94

GIGA MASTER-FINAL

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: GIGA MASTER-FINAL
Page 2: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

2

Table of Contents

Abbreviations...................................................................................................................................................... 5

Chapter 1 – Introduction .................................................................................................................................... 6

1.1 Problem Area ......................................................................................................................................6

1.2 Problem Formulation .........................................................................................................................9

1.3 Project Design .....................................................................................................................................9

1.4 Philosophies of Science ................................................................................................................... 11

1.5 Analytical Structure ......................................................................................................................... 12

1.6 Empirical Data ................................................................................................................................. 12

1.7 Critique of Sources .......................................................................................................................... 14

1.8 Limitations ....................................................................................................................................... 15

1.9 Bias .................................................................................................................................................. 16

Chapter 2 – Theoretical Basis ........................................................................................................................... 17

2.1 Monetarism ..................................................................................................................................... 17

2.2 Keynesianism ................................................................................................................................... 18

Chapter 3 – The Pacts ....................................................................................................................................... 20

3.1 The Stability and Growth Pact ......................................................................................................... 20

3.2 The Euro Plus Pact ........................................................................................................................... 22

3.3 The Scoreboard ............................................................................................................................... 24

Chapter 4 – The Debate of the Pact ................................................................................................................. 26

4.1 Main criticism of the SGP ................................................................................................................ 26

4.2 New-Keynesianism and the SGP ...................................................................................................... 28

4.3 Monetarism and the SGP ................................................................................................................ 29

Chapter 5 – The Mechanisms of a Monetary Union ........................................................................................ 31

Page 3: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

5.1 Optimum Currency Area.................................................................................................................. 31

5.2 Monetarism and the Monetary Union ............................................................................................ 33

Chapter 6 – The Public and Private Sector ....................................................................................................... 35

6.1 Public Sector Deficit......................................................................................................................... 35

Figure 6.0: Government Deficit .................................................................................................. 36

6.2 Public Debt ...................................................................................................................................... 37

Figure 6.1: Government Debt ...................................................................................................... 37

6.3 Fiscal Policy Instruments ................................................................................................................. 37

6.4 Budgetary Convergence .................................................................................................................. 40

6.5 Private Sector Debt.......................................................................................................................... 41

Figure 6.2: Total Debt to GDP (UK) ........................................................................................... 43

Figure 6.3: Total Debt to GDP (Spain) ....................................................................................... 44

Figure 6.4: Total Debt to GDP (Germany) .................................................................................. 45

6.6 Real Estate Bubble ........................................................................................................................... 46

6.7 Analytical Summary Part I ............................................................................................................... 48

Chapter 7 – Competitiveness ........................................................................................................................... 50

7.1 Exchange Rate and Real Effective Exchange Rate ........................................................................... 50

Figure 7.0: Exchange Rate .......................................................................................................... 51

7.2 Fixed Exchange Regimes .................................................................................................................. 51

7.3 The Balance of Payments ................................................................................................................ 54

7.4 The Balance of Payments in the EU ................................................................................................. 55

Figure 7.2: Current Account ........................................................................................................ 56

7.5 The Return of New Keynesianism? .................................................................................................. 57

7.6 Unit Labour Cost .............................................................................................................................. 59

Page 4: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

Figure 7.3: Competitiveness ........................................................................................................ 60

Figure 7.4: Unit Labour Costs ..................................................................................................... 61

Figure 7.5: Labour Productivity .................................................................................................. 62

7.7 Analytical Summary Part II .............................................................................................................. 63

Chapter 8 – The Political Arena ........................................................................................................................ 66

8.1 What Went Wrong? ........................................................................................................................ 66

8.2 Denmark and the Euro Plus Pact ..................................................................................................... 68

8.3 Political Discussion .......................................................................................................................... 73

Chapter 9 – Conclusion ..................................................................................................................................... 76

9.1 Future Prospects.............................................................................................................................. 77

Bibliography ...................................................................................................................................................... 79

Appendix ........................................................................................................................................................... 87

Page 5: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

5

Abbreviations

BoP: Balance of Payments

DKK: Danish Krone

ECB: European Central Bank

EFAC: Economic and Financial Affairs Council

EMU: European Monetary Union

EP: European Parliament

EPP: Euro Plus Pact

EU: European Union

EUR: Euro

GDP: Gross Domestic Product

GNP: Gross National Product

IT: Italy

OCA: Optimum Currency Area

PT: Portugal

R&D: Research and Development

REER: Real Effective Exchange Rate

SGP: Stability and Growth Pact

UK: United Kingdom

ULC: Unit Labour Cost

Page 6: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

6

Chapter 1 – Introduction

The goals and contents of this project were inspired from discussions of the recent financial crisis in

the EU perspective. The ongoing debate in the EU on bailouts and financials problems led to a

revision of the economic policies of the European countries and the interrelationship between

member states and the EU. Keeping this in mind we decided to work with the Stability and Growth

Pact and the newly created Euro Plus Pact. We feel there is something to contribute with in this

area, as it creates an interesting framework of knowledge regarding the assumptions and effects of

different schools of economics and the consequences they have on the economy. Further it allows

us to describe the relationship and interdependence of politics and economics on both a national and

an international level. Lastly the project has a very “real” dimension to it, insofar as it describes

current and ongoing problems and challenges for our society.

1.1 Problem Area

As basis for economic stability and security in the so-called Euro-zone has been the debated

”Stability and Growth Pact.” This pact has been criticized from many angles; in its traditional form,

called SGP-I, for being too rigid, but also after its reformation in 2005, called SGP-II. Criteria such

as the requirement of a maximum deficit on state budgets of 3%, have been exposed to especially

harsh criticism.1 A later attempt to meet this criticism came in October 2010, in the form of a

proposal made by a task-group under the European Council led by its president, Herman van

Rompuy, as well as the European Commission.2 This version was called SGP-III. This proposal was

also met with harsh criticism, for not meeting the demands for a less rigid pact. In fact, it was

criticized for being an even more rigid version of SGP-II. In the words of Paul De Grauwe:

”[...] the European Commission now proposes SGP-III; a

considerably tighter version of SGP-I. […] I want to argue that

1 Web: Stability and Growth Pact 2 Web: Van Rompuy task force agrees need for budgetary sanctions

Page 7: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

7

SGP-III is a very bad idea. […] it is based on a wrong diagnosis

of the causes of the debt crisis in the Euro-zone.”3

Furthermore: The SGP has in all its forms included mainly monetarist tools for stabilizing the

economy,4 exemplified in the desire to cut public spending and keep deficits in check. Keynesians

have of course been quick to criticize the monetarist pact, but also politicians and monetarist

economists have criticized its contents.

Amidst the debate of how to stabilize the Euro-zone, the SGP has been reformulated and

reconstructed numerous times, but one central concept has remained throughout: The fact that the

SGP focuses on the issues within the public sector. Budget deficit criteria and spending regulations

have been the norm, and although the various iterations of the SGP have had different ways of

handling rules for the public sectors in the member states, not once have either of these iterations

mentioned the private sector and its problems. How can this be so, when so many attribute the cause

of the financial crisis to irresponsible banks and an increasing private sector debt from “bad” loans?

In other words, there seems to be some merit in the suggestion that the financial crisis was caused

by problems in the private sector - not the public5, 6, 7

- and it strikes us as odd that this is not a

concern that the SGP has dealt with.

Through the years of its existence, criticism of both economic and political nature has hit the

SGP in all of its forms. When the financial crisis of the late 2000s hit, it shook the foundations of

the SGP. The SGP was to be an iron clad treaty, securing stability and thereby rendering bailouts

obsolete. Clearly, it did not succeed. The question then arises whether the SGP failed because the

treaty was not upheld, that is, a lack of sanctions and actions against members who broke or failed

to meet the criteria of the treaty. Or alternatively whether it was because the very essence of the

treaty was fundamentally flawed, so that even if upheld it would not be able to prevent a crisis.

Regardless of these questions, when the recession hit, it became clear that the SGP had not worked

as intended, and that a new treaty or a major revision was needed. On March 10, 2011, a suggestion

3 Web: Why a Tougher Stability and Growth Pact is a Bad Idea 4

Web: Monetarism and Monetary Policy – The Case of the Euro 5

Web: We Need to Curb Private Sector Debt 6 Web: Financial Crisis and Bank Lending 7 Web: How Government can Discourage Private Sector Reliance on Short-Term Debt

Page 8: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

8

for a reform of the SGP was on the table of the Economic and Financial Affairs Council (EFAC).8

On March 11, the Heads of State in the Euro-zone met to formulate a new pact – one that would

attempt to meet the criticisms of the SGP head on, and create a new basis for economic stability in

the Euro-zone.9 On March 15, The Council of the European Union met and ratified the need for

reform, enabling the president to start negotiations with the European Parliament (EP).10

On March

25, the Euro Plus Pact (EPP) was finally agreed upon,11

although many details and specifics remain

to be decided. Our first goal should then include a broad understanding of the economic basis for

the SGP, the EPP, and what has changed.

Following this economic debate, another question arises: that of political viability. Some argue

that the SGP was first and foremost ineffective due to its failings in the area of politics. Due to a

lack of sanctions, it was impossible to make sure the agreement was kept, and as countries broke the

rules of the pact and no action was taken from the Commission, mistrust ran rampant and faith in

the pact dissolved.12

When the Commission finally took steps to enforce the pact,13

the influential

economies, Germany and France, refused to answer to the rules of the pact, effectively numbing any

credibility the pact may have had.14

Thus, it is not sufficient to only discuss the economic

perspective of the SGP and the EPP, one must also think in terms of whether a pact – economically

viable or not – will have any bearing in the political reality. To better understand the role of politics

we will look at the political landscape of Denmark.

This report will take a look at the SGP, and the consequences it has had on the European

economy. It will then discuss the EPP from this perspective – does it meet the criticism of the SGP,

and will it help to solve the problems that still exist after ten years with the Stability and Growth

Pact?

8 Web: Note on Economic Governance 9 Web: Conclusions of the Heads of State or Government of the Euro Area of 11 March 2011 10 Web: Counsil Reaches Agreement on Measures to Strengthen Economic Governance 11 Web: 'Euro-Plus-Pact' Agreed Admid Portugal Crisis 12

Web: Will The New Stability and Growth Pact Succeed? 13 Web: Budgetary Sanctions Hit Germany and France 14

Grauwe (2009); p. 245-246

Page 9: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

9

1.2 Problem Formulation

Which factors contributed to the failure of the SGP and to what extent have these factors been

ratified in the EPP?

1.3 Project Design

In order to answer our problem formulation we have devised five research questions which will be

answered throughout the chapters and as such will lead the project. They are:

What are the key factors in the SGP and the EPP?

What are the key points of criticism from the debate surrounding the SGP?

How does the monetary union work?

What are the key theoretical concepts relating to the pacts?

What are the main political concerns relating to the pacts' viability?

The project is divided into the following chapters:

Chapter 1 – Introduction:

This chapter consists of our problem area, problem formulation, project design, analytical structure,

philosophy of science, empirical foundation, critique of sources, limitations and bias. The chapter

will introduce the reader to the methodological choices made and give a general outline of the

project and its different parts.

Chapter 2 – Theoretical Basis:

In this chapter we take a look at the core concepts from the key theories for the project:

Keynesianism and monetarism. We create a basic outline of these economic schools of thought, to

serve as basis for a more detailed theoretical discussion further on in the project.

Chapter 3 – The Pacts:

In this chapter we answer the first research question “What are the key factors in the SGP and the

EPP?” This is done by introducing three texts; The SGP, The EPP and The Scoreboard, all of which

Page 10: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

10

are introductory texts that outlines the contents of the legal documents. This chapter will

furthermore create the basis for the rest of the project as these three are our object of research.

Chapter 4 – The Debate of the Pact

The aim of this chapter is to outline the debate of the SGP and in doing so we will answer the

second research question “What are the key points of criticism from the debate surrounding the

SGP?” This chapter will furthermore work as an introduction to some of the concepts that we will

be treating in the analysis.

Chapter 5 – The Mechanisms of a Monetary Union:

In this chapter we introduce the theory of Optimum Currency Area and a general outline of the

principles of a monetary union and in doing so we answer the third research question “How does

the monetary union work?” As the monetary union is at the centre of the discussion in this project,

it will serve well as a basis for theoretical arguments made in the analysis.

Chapter 6 – The Public- and Private Sector:

This chapter is the first of two chapters which answer the fourth research question “What are the

key theoretical concepts relating to the pacts?” Furthermore we will start the analysis in this chapter

combining the theory with empirical data. The chapter focuses, as the title denotes, on the public

and the private sector, with special attentions to the exclusion of the problems with the private

sector. The chapter will conclude by summing up the analytical points made throughout the entire

chapter.

Chapter 7 – Competitiveness:

The focus in this chapter is mainly on the EPP and will be the final of two chapters answering

research question four: “What are the key theoretical concepts relating to the pacts?” As the

previous chapter, this will be analytical in nature combining theory and empirical data. The chapter

consists of the three parts: Unit Labour Cost (ULC), Real Effective Exchange Rate (REER) and

Balance of Payments (BoP). These are concepts which have been introduced with the EPP and The

Scoreboard and acts as a measurement for competitiveness. The chapter will conclude by summing

up the analytical points made throughout the chapter.

Page 11: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

11

Chapter 8 – The Political Arena:

With this chapter we introduce a new angle to the project; the political reality surrounding the pacts.

The chapter will answer the fifth research question “What are the main political concerns relating to

the pacts’ viability?” As the two previous chapters this will be analytical in nature. The chapter

starts out by introducing the political concerns of Marco Buti regarding the SGP, followed by an

introduction to the political climate in Denmark in relation to the EPP. The chapter concludes by

combining the two sections, assessing whether the EPP has taken former political problems, held

within the SGP, into consideration.

Chapter 9 – Conclusion:

This chapter will join the analytical points made throughout the three previous. It holds our

conclusion, in which we answer our problem formulation: “Which factors contributed to the failure

of the SGP and to what extent have these factors been ratified in the EPP?” Finally we will end the

chapter by giving our answer to which future prospects we think the EPP has, based on the

knowledge gained throughout the construction of this project.

1.4 Philosophies of Science

This chapter will introduce the scientific methodology of this project. The primary source in this

project will be the critical realism as detailed in Macroeconomic theory and in Videnskabsteori i

Samfundsvidenskaberne. As critical realists, the methodology originates from the ontology of our

research object.15

This means that our axiomatic approach is that facts exist independently of

research (objectivism), but further, it also means that facts and relationships between them are

subject to change, particularly over time. The main epistemological consideration in this case is that

causal relationships are inter related, as such economy should not be seen as a number of fixed

closed systems that assume a general equilibrium, except when necessary to explain a

relation(which is not to be assumed to explain causality). Rather, the economy should be considered

as a holistic system of interrelated parts that explains relations between different actors, within a

partially acknowledgeable framework and an uncertain future. To clarify this principle, the

contrasting idea would be one of many fixed systems that uses theory to explain reality; instead we

15

Fuglsang & Olsen (2004); p. 146

Page 12: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

12

use empirical data to explain and discuss the veracity of models.

Based on these ideas, the structure of the macroeconomic system is highly complex.16

Simply

put, everything is interrelated; therefore any description of the economic landscape will be

superficial. This is because regardless of whether the researcher is a positivist or a critical realist, a

monetarist of a Keynesianist, the facts will seem fairly straightforward: GDP, Balance of Payments

etc. are not particularly disputable. The dissimilarities arise once researchers attempt to clarify the

relationship between the different facts, and how they affect one another through the system over

time.17

In this framework, the first goal is to create an outline of the macroeconomic landscape. This

allows the researcher to zoom in on markets and institutions, for example the unemployment, and

its relationship with growth. With these in mind, an analysis of theories should look at the

interrelationships of theory and data, events and relationships, and how to use these to develop

hypotheses and method.

1.5 Analytical Structure

Throughout our project we will analyse the correlation between the theories used and the empirical

data we present. This in turn means that we will have a fluent analysis through chapters five, six

and seven. At the end of chapter five and six we will have a summary of the analytical points made

throughout the chapters. In chapter seven, which is rather short, the chapter ends with the analysis

of the data presented.

1.6 Empirical Data

The empirical data presented in this project consists of two sets with different purposes. The first set

is mainly based on legal documents, counting The Stability and Growth Pact, The Euro Plus Pact

and the Scoreboard. In addition to the legal documents, we have chosen relevant scientific articles

and books, treating, in particular, The Stability and Growth Pact and The Euro Plus Pact. In its

essence, the validity of this part of our empirical apparatus is strong as it is merely facts presented

in legal documents and as such cannot be contested. Additionally when we use scholars who have

16

Jespersen (2005); p. 37 17

Jespersen (2005); p. 38

Page 13: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

13

interpreted these legal documents, it is made clear that this is an interpretation. This part of the

empirical data acts as the core foundation in the project as these legal documents are our object of

research.

