34
Egypt’s Post Revolution Development Path From A Dynamic Economy Wide Model “A Three-Year Economic Recovery PlanMotaz Khorshid Professor, Cairo University Former Minister of Higher Education and State for Scientific Research Cairo, Egypt Mobile: + (20122)2440988 Tel. Work: + (202)33358241 Mail: [email protected] Asaad El- Sadek Ph.D. Student Faculty of Computers and Information Cairo University, Cairo, Egypt Mail: [email protected] 1

ecomod.net Ful…  · Web view16 -18 July, 2014. Bali, Indonesia. Abstract. ... an aggregate social accounting matrix (SAM) ... (from 2015/16 to 2016/17)

  • Upload
    ngotram

  • View
    213

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Egypt’s Post Revolution Development Path

From A Dynamic Economy Wide Model“A Three-Year Economic Recovery Plan”

Motaz KhorshidProfessor, Cairo University

Former Minister of Higher Education and State for Scientific Research

Cairo, EgyptMobile: + (20122)2440988

Tel. Work: + (202)33358241Mail: [email protected]

Asaad El- SadekPh.D. Student

Faculty of Computers and Information Cairo University, Cairo, Egypt

Mail: [email protected]

The international Conference on Economic Modeling (EcoMod14)

16 -18 July, 2014Bali, Indonesia

Abstract

1

The Egyptian revolution broke out in January 25, 2011, a revolution that sparked the

national movements in the Arab world and impressed the world as a model of an

unprecedented popular peaceful uprising included all the spectrums of Egypt’s

society. The revolution addressed corruption and tyranny and lift the banner of

freedom, justice and democracy. In June 30, 2012 Mohamed Morsi was elected as a

president of Egypt for a mandate of 4 years. Despite people’s aspiration for a better

future, the continuation of the political instability, social injustice and economic

problems during the year following the election have generated an increased feeling

of insecurity and discontent. In June 2013, the Egyptian people decided to rebel

against the unsatisfactory performance of the new political regime and succeeded to

isolate the president with a support from the national military force.

Since January revolution of 2011 and during the following transition period, Egypt

continued to witness a considerable slowdown of its economic activity, a drop in

domestic and foreign direct investments, a sizable decline in industrial production, a

notable deterioration in foreign reserves and foreign exchange revenues and a

growing government budget deficit. In 2014, Egypt’s socioeconomic indicators are

still showing a declining trend reflected in; i) less than 2 percent increase in GDP

coupled with a stagnated per capita real income, ii) an investment rate fluctuating

around 16% of GDP compared to 22% in 2008, iii) a continuing low rate of national

savings, iv) a sizable decline in the foreign direct investment flows - which amounted

to about 2 billion US Dollars per year, compared to an average of 13 billion dollars

during the 1990 decade and the begin of the current century, v) a critical

unemployment situation, especially among youth and educated women with an

average unemployment rate of more than 13% compared to 9% or less five years

ago, vi) a high poverty rate accounting to more than 25% of the total population

compared to less than 17% at the beginning of the third millennium, vii) a continuing

budget deficit and unprecedented levels of domestic public debts exceeding 80

percent of GDP in June 2013, viii) A trade deficit in the current account of the

balance of payments showing a continuous declining trend and ix) an upward rising

trend of inflation derived by the prevailing increase in the state budget deficit.

2

Against this background, the Egyptian Cabinet approved in 28/08/2013 an urgent

plan to stimulate the economy during the period from July 2014 until June 2017 (3

years). The overall objectives of this short/medium term plan is to achieve a GDP

growth rate between 5% and 7% and reduce the unemployment rate to less than

9%, which represents the rate prevailed before January 25, 2011. The plan primarily

depends on improving investments environment by relying on private, public and

foreign direct investments (FDI). The plan suggests also an increased role of

government in revitalizing the economy, with respect to investment spending, public

consumption and employment strategy.

To support the development and follow up of the three year stimulating plan of the

Egyptian economy and to formulate alternative socioeconomic development policies

and scenarios related to investment allocation and government spending policies, a

three-sector five-institution economy wide model is constructed and implemented.

