92
The Pennsylvania State University The Graduate School College of Health and Human Development EXPLORING BUNDLING STRATEGIES FOR TOTAL REVENUE MANAGEMENT A Dissertation in Hospitality Management by Myungekun Song © 2018 Myungkeun Song Submitted in Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements for the Degree of Doctor of Philosophy August 2018

EXPLORING BUNDLING STRATEGIES FOR TOTAL REVENUE …

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    1

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

The Pennsylvania State University

The Graduate School

College of Health and Human Development

EXPLORING BUNDLING STRATEGIES FOR TOTAL REVENUE

MANAGEMENT

A Dissertation in

Hospitality Management

by

Myungekun Song

© 2018 Myungkeun Song

Submitted in Partial Fulfillment

of the Requirements

for the Degree of

Doctor of Philosophy

August 2018

ii

The dissertation of Myungkeun Song was reviewed and approved* by the following:

Breffni Noone

Associate Professor of Hospitality Management

Dissertation Advisor

Chair of Committee

Anna S. Mattila

Marriott Professor of Lodging Management

Professor-in-Charge Graduate Program

Hubert B. Van Hoof

Professor of Hospitality Management

Lisa E. Bolton

Professor of Marketing

*Signatures are on file in the Graduate School

iii

ABSTRACT

Revenue optimization efforts are centered upon driving revenue from a focal

product offering in the traditional revenue management setting. However, service firms

that apply revenue management usually have multiple ancillary products that have the

potential to make a significant revenue contribution. Therefore, revenue management

practitioners should develop strategies to drive revenue across all revenue streams to

effectively maximize total revenue. This concept, total revenue management, was

introduced in the early 2000’s, but the revenue management literature provides little

guidance in terms of actionable strategies for total revenue management implementation.

To address this gap, this dissertation explores effective bundling strategies for

maximizing total consumer spend at the online point of purchase. Study 1 found that a

mixed-non-leader bundle discount frame was more effective than an integrated mixed-

joint bundle discount frame when the non-leader product was hedonic in nature.

However, when the non-leader product was utilitarian in nature, there was no significant

difference in purchase intentions across the two bundle discount frames. Study 2 suggests

that standardized company-designed bundling may be more effective than customized

self-designed bundling when the non-leader product is hedonic in nature. However, when

the non-leader product is utilitarian in nature, customized self-designed bundling may be

the most effective approach. These findings provide revenue practitioners with firm

guidance on effective bundling practices for total revenue management.

iv

TABLE OF CONTENTS

List of Figures……………………………………………..……………………………vii

List of Tables……………………………………………...……………………………viii

Acknowledgements……………………………………………………………………...ix

CHAPTER 1. INTRODUCTION……………………..…………………………….…..1

CHAPTER 2. LITERATURE REVIEW……………………………………………….6

Overview………………………………………………………………………………...6

2.1 Product and Service Bundling………………………………………………………6

2.2 Bundle Discount Framing…………………………………………………………...8

2.3 Bundle Discount Frame and Ease of Justification………………………………....10

2.4 Consumption Nature and Ease of Justification…………………………………….13

2.5 Ease of Justification, Perceived Savings, and Purchase Intention…………………15

2.6 Customized Bundling……………………………………………………….……...18

2.7 Evaluation Modes………………………………………………………………….20

Summary of Hypotheses……………………………………………………………….23

CHAPTER 3. METHODS AND RESULTS………………………………………….25

Overview….……………………………………………………………………………25

3.1 Study Context……………………………………………………………………...25

3.2 Pre-test……………………………………………………………………………..26

3.2.1 Pre-test 1…………………………………………………………..……………26

3.2.1.1 Pre-test 1 Procedures………………………………………………………..26

3.2.1.2 Pre-test 1 Results……………………………………………………………28

3.2.2 Pre-test 2………………………………………………………………………..29

3.2.2.1 Pre-test 2 Procedures………………………………………………………..29

3.2.2.2 Pre-test 2 Results……………………………………………………………30

3.3 Study 1……………………………………………………………………………..31

v

3.3.1 Procedures………………………………………………………………………31

3.3.2 Measures………………………………………………………………………..32

3.3.3 Results……………………………………………………………………...…...34

3.3.3.1 Sample Characteristics………………………………………………………34

3.3.3.2 Manipulation and Realism Checks……………………………...……….….36

3.3.3.3 Hypotheses Tests……………………………………………………………36

3.3.4 Discussion…………………………………………………………..……..……42

3.4 Study 2……………………………………………………………………….….…43

3.4.1 Procedures…………………………………...……………………………….....43

3.4.2 Measures………………………………..………………………………….…...44

3.4.3 Results………………………………………………………..………………...46

3.4.3.1 Sample Characteristics……………………………………………………...46

3.4.3.2 Manipulation and Realism Checks…………………………………………47

3.4.3.3 Hypotheses Tests……………………………………………………………49

3.4.4 Discussion…………………………………………………………..…………..53

CHAPTER 4. GENERAL DISCUSSION………………………..……………………55

4.1 Theoretical Implications…………………………………………………………...56

4.2 Managerial Implications…………………………………………………………...59

4.3 Limitations and Future Research Directions……………………………………….61

REFERENCES..........................................................................................................…...64

APPENDIX A: Study 1 Stimulus.....……………………………………………...……..75

APPENDIX A-1: Mixed-Non-Leader Frame & Hedonic Non-Leader Product

Condition…………………………………………………………....75

APPENDIX A-2: Mixed-Non-Leader Frame & Utilitarian Non-Leader Product

Condition……………………………………………………….…..76

APPENDIX A-3: Integrated Mixed-Joint & Hedonic Non-Leader Product Condition.77

APPENDIX A-4: Integrated Mixed-Joint & Utilitarian Non-Leader Product

vi

Condition…………………………………………………………..78

APPENDIX B: Study 2 Stimulus………………………………………………………..79

APPENDIX B-1: Company-Designed & Hedonic Non-Leader Product Condition….79

APPENDIX B-2: Company-Designed & Utilitarian Non-Leader Product Condition..80

APPENDIX B-3: Self-Designed Condition....……………..……………………..…...81

vii

LIST OF FIGURES

Figure 1 Conceptual Model for Study 1............................................................................18

Figure 2 Study 1: Mean Ratings for Ease of Justification by Experimental……………..38

Figure 3 Study 1: Mean Ratings for Perceived Savings by Experimental Condition……38

Figure 4 Study 1: Mean Ratings for Willingness to Purchase by Experimental

Condition……………………………………………………………..39

Figure 5 Study 2: Mean Ratings for Ease of Justification……………………………….52

Figure 6 Study 2: Mean Ratings for Willingness to Purchase…………………………...53

viii

LIST OF TABLES

Table 1 Scale Items………………………………………………………………………27

Table 2 Pre-Test 1: Means for Anticipated Price, Attractiveness, and Consumption

Nature by Non-Leader Product……………………………………..29

Table 3 Pre-Test 2: Means for Anticipated Price, Attractiveness, and Consumption

Nature by Non-Leader Product……………………………………..31

Table 4 Study 1: Scale Items…………………………………………………………….33

Table 5 Study 1: Sample Characteristics………………………………………………...35

Table 6 Study 1: Means for Ease of Justification, Perceived Savings, and Willingness to

Purchase by Experimental Condition………………………………….37

Table 7 Study 1: Result of Moderated Serial Mediation Analysis………………………41

Table 8 Study 2: Scale Items…………………………………………………………….46

Table 9 Study 2: Sample Characteristics………………………………………………...48

Table 10 Study 2: Means for Ease of Justification and Willingness to Purchase by

Experimental Condition………………………………………………51

Table 11. Study 2: MANOVA and univariate follow-up results………………………...52

ix

ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS

I would like to express my sincere appreciation to the many people who provided

support and direction toward the completion of this dissertation. This dissertation work

would not have been possible without their contributions and encouragement. First of all,

my deepest gratitude goes to my academic adviser and the committee chair, Dr. Breffni

Noone. Her insightful guidance was invaluable in conducting this dissertation. I

appreciate wholeheartedly, not only for her tremendous academic support, but also for

giving me so many wonderful opportunities. Dr. Noone, I will never forget the time I

spent with you here at Penn State. You made me a better educator as well as a better

researcher. It was truly my honor to have you as my academic adviser. I am so proud to

be your student. I will be missing you very much.

I would also like to express my sincere appreciation to Dr. Mattila, one of my

dissertation committee members. It was my honor to take your classes and work with

you. Also, I can’t thank you enough for all your help whenever I was struggling with my

research works including my dissertation. I sincerely appreciate your insightful guidance

and financial support for my research works. I will be missing you. And, Dr. Van Hoof

and Dr. Bolton, thank you very much for providing many invaluable insights and

suggestions that contributed to this dissertation. I really want to show my sincere respect

to you.

Further, special thanks to Dr. Quadri-Felitti for your endless support including

financial support. I could have not completed this dissertation without your support. Also,

x

I would like to thank all the incredible faculty, staff members, and my friends at School

of Hospitality Management.

Finally, I would like to express my gratitude to my parents and sister for their

support and encouragement. I could not have completed my doctoral study without your

love and faith in me. I love you all so much.

1

CHAPTER 1. INTRODUCTION

Revenue management (RM) is a form of a capacity management in which demand

and supply are managed by manipulating price, time, and space to maximize revenue

(Kimes & Chase, 1998; Kimes & Renaghan, 2011; Kimes & Thompson, 2004, Kimes &

Wirtz, 2015; Song & Noone, 2017). RM is applicable to industries that have a relatively

fixed capacity, perishable inventory, a relatively high fixed, and low variable, cost

structure, and predictable but fluctuating demand (Wirtz & Kimes, 2007). RM has

traditionally been applied in the airline (Rose, 2016), hotel (Kimes, 2016), and rental car

(Li & Pang, 2017) industries. More recently, there has been a movement towards the

application of RM across a number of other tourism-related industries including the

restaurant (Kimes & Beard, 2013), spa (Kimes & Singh, 2009), and theme park (Heo &

Lee, 2009) industries.

Of the three levers of RM – price, time, and space - the focus of this research is

price. Specifically, this research examines potential approaches to driving ancillary

revenue in the context of traditional RM applications. In the traditional RM setting (i.e.,

airlines, hotels, rental car), revenue optimization efforts are centered upon driving

revenue from a focal product offering which is largely utilitarian in nature. For example,

the primary purpose of a seat on a plane is to provide the consumer with transportation

from one destination to another, while the fundamental purpose of a hotel guestroom is to

provide the consumer a place to sleep. However, in addition to a focal product, multiple

ancillary products exist that have the potential to make a significant revenue contribution

(e.g., airline lounge access and checked baggage revenues, hotel food and beverage and

2

spa revenues, and rental car GPS and insurance revenues). Thus, in order to effectively

maximize total revenue, revenue managers need to develop strategies to drive revenue

across all revenue streams. Reflecting this, the concept of total revenue management

(TRM) was introduced into the RM literature in the early 2000’s (Kimes, 2003). TRM

represents a strategic approach to RM wherein the focus is on total revenue optimization

rather than revenue optimization for the focal product alone. However, the RM literature

provides little guidance in terms of actionable strategies and tools for TRM

implementation. The current research seeks to address this gap in the literature by

exploring potential strategies to motivate consumer purchase of ancillary (add-on)

products when purchasing a focal product in the online environment.

Service firms within the traditional RM setting primarily leverage a standardized

bundling approach to drive consumer spend at the online point of purchase. However,

little is known about the impact of bundle discount frames on consumers’ reactions to

standardized bundles, or the potential role of customized bundling in driving revenue

performance. In Study 1, the author explores the effects of two different bundle discount

frames - mixed-non-leader and integrated mixed-joint - on purchase intentions. Within a

mixed-non-leader discount frame, a discount is provided on the add-on (non-leader)

product rather than the focal (leader) product, and the discount amount and the source of

the discount is explicitly identified (e.g., “Get a $10 discount on the airline lounge access

fee when you purchase an airline ticket/airline lounge access package”). In contrast, an

integrated mixed-joint discount frame simply highlights that the discount amount is on

the bundle itself (e.g., “Get a $10 discount when you purchase an airline ticket/airline

lounge access package”) (Gilbride, Guiltinan, & Urbany, 2008). Traditional RM

3

applications typically attach a best available rate (BAR) guarantee to focal products. In

this context, it is not meaningful to employ a bundle discount frame wherein a discount,

beyond the advertised BAR, is given on the focal product (Palamar & Edwards, 2007;

Rohlfs & Kimes, 2007). Thus, of the four bundle discount frames that service firms can

employ to frame bundle discounts (Gilbride et al., 2008), the two frames of interest in this

study are relevant in the traditional RM context. Further, while bundle discount frames

have been extensively studied in the literature (e.g., Guiltinan, 1987; Janiszewski &

Cunha, 2004; Khan and Dhar, 2010; Yadav, 1994, 1995), to the author’s knowledge this

is the first study to examine potential differences in consumer reaction to mixed-non-

leader and integrated mixed-joint frames.

Study 1 also seeks to advance the literature by exploring the mediating effects of

ease of justification and perceived savings on the bundle discount frame-purchase

intentions relationship. Rather than simply comparing differences in purchase intentions

across the two bundle discount frames of interest, the author suggests the underlying

mechanisms that may explain these differences. Finally, Study 1 incorporates

examination of the moderating effect of the consumption nature of non-leader product

within a bundle (utilitarian vs. hedonic) on the bundle discount framing-ease of

justification relationship. Khan and Dhar (2010) examined the effects of the consumption

nature of bundle components on purchase behavior in the context of a cross-category

bundle where the two components in the bundle were equivalent in terms of price and

centrality (i.e., both products were focal in nature). This study extends Khan and Dhar’s

(2010) work by examining the role of consumption nature in the bundle discount frame-

4

ease of justification relationship in the context of a tie-in bundle (i.e., focal and add-on

products).

