Forecasting the Probability of Recession

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 7/28/2019 Forecasting the Probability of Recession

    1/24

    Forecasting the Probability of Recession

    May 13, 2013

    Andrew Gellert

    Arman Oganisian

    Economic Forecasting

    ECN 409-001

    Dr. Fang Dong

  • 7/28/2019 Forecasting the Probability of Recession

    2/24

    2

    Abstract

    Building on previous research, we estimate a probit model to forecast the

    probability of recession one month later. We use data from the St. Louis Federal

    Reserves database to estimate four different models. We choose the optimal model based

    on the models ability to make in-sample predictions of turning points from recession to

    expansion and its overall fit. The optimal model is then used to generate 18 out-of-sample

    forecasts from October 2011 to March 2013. These forecasts demonstrate that ability to

    capture real events, as the predicted probability of recessions jumped in periods of

    instability and dropped during periods of stability.

    Introduction

    The paper begins with a literature review surveying some key papers which build

    a probit model the probability of recession. Some papers have built dynamic models

    which exploit the autocorrelation structure of the binary dependent variable. Others use

    various financial explanatory variables, such as the yield curve, to capture the so called

    wisdom of the crowd contained in liquid secondary markets.

    We estimate four different models. Two of them are static models and the other

    two are nonhomogeneous Markov processes. The main model is described in our

    Model section, which is followed by a brief description of our data.

    The next section estimates the four models and compares their in-sample fits as

    well as their ability to predict turning points in the economy. Model 1 is chosen as the

    optimal model because it exhibits the best fit and turning-point predictions.

    In the final section, we use model 1 to generate 18 out-of-sample forecasts from

    October 2011 to March 2013. The model demonstrates a fine ability to capture the real

  • 7/28/2019 Forecasting the Probability of Recession

    3/24

    3

    macroeconomic risks stemming from the European sovereign debt crisis which raged

    from fall 2011 to fall 2012. During the crisis, predictions became very volatile,

    fluctuating around 50%. After the German constitutional court approved Greek bailout

    funds and the probability of a Greek exit declined, the models predictions decreased to

    about 10% and stayed there until the present.

    Literature Review

    Our model has several features that we borrow from previous models. First, we

    include the slope of the yield curve1 as an explanatory variable. Second, we include a

    lagged recession dummy as an explanatory variable, transforming the model into a first-

    order nonhomogenous Markov process. Finally, we use a probit model, which is the most

    widely used probability model in similar research.

    Dueker (1997) presents a theoretical argument for why the slope of the yield

    curve contains forward-looking information about the economy. He argues that the yields

    of long-term and short-term securities, because they are traded on a liquid secondary

    market, contain the so-called wisdom of the crowd. The yield curve, which plots the

    yields of bonds with different maturities, normally slopes upwards. Higher maturity debt

    carries a larger risk of the issuer defaulting and, thus, the market prices the debt at a

    premium to lower-maturity bonds2. When the economic outlook dims, the yield curve

    may flatten or invert. This is because investors expect looser monetary policy (i.e. lower

    short-term rates), so they choose to sell their short-term debt and buy long-term debt to

    lock in higher yield. This causes short-term rates to rise and long-term rates to decline.

    1Unlessotherwisenoted,hereafteryieldcurvereferstothedifferenceinyields

    betweena10-yeargovernmentbondanda3-monthT-bill.2Longer-maturitydebtispricedatapremiumbecauseotherrisks,suchasinflation

    spikes,alsoincreasewithtime.

  • 7/28/2019 Forecasting the Probability of Recession

    4/24

    4

    Thus, the slope ( = ) of the yield curveflattens or turns negative. The magnitude of the decline depends on the crowds view of

    the severity and duration of the coming downturn.3

    There is a wide body of literature devoted to producing multi-period forecasts of

    the probability of recession using the yield curve. Estrella and Mishkin (1998) examine

    the out-of-sample forecasting performance of several financial variables including the

    yield curve (spread between the 10-year and 3-month treasure yields), the NYSE

    composite stock index, Commerce Department leading index, as well as Stock-Watson

    leading index.