The developed model reflects the structural features of the Egyptian economy and

its modes of functioning and it is implemented using the general algebraic modeling

system (GAMS) software. The Planning model is viewed as a consistent economy

wide analytical tool following the general equilibrium tradition. To ensure the

generation of the future path of the economy, it is equipped with a set of dynamic

adjustment mechanisms. The development planning accounting framework of the

model represents a Social accounting matrix (SAM) with three productive activities

(primary, industrial and services activities), six institutions (urban and rural

households, private and public corporations, and general government) and the

outside world. Domestic institutions have both current and capital accounts. Factors

of production include labor and capital services. Labor factors (or compensation of

employees) are broken down by economic activity (private, public and government

labor) and household area (urban and rural areas). Capital services include both

public and private accounts. Commodities are composed of domestic, imported,

exported and composite goods and services (merging domestically produced with

imported goods) with each of them divided into primary, industry and services

activities. Gross fixed capital formation is composed of private (households and

private companies) and public (government and public enterprises) investments as

3

well as foreign direct investments (FDI). Government accounts disaggregate tax

income into direct, indirect taxes and subsidies. Finally, the rest of the world account

includes exports, imports, net transfers from abroad (in the form of worker’s

remittances, investment income, foreign direct investments and other current

transfers).

The purposes of the paper are: (1) to assess the economic impact of the revolution

and highlight the principal economy wide challenges facing the Egyptian economy,

(2) to develop the accounting framework, economic rationale and mathematical

structure of the economy wide model used to test the development policies of the

stimulating plan, (3) to use the developed model to simulate the behavior of the

economy under the selected development choices of the three year plan with the

purpose of identifying appropriate policy measures needed to achieve the purposes

of the three-year economic recovery program.

Despite the short/medium term nature of the planning period, the results show that

a sizable increase in annual growth rate of investment spending from 7.4 to 13

percent coupled with similar growth in government spending ranging from 5 to 7

percent per annum as well as an appropriate policies for attracting foreign direct

investments (FDI), would significantly improve the growth prospects of real GDP.

Based on the results of model, GDP is expected to increase from 3.4 percent in the

reference path to around 4.7 percent when the stimulating scenario is applied. It

should be noted however that, the failure to achieve a growth rate that exceeds 5

percent annually – based on the objectives of the recovery plan - is due to the

negative impact of the selected stimulating policies on Egypt’s trade balance or net

exports. Export promotion measures would be strongly requested in this respect to

overcome this difficulty. Finally, the adopted three-year recovery plan succeeds to

improve the per capita indicators and the welfare measures of Egyptians as well as

to reduce the average unemployment rate from 13 percent in 2013/14 to around 9.9

percent in 2016/17.

4

Based on the above rationale, the paper is organized around seven sections. After

this introductory part, the next two sections describe the post revolution economic

performance and outline the accounting framework of the model. Sections four

briefly describes the economic rationale, overall structure and disaggregation level of

the model as well as the policy measures amenable to analysis based on its

structure. Section five summarizes the components of the plan scenarios to be

tested by the model. The sixth section describes the results and summarizes the

main findings of applying the three year stimulating plan with special emphasis on

the capacity to reach the planned targets and the feasibility of the selected policy

measures to the Egyptian context. The final section includes the references.

Post revolution economic performance

Since January 2011 revolution, the Egyptian economy is witnessing a significant

decline in its overall performance [14, 15, 16]. The evolution of the rate of economic

growth over the three years - following the outbreak of the January 25 th revolution-

displays a deteriorating performance. The rate of GDP growth in real term collapsed

from a peak value of 7.2% in 2007/2008 to just 2.1% in 2012/2013 because of the

political stress and security unrest resulting generally in adverse consequences on

economic and development performance. The growth rates of most of economic

sectors followed the same declining pattern of the economy. However, on the

positive side, the fiscal year 2012/2013 witnessed a significant increase in the rate of

real growth (6.6%) in the tourism sector, compared to the year immediately

following the revolution (-5.9%). This is mainly attributed to the decision of a lot of

countries, led by Germany to ease degrees of travel warning to Egypt. The

construction sector also saw a notable growth during the same year (5.9%) as the

work in many of the giant real estate projects have resumed. On the negative side, in

2012/2013 there was a decline in the income from Suez Canal (-3.8%) because of the

security unrest. The following table shows total resources and uses of GDP over the

last two years in real terms.

