FinStResearcharticleCommodificationofEducation2012 - Copy

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 8/2/2019 FinStResearcharticleCommodificationofEducation2012 - Copy

    1/20

    1

    Project funded by the European Commission

    Research Article: Commodification of Higher

    Education

    Project Name:Financing the Students Future FinSt

    Ref. 510583LLP120101BEERASMUSEMHE

    Agreement no. 20103706/001001

    Focus Area: Lifelong Learning and Higher Education Area

    Document Title: FinSt Project Commodification of Higher Education

    Document Id: FinSt_D1.2_ESU_v1 (find it in the backoffice)Date of elaboration: 30/10/2011

    Author:Email address:

    Coauthors:

    Quality Reviewers: Project team members

    Date of Delivery: 31/10/2011

    Number of Pages: 17

    Distribution List: Partners mailing list/NUSes/Media

    Confidentiality Status: Public

  • 8/2/2019 FinStResearcharticleCommodificationofEducation2012 - Copy

    2/20

    2

    Following the Commodification Daemon

    Commodification of Education in higher education financing systems

    by Moritz Maurer, Angelika Gruber

    Recently, hardly any dispute on higher education (HE) between the different activestakeholders is held, without reasons related to the term of commodification. To many theterm must have become a daemon, haunting through the discussions, pulling the strings inactual developments of the higher education sector with one hand, with the other hand

    directing the chorus of global players trying to construct things called knowledge basedsociety, network economy, Bologna Process, GATS etc.

    The following article on commodification of education (CE) tries to make a part of that daemondisappear, making concrete political action in the field of HE financing possible by contributingto ESUs project, Financing of Students Future (FINST). The main questions the article dealswith are whether CE does influence higher education financing (does the daemon exist?),where and how CE influences higher education financing systems (who creates what daemonwhat for?) and what do students think about CE (do we believe in the daemon?). Therefore thefirst section of the article aims at clarifying the term and its historic development by aqualitative literature analysis. The purpose of this part is to introduce the reader to the topic byoutlining the main social and ethical problems of commodification. The first part of the articleserves to make the theses established and tested in the second part understandable. In a thirdpart the opinions of student union representatives on questions related to CE are investigatedin order to have an idea of the students perception of CE. This is done by studying data of theFINST survey, developed by the FINST research team and sent to ESU member unions. Finallywe draw a conclusion, trying to put emphasis on what should be further investigated, as well aswhat the results of this article imply to FINSTs attempt finding good solutions of HE financing.

  • 8/2/2019 FinStResearcharticleCommodificationofEducation2012 - Copy

    3/20

    3

    1.

    Definition of the term

    Starting to analyse the term this text is going to be about, major difficulties occur. The processof commodification is quite clear. Here we are going to define a commodity referring to Balzerdue to his practical and moderate definition: Commodities are objects of trade, they areproduced, they are associated with rights of disposition and they give its owner some sort ofbenefit (cf. Balzer 2003:89f). Commodification is the process that gives an object thecharacteristics named before. However the meaning of education is pretty unclear. The term isunderstood by some as a tool and chance for the individual to gain autonomy, majority andemancipation (cf. Bakic et al 2011:16). By others education is seen as an engine of future

    economic growth and prosperity and includes a chance to avoid economic, social,environmental and other crises the world seems to be shifting at (cf. for instance: EuropeanCommission 2010: Europe 2020). Beside the chorus that glorifies the role of educationreferring to quite different reasons, more critical voices argue that educational systems are alsosystems where relations of power and inequalities are reproduced and following the history ofeducation, its role to conform attending individuals to ideologies cannot be underestimated.

    In the UN declaration of universal human rights education is declared as a basic human right.But already in that article certain restrictions are put up. Regarding higher education the articlesays that it should be equally accessible to all on the basis of merit (cf. The Universal

    Declaration of Human Rights). Unfortunately the declaration doesnt clarify what this means.Actually it just opens the field to a political discussion, hardly excluding any perception ofeducation. What does equally accessible on the basis of merit mean? Who defines this basis ofmerit? How can be defined what exactly is meant by higher education and how it is distinctfrom other levels of education? Who can define quality of education, who defines theparameters its quality is measured with? And many questions more.

    Education and perhaps more obvious, the sense and quality of education is hard to define,Adorno even argues, its indefinable, and its furthermore not possible to earn it (cf. Adorno2006:44,33).

    Anyway if its so hard to define education it can be assumed that its also hardly possible tomake it a commodity. Looking at the commodification process, it becomes obvious that noteducation in general can be commoditized. What can be sold on markets are commoditieslinked to acquisition of defined skills, the certification of these skills and with that a promise ofan advantage on the markets for an individual, knowledge and knowledge production orknowledge producing institutions. As skills can be defined as internalized knowledge, it can befurther investigated how knowledge can be commoditized. To clarify this point, its necessaryto look a bit deeper into the characteristics of knowledge itself and see how thecommodification of knowledge is different to the commodification of other objects.

    Gorz postulates a distinction between two sorts of knowledge: Living knowledge and scientificknowledge. Living knowledge is bound to a subject. It comprises a broadvariety of individual skills, like intuition, power of judgment, learning

  • 8/2/2019 FinStResearcharticleCommodificationofEducation2012 - Copy

    4/20

    4

    abilities etc. Apart from that scientific knowledge can be formalized. It can exist without anindividual. This distinction is quite practical to explain the commodification process (cf. Gorz

    2004:41ff).