The second set introduces economic key numbers and statistics on the Euro-zone as a whole

and specific countries with exceptional circumstances to make the case of economic inconsistency

within the EU. The empirical data in this area is provided primarily from OECD and Eurostat and

are as such valid. The point of concern in terms of validity in this perspective is our selection of the

specific countries, the statistics and key figures from these countries and most importantly our

interpretation of this data set. We have chosen to do the selection of this set of data from a

theoretical perspective. Firstly we have treated the variables the SGP focuses on, mainly public

sector deficit and public sector debt, as the most important variables in a monetarist perspective. In

addition to this we have paired these variables with those that, from a Keynesian perspective, have

been neglected completely in the SGP and partly in the EPP.

The choice of countries, and how we use them, is based on a problem oriented approach. This

means the choice of countries is based on finding answers to our research questions, rather than

specific choices for comparative analyses. This also means that our empirical approach gives only a

limited picture of the economics of any one country – the data is meant as a framework for

analysing the treaties, and only deals with the countries insofar as to shed light on these treaties.

These countries should then help us illuminate the potential problems of the SGP and EPP,

comparing different countries ad hoc when it is relevant to a specific value or goal of these pacts.

This means the countries we will be looking at will include diverse parameters.

Firstly there are the countries that were affected the most by the financial crisis: Greece,

Ireland, Portugal and Spain. Secondly there are the great economic powers of Europe: Germany,

UK and Italy. Thirdly there are the Social Democratic welfare countries, Sweden and Netherlands

being the best examples. Lastly there is the Euro-zone as a whole to give a picture of the average.

However, this is only one way to present them. Depending on the assumptions we make in the

analysis, and what we wish to explain, the criteria would instead be different. For example if we

wish to look at the relationship of exchange rate policy to explain competitiveness, then we might

look at Germany and Greece, as two examples of Euro-zone countries vis-à-vis Sweden and UK

who have a floating (or somewhat managed) exchange rate.

Page 14: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

14

This shows us that the large numbers of countries provide a strong framework for analysing

the goals of a treaty which is to encompass them all. If one (or more) countries do not fit the goals

of the treaty, then problems are bound arise.

1.7 Critique of Sources

This chapter will present our sources from a critical perspective. It will be divided into two parts,

one that will primarily discuss our theoretical sources, and one that will primarily discuss our

empirical sources.

Theoretical sources

Our theoretical presentation is overall divided into three parts. In the first we introduce the core

concepts of the theories, in the second, we present a theoretical critique of the SGP, while in the

third we present some of the core theoretical concepts and terms that we will use to analyse and

discuss the problems presented in this chapter. The theoretical parts of this project are all based on

some basic books on the subject by authors aiming to introduce the theories. These include scholars

De Grauwe, Artis and Nixon, as well as Jespersen and more. There are two main concerns with our

theoretical sources. The first is that the authors we use all share a common trait; they are more or

less devoted to the school of thought that they represent, or alternatively have clear views about our

subject; the SGP and the debate surrounding it. This means that all of our theoretical basis is

normative. This is partly unavoidable considering our subject, as the methodological basis of any

author of economy will always colour the way he or she does his or her research. However, we

could have based more of our theoretical framework on primary sources discussing economics on a

more complex, but fundamental level, not specifically regarding the EU. This would have

broadened our overall economic discussion. However, considering our restricted time frame and the

nature of our subject, we found it most wise to focus on scholars directly related to the subject, so

that we might bring the discussion of the SGP to its highest level. But, as stated, this may have

diluted some of the overall debate on economics in this report.

The second primary concern is that our theoretical sources are somewhat basic in nature. Both

The Economics of the European Union and Economics of Monetary Union, as well as some of

Page 15: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

15

Jespersen's work, primarily aim to explain the basics of the economic theories regarding the

European Union and the SGP. We do not use primary sources of economic scholars explaining

these economic theories in detail, and this might impede the complexity of our economic discussion

in the overall perspective.

Empirical sources

Our empirical data mostly comes in two shapes; sources describing or discussing the pacts, and

statistical data. To begin with, we will discuss the first. Our empirical sources in this regard are,

overall, quite varied. We include both first-hand empirical data, such as official documents, as well

as second-hand empirical data such as scholarly articles, newspaper articles, reports and journals.

Our secondary sources generally come from a wide variety of normative bases as well. We include

both scholars of monetarist and Keynesian conviction, as well journals with more 'leftist' and 'right-

wing' approaches to economy.

When it comes to the statistical data, there is little to criticize regarding our selection of

sources – as they are mainly primary in nature. Criticism of our statistical data is mostly in the form

of how we selected the data we did, and how broad that selection was. These concerns are explained

more broadly in the Limitations and Empirical Data chapters.

1.8 Limitations

We have limited ourselves from looking at countries outside the EU. It would have been useful to

compare the EU with other economies such as the USA and China. Additionally, one cannot deny

the ever-growing interdependency caused by globalization. In this light we have limited ourselves

from looking at externalities, which imposes a weakness in the analysis, especially when you take

into consideration that the economic crisis, still in effect, is said to have been triggered by

investment banks in the USA. Drawing on the same reasoning as before, we have chosen to exclude

such factors, because the analysis would have been too difficult to undertake with so many

variables. On the other hand, because the EU has a floating exchange rate it makes sense to view the

region as a closed circuit, to a certain extent.

The political angle of our project is somewhat limited and there are a number of aspects which

Page 16: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

16

could have been useful to include. We have chosen to question the lack of sanctions within the

pacts and furthermore the vague formulations of goals and tools held within. In this perspective we

have an overall critique of the SGP put forward by Marco Buti, which we pair with the political

debate in Denmark on the subject of the Euro Plus Pact. In doing so we are excluding all other

members of the pact and the domestic political debates within these. Arguably by choosing only to

look at Denmark, the analysis might not be representative for the EU as a whole, but it works well

for the purpose of our overall analysis. Another interesting angle to include could have been the

political influence on these, otherwise economic, agreements. In other words does the political

reality compromise the creation of these economic agreements? We do not investigate this angle

however, because of the aforementioned time-frame issue.

1.9 Bias

Firstly it should be noted that Keynesianism is ingrained in many of the assumptions we make – this

is partly because of the political leanings of our group, and partly a consequence of our studies at

RUC. This means our choice of methodology and the reflections we make are by their very nature

Keynesian.

Our choice of problem area arises from a preconception that the SGP was by its nature a

monetarist/neo-classical project, and our analysis will therefore inevitably incorporate a Keynesian

critique of this. However, firstly we attempt to be explicit about being Keynesian, and secondly we

attempt to be explicit regarding which assumptions are Keynesian and which are monetarist/neo-

classical and how these different models will give different results. Thus we attempt to be as sincere

and explicit about our bias, and its consequences, as possible.

Page 17: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

17

Chapter 2 – Theoretical Basis

In this section we will give a brief introduction to the two main schools of economics used in this

project. Therefore we have chosen to give this brief introduction. This however should only be seen

as a basic introduction, we are aware that there are many scholars in the periphery of the schools

which might not fit this simple explanation, but for the sake of arguments using the basic concepts

of the theories this will be sufficient, as, when needed, we will expand upon these.

2.1 Monetarism

Monetarism has its roots in the works of Milton Friedman and the Chicago School of Economics,

which from the 1950’s reinvented the classical economics. It is based on the ideas of the 19th

century of scholars such as John Locke and David Ricardo, hence the term neo-classical. Building

on these ideas, the neo-classical school focuses on the concepts of the ability of the market to

stabilize itself through the actions of individuals seeking to maximize their utility.18

Following this

train of thought, it is assumed that the market forces, working through flexible price and wage

adjustments will always approximate demand and supply, thereby reaching economic equilibrium.

This is so as individuals are always attempting to get the highest possible utility at the lowest

possible cost, and they make such decisions based on rational profit maximization and full

information. Through this automatic equilibrium, the basic assumption is that a deregulated market

with entirely free price and wage levels will ensure growth and stability. The concept of the market

being automatically adjusting to maximal distribution is known as the Invisible Hand. It is the free

price setting in combination with a strong competition which automatically secures employment

and stable prices. This is where the strong scepticism of political meddling in the market comes

from, as the political actors do not act rationally and therefore distort the natural equilibrium, and

hence should be kept to a minimum. Monetarists using these assumptions understood that the

supply of money has no effect on the real economy (the neutrality of money) but only affects the

price level, and therefore monetary policy should be left in the hands of an independent central

bank. If the central bank is not removed from the political process, there will always be a risk that

18

Web: Monetarism

Page 18: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

18

political actors will abuse the monetary instruments for short sighted political gain.19

In summary, the neutrality of money, the flexibility of price and wages, the free market as

opposed to the government spending, and supply creating its own demand are the main tenants of

monetarism. Our main source of monetarism specifically regarding the EU is the book The

Economics of the European Union by Mike Artis & Frederick Nixson.

2.2 Keynesianism

The proponents of Keynesianism believe in activist government policies as a tool to control the

economy. Forged by John Maynard Keynes in the wake of The Great Depression, Keynesian

economics promotes government spending to stimulate aggregate demand. The core of the

Keynesian idea is that a combination of public spending and taxation are of primary importance in

managing demand in order to move to full employment, as this is desirable. Keynes' theory was

rooted in the depression of the 1930s. Keynes felt that the economic crisis showed a major flaw in

the free market paradigms. Keynes illustrated that the market forces were unable to create the

general equilibrium that ensured growth and stability on their own. It was a fantasy that the

assumptions of the neo-classical models would lead to such progress, and a helping hand was

needed – an active government economic policy was needed to ensure the well-being of the

economy and full employment, and thereby the well-being of all of the people. This government

policy can take the form of many different tools – but all with the goal of ensuring full employment

and stability. While there are different interpretations of Keynes, most can agree on several basic

rules. Unlike monetarists, Keynesianists believe money has a real effect on the economy by

stimulating aggregate demand – therefore fiscal deficit spending can be used to stimulate the

economy. Rigidities of prices and wages are a fundamental function of markets, and they adjust

only slowly to pressure, i.e. wages do not instantly drop as unemployment goes up.

Keynesianism was exposed to harsh criticism during the 1970s however, where an influx of

inflation caused major problems.20

In response, new takes on Keynesianism were developed. When

we talk about Keynesianism in this report, we talk about the concepts known as New Keynesianism

and Post-Keynesianism. For the discussion of Keynesiansim, Jespersen's Macroeconomic theory

19

Web: Monetarism 20 Web: Keynesian

Page 19: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

19

will be the main source of Post-Keynesianism, and Paul De Grauwe's Economics of Monetary

Union will be the main source of New Keynesianism.

At the core of Post-Keynesianism is its methodology, a methodology vastly different than that

of monetarists. Post-Keynesianists take a more pragmatic approach to economics rather than a more

theoretical one. Instead of setting up advanced, refined models to predict the future, Post-

Keynesianism observes reality, and focuses on a few, observable causalities to arrive at its

conclusions.21

Thus, in Post-Keynesianism theory, emphasis is not on predicting the future per se,

but instead on using the observed causalities to identify robust tendencies that will grant some

insight into the workings of economic society. Fiscal policy therefore plays a major role in Post-

Keynesianism, particularly because of focuses on employment and its relationship with demand

stimulus.22

New-Keynesianism23

on the other hand can be seen as a sort of middle ground between

monetarists and Post-Keynesianists. While its proponents agree with monetarists in the long run,

they also focus their study on market failures, failures of coordination, and numerous other reasons

to explain recessions and as a critique of laissez-faire economists. The goal of any Keynesianist

therefore is to ensure approximate full employment, and the most useful tool for achieving this is

for the (responsible) politicians to use demand stimulus to make up for market failures and the

savings paradox.

21 Jespersen (2005); p. 187 22

Jespersen (2005); p. 188 23 Web: New Keynesian Economics

Page 20: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

20

Chapter 3 – The Pacts

This chapter consists of three parts. In the first part we introduce the Stability and Growth Pact,

starting with a short historical introduction of the origins of the pact, which leads to the specifics of

the pact and finally we outline the changes made to the pact in 2005. The second part of the chapter

will introduce the contents of the Euro Plus Pact. Finally in the third section of the chapter, the

specific measurements and values set out in the Scoreboard for the Euro Plus Pact will be outlined.

3.1 The Stability and Growth Pact

The Stability and Growth Pact was initially initiated by the German government. The initiative, as it

was then called “Stability Pact for Europe”, expressed concerns regarding the stability of the

German government, before and during the negotiations of the Maastricht Treaty, as well as a

reflection of the ratification process in Germany and the position of the Bundesbank.24

One of the

goals was to reassure the German public that the EURO would be as strong a currency as the

Deutsche Mark.

From the outset, the proposal aimed to ensure budgetary discipline in the final stage, and in

doing so also strengthening the credibility of the European Monetary Union.25

Not only did the

original document contain guidelines for reduction of deficits and public sector debt, but also more

visionary features such as limiting public expenses and orientating government spending towards

public investment. The latter aimed at helping business and promote private investment. So

although the title of the original initiative did not express growth as an aim, this was to some extent

a feature. One, as we will see further on, has been expanded widely in later revisions.

The elements of the original document include requirements of stability in preparation of

national budgets. The medium term goals specified that public sector spending should be kept

below the growth in nominal GNP, a deficit goal of 1% of GDP was set as a safeguard for keeping

the deficit under 3% of GDP in economically unfavourable times. The 3% limit was only to be

exceeded in “extreme exceptional circumstances” with the agreement of a qualified majority of the

24 Web: Stability and Growth Pact Experiences and Future Aspects, The; p. 3 25 Ibid.; p. 4

Page 21: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

21

participating member states.26

Examples of “exceptional circumstances” were given in the book

“The Stability and Growth Pact”:

“An annual decline in real output of more than 2 per cent of

GDP would be considered exceptional; a decline of 0.75 per

cent of GDP might be deemed exceptional if there is additional

supporting evidence.”27

Furthermore the maximum public debt level was set to 60%.28

The most explicit proposals however, were regarding the sanctions. The German government

wanted automatism in the sanction process and the freedom to enact the most stringent sanctions

right away. The Stability and Growth Pact was finally concluded, by the European Council, at the

Dublin Summit in December 1996. In 2005 the SGP was softened up. This happened after the

Commission took the Council to the European Court of Justice, for failing to take further actions

against Germany and France, who had persistently breached the set of rules in the SGP.29

The changes in the SGP included:

The excessive deficit procedure

Country specific medium term objectives

Greater reliability in statistics provided by member states

Involvement of national parliaments

Countries experiencing negative growth or a prolonged period of low growth avoid the excessive

deficit procedure. The original margin for this was a negative growth of 2% or more. Furthermore,

countries with a short term deficit or one close to the 3% margin, will be able to avoid the excessive

deficit procedure if they can refer a series of relevant factors. Factors such as potential growth, the

26 Ibid.; p. 4 27 Buti & Franco (2001); p. 54 28 Web: Stability and Growth Pact Experiences and Future Aspects, The; p. 4 29 Web: Stability and Growth Pact

Page 22: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

22

business cycle, policies supporting R&D and medium term budgetary efforts.30

As a monetarist

project the SGP only focused on the public sector, without giving much attention to the private

sector debt, an aspect that will be critically assessed throughout this project.

3.2 The Euro Plus Pact

The Euro Plus Pact (EPP) was concluded the 25th

of March 2011. The pact was agreed upon by the

Euro-zone heads of state and an additional six member states including Denmark. All EU member

states are invited to join on a voluntary basis. The aim of the pact is to lead EU member states out

of the financial crisis and to secure stability and growth in the EU on the medium and long term.