5

Item 2011/2012 2012/2013% to GDP

2011/2012 2012/2013

GDP 1575.5 1608.6 100.0 100.0

Imports 407.2 402.8 25.8 25.0

Total resources 1982.7 2011.4 125.8 125.0

Private

consumption1271.0 1307.0 80.7 81.3

Public consumption 179.0 185.2 11.4 11.5

Total consumption 1450.0 1492.2 92.0 92.8

Investments 258.1 233.3 16.4 14.5

Exports 274.6 285.9 17.4 17.8

Total uses 1982.7 2011.4 125.8 125.0

At current prices after reaching 22.4% in 2007/2008, the last three years witnessed a

decline in the rate of investment from 17.1% to 14.2%, with low domestic savings

rate, which led to an increase in the savings gap from about 4.1% during the year

2010/2011 to around 8.4% in 2011/2012, and then a decline to 7% in 2012/2013.

The Egyptian economy also experienced a dramatic decrease in net foreign direct

investment over the three years following the revolution. From a peak value of $13.1

billion in 2007/2008, the net FDI decreased to only 3 billion dollars in 2012/2013.

This significant decline in the rates of investment and net foreign direct investment

explains the deteriorating economic growth over the last three years.

Over the last four years, the deficit in the balance of trade increased from $25.1

billion in 2009/2010 – a year before the revolution - to $31.5 billion in 2012/2013.

Although exports of goods over this period increased by 8.8% from $23.9 billion to

$26.0 billion, the problem was in the large rise in imports of goods. Because of the

drop in domestic production – resulting from the political uncertainty and the

unprecedented labor strikes requesting the adjustment of their salary level, imports

of goods increased by 17% from $49.0 billion to $57.5 billion. The surplus in balance

of services, on the other hand, decreased from $10.3 billion in 2009/2010 to just

$6.7 billion in 2012/2013. The only exception to the deteriorating performance of

6

the foreign exchange indicators is the net worker’s remittances from abroad that

increased from $10.5 in 2009/2010 billion to $19.3 billion in 2012/2013. This might

be explained by the desire of Egyptian citizens living abroad to participate in

redressing the Egyptian economy and helping in overcoming its current difficulties,

despite the increasing level of uncertainty facing their country. In balance, these

unfavorable changes in external economic transactions resulted in an increase in the

current account deficit from $4.32 billion in 2009/2010 to $5.6 billion in 2012/2013.

The deteriorated current external balance in the post revolution period, has led

similarly to a serious decline in the foreign reserves in US $. The net foreign

exchange reserves declined from $36 billion in 2009/2010 to values ranging between

$13.4 billion (March 2013) and $16 billion (May 2013). The steady decline in the net

foreign exchange reserves during the past three years is attributed to the decline in

both the revenues of tourism sector and foreign investments, in addition to the use

of international reserves to finance imports and to prevent the deterioration in the

value of the Egyptian pound.

Despite the declining economic growth since the outbreak of the revolution,

consumer spending in current prices continues to occupy a large proportion of GDP.

Final consumption expenditure at current prices reached during the year 2012/2013

LE1.6 billion, which represents 92.8% of GDP at current prices, compared to LE1.0

billion in 2009/2010, equivalent to 85.7% of GDP at current prices. With the decline

in investments and net exports, the increase in final consumption is still the main

source of economic growth.

The impact of January revolution on the deficit of general government budget was

considerable. During the financial year 2012/2013, total deficit in the state budget

reached LE240 billion compared to LE 98 billion in 2009/2010 - the year before the

revolution, with a 145% Increase. This resulted in an increase in public debt. Total

domestic public debt reached to LE1404.7 billion in 2012/2013, representing 81% of

GDP at current prices compared to LE 663.8 billion in 2009/2010, representing 55%

of the GDP at the same year. Foreign debts have also become a problem, increased

from $34.4 billion in June 2011 to $43.2 billion in July 2010, an increase of 25.6%.

7

Finally, the slowdown of Egypt’s economic activity has aggravated the

unemployment problem since the unemployment rate increased from 9 percent

during the two years preceding the revolution to around 13.3% in 2012/2013. It also

resulted in 8% inflation.

The Accounting Framework of the Model

The accounting structure and parameters of the model is broken down into two main

components; a) an aggregate social accounting matrix (SAM) constructed for the year

2008-09 to support the within-period static part of the model [1,6,9,19] and b) a non

SAM socioeconomic indicators needed to adjust the inter-period module ensuring the

dynamic path of the economy.