    The first category of knowledge, living knowledge, is learned by use and results due to thepossibility of the subject to produce itself. It contains the knowledge of interpersonal relationsand can be used without understanding it, without possessing it formalized, likewise to alanguage that can be spoken without knowing any rules of grammar(cf. Gorz 2004:42). Forinstance the ERT (European round table of industrialists) refers to this knowledge whendemanding a product [sic] of this education chain to be well rounded individuals trainedhow to learn and to be motivated always to learn more (cf. ERT 1994:7). This knowledge can becommoditized partially, transformed into professional skills that can be distributed as servicesbut it cannot yet be totally formalized because the performance of these actions needs alwaysa rest of personal engagement. The value of the service is hardly predictable (cf. Gorz 2004:43).Imagine a scientist being employed for creating innovation. The value for society of the productshe/he creates cannot be forecast and must not be contingent with the time its creation took.Regarding to the definition of a commodity, we know that it is linked to production and benefit.The impossibility to predict a correlation between effort of production and benefit ofknowledge makes its commodification process complex. Anyway this is one of the dimensionsas which institutionalized education can be offered on a market. For example the service of amotivational seminar can be offered to individuals or corporations or the service of qualitytesting of workers by testing skills can be sold as a product.

    Formalized knowledge on the other hand can be offered on a market as patents, copyrightagreements or bound to a product as an innovation. Both these processes to sell knowledgehave in common, that in order to make them a commodity, their access needs to be controlled.A generalized service that is connected to knowledge of an individual gets a tradablecommodity only if the knowledge is not part of societys general knowledge (Gorz 2004:42). Forformalized wisdom the need to control its access, in order to make it a commodity, is easier tograb. The costs to develop formalizable knowledge are insecure and totally different to thecosts of its reproduction. To produce the first unit can be very costly but the reproduction costsof each other unit go close to zero (cf. Gorz 2004:47). A good example here is the softwareindustry. To develop a new program is quite costly. But when the software is finished it can be

    easily distributed via internet without any costs. So to be able to sell the program the producercompany needs to limit the access by copy protection etc.

    To sum up, its obvious that knowledge is not an ordinary commodity. Its worth is notpredictable, and not measurable. If its possible to digitalize it, it can be reproduced withoutcosts and limits and its distribution increases its value. The privatization of knowledge whereasreduces its value and contradicts its characteristics (cf. Gorz 2004:79).

    These particularities of knowledge commodification bring in a new perspective to thediscussion of the commodification process: Is it ethical or wanted to limit the access of a goodthat could be accessible to everybody as a public good?

    Furthermore with these particularities some of the bias in the

  • 8/2/2019 FinStResearcharticleCommodificationofEducation2012 - Copy

    5/20

    5

    dispute of HE financing can be explained:

    Egalitarian approach vs. Individualist approach (HE should be accessible to all due to thebenefit of all vs. benefit of merit leads to more innovation for the benefit of all). Furtherexplanation follows later in the text.

    The problem to quantify quality of outcomes: critics argue that quantifying quality ofeducation system outputs by allocation of funds by marketlike criteria, leads to wrongdecisions in the allocation of limited resources.

    The following example out of the pharmaceutical industry aims at making this problem moreunderstandable: A company invents a medication that treats a serious disease. The medicationcan be produced easily and without danger. The company wishes to get a patent on theirproduct. Isnt it quite unethical, to not give the knowledge how to produce the medication to

    everyone who has the disease or to everyone that could produce the medication (egalitarian oremanzipative approach)? The company argues that the production of this knowledge was veryexpensive and they couldnt have done it if they didnt have the perspective of gaining profit bythe monopolist rent of their innovation (individualist approach). Regarding the medical supplyof weaker economies, this problem is existent and the inequalities that this restriction of use ofknowledge creates are outrageous (cf. Seefeld 2002).

    From commodification of knowledge to economization of HEI to commodification of

    education

    The apparent necessity of limiting the access to knowledge is nothing new. Already in ahumanistic argumentation for education in Humboldts tradition a situation of competition ofindividuals, that struggle for economic success concludes in a wish of individuals to restrictcertain knowledge (cf. Bakic et al. 2011:17). And due to the saying knowledge is power it canbe assumed that knowledge and the control of its access always has been an aid to implementthe power of an individual, a class or a state.

    Nevertheless this article is supposed to be about higher education, so the data investigated in

    the following sections is directed to higher education institutions. The previous disquisition wasboth necessary to draw the connection from the commodification of knowledge to thecommodification of an idea of institutionalized education and to show that the treatment ofknowledge within an educational institution influences its understanding of education.Furthermore the presumption that its not possible to find a common definition of educationand therefore it also cannot be commoditised, opens the sight to what all the rumour in thislong lasting discussion is about. Education is interpreted by different social entities differently.The commodification of knowledge products means an interpretation of education due tomarket analogue criteria. The adaption of organizational structure to make these criteriaapplicable could be seen as the link to the concept of economization (cf: Balzer 2003:93).

    Krautz describes three dimensions of an economization process of education (cf. Krautz2007:111):

  • 8/2/2019 FinStResearcharticleCommodificationofEducation2012 - Copy

    6/20

    6

    Economization of content: this dimension refers to an adaption of the content of taughtknowledge due to its economic relevance (In this dimension we include the adoption of content

    due to the relevance of students/post students purchase capacity. Students are consumers ofproducts designed to ease studying and research. Former students will be both advertisers andcostumers of products related to their studies. Both might have an influence on taught andresearched content1.)

