2
Global Macro Commentary Diagnoses Matter Tuesday, May 03, 2016 Guy Haselmann (212) 225-6686 Director, Capital Markets Strategy Diagnoses Matter It is generally believed that the Fed has a dual mandate of full employment and a 2% inflation target. However this is not really true. The Fed’s legally mandated ‘Monetary Policy Objectives’ are set out in Section 2A of the Federal Reserve Act. o Section 2A reads: “The Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System and the Federal Open Market Committee shall maintain long run growth of the monetary and credit aggregates commensurate with economy’s long run potential to increase production, so as to promote effectively the goals of maximum employment, stable prices and moderate longterm interest rates.” This ‘jambalaya’ of words when stated more clearly basically says that ‘the Fed is to maintain a growth level of monetary and credit aggregates with the intent of trying to achieve a few broader goals’. Therefore, if incorrect assumptions are made about how money and credit works, then all resulting conclusions will be erroneous. Slight differences in the assumptions about how monetary aggregates behave could (even) result in the conclusion that easy monetary policy, is, or has become at some point, counterproductive (See March 8 th note, “The HCurve”) It is in these assumptions where the debate between supporters and critics of experimental central bank policies arise. Most central bankers believe that expanding the supply of money will increase growth and inflation; while lowering longterm interest rates will increase credit aggregates leading to the same results. These longstanding firstorder conclusions might be taken for granted and actually be a grand misdiagnosis for the following reasons: o The Fed can ‘spill’ money into the system, but it cannot control where it flows. o Low longterm interest rates should not assume that both credit demand and supply increases. When credit spreads fall and the yield curve flattens, the supply of credit will likely decrease due to a fall in bank NIMs (net interest margin). The velocity of money has plummeted globally for a reason. o Banks ‘borrow short’ and ‘lend long’, so a flatter curve disincentivizes lending activity. Would the yield curve be steeper if the Fed did not do twist, or if it were not ‘reinvesting’ its balance sheet out the curve? These maybe counterfactual, but I found them interesting. o Regardless, banks have been hit with a slew of new regulatory measures that also contract lending incentives. Lenders (banks) will not lend if they believe they are not being adequately compensated in terms of counterparty risks and balance sheet costs. o Borrowing may not increase just because the price of money falls from a negligible amount to a deeper negligible amount. Borrowers will not invest in fixed capital projects if there is a lack of visibility on the payout of that endeavor. Visibility is low due to uncertainties: tax code, health care costs, politics, time frame for artificially low interest rates, EU refugees, global indebtedness, and Chinese shadow loans, among other factors. Draghi’s ECB is arguing that there is a savings glut that is limiting investment opportunity (page 4 of today’s FT). Yet, imposing a tax on savers will not encourage the freeing of that money for investment purposes. Negative rates and asset purchases does not increase visibility or make capital investments look more attractive. On the contrary, they are fueling more savings, further worrying consumers, causing further retrenchment and moving savings into real assets or into cash hoarding. Japan’s number one problem is a shrinking and aging population which cannot be addressed by the BoJ’s negative rate or asset purchase policies The Fed appears to be trying to prevent an Irving Fisher type of debt deflation dynamic. Balance sheets typically have fixed liabilities but variable asset prices, so it is essential that asset prices and incomes do not decline relative to fixed liabilities. Should that occur, debt or assets might have to be sold to service the outstanding debt. These sales results in everlower asset prices, creating a spiral where the liquidation defeats itself as even more sales become necessary. The current paradigm of growing corporate debt issuance combined with factors artificiallygenerating asset froth is highly combustible. The lack of investment visibility and impairments to credit normalcy will act to limit economic growth. Throw in paralyzed fiscal levers and exhausted monetary tools and the mix is problematic. Making matters much worse is the decision yesterday by the China Banking Regulatory Commission to crack down on their shadow banks. Their banks will no longer be able to disguise loans as investment. Buy Treasuries. “Get your facts first, then you can distort them as you please” – Mark Twain

Global Macro Commentary May 3 - Diagnoses Matter

  • Upload
    dpbasic

  • View
    374

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

DESCRIPTION

by Guy Haselmann, Director, Capital Markets Strategy, Scotiabank GBM

Citation preview

Page 1: Global Macro Commentary May 3 - Diagnoses Matter

Global Macro Commentary Diagnoses Matter Tuesday, May 03, 2016

Guy Haselmann (212) 225-6686 Director, Capital Markets Strategy

    

Diagnoses Matter 

It is generally believed that the Fed has a dual mandate of full employment and a 2% inflation target.  However this is not really true. The Fed’s legally mandated ‘Monetary Policy Objectives’ are set out in Section 2A of the Federal Reserve Act.   

o Section 2A reads: “The Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System and the Federal Open Market Committee shall maintain long run growth of the monetary and credit aggregates commensurate with economy’s long run potential to increase production, so as to promote effectively the goals of maximum employment, stable prices and moderate long‐term interest rates.” 