In Study 2, the author examines the differential effects of company-designed

bundling (i.e., standardized bundling) and self-designed bundling (i.e., customized

bundling) on purchase intentions. For the purpose of this study, company-designed

bundling refers to the practice wherein a company bundles a focal (leader) product with a

single add-on (non-leader) product, and offers this standardized bundle to all consumers.

In contrast, self-designed bundling refers to the practice wherein a company provides the

consumer a choice of two non-leader products (one utilitarian and one hedonic), such that

the consumer can combine the non-leader product of their choice with the leader product

to create a customized bundle. Prior literature suggests that customized bundling will

yield a more positive consumer response than standardized bundling (e.g., Coulter &

Coulter, 2002; Coelho & Henseler, 2012). However, it is proposed that this finding may

not always hold. Rather, drawing on the concept of separate versus joint evaluation

modes, the author seeks to extend the literature, by suggesting that the consumption

nature of the non-leader product in the bundle may influence the effects bundling

(standardized versus customized) on purchase intentions.

From a managerial standpoint, it is anticipated that the insights yielded from this

study will provide revenue managers with firm guidance on effective bundling practices.

In the context of traditional RM applications, revenue managers are tasked with driving

revenue from a range of ancillary products that vary in terms of their consumption nature

(utilitarian vs. hedonic). By exploring the role of ancillary products’ consumption nature

on consumers’ reactions to bundle discount frames and customized bundles, this research

5

provides guidance on the optimal bundle discount frame and customization approach to

match with the ancillary product on offer. In doing so, the goal is to maximize the

likelihood of successfully cross-selling ancillary products and maximize revenue from all

revenue-generating assets within the organization.

This dissertation is organized as follows. In Chapter 2, relevant literature in the

domains of bundling, bundle discount frames, and customization is reviewed. Hypotheses

relating to the roles of ease of justification, perceived savings, and the consumption

nature of non-leaders products in consumers’ behavioral response to bundle discount

frames and customization are presented. In Chapter 3, a description of the research

methodology employed in Study 1 and Study 2, and the empirical results of the studies,

are provided. Finally, in Chapter 4, the theoretical and practical implications of the

findings from Study 1 and Study 2 are discussed, and directions for future research are

identified.

6

CHAPTER 2. LITERATURE REVIEW

Overview

In this chapter, the theoretical framework for the author’s research hypotheses is

presented. First, the role, and types, of bundling for RM are discussed. The author then

outlines the four types of bundle discount frames available to service providers, and

discusses the relevance of two specific frames, mixed-non-leader and integrated mixed-

joint, to traditional RM applications. The literature relating to the potential mediating

roles of ease of justification and perceived savings in the bundle discount frame-purchase

intentions relationship is presented. In addition, the potential moderating role of the

consumption nature of the non-leader product within a bundle on the bundle discount

frame-ease of justification relationship is discussed. Finally, the potential effect of

customized (versus standardized) bundling on purchase intentions is explored, with a

focus on the consumption nature of the non-leader product on consumers’ reaction to

customized bundling.

2.1 Product and Service Bundling

Product or service bundling encompasses the parceling of two or more products

and/or services, usually at a discounted price, and can be effective in driving consumer

spend, and increasing capacity utilization, across a service firm’s multiple revenue

streams (Ng, Wirtz, & Lee, 1999). Bundling can be categorized as pure or mixed (Adams

& Yelles, 1976; Guiltinan, 1987; Schmalensee, 1984). Pure bundling entails selling

products or services only in a bundled form (e.g., all-inclusive hotels and resorts) while

7

mixed bundling, the focus of this study, enables consumers to either to purchase products

and services individually or purchase them together in a bundle (e.g., a hotel guest room

only, dinner only, or guestroom and dinner package). A primary objective of mixed

bundling is to cross-sell products and services (Guiltinan, 1987). It can entice consumers

who are already willing to purchase a focal product (e.g., airline seat) into buying

additional products and/or services (e.g., airline lounge access, checked baggage, travel

insurance, or in-flight meal) that they initially may not have been willing to buy.

Underlying mixed bundling is the concept of consumer surplus (Guiltinan, 1987).

When an individual’s reservation price (i.e., the maximum amount he or she is willing to

pay for a certain product) exceeds the actual price of a certain product, consumer surplus

is created. In contrast, when an individual’s reservation price is less than the actual price

of a certain product, negative utility will be created. Without a bundle, consumers will

only purchase the product whose reservation price exceeds or at least equals to the actual

price. By combining two or more products, marketers expect that consumer surplus from

the high-value product (i.e., reservation price exceeds the actual price of the product) is

transferred to the low-value products (i.e., reservation price is lower than the actual price

of the product) and covers the negative utility. In turn, consumers are more likely to

purchase all products in the bundle. In addition, a price discount, an inherent element of

bundling, increases the change of cross-selling by increasing the consumer surplus from a

high-value product and/or decreasing the negative utility from a low-value product

(Guiltinan, 1987).

8

2.2 Bundle Discount Framing

If we assume that two products, A and B are in a bundled format, four different

bundle discount framings can emerge (Gilbride et al., 2008).

Discount frame 1: Discount on product A

Discount frame 2: Discount on product B

Discount frame 3: Discount on both product A and B

Discount frame 4: Discount on the bundle itself.

Assuming that consumers are already willing to buy product A but not B, A is the leader

product, and B can be considered as the non-leader product. Giving a discount on A

constitutes a mixed-leader frame, and giving a discount on B constitutes a mixed-non-

leader frame. Giving a discount on both A and B represents a segregated mixed-joint

frame, and giving a discount on the bundle itself represents an integrated mixed-joint

frame (Gilbride et al., 2008). Among these four discount frames, only two frames –

mixed-non-leader and integrated mixed-joint frames – may be relevant to traditional RM

applications.

RM requires the use of variable pricing to balance supply and demand (Kimes &

Chase, 1998). During low demand periods, revenue managers use price discounts to

stimulate demand and increase capacity utilization, while during high demand periods,

revenue managers close out lower rates and focus on building average rate from existing

demand. In the hotel industry, for example, a hotel will publish a BAR which represents

the lowest unqualified rate available on any given day based on prevailing market

9

conditions. In other words, if a consumer does not qualify for a special rate such as an

AAA, AARP, government, or corporate rate, they will be quoted the BAR rate (Palamar

& Edwards, 2007). BAR pricing is designed to reduce confusion amongst consumers, and

to guarantee that the consumer is quoted the lowest available rate for products or services

they provide regardless of booking channel (e.g., company direct or third-party

distribution channel) (Rohlfs & Kimes, 2007; Noone & Mattila, 2009). Based on the

principle of BAR pricing, it is unlikely that a service firm would employ a bundling

strategy wherein a further discount, beyond the advertised BAR, is given on the leader

product. Thus, of the four mixed bundle discount frames (mixed-leader, mixed-non-

leader, mixed-joint, and integrated mixed-joint), the mixed-non-leader and integrated

mixed-joint discount frames which do not encompass a discount on the leader product

(e.g., the guest room in a hotel and the airline seat in an airline) are most relevant to

bundling for traditional RM applications.

According to Guiltinan (1987), the consumer surplus created from one product in

a given bundle will readily transfer to other products in the bundle. In other words, in a

two-product bundle, a discount on one product will have the same effect on the bundle

evaluation as an equivalent discount on the other product in the bundle. Thus, it should

not matter which product is discounted as long as a discount amount is equivalent.

However, a number of research studies suggest that discount framing does impact bundle

evaluation (Janiszewski & Cunha, 2004; Gilbride et al., 2008; Yadav, 1994, 1995). For

example, Yadav (1995) in the context of non-durable goods, demonstrated the superiority

of a mixed-leader frame over a mixed-non-leader frame, and suggested the weighted

average model to explain this result (i.e., consumers sequentially evaluate each product in

10

the bundle, starting with the focal product, and tend to anchor the evaluation of the

bundle to their initial evaluation). In contrast, others demonstrated the superiority of the

mixed-non-leader frame over the mixed-leader frame. For example, drawing on the value

function from prospect theory, Janiszewski and Cunha (2004) found, in the context of

non-durable goods, that a mixed-non-leader frame was preferred to a mixed-leader frame

(Tversky & Kahneman, 1991). Other researchers have also investigated consumer

reaction to integrated and segregated bundle discount frames. For example, Gilbride et al.

(2008) used transaction utility theory to explain their findings in relation to the superior

impact of an integrated mixed-joint frame (vs. segregate mixed-joint, and mixed-leader,

frames) on purchase choice (Thaler, 1985). Here, the author seeks to advance the

literature by examining consumer response to two bundle discount frames which hitherto

have not been compared: mixed-non-leader and integrated mixed-joint.

2.3 Bundle Discount Frame and Ease of Justification

The ability to justify a decision has been identified as one of the most important

aspects of consumer decision-making (Bettman. Luce, & Payne, 1998). Since consumers’

purchase decisions are often evaluated by others as well as oneself, the ease with which a

purchase can be justified constitutes an approach goal that affects consumers’ purchase

intention and decision satisfaction (Bettman et al., 1998). In other words, consumers’

decisions such as whether to buy a bundle, and which product among options to select,

are affected by the degree of ease with which they can justify their decision. Here, it is

proposed that, by virtue of enhanced information transparency, consumers will perceive

11

the purchase of a bundle with a mixed-non-leader frame as easier to justify than a bundle

with an integrated mixed-joint frame.

A key difference between mixed-non-leader and integrated mixed-joint frames is

the degree of savings information transparency associated with them. Information

transparency is defined as the degree of availability, accessibility, and visibility of

information (Zhu, 2002). It has been suggested that transparent information aids product

evaluation because useful information is more readily available to the consumer during

the evaluation process (Lynch and Ariely, 2000; Grewal, Hardestry, and Iyer, 2004).

Chaiken, Liberman, and Eagly (1989) advance the Heuristic – Systematic Model (HSM)

of information processing as a framework to understand the role of information

transparency in consumers’ evaluations. According to the HSM, individuals process

information systematically (i.e., comprehensive and analytic information processing

where the individual scrutinizes all information), and/or heuristically (i.e., simple

inferential information processing that includes minimal amount of information and

analysis). The HSM suggests that an individual is likely to employ a less effortful,

heuristic information processing mode as long as a heuristic cue is available. Chaiken et

al. (1989) suggest that information transparency can be a heuristic signal for persuasive

and credible information. Prior research supports the notion that information transparency

can influence message persuasiveness. For example, Lynch and Ariely (2000)

demonstrated, in the context of online shopping, that more transparent information can

lead to higher consumer welfare. In the same context, Grewal et al. (2004) demonstrated

that relatively more transparent price information can mitigate the negative effect of price

discrimination on perceptions of trust, price fairness, and repurchase intentions. Miao and

12

Mattila (2007) demonstrated that consumers feel more confident when evaluating

products when they have access to highly transparent information than when they have

access to information that is low in transparency. Moreover, Tanford, Baloglu, & Erdem

(2012) suggest that the benefits associated with transparent information are most salient

when the information is related to benefits such as a discount. In sum, these findings

suggest that information transparency, particularly in relation to saving information, is

positively associated with consumer’s evaluation of a product.

Here, it is proposed that the greater information transparency associated with a

mixed-non-leader frame (vs. integrated mixed-joint frame) will facilitate consumers’

evaluations of the discount given to bundle by reducing the cognitive effort required for

evaluation. With a mixed-non-leader frame information regarding the amount of the

discount and the source of discount is explicitly provided to consumers, while with an

integrated mixed-joint frame, the only information consumers are provided is the amount

of the discount in relation to the bundle as a whole. Drawing on the notion that

information transparency can provide a heuristic signal for persuasive and credible

information (Chaiken et al., 1989), it is suggested that the greater information

transparency associated with a mixed-non-leader frame (vs. integrated mixed-joint

frame), will enable consumers to more easily justify the purchase of a bundle. Further, it

is expected that the effect of bundle discount frame on ease of justification will be

moderated by consumption nature of the non-leader product.

13

2.4 Consumption Nature and Ease of Justification

The literature distinguishes two types of consumption value: utilitarian and

hedonic. Utilitarian consumption value is related to rationally-oriented benefit, practical

functionality, and instrumentality. In contrast, hedonic consumption value is related to

affective and sensory gratification, fun, and entertainment (e.g., Babin, Darden, &

Griffin, 1994; Batra & Ahtola, 1990; Drolet & Williams, 2007; Lim & Ang, 2008;

Okada, 2005; Voss, Spangenber, & Grohmann, 2003). Therefore, hedonic consumption

represents relatively more guilt-inducing consumption than utilitarian consumption

(Okada, 2005). Utilitarian consumption is more closely related to necessary choice, while

hedonic consumption is more closely related to discretionary choice (Okada, 2005).

Moreover, the outcome of utilitarian consumption is easier to quantify because it is

related to a task and functional outcome, whereas the outcome of hedonic consumption is

more difficult to quantify because it is related to a personal and experiential outcome

(Okada, 2005).