The EPP is a comprehensive financial agreement consistent with existing financial instruments,

such as the SGP and Europe 2020.31

The main goals of the EPP are to:

Foster competitiveness

Foster employment

Contribute further to the sustainability of public finances

Reinforce financial stability

These areas fall under national competences and it is up to the participating member states

themselves to decide how they want to achieve the goals, although specific attention will be given

to a set of possible measures.32

Competitiveness will be assessed on “wage and productivity developments and

competitiveness adjustment needs.” To measure these factors Unit Labour Cost (ULC) will be

monitored over a period of time, by comparing with other Euro-zone countries and relevant trading

partners. ULC will be monitored for each country separately, for the economy of the country as a

whole and in each of the major economic sectors of the country. The specifics of the reforms in the

30 Ibid. 31 Web: EPP p. 13-14 32 Ibid.; p. 15

Page 23: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

23

individual countries are up to the member states themselves to decide. Special attention however,

will be given to reforms ensuring that cost developments are in line with productivity. In this vein

focus is on wage setting arrangements and keeping public sector wages at a level which supports

efforts of keeping wage costs at a competitive level in the private sector. Furthermore, efforts to

increase productivity by investing in education and infrastructure, removal of restrictions which

hamper competitiveness, etc., will be given attention.33

Employment is an important factor in the competitiveness of the Euro area and progress in this

area will be assessed on long term and youth unemployment rates and labour participation rates.

Although the participating member states are responsible for policy actions taken to ensure progress

in this area, specific reforms will be given particular attention. Reforms which promote

“flexicurity,” reduce undeclared work, increase labour participation, promote life-long learning and

tax-reforms lowering the taxes on work in order to ensure a high level of employment.34

Sustainability of public finances to guarantee the full implementation of the SGP will focus on

“Sustainability of pensions, health care and social benefits” and “National fiscal rules.” Proposals

for reforms in this regard include aligning the pension system to the national demographic situation,

limiting early retirement schemes and using targeted incentives to employ older workers. Regarding

the national fiscal rules, the participating member states are committed to adopting the EU fiscal

rules set out in the SGP into national legislation.35

Reinforcing fiscal stability and the strength of the financial sector is of grave importance to

the overall stability of the Euro-zone. In this vein a wide reform of the EU framework for financial

sector supervision has been launched. Furthermore the participating member states have committed

themselves to incorporating national legislation in full respect of the Community Aquis. Strict bank

stress tests will be conducted on a regular basis and will be coordinated at EU level. The level of

private debt for banks, households and non-financial firms will be closely monitored. In addition

special attention will be paid to tax policy coordination. Member states are committed to participate

in structured discussions on tax policy issues.36

33 Ibid.; p. 16-17 34 Ibid. p. 17 35 Ibid. p. 18-19 36 Ibid. p.19-20

Page 24: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

24

3.3 The Scoreboard

In relation to the new Euro Plus Pact (EPP), a scoreboard37

has been proposed to help assess macro

economic imbalances in the EU. The aim of the Scoreboard is to help the EU and its member-states

identify major imbalances in time, before harsh economic adjustments are forced to take place. The

scoreboard is based on 4 criteria:

The chosen indicators should reveal imbalances that suggest a weakening of

competitiveness

The scoreboard should be a limited number of indicators

The scoreboard should be simple and transparent

The indicators should keep in mind accessibility, actuality and quality of the available data

Based on these criteria a number of indicators were proposed:38,39

- Balances of Payments, as a % of GDP over a 3-year period. Major imbalances, such as 4% deficit

of GDP in the current account are to be suggestive of an imbalance and might imply a weakness in

competitiveness and inversely an equally large surplus might imply a weakness in domestic

demand.

- Net change in national control of assets. This is related BoP, as it shows the long run ownership of

foreign assets contra foreign ownership of domestic assets, with a value of 35% of GDP. A deficit

here means a country will be burdened by payment of interests.

- Export market share, as measured in a 5 year period with changes of -6%, which is also to be

suggestive as a measure of a country's competitiveness.

37 Web: Proposal for a REGULATION OF THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND OF THE COUNCIL 38 Web: Indikatorer og scoreboard om overvågningen af makroøkonomiske ubalance 39 This scoreboard is not necessarily representative of the final, as it is currently only a proposal, and is still in ongoing debate. The article in question does however mention that both Denmark and the other member states seem agreeable to the overall measures and indicators

Page 25: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

25

- Unit Labour Cost, as a measurement of changes over a 3-year period with a value of 9% for Euro-

zone countries and 12% for non-Euro-zone member-states. Increasing ULC is seen as wages

increasing faster than production, the reason for differentiation between Euro-zone members and

non-members is because the Euro-zone members have a common currency, meaning the exchange

rate cannot function as a shock absorber of diverging levels of competitiveness, which it can in the

case of non-members.

- Real effective Exchange rate, as changes over a 3-year period surpassing ±5% for Euro-zone

countries and 11% for non-Euro-zone members.

- Private and Public Debt. Private debt is to have a loft of 160% of GDP as increases above this can

have a weakening effect on the demand and stability of financial sector and make it vulnerable to

shocks in asset valuation, inflation and interest rate. Public debt is still to follow the old and

separate system of the Stability and Growth Pact, but is to be included as an indicator to help give a

more complete picture of the size of a countries debt.

- Size and terms of private sector loans and development of real estate prices. A loft on growth of

15% in the total credit to the private sector and a 6% increases in the price of total value of real

estate is proposed because these tend to suggest an increase in value which is incompatible with any

real value increase. This is considered as a good measure because these values tend to follow the

cyclical development quite closely, and as the recent crisis showed the increasing profits of banks

and value of real estate was mostly speculation (a bubble) rather than representative of “true”

growth.

Lastly the Commission is expected to make a list of supplementary indicators which are to be

adjusted on a yearly basis along with the economic analysis upon which the Commission is to base

its actions. If these indicators and measures are accepted by the member countries, and the member

states fail to adhere to the recommendation by the Commission, any member who is found to be in

breach of these thresholds by the Commission is to be subject to a corrective action plan, as

proposed by the council with the possibility of a fine of up to 0,1 % of GDP.40

40 While the member states seem agreeable to the measures and indicators, even with small disagreements on what the correct values and thresholds are to be set as, there is however considerable debate on

Page 26: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

26

Chapter 4 – The Debate of the Pact

This chapter will serve as an introduction to the complex debate surrounding the Stability and

Growth Pact. The aim of this project is to delve deeper into this to debate. Thus, this chapter will

serve mainly to introduce elements in the debate that are not brought forth by us, but which have

been discussed prior to the writing of this report. The chapter will start with a brief overview of

some of the main criticisms of the SGP, which will serve to give a basic understanding of the SGP's

supposed problems. Next we will identify the overall approach of Keynesianism and monetarism to

the SGP. We do this to give an overview of the theories' standpoints – standpoints which we will

expand upon in later chapters.

4.1 Main criticism of the SGP

One important thing to remember in order to understand the criticism of the SGP is that although it

revolves around the concept of 'fiscal discipline' – the restrictions on budget deficits for example - it

is not the very idea of fiscal discipline that many criticise, but the way it has been implemented in

the varying versions of the SGP. As scholars Alves and Alfonso put it:

”[The deficit-restriction] has been the object of deep discussion

and criticism in political and academic circles. This does not

generally involve questioning the need for fiscal discipline […]

Instead, the discussion has been centred around the way in

which this discipline should be implemented and controlled.”41

Thus, while many scholars support the idea of fiscal control, and view it as a necessity for a

cooperating monetary union, the tools that the SGP have relied on were seen as possibly detrimental

to growth and economic stability. The three main reasons were:

1) That the pact had too much focus on restrictive rules

2) That these rules seemed to focus on the objective of low inflation, without taking into

the functioning of corrective actions and the process and tools of that are to be used in case of a breach. This will be elaborated on in a later chapter. 41 Web: “New” Stability and Growth Pact: More Flexible, Less Stupid?, The; p. 5

Page 27: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

27

consideration alternative options

3) That these rules presupposed negative consequences from budget deficits, not taking into account

possibilities of expansionist economic policies42

When delving deeper into the pact, many criticized the SGP from a more pragmatic angle.

Questions were raised as to the precise solutions to instability the pact used, and what basis these

had been selected on – for example, the 3% budget deficit restriction. Furthermore, how were the

values in the pact calculated? Which methods would be used to establish a state's public deficit –

would things like public investments be taken into account or not?43

One of the fears of people criticizing the SGP, was that the lack of flexibility would prove not

only ineffective, but even harmful, to economic stability in the Euro-zone. If countries had to

adhere to strict fiscal rules during a crisis, and thus have their ability to react with economic policies

restricted, a crisis could worsen as a result.44

Some scholars, including Paul De Grauwe, also

criticise the very basis for the SGP, in this case the SGP-III. The SGP-III, Grauwe said, was

founded on the idea that public debt was increasing and that this was a problem that needed to be

solved. But public debt had been steadily declining until 2007, when the crisis struck and

governments had to bail out banks and a struggling private sector, all the while dealing with

reduced tax revenues. Thus, the ”public debt crisis” only exists in so far as it is related to the

financial crisis. The debt-crisis might then be: 1) not a result of irresponsible governing and 2)

perhaps entirely unavoidable.45

A study by Andrew Hughes Hallet, John Lewis and Jürgen von

Hagen lends credibility to this argument. According to this study, “[...] Most Euro-zone countries

have avoided the 3% budget deficit limit of the Stability and Growth Pact (SGP) due mainly to

economic growth.” In other words; expansion, not restriction, has been responsible for the “stars”

in Euro-zone economies.46

Another important point of critique relating to the SGP is political or “practical.” This critique

claims that the SGP is simply too difficult to enforce. Evidence of the lack of enforcement is most

outspoken in the case of France and Germany, who exceeded the limit of the budget deficits but,

42 Web: “New” Stability and Growth Pact: More Flexible, Less Stupid?, The; p. 6 43 Web: “New” Stability and Growth Pact: More Flexible, Less Stupid?, The; p. 6 44 Web: “New” Stability and Growth Pact: More Flexible, Less Stupid?, The; p. 6 45 Web: Why a Tougher Stability and Growth Pact is a Bad Idea 46 Web: Study Finds Lack of Market Flexibility Has Undermined Stability and Growth Pact

Page 28: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

28

despite threats from ECOFIN, were never penalized.47 This institutional criticism of the SGP is

expanded with a criticism of the ECB's role in managing the fiscal policy of the member states:

“The ECB has long claimed that its only purpose is to pursue

price stability, e.g. control inflation. Nevertheless, [...] the ECB

reacted too little, too late when economic growth slowed in the

early 2000s. [...] The result was that it became exceedingly

difficult, if not impossible, for some member states to satisfy the

SGP’s requirements.”48

Thus, another perspective of the criticism is that institutions such as the ECB react with their policy

regulations with “bad timing,” causing more harm than good. The last central point of overall

criticism of the pact is that while it is not sufficient to solve the problems of the Euro-zone and

stabilize its economies, it is still “better than nothing.” Martin Heipertz concludes in his report on

The Stability and Growth Pact that the incentives the pact gives to states to follow it are too limited.

Additionally, that pact focuses too much on restrictive short-term goals instead of preventing long-

term instability, and that it, by not being based on voter-participation and not generating enough

results, fails both an “input” and “output” legitimacy-test. Still, Heipertz concludes: “It [the SGP] is

surely not the optimal solution. However, the second best is still better than nothing.” From

Heipertz' point of view, countries that systematically fail to adhere to the pact will be politically

forced to formulate alternatives, which can provide the basis for a stronger pact.49 In light of the

recent developments regarding the EPP, Heipertz may have formulated a correct thesis on the last

bit; that the failure of one pact paves the way for another by way of necessity.

4.2 New-Keynesianism and the SGP

According to Paul De Grauwe, the two primary focuses of a stability pact in a monetary union

should be50

1) Making sure there is flexibility to make up for the lack of an exchange rate tool, so

that countries can combat asymmetric shocks, and 2) Defending against spill-over effects from

47 Web: It is broken. Can it be Fixed?; p. 12 48 Web: It is Broken. Can it be Fixed?; p. 13 49 Web: Stability and Growth Pact, The – Not the Best but Better than Nothing; Chapter 4 – Conclusion 50 De Grauwe (2009); p. 244

Page 29: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

29

budget deficits and public debt in the member-states. However, it seems that the SGP has focused

almost solely on the latter of these two concerns. Even worse; countries which have seen a

moderate decline in GDP during the recession would have too small a decline in GDP (between 0%

and 2%) to be protected against the deficit penalty. If the Euro-zone followed the rules of the SGP

strictly, these countries would be subject to fines because of their budget deficit, prompting them to

further tighten the reins on their fiscal policies. Considering the need for fiscal flexibility in a crisis,

this part of the SGP can be directly harmful for the economies of the member-states, causing even

worse spill-over effects.51

In 2002, major economic downturns for, among others, France and

Germany, had the result that the Commission recommended actions against the two states;

imposing the SGP's budgetary balance even in times of declining growth or stagnation. Refusing to

do this, it came down to a political brawl between France and Germany, and the Commission.

Predictably, the nation states won this battle, even though the Commission might have been “right”

according to the rules laid down in the SGP. This, of course, invalidated the pact. As De Grauwe

puts it: “For all practical purposes the Pact had become a dead letter.”52

Ergo, this presents

another danger of requiring tight budgets in a monetary union; in situations where countries cannot

comply with the rules, the rules risk being effectively annulled. Since both Keynesians and

monetarists agree that some form of conformity on fiscal policy is required in a monetary union,

this must be perceived as negative in any case. Most Keynesians agree that the objectives of the

SGP were good – budget control and sustainable debt levels – however, De Grauwe uses the classic

Keynesian argument that in times of recession, because of the savings paradox, it is useful for

governments to be able to stimulate demand even if it incurs some debt doing so.53

4.3 Monetarism and the SGP

The SGP was, from a monetarist point of view, supposed to bolster the agreements already present

in the treaties of fiscal discipline in Europe. Criticism has been levelled against the SGP for being

too constrained, in particular for not letting automatic stabilizers operate. According to the

51 De Grauwe (2009); p. 244-245 52 De Grauwe (2009); p. 245-246 53 De Grauwe (2009); p. 246

Page 30: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

30

monetarists, however, this is untrue.54

Rather, problems with the SGP have been due to the national

governments – in particular their failure to “undertake sufficient consolidation in “good times.””55

In other words, countries may have complied with the rules in the SGP and the maximum budget

deficit restriction, but at the same time neglected to prepare for economic difficulties while

circumstances were beneficial and the economic surplus was there to help preparations. Another

problem in this vein is related to the collaborative ignorance displayed by the Euro-zone members

with regards to the SGP. Lack of peer-pressure towards economically irresponsible member-states

resulted in a complete lack of sanctions. Most notably, countries that presented “overly optimistic”

predictions of financial growth were not criticized and their behaviour was not questioned.56

When

pressure was put on countries, it did not have the desired effect, or was inaccurate. In addition, the

commission warned national governments without effect. For example, the commission

recommended 'early warnings' to the Portuguese and German governments in 2002. The Council

however, did not find it prudent to release these warnings, since the Council argued the

Commission's worries had already been taken into account by the “accused” governments. Later,

however, an audit showed that Portugal and Germany had indeed exceeded the 3% budget deficit.57

“The monetarist conclusion” to the SGP and its successes and failures thus becomes a

relatively simple matter. The SGP and the monetary union functions in theory, but in practice they

have been undermined by non-compliant governments, institutional inefficiency and the lack of

ability to sanction “offending member-states.”58

54 Artis & Nixon (2007); p. 307 55 Artis & Nixon (2007); p. 308 56 Artis & Nixon (2007); p. 308 57 Artis & Nixon (2007); p. 309 58 Artis & Nixon (2007); p. 311

Page 31: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

31

Chapter 5 – The Mechanisms of a Monetary Union

The aim of this chapter is to give a theoretical basis for the discussion of the monetary union. Firstly

the reader will be introduced to the theory of optimum currency area, which lies at the heart of the

monetary union. This will be followed by a more pragmatic discussion of the concepts of the

optimum currency area as well as additional arguments for a monetary union.

5.1 Optimum Currency Area

In order for a monetary union to work, the participating member states have to give up national

monetary instruments to a central administration. This means that national central banks will either

cease to exist or have no real power. Not all nation states are alike and the authority to control

exchange rates can, in many cases, prove to be a valued policy instrument. This transfer of national

monetary competences to a common central bank is one of the costs of a common currency. In the

60’s Mundell, McKinnon and Kenen founded theoretical thoughts on this subject.59

In the following

we will present the basics of this “theory of optimum currency areas” as it will prove to be at the

core of several arguments throughout this report.

At the core of the theory of optimum currency areas lies the analysis of demand shifts or

asymmetric demand shocks, as they will be referred to in the following. We have chosen to take our

basis in De Grauwe’s60

explanation of this theory, making the argument from a monetary union set

up between two countries, as it explains the mechanisms of the optimum currency area without

over-complicating it. Obviously a monetary union between 17 countries with different national

constellations, as is the case with the EMU, is far more complicated. But for the sake of our

argument this basic explanation will be sufficient.