    They evaluate the performance of the variables by using a pseudo-R2

    after

    estimating their probit model using maximum likelihood.4 For short forecasting periods

    of one to three quarter horizons, stock prices have superior forecasting ability. Beyond

    this period, however, the slope of the yield curve dominates. The pseudo R2for the yield

    curve is only .072 for 1-quarter-ahead forecasts, but increases to .295 for 4-quarters-

    ahead forecasts. NYSEs pseudo R2, by contrast, is .161 for 1-quarter-ahead forecasts.

    However, this metric declines to .016 for 4-quarters-ahead forecasts.

    Dueker runs Estrella and Mishkins probit model using monthly 30-year treasury

    yields (as opposed to the quarterly 10-year treasury yields) and confirms their results. He

    finds that the yield curves predictive power is optimized with a lag of 9 months. The

    yield curve becomes the dominant predictor after 3 months (1 quarter), which is

    3Theyieldcurveisnotfoolproof.Monetarypolicyisnotbasedsolelyontheexpectedfuturestateof

    theeconomy.Itisalsobasedoninflationexpectationsandpurerandomness.

    4! = 1 (!"# !!!"# !!

    )!

    !

    !!"#!!,where0and1correspondtonofitandperfectfit,respectively.

    TheuseofthismetricisjustifiedinEstrellaandMishkinspaper,aswellastheuseofNewey-West

    standarderrorstohandleautocorrelatedforecasterrors.

  • 7/28/2019 Forecasting the Probability of Recession

    5/24

    5

    consistent with Estrella and Mishkin. Before ending his paper, he presents a probit model

    augmented with a Markov switching process. He argues that this may be superior since it

    exploits the autocorrelation structure of the binary dependent variable.

    Chauvet and Potter (2001) criticize the use of Estrella and Mishkins probit

    model, claiming that the model is misspecified in two fundamental ways: (1) estimated

    parameters are not constant over time and (2) the model does not properly account for

    autocorrelated errors. Estrella, Rodrigues, and Schich (2003) examine both U.S. and

    German data and find no evidence of breakpoints. Chauvet and Potter develop a

    computationally difficult method by applying Bayesian numerical methods (Kauppi,

    2008).

    According to Kauppi, this approach, and other similar approaches, have

    problems in their interpretation, practical implementation, and flexibility. Instead, he

    builds a dynamic probit model by including a lagged dependent variable as an

    explanatory variable, thus modeling the economy as a first-order nonhomogeneous

    Markov chain. It is nonhomogeneous because the transition matrix varies with respect to

    the slope of the yield curve. He finds that there is no evidence for parameter instability

    provided that the apparent serial dependence of the recession indicator is taken into

    account using the lagged dependent variable as an explanatory variable.

    Kauppis model is

    (! = 1) = (! + !!!! + !!!!").

    Xt-12 is the lagged yield curve, yt-1 is the lagged dependent variable, and () is the

    cumulative distribution function of N(0,2). The model predicts the probability of

  • 7/28/2019 Forecasting the Probability of Recession

    6/24

    6

    recession 12 months ahead, where yt=1indicates a state of recession. This probability

    varies with respect to the slope of the yield curve.

    The probabilities outputted by the model form the transition matrix, which, again,

    vary with respect to the slope of the yield curve. In a two-state Markov (state 1 is

    recession and state 2 is no recession), the transition probabilities from one state to another

    can be expressed in a 2x2 matrix:

    !! !"

    !" !!=

    !! 1 !!

    1 !! !!

    =

    (! + ! + !!!!") 1 [1 ! + !!!!" ]

    (1

    ! + ! + !!!!" ) 1 (! + !!!!")5

    We extend upon Kauppis dynamic probit model by adding a causal dimension to

    the model by way of several leading indicators of consumption, housing, and investment.