Because of the characteristics of hedonic consumption – guilt-inducing,

discretionary consumption with outcomes that are difficult to quantify – it is more

difficult to justify hedonic consumption than utilitarian consumption (Hsee, 1996; Khan

& Dhar, 2010; Okada, 2005). Consequently, consumers typically seek additional reasons

to justify hedonic consumption. For example, Kivetz and Simonson (2002) suggest that

the degree of effort that a consumer has to exert to obtain a hedonic product is positively

related to the perceived right to engage in hedonic consumption. Associating charity

donations with hedonic consumption can also help to justify that consumption

(Strahilevitz & Myers, 1998). Khan and Dhar (2010) suggest the use of a price discount

14

as a means of helping consumers to justify hedonic consumption in the context of cross-

category bundling. They define a heterogeneous bundle as the combination of two

products that differ in consumption nature (i.e., one utilitarian and one hedonic product)

and a homogeneous bundle as the combination of two products with a similar

consumption nature (i.e., both products are either utilitarian or hedonic). They found, in

the context of heterogeneous bundles, that a discount on the hedonic product led to higher

purchase intentions than a discount on the utilitarian product. The price discount on the

hedonic product reduced the difficulty in justifying hedonic consumption. Giving a

discount on the utilitarian product, on the other hand, did nothing to enable the consumer

to justify consumption of the hedonic product in the bundle, and therefore was less

effective in increasing purchase intention for the bundle. In the case of a homogeneous

bundle, giving a discount on one or other of the products in the bundle did not have a

significant effect on ease of justification.

As previously noted, the focal or leader product in the context of traditional RM

applications is considered as largely utilitarian in nature because it provides functional

and necessary value (e.g., airline seat – transportation from the origin to the destination).

Therefore, when bundled with a non-leader product that is relatively hedonic in nature,

the bundle will be a heterogeneous bundle. In contrast, when the leader product is

bundled with a non-leader product that is relatively utilitarian in nature, the bundle will

be a homogeneous utilitarian bundle. In the case of a heterogeneous bundle (i.e., the non-

leader product is largely hedonic), a mixed-non-leader frame explicitly identifies that the

discount is on the non-leader product (e.g., $10 discount on airline lounge access). In

contrast, an integrated mixed-joint frame does not clearly state where discount comes

15

from (e.g., $10 discount on the package). In line with Khan and Dhar (2010), the author

expects that a mixed-non-leader frame will lead to higher ratings of ease of justification

than integrated mixed-joint frame when the non-leader product is hedonic. Further, given

that Khan and Dhar (2010) demonstrated that discounted product type (a discount on the

leader vs. a discount on the non-leader) does not have a differential effect on consumers’

perceptions of ease of justification for homogeneous bundles, the author proposes that the

bundle discount frame (mixed-non-leader frame vs. integrated mixed-joint frame) will

not have a significant impact on ease of justification when a non-leader product is

utilitarian.

H1: Consumption nature will moderate the relationship between bundle discount

frame and ease of justification. When the non-leader product is hedonic in nature,

a mixed-non-leader frame will lead to higher ratings for ease of justification than

an integrated mixed-joint frame. However, this gap in ease of justification ratings

between bundle discount frames (mixed-non-leader vs. integrated mixed-joint)

will not be as pronounced when the non-leader product is utilitarian in nature.

2.5 Ease of Justification, Perceived Savings, and Purchase Intention

Consumers, by virtue of their limited cognitive resources, generally desire to

minimize cognitive effort during decision making (March, 1978; Simon, 1955). Thus,

they tend to positively react to environments in which they can easily justify a given

decision (Bettman et al., 1998). Drawing on the concept of confirmation bias, it is

16

suggested here that the ease with which consumers can justify a product bundle will

positively impact their perceptions of the savings associated with that bundle.

Research in the domain of confirmation bias suggests that it is difficult to alter

consumers’ initial impressions about a given deal (e.g., Campbell & Warren, 2014;

Chernev, 2001; Klayman, 1995; Nakayama & Sutcliffe, 2005; Nickerson, 1998; Yin,

Mitra, & Zhang, 2016). Confirmation bias is defined as an individual’s tendency to seek,

and focus relatively more on, information that he thinks is supportive of his existing

beliefs. Individuals do not treat evidence supporting and opposing their existing beliefs

equally (Klayman, 1995). They either seek only supporting evidence, overweighting this

supporting evidence, or distort opposing evidence (Nickerson, 1998). This is likely due to

the fact that individuals are fundamentally limited to thinking of only one thing at a time,

and, once they focus on a particular hypothesis or belief, they continue to do so (Doherty

& Mynatt, 1986). Therefore, they collect information and evidence that can support their

beliefs instead of alternative beliefs (Doherty & Mynatt, 1986). The idea of confirmation

bias has been widely demonstrated in the literature. For example, Chernev (2001)

demonstrated that consumers evaluate common features in a manner that supports their

existing preferences. In the context of a choice task, positive common features were used

as evidence that supported already established preference. In contrast, negative common

features were discounted as evidence that opposed the established preference. In addition,

Yin et al. (2016) suggested confirmation bias as a theory that reconciles contradicting

findings in the context of consumer reactions to online reviews. They found that when

consumers’ initial impressions about a product were positive, the effect of positive

reviews on consumers’ subsequent evaluations of that product was more salient than the

17

effect of negative reviews. In contrast, when consumers’ initial impressions about a

product were negative, the effect of negative reviews on consumers’ subsequent

evaluation of that product was more salient than the effect of positive reviews.

Based on these findings, the author suggests that the initial impression that

consumers form about a deal, as a function of how easy they find it to justify the deal,

will affect their subsequent evaluation of the deal. If consumers perceive a deal as easy to

justify, they will perceive it as a fairly good deal. Subsequently, they will process

additional aspects of the deal, in particular the perceived savings associated with the deal,

in a manner that supports their initial belief about the deal. In other words, ease of

justification will be positively associated with the perceived savings associated with a

deal. Further, in line with previous research (e.g., Gonzalez, Esteva, Roggeveen, &

Grewal, 2016; Gupta & Cooper, 1992), the author expects that perceived savings will

positively affect willingness to purchase.

In sum, the author proposes that when the non-leader product within a bundle is

hedonic in nature, the higher ease of justification associated with a mixed-non-leader

frame (vs. an integrated mixed-joint) will drive higher perceptions of savings. This will

eventually yield a greater impact on consumers’ willingness to purchase for a mixed-non-

leader frame (vs. an integrated mixed-joint). In the case of a utilitarian non-leader

product, an insignificant difference in ease of justification between a mixed-non-leader

frame and an integrated mixed-joint frame will also lead to insignificant differences in

perceived savings and willingness to purchase between these two frames.

18

H2: There will be an indirect effect of bundle discount frame on willingness to

purchase through ease of justification and perceived savings. The serial

mediation effects will be more salient when the consumption nature of the non-

leader product in the bundle is hedonic (vs. utilitarian).

See Figure 1 for the conceptual model for Study 1.

Figure 1. Conceptual Model for Study 1

2.6 Customized Bundling

Over the past number of decades, there has been a growing recognition among

scholars and practitioners that product and service differentiation represents a source of

competitive advantage (Coelho & Henseler, 2012). One form of differentiation,

customization, represents the degree to which the firm’s offering is tailored to meet

heterogeneous consumers’ needs (Anderson, Fornell, & Rust, 1997), with the core goal of

Bundle

Discount Frame

Ease of

Justification

Perceived

Savings

Willingness

to Purchase

Consumption

Nature

19

customization being to design products and services that optimally satisfy the needs of a

given target market (Coelho & Henseler, 2012).

Several researchers have demonstrated the positive effects of customization on

consumer behavior. For example, Franke and his colleagues (2009) demonstrated that

product customization results in significantly higher purchase intentions, and a more

favorable attitude toward a given product than standard products because customization

more closely fits consumers’ preferences. In addition, Coelho and Henseler (2012)

showed that customization increases consumers’ perceived service quality, satisfaction,

and loyalty toward a service provider. Moreover, they demonstrated that customization

increases consumers’ trust toward providers, as customization represents a company’s

effort to reduce consumers’ uncertainty regarding a given product, and better satisfy

consumers’ heterogeneous needs. In a similar vein, Coulter and Coulter (2002) identified

seven significant predictors of trust, and demonstrated that customization was one of the

most powerful and durable builders of trust among the seven identified predictors.

Together, these findings suggest that consumers, in the context of product bundling, may

prefer customized bundles over standardized bundles. Based on the author’s expectation

of the general superiority of a mixed-non-leader bundle discount frame over an integrated

mixed-joint frame, the author focuses solely on a mixed-non-leader frame in the

following examination of customized (vs. standardized) bundling.

In the context of bundling, a service firm can simply choose and offer a single

non-leader product to cross-sell at the point of purchase with the leader product,

regardless of individual consumer’s needs. This represents a company-designed, or

standardized, bundle. In contrast, a service firm can provide a list of available non-leader

20

products from which consumers can choose a product to bundle with the leader product.

This represents a self-designed, or self-customized, bundle. In the case of self-designed

bundles, consumers participate in the bundle design process because they actually define

the elements of their bundled product. Prior research has demonstrated a positive

association between consumer participation and perceived control (e.g., Bateson, 1985;

Chan, Yim, and & Lam, 2010; Dabholkar, 2015), with perceived control, in turn,

positively influencing consumers’ evaluations of service experiences (Hui & Bateson,

1991; Noone, 2008; Noone, Wirtz, & Kimes, 2010). These findings suggest that a self-

designed bundle will be preferred over a company-designed bundle. However, the author

suggests that a self-designed bundle may not always be perceived as superior. Rather,

drawing on the concept of evaluation modes, it is proposed that the utilitarian versus

hedonic consumption value associated with the non-leader product in a bundle will

influence consumers’ reactions to self-designed (vs. company-designed) bundling.

2.7 Evaluation Modes

Evaluation mode refers to the distinction between evaluating a product in

isolation (i.e., separate evaluation mode) and evaluating it in the context of one or more

alternatives (i.e., joint evaluation mode) (Krüger, Mata, & Imhels, 2014). According to

evaluative theory, any evaluation represents one of these two modes (Hsee & Zhang,

2010). The situation wherein the consumer is presented a company-designed bundle,

comprising of a leader product and a single non-leader product, represents a separate

evaluation mode (i.e., the consumer has to evaluate only one non-leader product). In

21

contrast, with a self-designed bundle, consumers will be presented with multiple non-

leader products and must decide which product amongst those available they want to

include in their bundle. This situation represents a joint evaluation mode (i.e., the

consumer has to evaluate multiple non-leader products), where the non-leader products

will either be more utilitarian (e.g., travel insurance) or hedonic (e.g., airline lounge

access) in nature.

As previously mentioned, consumers find it relatively difficult to justify hedonic

consumption (vs. utilitarian consumption) because hedonic consumption is relatively

more guilt-inducing, discretionary, and its outcomes are more difficult to quantify, than

utilitarian consumption (Hsee, 1996; Khan & Dhar, 2010; Okada, 2005). Furthermore,

Okada (2005) demonstrated that consumers prefer hedonic consumption when it is

separately evaluated from, rather than jointly evaluated with, utilitarian consumption. In

other words, consumers find it more difficult to justify their hedonic consumption when it

is jointly evaluated with utilitarian consumption, which is relatively easy to justify, than

when hedonic consumption is evaluated alone. This is due to the contrast effect.

Consumers’ perceptions of an object are influenced by other objects in a comparison set.

For example, Thornton and Moore (1993) demonstrated that self-ratings of attractiveness

by men and women were influenced by the level of attractiveness of same-sex others in a

comparison set. When men and women were exposed to a highly attractive same-sex

person, their self-attractiveness ratings were lower than the self-attractiveness ratings of

those who were not. The high attractiveness of others highlighted the relatively lower

attractiveness of the individual when jointly evaluated. In a similar vein, Thornton and

Maurice (1997) demonstrated that women who were exposed to photos of models

22

typifying idealized thin physiques indicated lower self-esteem and higher self-

consciousness, social physique anxiety, and body dissatisfaction than women who were

not exposed to any photo. These findings suggest that, when consumers jointly evaluate

hedonic and utilitarian non-leader products during self-customization, the characteristics

of the relatively more utilitarian product will highlight the characteristics of the hedonic

non-leader products (i.e., discretionary, guilt-inducing, with difficult to quantify

outcomes) due to the contrast effect (Thornton & Moore, 1993). Thus, it is proposed that

consumers will be more likely to find it easier to justify the purchase of a self-customized

bundle that contains a utilitarian non-leader product rather than one with a hedonic non-

leader product. Consequently, they will be more willing to purchase a self-customized

bundle with a utilitarian non-leader product than one with a hedonic non-leader product.

In contrast, it is expected that, in a separate evaluation mode (company-designed

bundle), consumers will not demonstrate a preference for a utilitarian non-leader product

over a hedonic non-leader product. In the context of a separate evaluation mode, the

consumer has little information about other non-leader products that are available to

them, or even the existence of other options. Consumers construct justifications for the

decisions that they are motivated to make (Kunda, 1990). Thus, in the absence of an

explicit comparison against utilitarian non-leader products in the separate evaluation

mode, it is relatively easy for the consumer to justify purchasing a hedonic non-leader

product. Consequently, it is proposed that there will be no significant difference in ease

of justification across hedonic and utilitarian non-leader product bundles in a separate

evaluation mode. By extension, it is expected that willingness to purchase ratings will not

23

be significantly different between bundles with a hedonic non-leader product and those

with a utilitarian non-leader product. Hence, it is hypothesized:

H3a: For self-designed bundles, a bundle with a utilitarian non-leader product will

yield significantly higher ease of justification ratings than a bundle with a hedonic

non-leader product.

H3b: For company-designed bundles, there will be no significant difference in

ease of justification ratings between a bundle with a utilitarian non-leader product

and a bundle with a hedonic non-leader product.

H4a: For self-designed bundles, consumers will be more inclined to purchase a

bundle with a utilitarian non-leader product.

H4b: For company-designed bundles, there will be no significant difference in

willingness to purchase ratings between a bundle with a utilitarian non-leader

product and a bundle with a hedonic non-leader product.