In this specific SAM, activities are broken down into three distinctive accounts;

primary, industry and services. This classification is the one adopted in the

International Standard Industrial Classification of all economic activities (ISIC),

Revision 4 [9]. The disaggregated three productive activities of the SAM are shown in

the table below. Commodities are classified into; composite, domestic, imported and

exported with each bundle of commodities broken down into primary, industry and

services. Factors are represented in the SAM by two groups of accounts; labor

compensation accounts and capital services accounts. Labor compensation accounts

are broken down by economic activity into; private, public and net worker remittances

representing those who work in the private corporations, public corporations and

abroad, respectively.

The same applies to capital services accounts that are classified into; private, public

and investment income representing capital employed in private corporations, public

corporations and abroad, respectively. The economy includes three domestic

institutions; households, firms and government. Households are represented by two

accounts; urban and rural households. Firms or organized corporations are broken

down into two separate accounts; private and public corporations. Government is

broken down into three accounts; one account for general government income and

spending and one account for taxes and another for subsidies. Savings are broken

down into two accounts; private savings (households and private corporations) and

public savings (public corporations and public government). Investments are also

8

broken down into two accounts; private and public. Finally, there is one current

account for the rest-of-world. In total, this will give us (3434) SAM matrix.

Economic activities as disaggregated by

Egypt’s National accounts The proposed scheme of disaggregation

1. Agriculture

Primary2. Extraction of crude petroleum &

natural gas

3. Other extraction

4. Petroleum refinement

Industry

5. Other manufacturing

6. Electricity and gas

7. Water

8. Sewerage

9. Building & construction

10.Wholesale and retail trade

Services

11.Financial services

12.Insurance

13.Transportation & storage

14.Communication

15.Information

16.Suez Canal

17.Restaurants and hotels

18.Real estate ownership

19.Business activities

20.Social insurance

21.Education

22.Health

23.Other services

24.Government

25.NPISHs

The SAM is constructed for the fiscal year 2008/2009 in LE millions.

Model Structure and Economic Rationale

9

To support the socioeconomic development planning process in Egypt following

the revolution of January 25, 2011 and its second wave in June 30, 2013, the

Ministry of Planning (MOP) developed two socioeconomic plans. A 10-year long

term plan to capture both the recovery period needed to reach the normal

performance of the economy and analyze as well its growth prospects in the post

recovery period up to 2021/22 [12]. This long term plan mainly adopts a

comprehensive set of policy measures with a target to double the real per capita

income as a way to improve the living standards of the Egyptian citizens.

Furthermore, to overcome the short/medium term difficulties resulting from the

devastating impact of the revolution, the government of Egypt decided to adopt a

three-year recovery plan to stimulate the economy in order to accelerate the

return back to its normal functioning [18]. To achieve this short term objective, a

three-sector five-institution medium term economy wide model was

constructed, implemented and used to formulate and test alternative

socioeconomic development options and scenarios. The constructed model

reflects the structural features of the Egyptian economy along with its modes of

functioning and it is implemented using the general algebraic modeling system

(GAMS) software [7,10 ,11,12].

The model is particularly designed to project Egypt’s socioeconomic indicators

and assess the impact of alternative policy measures and external conditions

such as: (1) Investment spending policies reflected in the private and public

gross fixed capital formation, (2) foreign direct investment (FDI) flows needed to

complement domestic investments in supporting the growth prospects of the

economy, (3) government spending policies such as government wage bill and

employment policy, final consumption spending as well as public transfers to

domestic and foreign institutions, (4) government fiscal policy including various

taxes and subsidies, (5) export promotion and subsidy policy, (6) total factors

productivity and labor efficiency policies, (7) external balance policies reflected

in changes in investment income from abroad, worker remittances, interest on

foreign assets and other foreign transfers from abroad , (8) wage rate and

commodity pricing policies and (9) alternative population, labor force and

unemployment reduction policies.

10

The development planning model represents an economy with three productive

activities (primary, industrial and services activities), six institutions (urban and

rural households, private and public corporations, and general government) and

the outside world. Domestic institutions have both current and capital accounts.

Factors of production include labor and capital services. Labor factors (or

compensation of employees) are broken down by economic activity (private,

public and government labor) and household area (urban and rural). Capital

services include both public and private accounts. The markets of goods and

services in the model are composed of domestic, imported, exported and

composite commodities (merging domestic with imported goods), with each of

them divided into primary, industry and services. Gross capital formation is

composed of private (households and private companies) and public

(government and public enterprises) investments as well as foreign direct

investments (FDI). Government account disaggregates net tax income into direct

and indirect taxes and subsidies. Finally, the rest of the world account includes

net transfers from abroad in the form of worker’s remittances, investment

income, foreign direct investments, current transfers to domestic institutions as

well as imports and exports of goods and services.