In this explanation we will use the example of a monetary union set up between two countries,

Italy (IT) and Portugal (PT). The two countries IT and PT set up a common currency which is

managed by a central bank. We devise a thought-experiment; that the consumers within the

monetary union shifts their preference in favour of products produced in IT, at the cost of a

decreased demand for products produced in PT. This results in an asymmetric demand shock. The

59 De Grauwe (2009); p. 5 60 De Grauwe (2009); p. 5

Page 32: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

32

increased demand for products made in IT will increase the price level and thereby the incentives

for the producers in IT to increase their output, which in turn lowers the unemployment in the

country i.e. greater output, require a greater workforce. In contrast the output in PT is likely to

decrease, which leads to increased unemployment. There are two factors which can help to adjust

this imbalance between IT and PT: wage flexibility and mobility of labour.61

If there is sufficient wage flexibility, wages in PT will decrease and adjust to the lessened

demand, in turn making Portuguese products cheaper to produce and thereby more competitive. The

opposite will happen in IT where wages are likely to go up making Italian products less

competitive. This has stabilizing effect on the demand i.e. increasing demand for Portuguese

products and decreasing the demand for Italian products.62

The second adjustment mechanism, labour mobility, relies on the assumption that the

unemployed workers in PT, will move to IT where there is an increased demand for labour. In

doing so the price level in PT will not decline due to greater unemployment and the wages in IT

will not increase due to the decrease in unemployment.63

If one or both of these mechanisms are in place, the adjustment problem will be solved. If this

is not the case however, if prices in PT do not decline and the Portuguese workers are unwilling to

move to Italy, the increased demand for Italian products will force the wages and thereby prices up,

leading to an increased competitiveness in products produced in PT. In other words, if wage

flexibility and labour mobility are too rigid, equilibrium will only be reached through inflation in

Italy.

If the two countries had not been in a monetary union and kept their monetary policy

instruments intact, they could have done several things to adjust to the asymmetric demand shock.

De Grauwe distinguishes between two types of exchange rate regimes, flexible exchange rate

regimes and regimes where countries peg their currency to another currency. If PT and IT had

chosen a flexible exchange rate system, PT could have lowered their interest rate increasing

aggregate demand and IT could have done the opposite raising their interest rate and decreasing the

demand. This could lead to a depreciation of the PT currency and an appreciation of the IT

61 De Grauwe (2009); p. 6 62 De Grauwe (2009); p. 7 63 De Grauwe (2009); p. 5

Page 33: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

33

currency, making Portuguese products less expensive in Italy and thereby increasing demand. If

they in the other case had chosen to peg their currencies, PT could have devalued their currency

against the Italian making their products more competitive, which again would lead to increased

demand.64

To sum up, when countries in a monetary union are hit by asymmetric demand shocks there

are two adjustment tools to reach equilibrium: wage flexibility and labour mobility. If these are not

sufficiently present, a shock can lead to inflation. When in a flexible exchange rate system,

countries can adjust their interest rate to boost demand. If they, however, are in a regime where they

have pegged their currencies they can choose devaluation to boost demand and reach equilibrium.

5.2 Monetarism and the Monetary Union

From a neo-classical or monetarist perspective, a central element in the success of the monetary

union was limiting national government's continued public deficit. The increase in public debt led to

“an increase in equilibrium real interest rates, crowding out of private investment, and, therefore,

to lower capital stock.”65

In other words; governments had failed to control economy via fiscal

policy, thus, they had to be constrained. This need is further solidified by the fact that negative

economical situations in one country undoubtedly will have “spill-over” effects on other countries,

particularly within the Euro-zone. In the mind of a monetarist, this reinforces the argument for a

need for common restrictive policies to ensure one country's debt problems do not become the debt

problem of the collective union.66

Another argument for the monetary union and the constraints on

national fiscal policy it came with, was the fact that factors such as an integrated market, free

movement of good and workers, as well as flexibility within a market, were key to protect

economies against economic shocks. Research showed that in these areas Europe scored much

worse than USA. The argument then became that an EMU in itself would contribute to the

aforementioned factors; that it would positively affect the integration of the European market,

which would in turn help defend European economies from economic shocks. Along with

promoting and strengthening free movement of goods and people, this could empower the European

64 De Grauwe (2009); p. 8 65 Artis & Nixon (2007); p. 281 66 Artis & Nixon (2007); p. 282

Page 34: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

34

economy, making it less vulnerable and more able to adjust. This, in turn, reduced the need for

active fiscal policy. Furthermore, the monetarists claim, empirical evidence gathered within the last

decade seems to show that an increase in public debt results in an increased interest rate.67

One of the benefits of the Monetary Union is that it strips the national governments from its

ability to print money – thus rendering it insusceptible to inflation-bias:

“For example, once social partners have concluded wage

agreements, higher than anticipated inflation will reduce ex post

real wages and thus increase output and employment. Such

incentives to inflate will, however, be understood ex ante by a

rational public who adjust their inflation expectations

accordingly.”68

In other words, a government that attempts to increase production and employment via inflation will

be predicted by the rational public which will “adjust their actions accordingly.” When stripped of

its ability to inflate via money-printing, a government can no longer cause this or similar situations.

This is obviously beneficial to the economy, if the claim of a rational public is true. The other basic

power of governments – the power of taxation – is also affected by a tight, monetary union. As

flexibility and freedom of movement grows, countries will compete for workers and products via

their tax-rates, forcing governments to lower their taxes – or at least forcing them not to increase

them. This reduced control of tax-rates for governments is not an argument against the monetary

union though; rather it is perceived as yet another argument for more fiscal discipline and public

deficit control. Put differently, the lowered income from taxes resulting from increased competition

among the member-states must be balanced by more fiscal discipline.69

67 Artis & Nixon (2007); p. 282-283 68 Artis & Nixon (2007); p. 285 69 Artis & Nixon (2007); p. 287

Page 35: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

35

Chapter 6 – The Public and Private Sector

In this chapter we introduce the core issues of the SGP concerning its lack of focus on the private

sector, as well as the secondary concerns of a 3% public sector deficit and a government debt not

exceeding 60% of GDP. As mentioned earlier, these values were seen as a central condition for

growth and stability within the union. This chapter starts by introducing the concept of the public

sector budget and introduces the relevant data in order to compare the economies of Europe. We

analyse the preconditions that lie behind the budgetary criterion and then contextualise these with

our empirical data as well as our theoretical understanding. We continue by analysing the

shortcomings of the SGP and its narrow focus on the public sector budget excluding the private

sector. We conclude by looking at the recent real estate bubble as our macroeconomic theory

indicates that an understanding of this is crucial, in order to understand the boom-and-bust cycle

and crisis in general.

6.1 Public Sector Deficit

Simply put, the public sector budget is made up by receipts and expenses, which then are

subtracted, making up a country’s public sector budget deficit. A more thorough explanation is

given here below.

Expenses Receipts

Wages to employees

Purchase of goods

Real investments

Social benefits/pensions

Subsidies loans

Income taxes

VAT and excise duties

user charges

The public sector's revenue and expenses can not be viewed independently. For instance, if a

government approves new expenditures, it must simultaneously find a way to finance this new

Page 36: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

36

expenditure.70

For example, if a government decides to lay off people in the public sector and these

do not find employment in the private sector, then they still become an expense due to receiving

welfare benefits (unemployment). So this argument preconditions that a job in the public sector has

its equivalence in the private sector in order to create real savings.

A significant part of the SGP has been on financial discipline, or, in other words, a balanced

budget, where revenues meet expenses. As mentioned earlier the criteria for this is an annual budget

deficit no higher than 3% of GDP. Introducing figure 6.0 we see how countries have managed to

meet these criteria:

Figure 6.0: Government Deficit71

Until the crisis, we see that the Euro area as a whole has kept its deficit approximately at the desired

level of deficit. However countries such as Greece and Portugal have had problems meeting this

criteria and the international crisis has only worsened this. At the moment all countries as a result of

the crisis are breaching or coming close to breaching the 3% criteria.

70

Jespersen (2009); p. 154 71 Appendix 1

Page 37: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

37

6.2 Public Debt

Another criteria in the SGP is a national debt lower than 60% of GDP or approaching this value.

We see on figure 6.1, that the Euro area as a whole has kept its government debt at constant level

around 70%, whereas Greece and Italy have been running with a government debt around and

above 100% of GDP.

Figure 6.1: Government Debt72

6.3 Fiscal Policy Instruments

Fiscal policy is the government's use of expenditure and revenue, with an aim to influence the

economy. However not all expenditures and revenues can be used as fiscal policy instruments. We

have to distinguish between

“1) discretionary interventions initiated by politicians, and 2)

business cycle dependent expenditures and revenues, the so-

72 Appendix 2

Page 38: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

38

called automatic budget-changes or automatic stabilizers, which

are beyond the direct control of the government.”73

Decisions concerning discretionary items can be made up in specific expenses such as investments

in infrastructure. The point to be made here is that discretionary expenditures can be set according

to political belief and desires. In opposition to this, we find the business cycle dependent

expenditures and revenues. It is impossible, in advance, to set the cost of for instance

unemployment benefit, social benefits and early retirement pensions, as these payments are

dependent on the actual business cycle.74

It is not possible for the politicians to set the margin of

these expenditures. However, politicians are able to raise for instance the requirements for gaining

social benefits or raising the minimum retirement age.

Within the EU, the member states have different levels of welfare systems and in this context

different unemployment benefit schemes or automatic stabilizers. These automatic stabilizers have

been set in place to reduce the sensitivity of the economy when a “slump” occurs. In general a

“slump” is a result of a decline in demand. The decline in demand automatically lowers the output

i.e. a percent of the workforce relevant to the decline in output will become unemployed. When

unemployment benefits are in place, the unemployed will receive income in form of unemployment

subsidies, thus keeping their purchasing power at a respectable level and thereby in turn keeping

their demand at a respectable level. In other words the unemployment benefits to some extent

counteract the expected decrease in demand. One downside of these automatic stabilizers is that

when the economy is exposed to a continuous “slump” and unemployment rises, the public sector

spending can spin out of control. The main factors which contribute to this are reduced tax income

from work and increased expenses in form of unemployment benefits.75

As the member states have

different levels of automatic stabilizers, the effect an economic “slump” will have on the member

states will differ i.e. countries with extended unemployment benefits will suffer bigger losses on the

public sector budgets, than those with more restricted unemployment benefits. This in turn means

that member states with an extended welfare system are more prone to exceed the 3% budget deficit

cap set out in the SGP, which could lead to a set of restrictions and economic penalties as set out in

73 �

Jespersen (2005); p. 135 74 �

Jespersen (2009); p. 156 75 Jespersen (2009); p. 166-167

Page 39: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

39

the excessive deficit procedure.

As mentioned earlier, governments have different methods available to bring down their

deficits. They can either raise the receipt side or reduce their expenses. Governments can choose to

reduce the public sector, thereby making savings through reduced wage costs. In order for this to be

a successful manoeuvre you would have to ensure that the private sector is able to absorb this

increase in labour supply. Another way to bring down the deficit is by reducing the level of real

investments in infrastructure (roads, railways etc.). However, this will also lead to a fall in demand,

which again will affect the private sector and its ability to employ. Governments could also choose

to reduce its social benefits. This however would lead to a fall in private consumption, which in turn

would lead to a fall in aggregate demand, causing further unemployment. And lastly another way to

go is to simply increase its revenues through higher taxes. This would however again cause a fall in

consumption, and again fall in demand. These arguments for savings could however be countered

by arguments in favour of budget deficits not being a decisive factor and instead focus on

increasing aggregate demand. This could be done by economic stimulus via an expansionary fiscal

policy, for example by implementing discretionary measures such as major public investment

programs. Of course, this would in the very-short run lead to further budget deficit, but will also

help ensure both a higher growth and lower expenses on other accounts such as unemployment

benefits. Professor at Columbia University, Joseph Stiglitz, agrees that sometimes savings are

necessary. However too many European countries are leading tight fiscal policies, which only

worsens the economic downturn.76

Instead, he argues, investments should be made in order to

ensure growth. This would stimulate the private sector, ensure employment and is in his view the

best way to bring down the budget deficit in the long run.77

This debate over fiscal responsibility then becomes a debate about which assumptions are the

true conditions of macroeconomic behaviour. If the assumptions are neo-classical or monetarist,

then savings in the public sector will reduce investment crowding, thereby having a positive effect

on both growth and public budgets. This line of thought is what is behind the 3% and 60% criterion

of the SGP.78

In response to this we find the Keynesian argument, which argues that a budget deficit

76 Article: Økonomiens superstjerner i København 77 Ibid. 78 Artis & Nixon (2007); p. 283-285

Page 40: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

40

is not necessarily a negative factor. A Keynesian would argue that discretionary measures are

necessary in order to help the economy move towards full employment, thereby solving the above-

mentioned problems.

6.4 Budgetary Convergence

Many economists have criticised the 3% and 60% norms as being too arbitrary. The formula

determining the budget deficit needed to stabilize the government debt is a follows:79

d = g · b

b is the steady state level at which the government debt is to be stabilized (as a percentage of GDP

(60%)), g is the growth rate of nominal GDP, and d is the government deficit (as a percentage of

GDP).80

From the formula we see that in order to reach the desired level of government debt at 60

percent of GDP, budget deficit must be brought to 3% of GDP if and only if the nominal growth of

GDP is 5% (0.03 = 0.05 · 0.6). It is unclear as to why the debt should be stabilized at 60%. If for

example other numbers such as 70% or 50% were chosen, then the deficit should be 3.5% and 2.5%

respectively. These numbers are very important as they constitute the meaning of budget discipline

and a ±0.5% deviation would have a major impact on states and their room for fiscal policy.

However these values were set at Maastricht, where the average debt-GDP ratio was 60%. Secondly

they were conditioned on the nominal growth rate of GDP, which at that time was relatively high. It

is however interesting to see what would happen if growth were to slow down to for instance 2.0%.

Then the budget deficit should not exceed 1.2%, which shows the fragile mathematical equation

upon which these criteria were formed.

Growth Rate Government Debt Budget Deficit

0,05 0,6 0,03

0,04 0,6 0,02

0,03 0,6 0,02

0,02 0,6 0,01

0,01 0,6 0,01

79 �

De Grauwe (2009); p. 148 80 �

De Grauwe (2009); p. 148

Page 41: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

41

This mathematical way of arguing furthermore shows us, that if the budget deficit is made

dependent on the annual growth, then a slowdown in growth should lead to fiscal tightening in

order to compensate for a lack in growth. And this way of arguing has also been criticised from

different sides. Especially Keynesians see these debt and deficit values as a straitjacket which does

not allow for much fiscal freedom within the member states. They argue that fiscal tightening

during an economic downturn is not desirable, as expansionary fiscal policy is seen as the best way

in order to help create demand.

One of the major problems with the 3% and 60% is that they precondition a 5% annual growth

rate. This is based on the assumption that a state of equilibrium between these values is possible.

And from a strictly mathematical view this is true. However the problem arises when one of these

start changing rapidly. For instance in welfare states, where business cycle dependent expenditures

such as unemployment benefits are relatively high, an economic downturn would have a significant

impact on the budget deficit. Keynesians argue that in times of economic downturn, governments

must step in and stimulate the economy and raise aggregate demand. However, this is impossible

according to the mathematical reasoning which lies behind the SGP, as a fall in growth should lead

to fiscal tightening.

6.5 Private Sector Debt

Much of the recent criticism against the SGP has been that it ignores private debt. This criticism has

been strengthened due to the financial crisis. Therefore this sub-chapter aims to first give a

theoretical insight into the effects of private debt, and secondly to establish what the main

divergences are, and how big these are, in the EU. There is an economic equilibrium relating to

current account balance, budget balance and private sector balance. To clarify, this means that when

a country runs a current account deficit, the private sector and the public sector cannot de-leverage

at the same time:

Private Balance + Budget Balance = Current Account Balance

Page 42: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

42

From this we denote Private Balance = Private Saving – Investment.81

An unsound development in

the private sector debt could potentially harm domestic demand, growth and cause financial

instability.82

It has been argued that this unsound development in the private sector was the decisive

factor causing the recent crisis, and not profligacy of national governments. Paul De Grauwe

argues, and our empirical data shows, that prior to the crisis, government debt to GDP ratio in the

Euro-zone was actually declining.83

The private debt however has risen across the economy. From

consumers using credit cards, through industrial companies borrowing for expansion, and financial

companies using debt to buy risky assets. In theory there is no maximum level for this debt relative

to GDP, but Ireland and Iceland found the limit in practice when their debt level reached 700% and

1200% respectively.84

This burden proved too much and threw them into financial crisis.