Summary of Hypotheses

In this chapter, a number of hypotheses were presented regarding the nature of the

relationship between types of bundle discount frames (mixed-non-leader and integrated

mixed-joint) and consumers’ willingness to purchase. Based on the lower cognitive effort

associated with processing transparent (vs. non-transparent) information, it was proposed

that the purchase of a bundle with a mixed-non-leader frame will be perceived as easier

to justify than the purchase of a bundle with an integrated mixed-joint frame when the

24

non-leader product is hedonic nature. This gap is not expected to be significant when the

non-leader product is utilitarian in nature. In addition, based on confirmation bias theory,

and findings in the previous literature in relation to the positive relationship between

perceived savings and willingness to purchase, the author expects the indirect effect of

the type of bundle discount frame on willingness to purchase through ease of justification

and perceived savings will be more salient when the non-leader product is hedonic

nature.

In addition, two hypotheses were presented regarding the effect of bundle type

(self-designed vs. company-designed) on ease of justification and willingness to purchase

depending upon the consumption nature of the non-leader product in the bundle. Drawing

on the concept of evaluation mode, it was proposed that there would be no significant

difference in ease of justification and willingness to purchase ratings between company-

designed bundles that contain a hedonic non-leader product and those that contain a

utilitarian non-leader product. However, in the case of a self-designed bundle, it was

proposed that the consumer will find it significantly easier to justify the purchase of a

bundle with a utilitarian non-leader product than one with a hedonic non-leader product,

and consequently, willingness to purchase ratings will be higher for a bundle with a

utilitarian non-leader product.

25

CHAPTER 3. METHODS AND RESULTS

Overview

The current research is composed of two studies. Study 1 tests H1 and H2 by

examining a) the moderating role of the consumption nature of the non-leader product in

a bundle on the relationship between bundle discount frames (mixed-non-leader vs.

integrated mixed-joint) and ease of justification and b) the serial mediating role of ease of

justification and perceived savings on the relationship between bundle discount frames

and willingness to purchase. Study 2 tests H3 and H4 by examining the effect of bundle

type (self-designed vs. company-designed), and the consumption nature of the non-leader

product in a bundle, on ease of justification and purchase intentions. In the following

sections, the author describes the pre-tests conducted in advance of Studies 1 and 2,

followed by descriptions of the design of the studies including the stimuli, procedures and

measures employed, and the results of the hypotheses tests.

3.1 Study Context

The airline industry, which represents a traditional application of RM, was

selected as the context for this research. The focal product, a seat on an airplane, is

largely utilitarian in nature, thus fitting the examination of the bundle discount frames of

interest in this research. Additionally, the airline industry has multiple ancillary revenue

sources, that can be classified as relatively more hedonic (e.g., airline lounge access and

in-flight entertainment) or utilitarian (e.g., checked baggage and travel insurance) in

nature, allowing for the examination of the role of the consumption nature of the non-

26

leader product within a given bundle on consumer reaction to different types of bundle

discount frames, and customized (vs. standardized) bundles.

3.2 Pre-tests

Before Study 1 and Study 2 were conducted, the author conducted two pre-tests to

identify appropriate and comparable hedonic and utilitarian non-leader products in terms

of anticipated price and perceived attractiveness. Anticipated price was measured because

it has been widely demonstrated that price of a product affects consumers’ value and

quality perceptions and their purchase intention (e.g., Zeithmal, 1988). Perceived

attractiveness was also measured as it has been shown that the attractiveness of a product

may influence the ease with which consumers can justify product choice (Khan & Dhar,

2010), and approach behaviors (Bloch, 1995; Crilly, Moultrie, & Clarkson, 2004).

3.2.1 Pre-test 1

3.2.1.1 Pre-test 1 Procedures

The author included a total of seven non-leader products – checked-baggage,

airline lounge access, a seat with extended leg-room, travel insurance, in-flight

entertainment, a light-meal package, and on-board dining – in Pre-test 1. Participants

were randomly assigned to one of the seven non-leader products. In each condition,

participants were presented with a description, and a photograph, of a non-leader product,

and they were asked to rate the hedonic and utilitarian consumption nature of that product

27

using a single product, 7-point bipolar scale anchored by primarily utilitarian and

primarily hedonic (Khan & Dhar, 2010). Prior to completing this scale, participants were

provided with definitions of utilitarian (“a product is purchased for functional,

instrumental, and practical purposes) and hedonic (“a product is purchased for fun,

enjoyable experience, and entertainment purpose”) products. Participants were also asked

to specify the price they would anticipate paying for the product by using a sliding-scale

from $20 to $70. This price range was based on online search of major U.S. airlines’

website conducted in November 2017. Finally, participants were asked to rate the

attractiveness of the non-leader products using a 5-item, 7-point Likert scale anchored by

strongly disagree and strongly agree (Khan & Dhar, 2010; Cronbach’s α = 0.83). See

Table 1 for all scale items. Participants were recruited using Amazon Mechanical-Turk.

Table 1. Scale Products

Hedonic and utilitarian consumption nature (Khan and Dahr, 2010)

This checked-baggage service (the other six products) is ----- primarily utilitarian ~ primarily hedonic

Anticipated price

Please, rate your anticipated price for this checked-baggage service (the other six products) by using the

price scale from $20 to $70

Attractiveness

This checked-baggage service (the other six products) is attractive

This checked-baggage service (the other six products) can considerably improve the quality of my travel

experience.

Many other customers want to buy this checked-baggage service (the other six products).

This checked-baggage service (the other six products) fills a real need for me.

This checked-baggage service (the other six products) can give me real value

28

3.2.1.2 Pre-test 1 Results

A total of 70 individuals who passed simple attention checks were included in the

analyses, yielding an equal number of participants in each condition (n = 10 for each of

all seven conditions). The mean ratings for anticipated price, attractiveness, and

consumption nature by non-leader product are reported in Table 2. In terms of anticipated

price and attractiveness, four products – airline lounge access, on-board dining, checked-

baggage, and travel insurance – grouped together (Anticipated price: Mairline lounge access =

$32.47, Mon-board dining = $30.91, Mchecked-baggage = $31.00, Mtravel insurance = $34.53, p>0.4;

Attractiveness: Mairline lounge access = 4.57, Mon-board dining = 4.99, Mchecked-baggage = 4.55, Mtravel

insurance = 4.93, p>0.2). Another two products – a seat with extended leg-room and in-

flight entertainment – emerged as comparable on anticipated price and attractiveness

ratings (Anticipated price: Ma seat with extra legroom = $23.93, Min-flight entertainment =$21.53,

p>0.5; Attractiveness: Ma seat with extra legroom = 4.99, Min-flight entertainment = 5.34, p>0.1). The

final product - a light meal package - was rated significantly lower than the other six

products in terms of anticipated price (Mlight meal package = $14.04, p<0.05). Therefore, this

product was excluded from the further analysis.

In terms of the consumption nature of the products, two products among the set of

four comparable products – airline lounge access and on-board dining – were perceived

as relatively hedonic in nature (Mairline lounge access = 5.67, Mon-board dining = 5.00), and the

other two products – checked-baggage and travel insurance – were perceived as relatively

utilitarian in nature (Mchecked-baggage = 2.35, Mtravel insurance = 2.09). Both the seat with

extended leg-room and in-flight entertainment were perceived as relatively hedonic in

nature (Ma seat with extra legroom = 5.00, Min-flight entertainment =5.72). As a result, the four products

29

that were comparable in terms of anticipated price and attractiveness were selected for

further investigation in the second pre-test. Specifically, airline lounge access and on-

board dining were selected to represent products that are largely hedonic in nature, and

checked-baggage and travel insurance were selected to represent products that are largely

utilitarian in nature.

Table 2. Pre-Test 1: Means for Anticipated Price, Attractiveness, and Consumption

Nature by Non-Leader Product

Non-Leader Products

Means

Anticipated

Price Attractiveness

Consumption

Nature

Airline lounge access $32.47 4.57 5.67

On-board dining $30.91 4.99 5.00

Checked-baggage $31.00 4.55 2.35

Travel insurance $34.53 4.93 2.09

Light meal package $14.04 4.93 4.30

Extended-legroom $23.93 4.99 5.00

In-flight entertainment $21.53 5.34 5.72

3.2.2 Pre-test 2

3.2.2.1 Pre-test 2 Procedures

Pre-test 2 was conducted to ensure that the findings in relation to the four non-

leader products selected in Pre-test 1 held across a different sample of consumers. As

with Pre-test 1, participants were recruited using Amazon Mechanical-Turk, and were

randomly assigned to one of four non-leader products. The procedure and scales

employed in Pre-test 2 were identical to those used in Pre-test 1. The attractiveness scale

was reliable (Cronbach’s α = 0.89; Khan & Dhar, 2010).

30

3.2.2.2 Pre-test 2 Results

A total of 136 participants who passed simple attention checks were included in

the analysis, yielding an equal number of participants in each condition (n = 34 for each

of all four conditions). The mean ratings for anticipated price, attractiveness, and

consumption nature by non-leader product are reported in Table 3. In terms of anticipated

price, three products – airline lounge access, checked-baggage, and travel insurance –

were comparable (Mairline lounge access = $40.65, Mchecked-baggage = $35.74, and Mtravel insurance =

$42.84, p>0.1). The on-board dining was excluded from further analysis because the

anticipated price was not comparable with airline lounge access (Mon-board dining = $29.71,

Mairline lounge access = $40.65, p<0.05) and travel insurance (Mon-board dining = $29.71, Mairline

lounge access = $42.84, p<0.01). In terms of attractiveness, the three selected products were

comparable (Mairline lounge access = 4.62, Mchecked-baggage = 4.79, Mtravel insurance = 4.27, p>0.3).

In terms of the consumption nature of the products, airline lounge access was perceived

as significantly more hedonic than the other two products (Mairline lounge access = 6.16,

Mchecked-baggage = 1.97, p<0.0001; Mairline lounge access = 6.16, Mtravel insurance = 2.03, p<0.0001).

Based on the results of Pre-test 2, the author selected airline lounge access as the hedonic

non-leader product and checked-baggage and travel insurance as the utilitarian non-leader

product for Study 1.

31

Table 3. Pre-Test 2: Means for Anticipated Price, Attractiveness, and Consumption

Nature by Non-Leader Product

Non-Leader Products

Means

Anticipated Price Attractiveness

Consumption

Nature

Airline lounge access $40.65 4.62 6.16

Checked baggage $35.74 4.79 1.97

Travel insurance $42.84 4.27 2.03

On-board dining $29.71 5.07 5.55

3.3 Study 1

3.3.1 Procedures

To test H1 and H2, the author employed a 2 (bundle discount frame: mixed-

non-leader vs. integrated mixed-joint) x 2 (consumption nature of the non-leader product:

hedonic vs. utilitarian) between-subject experimental design. Participants were randomly

assigned to one of the four conditions. All participants were asked to imagine that they

planned to travel to a city located in the U.S. They were told that they decided to

purchase a round trip ticket, that the price of this round-trip ticket was $250, and that the

price included a regular economy seat for their flights to, and back from, the destination

city, as well as one carry-on personal product that could fit under the seat. Finally, they

were told that the airline company provided additional services for extra charges. For

participants who were assigned to the utilitarian (hedonic) condition, checked baggage

(airline lounge access) was shown as the non-leader product in the bundle. Participants

were informed that the regular price of the non-leader products was $35. This price was

based on market research, as well as the anticipated prices reported by participants in Pre-

tests 1 and 2. Participants who were assigned to the mixed-non-leader frame condition

(the integrated mixed-joint frame condition) were informed that they would receive a $10

32

discount on the $35 value of non-leader product (a $10 discount on the $285 total

package cost) if they purchased the package. See the stimuli in Appendix A. After

reading their assigned scenario, participants completed a questionnaire that contained

items used as manipulation checks, measures for the key variables, a realism check, and

demographic questions.

3.3.2 Measures

Willingness to purchase was measured using a 3-item, 7-point Likert scale

anchored by strongly disagree and strongly agree (Maxwell, 2002; Cronbach’s α = 0.97).

A 3-item, 7-point Likert scale anchored by strongly disagree and strongly agree was used

to measure ease of justification (Heitman et al., 2007; Cronbach’s α = 0.83). Perceived

savings were measured using a 2-item, 7-point Likert scale anchored by strongly disagree

and strongly agree (Gonzalez et al., 2016; r=0.75).

Level of complementarity was included as a control variable in the analyses.

Complementarity implies that the reservation price for one product is increased if the

other is purchased (Guiltinan, 1987). Thus, to control for the potential effects of

differences in the perceived level of complementarity of products across bundles on the

outcome variables of interested in the study, level of complementarity was measured

using a 3-item, 7-point Likert scale anchored by strongly disagree and strongly agree was

used (Sheng, Parker, & Nakamoto, 2007; Cronbach’s α =0.73).

The author used a single item, 7-point bipolar scale anchored by primarily

utilitarian (1) and primarily hedonic (7) to ensure that the manipulation for consumption

33

nature of the non-leader product was successful (Khan & Dhar, 2010). As in the pre-tests,

definitions of utilitarian and hedonic products were provided. In addition, to ensure that

the manipulation for bundle discount framing was successful, participants were asked to

indicate which product in the bundle was discounted. Finally, a single item measure was

used to assess the realism of the scenarios presented to the study’s participants (7-point

Likert scale, anchored by highly unrealistic and highly realistic). See Table 4 for all scale

products.