The Planning model is viewed as a consistent economy wide simulation model

equipped with a set of dynamic adjustment mechanisms to ensure the

generation of the medium to long term path of the economy [2, 3, 4, 5]. Most of

the model structural parameters are computed from the SAM where as the

behavior parameters are based on estimates of other models and similar studies

for Egypt. The model represents an economy with an investment/saving

macroeconomic closure rule that treats public and private gross fixed capital

formations as exogenous variables, gross savings as an endogenous variable

depending on institutional income and expenditure patterns and the foreign

savings that clear the macroeconomic system. Production sectors apply a

flexible price clearing mechanisms with an imperfect substitution between

domestic and imported goods (Armington Elasticity function). Distribution of

gross output between domestic sales and exports is based on a constant

11

elasticity of transformation (CET) function. Transfers from the rest of the world

are fixed in foreign currency whereas transfers of the domestic institutions to

the outside world are a function of their disposable income. World prices and

interest on foreign assets are determined exogenously in the model. Exports of

commodities are computed as the equilibrium quantity between supply of and

demand for exported goods and services. The ratio of domestic to world price of

commodity and the elasticity of trade determine world demand for exports.

Government income is composed of direct and indirect taxes, public enterprises

transferred operating surplus and transfers from domestic and foreign

institutions. Government final consumption spending is fixed in real term and

public savings are computed as a residual. Households and companies

expenditures are computed as a fixed share of their nominal income and

household final consumption spending is computed by a linear expenditure

system (LES) . The model is equipped with institutional capital flows matrix that

balances exogenous investments with savings and capital transfers. Given

market imperfection and high unemployment rates, wage rates are fixed within

period but change between periods based on employment and wage policy.

Natural growth rate of population and labor participation policies are used to

dynamically adjust population and labor force size between periods. The

dynamic adjustment of capital stock between periods - by production activity –

is based on the initial capital stock, gross fixed capital formation in real term and

the consumption of fixed capital. Similar dynamic adjustment mechanisms are

derived for investment income from abroad and foreign direct investments

(FDI).

Development of the recovery Plan Scenarios

Based on the Egyptian Cabinet decision in 28/08/2013 to implement a short-term

recovery plan with the objective of stimulating the economic performance during

the period from July 2014 until June 2017 (3 years), a set of experiments – based on

the constructed model – is designed and tested. Given the official plan document,

These experiments assume –– that overall objectives of the medium-term plan is to

achieve on the one hand a GDP real growth rate between 5% and 7% and reduce on

the other hand the unemployment rate to less than 9%, which represents the

12

rate prevailed before January 25, 2011. In order to meet these short-term

targets, a comprehensive development scenario is formulated with the following

policy measures:

(i) Increase the growth rate of private, public and foreign direct

investments (FDI) spending during the coming three years up to 2016/17.

It is assumed that the Egyptian authorities will succeed to revitalize FDI

with respect to both the public and private sectors. This effort would

result in an average annual increase of FDI ranging from 12 to 14 percent

during the plan three years. Furthermore, public and private gross fixed

capital formation – in real term – are assumed to reach an average annual

growth of 10 and 15 percent respectively, compared to only 5 and 9

percent in the reference path (or business as usual). These figures are

estimated considering the prevailing investment capacity of Egypt as well

as government effort to mobilize the needed resources.

(ii) The plan suggests also an increase in the role of government to revitalize

the economy, with respect to government current expenditures and

transfers as well as employment strategy. In this respect, government

wage bill and purchases of goods and services in real term are assumed to

increase respectively by 5 and 7 percent in the stimulating scenario

compared to only 2.5 and 4.5 percent considering the reference path

assumptions. In addition, the stimulating scenario suggests an increase in

government transfers to domestic institution (households and business

sectors) to allow for further activation of the domestic demand for

commodities.

Given the above assumptions, the constructed model was used to compare the

performance of the Egyptian economy up to 2016/17 in light of the assumption of

the reference path and the stimulating (or recovery) scenarios.