“Throughout the 1980s and 1990s a rise in debt levels

accompanied what economists called the “great moderation”,

when growth was steady and unemployment and inflation

remained low. No longer did Western banks have to raise rates

to halt consumer booms... asset prices were rising even faster, so

balance-sheets looked healthy.”85

However, in early 2007 and onwards there were signs that economies were reaching the limit of

their ability to absorb more borrowing. The growth-boosting potential of debt seemed to peter out.86

In the wake of the financial crisis it has become harder to distinguish between debt in the private

and public sector as they relate to each other:

“If the private sector suffers, the public sector may be forced to

step in and guarantee the debt … Otherwise the economy may

81 Web: Deciphering the G10 Sovereign Debt Crisis: A Macroeconomic Perspective 82 Web: Indikatorer of scoreboard om overvågningen af makroøkonomiske ubalancer 83

Web: Fighting the wrong enemy 84 Web: Indebtedness after the financial crisis – World debt 85 Web: Repent at leisure 86 Ibid.

Page 43: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

43

suffer a deep recession which will cut the tax revenues

governments need to service their own debt.”87

As a result of this, government debt in many countries exploded in 2007. Therefore, it became a

necessity to save the private sector; in particular the financial sector. As noted earlier, the SGP

focuses mainly on government debt and deficit discipline. However, as Paul De Grauwe points out,

it seems to fight the wrong enemy.

If we look at government debt in the United Kingdom we see that the UK has kept its government

debt below the desired 60% of GDP (Figure 6.2). The total debt however has exploded to 466%,

where government debt “only” contributes with 59%. One can see that UK borrowing primarily was

driven by growth of the financial sector.

Figure 6.2: Total Debt to GDP (UK)88

87 Ibid. 88

Appendix 3

Page 44: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

44

If we then take a look at Spain we see a similar pattern unfold. Spain's debt has grown rapidly since 2000 in

spite of significant government reduction (figure 6.3). We see here as in the UK that it is primarily the

private sector which accumulates significant debt.

Figure 6.3: Total Debt to GDP (Spain)89

And finally turning to Germany in figure 6.4 we notice that Germany experienced increased growth after

reunification but this has stabilized after 2000. It also worth noticing that of all these countries it is

Germany who has the highest government debt (73%) making it the only country in violation with the 60%

rule. It seems somewhat peculiar in this regard that Germany is regarded as one of the strong-performers

of the SGP.

89

Appendix 4

Page 45: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

45

Figure 6.4: Total Debt to GDP (Germany)90

From these countries we see that it has not been a growth in government debt that constituted the

most significant problem, but debt accumulated in the private sector. One of the main problems

related to this is the fact that the SGP does not mention private sector debt with a single word,

thereby rendering it irrelevant in relations to measurement of member-states performance. This has

been based on an assumption: that private and public sector debt could be meaningfully separated.

However as mentioned before, the financial crisis proved this assumption to be wrong.

Governments were forced to increase their public deficit and guarantee the debt, in order to save the

private sector from a regular meltdown. From this perspective it seems quite odd that the SGP

focuses so narrowly on the public sector and its deficit, when the small imbalances of Germany and

even the considerable public debt of Italy has not caused problems of anywhere near the magnitude

of for instance Ireland. It seems quite arbitrary that no measurements or rules apply for the private

sector and its debt.

As mentioned earlier, the SGP was founded on a monetarist discourse, which stipulates that

government and its debt and deficit are the main factors which hinder growth and stability. Limiting

government and its intervention in the economy would leave the market forces free to pursue profit

maximising and secure growth and thereby stability, which would be to the benefit of all. However,

this is a theoretical approach. Reality shows us that market forces alone will not provide stability.

Neither will the SGP be the “iron-clad” guarantee against collapse, such as was theorised. The

90 Appendix 5

Page 46: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

46

collapse of the financial sector showed the instability of the private sector. Several financial

institutions had become “too big to fail”91

and had to be bailed out by governments in order to

prevent a threatening depression. This shows us that it is not sufficient to look only at the public

sector as this only shows us a partial view of the economy as a whole. It is questionable to speak of

fiscal discipline in the public sector without looking at the private sector, as reality has shown that a

separation of these two is only true in theory. The debt which accumulated in the private sector was

transferred, becoming public debt and making the difference between the public and private sector

debt blurry.

6.6 Real Estate Bubble

Another contributor to the recent financial crisis was the collapse of real estate bubbles. A real

estate bubble is characterized by

“rapid increases in the valuations of real property such as

housing until they reach unsustainable levels relative to incomes

and other economic indicators, followed by decreases that can

result in many owners holding negative equity (a mortgage debt

higher than the value of the property).”92

The Economist asks the question of whether housing is the most dangerous asset in the world,

because the purchasing of a house usually involves taking on lots of debt. The bursting of a real

estate bubble hits banks disproportionally hard and research in financial crisis show a consistent

link between house-price cycles and banking busts. Falling house prices lead to an increase in banks

non-performing loans, and as their collateral shrink, so does their capacity to lend.

The recent boom in house prices were driven by two common factors: low interest rates

encouraged home buyers to borrow more money and the households lost faith in equities, making

properties look more attractive. One of the major problems has been that

91 Web: Greenspan Says U.S. Should consider Breaking Up Large Banks 92 Web: Real estate bubble

Page 47: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

47

“rising house prices have boosted consumer spending by making

people feel wealthier, offsetting the effect of falling share prices.

Consumers have also been able to borrow more against the

higher value of their homes, turning capital gains into cash

which they can spend on a new car or a holiday.”93

Rising house prices help boost spending, however when these prices fall, so does consumption,

causing pain for the economy. Even a modest weakening of house prices would hurt consumer

spending, because home-owners have been cashing out their capital gains at a record pace.

Furthermore a decline in property prices will leave some households with homes worth less than the

amount they have borrowed. This could lead them into insolvency. An example: in the wake of the

Danish real estate bubble burst in 2007 it was estimated that, in 2009, around 120.000 home owners

were considered insolvent.94

Looking at figure 6.5 we see that housing prices have risen

significantly since 1996 reaching a high around 2007, where the financial crisis began. After this

prices started declining, however at different rates. Ireland, however, has experienced a regular

meltdown falling from around 400% to around 250%.

Figure 6.5: House-price Index95

93 Web: House of cards 94 Web: 120.000 boligejere teknisk insolvente

95 Web: Clicks and Mortar

Page 48: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

48

The effect of this massive growth in housing prices is that there is a boost in wealth, or at least how

rich people believe themselves to be. On the one hand this stimulates consumption and thereby

creates demand. But on the other hand when prices go down, people feel poorer and spend less,

thereby decreasing aggregate demand. The problem is that when bubbles burst, the value of

property falls, but the level of debt does not. The burden of repaying this debt is likely to depress

aggregate demand, thereby causing economic slump. This shows us that the instability of housing

prices has the effect of deepening a recession and overheating the economy in good times. The

monetarist view, at least in its more basic form, will of course be that the market forces are best left

to handle this on their own. The Keynesian view on the other hand is that the government should,

through regulation, fiscal and monetary policy, ensure that the stability of house prices does not get

out of control. However, this is not entirely unproblematic. Many of the SGP members are also

members of the Euro, and therefore rely on the European Central Bank for control of their interest

rates, and further interest rate has other effects on the economy than merely housing prices. Fiscal

policy on the other hand would mainly take the form of either raising estate taxes or implementing

transaction costs on the value growth of houses. However raising taxes for a large segment of the

population, or increasing transactions for sales, has despite the positive view of many economists,

proven to be extremely difficult to implement politically.

6.7 Analytical Summary Part I

In this chapter we have identified two core problems with the SGP. The main problem being that the

pact completely ignores the significance of the private sector and the secondary problem being the

3- and 60% thresholds. The latter are chosen from a mathematical theoretical perspective that only

makes sense when connected to a specific growth rate. This is, in our minds, not a sensible way to

conduct economic policy. This is evidenced by the fact that the 3% criteria was chosen due to a

period-specific growth rate, and the 60% criteria was chosen because it was the average public

sector debt in the Euro-zone at the time. But, even making these rates flexible would not have been

enough. This is because these criteria completely ignore the fundamental problem that caused the

Page 49: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

49

financial crisis; the growing debt-issues in the private sector. Thus, not only must the rates become

flexible in order to make economic sense; the SGP should also have taken heed of the private sector

and its problems, notably private sector debt. The public and private sector cannot be kept apart in

theory or in practice, as their economic fortunes are intertwined. One extreme example is the bank

bail-outs which blurred the borders between state and the private sector. Financial institutions –

banks – are integrated in the modern economy in a way that makes them key to the stability of it. It

is unwise to ignore them and their effect in a Stability and Growth Pact. Thus, a solid pact should

include details about how to secure the financial institutions that are among the most important

factors in our economy. However, even a pact that answers these concerns might be problematic.

This is so because of the restrictive nature of a focus on the public sector that does away with a very

important tool for financial policy; the expansive financial policy. As we have shown earlier, this

can cripple economies already in trouble due to the economic crisis. If the only tool available during

a financial crisis in which demand is low is to restrict the public budget, thus averting one-self from

aggregating demand, a vicious circle where demand plummets can potentially occur. One can only

speculate how bad a situation the EU might have been in, were it not for the last-minute save from

the central governments in the form of aforementioned bank bail-outs. Something ill-advisable

following a monetarist line of thought became a necessity to undo the damage caused by the crisis.

Furthermore, countries who have automatic stabilizers in place to protect them against these

situations - i.e. a fall in demand when a “slump” in the economy occurs - will be in even greater

jeopardy if the “slump” is long lasting, because unemployment benefits will start to hollow out the

government treasury. Thus, member states with extended welfare systems and hereby extended

unemployment benefits will be more prone to exceed the 3% budget deficit.

Page 50: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

50

Chapter 7 – Competitiveness

In this chapter we introduce some of the relevant macroeconomic factors concerning competition.

This is relevant in accordance to the Euro Plus Pact as its main focus is on fostering

competitiveness. First we introduce the concept of exchange rate, as the exchange rate is a main

measurement of the demand for the currency of a nation and thereby its status in the international

markets. Further as it is affected by both market forces, and by government actions such as

monetary policy, it is an interesting point of intersection between these two. Lastly it is important to

understand in a nuanced fashion. This is because of the different relationships between countries

with different exchange rate systems and the consequences membership of the Euro-zone can have

for these. Following this the Balance of Payments will then be introduced as it gives a general idea

of the current state of the ratio between imports and exports. The EPP mentions countries with

major imbalances on the Balance of Payments are also the countries which are suffering the most as

a result of the recent crisis. Lastly we will look at Unit Labour Cost, as it is a good indicator on how

competitiveness is developing between the different European countries.

7.1 Exchange Rate and Real Effective Exchange Rate

Currency is used as a means of payment domestically; however, foreign currency is rarely able to

be used in this same fashion. Foreign currency is instead used for payment transactions to and from

other countries. The foreign exchange market (Forex) exchanges one national currency for

another.96

The exchange rate is the price at which two currencies exchange. The figure below shows

how changes in supply and demand of currency affect the exchange rate with a floating exchange

rate.

96 �

Begg (2006); p. 294-296

Page 51: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

51

Figure 7.0: Exchange Rate97

To give an example, we will use Denmark. If we look at S1 then the point of where it crosses D1 is

the current exchange rate. Following if an increase in demand for DKK takes place, perhaps Danish

goods suddenly become fashionable in Europe, then the crossing point changes to S1D2, causing an

appreciation in currency. In the same way if demand for Danish goods was to fall, then demand for

DKK would also decrease, therefore depreciating the value of the currency. In conclusion the value

of the currency is affected by market forces (mainly trade and capital flow) and it is the macro

economic performance, mainly competitiveness, which drives the value of the currency.

7.2 Fixed Exchange Regimes

The different exchange rate regimes describe the different governmental approaches to exchange

rate policy.98

A fixed exchange rate means that central banks will by or sell as much currency as

people demand at a fixed rate. In the figure above, assuming supply is at S1 and demand at D1 is

the free market equilibrium – suppose the demand then were to shift to D2, Europeans hooked on

Danish exports need more DKK to import from Denmark. In a fixed exchange rate, rather than the

DKK being appreciated in value, the bank then prints money and sells them adding to the Danish

foreign exchange reserves. If Danes experience an increasing demand for goods from Euro

countries, moving the crossing point for S1D2 to S1D1, then, in order to “defend” the Danish

exchange rate, the central bank must then buy DKK using the foreign exchange reserves, thereby

intervening in the market.

97 Web: Fixed and Floating Exhange Rates 98 �

Begg (2006); p. 296-298

Page 52: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

52

The Euro-zone, was created to secure a more stable currency market with less fluctuations.

Furthermore, one of the goals was to decrease “selfish” behaviour by countries, such as devaluing

the currency, the aptly named “beggar-your-neighbour” policies, as the consequence of this usually

was to simply move unemployment from one country to the other. However, an increase in one

country's competitiveness, whether due to a reduction in domestic wage costs or through a currency

adjustment (devaluation), can only happen at the expense of other countries. Later on we will focus

on the consequences of a common currency and its effect on competitiveness.

This shows us that there is a relationship between competitiveness and exchange rate, and

depending on which exchange rate regime is chosen, the relationship will differ. True floating

exchange rates are quite rare, as most governments will attempt to manipulate it at least to a certain

degree.99

Furthermore, there are other options, such as Denmark which in reality has a semi-fixed

exchange rate where the DKK is allowed to fluctuate within certain parameters while still being

pegged to the Euro, which in turn is free floating against foreign currencies (that is, those not

pegged to it). In addition, it is important to look at the effective exchange rate, which is the

exchange rate of for example Denmark compared to its major trading partners weighed by their

trade share.100

If all of Denmark's trade was with Euro-countries, the exchange rate should be fixed,

however Euro-trade accounts only for about half of Denmark's trade, with the rest being constituted

by Sweden, UK and other countries. The effective exchange rate of the DKK can therefore

fluctuate considerably in relation to these countries. However this is still insufficient to explain

exchange relations in the EU. There is also the matter of real exchange rate which further

complicates these matters. The real exchange rate is the purchasing power of two currencies relative

to one another. By looking at the purchasing power, real exchange rate takes into account inflation.

When it is then deflated by a measurement such as the Unit Labour Cost, it becomes Real effective

exchange rate (REER). As real effective exchange rate takes into account both inflation (Real

Exchange rate) and the consequences of currencies being traded with multiple partners (effective

exchange rate), it better displays the progression of competitiveness over time.

If we take a brief look the the Real Effective Exchange rates between some of the European countries.

99 �

Web: Fixed and Floating Exhange Rates 100 Jespersen (2005); p. 104

Page 53: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

53

Figure 7.1, Real Effective Exchange rate101

The chosen countries compares the EU average, with some of the Euro-zone countries that were

affected the most by the financial crisis, Germany, and the UK which has a flexible exchange rate.

It is clear that despite the EU goals of convergence there has been some considerable divergence in

the EU. The UK allowed its flexible exchange rate to work as a shock absorber, while the many

Euro-zone countries, with the common monetary policy of the ECB, did not have this luxury.

Though the effect of a depreciated currency will of course make UK's exports worth less, it will

also increase its competitiveness, and therefore exports will start increasing soon after. The Euro-

101 Appendix 6, Note that the Euro average is at times higher than any of the countries because of the excluded countries, epsecially the new joiners of Eastern Europe.

Page 54: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

54

zone countries on the other hand, are tied down by the fact that Germany remains so competitive. If

we assume the European Central Bank then follows a policy which aims to work for all of the EU,

the effects for Germany and the other Euro-zone countries would only diverge further. While it may

be possible for the ECB to improve the competitiveness of the Euro-zone countries vis a vis the rest

of the world, its ability to affect the intra EU imbalances is quite limited. The relationship of REER

is one of the main reasons for imbalances on the Balance of Payments in the EU, which the

following chapter will cover.