Table 4. Study 1: Scale Items

Willingness to purchase (Maxwell, 2002)

The likelihood of me buying this airline ticket/checked baggage package (airline ticket/airline lounge

access package) is

My willingness to buying this airline ticket/checked baggage package (airline ticket/airline lounge access

package) is

The probability that I would consider buying this airline ticket/checked baggage package (airline

ticket/airline lounge access package) is

Perceived Savings (Gonzalez et al., 2016)

I would be saving a lot of money if I purchase this airline ticket/checked baggage package (airline

ticket/airline lounge access package)

This airline is selling airline ticket/checked baggage package (airline ticket/airline lounge access

package) at a considerable discount

Ease of justification (Heitmann et al., 2007)

I think it would be easy to justify buying this airline ticket/checked baggage package (airline

ticket/airline lounge access package)

I am able to see at first sight that this airline ticket/checked baggage package (airline ticket/airline lounge

access package) is attractive

In order to make a purchase decision for this airline ticket/checked baggage package (airline

ticket/airline lounge access package), it was not necessary to make any difficult trade-offs

Level of Complementarity (Sheng et al., 2007)

Airline ticket and checked baggage (airline lounge access) are highly complementary

Airline ticket checked baggage (airline lounge access) are very likely to be used together

Hedonic and utilitarian consumption nature (Khan and Dahr, 2010)

The checked baggage (airline lounge access) is ----- primarily utilitarian ~ primarily hedonic

Realism check

The situation described in the scenario was realistic.

34

3.3.3 Results

3.3.3.1 Sample Characteristics

A total of 200 participants were recruited via a 3rd party data collection

company, and 178 individuals who passed the attention checks were retained for the

analysis, yielding an approximately equal number of participants in each experimental

condition (n=44 for the mixed-non-leader/hedonic, and the mixed-non-leader/utilitarian

conditions; n=45 for the integrated mixed-joint/hedonic, and the integrated mixed-

joint/utilitarian conditions). Approximately, 47% (n=84) of the participants were male.

The average age of the participants was 44.49. The majority of participants had a college

degree or higher education (88.2%; n=157) and a full-time job (73.6%; n=131), with

79.2% (n=141) having a household income higher than $50,000. The majority of

participants (35.4%; n=63) had taken a flight 3 or 4 times for trip in the 24 months prior

to participating in the survey, with a further 44.3% (n=79) taking a flight more than 4

times. See Table 5 for the full characteristics of the sample.

35

Table 5. Study 1: Sample Characteristics

a last 24 months

Variable N %

Gender

Male 84 47.2

Female 94 52.8

Age

34 or under 58 32.58

35 – 50

51 – 69

70 or older

56

60

4

31.46

33.71

2.25

Education

Some High school or less 1 0.6

High School 20 11.2

College 101 56.7

Graduate school 56 31.5

Employment

Full-time 131 73.6

Part-time 15 8.4

Not currently employed 7 3.9

Retired 20 11.2

Student 3 1.7

Other 2 1.1

Household income

Less than $25,000 11 6.2

$25,000 to $49,999 26 14.6

$50,000 to $74,999 24 13.5

$75,000 to $99,999 33 18.5

$100,000 to $124,999 26 14.6

$125,000 to $ 149,999 22 12.4

$150,000 or more 36 20.2

Frequency of taking a flight for tripsa

1-2 times 36 20.2

3-4 times 63 35.4

5-6 times 20 11.2

More than 6 times 59 33.1

36

3.3.3.2 Manipulation and Realism Checks

For the consumption nature of the non-leader product manipulation, the

ratings were significantly higher in the hedonic condition than in the utilitarian condition

(Mhedonic = 5.02, Mutilitarian = 3.45, p<0.001). Thus, the manipulation for the consumption

nature of the non-leader product was successful. In terms of the bundle discount framing

manipulation, all participants in the mixed-non-leader frame condition correctly indicated

that the $10 discount was given on the non-leader product, and all participants in the

integrated mixed-joint frame condition correctly answered that $10 discount was given

on the bundle itself. Therefore, the bundle discount framing manipulation was successful.

All four scenarios were perceived as realistic (Mmixed-non-leader & hedonic = 5.34, Mmixed-non-

leader & utilitarian = 5.49, Mintegrated mixed-joint & hedonic = 5.71, Mintegrated-mixed-joint & utilitarian = 5.63).

3.3.3.3 Hypotheses Tests

The cell means for ease of justification, perceived savings, and willingness to

purchase are reported by experimental condition in Table 6. Consistent with expectations,

the cell means for ease of justification indicated that, when the consumption nature of the

non-leader product was hedonic, participants perceived the mixed-non-leader frame as

significantly easier to justify than the integrated mixed-joint frame (Mmixed-non-leader = 4.95,

Mintegrated mixed-joint= 3.47; p < 0.001). The gap in ease of justification was not significant

when the consumption nature of the non-leader product was utilitarian (Mmixed-non-leader =

5.03, Mintegrated mixed-joint = 4.57; p > 0.1). A similar pattern in cell means was present for

perceived savings and willingness to purchase. Participants perceived savings in the

37

mixed-non-leader frame as significantly greater than savings in the integrated mixed-joint

frame when the consumption nature of the non-leader product was hedonic (Mmixed-non-

leader = 4.20, Mintegrated mixed-joint= 2.68; p < 0.001). However, the gap in perceived savings

between the mixed-non-leader, and integrated mixed-joint, frames was not significant

when the non-leader product was utilitarian in nature (Mmixed-non-leader = 4.14, Mintegrated

mixed-joint= 3.69; p > 0.1). Finally, when the consumption nature of the non-leader product

was hedonic, a mixed-non-leader frame led to significantly higher ratings for willingness

to purchase than an integrated mixed-joint frame (Mmixed-non-leader = 4.54, Mintegrated mixed-

joint= 2.48; p < 0.001). But, the gap in willingness to purchase between the mixed-non-

leader and integrated mixed-joint frames was not significant when the non-leader product

was utilitarian in nature (Mmixed-non-leader = 4.68, Mintegrated mixed-joint= 4.27; p > 0.5).

Together, these results provide initial support for H1 and H2. These results are visualized

in Figure 2 to 4.

Table 6. Study 1: Means for Ease of Justification, Perceived Savings, and

Willingness to Purchase by Experimental Condition

Frame Consumption

Nature

Means

Ease of

justification

Perceived

savings

Willingness to

purchase

Mixed-non-

leader

Hedonic 4.95 4.20 4.54

Utilitarian 5.03 4.14 4.68

Integrated

mixed-joint

Hedonic 3.47 2.68 2.48

Utilitarian 4.57 3.69 4.27

38

Figure 2. Study 1: Mean Ratings for Ease of Justification by Experimental

Condition

Figure 3. Study 1: Mean Ratings for Perceived Savings by Experimental Condition

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

Hedonic Utilitarian

Mea

n R

atin

gs

for

Eas

e o

f Ju

stif

icat

ion

Consumption Nature of the Non-Leader Products

Mixed-non-leader Integrated mixed-joint

39

Figure 4. Study 1: Mean Ratings for Willingness to Purchase by Experimental

Condition

A customized PROCESS model macro in SPSS was employed to formally test

H1 and H2 (Hayes, 2017). This procedure used an ordinary-least squares path analysis to

estimate the coefficients in the model in order to determine the direct and indirect effects

of bundle discount frames on willingness to purchase. The author specified a bmatrix to

reflect the hypothesized mediating effects of ease of justification and perceived savings

on the bundle discount frame type-willingness to purchase relationship; a wmatrix to

incorporate the hypothesized moderating effect of consumption nature of the non-leader

product on the bundle discount frame type-ease of justification relationship; and, the level

of complementarity between two products in the bundle as a covariate. Bootstrapping

40

was implemented in these analyses to obtain bias-corrected 95% confidence intervals for

making statistical inference about specific and total indirect effects (see Preacher &

Hayes, 2008).

The results of the moderated serial mediation analysis are presented in Table

7. First, the results indicated that the interaction effect of bundle discount frame type and

the consumption nature of the non-leader product on ease of justification was significant

(β = 0.84, CI: 0.26, 1.42). This interaction effect is visualized in Figure 2. Specifically,

when the non-leader product was hedonic in nature, a mixed-non-leader frame led to

significantly higher ratings for ease of justification than an integrated mixed-joint frame

(Effect: -1.12, CI: -1.53, -0.70). Conversely, when a non-leader product was utilitarian in

nature, the gap in ease of justification between a mixed-non-leader and an integrated

mixed-joint frame was not significant (Effect: -0.28, CI: -0.69, 0.13). Thus, H1 was

supported.

The index of moderated serial mediation for the conditional indirect effect of

bundle discount frame type on willingness to purchase through ease of justification and

perceived savings was significant (Index = 0.32, CI = 0.09 to 0.62). When the non-leader

product was hedonic in nature, the serial mediating effects of ease of justification and

perceived savings on the bundle discount frame type-willingness to purchase relationship

were significant (Effect: -0.43, CI = -0.72 to -0.19). A mixed-non-leader frame led to

significantly higher ratings for willingness to purchase through higher ratings for ease of

justification and perceived savings when a non-leader product was hedonic in nature.

However, these serial mediation effects did not hold when a non-leader product was

utilitarian in nature (Effect: -0.11, CI: -0.29, 0.05). In other words, the gap in willingness

41

to purchase between the mixed-non-leader and integrated mixed-joint frames was no

longer significant when the non-leader product was utilitarian in nature. Thus, H2 was

supported.

Table 7. Study 1: Result of Moderated Serial Mediation Analysis

Ease of justification Perceived savings Willingness to

purchase

Coefficient 95% CI Coefficient 95% CI Coefficie

nt 95% CI

Constant 2.24 1.60,2.89 -0.08 -0.85,0.70 0.24 -0.52,1.00

Bundle frame type1 -1.12 -1.53,-0.70 -0.51 -0.88,-0.14

Consumption Nature2 0.08 -0.34,0.49

Interaction3 0.84 0.26,1.42

Ease of justification 0.77 0.59,0.94

Perceived savings 0.50 0.38,0.62

Complementarity 0.55 0.43,0.66 0.06 -0.12,0.25 0.46 0.31,0.61

R 0.69 0.64 0.75

R2 0.48 0.41 0.56

F 39.79 61.73 72.89

df1 (df2) 4 (173) 2 (175) 3 (174)

P <0.0001 <0.0001 <0.0001

Conditional effects4:

Nature Effect 95% CI

Hedonic -1.12 -1.53,-0.70

Utilitarian -0.28 -0.69,0.13

Indirect effects5:

Nature

Effect

-0.06

0.13

95% CI

-0.16,0.03

0.02,0.29 Hedonic -0.43 -0.72,-0.19

Utilitarian -0.11 -0.29,0.05

Index of moderated mediation

Index

0.32

95% CI

0.09,0.62

1Referece group: Mixed-non-leader frame 2Referece group: Hedonic 3Interaction: Perceived savings x Consumption nature of the non-leader product 4Interaction effect of bundle discount frame types and consumption nature on ease of justification 5Bundle discount frame -> Ease of justification -> Perceived savings -> Willingness to purchase

42

Finally, the control variable, the level of complementarity between the two

products in the bundle, had a significant effect on ease of justification (β = 0.55, CI: 0.43,

0.66) and willingness to purchase (β = 0.46, CI: 0.31, 0.61), but had an insignificant on

perceived savings (β = 0.06, CI: -0.12, 0.25).

3.3.4 Discussion

Consumer reaction to bundle discount frames has been widely studied (e.g.,

Guiltinan, 1987; Janiszewski & Cunha, 2004; Yadav, 1994, 1995). However, the two

bundle discount frames of interest in this study– mixed-non-leader and integrated mixed-

joint – have never been directly compared in the literature. Given the fact that these two

bundle discount frames are the most applicable to traditional RM applications, it is

important that the potential differential effects of these frames on consumers’ purchase

intentions is understood. It is also important to understand how the consumption nature of

the non-leader products promoted within a given bundle influences consumers’ reactions

to bundle discount frames. As expected, Study 1’s results demonstrated that a mixed-non-

leader frame was generally perceived as superior to an integrated mixed-joint frame in

terms of ease of justification when the non-leader product was hedonic (vs. utilitarian) in

nature. In other words, participants were likely to justify their decision to purchase a

hedonic non-leader product more easily when they were presented in a mixed-non-leader

discount frame than in an integrated mixed-joint frame. Consequently, participants

perceived higher savings, and were more willing to purchase a hedonic non-leader

product when a mixed-non-leader discount frame was presented. However, when the

non-leader product was utilitarian in nature, participants were likely to perceive mixed-

43

non-leader and integrated mixed-joint frames as equally easy to justify. Consequently,

perceived savings and willingness to purchase did not vary significantly across the two

bundle discount frames.

3.4 Study 2

3.4.1 Procedures

In Study 2, the focus was solely on mixed-non-leader bundle discount frames.

Specifically, Study 2 examined the role of customization, and further explored the impact

of the consumption nature of the non-leader product in a bundle, on consumers’ reactions

to bundling in the context of a mixed-non-leader bundle discount frame. Participants

were randomly assigned to one of three conditions. In the first condition, Company-

Designed-Utilitarian, participants were exposed to a company-designed bundle that

consisted of an airline ticket and travel insurance. In the second condition, Company-

Designed-Hedonic, participants were exposed to a company-designed bundle that

consisted of an airline ticket and airline lounge access. Finally, in the Self-Designed

condition, participants were exposed to a consumer self-designed bundle (i.e., customized

bundle) that consisted of an airline ticket and a choice between travel insurance.

(utilitarian non-leader product) and airline lounge access (hedonic non-leader product).

Travel insurance, identified as a largely utilitarian product in the pre-tests, was used to

represent a utilitarian non-leader product in Study 2 to broaden the range of non-leader

products tested in this research. However, airline lounge access was retained as the

hedonic product as it emerged as the most appropriate hedonic non-leaser product form

44

Pre-test 2 in terms of both anticipated price and attractiveness. See the stimuli in

Appendix B. All participants were exposed to the same basic scenario as participants in

Study 1 (i.e., traveling to a city located in the U.S., with a price of $250 for a regular

economy seat). Participants were also informed that the airline provided additional

services at an extra charge. Participants then completed a questionnaire that contained

items used as manipulation checks, measures for the key variables of interest, a realism

check, and demographic questions.