Experimental Results and Basic Findings

13

The model results corresponding to the reference path and the stimulating scenarios

during the period (2013/14 -2016/17) is summarized in three tables:

a) Table (1) records the changes in the sources of financing the growth of

GDP. It shows the uses (or applications) of GDP in real term up to

2016/17 which is the terminal year of the short/medium term plan. In

the table, consumption and investment is broken down into private and

public spending. When net exports (exports less imports) are included,

the uses of GDP are completely identified. Note here that the table

records the annual growth rate of the plan target year (from 2015/16 to

2016/17) as well as the structural changes in the components of GDP

(uses as a percent of GDP).

b) Table (2) summarizes the changes in real GDP during the planning period

broken down into private, government and public sectors. It can be used

then to measure the contribution of each production sector to GDP. The

table shows also other important economic welfare indicators such as

per-capita GDP, GNP and household consumption.

c) Since reducing the unemployment rate represents a major policy option

in the three-year plan – or any other policy exercise in Egypt – table (3)

shows the impact of alternative scenarios on labor supply and demand

divided into private, public and government workers. These indicators

are used also to determine the unemployment level at the end of the

planning period or equivalently the target year (2016/17).

Growth Prospects:

Given the assumptions of alternative development scenarios, the structural and

behavioral features of the Egyptian economy reflected in the constructed medium

term planning model and the projected socioeconomic indicators up to the target

year (2016/17), the following analytical results and concluding remarks can be

delineated:

1. If the government succeeds to mobilize its available resources for enhancing

public sector investment opportunities and attracting foreign direct

14

investments to finance public enterprises, and assuming that it will succeed

also to adopt various policy measures to encourage private investor and

enterprises - with special reference to their participation in national

development programs and support to youth projects - Egypt will be in a

position to accelerate economic growth, reduce its financial and commercial

resource gaps, face labor market structural imbalances and improve the

welfare level of citizens.

2. It should be noted however that the selected policy measures need to

respect Egypt’s feasibility limits reflected in its structural rigidities and

prevailing distortions. Furthermore, in many instances, policy means can

have contradicting effects. For example, a surge in investment spending

would contribute to enhancing economic growth via its positive impact on

capital stock and return on capital, but it might however lead to an increase

in the demand for imports of investment goods and then contribute to

reducing the growth prospects of GDP. On the other hand, an increase in

private and government consumption spending would normally have positive

impact on GDP growth as a component of its uses. Further increase of

consumption spending would lead meanwhile to reducing the part of the

domestic production that can be directed to exports which is a factor

contributing to reducing GDP growth and negatively affecting external

balance.

3. Keeping the above economic rationale in mind, table (1) shows that annual

growth rate of Real GDP in 2016/17 increases from 3.4 percent in the

reference path to around 4.7 when the stimulating scenario is adopted. The

enhanced investment performance (average annual growth rate is assumed

to increase from 7.4 to around 13 percent) and the improved government

final consumption (annual growth rate is assumed to increase from 2.8 to 5.7

percent on the average), are the major factors for achieving the growth of

GDP in real term. The table shows also the negative impact on GDP growth in

2016/17 resulting from the increase in the growth of imports from 6.1

percent in the reference path to around 9.9 percent when the stimulating

scenario is adopted. It reflects also the stagnated performance of exports

15

with an average growth rate that does not exceed 1.3 to 1.6 percent on the

average. This finding suggests that the stimulating policy package should

include – in addition to investment, FDI and government spending policies –

an export measures.

4. Table (2) shows the contribution of the production sectors to the growth of

GDP in real term evaluated at factor cost. According to the stimulating

scenario, the private sector appears on top of the list with respect to its

contribution to the growth of GDP (5.4 percent growth rate of private sector

GDP in 2016/17). Because the general government GDP is composed mainly

of real wage bill, its growth rate is reflected directly in the labor market

functioning and unemployment rate.

Structural Changes

Given the short period of analysis (2013/14 – 2016/17), one would expect that the

structural changes in the economy resulting from the tested scenarios are limited.

The sizable increase in investment and government spending might result however

in some changes in the structure of GDP. This is true with respect to total investment

spending and demand for imports. In table(1), gross investment spending as a

percent of GDP in 2016/17 increased from 25% in the reference path scenario to

around 29% when adopting the stimulating scenario. Similarly, imports as a percent

of GDP increased considerably from 34% to 38% as a result of applying the

stimulation package.