    We will see whether this extension significantly improves the models probability

    forecasts.

    ModelWe will construct a time series model that will output an 1-month-ahead forecast

    of the probability of recession. Our main model will take the following form:

    (!!! = 1) = (! + !), !"#; !; ~. .,(0,!)

    Where:

    () = c.d.f. for the normal distribution.n = 414k= 4

    R = a column vector containing n observations of either 0 or 1, where 0indicates a state of no recession in time t+1 and 1 indicates recession in

    time t+1.

    5P11istheprobabilityofmovingfromastateofrecessioninperiod ttoanotherstateofrecessionin

    periodt+1.P12istheprobabilityofmovingfromastateofrecessioninperiod ttoastateofno

    recessioninperiodt+1.

  • 7/28/2019 Forecasting the Probability of Recession

    7/24

    7

    = a vector containing 5 coefficients and one constant term to be

    estimated.X = A 415x6 matrix of the following independent variables at time t

    (except for the yield curve and lagged dependent variable, which arelagged): housing starts (hs), industrial production index (ip), consumer

    sentiment (cs), yield curve (yc) (lagged 11 months, and dependent variable(lagged 1 month).

    As mentioned at the end of the literature review, our research seeks to improve

    previous models using the yield curve and Markov-switching by adding several

    covariates.

    We include housing starts as a leading indicator of the housing sector, which is a

    large component of residential investment and, consequently, GDP. Building permits

    would be an equally valid, yet identical leading indicator. A simple correlation coefficient

    indicates that the two variables are correlated with r = .98.

    The industrial production index is a good leading indicator of the industrials

    sector (which includes manufacturing, mining, and utilities). This is an interest-sensitive

    sector, so it is particularly useful when dealing with the business cycle. Adverse shocks to

    the economy will hit this sector before all others. Thus, IP is a good leading indicator of

    the economy as a whole. Additionally, we include the Michigan sentiment survey as a

    leading indicator of consumption activity, which comprises some 70% of total U.S.

    output.

    We also include the yield curve (lagged 11 months) and the dependent variable

    (lagged 1 month) for reasons outlines in the previous literature review. We lag the yield

    curve 11-months because previous research shows that the yield curves predictive power

    is optimal at a 3-4 quarter horizon. Since the yield curve is at time tis the value from t-

  • 7/28/2019 Forecasting the Probability of Recession

    8/24

    8

    11, t+1 (the 1-month-ahead forecast) falls in the optimal time horizon. For a 2-months-

    ahead forecast, a 10-month lag must be used for the yield curve.

    Thus, the previous model,

    Pr(!!! = 1) = (0 + 1! + 2! + 3! + 4!!!! + 5! + !)~. .,(0,!),

    which predicts the probability of recession in t+1, can be used to predict fsteps ahead

    with the following generalized model:

    Pr(!!! = 1) = (0 + 1! +2! +3! +4!!(!"!!) + 5Pr(!!(!!!) + !)

    This model assumes that all forecasts are made in time t, so that the information

    set available at time texcludes all information available after this period. This is a huge

    drawback because the information set does not increase with the prediction horizon,

    which decreases the accuracy of high-fforecasts. The most accurate forecast, therefore, is

    the forecast forf=1. If the forecast for period t+fis made in period t+(f-1), this would not

    be the case.

    We will also estimate three other variations of this model. One model will omit

    the lagged recession variable. The third will just include the yield curve and the fourth

    will include only the yield curve and the lagged recession variable. Model 1, which will

    prove superior to the other three models, does not succumb to the shortcomings of the

    model described above. Since it is not a dynamic model, previous predictions are not

    explanatory variables, thus the information set depends on values of HS, IP, CS, and YC,

    which are exogenously determined.