7.3 The Balance of Payments

The Balance of Payments is the accounting of the monetary transactions between one country and

the rest of the world. These transactions include the export and import (of goods, services and

capital) and financial transactions. In simple terms, the Balance of Payments is what describes the

flow of money and trade between countries. Sources of funds (inflow) come from exports and

receipts of loans as surplus items, while imports and investment in foreign countries are deficits

(outflow).102

The Balance of Payments (BoP) as defined by IMF, OECD and the UN is:103

However the definitions of financial account and capital account vary by account and are often

combined into the simpler equation below, which will henceforth be used:

104

The current account is composed of the balance of trade (imports and exports), net factor income

and net transfer payments. The capital account shows the net change in domestic ownership of

assets and capital. As the current account minus capital account should always equal zero, the

balancing item is a statistical adjustment, which accounts for failures of measurement and adds or

subtracts so the total result is zero. The reason it should always equal zero is because the Balance of

102 Begg (2006); p. 298 103 Web: Balance of Payments and International Investment Manual; p. 45 104 �

Web: Balance of Payments and International Investment Manual; p. 46

Page 55: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

55

Payments is an accounting balance sheet.105

So from this framework it follows that if a country is

importing more than it is exporting it is running a deficit on the current account, which must in turn

be balanced by a surplus on the capital account. The net result is that a deficit of trade results in loss

of domestic ownership of assets.106

Small deficits and surpluses on the current account should generally not be a problem, and

classic economic theory holds that the current account should be self-balancing, as being successful

(a surplus) would effectively appreciate the effective value and currency, and vice versa running a

deficit should devalue the currency effectively making a country more competitive. This line of

thought is central to monetarism and as such to the shaping of the original SGP. Of course, this is

based on the assumption that the optimal currency area (OCA) is functioning well, regarding price

and wage flexibility, and that capital mobility and labour mobility is high. While capital mobility

has indeed proven to be high, sticky wages, sticky prices and mobility of labour has lagged behind,

which explains why a monetarist such as Milton Friedman opposed it. The OCA was based on the

idea that integration would create further integration and eventually economies would converge,

rendering the BoP irrelevant. This view is opposed by Keynesians such as Jespersen,107

who argues

that a deficit to other Euro-zone countries will still have a negative effect even though import and

exports are in the same currency.

7.4 The Balance of Payments in the EU

Before discussing the Balance of Payments vis-à-vis the SPG and the Euro-Plus Pact, an empirical

overview of the Balance of Payments in the EU should be established.

105

Begg (2006); p. 299 106 Begg (2006); p. 299 107 Jespersen (2005); p. 108

Page 56: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

56

Figure 7.2: Current Account108

If we take a look at the chart we can firstly see one thing: the Euro-area as a whole has been fairly

consistent around zero, even during the early 2000s downturn and the 2007 crisis it dropped only a

few percent below zero which is within “acceptable” parameters. To some extent, the trade deficits

are therefore to be found between the Euro-zone countries.

With this assumption, that we can look at the countries as a closed system, we conclude that

within this system there are some big winners, and some big losers. The second thing we see is that

there are some very noticeable discrepancies between the countries. Portugal and Greece, and to

some degree Spain, have consistently had a deficit in excess of 5% over a rather extended period.

On the opposite side of the spectrum we find Germany, Sweden and Netherlands whose surpluses

are equally large.

Paul De Grauwe recognizes two different models: the optimistic Commission-view

(monetarist) which holds that asymmetries should grow smaller with time, making shocks less

significant.109

The other view is the Krugman-view (New Keynesian), which argues that as

countries specialize to take advantage of comparative advantages, they actually become more

exposed to asymmetric shocks when they integrate. These two models explain the basic

disagreement about the Balance of Payments. The monetarist view holds that the current accounts

108

Appendix 7 109 �

De Grauwe (2009); p. 86

Page 57: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

57

are unimportant, and also implies they should be self-adjusting, while the New Keynesians, worried

about the increasing deficits, point to the empirical data and ask how the deficits can continue to

grow if this were true.

If a sizeable deficit is retained over several years, there are some problems, as even if a

country is now running a surplus, much of this will be used simply to pay off interest rates on

loans.110

Furthermore, such a situation could also imply a movement of production and employment

and migration. This is a particularly egregious if unemployment is already high, as it signals a

weakness of competitiveness. It is also made interesting by the fact that one of the goals of the EU

is the mobility of residents/workers, and as most of the employment in the EU is within the tertiary

(service) sector, and therefore is not bound to locations by means of access to resources.

7.5 The Return of New Keynesianism?

The Stability and Growth Pact does not take imbalances in the Balance of Payments into account.

This is because it took its point of departure in the monetarist ideas of the Washington Consensus.

The Washington Consensus argued that there was no particular reason to worry about the

imbalances on the Balance of Payments, as with a floating exchange rate, the economy should be

self correcting. Notable monetarist Milton Friedman and Austria school scholar Murray Rothbard

thought little of such concerns:

“Fortunately, the absurdity of worrying about the balance of

payments is made evident by focusing on inter-state trade. For

nobody worries about the balance of payments between New

York and New Jersey, or, for that matter, between Manhattan

and Brooklyn, because there are no customs officials recording

such trade and such balances.”111

This quote reflects the core thoughts of monetarism on the Balance of Payments. If the EU has a

single currency, then it follows that monitoring the Balance of Payments is no more purposeful than

monitoring it within a country. However, Friedman remained sceptical that the conditions of the

110 Jespersen (2005); p. 88 111 Web: Protectionism and the Destruction of Prosperity

Page 58: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

58

Euro-zone would be sufficient to create a system where BoP would be irrelevant. If the Euro-zone

could be considered as one state, with one single fiscal entity, or at least a system of redistribution,

between exporters and importers, as was actually originally proposed by Mundell, the father of the

OCA, then there would be not a problem, as the surplus of one country would automatically

mitigate the deficit in another. Jespersen adds to this argument that “The stability and growth pact

should have been shaped in such a way as to make mitigating the imbalances in the BoP within the

Euro-zone a requirement and high priority.”112

However, this would require the Euro-zone

countries to cooperate on fiscal policy to a hitherto unprecedented level. Similarly if browsing The

Economics of the European Union,113

the main source of monetarism in the EU for this project, the

reader will find next to nothing on the Balance of Trade.

While the EPP, sometimes referred to as the Competition Pact, makes no mention of the

Balance of Payments, the proposed scoreboard takes a rather new stance on the issue. The current

account is now a very useful indicator showing competitiveness.114

If one country imports more

goods than it exports, it will be running a deficit on the balance of trade, signalling a weakness in its

competitiveness. Similarly countries with a too large surplus may be suffering from overly low

domestic demand and investment. Further it points out that many of the countries affected by the

financial crisis (Greece, Spain, and Ireland) ran extremely large deficits. The scoreboard

recommends that countries should aim to keep their BoP within a ±4% of GDP to avoid problems,

and imbalances greater than this will risk disciplinary actions from the commission. While our

empirical data suggests that the BoP does indeed matter, and that these imbalances are problematic,

it does not however mention how exactly countries are to solve these imbalances. As the monetary

policy is now effectively in the hands of the European Central Bank, devaluation is certainly not

going to be a possible option. Another way could then be for countries to make large investments in

infrastructure or education to improve their competitiveness; however such measure would only

have a real effect in the long term, and would require government investments, incurring debt,

which would of course clash with the requirement of limiting public deficit. Thus, there seems to be

a somewhat contradicting line of thought evident here: on the one hand, the EPP acknowledges the

112 Jespersen (2008); p. 24 113 �

Artis & Nixon (2007) 114 Web: Indikatorer og scoreboard om overvågningen af makroøkonomiske ubalance

Page 59: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

59

importance of the Balance of Payments, on the other hand, it turns a blind eye to how countries can

bring it under control whilst adhering to the requirements of the SGP.

7.6 Unit Labour Cost

The cost of production plays a vital role for competitiveness in the economic system. It is important

domestic as well as abroad and the decisive question is how the costs per produced unit is

determined in each country. Given that the most significant competitors are located in other western

industrialized countries, where production techniques more or less are the same, this is unlikely to

become a factor. The capital markets are furthermore integrated to such a degree, that differences in

capital costs are relatively small. The most important cost factor that varies between countries must

therefore be linked to labour. And the variations here can be rather substantial. Wage determination

is still a national matter due to the lack of international integration, and is still modest within the

European Union. The difference in wage cost therefore plays a significant role in relation to making

up the competitiveness. The development in competitiveness is based on an index, Unit Labour

Cost (ULC), for each country, which then is corrected in relations for the real effective exchange

rate. When a currency drops in value compared to for instance the dollar, this will then lead to a

drop in domestic costs in dollar, which makes earnings in domestic industries go up as seen in

figure 7.3.

Page 60: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

60

Figure 7.3: Competitiveness115

As seen in the figure, costs play a more substantial role for the export in a sector that produces to a

market with a horizontal rather than a steep demand curve. The steeper the demand curve, the less

does the cost reductions affect the level of quantity.116

Unit Labour Cost measures the average cost of labour per unit of output and is calculated as

the ratio of total labour costs to real output. It represents a direct link between productivity and the

cost of labour used in generating output.

“A rise in an economy's unit labour costs represents an

increased reward for labour's contribution to output. However, a

rise in labour costs higher than the rise in labour productivity

may be a threat to an economy's cost competitiveness, if other

costs are not adjusted in compensation.”117

Another important measurement which has to do with competitiveness is labour productivity, and it

is measured as output per unit of labour. The economic growth of an economy can be ascribed

either to increased employment or to more effective work by those who are employed. Important

factors behind improvement in labour productivity are the accumulation of machinery and

115 Jespersen (2009); p. 106 (translated from Danish) 116 �Jespersen (2009); p. 106 117 �Web: Unit Labour Costs OECD

Page 61: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

61

equipment, improvements in organisation as well as physical and institutional infrastructures,

“human capital” (improved health and skills of workers), and the generation of new technology.

Labour productivity estimates can be useful to monitor and develop the effects of labour market

policies. High labour productivity is often associated with high levels or particular types of human

capital, indicating priorities for specific education and training policies.118

It can furthermore be

used to understand the effects of wage settlements on rates of inflation or to ensure that such

settlements will compensate workers for realised productivity improvements.

Figure 7.4: Unit Labour Costs119

Looking at figure 7.4 it becomes clear that countries within the Euro area are not homogeneous

when it comes to reducing their Unit Labour Cost, which as stated earlier is a helpful indicator

when measuring competitiveness. The overall tendency is ascending besides Germany's ULC,

which throughout the late '90s and early '00s, was relatively high compared to other countries.

Germany however seems to be the only country able to improve its ULC. But as stated earlier a

high ULC is also an indication on increasing reward for labour in the form of higher wages. This

does not constitute a problem per se. The problem arises when wages costs per unit evolves higher

118 �

Web: Labour Productivity 119

Web: Germany's Massive Rebound Has Nothing To Do With Exports To Europe

Page 62: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

62

than labour productivity, which in turn will lead to weaken competitiveness. Turning to figure 7.5,

which is a figure over labour productivity we see also ascending tendency in productivity. All

countries experience increased productivity, with Italy as an exemption, which experience constant

productivity, which constitutes a problem as ULC has gone up through the years (see figure 7.4).

The Euro-zone as a whole has only increased its productivity marginally and has virtually remained

constant since 2005, which again constitutes a problem as the tendency in ULC is ascending.

Figure 7.5: Labour Productivity120

Turning to the newly enacted Euro Plus Pact, negotiations now evolve on goals to increase

competitiveness. Threshold values relating to Unit Labour Costs have been suggested as a

measurement to ensure development in competitiveness. These values should differentiate between

Euro-members (9%) and non-members (12%), reflecting the fact that member states' mutual

exchange rate per definition is fixed. The fixed exchange rate is not able to absorb divergent

progresses in competitiveness.121

As mentioned earlier one the ways to ensure competitiveness is simply to lower wages.

However as we noted in the previous chapter this has some macroeconomic consequences, which

should also be considered. A lower reward for labour will inevitably lead to a fall in private

consumption, which again affects aggregate demand. Another way to increase competitiveness is by

investing in human capital, thereby ensuring that your labour force is well educated. However if this

120 Appendix 8 121 Web: Indikatorer og scoreboard om overvågningen af makroøkonomiske ubalance

Page 63: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

63

is a priority from the government, then this would inevitably lead to an increase in public spending,

which might conflict with the SGP rule concerning a 3 % budget deficit. One could argue, that if

wages were to be reduced, companies would have an incentive to invest more as their level of profit

would go up in accordance with the wage reduction.

7.7 Analytical Summary Part II

While the EPP only covers the economic subjects in general, negotiations surrounding

measurements and which values should be applied are still ongoing. However, much of the debate

is not focused on what the values should be, but rather the nature of implementation and how

breaches of the limits should be dealt with by the Commission – in essence it is a debate on whether

the nation states or the EU should interpret and enforce these rules and values. Based on this we

will make the assumption, for the sake of analysis, that the proposed scoreboard will be agreed

upon, and that these values will be treated as effective. This allows us a theoretical debate on the

economic aspects of the EPP, and how politics might affect it, without being constrained by the

reality of political negotiations.

The scoreboard has set a range of new goals for the private sector, including a limit of 160%

debt, a loft on growth of 15% in the total credit to the private sector and a 6% increases in the price

of total value of real estate. If we look at the examples from Chapter 5, we can see that the UK has a

total debt of above 450% of GDP, of which the government debt is only roughly 60%. This leaves

the private sector with a debt just shy of 400%. There is a long way from 400% to the 160% limit. It

is somewhat unclear in the scoreboard exactly how debt is to be brought down to this level, and

there is no obvious solution. Stringent regulation limiting the lending ability of the financial sector

will have far reaching macro economic consequences as it is likely to further a recession by limiting

growth. There has been a difference as to where the private sector debt lies within the countries – it

is not a homogeneous size. This is exemplified by the comparison of UK and Spain. UK has

accumulated debt especially in the financial sector, whereas Spain has accumulated in the non-

financial sectors (especially real estate). This again makes it difficult to talk about private sector

debt as one entity. Regulation of the private sector therefore seems to be somewhat of a blurry

concept. The EPP states that it is up to the member states to bring down their private sector debt.

However, this could harm competition if some countries set up regulation in some sectors, where

Page 64: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

64

other countries do not. A counterargument here could be setting up rules on a supranational level.

This in turn is difficult because the many countries already have different debt levels; therefore it

would lead to the same problems such as ECB's monetary policy of “one size fits all.” This problem

can, hypothetically, be avoided by taking into account the different economic situations in different

countries when making economic policy on a supranational level. As mentioned in Chapter 5 the

bursting of the real estate bubble was one of the contributors to the recent crisis. Measurements in

order to prevent a new bubble to arise have been suggested, specifically the 6% increase on real

estate prices. This is one of the more realistic goals of the scoreboard, as it does not have the

problem of the 160% limit in that the limit has already been passed. Further it has the advantage

that the real estate market was recently deflated, as a limit on real estate price growth would be odd

if prices were already above a level which is considered sustainable.

The second set of parameters of the EPP and the scoreboard has to do with the indicators of

competitiveness. Balance of Payments (BoP), Unit Labour Cost (ULC) and Real Effective

Exchange Rate (REER) are all now to be closely monitored to measure a country's international

competitiveness. The reason ULC and REER have risen to become such as valuable measurement is

because of the Optimum Currency Area (OCA). Without individual exchange rates, countries are no

longer able to absorb asymmetric shocks through the exchange rate, and become more competitive

by adjusting this. Because of the fixed exchange rate, ULC and REER are the good tools for

measuring the competitiveness which is so crucial to the Balance of Payments. However while

these measurements are indeed good indicators, simply having these goals does not necessarily

mean member-states will be able to improve on them. This is a key concern with the EPP and the

scoreboard: there is a difference between measurements and tools for adjusting these, and the EPP

mainly concerns the first. So while both Greece and the Commission can look at the ULC and see

that Greece’s ULC has been increasing too much, i.e. wage inflation has surpassed productivity

growth, neither the Commission nor Greece will necessarily have the tools to do anything about it.

One tool that can be used is wage reduction, i.e. governments taking a hard-line stance demanding a

lowering of current wages or at least limiting wage growth. However the government can mainly

affect the public sector wages and even these are often subject to collective wage settlements

between labour unions and employers. In short they tend to be politically complicated. If these

wage reductions however are forced through by political intervention, then another macroeconomic

Page 65: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

65

problem arises. These wage reductions result in lower income, which again results in lower private

consumption affecting aggregate demand. In a time of recession this seems ill-advisable. Of course

this decrease in aggregate demand could be countered by social benefits; indeed the EPP has

brought attention to the success of the so-called “flexicurity” model, which allows companies to fire

people freely, and people to accept this because they know they will receive unemployment

benefits, thereby creating a more flexible labour market. This of course will in turn require public

spending, and as such clash with the still very much alive SGP and its financial restrictions which

the EPP and scoreboard intend to maintain.

The above mentioned arguments are of course based on Keynesian assumptions on what

effects wage reduction will have on aggregate demand. A monetarist would argue that the high

wages and the lack of wage flexibility is the reason for lack of competitiveness.