16

Table (1) Uses of GDP in real term Ec

onomic

Indicators

(Real Term)

Base year (2013/14) Development Scenarios

Indicator Structure

(%)

Reference Path Stimulating Scenario

2013/14

Target year

2016/17

Target year

Growth

(%)

GDP

Structure

(%)

Growt

h (%)

GDP

Structure

(%)

Private

Consumption880,058 73 997,247 4.0 75 1022,476 5.1 75

Public

Consumption145,007 12 157,486 2.8 12 170,618 5.7 13

Total

Consumption 1025,065 85 1154,733 3.8 87 1193,094 5.2 88

Private

Investments145,313 12 189,678 9.3 14 218,624 15.0 16

Public

Investments 128,863 11 149,993 5.0 11 170,085 10.0 13

Total

Investments 274,176 23 338,711 7.4 25 388,709 12.8 29

Exports288,654 24 296,314 1.6 22 291,682 1.3 21

(-) Imports375,520 32 463,833 6.1 34 510,462 9.9 38

GDP uses

(Market Price)1212,375 100% 1325,925 3.4 100% 1363,023 4.7 100%

17

Table (2) GDP break down by sector and per capita indicators

Economic Indicators

Base yearDevelopment Scenarios

(2013/14

)

GDP

Structur

e

(%)

Reference Path Stimulating Scenario

2016/17

Target year

2016/17

Target year

Growt

h (%)

GDP

Structur

e

(%)

Growth

(%)

GDP

Structur

e

(%)

Private GDP714,821 62 793,488 4.1 63 814,190 5.4 62

Public GDP322,864 28 344,504 2.5 27 350,902 3.4 27

Government GDP120,268 10 129,010 2.4 10 139,225 5.0 11

GDP Sources

(at factor cost)1157,952 100% 1267,002 3.5 100

1304,31

74.8 100

Pre-Capita GDP

(Real Term)14,247 - 14,625 1.13 - 15,049 1.8 -

Pre-Capita GDP

(Nominal)22,397 - 25,061 3.96 - 27,056 6.9 -

Pre-Capita GNP22,738 - 25,457 3.99 - 27,451 6.9 -

Per-Capita

Household

Consumption

16616 - 18677 4.1 - 20017 6.8 -

Table (3) Labor Supply, Demand and unemployment ratePopulation/Labor Indicators

(Thousands)

Stimulating Scenario

2013/14 2014/15 2015/16 2016/17

Population Size85,096 86,883 88,708 90,571

Labor Force Supply30,209 30,409 31,491 32,605

Labor Demand26,248 26,708 27,900 29,361

Unemployment Rate (%)13.11 12.17 11.40 9.95

Labor Demand by sector:

- Private

- Public

- Government

18,786

795

6,667

19,056

796

6,856

19,883

818

7,199

20,956

846

7,559

18

Per Capita Indicators

In the context of this study, per capita indicators can serve two purposes; i)

Economic growth adjusted by population size and ii) welfare level of citizens. Per

capita GDP in real term slightly increases from LE 14,625 in the reference path to LE

15,049 in 2016/17 due to the adoption of the stimulating policies. The impact on per

capita GDP and GNP in nominal term is clearer. The average annual growth rates of

per-capita GDP in nominal term witness a sizable increase from 3.96% to 6.9% when

applying the stimulation package. Furthermore, the implementation of the

stimulation scenario produces a significantly positive effect on the per capita

household consumption with an absolute increase from LE 18,677 to LE 20,017 in

2016/17.

Labor Market and Unemployment

The impact of the stimulating scenario on supply of and demand for labor services as

well as unemployment rate is shown in table (3). When carrying on the modeling

experiments, we assumed no changes between the reference path and the

stimulating scenario with respect to population size and supply of labor force. The

demand for labor services is meanwhile affected by the economic policy measures

included in the stimulating scenario. On the average, the demand for labor – which

reflects in a way the job opportunities offered by the productive sectors of the

economy – increases by around 4 percent per annum resulting in a growth of

demand from 26,248 thousand laborers in 2013/14 to around 29, 361 thousands in

2016/17. As a direct consequence, unemployment rates decreases from 13.11

percent in 2013/14 to around 9.95 percent which represents approximately the pre-

revolution performance (the prevailing official unemployment rate in 2010 was

around 9 percent). Table (3) shows also the breakdown of labor demand by

production sector. Given the short term nature of the analysis, the impact on

demand for labor is felt in the private and government sectors more the public

enterprises. The discussion of this point needs some micro analysis that goes beyond

the scope of this study. Based on the results of the model, average annual growth

rate of demand for labor has increased by 3.85% and 4.4% in the private and

19

government sector, respectively. The demand for labor in public enterprises

increases only by 2.14% per annum on the average.