    Economization of educational services: this dimension refers to the implementation of a marketwith educational services. This means a privatization of educational institutions and theimplementation of a market for knowledge commodities.

    Economization of educational institutions and pedagogic relations: This dimension refers to ainternal adoption of the leadership and management style of educational institutions to a morebusiness like organization and the implementation of a situation of competition of educationinstitutions. This adoption leads to an economization of relations between humans and the

    pedagogic relations between students and teachers (This includes perceptions of students beingan investment in their own and their countries economic benefit. For that presumption the biasin the dispute on HE mentioned previously is applicable. Also choice of study based on economiccriteria will be mentioned in the following text several times and therefore it should be clarifiedthat we see it as a part of this dimension. For more information on inequalities, probablyresulting from this, FINST article on social dimension can be consulted).

    All these dimensions can be seen as a result of the commodification process. Markets arebased on norms involved persons are willing to accept. The maintaining of these normsconcerns juridical and police administration, which define and persecute violations of these

    norms (cf. Balzer 2003:105). Also the market for knowledge is created and supported by statesor international contracts (f.I. GATS, patent right, copyright agreement etc.) (cf. Lichtblau2008:53).

    What happened, where are we now and what are we going to face?

    It can be stated quite clearly, that economic reasoning did always play a role in the individualchoice of study, creation of curricula, funding of higher education institutions etc. So what didchange, that critics of the ongoing development feel education endangered by an economicapproach (for instance: ESIB compendium on tuition fees 2005, 2)? David Bridges and RuthJonathan investigate in an essay on education on the market (cf. Blake et al 2002:126ff) inphilosophical strands on the view of education and their historic uprisings in post war Europessociety. Jonathan argues that the individualistic turn of education and the quasimarketization in these days cannot be understood without analysing the historic change of thedebate in the philosophy of education (cf. Blake et al in Philosophy of Education 2002:138). Toshorten up relevant information out of their analyses, without going too much into detail, three

    1Unfortunately we could not find a qualitative source for this assumption. As an example for its legitimation, useof ICT products in university surroundings might be considered.

  • 8/2/2019 FinStResearcharticleCommodificationofEducation2012 - Copy

    7/20

    7

    major common developments in the understanding of higher education can be distilled out ofJonathans assumptions:

    In the post war years until the 1970s education was only available to the privileged andphilosophers tried to explain to all, the benefits of liberal education. The socially funded andstate regulated education given to some should emancipate them and wealth and knowledgewould trickle down to the whole of society (cf. Jonathan et al 2002:139). The 1960s and 70swere branded by the idea of liberal education for all instead of some. Still the emphasis was onthe idea, that education would emancipate individuals and enable them to take part indemocratic processes etc. To ensure liberal education, the search for an epistemologicalrationale for curricula became central (cf. Jonathan et al 2002:139) and developed further intodebates over who should control the curriculum and into democratic approaches of theircontrol. Thus during the 80s a general individualist or neoliberal turn hit the debates. Theegalitarian approach got challenged by centralising the proper award of merit that accompaniesa more competitive and productive environment. Jonathan relates these challenges to theegalitarian postwar impetus to the general individualist or neoliberal turn with its politicalmoment in the 1980s.

    On these arguments, market principles were applied in an established public education servicemanaged in some way through the apparatus of the states. Bridges further analyses, taking theUK as an example that the application of market principles is nearly always at the expanse of anationally or locally administrated state bureaucracy which is subject to national and localdorms of democratic accountability. Critics of such systems highlight the predominance of the

    role of the state bureaucracy in their operations (cf. Jonathan et al 2002:127).

    But as Bridges further explains, taking the development in the UK as an example, theimplementation of market like criteria was actually pretty halfhearted. Actually Bridges states,taking into account several sources, that the implementation was followed by centralisation ofthe control of curricula development, policed through a combination of nationally definedtests, benchmarks of achievement, and a state controlled system of inspection. Traditionalsystems were replaced to ensure the conformity of independent institutions to the will ofgovernment (cf. Jonathan et al 2002:129). In Austria an analogous development could beobserved (cf. Maurer et al 2011:237ff).

    Having a look at the characteristics of the current state of education and HEI the analyses byBridges that theyre to be seen somewhere in the middle of a development to quasi marketlike structures seem to be very applicable. The role of HEI is ambivalent. Weingart describes thestatus as a division into two knowledge cultures. One has free access and the production ofknowledge there is supported by society. The other one is commercialized and the producedknowledge is traded on markets, provided with property rights. (cf. Weingart 2008:477). Thesame ambivalence, regarding the treatment of knowledge, can be found within the EU2020vision paper. On one hand the access to higher education should be widened, on the otherhand the innovation union pictures an economy that demands the restriction of the access toknowledge (cf. European Commission 2010: Europe 2020).

    The question that comes up is whether we face a drastic or evencomplete transformation of knowledge and knowledge producing

  • 8/2/2019 FinStResearcharticleCommodificationofEducation2012 - Copy

    8/20

    8

    institutions to commodities and what the effects of this transformation would be (cf. Weingart2008:477). Picturing future socioeconomic complexes and work atmospheres as described by

    Luc Boltanski/ ve Chiapello (cf. Boltanski et Chiapello 2006:f.I.287 ) or Gorz (cf. Gorz 2004:20),where selfproduction of individual knowledge capital becomes a total constraint, a moreextensive shift of this ambivalence towards commercial knowledge producing institutions ispossible. Also arguments in favour of the described individualistic turn take up a line going intothat direction.