In summary, the EPP and the proposed scoreboard have introduced a range of interesting

measurements that will give a better view on the economic development of competitiveness in the

EU. However the range of possibilities the member-states are able to use is questionable. In essence

the EPP does not solve all the problems of the SGP. While the member states have these new

measurements, there is still the fundamental problem of not having the right tools. The division of

fiscal and monetary policy between member state and the ECB means that the Euro-zone members

in particular will still be facing all the same problems and imbalances that they have done for the

last dozen years. The fact that they now have the correct measuring tools merely means that they are

now aware of these problems.

Page 66: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

66

Chapter 8 – The Political Arena

In this chapter we will add another aspect to our analysis of the SGP and EPP: the political

circumstances affecting these economic agreements. More specifically we will take the political

concerns of Marco Buti regarding the SGP and apply them to the debate of the EPP in Denmark. In

doing so we aim to shed light on the political difficulties these agreements are surrounded by.

8.1 What Went Wrong?

First and foremost, this report asks the question above in regards to the economic failure of the

SGP, but this chapter expands on that perspective. The pact is criticized by both monetarists and

Keynesians alike, so economic schools of thought cannot take full responsibility for the failings of

the pact. Politics is the deciding factor in the European Union – no less so for the pact. This chapter

aims to examine some of the flawed political reasoning behind the pact. To do this, we will use an

economic paper written by Marco Buti, Directorate-General for Economic and Financial Affairs in

the European Commission, published in 2006. In the paper, Buti identifies several overall political

concepts in the pact – we shall look at them from a critical angle.

Buti sets up five parameters for potential missteps in the original SGP. They are: Political

Visibility, Clear Incentives, Political Ownership, Constraining Calendar and Collegial

Culture.122

Political Visibility

A concept which we have pondered on and discussed throughout this project is the seemingly

arbitrary 3% maximum budget deficit criterion. The question remains why this arbitrary number

was selected. Buti suggests an answer. According to him, the 3% might very well have been chosen

because it achieved some political goals, while not offending the economists behind the pact. It

offered a clear-cut goal for member states: “Bring your deficit below 3%.” It was also easy to

profile and bring forth into the public debate. Instead of having complex mechanisms determining

different variations on the criterion for different member states, the 3% also allowed the

122 Web: Will the New Stability and Growth Pact Succeed; p. 19

Page 67: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

67

Commission to easily monitor and secure genuine implementation of the criterion.123

As we have

already explained, the 3% criterion would falter in other areas, most notably in terms of economy.

As we have also explained, in spite of the Commission's ability to monitor the member states'

adherence to this criterion, the Commission was ultimately rendered powerless to enforce the Pact

when the political forces behind the SGP (Germany and France) broke it themselves and refused to

abide by the Commission's suggestions. The 3% might have seemed a good idea from a political

perspective at the time, but time has clarified that it is ineffective both from an economic and

political angle.

Clear Incentives

Within the framework of SGP, incentives to adhere to the pact were watered down from the original

incentives laid out in the Maastricht treaty. Instead of a clear balance between “the carrot” of

membership of the Euro zone, and “the stick,” the threat of exclusion and penalties for failure to

adhere to the agreement, the SGP included the carrot right from the beginning, while only posing

the threat of a stick in a far future. In essence, the sanctions in the SGP were unlikely to see the light

of day, especially against large, influential member states. Thus, entering the SGP would yield a

carrot to each member state, while an artificial stick, almost toothless, would hang as a false threat

over the non-compliant member states.124

From our perspective, this gives ample political reason to

enter the pact, but it's also apparent that any incentives to adhere to the pact were symbolic at best.

Political ownership

The Pact's primary engineer and political owner was Germany, who, from the beginning, enforced a

rigorous set of rules for macroeconomic stability within the pact. The reason that Germany could

demand these strict rules were two-fold; firstly, because Germany's participation was important for

the survival of the pact, and secondly, because many small member states with good economies had

no problems backing up strict requirements for fiscal policy. These “virtuous”, small member states

adhered to the rules of the Pact before they were laid out and thus had no reason to protest against

the strict set of rules. With Germany as the main architect and political owner, it became alpha

omega that Germany “lead by example”, however. If Germany, the number one promoter of tight

123 Web: Will the New Stability and Growth Pact Succeed; p. 19-20 124 Web: Will the New Stability and Growth Pact Succeed; p. 20

Page 68: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

68

macroeconomic rules, would not enforce the pact itself, who would?125

This obviously posed a

problem for the pact, when Germany later broke the criterion.

Constraining Calendar

The time-frame for the objectives set for members of the Pact operated within an extremely small

window. Member states were required to comply with the rules of the SGP fairly quickly, and had

no choice in when or how to consolidate with the convergence requirements.126

Collegial Culture

To succeed, a Pact must be built on mutual trust and compliance from all member states. In other

words, the parties must believe that the other members will hold to their end of the bargain if they

are to do it themselves. But in the case of the SGP, mutual trust was replaced with dispute between

the Commission and the Council, leading to a court appeal. On top of this, when Germany and

France began failing to adhere to the convergence criteria, the dispute over when to sanction

evolved into a conflict between small and large member states. In the end, the system favoured

“financial sinners” - some member states backed up “sinning” member states with the promise of

being backed up later themselves.127

In the end, Buti concludes that no matter the strength of the economic ideas behind a pact, it

can only be enforced and therefore functional if a) the strong regional parties support and adhere to

it and b) the pact is fully integrated into the national policy framework.128

8.2 Denmark and the Euro Plus Pact

Denmark, along with Poland, Lithuania, Latvia, Romania, Bulgaria and the 17 Euro countries,

joined the Euro Plus Pact. In Denmark however there is a wide variety of opinions on which effects

the Euro Plus Pact will have on the Danish economy and which obligations Denmark has to fulfil as

a member of the pact. This section will aim to outline these differences and in some cases

contradictions. The section will be divided into two subsections, presenting the arguments for

Denmark joining the EPP firstly and then presenting the arguments against Denmark joining the

125 Web: Will the New Stability and Growth Pact Succeed; p. 20-21 126 Web: Will the New Stability and Growth Pact Succeed; p. 21 127 Web: Will the New Stability and Growth Pact Succeed; p. 21 128 Web: Will the New Stability and Growth Pact Succeed; p. 23

Page 69: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

69

EPP. Each section will include the concerns behind the arguments. The quotes used below are

translated from Danish, but can be found in their original form in the sources.

The Danish Prime Minister Lars Løkke Rasmussen expressed his optimism regarding the EPP

after the summit meeting concerning the EPP on March 4, 2011. According to Lars Løkke

Rasmussen the EPP will have a positive effect on the politics in the EU. It is the heads of state who

will collectively discuss the economies of the single countries from an EU perspective and this will

according to the Danish Prime Minister make the politics more systematic. Furthermore Denmark

has an interest in joining the pact, because it will help the difficult discussions on the necessary

actions Denmark needs to take, in order to lower the public sector deficit.129

The Danish Social Democrats, Socialdemokraterne (S), along with Socialistisk Folkeparti and

Radikale Venstre, announced their full support of the pact after reaching an agreement with the

Danish government. According to financial spokesman from Socialdemokraterne Morten Bødskov,

the initial concern of the EPP handing control of central policy areas to the EU, such as labour

market policy and the Danish sovereignty over the fiscal policy, has been answered in a satisfactory

manner. The agreement reached with the government met the following criteria for Bødskov:

“The option of undertaking expansionary financial politics during times of economic crisis has

been maintained”130

“The Danish parliament alone will determine the content of the Danish fiscal policy”131

“The labour market’s social partners independent right to negotiate wage- and working

conditions, will remain untouched”132

Executive director of Dansk Industri, a Danish interest group composing of private companies,

Karsten Dybvad, is likewise optimistic about Denmark joining the EPP. Karsten Dybvad points out

that the EPP will have a positive effect on the competitiveness and employment in Danish

companies. As a member of the pact Denmark has to make clear which initiatives they will start in

order to foster competitiveness and fulfil the fixed goals within twelve months. In this light, Karsten

129 Web: euroPlus pagt giver politisk systematik 130 Web: S, SF og R sikrer ansvarlig dansk EU-politik 131 Web: S, SF og R sikrer ansvarlig dansk EU-politik 132 Web: S, SF og R sikrer ansvarlig dansk EU-politik

Page 70: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

70

Dybvad is looking forward to seeing the Danish politicians passing the needed reforms in this

area.133

Not all the parties of the Danish parliament supported the Danish participation in the EPP.

Enhedslisten was the most outspoken critic of the EPP, but Dank Folkeparti and Liberal Alliance

were against Denmark joining as well. Per Clausen from Enhedslisten wrote in a chronic that:

”Not only does it limit Denmark’s political wiggle room for

conducting independent economic politics, it also refers one-

sidedly to a right-winged crisis-solution policy, in which the

policy of the VKO-majority with cutbacks on public welfare,

reduced subsistence, decrease in real wages, as well as renewed

attacks on retirement funds, are articulated as the only relevant

economic policy.”134

The criticism of the EPP and the Danish participation has not been limited to the political arena.

Leading professors from the Danish universities have met the pact with harsh criticism, a criticism

that ranges from democratic deficit to its lack of sanctions.

Professor in economics at Syddansk Universitet and former economic adviser Christen

Sørensen, criticizes the pact for taking influence from the national parliaments and giving it to the

heads of government.135

Each year common economic goals for the members of the Euro Plus Pact

will be set out, which will be negotiated between the heads of government. Goals, which may be up

to the members states to reach in their preference, but none the less goals which have to be fulfilled.

This dislocation of power from the parliaments to the heads of government is according to Christen

Sørensen136

an inevitable step towards strong economic integration, required for the functioning of

a common currency, even though the population is not in favour of this. Christen Sørensen points

out that this dislocation of power was not discussed when the Danish parliament undertook the

negotiations for the pact. Furthermore Sørensen expresses his concerns about the lack of sanctions

in the pact, as it may be a disadvantage when it comes to securing confidence in the Euro.

133 Web: Venstrefløjstrid om europagt forsætter 134 Web: Europagt forpligter 135 Web: Europagt skaber demokratisk underskud 136 Web: Europagt skaber demokratisk underskud

Page 71: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

71

Professor in economics at Aarhus University, Torben M. Andersen, echoes Christian

Sørensen’s critique of the EPP for its lack of sanctions. According to him the EPP is merely a list of

obvious economic tools, which the member states are already acquainted with, and the EPP is likely

to end up as just another EU document filled with fancy words no one can disagree with, but with

no real weight behind it.137

Professor at Centre for European Politics at Copenhagen University, Marlene Wind, predicts

that the EPP will be used as a scapegoat by the Danish government, when they have make spending

cuts in the public sector.

”Just imagine a government led by S and SF that has to make

cutbacks in the public sector in contradiction to what they have

said they will do – then they can use EU as a scapegoat and say

’unfortunately we have no choice, it comes from Brussels.’

That’s the way it is going to be used, as certain as death and

taxes.”138

Another interesting angle of this discussion is the degree to which the EPP is binding for the

member states. In Denmark the debate on this subject has been a heated one. Does the fact that the

EPP is not legally binding mean that the member states do not need to adhere to it? Or does the

political agreement have so much political value that the member states have to abide by it?

Mogens Ove Madsen, lector at Aalborg University, made it clear in an interview with

Arbejderen that Denmark was not obligated to fulfil requirements set out in the future Euro Plus

Pact negotiations, due to the fact that it is not legally binding and Denmark is not a part of the

monetary union and therefore has greater freedom.

“It is worth it to underline that we are not obligated to

implement the recommendations the commission might put

forward e.g. in terms of the convergence criteria. It is important

not to get caught up in the conservative and new liberal politics

137 Web: Europagten – Hvad løser den? 138 Web: Europagten er en sejr for tysk økonomisk tænkning

Page 72: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

72

which is at focus in the pact. We still have more freedom than

the Euro countries, no matter how much the government would

like us to be bound to it.” 139

Contrary to the above statement comes the statements from the Danish prime minister, Lars Løkke

Rasmussen, which seem to enforce the idea that Denmark is obligated under the pact:

“It is the sovereign right of the government to decide which

concrete goals Denmark as a Europact-country must commit to

within the next year's time. And Denmark must commit itself to

getting rid of the special retirement.”140

This ”special retirement” is the Danish ”efterløn”, which is a subsidized retirement plan from the

government that allows withdrawal with benefits at the age of 62 for members of the plan.

According to Lars Løkke Rasmussen, Denmark is obligated to rid itself of this special retirement

under the Euro Plus Pact. However, according to the opposition, Socialdemokraterne and

Socialistisk Folkeparti, Denmark is free to not adhere to this part of the pact.141

If the opposition and

Mogens Ove Madsen is right, this reinforces the point of Malene Wind; that the national

government is using the pact as an excuse for cutbacks.

It is clear that there are differences in opinions within the Danish parliament when it comes to

the EPP. Those in favour state that the pact will not jeopardize the Danish sovereignty over fiscal

policy, nor will it put restraints on the labour market policies. The critics within the parliament,

however, have a contradicting view of this, in their opinion the pact is one-sided and only leaves

room for conservative politics, where cut-backs in the public sector is a given. How can there be

two such different perceptions of the Euro Plus Pact? Is it merely a case of political spin where the

political parties take the EPP hostage in order to promote their own goals and values? These

questions will be dealt with in the analysis, along with the concerns of the experts, counting

democratic deficit, the EPP as a scapegoat and the lack of sanctions.

139 Web: Europagt en stakket frist 140 Web: Løkkes valgpagt 141 Web: Løkkes valgpagt

Page 73: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

73

8.3 Political Discussion

When looking at the case of Denmark and the political responses to the pact, it is difficult to not be

pessimistic about the pact's future. It seems that although the Danish parliament is in agreement that

joining the pact is the right thing to do, they have very different outlooks on why exactly. Let's start

at the beginning: We have identified some “political pit-traps” that the SGP “fell into” during its

time. The question now becomes whether the EPP will fall into the exact same traps. To ascertain

this, we will compare the political reactions and the contents of the EPP to these political pit-traps.

Firstly there is the question of Political Visibility. On one hand, the EPP has rid itself of the

burden of the 3% budget deficit restriction, which was one of the things that, according to Buti, tore

down the SGP. On the other hand, the differences in opinion in the Danish parliament can with

some weight be argued as 'political confusion'. Whether this confusion stems from actual difference

in beliefs about what the pact entails on behalf of the politicians, or is just a result of political spin

from the Danish parliament to maximize political output in favour of their own policies, it casts a

deep shadow over the political visibility of the EPP.

Next comes the question of Clear Incentives. A major problem with the SGP was that it

presented an initial carrot – the Euro - but yielded no stick when the rules were violated. The EPP

seems to have blatantly ignored this criticism of the SGP, moving, instead, in the other directions.

Now the heads of government will debate amongst themselves how well each individual member

complies with the pact. But what actions these heads of government will take against big countries

like Germany and France if they do not comply, remains to be seen. There are no clear definitions

of sanctions or similar concepts in the EPP in this regard. It can often be difficult to initiate

agreements in which the countries have to agree to being punished for “bad behaviour,” but as

outlined throughout the discussion of the SGP, sometimes no sanctions means an agreement can

become so hollow it loses everything but its symbolic meaning. Furthermore, a lack of sanctions

might, as we earlier indicated, result in a lack of faith in the Euro from the member-states.

There is also the question of Political Ownership. This is mostly a question that only the

future can answer. We can make some qualified guesses as to who has ownership of the pact for

now though – Germany certainly seems to have assumed part of this ownership once again with

Page 74: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

74

Angela Merkel leading the negotiations142

and defending the pact quite vigorously,143

but we cannot

foresee whether Germany, or anyone else for that matter, will pick up the gauntlet and lead by

example. Based on experiences with the SGP, this is not likely to happen unless steps are taken to

ensure it. Nevertheless, this is a crucial political concept, and what we can say is that there already

seem to be emerging trouble in this area. The wildly different claims as to what exactly the EPP

means for the national governments, as viewed from the different Danish politicians, sends a clear

signal that there is confusion – or, indeed, reason to create confusion – as to how bound the member

states are by the pact, and how much sovereign influence still remains. If the content of the EPP is

that much up to the governments of each member-state to decide, then how will this be reflected

when the heads of government meet and have interpreted the pact in different ways? Imagine a

social-democratic Danish Prime Minister at the annual EPP meeting between the heads of

government, in which Denmark fights with financial issues, saying “The Danish parliament alone

will determine the content of the Danish fiscal policy”144

to a German Angela Merkel, who might

hold that the rules in the EPP determine national policy, not the other way around. In this aspect,

there is already room for strife in the workings of the EPP.