References

[1] Aboul-Einein, S. and Motaz Khorshid (2009) “A Social Accounting Matrix

to Assess the Strategies for achieving the Millennium Development Goal in

Egypt” Unpublished Working Paper, Regional Project for Assessing Development

Strategies to Achieve the Millennium Development Goals in the Arab region,

UNDP-RBAS, UN-DESA and World Bank.

[2] Dervis, K., J. De Melo and S. Robinson (1982) “General equilibrium

Models for Development policy.” Cambridge University Press, New York.

[3] Drud, A., W. Grais and G. Pyatt (1986) “Macroeconomic Modeling Based

on Social Accounting Principles. “Journal of Policy modeling. Vol. 8. No.

1:111-145.

[4] Khorshid, M. (1994) “A Dynamic Multi-sector Economy-wide Model for

Egypt: Database, Structure and Policy Analysis.” The IBK Papers. The

Industrial Bank of Kuwait. No. 41: 1-68.

[5] Khorshid, M. (1996) "A Multi-sector Population Economy-wide

Simulation Model for Egypt" Finance and Industry. The Industrial Bank of

Kuwait, No. 12: 39-155.

[6] Khorshid M. (2002) “Issue-Oriented Social Accounting Matrices for Development

Policy: Experience from the Middle East and North Africa Region”, The proceedings

of the 14th International Conference on Input-Output Techniques, Montreal,

Canada, October 10-15.

[7] Khorshid M . (2003) "Alternative Socioeconomic Development Scenarios for

Egypt: Results from an Economy-Wide Simulation Model", published by the

20

Economic Research Forum (ERF) for the Arab Countries, Iran and Turkey,

December.

[8] Khorshid M. (2008) "Social Accounting Matrices for Modeling and Policy Analysis-

Development Issues from the Middle East" Proceedings of the International

Conference on Policy Modeling, Berlin, Germany, July 2-4.

[9] Khorshid, M. and A. El-Sadek (2010) "An ICT Economy Wide Interaction Social

Accounting Matrix for Egypt – Structure, Economic Rationale and Analytical

Indicators" Proceedings of the International Conference on Policy Modeling,

EcoMod10, Istanbul, Turkey, July 7-10.

[10] Khorshid M. and A. El sadek (2011) "An ICT Economy Interaction Model

for Egypt – Impact on Growth and Productivity" Proceedings of the

International Conference on Economic Policy Modeling (EcoMod11),

Azores, Portugal, June 27-29.

[11] Khorshid M. and A. El sadek (2012) "A multi-sector ICT Economy

Interaction Model For Egypt – The Path to Information Society" Proceedings of

the International Conference on Economic Policy Modeling (EcoMod12),

Seville, Spain, July 4-6.

[12] Khorshid M. and A. El sadek (2013) "Egypt’s Post Revolution

Development Path From A Dynamic Economy Wide Model – A Goal Seeking

Analysis" Proceedings of the International Conference on Economic Policy

Modeling (EcoMod12), Prague, July 1-3.

[13] Ministry of Planning and International Co-operation (2010), "Strategic

Framework for Socio-economic Development Plan until 2022", Ministry of

Planning and International Co-operation, Cairo.

[14] Ministry of Planning and International Co-operation (2011), "Follow up

report – 2010/2011", Ministry of Planning and International Co-operation,

Cairo.

21

[15] Ministry of Planning and International Co-operation (2012), "Follow up

report – 2011/2012", Ministry of Planning and International Co-operation,

Cairo.

[16] Ministry of Planning and International Co-operation (2013), "Follow up

report – 2012/2013", Ministry of Planning and International Co-operation,

Cairo.

[17] Ministry of Planning and International Co-operation (2009), "National

Accounts 2008/2009", Ministry of Planning and International Co-operation,

Cairo.

[18] Ministry of Planning and International Co-operation (2013), "An urgen

plan for economic recovery", Ministry of Planning and International Co-

operation, Cairo.

[19] Pyatt, G. and J. Round (1985), "Social Accounting Matrices: A Basis for

Planning, World Bank Publication.", Washington, D.C.

22