    With the basic understanding of the commodification process of education explained in theprevious text we can go on to a hypothesis testing section. Here we will investigate whether adevelopment of commodification within higher education financing systems can be observed.

    2. Commodification of Education in HE financing systemsThe following chapter is about trends in funding mechanisms with an emphasize on the impactof commodification of education in higher education financing systems. To grasp theimplementation of quasi market situations in the allocation of funds to higher educationinstitutions we will discuss two dimensions of economization that are built up on the thesis ofthe previous chapter. The privatization of educational institutions and the implementation of amarket for knowledge commodities imply a shift from public to private funding structures,whereas the economization of educational institutions and pedagogic relations refers toadoption of the management style. We argue that the view of the entrepreneurial universityalso leads to changes in the criteria that drive the allocation of the government appropriationsto the institutions. Thus, two Hypotheses are going to be tested, to grasp the implementationof quasi market situations in the allocation of funds to higher education institutions:

    The share of individual contributions and the share of nonprivate household contributions tohigher education institution increased

    The share of via competition allocated funds to higher education institutions increased

    The share of nonprivate households is an indicator of the quantity and quality of outputs for

    use as commodities and the share of via competition allocated funds can be seen as an

    indicator of implementation of market like criteria in HE financing systems. The mapped data,

    an output of FINST desktop research, could unfortunately not be used to test this hypothesis

    because FINST just investigated a picture of the currant HEI financing systems. To test the two

    hypotheses however changes needed to be taken into the elaborations. Data that is compared

    for the first hypotheses come from OECD sources. For the last Hypothesis a more qualitative

    approach is carried out, the hypotheses is answered with expert literature on the topic.

    2.1 levels of public and private funding

    Even though European universities are predominantly funded by

  • 8/2/2019 FinStResearcharticleCommodificationofEducation2012 - Copy

    9/20

    9

    public sources there is a noticeable increase in the share of private contribution. Figure 1

    approves that thesis with increasing shares of non governmental sources, especially via

    student tuition and other fees, between 1999 and 2008 for selected countries. This trend canbe observed in other European countries as well. The selection of the countries was mainly

    made to underline the different kind of levels of public and private funding. This might have

    various reasons, but in a nutshell can be explained by the different shape of welfare system.

    Well known Esping Andersen tries to overview the classification of welfare systems in a very

    simple and short way. According to the Danish sociologist welfare systems can be clustered into

    three kinds of categories: the Liberal, the CorporatistStatist or the Social Democratic system.

    More in general, of course it might seem absurd to characterize a complex mechanism such as

    a 'welfare state' in one of three categories, as even Esping Andersen himself acknowledges.

    However the selected countries some kind of fit into one of those welfare state types. In terms

    of funding higher education, it is namely observed that in social democratic systems such as

    Norway or Sweden the university system is solely or at least almost solely financed by

    government, whereas liberal welfare states such as the UK or the US notes very high shares of

    private funding of HE. Corporate Statist countries like Germany or Austria lie somewhere in

    between the two extremes. Anyways it is well noticeable that shares were rising in nearly all

    selected countries between 1999 and 2008. The stagnating trend in public spending until

    2008, combined with the impact of the current economic crisis signal that, unless a major policy

    commitment is made, prospects are not bright for a significant increase in the level of higher

    education funding (EACEA 2011, 35). This of course heats the debate about the need of private

    contribution for financing tertiary education.

    Figure1: Private expenditure as a percentage of total expenditure to tertiary education

    Source: OECD

    0% 20% 40% 60% 80% 100%

    Austria

    France

    Germany

    Netherlands

    Norway

    UK

    USA

    Sweden

    2008

    1999

  • 8/2/2019 FinStResearcharticleCommodificationofEducation2012 - Copy

    10/20

    10

    Those developments are followed by the incentives that are set by governments and universityadministration to generate external (i.e. competitive, third party, industry based) income.

    Universities are encouraged to enforce their ties to industry. This is especially true for financing

    academic R&D. The share of industry based income is 12,6% in Germany, 6,8% in the

    Netherlands and about 5% in the UK with the effect of growing influence of industry to research

    findings (cf. Leitner 2007, 1).

    Figure 2 should state the growing interest of private institutions and direct payment from

    business for service provided by universities. Obviously education as investment in humancapital, as one of the main factors of economic growth in modern industries, has become a keyplank of official educational policy platforms in many countries. The dominance of economicsover educational policy continues. As discussed before, this also changes the funding structureswhere individuals or businesses play a greater role than ever before (cf. Yang 2003, 278). Again,there is a remarkable increase of private expenditures (other than households) to tertiaryeducation between 1999 and 2008.

    Figure 2: percentage of private expenditures other than households to tertiary education

    Source: OECD

    0,0% 2,0% 4,0% 6,0% 8,0% 10,0% 12,0% 14,0%

    Austria

    France

    Netherlands

    Sweden

    UK

    2008

    1999

  • 8/2/2019 FinStResearcharticleCommodificationofEducation2012 - Copy

    11/20

    11

    2.2 Performance based funding (PBF)The impact of the commodification process on financing systems can not only be observed by ashift from public to private funding sources, but mainly by the emphasis of the evaluation ofuniversity performance. This changing financing structure is connected to the main idea thatacademic output can be improved by imposing incentives to competition between universitiesand performance orientation. Universities should be run like a business, new publicmanagement structures should enforce universities to act more efficiently. As regards Europe,in most of the countries public funding is no longer tied to input measures (such as students).Governmental initiatives go towards a more competitive allocation of operation funds. This canbe mainly measured by the degree of the output orientation in public funding and the degree

    of competition implied by funding decisions (cf. Jongbloed 2008, 16). Probably the mainreason for introducing a performance based approach to the funding of university research isthe belief that it is meritocratic, providing a reward for those with a record of successfulresearch, and thus constituting a strong incentive for improving the quality of research asmeasured by the selected performance indicators (Genua/Martin 2001, 26).