  • 7/28/2019 Forecasting the Probability of Recession

    9/24

    9

    Data

    We retrieved all of our data from the Federal Reserve Economic Data (FRED)

    database at the St. Louis Federal Reserve Bank. All data series are seasonally adjusted

    and recorded on a monthly basis. Our time sample period is from March 1, 1977 to

    September 1, 2011. Summary statistics are available in the table below along with the

    expected sign of the variables coefficient. All data was lagged within excel.

    Table 1: Data Summary

    Variable N Mean St. Dev. Minimum Maximum Expected Sign

    Housing Starts 415 1459.95 405.98 478 2273 -

    Industrial Production 415 72.15 17.68 46.6 100.7 -

    Consumer Sentiment 415 85.39 13.28 51.7 112 -Yield Curve 415 00.13 00.34 0 1 -

    Recession 415 01.16 01.21 -3.1 3.4 +

    The chart below is a time series of the 11-month lagged yield curve from March

    1, 1977 to September 1, 2011, a key component of our data. Since the series is lagged, the

    yield curve is flat or negative during or right before recession (indicated in blue).

    Estimation and Results

    0

    0.1

    0.2

    0.3

    0.4

    0.5

    0.6

    0.7

    0.8

    0.9

    1

    -5

    -3

    -1

    1

    3

    5

    7

    9

    11

    13

    15

    Mar-77

    Mar-78

    Mar-79

    Mar-80

    Mar-81

    Mar-82

    Mar-83

    Mar-84

    Mar-85

    Mar-86

    Mar-87

    Mar-88

    Mar-89

    Mar-90

    Mar-91

    Mar-92

    Mar-93

    Mar-94

    Mar-95

    Mar-96

    Mar-97

    Mar-98

    Mar-99

    Mar-00

    Mar-01

    Mar-02

    Mar-03

    Mar-04

    Mar-05

    Mar-06

    Mar-07

    Mar-08

    Mar-09

    Mar-10

    Mar-11

    YieldCurveSlope(%)

    Figure1:YieldCurveSlopeDipsIntoNega

  • 7/28/2019 Forecasting the Probability of Recession

    10/24

    10

    We estimate the four models and compare the fits of each model. The fourth one

    is almost identical to Kauppis model.

    1 : (!!! = 1) = (! + !HS+ !IP+ !CS+ !YC+ !)2 : (!!! = 1) = (! + !HS+ !IP+ !CS+ !YC+ !R! + !)3 : (!!! = 1) = (!YC+ !)4 : (!!! = 1) = (!YC+ !R! + !)

    The estimation results can be found in the appendix to this paper. In model 1, all

    the coefficients of the independent variables are significant with p

  • 7/28/2019 Forecasting the Probability of Recession

    11/24

    11

    Table2:Max-RescaledR2

    Model1 Static 0.6605

    Model2 Dynamic 0.8585

    Model3 StaticYieldCurve 0.2831

    Model4 DynamicYieldCurve 0.8286

    Clearly, the dynamic model with all of the explanatory variables achieves the best

    fit. Indeed, the R2

    value is slightly higher than that of model 4, which is an imitation of

    Kauppis model.7

    A graphical analysis of the models predicted and actual events is beneficial. The

    chart below plots the two models prediction of a recession in time t. The blue areas

    indicate recession in time t. Model 1 fits the data better than model 3. This indicates that

    a model with both the yield curve andthe selected independent variables outperforms the

    yield curve alone. However, they are both extremely volatile. Model 1s predictions were

    very volatile from 1995 to 2001, before the recession in the early 2000s.

    Nevertheless, model 1 is very good at identifying turning points in the economy.

    When the economy was not yet in a recession in the early 80s, the model predicted an

    84.5% chance of recession next month. Next month, there was a recession. Its previous

    prediction was only 32%. For each of the 3 months before the 2008 recession, the model

    predicted a 65% chance of recession. While the economy was still in the 2008 recession,

    7Thismodelisjustanimitation.KauppiusedBayesianestimationandapseudo-R2.