Next comes a question we can discuss, but not answer. That of Constraining Calender. What

we know of the EPP, is that the heads of state will meet annually. What this means for how quickly

countries need to implement the reforms suggested in the pact, we do not know. We can, however,

say that it would be wise for the heads of government to take its time agreeing upon how the pact

should be collectively understood, before pushing for major reforms of given member states. This is

even more important considering the diverging opinions on the EPP in the national parliament of

Denmark. If we imagine the same divergence across nations, then how will this divergence reflect

on the actual agreements that must be reached annually? We cannot answer this question, but we

can speculate that getting solid policies out of the negotiations might be incredibly tough, and there

is, as we have previously concluded, room for plenty of strife in the workings of the EPP and its

institutions.

Last comes the question of Collegial Culture. This is an aspect that the EPP might have

142 Web: Can Angela Merkel Hold Europe Together? 143 Web: Merkel defends Euro Plus Pact 144 Web: S, SF og R sikrer ansvarlig dansk EU-politik

Page 75: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

75

answers to. A problem with the SGP was its form of monitoring, in which the Commission debated

with the Council, and was ultimately rendered powerless. In the EPP, the heads of government

seems to be the most influential party, which creates a single institution with main control. This

does away with “the problem” of two institutions, however, it seems to ignore the “real problem,”

the fact that “financial sinners” could back each other up to avoid sanctions. Instead of a somewhat

independent controller in the form of the Commission, the heads of government can in theory

continue the “bad collegial culture” of the SGP, supporting each other if they break the rules, or

back up each others sovereign right to decide their own fiscal policy. This might be why we're

seeing politicians from Denmark maintain that national control over fiscal policy has been secured,

in spite of the pact's seeming intentions to control some matters of national fiscal policy. The

construction of more of less total control to the national governments seem contradictory to making

the pact work. On one hand, the fact that everything must be agreed upon by all members of the

pact might make us more hopeful that they will abide by the decisions that are made within the

framework of the EPP. On the other hand, bad collegial behaviour as seen in the SGP has as much

if not more room to function in the EPP's annual meetings.

To conclude, one central concern of Marco Buti seems to be extremely relevant: Will the

workings of the pact be fully integrated into national policy framework? We cannot conclude

anything completely on the matter, but it is doubtful whether the EPP has taken any steps at all to

secure that the political failings of the SGP will not happen again.

Page 76: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

76

Chapter 9 – Conclusion

Problem formulation: Which factors contributed to the failure of the SGP and to what extent have

these factors been ratified in the EPP?

The main reason as to why the Stability and Growth Pact failed was its lack of focus on the private

sector. Most Euro countries managed to comply with the SGP's goals of public sector fiscal

discipline, until the crisis occurred, but as we have seen throughout this project it has been

somewhat overshadowed by the private sector's accumulation of debt. Spain being a glorious

example of this running surplus on the public sector budget, whilst the private sector debt was

spinning out of control. When constructing the SGP the creators failed to see the importance of the

private sector and its relation to the public sector. Thus the assumption that stability alone could be

measured on the public sector budget has been falsified. Furthermore, the setting of the deficit level

at 3% has reduced the member-states' room to conduct expansionary fiscal policy, when hit by an

asymmetric shock. In this light the SGP has favoured restrictive fiscal policy and cutbacks in times

of economic downturn. When making cutbacks in the public sector it can have a negative effect on

aggregate demand if the private sector is not able to absorb this excess of labour. Additionally, the

SGP had a restricted access to sanctions against member states breaching the rules of the pact and

when the battle between the Commission, Germany and France unfolded in 2003 the pact was

effectively rendered ineffectual. As Paul De Grauwe put it, making it a “dead letter.”

Turning to the newly enacted Euro Plus Pact, it is clear there have been some improvements.

At first glance it is obvious that the EPP has a more holistic approach than the SGP. In theoretical

terms, it has taken on some Keynesian dimensions by including private sector debt as being a factor

in macroeconomic stability. Furthermore the EPP has expanded widely on the importance of

competitiveness by introducing Unit Labour Cost and Balance of Payments as indicators for

competitiveness. Reducing ULC is a great tool to improve competitiveness, especially for countries

in a monetary union, as they have rid themselves of conventional economic tools such as the control

of exchange rates. Although limited, the EPP also sets goals for fostering employment. The EPP has

introduced a variety of economic goals, which are hard to disagree with. What it has not, however,

is given any specific tools as to how to reach these goals. Furthermore, as the SGP is still very much

Page 77: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

77

active, concerns could be raised on whether or not some of these goals will prove to be

contradictory. For example, an attempt to improve competitiveness to meet the goals regarding

Balance of Payments could easily clash with the limits on government deficits and risk limiting

growth. As such, the EPP presents some of the right goals, but it fails to present the tools that

should go with them. Left to fend on their own, member-states may have a hard time deciding

exactly what and how they should do to meet the criteria. After all, as we have stated earlier, serious

issues with competitiveness can and will arise if the member-states' level of efforts diverge.

The road to the goals of the EPP is still for the member-states to pave as it is still a matter of

national competence to regulate these fiscal policy areas. The only real, concrete initiative is the

progress meetings every twelve months. These meetings are set up between the heads of state and

will have the objective of supervising the progress of the individual member states and set goals for

the coming year. The important thing here is that it is an international collaboration and not a

supranational one, which can lead to bargaining between member-states of opposing opinions. This

leads us to the next point; the lack of sanctions. As some have argued the lack of stringency in the

SGP caused problems for the convergence of the member states. Following this line of thought this

might cause problems for the EPP as well; as we have shown there are great deviations in the

interpretation of the degree of which the pact are binding for the countries. This stems from the fact

that the EPP is not legally binding.

The most promising thing about the EPP is the scoreboard of measurements which is yet to be

agreed upon. Contrary to the EPP itself the scoreboard is very specific and sets threshold values for

debt in the private sector and values for the growth in ULC amongst others. Finally, although the

EPP is more holistic than the SGP, major weight is still put on the public sector budget and its

deficit as a measurement for stability. As such, the EPP cannot, despite how it may initially seem,

be viewed as a major concession from those that engineered and still stand by a faulty SGP.

9.1 Future Prospects

The most promising elements of the Euro Plus Pact lies within the Scoreboard, which is yet to be

agreed upon. It is however somewhat unclear what the relation between threshold values and

sanctions will be. Even with the assumption of a strong and enforceable agreement, there is still the

fundamental problem that attempting to reach one threshold might prove counterproductive to

Page 78: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

78

another. Keeping this in mind, the EPP can still be seen as a step in the right direction, firstly

because of the new-found focus on the private sector, and some of the specific targets such as

limiting growth in the value of real estate is both a good, and a realistic, idea. The problems on the

other hand is that while the EPP provides new measurements which accommodate much of the

Keynesian critique, issues on its lack of focus on unemployment aside, it still lacks the necessary

tools a Keynesian would require to fix imbalances. In the words of Paul De Grauwe, the EU has

now has a fire alarm, but no fire brigade. Further the EPP does not give any solution to the intrinsic

problems of the OCA and the consequences of exchange rate and competition that follow this. The

OCA theory proposed by Mundell, required collaboration on fiscal policy, certain transfer payments

to fix the imbalances that were bound to arise, as elaborated on by both Jesper Jespersen and Paul

De Grauwe that have never been implemented. This ultimately leaves the EU with two options, it

can either move towards more fiscal integration, a monumentally difficult task, as it would require a

degree of federalism hitherto unseen. Even with the issues of nationalism and independent nation

states aside, there are the basic and fundamental problems such as the different nature of the welfare

regimes across Europe. To solve the imbalances would therefore require an integration of EU that

would be a large leap towards true federalism. Alternatively the EU could give up on the Euro and

the ECB. This would in turn revert the EU to an earlier incarnation and would bring back the old

problems of currency speculation, devaluation wars, and the many other issues of having numerous

independent free (or somewhat managed) floating exchange rates.

Page 79: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

79

Bibliography

Articles:

Politikken (Danish newspaper), May 14, 2011:

Økonomiens superstjerner i København

Books:

Artis, Mike & Nixon, Frederik (2007): The Economics of the European Union, Oxford University

Press

Begg, David (2006): Foundations of Economics, McGraw-Hill

Buti, Marco & Franco, Daniele (2001): The Stability and Growth Pact, Palgrave.

De Grauwe, Paul (2009): Economics of Monetary Union, Oxford University Press

Fuglsang, Lars & Olsen, Poul Bitsch (2004): Videnskabsteori i samfundsvidenskaberne, Roskilde

Universitetsforlag

Jespersen, Jesper (2005): Introduction to Macroeconomic Theory, Jurist- og Økonomforbundets

Forlag

Jespersen, Jesper (2008): Dansk valutakurspolitik i et EU-økonomisk perspektiv, Tænketanken

NyAgenda

Jespersen, Jesper (2009): Introduktion til Makroøkonomi, Jurist- og Økonomforbundets Forlag

Page 80: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

80

Web

120.000 boligejere teknisk insolvente:

http://borsen.dk/nyheder/privatoekonomi/artikel/1/149846/120000_boligejere_teknisk_insolvente.html

Balance of Payments and International Investment Manual, Sixth Edition, IMF:

http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/bop/2007/pdf/bpm6.pdf

Balance of Payments (MEI) (OECD Statistical Database):

http://stats.oecd.org/Index.aspx?DataSetCode=MEI_BOP

Budget Sanctions Hit Germany and France:

http://news.bbc.co.uk/2/hi/business/2492339.stm

Can Angela Merkel hold Europe together?:

http://www.economist.com/node/18332786

Clicks and Mortar:

http://www.economist.com/blogs/freeexchange/2011/03/global_house_prices

Conclusions of the Heads of State or Government of the Euro Area of 11 March 2011:

http://www.consilium.europa.eu/uedocs/cms_data/docs/pressdata/en/ec/119809.pdf

Council Reaches Agreement on Measures to Strengthen Economic Governance:

http://www.consilium.europa.eu/uedocs/cms_data/docs/pressdata/en/ecofin/119888.pdf

Critics of EU Budgetary Limits Are Wrong:

http://www.europeaninstitute.org/20090708380/Summer/Fall-2003/critics-of-eu-budgetary-limits-are-

wrong.html

Deciphering the G10 Sovereign Debt Crisis: A Macroeconomic Perspective:

Page 81: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

81

http://www.riskelia.com/blog/2010/03/deciphering-the-g10-sovereign-debt-crisis-a-macroeconomic-

perspective/

Economist, The: House-Price Indicators:

http://www.economist.com/blogs/freeexchange/2011/03/global_house_prices

EPP (Euro Plus Pact):

http://www.consilium.europa.eu/uedocs/cms_data/docs/pressdata/en/ec/120296.pdf

Europagt en stakket frist:

http://www.eufagligt.dk/artikel/europagt_en_stakket_frist/

Europagten er en sejr for tysk økonomisk tænkning:

http://www.information.dk/263698

Europagt forpligter:

http://nordjyske.dk/artikel/10/5/2/3825725/3/europagt%20forpligter

Europagten – Hvad løser den?:

http://www.e-pages.dk/politiken/5136/44

Europagt skaber demokratisk underskud:

http://i.pol.dk/debat/analyse/article1240198.ece

'Euro-Plus-Pact' Agreed Amid Portugal Crisis:

http://euobserver.com/9/32062

euroPlus pagt giver politisk systematik:

http://www.zealanddenmark.eu/9073/

Page 82: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

82

Fighting the wrong enemy:

http://www.voxeu.org/index.php?q=node/5062

Financial Crisis and Bank Lending:

http://www.frbsf.org/publications/economics/papers/2010/wp10-11bk.pdf

Fixed and Floating Exchange Rates:

http://tutor2u.net/economics/content/topics/exchangerates/fixed_floating.htm

Germany's Massive Rebound Has Nothing To Do With Exports To Europe:

http://www.businessinsider.com/germany-export-growth-2010-10

Greenspan Says U.S. Should consider Breaking Up Large Banks:

http://www.bloomberg.com/apps/news?pid=newsarchive&sid=aJ8HPmNUfchg

House of cards:

http://www.economist.com/node/1794873?Story_id=1794873

How Government can Discourage Private Sector Reliance on Short-Term Debt:

http://hbswk.hbs.edu/item/6463.html

Indebtedness after the financial crisis – World debt:

http://www.economist.com/blogs/buttonwood/2010/06/indebtedness_after_financial_crisis

Page 83: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

83

Indikatorer og scoreboard om overvågningen af makroøkonomiske

ubalancer:

http://www.eu-oplysningen.dk/upload/application/pdf/dc4f4539/201005272.pdf

It Is Broken. Can It Be Fixed?:

http://www.unomaha.edu/esc/2005Proceedings/SGP.pdf

Keynesian

http://www.economist.com/research/Economics/alphabetic.cfm?letter=K

Labour Productivity:

http://stats.oecd.org/glossary/detail.asp?ID=4819

Løkkes valgpagt:

http://arbejderen.dk/content/l-kkes-valgpagt

Merkel defends Euro Plus Pact:

http://wn.com/merkel_defends_euro_plus_pact?orderby=relevance&upload_time=this_month

Monetarism:

http://www.econlib.org/library/Enc/Monetarism.html

Monetarism and Monetary Policy – The Case of the Euro:

http://www.google.dk/url?sa=t&source=web&cd=5&ved=0CEIQFjAE&url=http%3A%2F%2Fwww.ecaef.org%2Fklex

%2Fuser%2F1%2F4043220_10_01.doc&rct=j&q=growth%20and%20stability%20pact%20monetarism&ei=nWKDTY

yaKs2dOsbUldgI&usg=AFQjCNH8Q-NDyvDNG8Jt0TrIDP5JXZ3Y6g&sig2=DMwAQ46wu1jbhyc-9z_GhA

Page 84: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

84

New Keynesian Economics:

http://www.econlib.org/library/Enc/NewKeynesianEconomics.html

“New” Stability and Growth Pact: More Flexible, Less Stupid?, The:

http://www.fep.up.pt/investigacao/workingpapers/06.07.04_WP218_rhalvesafonso.pdf

Note on Economic Governance:

http://www.consilium.europa.eu/ueDocs/cms_Data/docs/pressData/en/ecofin/119737.pdf

Proposal for a REGULATION OF THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND OF THE

COUNCIL:

http://eur-lex.europa.eu/LexUriServ/LexUriServ.do?uri=COM:2010:0527:FIN:EN:PDF

Protectionism and the Destruction of Prosperity:

http://www.lewrockwell.com/rothbard/rothbard125.html

Real estate bubble:

http://www.investordictionary.com/definition/real-estate-bubble

Repent at leisure:

http://www.economist.com/node/16397110?story_id=16397110

S, SF og R sikrer ansvarlig dansk EU-politik:

http://socialdemokraterne.dk/Default.aspx?func=article.view&id=717272&menuID=700835&menuAction=select&top

menuID=700835

Stability and Growth Pact:

http://www.euractiv.com/en/euro/stability-growth-pact/article-133199

Page 85: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

85

Stability and Growth Pact Experiences and Future Aspects, The:

http://www.springerlink.com.molly.ruc.dk/content/q74660/#section=344907&page=12&locus=41

Stability and Growth Pact, The – Not the Best but Better than Nothing:

http://econstor.eu/bitstream/10419/44274/1/644409398.pdf

Study Finds Lack of Market Flexibility Has Undermined Stability and Growth Pact:

http://www.cepr.org/press/p166.htm

Unit Labour Costs OECD:

http://stats.oecd.org/glossary/detail.asp?ID=2809

Van Rompuy task force agrees need for budgetary sanctions

http://euobserver.com/9/30124

Venstrefløjstrid om europagt fortsætter:

http://www.udenriget.dk/?p=901

We Need to Curb Private Sector Debt:

http://www.efinancialnews.com/story/2010-12-06/need-to-curb-private-sector-debt

Will the New Stability and Growth Pact Succeed?:

http://ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/publications/publication841_en.pdf

Page 86: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

86

Why a Tougher Stability and Growth Pact is a Bad Idea:

http://www.voxeu.org/index.php?q=node/5615

Page 87: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

Appendix

Appendix 1: Government Deficit

Page 88: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

Appendix 2: Government Debt

Page 89: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

Appendix 3: Total Debt to GDP (UK)

Page 90: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

Appendix 4: Total Deb to GDP (Spain)

Page 91: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

Appendix 5: Total Debt to GDP (Germany)

Page 92: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

Appendix 6: Real Effective Exchange Rate

Page 93: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

Appendix 7: Current Account

Page 94: GIGA MASTER-FINAL

Appendix 8: Labour Productivity