    For the classification of funding mechanism Jungbloed uses two questions: What is funded bythe government?, how is funded?. The first question concerns the funding base for thegovernment allocations to higher education institutions: Are the funds tied to educationaloutputs and performance, or rather to inputs? The second question relates to the issue of the

    degree of market orientation in the funding arrangements (Jongbloed 2008, 18). To classifyfunding arrangements he distinguishes four quadrants (see figure 3).

    Figure 3: Classifying funding mechanisms

    Source: Jongbloed 2008

    Centralised (regulated) approaches

    Output

    orientation

    Input

    orientation

    Decentralised (market) approaches

    Q1 Q2

    Q4 Q3

  • 8/2/2019 FinStResearcharticleCommodificationofEducation2012 - Copy

    12/20

    12

    The vertical axis depicts the degree of (de) centralisation, the horizontal axis expresses thedegree to which governments are paying for outcomes or inputs. Q1 represents a centralized

    system of funding (in most of the times budgets are negotiated between government anduniversities), Q2 is still centralized, but now the criteria on which funding is allocated referrather to outputs then to inputs (for example a formula is calculated based on outputs such asstudents that are passing exams). Q3 instead is more market oriented: higher educationinstitutions are encouraged to compete with one another, while they commit themselves toproduce a certain output. The last quadrant Q4 represents a demand driven input basedfunding system. Core funding then is supplied through the clients of higher educationinstitutions (the university charges the students a certain amount of the course costs forexample).

    In practice the financing structure of European universities is a mixture between the modelsdescribed above. They most of the time include unconditional allocation mechanisms (mostlybased on negotiations between government and universities) as well as conditional allocationmechanisms, where allocation is calculated on the basis of formulas. Also, formulas are mostbalanced on input as well as output criteria, even though there is a clear tendency to outputcriteria. Jongbloed and other financing experts (also see Leitner 2011) attest that development,mainly because of rethinking the university system and the term of education itself, which wasdescribed in the first section. In specific, changes in universities funding environment are atrend towards performancebased funding, where budgets are increasingly based on measuresof institutional performances based on either actual or projected results. Common measuresare the number of degrees or credits accumulated by students, as mentioned before, or theallocation of grants and contracts in a competitive process such as through a research council(cf. Jongbloed 2008, 23). While we observe a growing use of performance measures, there isyet no uniformity in the choice of indicators. Our overview shows that use is made of thefollowing performance indicators: number of (BA and MA) degrees, credits, graduation rates,success in winning competitive research grants, academic publications, and research evaluationoutcomes (Jongbloed 2008, 28). To sketch the changes the so called CHINC project (Changes inUniversity Incomes and their Impact on university based research and innovation) illustratedthose developments over the period 19952003. Its findings concerning the tendencies thatpoint in the direction of Performance based funding stand out clear: nearly all Europeancountries use mechanisms that are based in quadrant Q3: Especially the use of allocation of

    grants and contracts in a competitive process, such as through a research council, has beensignificantly increasing. Research funding is more and more financed through public funds.Figure 4 approves those tendencies.

  • 8/2/2019 FinStResearcharticleCommodificationofEducation2012 - Copy

    13/20

    13

    Figure 4: development of competitive finance structure 19952003

    Source: CHINC project (Lapori et al. 2005), Jongbloed 2008

    The University of Twente in the Netherland is often cited as to be the role model of the modernentrepreneurial university. It completely changed its organizational culture and internalvalues through the ideologization of the entrepreneurial university idea (cf. Leitner et al. 2007,69). About a third of its resources come from industry, there is in general a very closecooperation to the local business structure and its research findings are highly related to labour

    market and industrys needs.But those tendencies, of course, did not happen without being criticized by many experts.Bultmann and Weitkamp for example argued, that third party funding and competitivefinancing lead to a concentration of funds to only those universities that are attractive to theeconomy. Public funds are now often allocated based on winning competitive research grants.This concentration will even increase at the expense of smaller, less competitive universities,that are not well linked to the economy (cf. Bultmann/Weitkamp 2008, 49). All in allperformance based funding is first of all implemented to encourage efficiency, but also to haveuniversities produce relevant outputs. It can move resources from less well performingareas to areas where they can be used to greater effect (Jongbloed 2008, 32). But as a

    consequence this system fully disregards the overall responsibility of the higher educationsystem and will also lead to a reduction of education due to its exploitable parts, as describedin the previous section.

  • 8/2/2019 FinStResearcharticleCommodificationofEducation2012 - Copy

    14/20

    14

    3. Student representative perception of developments linked tocommodification of education:

    Regarding the hypotheses tested in the previous chapter the student unions perception of thetested development is going to be investigated. Therefore a questionnaire, carried out by FINSTresearch team and sent to European students union representatives is used. (A detailedinvestigation of the survey can be found in the research article How do national studentsunions in Europe perceive their student finance systems?.) In the fallowing text we display aselection of Questions that can be associated to the hypothesis, and therefore to a marketanalogue change of the financing systems. Some of the questions not displayed could beassociated with CE but answers on them are too vague to find clear perceptions. Within the

    consultation process of the article we asked some union representatives for explanations ofparadox answers by some of the unions. Interesting answers from that are displayed andmarked within the disquisitions of the survey results.