    Thus,ourresultsarenotdirectlycomparable.ThehighestR2outofallofKauppis

    modelswas.77.KauppiandEstrellausethesameR2:

    Pseudo-R2=1-(log(Lu)/log(Lc))^(2log(Lc)/T).

    Here,Luis theunconstrainedmaximizedlikelihood function.Lcis theconstrained

    likelihoodfunctionwiththeconstraintthatallcoefficients,excepttheconstant,are

    zero.Tisthenumberofobservations.

  • 7/28/2019 Forecasting the Probability of Recession

    12/24

    12

    0%

    10%

    20%

    30%

    40%

    50%

    60%

    70%80%

    90%

    100%

    0

    0.1

    0.2

    0.3

    0.4

    0.5

    0.6

    0.7

    0.8

    0.9

    1

    March-77

    March-78

    March-79

    March-80

    March-81

    March-82

    March-83

    March-84

    March-85

    March-86

    March-87

    March-88

    March-89

    March-90

    March-91

    March-92

    March-93

    March-94

    March-95

    March-96

    March-97

    March-98

    March-99

    March-00

    March-01

    March-02

    March-03

    March-04

    March-05

    March-06

    March-07

    March-08

    March-09

    March-10

    March-11

    Figure2:StaticModels

    Model3

    Model1

    the model predicted a 5% chance of recession the next month. The recession did end the

    following month.

    As another example, the model was assigning a 7% chance of recession for the

    month of March 1990. Its prediction for the next month shockingly jumped to 20%, then

    40% the next month, until finally calling a 55% chance of recession in August. Indeed, a

    recession did begin in August. While the nation was still in recession, the model

    predicted a 27% chance of recession next month, down from 40% the month before. The

    recession did end the next month.

  • 7/28/2019 Forecasting the Probability of Recession

    13/24

    13

    The chart above plots the probability of recession in time tas predicted by model

    2 and 4. Again, the shaded area represents recession in time t. The dynamic models

    forecasts are much less volatile than the static forecasts. However, they do a poor job at

    identifying turning points in the economy. Model 2 assigned a 4% probability of

    recession to August 1981. However, a recession did start that month. That recession

    ended in December 1982. However, Model 2 had assigned a 97% chance of a recession

    to that month. Model 4 made a similar blunder with that recession. It assigned a 5%

    probability of a recession to August 1981 and a 97% probability of recession to

    December 1982. For every month between the first and last months of the recession, the

    model would consistently predict over 90% probabilities of recession.

    Both dynamic models follow this pattern for every recession in our sample. We

    believe this occurs because of the large coefficient on the recession lag. In both dynamic

    models, it is the largest and most significant coefficient. This emphasis on recessionary

    0%

    10%

    20%

    30%

    40%

    50%

    60%

    70%

    80%

    90%

    100%

    0

    0.2

    0.4

    0.6

    0.8

    1

    1.2Figure3:DynamicModels

    Model2

    Model4

  • 7/28/2019 Forecasting the Probability of Recession

    14/24

    14

    state in the current month as a predictor of recession next month is a flaw. The models are

    unable to correctly predict turning points.

    Thus, we decided to select our optimal model from the static group. We select the

    model with the highest max-rescaled R2, model 1. Model one has the highest R

    2metric of

    .66, making it the best-fit model.

    Out-of-Sample Predictions

    While the in-sample forecasts are good, it remains to be seen whether the out-of-

    sample forecasts are accurate. Figure 4 plots model 1s out-of-sample and in-sample

    predictions of the probability of recession. The line is marked in red with an arrow

    pointing to the future. We make 18 out-of-sample predictions.