3.4.2 Measures

The author used the same willingness to purchase (Maxwell, 2002; Cronbach’s

α=0.94) and ease of justification (Heitman et al., 2007; Cronbach’s α=0.88) scales as in

Study 1.

In the Company-Designed-Utilitarian, and the Company-Designed-Hedonic

conditions, participants rated willingness to purchase for the bundle that they were

exposed to in the same manner as in Study 1 (i.e., they rated the 3 willingness to book

items on 7-point scales anchored by strongly disagree and strongly agree). In the Self-

Designed condition, the goal was to tap into participants’ preferences between the

hedonic and utilitarian non-leader products presented to them. Thus, for each of the 3

willingness to book items, participants completed 7-point bipolar scales, with 7 indicating

a high preference for the utilitarian non-leader product and 1 indicating a high preference

for the hedonic non-leader product (See Table 8).

45

In the Company-Designed-Utilitarian, and Company-Designed-Hedonic

conditions, participants rated ease of justification for the bundle that they were exposed

to. In the Self-Designed condition, participants were asked to rate ease of justification for

both bundles on offer (airline ticket and airline lounge access, and airline ticket and travel

insurance). The order in which these scales (ease of justification for the bundle with the

hedonic non-leader product, and ease of justification for the bundle with the utilitarian

non-leader product) were presented to participants was randomized to control any

question order bias (Perreault, 1975).

In addition to these key variables, the author measured anticipated satisfaction

with the bundle purchase using a 4-item, 7-point bipolar scale anchored by not at all and

extremely (Botti & McGill, 2010; Cronbach’s α=0.93). Anticipated satisfaction was

measured to rule out the possibility that differences across the customized (Self-

Designed) and standardized (Company- Choice) conditions was simply a function of

differences in access to choice. See Table 8 for scale items.

To ensure that the manipulation for the consumption nature of the non-leader

product was successful, the single item, 7-point bipolar scale from Study 1 was used. In

addition, participants were asked to indicate how many options for the non-leader product

were presented to them to ensure that the Company-Designed versus Self-Designed

manipulation was successful. Finally, a single item measure from Study 1was used to

assess the realism of the scenarios presented to the study’s participants.

46

Table 8. Study 2: Scale Items

Willingness to purchase – Company-Designed conditions

(1 = strongly disagree; 7 = strongly agree)

The likelihood of me buying this airline ticket/checked baggage package (airline ticket/airline lounge

access package) is

My willingness to buying this airline ticket/checked baggage package (airline ticket/airline lounge

access package) is

The probability that I would consider buying this airline ticket/checked baggage package (airline

ticket/airline lounge access package) is

Willingness to Purchase – Self-Designed condition

(1 = Airline lounge access (high); 7 = Travel insurance (high))

The likelihood of me buying airline lounge access or travel insurance along with airline ticket is

My willingness to buy airline lounge access or travel insurance along with airline ticket is

The probability that I would consider buying airline lounge access or travel insurance along with airline

ticket is

Anticipated satisfaction

How much do you think you would like and enjoy this package?

How satisfied do you think you would be with this package?

How confident do you think you would like this package?

How good do you think you would feel about this package?

3.4.3 Results

3.4.3.1 Sample Characteristics

A total of 150 participants were recruited via a 3rd party data collection

company, and the 125 individuals who passed attention checks were retained for the

analysis, yielding an approximately equal number of participants in each experimental

condition (n=43 for the Company-Designed-Hedonic condition; n=40 for the Company-

Designed-Utilitarian condition; n=42 for the Self-Designed condition). In total, 42.4%

(n=53) of the participants were male. The average age of the participants was 38.75. The

majority of participants had a college degree or higher education (73.6%; n=92), and a

full-time job (60.8%, n=68), with 64.8% (n=81) having a household income higher than

47

$50,000. The majority of participants (53.6%; n=67) had taken a flight more than twice

for a trip in the 24 months prior to participating in the survey. See Table 9 for the full

characteristics of the sample.

3.4.3.2 Manipulation and Realism Checks

The ratings for the item measuring the consumption nature of the non-leader

product were significantly higher for the hedonic condition than the utilitarian condition

(Company-Designed: Mhedonic = 5.35, Mutilitarian = 2.82, p<0.001; Self-Designed: Mhedonic =

6.02, Mutilitarian = 2.05, p<0.001). Thus, the manipulation for the consumption nature of

the non-leader product was successful. In terms of the Company-Designed versus Self-

Designed manipulation, all participants in the Company-Designed condition correctly

indicated that one add-on option was provided, and all participants in the Self-Designed

condition correctly answered that more than one add-on option was provided. Therefore,

the Company-Designed versus Self-Designed manipulation was successful. All three

scenarios were perceived as realistic (Mcompany-designed-hedonic = 5.24, Mcompany-designed-utilitarian

= 5.29, Mself-designed = 5.71)

48

Table 9. Study 2: Sample Characteristics

a last 24 months

Variable N %

Gender

Male 53 42.4

Female 72 57.6

Age

34 or under 59 47.2

35 – 50

51 – 69

70 or older

36

25

5

28.8

20.0

4.0

Education

Some High school or less 0 0

High School 33 26.4

College 72 57.6

Graduate school 20 16.0

Employment

Full-time 76 60.8

Part-time 17 13.6

Not currently employed 12 9.6

Retired 10 8.0

Student 6 4.8

Other 4 3.2

Household income

Less than $25,000 14 11.2

$25,000 to $49,999 30 24.0

$50,000 to $74,999 37 29.6

$75,000 to $99,999 18 14.4

$100,000 to $124,999 8 6.4

$125,000 to $ 149,999 5 4.0

$150,000 or more 13 10.4

Frequency of taking a flight for tripsa

1-2 times 58 46.4

3-4 times 38 30.4

5-6 times 14 11.2

More than 6 times 15 12.0

49

3.4.3.3 Hypotheses Tests

Before conducting any hypotheses tests, a one-way ANOVA was employed to

test whether the customized and standardized conditions led to significant difference in

anticipated satisfaction ratings. There was no significant difference among three

conditions (Mcompany-designed&hedonic = 4.85, Mcompany-designed&utilitarian = 4.53, Mself-designed =

4.99, p>0.1. Therefore, the author could rule out the possibility that differences across the

customized and standardized conditions was simply a function of differences in access to

choice.

The cell means for ease of justification and willingness to purchase by

experimental condition are provided in Table 10. For the purpose of testing Hypotheses 3

and 4, the author separately analyzed the data in the Self-Designed and Company-

Designed conditions.

Self-Designed Condition

Ease of justification: Since each participant in the Self-Designed condition

rated ease of justification for both hedonic and utilitarian non-leader bundles, a one-way

repeated measures ANOVA was conducted to test H3a. The cell means for ease of

justification indicate that participants perceived the bundle with the utilitarian non-leader

product as easier to justify than the bundle with the hedonic non-leader product (Mhedonic

= 3.03, Mutilitarian = 5.29). The results of the repeated measures ANOVA revealed a

significant main effect of the consumption nature of the non-leader product on ease of

justification (F(1,41) = 49.09, p<0.0001). Thus, H3a was supported.

50

Willingness to purchase: Each participant in the Self-Designed condition rated

willingness to purchase on a bipolar scale (with 7 indicating a high preference for the

utilitarian non-leader product, and 1 indicating a high preference for the hedonic non-

leader product). As indicated in Table 10, the mean rating for willingness to purchase was

skewed towards the bundle with the utilitarian non-leader product (M = 5.48, standard

deviation = 1.5). In other words, participants indicated that they were more likely to

purchase a bundle with a utilitarian non-leader product than a bundle with a hedonic non-

leader product when provided both options to choose from. Thus, H4a was supported.

Company-Designed Conditions

A one-way MANOVA was employed to test H3b and H4b regarding the effect

of the consumption nature of the non-leader product on ease of justification and

willingness to purchase in the Company-Design conditions. MANOVA has the benefit of

controlling the experiment-wise error rate when some level of inter-correlation among

multiple dependent variables exists (Hair, Black, Babin, & Anderson, 2010).

The five assumptions underlying MANOVA were checked. First, there were

five outliers that exceeded the suggested Mahalanobis distance cutoff-point in the data

set, so those observations were excluded from further analysis. Second, a Box’s M test

was conducted to check homogeneity of covariance matrices assumption (p>0.1). Third,

in terms of the multi-collinearity assumption, the correlation between the two dependent

variables was 0.7. Box plot and scatter plots were used to test normality and linearity

51

assumption. The results of these assumption checks indicated that all assumptions were

satisfied.

As reported in Table 10, the cell means for ease of justification (Mhedonic =

4.62, Mutilitarian = 4.73) and willingness to purchase (Mhedonic = 3.90, Mutilitarian = 4.14)

provide initial support for H3b and H4b. A one-way MANOVA, with the consumption

nature of the non-leader product as an independent variable, was conducted on ease of

justification and willingness to purchase, along with follow-up univariate analyses. The

multivariate test results indicated an insignificant impact of the consumption nature of the

non-leader product on the multivariate dependent measure (F(2,80) = 0.28, p > 0.5). The

follow-up univariate test results indicated an insignificant impact of the consumption

nature of the non-leader product on both ease of justification (F(1,81) = 0.30, p > 0.5) and

willingness to purchase (F(1,81) = 0.56, p > 0.4) (See Table 11). Therefore, H3b and H4b

were supported. Figures 5 and 6 visualize the study’s findings in relation to H3a and H3b,

and H4a and H4b.

Table 10. Study 2: Means for Ease of Justification and Willingness to Purchase by

Experimental Condition

Frame Consumption

Nature

Means

Ease of

justification

Willingness to

purchase

Self-Designed Hedonic 3.03

5.481 Utilitarian 5.29

Company-

Designed

Hedonic 4.62 3.90

Utilitarian 4.73 4.14 1 7-point bipolar scale – 1: High willingness to purchase a hedonic non-leader product to

7: High willingness to purchase a utilitarian non-leader product

52

Table 11. Study 2: MANOVA and univariate follow-up results

Source Pillai’s

trace

(p-value)

Univariate follow-ups

Dependent variable Type

III SS

DF MS F p-value

Intercept 938.8

(p<0.001)

Ease of Justification 1807 1 1807 1839 p<0.001

Willingness to Purchase 1334 1 1334 632.9 P<0.001

Consumption

Nature1

0.28

(p>0.5)

Ease of Justification 0.29 1 0.29 0.30 p>0.5

Willingness to Purchase 1.18 1 1.18 0.56 p>0.4

Error - Ease of Justification 79.58 81 0.98

Willingness to Purchase 170.7 81 2.11

Total - Ease of Justification 1896 83

Willingness to Purchase 1516 83

Corrected

total

- Ease of Justification 79.88 82

Willingness to Purchase 171.9 82 1Referece group: Hedonic

Figure 5. Study 2: Mean Ratings for Ease of Justification

53

Figure 6. Study 2: Mean Ratings for Willingness to Purchase

3.4.4 Discussion

The positive effects of customization on consumers’ reactions including

perceived quality, satisfaction, and purchase intention have been widely demonstrated in

the literature (e.g., Coelho & Henseler, 2012; Coulter & Coulter, 2002; Franke et al.,

2009). However, the results from Study 2 suggest that this may not always be the case. In

this study, the self-designed bundle represented a customized bundle, while the company-

designed bundles represented standardized bundles. The results indicate that, when

participants were offered a self-designed bundle, which represents a situation where

consumers have to evaluate multiple non-leader products (i.e., a joint evaluation mode),

they were better able to justify the utilitarian non-leader product bundle than the hedonic

54

non-leader product bundle. Consequently, they were more likely to choose the utilitarian

non-leader product bundle. In contrast, when participants were offered a company-

designed bundle, which represents a situation where consumers have to evaluate only one

non-leader product (i.e., a separate evaluation mode), there was no significant difference

ease of justification or willingness to purchase across the utilitarian, and hedonic, non-

leader product bundles. In sum, these findings suggest that a customized bundle will be

more effective when promoting a utilitarian non-leader product. However, a standardized

company-designed bundle is more likely to encourage bundle purchase when promoting a

hedonic non-leader product.

55

CHAPTER 4. GENERAL DISCUSSION

Bundling is widely used by service providers as a strategy to cross-sell

products, and to encourage consumers who are already willing to purchase a focal

product to purchase additional products (Derdenger & Kumar, 2013; Janiszewski &

Cunha, 2004; Krüger et al., 2014; Mittelman, Andrade, Chattopadhyay, & Brendl, 2014;

Ng et al., 1999). In the context of TRM, therefore, bundling has the potential to play a

significant role in maximizing revenue across all of a firm’s revenue streams.

The overall goal of this research was to explore effective bundling strategies

for TRM. Prior research in the domain of bundling has examined consumers’ reactions to

different types of bundle discount frames (e.g., mixed-leader vs. mixed-non-leader,

mixed-leader vs. segregate mixed-joint vs. integrated mixed-joint). However, it provides

limited insight into the efficacy of the bundle discount frames that are relevant in a

traditional RM setting: mixed-non-leader, and integrated-mixed-joint, frames. Further,

the literature does not address the potential role that the consumption nature of the non-

leader product in the bundle plays in consumers’ reactions to bundle discount frames.

Similarly, it does not address the potential impact of the consumption nature of the non-

leader product in the bundle on consumer response to customized (vs. standardized)

bundling. Thus, this research sought to address these gaps in the literature, and provide

revenue managers with insights to guide their TRM efforts.