    Ideological positions of national unions on students finance

    The survey asked the National Unions of Students (NUS) weather they have an ideological orpolitical position regarding the system of student finance. 14 of 35 NUS clearly responded that

    education should be free for all. Looking closer on the positions, a striking majority of unionsshare an egalitarian emphasis of the access to Higher Education.

    Participation in higher education

    On the question on unions perception on the quantity of participating individuals, 35%answered that the number is too low. This first result can be seen as a statement for highereducation as a public good that is to be accessible to all or a statement that a higher

    participation rate would result in a benefit for all. But summed up almost half of the unions arenot convinced of that understanding and think the participation rate is about right or even toohigh. Quite interestingly the answers seem to be contradictory to the answers of the firstquestion. The survey didnt ask for explanations in this item so this curiosity couldn t be solvedwith it. We asked at the consultation seminar some of the participants to find explanations. Theoutcome was, that some unions might have the feeling, that reasoning for free education is aloss of their credibility when the perception of the students body and other stakeholders, theunion is debating with, is that free education is a unrealistic phantasy. The second explanationthat came up is, that in some countries entering bachelor studies became quite asocioeconomic constraint, for young people. Combined with low quality of the Bachelor degreeand vast mechanism that reduce number of students within Bachelor level or before enteringMaster studies, this evolves in a situation, where participation in HE doesnot generally alter perspectives and chances for individual future nor

  • 8/2/2019 FinStResearcharticleCommodificationofEducation2012 - Copy

    15/20

    15

    societies future. Both the ideas for explaining the contradiction within the answers lack ofverification. They are mentioned here, as an possible approach for fruitful further

    investigations.

    How do you feel about the way the student financing system in your country shapes student

    choices of course, field of study and/ or institution?

    This question could be seen highly related to perception of commodification because it seemsto be highly related to the question whether it is good or not that students choices of course,field of study and/ or institutions are affected by economical individual thoughts. About one

    third of the NUS repeated that the affection is a problem. Comments on questions are rare butthose available, say that regulation by private fees fail to reflect actual needs of society oreconomic needs and differences in private costs of different fields of study lead to inequitiesprivileging students with better socio economic background.

    A clear consensus in the perception on questions about developments in the field of highereducation, which could be linked to the individualist turn, doesnt show up. The unions seem tohave quite different points of critique on their systems. This can be on one side explained byhuge differences in the financing systems and different problems in HE, on the other hand by adifferent understanding of higher education and the student unions role within it.

    In the consultation seminar workshop on the paper another curiosity appeared. To some of theunions the bias around commodification of education is quite unknown or is only seen in acontext with tuition fees. Problems that can be seen as a result of commodification of HE arenot necessarily contextualised to commodification of HE. This must lead to somemisunderstandings within the discussion of different student unions. The following quote fromminutes taken at the consultation seminar might explain the stated misunderstanding:

    We dont have a policy [on commodification of HE] because our education is free. Our HEsystem is public. Education should be free to all. It doesnt seem to be likely that our HEsystem is going to change, so we dont need a strategy regarding commodification. We

    support free higher education as an investment in the economy's futureLooking at ESIB policy on commodification 2005 and compendiums on tuition fees 2005 and2007, ESU/ESIBS perception of the commodification of education is very clear (cf. ESIBcompendium on tuition fees 2005, ESU compendium on tuition fees 2007, ESIB policy oncommodification of education 2005). Strong arguments against commodification of educationin favour of education as being a key factor of social development can be found and reasonscovering the dimensions, tested in the previous chapter. Although data validating ESUs andESIBs assumptions is missing. One as an example should be mentioned here:

    ESIB rejects the idea of education as a commodity and is therefore in opposition to the

    process of commodification of education. (...) ESIB is opposed to anytuition fees; no matter if they are raised in public, private or forprofitsystems. Tuition fees are a tool of exclusion and hinder free access

  • 8/2/2019 FinStResearcharticleCommodificationofEducation2012 - Copy

    16/20

    16

    to higher education throughout the world. ESIB further believes that Education is a basichuman right and has to be accessible to as many people as possible (ESIB compendium on

    tuition fees 2005: 2).

    4. ConclusionWhat happened to the daemon in the end?The daemon analogy described in the abstract of the article, helped us handling a complextopic. With the help of the analogy, we were able to link two processes and describe them

    almost as one: The substitution of education under economy by reasoning in favour of competiveness

    and efficiency and developments in organisation of the HE sector analogous to markets

    The commodification of knowledge goods and therefor of education and the arising ofan international market for these goods

    In the end, these semantic fields may not be completely linked, as the meanings of them aredifferent (for instance, economization can also lead to more direct control of state entities asdescribed in section one of this paper). On the other hand, the discursive fields seem to behighly interactive. Hyrinen Alesto et al fuses these fields regarding countries favouring market

    governance: The knowledge economy stands for a new socioeconomic order where newtechnologies are in the core of knowledge production and application. In this frame science andtechnology among other social functions are governed with attention put on marketorientation(Hyrinen Alesto et al 2006: 253). In dependence on this statement, we find thelinkage legitimated by two similarities:

    Outcomes of developments regarding both discursive fields from a student point ofview: vast and intransparent control of taught and researched knowledge by structuresof hegemony2

    Reasoning in favour of the individualistic turn as described in section one of thearticle