This ‘jambalaya’ of words when stated more clearly basically says that ‘the Fed is to maintain a growth level of monetary and credit aggregates with the intent of trying to achieve a few broader goals’. Therefore, if incorrect assumptions are made about how money and credit works, then all resulting conclusions will be erroneous. Slight differences in the assumptions about how monetary aggregates behave could (even) result in the conclusion that easy monetary policy, is, or has become at some point, counter‐productive (See March 8th note, “The H‐Curve”)   

It is in these assumptions where the debate between supporters and critics of experimental central bank policies arise.  Most central bankers believe that expanding the supply of money will increase growth and inflation; while lowering long‐term interest rates will increase credit aggregates leading to the same results. These long‐standing first‐order conclusions might be taken for granted and actually be a grand mis‐diagnosis for the following reasons:   

o The Fed can ‘spill’ money into the system, but it cannot control where it flows.   o Low long‐term interest rates should not assume that both credit demand and supply increases. When credit 

spreads fall and the yield curve flattens, the supply of credit will likely decrease due to a fall in bank NIMs (net interest margin).  The velocity of money has plummeted globally for a reason. 

o Banks ‘borrow short’ and ‘lend long’, so a flatter curve disincentivizes lending activity.  Would the yield curve be steeper if the Fed did not do twist, or if it were not ‘reinvesting’ its balance sheet out the curve? These maybe counterfactual, but I found them interesting. 

o Regardless, banks have been hit with a slew of new regulatory measures that also contract lending incentives. Lenders (banks) will not lend if they believe they are not being adequately compensated in terms of counter‐party risks and balance sheet costs. 

o Borrowing may not increase just because the price of money falls from a negligible amount to a deeper negligible amount.  Borrowers will not invest in fixed capital projects if there is a lack of visibility on the payout of that endeavor.  Visibility is low due to uncertainties: tax code, health care costs, politics, time frame for artificially low interest rates, EU refugees, global indebtedness, and Chinese shadow loans, among other factors.     

Draghi’s ECB is arguing that there is a savings glut that is limiting investment opportunity (page 4 of today’s FT).  Yet, imposing a tax on savers will not encourage the freeing of that money for investment purposes. Negative rates and asset purchases does not increase visibility or make capital investments look more attractive.  On the contrary, they are fueling more savings, further worrying consumers, causing further retrenchment and moving savings into real assets or into cash hoarding.  

Japan’s number one problem is a shrinking and aging population which cannot be addressed by the BoJ’s negative rate or asset purchase policies 

The Fed appears to be trying to prevent an Irving Fisher type of debt deflation dynamic.  Balance sheets typically have fixed liabilities but variable asset prices, so it is essential that asset prices and incomes do not decline relative to fixed liabilities.  Should that occur, debt or assets might have to be sold to service the outstanding debt. These sales results in ever‐lower asset prices, creating a spiral where the liquidation defeats itself as even more sales become necessary.   

The current paradigm of growing corporate debt issuance combined with factors artificially‐generating asset froth is highly combustible. The lack of investment visibility and impairments to credit normalcy will act to limit economic growth. Throw in paralyzed fiscal levers and exhausted monetary tools and the mix is problematic. 

Making matters much worse is the decision yesterday by the China Banking Regulatory Commission to crack down on their shadow banks. Their banks will no longer be able to disguise loans as investment.  Buy Treasuries.     

“Get your facts first, then you can distort them as you please” – Mark Twain  

Page 2: Global Macro Commentary May 3 - Diagnoses Matter

www.gbm.scotiabank.com

TM Trademark of The Bank of Nova Scotia. Used under license, where applicable. Scotiabank, together with "Global Banking and Markets", is a marketing name for the global corporate and investment banking and capital markets businesses of The Bank of Nova Scotia and certain of its affiliates in the countries where they operate, including Scotia Capital Inc. Disclaimer This publication has been prepared for Major U.S. Institutional Investors by Fixed Income Strategists of the Bank of Nova Scotia, New York Agency. (“BNS/NYA”). BNS/NYA Fixed Income Strategists are employees of Scotiabank’s Fixed Income Credit Sales & Trading Desk and support the trading desk through the preparation of market commentary, including specific trading ideas, and other materials, both written and verbal, which may or may not be made publicly available, and which may or may not be made publicly available at the same time it is made available to the Fixed Income Credit Sales & Trading Desk. Fixed Income Strategists are not research analysts, and this report was not reviewed by the Research Departments of Scotiabank. Fixed Income Strategist publications are not research reports and the views expressed by Fixed Income Strategists in this and other reports may differ from the views expressed by other departments, including the Research Department, of Scotiabank. The securities laws and regulations, and the policies of Scotiabank that are applicable to Research Analysts may not be applicable to Fixed Income Strategists.

This publication is provided to you for informational purposes only. Prices shown in this publication are indicative and Scotiabank is not offering to buy or sell, or soliciting offers to buy or sell any financial instrument. Scotiabank may engage in transactions in a manner inconsistent with the views discussed herein. Scotiabank may have positions, or be in the process of acquiring or disposing of positions, referred to in this publication. Other than the disclosures related to Scotiabank, the information contained in this publication has been obtained from sources that Scotiabank knows to be reliable, however we do not represent or warrant that such information is accurate and complete. The views expressed herein are the views of the Fixed Income Strategists of Scotiabank and are subject to change, and Scotiabank has no obligation to update its opinions or information in this publication. Scotiabank and any of its officers, directors and employees, including any persons involved in the preparation or issuance of this document, may from time to time act as managers, co-managers or underwriters of a public offering or act as principals or agents, deal in, own or act as market-makers or advisors, brokers or commercial and/or investment bankers in relation to the securities or related derivatives which are the subject of this publication.

Neither Scotiabank nor any of its officers, directors, partners, or employees accepts any liability for any direct or consequential loss arising from this publication or its contents. The securities discussed in this publication may not be suitable for all investors. Scotiabank recommends that investors independently evaluate each issuer and security discussed in this publication, and consult with any advisors they deem necessary prior to making any investment.