56

4.1 Theoretical Implications

This research extends the literature in a number of ways. First, it examined the

role of different bundle discount frames in driving consumers’ purchase intentions. The

two bundle discount frames of interest in this research – mixed-non-leader and integrated

mixed-joint – are pertinent to bundling for TRM but have not previously been directly

compared in the literature. Second, this research probed the impact of bundle discount

frames on ease of justification, and the role of the consumption nature of the non-leader

product within a bundle in the discount frames–ease of consumption justification

relationship. A key difference between the two bundle discount frames studied in this

research is the amount of discount information provided to the consumer. The relatively

more transparent discount information associated with the mixed-non-leader frame

allows consumers to justify the purchase of a given bundle more easily than an integrated

mixed-joint frame. The more transparent information provided by the mixed-non-leader

frame is a heuristic cue for persuasive and credible information (Chaiken et al., 1989).

This transparency is key when the non-leader product is hedonic in nature. Consumers

seek reasons to justify their purchase decisions (Shafir, Simonson, & Tversky, 1993).

When a purchase decision is difficult to justify, consumers have to actively seek

additional reasons to justify their decisions. However, when a purchase decision is

relatively easy to justify, consumers are less involved in additional justification processes

(Shafir et al., 1993). Given that hedonic consumption is more difficult to justify than

utilitarian consumption (Hsee, 1996; Okada, 2005), consumers are more sensitive to

additional reasons such as price discount information with hedonic (vs. utilitarian)

consumption to help them to justify their purchase. Thus, extending the work of Khan

57

and Dhar (2010), this research suggests in the context of tie-in bundling, that a mixed-

non-leader bundle discount frame, by virtue of information transparency, will drive

higher ease of justification ratings when the non-leader product is hedonic in nature.

Third, this research advances the literature by demonstrating the mediating

roles of ease of justification and perceived savings on the relationship between bundle

discount frames and purchase intentions when the non-leader product in a given bundle is

hedonic in nature. As previously mentioned, a mixed-non-leader bundle discount frame is

likely to be easier to justify than an integrated mixed-joint frame with hedonic non-leader

products. Once consumers form their first impression of a product based on its

justifiability, this first impression influences subsequent evaluations of the perceived

savings associated with that product. Prior research has widely examined confirmation

bias, a type of cognitive bias in the information processing (e.g., Campbell & Warren,

2014; Chernev, 2001; Klayman, 1995; Nakayama & Sutcliffe, 2005; Nickerson, 1998;

Yin et al., 2016). Once consumers form an impression of a product, they tend to process

other aspects of the product in a way that supports this first impression. They seek, and

overweight, supporting evidence. The notion of confirmation bias was supported by the

findings of this research, with a positive relationship between ease of justification and

perceived savings observed when the non-leader product was hedonic in nature. Thus,

this research supported an indirect effect of bundle discount frame on willingness to

purchase through ease of justification and perceived savings when the non-leader product

was hedonic nature. This research also suggests that, when the non-leader product is

utilitarian in nature, the two bundle discount frames under examination do not have a

significantly different impact on ease of justification. In the absence of the need for

58

additional reasons to justify the purchase of a bundle a utilitarian non-leader product, the

bundle discount frame did not produce a differential effect on ease of justification, and

consequently, perceived saving and willingness to purchase did not vary significantly

across the two bundle discount frames.

Fourth, this research extends the literature in terms of consumers’ response to

bundle customization. Prior research suggests that customized bundling may be preferred

over standardized bundling (e.g., Bateson, 1985; Coulter & Coulter, 2002; Coelho &

Henseler, 2012). However, the findings of Study 2 suggest that this may not necessarily

be the case. Rather, the findings support the idea that, by virtue of differences in

evaluation modes across self-designed and company-designed bundles, coupled with the

consumption nature of the non-leader product within a given bundle, self-designed

bundling may work best when the non-leader product is utilitarian in nature. With self-

designed bundling, consumers have to evaluate multiple non-leader products (i.e., joint

evaluation mode). In this context, consumers’ evaluations of a product are influenced by

the other products in the comparison set. Thus, due to the contrast effect (Thornton &

Maurice, 1997; Thornton & Moore, 1993), the purchase of a bundle with a utilitarian

non-leader product will be easier to justify than the purchase of a bundle with a hedonic

non-leader product. In contrast, with company-designed bundling, consumers have to

evaluate only one single non-leader product (i.e., separate evaluation mode). They do not

have information about the other products so they construct justifications for the

decisions that they are motivated to make (Kunda, 1990). Thus, when the non-leader

product within a bundle is hedonic in nature, the findings of this research suggest that

59

company-designed bundle will drive higher ratings for ease of justification and

willingness to purchase than a self-designed bundle.

4.2 Managerial Implications

This research provides a number of insights for RM practitioners regarding the

deployment of bundling strategies for TRM. The first step in the development of

bundling strategies is to make a decision regarding what ancillary products to promote.

Several factors may drive this decision. For example, a firm may choose to focus on

ancillary products that yield a high contribution margin, such that flow through to the

bottom line is maximized. Alternatively, the goal may be to push sales for new ancillary

products, or drive demand for revenue-generating assets that are being under-utilized

(e.g., hotel food and beverage facilities). Once, the decision has been made regarding

what to promote, the findings of this research suggest that management should next

classify those ancillary products targeted for promotion in bundles by consumption

nature. Products tend to be comprised of both utilitarian and hedonic components, so the

focus here should be on classifying ancillary products based on the relative strength of

their consumption nature. For example, access to an airline lounge can be considered

relatively more hedonic than utilitarian in nature, while a grab and go breakfast at a hotel

can be considered primarily utilitarian in nature.

Once products have been classified by consumption nature, the next decision

is how to present the discount on the bundle. The findings of this research suggest that

the choice of bundle discount frame (mixed-non-leader vs. integrated mixed-joint) should

60

be guided by the consumption nature of the ancillary product. Specifically, a mixed-non-

leader frame (vs. an integrated mixed-joint frame) may yield a greater volume of

purchase activity when the consumption nature of the ancillary product is largely

hedonic. In this instance, consumers will likely perceive that, by virtue of greater

information transparency, the discount in the mixed-non-leader frame is easier to justify,

and by extension will yield higher perceptions of savings on the bundle. In contrast, the

choice of bundle discount frame may be less critical when the consumption nature of the

ancillary product is largely utilitarian. In this context, consumers are not seeking

additional reasons to justify their purchase, thus information regarding which product in

the bundle is discounted becomes less important. Consumers are likely to perceive both

bundle discount frames (mixed-non-leader and integrated mixed-joint) as equivalent in

terms of ease of justification, yielding little differences in perceived savings and

willingness to purchase across the two types of frames.

In terms of the choice regarding pursuit of customized (vs. standardized)

bundling, again practitioners should be guided by the consumption nature of the ancillary

product. The findings of this research suggest that self-designed bundling is more

effective when promoting utilitarian, rather than hedonic, ancillary products. When

presented with a choice between a utilitarian and a hedonic ancillary product, the

purchase of a utilitarian product is easier to justify. In contrast, research findings indicate

that company-designed bundles will work equally effectively for the promotion of

utilitarian and hedonic ancillary products.

61

4.3 Limitations and Future Research Directions

As with any single piece of research, the findings of this research should be

interpreted with caution for several reasons. First, the author employed a controlled

experimental design for both Study 1 and Study 2. This approach allowed the author to

test precise predictions derived from theory while holding all else constant (Calder,

Phillips, & Tybout, 1981). To simulate reality as accurately as possible, stimuli were

presented to participants in a manner that mimicked the user experience of an individual

airline webpage, with participants’ scores on the realism check suggesting that the

scenarios were perceived as realistic. However, a limitation of experimental design is that

it often lacks external validity, limiting generalizability across populations and settings.

Additional research employing a field study that examines actual choice behavior is also

needed to complement the findings of this research. Further, by their nature, controlled

experimental conditions limit the amount of information that the participant can use to

evaluate a given scenario. Consequently, high correlation may be observed among related

constructs of interest. I observed a relatively high correlation between two variables -

ease of justification and willingness to purchase - in Study 1. Therefore, the serial

mediating effects observed in Study 1 should be interpreted with caution. Further

research is merited to probe these relationships.

This research was conducted in an airline context, with three airline-related

non-leader products represented: airline lounge access (hedonic non-leader product), and

checked-baggage and travel insurance (utilitarian non-leader products). Future research

utilizing different contexts and related non-leader products (e.g., hotels, with hotel stay-

related non-leader products) is needed to assess the robustness of the findings across

62

different RM contexts. On a related note, this research focused on bundles that either

included one leader product and one non-leader product (Study 1 and Company-Designed

in Study 2), or one leader product and a choice between two non-leader products (Self-

Designed in Study 2). In reality, a service firm may bundle more than two products.

Thus, further research is required to assess how consumers evaluate multiple hedonic and

utilitarian non-leader options simultaneously. Prior research has demonstrated that too

many options can create choice overload, and negatively affect consumers’ responses

(Chernev, Bockenholt, & Goodman, 2015; Iyengar & Lepper, 2000; Scheibehenne,

Greifeneder, & Todd, 2010). Thus, examination of how consumers simultaneously assess

multiple hedonic and utilitarian non-leader options should incorporate consideration of

choice set size.

The prices associated with the non-leader products in both studies were relatively

low in comparison to the price of the focal product (e.g., $35 for airline lounge access

versus $250 for an airline ticket). Research is merited to investigate whether the study’s

findings would hold when price differences between leader and non-leader products is

less significant (e.g., hotel room rate and a spa treatment). Examination of the impact of

prices differences across bundles (by virtue of the price differences associated with

different ancillary products) on consumer response to bundle discount frames is also

warranted. On a related note, participants in this research were presented with ancillary

products which were comparable in terms of attractiveness. It would be interesting to

probe the potential role of variability in the perceived attractiveness of non-leader

products on consumer response to bundle discount frames and customized bundles. In

this research, the focus was on the moderating effect of the consumption nature of non-

63

leader items on consumer reactions to bundle discount frames and degree of

customization. Future research should encompass other potential moderators. For

example, familiarity with the non-leader product may affect the ease with which the

consumer justifies different bundle discount frames and customized bundle offerings

(Raju, 1977). Product familiarity is directly related with evaluation process. Consumers

who are familiar with the product, they can evaluate the product more easily, and this will

positively affect the confidence in the evaluation process (Raju, 1977). Therefore, it is

highly likely that familiarity affects ease of justification. This is particularly important

when promoting a new non-leader product because a new item is typically less familiar to

consumers compared to existing products.

64

REFERENCES

Adams, W. J., & Yellen, J. L. (1976). Commodity bundling and the burden of monopoly.

Quarterly Journal of Economics, 90(3), 475-498.

Anderson, E. W., Fornell, C., & Rust, R. T. (1997). Customer satisfaction, productivity,

and profitability: Differences between goods and services. Marketing

science, 16(2), 129-145.

Babin, B. J., Darden, W. R., & Griffin, M. (1994). Work and/or fun: measuring hedonic

and utilitarian shopping value. Journal of consumer research, 20(4), 644-656.

Bateson, J. E. (1985). Perceived control and the service encounter. The service

encounter: Managing employee/customer interaction in service businesses, 67-82.

Batra, R., & Ahtola, O. T. (1991). Measuring the hedonic and utilitarian sources of

consumer attitudes. Marketing letters, 2(2), 159-170.

Bettman, J. R., Luce, M. F., & Payne, J. W. (1998). Constructive consumer choice

processes. Journal of consumer research, 25(3), 187-217.

Bloch, P. H. (1995). Seeking the ideal form: Product design and consumer response. The

Journal of Marketing, 16-29.

Botti, S., & McGill, A. L. (2010). The locus of choice: Personal causality and satisfaction

with hedonic and utilitarian decisions. Journal of Consumer Research, 37(6), 1065-

1078.

65

Campbell, M. C., & Warren, C. (2014). The progress bias in goal pursuit: When one step

forward seems larger than one step back. Journal of consumer research, 41(5),

1316-1331.

Chernev, A. (2001). The impact of common features on consumer preferences: A case of

confirmatory reasoning. Journal of Consumer Research, 27(4), 475-488.

Chernev, A., Böckenholt, U., & Goodman, J. (2015). Choice overload: A conceptual

review and meta-analysis. Journal of Consumer Psychology, 25(2), 333-358.

Chaiken, S., Liberman, A., & Eagly, A. H. (1989). Heuristic and Systematic Information

Processing within and beyond the Persuasion Context. In J. S. Uleman, & J. A.

Bargh (Eds.), Unintended Thought (pp. 212-252). New York: Guilford.

Chan, K. W., Yim, C. K., & Lam, S. S. (2010). Is customer participation in value creation

a double-edged sword? Evidence from professional financial services across

cultures. Journal of marketing, 74(3), 48-64.

Chen, A., Peng, N., & Hung, K. P. (2015). Strategic management of salespeople when

promoting new products: Moderating effects of sales-related organizational

psychological climate. European Journal of Marketing, 49(9/10), 1616-1644.

Coulter, K. S., & Coulter, R. A. (2002). Determinants of trust in a service provider: the

moderating role of length of relationship. Journal of services marketing, 16(1), 35-

50.

Coelho, P. S., & Henseler, J. (2012). Creating customer loyalty through service

customization. European Journal of Marketing, 46(3/4), 331-356.

66

Crilly, N., Moultrie, J., & Clarkson, P. J. (2004). Seeing things: consumer response to the

visual domain in product design. Design studies, 25(6), 547-577.

Dabholkar, P. A. (2015). How to improve perceived service quality by increasing

customer participation. In Proceedings of the 1990 academy of marketing science

(AMS) annual conference (pp. 483-487). Springer, Cham.

Derdenger, T., & Kumar, V. (2013). The dynamic effects of bundling as a product

strategy. Marketing Science, 32(6), 827-859.