    Financing models are a tool to regulate in and outputs. So the first question the article comesup with, does CE influence HE financing systems, has to be answered clearly positively asnumerous developments in HE financing show (see f.i. section two of the article). Alsonumerous entities reasoning in favour of commodification and economization as a necessitystate the existence of the daemon (f.i. ERT, OECD etc.). Having a look at the legitimation ofthe reasoning in favour of commodification of education beside the criterion of efficiency itseems to be pretty shakily. F.i. Hayekian philosophers argue that the cause of equity sufferingthe past two decades is the state not being removed far enough from the provision andregulation of education yet (Tooley 2000 in Bridges et al 2003: 143). But their vision anyhow

    2We refer here to a concept of hegemony as defined by Gramsci 2004: 80, Gramsci, Antonio. 2004.Erziehung undBildung.1.Aufl. Argument Verlag, Hamburg

  • 8/2/2019 FinStResearcharticleCommodificationofEducation2012 - Copy

    17/20

    17

    has dark corners that need to be lighted. As for instance Barnett draws a picture of anentrepreneurial university that is a key institution in the development of the networked global

    economy built up on already mentioned critiques of a bureaucratic, state controlled universitywith untenable claim of universality and few connections to the industry. Entrepreneurial in hissense is clearly linked to taking on characteristics of a market (cf. Barnett, Higher education andthe university). Of course his critique is partly eligible but the proposed solution seems to bekind of an out of the frying pan into the fire, from state controlled education to marketcontrolled education approach. Thus Barnett doesnt take into account, neither uprisingcriticism of market driven decisions (see f.i. Bridges et al 2003: 131) nor possible appearance ofinequalities and inequities in a so called network society (as analysed complexly by LucBoltanski and ve Chiapello 1999 (cf. der neue Geist des Kapitalismus, 397 ff).

    Regarding the criterion of efficiency, the present tendencies of implementing market likestructures via financing systems doesnt answer the markets tautology problem as formulatedby Bridges:

    The free market is held to have an almost magical power to generate the best solution toa problem, the best response to a perceived need, at the lowest possible cost. Indeed sostrong is this particular faith that the best solution becomes defined as that producedunder ideal market conditions, with the result that the claim becomes virtuallytautologous (Bridges et al in Education of Philosophy 2003: 131).

    The second question, where and how CE influences higher education financing systems, cannot

    be answered clearly. Generally it can be stated as mentioned before, that CE leads to regulationof taught and research content regarding market analogue criteria. Models of achievement ofthis linkage defer in detail in the countries investigated in the project. But as shown in sectiontwo of the article such developments are detectable. Benefiters of the developments defer aswell, especially when switching between the two discursive fields. Anyway we tried to build upthe article in a way developments in national HE financing systems and international processes,such as Bologna or GATS can be contextualised to CE. For more precise analyses furtherinvestigation into linkages between markets (global/ national), their entrepreneurs and HEfinancing systems and their effects is needed. Therefore HEI and responsible state regulationinstitutions (ministries etc.) are needed to make data on these linkages transparent and survey

    data on their effects (f.i. social dimension). Why and by whom the daemon is created dependson the context that is investigated (national, international, conservative or developingenvironment etc.)

    The last question, what do students think about CE, remains unclear as well. With themethodology we used to answer it some problems appeared. First of all we dont know muchabout correlations between student union representative perceptions and students perception.So conclusions between students perception and student representative perception have to behandled with care. Also the survey questions were not especially designed for answeringquestions regarding CE what resulted in unspecific answers. Anyway it can be stated, that theunion representatives and therefore also the students themselves defer a lot in opinion and

    knowledge on the topic. Partially we do believe in the daemon, partiallywe do neglect it. Further investigation in the student and student

  • 8/2/2019 FinStResearcharticleCommodificationofEducation2012 - Copy

    18/20

    18

    union perception on the topic and their conception and strategies of political action could bevery fruitful.

    The vast development of HE financial systems that lead more or less obviously to marketanalogue organisation of the distribution of knowledge cannot be taken as a developmentthats natural and unchangeable by the students unions of Europe. As representatives ofstudents, obviously one of the most affected group, we can demand some corner stones to betaken into account in the further development of HE financing systems. State and or privateentities (direct or indirect via quasi markets) nor logics of markets and capitalism itselfshouldnt totally control curricula, quality, output and access of and to higher education ontheir own. The allocation of funds is highly political and therefore decision making in that fieldshould be transparent and students should be properly involved in the decision making process,especially when external sources of funding are involved and especially when curricula andoutputs are influenced (cf. ESU compendium on tuition fees 2005,11). In general knowledgeproduced and processed should be handled regarding its characteristics as described in the firstsection of the article and should be made accessible to as many people as possible due to thebenefit of all. This is not to be understood as making the collaboration betweenindustry/economy and HEI more difficult, like protagonists of the individualist turn criticised(see section 1). The question remains, who it is to decide usability, effects and access ofknowledge generated within HEIs and therefore how limited resources are distributed.Students are not to be treated as consumers, but as a part of the HEI and therefore have to beinvolved in organisation of HEI regardless of their financial capacity. Allocation of funds withinand to HEIs should be organised in a way that avoids drastic influence by state or privateentities. Or formulated positively: Curricula, research fields, allocation of funds and handling ofoutputs should be results of a dispute of the stakeholders, embedded in the democraticorganization of HEIs and proper pedagogic relations of teachers and students.

    5. Bibliography3

    Adorno, Theodor W. 2006. Theorie der Halbbildung. 1. Aufl. Suhrkamp Verlag.

