changes Deforestation Dynamics in The Southern Brazilian Amazon.”PNAS, Vol. 103 no. 39 September 26, 2006 14637-1464

Narayanan G., B. and T. L. Walmsley, Eds. (2008). Global Trade, Assistance and Protection: The GTAP 7 Database. Center for Global Trade Analysis, Purdue University. https://www.gtap.agecon.purdue.edu/databases/v7/v7_doco.asp

OECD/FAO (2008) OECD/FAO Agricultural Outlook 2008-2017, http://www.agri-outlook.org

OECD (2008). Economic Assessment of Biofuel Support Policies, Directorate for Trade and Agriculture, OECD Paris, at: http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/19/62/41007840.pdf

OECD (2006). “Agricultural Market Impacts of Future Growth in the Production of Biofuels, Working Party on Agricultural Policies and Markets.” OECD Paris.

Page 124: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

124

Okagawa, A. and K. Ban (2008). "Estimation of Substitution Elasticities for CGE Models," Discussion Papers in Economics and Business from Osaka University No 08-16, Graduate School of Economics and Osaka School of International Public Policy (OSIPP).

Peterson, E. (2008). "GTAP 7 Data Base Documentation Chapter 8.A: Food and Agricultural Data Base." Center for Global Trade Analysis. [Online]. Available from : https://www.gtap.agecon.purdue.edu/resources/download/4178.pdf

Rajagopal, D. and D. Zilberman. (2007). "Review of Environmental, Economic and Policy Aspects of Biofuels," World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 4341.

Ramankutty, N., J.A. Foley and N. Olejniczak (2002). 'People on the Land: Changes in Global Population and Croplands during the 20th Century', Ambio 31(3), 251--257.

Reilly, J. and S. Paltsev (2007). "Biomass Energy and Competition for Land," MIT Joint Program on the Science and Policy of Global Change, Report No.145. Available at: http://web.mit.edu/globalchange/www/MITJPSPGC_Rpt145.pdf

Renewable Fuels Agency (2008). “The Gallagher Review of the Indirect Effects of Biofuels Production.” Renewable Fuels Agency, London. At renewablefuelsagency.org.

Rosegrant, M. (2008). “Biofuels and Grain Prices – Impacts and Policy Responses.” Testimony for the U.S. Senate Committee on Homeland Security and Governmental Affairs, May 7, 2008.

Rosegrant, M., C. Ringler, S. Msangi, T.B. Sulser, T.Zhu and S. Cline (2008). “International Model for Policy Analysis of Agricultural Commodities andTrade: Model Description.” International Food Policy Research Institute.

Rutherford, Thomas F., W. David Montgomery and Paul M. Bernstein (1997)."CETM: A Dynamic General Equilibrium Model of Global Energy Markets, Carbon Dioxide Emissions and International Trade," February 1997.

Seale, J., A. Regmi, and J.A. Bernstein. (2003). “International Evidence on Food Consumption Patterns.” Technical Bulletin No. TB1904.

Searchinger, T., R. Heimlich, R.A. Houghton, F. Dong, A. Elobeid, J. Fabiosa, S. Tokgoz, D. Hayes, and T.H. Yu. (2008). “Use of US Croplands for Biofuels Increases Greenhouse Gases Through Emissions from Land Use Change.” Science Express, February 7th 2008.

Sheeran, J. (2008). “Testimony to The European Parliament Development Committee on Behalf of the World Food Programme.” Brussels, 6/3/08.

Taheripour, F., D.K. Birur, T.W. Hertel, and W.E. Tyner. (2008). “Biofuels and Their By-Products: Global Economic and Environmental Implications.” GTAP Conference paper, Helsinki, June 2008.

Taheripour, F., D.K. Birur, T.W. Hertel, and W.E. Tyner. (2007). “Introducing Liquid Biofuels into the GTAP Database.” GTAP Research Memorandum. Center for Global Trade Analysis, Purdue University.

Tipper, R., C. Hutchison, and M. Brander (2009). A Practical Approach for Policies to Address GHG Emissions from Indirect Land Use Chane Associated with Biofuels. Ecometrica Technical Paper TP-080212-A.

United Nations (2007). “Biofuels Issues in The New Legislation on the Promotionof Renewable Energy.” Contribution from the United Nations1 (UNEP, FAO, UNDP, UN-HABITAT, UNIDO and WHO) to the consultation, http://ec.europa.eu/energy/res/consultation/doc/2007_06_04_biofuels/non_og/un_en.pdf

United States Government Accounting Office (2009). Biofuels: Potential Effects and Challenges of Required Increases in Production and Use. US GAO Report to Congressional Requesters, August 2009.

Page 125: Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the EU ...trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145954.pdf · Global Trade and Environmental Impact Study of the ... 3.3

125

Valin, H., B. Dimaranan, and A. Bouet (2009). “Biofuels in the World Markets: CGE Assessment of Environmental Costs Related to Land Use Changes.” GTAP Conference Paper, XIIth Conference on Global Economic Analysis.

Von Braun, J. (2008). “Biofuels, International Food Prices and the Poor, Testimony to the United States Senate Committee on Energy And Natural Resources.” June 12, 2008, Washington DC.

Wetlands International website: http://www.wetlands.org/

Witzke, P. et al. (2008). “Modeling of Energy-Crops in Agricultural Sector Models – A Review of Existing Methodologies,” JRC Scientific and Technical Reports.

Worldwatch Institute (2006). ‘Biofuels for Transportation: Global Potential and Implications for Sustainable Agriculture and Energy in the 21st Century’. Washington, DC.: Worldwatch Institute.

.Zah, R., H. Boni, M. Gauch, R. Hischier, M. Lehman, and P. Wager. (2008). “Life Cycle Assessment of Energy Products: Environmental Assessment of Biofuels.” Technical report, EMPA – Materials Science & Technology, Federal Office for Energy (BFE), Bern.