    The model gets jumpy in the future in the first few months. The model predicted a

    55% chance of recession in October 2011, the first month in the out-of-sample forecast

    0

    0.1

    0.2

    0.3

    0.4

    0.5

    0.6

    0.7

    0.8

    0.9

    1

    0%

    10%

    20%

    30%

    40%

    50%

    60%

    70%

    80%

    90%

    100%

    Mar-77

    Mar-79

    Mar-81

    Mar-83

    Mar-85

    Mar-87

    Mar-89

    Mar-91

    Mar-93

    Mar-95

    Mar-97

    Mar-99

    Mar-01

    Mar-03

    Mar-05

    Mar-07

    Mar-09

    Mar-11

    Mar-13

    Figure4:Model1withOut-of-Sample

    Predictions

    Model1

  • 7/28/2019 Forecasting the Probability of Recession

    15/24

    15

    period. It fluctuated greatly around 50% for the next following months before lowering to

    around 10% from December 2012 to March 2013. This fluctuation and apparent

    uncertainty is not without cause and we do not believe that it reflects inaccuracies in the

    model.

    Instead, the period of uncertainty, from October 2011 to November 2012,

    corresponds to the uncertainty regarding the European sovereign debt crisis. Yields on

    Spanish, Greek, and Italian long-term maturity bonds were soaring throughout this

    period. Analysts were entertaining the possibility of contagion, as U.S. banks with

    large stakes in European sovereign debt were at risk. Similarly, experts and political

    leaders were questioning the very existence of the European Union. There was

    widespread fear that a Greek exit from the Euro would spark capital flight out of the

    continent and plunge the EU into a recession. There was widespread fear that this would

    cause a double-dip recession in the United States. These fears largely subsided after the

    German constitutional court decided that a Greek bailout was legal. The fear of a Greek

    exit and subsequent macroeconomic shocks disappeared. The model reflects this with

    lower recession probability forecasts. The average forecast from December 2012 to

    March 2013 was 10%.

    Conclusion

    Both in-sample and out-of-sample predictions confirm that model one is the

    superior performer, as discussed in the previous section. Furthermore, it is worth noting

    that model 1, which includes additional explanatory variables is superior to model 2, in

    terms of in-sample fit. Thus, a model which augments the yield curve with IP, HS, and

    CS is superior to a model which includes YC as the sole explanatory variable. Model 1 is

    also superior to both dynamic models, which fail to predict turning points in the

    economy.

  • 7/28/2019 Forecasting the Probability of Recession

    16/24

    16

    Bibliography

    1. Arturo Estrella & Frederic S. Mishkin, 1996. "Predicting U.S. recessions:financial variables as leading indicators," Research Paper 9609, Federal Reserve

    Bank of New York.o http://www.albany.edu/~xl843228/teaching/ECON350/EstrellaMishkin19

    98.pdf

    2. Arturo Estrella & Frederic S. Mishkin, 1996."The Yield Curve as a Predictor ofU.S. Recessions," Current Issues in Economics and Finance, Federal Reserve

    Bank of New York, issue Jun.

    o http://www.newyorkfed.org/research/current_issues/ci2-7.pdf3. Heikki Kauppi, 2008."Yield-Curve Based Probit Models for Forecasting U.S.

    Recessions: Stability and Dynamics," Discussion Papers 31, Aboa Centre for

    Economics.

    o http://ethesis.helsinki.fi/julkaisut/eri/hecer/disc/221/yieldcur.pdf4. Marcelle Chauvet & Simon Potter, 2005."Forecasting recessions using the yield

    curve," Journal of Forecasting, John Wiley & Sons, Ltd., vol. 24(2), pages 77-

    103.

    o http://www.newyorkfed.org/research/staff_reports/sr134.pdf5. Michael Dueker, 1997. "Strengthening the case for the yield curve as a predictor

    of U.S. recessions," Review, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, issue Mar, pages

    41-51.