Doherty, M. E., & Mynatt, C. R. (1986). The magical number one. In D. Moates & R.

Butrick (Eds.), Inference Ohio University Interdisciplinary Conference 86 (pp.

221-230).

Drolet, A., Williams, P., & Lau-Gesk, L. (2007). Age-related differences in responses to

affective vs. rational ads for hedonic vs. utilitarian products. Marketing

letters, 18(4), 211-221.

Franke, N., Keinz, P., & Steger, C. J. (2009). Testing the value of customization: when

do customers really prefer products tailored to their preferences?. Journal of

Marketing, 73(5), 103-121.

Gilbride, T. J., Guiltinan, J. P., & Urbany, J. E. (2008). Framing effects in mixed price

bundling. Marketing Letters, 19(2), 125-139.

González, E. M., Esteva, E., Roggeveen, A. L., & Grewal, D. (2016). Amount off versus

percentage off—when does it matter?. Journal of Business Research, 69(3), 1022-

1027.

67

Grewal, D., Hardesty, D. M., & Iyer, G. R. (2004). The effects of buyer identification and

purchase timing on consumers’ perceptions of trust, price fairness, and repurchase

intentions. Journal of Interactive Marketing, 18(4), 87-98.

Guiltinan, J. P. (1987). The price bundling of services: A normative framework. Journal

of Marketing, 51(2), 74-85.

Gupta, S., & Cooper, L. G. (1992). The discounting of discounts and promotion

thresholds. Journal of consumer research, 19(3), 401-411.

Hair, J. F. (2010). Black, WC, Babin, BJ, & Anderson, RE (2010). Multivariate data

analysis, 7. Prentice Hall, Englewood Cliffs, NJ

Hayes, A. F. 2017. Introduction to mediation, moderation, and conditional process

analysis: A regression-based approach. New York, NY: Guilford Publications.

Heitmann, M., Lehmann, D. R., & Herrmann, A. (2007). Choice goal attainment and

decision and consumption satisfaction. Journal of marketing research, 44(2), 234-

250.

Heo, C. Y., & Lee, S. (2009). Application of revenue management practices to the theme

park industry. International Journal of Hospitality Management, 28(3), 446-453.

Hsee, C. K. (1996). Elastic justification: How unjustifiable factors influence

judgments. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 66(1), 122-

129.

68

Hitt, L. M., & Chen, P. Y. (2005). Bundling with customer self-selection: A simple

approach to bundling low-marginal-cost goods. Management Science, 51(10),

1481-1493.

Hsee, C. K., & Zhang, J. (2010). General evaluability theory. Perspectives on

Psychological Science, 5(4), 343-355.

Hui, M. K., & Bateson, J. E. (1991). Perceived control and the effects of crowding and

consumer choice on the service experience. Journal of consumer research, 18(2),

174-184.

Iyengar, S. S., & Lepper, M. R. (2000). When choice is demotivating: Can one desire too

much of a good thing?. Journal of personality and social psychology, 79(6), 995.

Janiszewski, C., & Cunha, M. (2004). The influence of price discount framing on the

evaluation of a product bundle. Journal of Consumer Research, 30(4), 534-546.

Khan, U., & Dhar, R. (2010). Price-framing effects on the purchase of hedonic and

utilitarian bundles. Journal of Marketing Research, 47(6), 1090-1099.

Kimes, S. E. (2003). Revenue management: A retrospective. Cornell Hospitality

Quarterly, 44(5/6), 131.

Kimes, S. E. (2016). The evolution of hotel revenue management. Journal of Revenue

and Pricing Management, 15(3-4), 247-251.

Kimes, S. E., & Beard, J. (2013). The future of restaurant revenue management. Journal

of Revenue and Pricing Management, 12(5), 464-469

69

Kimes, S. E., & Chase, R.B.(1998) The strategic levers of yield management, Journal of

Service Research, 1 (2), 156-166.

Kimes, S. E., & Renaghan, L. M. (2011). The role of space in revenue management.

Revenue Management Theories and Issues, Practical Pricing Perspective.

Houndmills: Macmillan Publishers Limited, 17-28

Kimes, S. E., & Singh, S. (2009). Spa revenue management. Cornell Hospitality

Quarterly, 50(1), 82-95

Kimes, S. E., & Thompson, G. M. (2004). Restaurant revenue management at Chevys:

Determining the best table mix. Decision Sciences, 35(3), 371-392.

Kimes, S. E., & Wirtz, J. (2015). Revenue management: Advanced strategies and tools to

enhance firm profitability. Foundations and Trends in Marketing, 8(1), 1-68

Kivetz, R., & Simonson, I. (2002). Earning the right to indulge: Effort as a determinant of

customer preferences toward frequency program rewards. Journal of Marketing

Research, 39(2), 155-170.

Klayman, J. (1995). Varieties of confirmation bias. In Psychology of learning and

motivation (Vol. 32, pp. 385-418). Academic Press.

Krüger, T., Mata, A., & Ihmels, M. (2014). The Presenter's Paradox Revisited: An

Evaluation Mode Account. Journal of Consumer Research, 41(4), 1127-1136.

Kunda, Z. (1990). The case for motivated reasoning. Psychological bulletin, 108(3), 480.

70

Li, D., & Pang, Z. (2017). Dynamic booking control for car rental revenue management:

A decomposition approach. European Journal of Operational Research, 256(3),

850-867.

Lim, E. A. C., & Ang, S. H. (2008). Hedonic vs. utilitarian consumption: A cross-cultural

perspective based on cultural conditioning. Journal of business research, 61(3),

225-232.

Lynch Jr, J. G., & Ariely, D. (2000). Wine online: Search costs affect competition on

price, quality, and distribution. Marketing science, 19(1), 83-103.

March, J. G. (1978). Bounded rationality, ambiguity, and the engineering of choice. The

Bell Journal of Economics, 587-608.

Maxwell, S. (2002). Rule-based price fairness and its effect on willingness to

purchase. Journal of economic psychology, 23(2), 191-212.

Miao, L., & Mattila, A. S. (2007). How and how much to reveal? The effects of price

transparency on consumers' price perceptions. Journal of Hospitality & Tourism

Research, 31(4), 530-545.

Mittelman, M., Andrade, E. B., Chattopadhyay, A., & Brendl, C. M. (2014). The offer

framing effect: choosing single versus bundled offerings affects variety

seeking. Journal of Consumer Research, 41(4), 953-964.

Nakayama, M., & Sutcliffe, N. G. (2005). Exploratory analysis on the halo effect of

strategic goals on IOS effectiveness evaluation. Information &

Management, 42(2), 275-288.

71

Ng, I. C., Wirtz, J., & Sheang Lee, K. (1999). The strategic role of unused service

capacity. International Journal of Service Industry Management, 10(2), 211-244.

Nickerson, R. S. (1998). Confirmation bias: A ubiquitous phenomenon in many

guises. Review of general psychology, 2(2), 175-220.

Noone, B. M. (2008). Customer perceived control and the moderating effect of restaurant

type on evaluations of restaurant employee performance. International Journal of

Hospitality Management, 27, 23-29

Noone, B. M., & Mattila, A. S. (2009). Hotel revenue management and the Internet: The

effect of price presentation strategies on customers’ willingness to

book. International Journal of Hospitality Management, 28(2), 272-279.

Noone, B. M., Wirtz, J., & Kimes, S. E. (2010). The effect of perceived control on

consumer responses to service encounter pace: A revenue management

perspective. Cornell Hospitality Quarterly, 53(4), 295-307

Okada, E. M. (2005). Justification effects on consumer choice of hedonic and utilitarian

goods. Journal of marketing research, 42(1), 43-53.

Palamar, J., & Edwards, V. (2007). Dynamic pricing: Friend or foe. USA: BTE Tourism

Training and Consulting, Buckhiester Management, 1-14.

Perreault, W. D. (1975). Controlling order-effect bias. The Public Opinion

Quarterly, 39(4), 544-551.

72

Preacher, K. J., Hayes, A. F. 2008. Asymptotic and resampling strategies for assessing

and comparing indirect effects in multiple mediator models. Behavior Research

Methods, 40(3), 879-891.

Raju, P. S. (1977). Product familiarity, brand name, and price influences on product

evaluation. ACR North American Advances.

Rohlfs, K. V., & Kimes, S. E. (2007). Customers' perceptions of best available hotel

rates. Cornell Hotel and Restaurant Administration Quarterly, 48(2), 151-162.

Rose, P. (2016). A lifetime in airline revenue management. Journal of Revenue and

Pricing Management, 15, 197-202

Scheibehenne, B., Greifeneder, R., & Todd, P. M. (2010). Can there ever be too many

options? A meta-analytic review of choice overload. Journal of Consumer

Research, 37(3), 409-425.

Schmalensee, R. (1984). Gaussian demand and commodity bundling. Journal of business,

S211-S230.

Shafir, E., Simonson, I., & Tversky, A. (1993). Reason-based choice. Cognition, 49(1),

11-36.

Sheng, S., Parker, A. M., & Nakamoto, K. (2007). The effects of price discount and

product complementarity on consumer evaluations of bundle components. Journal

of Marketing Theory and Practice, 15(1), 53-64.

Simon, H. A. (1955). A behavioral model of rational choice. The quarterly journal of

economics, 69(1), 99-118.

73

Song, M., & Noone, B. M. (2017). The moderating effect of perceived spatial crowding

on the relationship between perceived service encounter pace and customer

satisfaction. International Journal of Hospitality Management, 65, 37-46.

Strahilevitz, M., & Myers, J. G. (1998). Donations to charity as purchase incentives: How

well they work may depend on what you are trying to sell. Journal of consumer

research, 24(4), 434-446.

Tanford, S., Baloglu, S., & Erdem, M. (2012). Travel packaging on the Internet: The

impact of pricing information and perceived value on consumer choice. Journal of

Travel Research, 51(1), 68-80.

Thaler, R. (1985). Mental accounting and consumer choice. Marketing science, 4(3), 199-

214.

Thornton, B., & Maurice, J. (1997). Physique contrast effect: Adverse impact of idealized

body images for women. Sex Roles, 37(5-6), 433-439.

Thornton, B., & Moore, S. (1993). Physical attractiveness contrast effect: Implications

for self-esteem and evaluations of the social self. Personality and Social

Psychology Bulletin, 19(4), 474-480.

Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1991). Loss aversion in riskless choice: A reference-

dependent model. The quarterly journal of economics, 106(4), 1039-1061.

Voss, K. E., Spangenberg, E. R., & Grohmann, B. (2003). Measuring the hedonic and

utilitarian dimensions of consumer attitude. Journal of marketing research, 40(3),

310-320.

74

Wirtz, J., & Kimes, S. E. (2007). The moderating role of familiarity in fairness

perceptions of revenue management pricing. Journal of Service Research, 9(3),

229-240.

Yadav, M. S. (1994). How buyers evaluate product bundles: A model of anchoring and

adjustment. Journal of Consumer Research, 21(2), 342-353.

Yadav, M. S. (1995). Bundle evaluation in different market segments: The effects of

discount framing and buyers' preference heterogeneity. Journal of the Academy of

Marketing Science, 23(3), 206-215.

Yin, D., Mitra, S., & Zhang, H. (2016). Research note—When do consumers value

positive vs. negative reviews? An empirical investigation of confirmation bias in

online word of mouth. Information Systems Research, 27(1), 131-144.

Zeithaml, V. A. (1988). Consumer perceptions of price, quality, and value: a means-end

model and synthesis of evidence. The Journal of marketing, 2-22.

Zhu, K. (2002). Information transparency in electronic marketplaces: Why data

transparency may hinder the adoption of B2B exchanges. Electronic

markets, 12(2), 92-99.

75

APPENDIX A-1. Study 1 Stimulus: Mixed-Non-Leader Frame & Hedonic Non-

Leader Product Condition

76

APPENDIX A-2. Study 1 Stimulus: Mixed-Non-Leader Frame & Utilitarian Non-

Leader Product Condition

77

APPENDIX A-3. Study 1 Stimulus: Integrated Mixed-Joint Frame & Hedonic Non-

Leader Product Condition

78

APPENDIX A-4. Study 1 Stimulus: Integrated Mixed-Joint Frame & Utilitarian

Non-Leader Product Condition

79

APPENDIX B-1. Study 2 Stimulus: Company-Designed & Hedonic Non-Leader

Product Condition

80

APPENDIX B-2. Study 2 Stimulus: Company-Designed & Utilitarian Non-Leader

Product Condition

81

APPENDIX B-3. Study 2 Stimulus: Self-Designed Condition

VITA

MyungKeun Song

EDUCATION

2018 The Pennsylvania State University, School of Hospitality Management

Ph.D. in Hospitality Management

2013 Cornell University, School of Hotel Administration

Master of Management in Hospitality

2013 University of Nevada, Las Vegas, College of Hotel Administration

B.S. Hospitality Management

HONORS AND AWARDS

Small Project Grant, The Pennsylvania State University, 2016

Dean’s Honor List, University of Nevada, Las Vegas, 2004, 2005

Best Performance in Speech Contest, Minister of Culture and Tourism Award, 2000

REFEREED JOURNAL ARTICLES

Song, M., & Noone, B. M. (2017). The moderating effect of perceived spatial crowding

on the relationship between perceived service encounter pace and customer satisfaction.

International Journal of Hospitality Management. 65, 37-46

Song, M., Noone, B. M., & Mattila, A. S. (In press). A tale of two cultures: Consumer

reactance and willingness to book fenced rates. Journal of Travel Research.

Song, M., Noone, B. M., & Han. J. R. An examination of the role of booking lead time in

consumers’ reactions to online scarcity messages (Under review in International Journal

of Hospitality Management).