    Bakic, Josef, Wolfgang Horvath. 2011. Diesseits und jenseits ntzlicher Bildung published inWessen Bildung?: Beitrge und Positionen zur bildungspolitischen Debatte.Bundesvertretung der sterreichischen HochschlerInnenschaft. Mandelbaum.

    Balzer, Wolfgang. 2003. Wissen und Wissenschaft als Waren. Erkenntniss.

    Barnett, Roland, Paul Standish. 2002. Higher Education and the University. published in "The

    Blackwell Guide to the Philosophy of Education". Wiley Blackwell.

    3 Much of the literature we used for this article we did paraphrase from sources in German language. If quotedsources are available in English or other language too, title is written in braces behind the German title. Pagenumbers refer to the German source though.

  • 8/2/2019 FinStResearcharticleCommodificationofEducation2012 - Copy

    19/20

    19

    Boltanski, Luc, ve Chiapello. 2006. Der neue Geist des Kapitalismus(The New Spirit ofCapitalism). Sonderausgabe. Uvk.

    Bridges, David, Ruth Jonathan. 2002. Education and the Market. Published in " The Blackwell

    Guide to the Philosophy of Education". Wiley Blackwell.

    Bultmann, Torsten, Weitkamp, Rolf. 2008. Mehr Ungleichheit wagen! Elitenfrderung alsDementi der ersten Hochschulreform. Published in: BdWi Studienheft 5: Hochschuleund Demokratie, Marburg.

    ERT. 1994. Education for Europeans. Abgerufen August 19, 2011(http://www.ert.be/key_messages.aspx).

    ESIB. 2005. Compendium on tuition fees. recalled 23.10. 2011.http://www.esib.org/documents/publications/official_publications/tuitionfees

    compendium_2005.pdf

    ESU. 2007. Compendium on tuition fees.

    ESU. 2005. Policy Paper "Commodification of Education. recalled 23.10.2011

    http://www.esib.org/index.php/documents/policypapers/298ppcomm.html

    Geuna, A., Martin, B. 2003. University Research Evaluation and Funding: An international

    comparison, Minerva.

    Gorz, Andre. 2004. Wissen, Wert und Kapital: Zur Kritik der Wissenskonomie (L'immatriel Connaissance, valeur et capital). 3. Aufl. Rotpunktverlag, Zrich.

    Gramsci, Antonio. 2004. Erziehung und Bildung. 1.Aufl. Argument Verlag, Hamburg

    Hyrinen-Alestalo, Marja, Ulla Peltola. 2006. The problem of a market-oriented university. Higher

    Education. Springer

    Himpele, Klemens. 2005. Wohin steuern Studiengebhren das Hochschulsystem?Published in:

    BdWi Studienheft 3: Chancengleichheit qua Geburt?, Marburg.

    HochschlerInnenschaft, Bundesvertretung der sterreichischen. 2011. Wessen Bildung?:Beitrge und Positionen zur bildungspolitischen Debatte. 1. Aufl. Mandelbaum.

    Krautz, Jochen. 2007. Ware Bildung: Schule und Universitt unter dem Diktat der konomie. 1.Aufl. Diederichs.

    Jongbloed, Ben. 2008. Wirkungen aus der Sicht der Hochschulforschung. Published in: Bilanz und

    Perspektiven der leistungsorientierten Mittelverteilung.

    recalled at September 10, 2011

  • 8/2/2019 FinStResearcharticleCommodificationofEducation2012 - Copy

    20/20

    20

    (http://www.che.de/downloads/CHE_AP111_Analyse_Leistungsorientierte_Mittelverteilung.pd

    f)

    Leitner, Karl Heinz et al., 2007. Finanzierungsstruktur von Universitten: Internationale

    Erfahrungen zum Verhltnis zwischen Basisfinanzierung und kompetitiver

    Forschungsfinanzierung. TIP (technology information policy consulting).

    http://www.tip.ac.at/publications/tip%20Studie%20Finanzierungsstruktur.pdf (Zugriff am

    30.12.2011)

    Lepori, B. et al., 2005. Changing patterns of higher education funding: evidence from CHINC

    countries. An interim report for the project Changes in University Incomes: Their impact on

    University Based research and Innovation (CHINC). NIFU STEP, Oslo

    Lichtblau, Pia. 2008. konomisierung der Bildung. Tendenzen, Strategien, Alternativen. 3. Aufl.Mandelbaum.

    Maurer, Sigrid, Lukas Kohl. 2011. Wessen Autonomie? Zur Organisation der HochschulenWessen Bildung?: Beitrge und Positionen zur bildungspolitischen Debatte.Bundesvertretung der sterreichischen HochschlerInnenschaft. Mandelbaum.

    Europe 2020 EU Strategy for smart, sustainable and inclusive growth. Abgerufen August 19,2011a (http://ec.europa.eu/europe2020/index_en.htm).

    The Universal Declaration of Human Rights. recalled August 19, 2011b(http://www.un.org/en/documents/udhr/index.shtml#a26).).

    Seefeld, Katja. 2002. Pillen und Patente | Telepolis. heise online. Abgerufen August 19, 2011(http://www.heise.de/tp/artikel/11/11955/1.html).

    Weingart, Peter. 2008. konomisierung der Wissenschaft. NTM Journal of the History ofScience.

    Yang, Rui. 2003. Globalisation and higher Education Development: a critical analysis.

    International Review of education. Abgerufen September 10, 2011(http://www.springerlink.com/content/g21g44j6h5614624/fulltext.pdf)