    o http://research.stlouisfed.org/publications/review/97/03/9703md.pdf6. Arturo Estrella & Anthony P. Rodrigues & Sebastian Schich, 2000."How stable is

    the predictive power of the yield curve? evidence from Germany and the United

    States," Staff Reports 113, Federal Reserve Bank of New York.

    o http://www.newyorkfed.org/research/staff_reports/sr113.pdf

  • 7/28/2019 Forecasting the Probability of Recession

    17/24

    17

    Appendix

    Model estimates:

    The LOGISTIC Procedure: MODEL 1

    Model Information

    Data Set WORK.SET1Response Variable rec Recession Dummy (dependent)

    Number of Response Levels 2

    Model binary probit

    Optimization Technique Fisher's scoring

    Number of Observations Read 415

    Number of Observations Used 415

    Response Profile

    Ordered Total

    Value rec Frequency

    1 0 359

    2 1 56

    Probability modeled is rec=1.

    Model Convergence Status

    Convergence criterion (GCONV=1E-8) satisfied.

    Model Fit Statistics

    Intercept

    Intercept and

    Criterion Only Covariates

    AIC 330.406 152.452

    SC 334.435 172.594

    -2 Log L 328.406 142.452

    R-Square 0.3611 Max-rescaled R-Square 0.6605

  • 7/28/2019 Forecasting the Probability of Recession

    18/24

    18

    The LOGISTIC Procedure

    Testing Global Null Hypothesis: BETA=0

    Test Chi-Square DF Pr > ChiSq

    Likelihood Ratio 185.9540 4

  • 7/28/2019 Forecasting the Probability of Recession

    19/24

    19

    The LOGISTIC Procedure: MODEL 2

    Model Information

    Data Set WORK.SET1

    Response Variable rec Recession Dummy (dependent)

    Number of Response Levels 2

    Model binary probit

    Optimization Technique Fisher's scoring

    Number of Observations Read 415

    Number of Observations Used 415

    Response Profile

    Ordered Total

    Value rec Frequency

    1 0 359

    2 1 56

    Probability modeled is rec=1.

    Model Convergence Status

    Convergence criterion (GCONV=1E-8) satisfied.

    Model Fit Statistics

    Intercept

    Intercept and

    Criterion Only Covariates

    AIC 330.406 77.425

    SC 334.435 101.595

    -2 Log L 328.406 65.425

    R-Square 0.4694 Max-rescaled R-Square 0.8585

  • 7/28/2019 Forecasting the Probability of Recession

    20/24

    20

    The LOGISTIC Procedure

    Testing Global Null Hypothesis: BETA=0

    Test Chi-Square DF Pr > ChiSq

    Likelihood Ratio 262.9813 5

  • 7/28/2019 Forecasting the Probability of Recession

    21/24

    21

    The LOGISTIC Procedure: MODEL 3

    Model Information

    Data Set WORK.SET1

    Response Variable rec Recession Dummy (dependent)

    Number of Response Levels 2

    Model binary probit

    Optimization Technique Fisher's scoring

    Number of Observations Read 415

    Number of Observations Used 415

    Response Profile

    Ordered Total

    Value rec Frequency

    1 0 359

    2 1 56

    Probability modeled is rec=1.

    Model Convergence Status

    Convergence criterion (GCONV=1E-8) satisfied.

    Model Fit Statistics

    Intercept

    Intercept and

    Criterion Only Covariates

    AIC 330.406 262.622

    SC 334.435 270.679

    -2 Log L 328.406 258.622

    R-Square 0.1548 Max-rescaled R-Square 0.2831

  • 7/28/2019 Forecasting the Probability of Recession

    22/24

  • 7/28/2019 Forecasting the Probability of Recession

    23/24

  • 7/28/2019 Forecasting the Probability of Recession

    24/24

    24

    The LOGISTIC Procedure

    Testing Global Null Hypothesis: BETA=0

    Test Chi-Square DF Pr > ChiSq

    Likelihood Ratio 250.4143 2