57
Executive Compensation in Widely-Held US Firms ESNIE 2007 Jesse Fried Boalt Hall School of Law U.C. Berkeley

Executive Compensation in Widely-Held US Firms ESNIE 2007 Jesse Fried Boalt Hall School of Law U.C. Berkeley

  • View
    214

  • Download
    1

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Executive Compensation in Widely-Held US Firms ESNIE 2007 Jesse Fried Boalt Hall School of Law U.C. Berkeley

Executive Compensation in Widely-Held US Firms

ESNIE 2007

Jesse FriedBoalt Hall School of Law

U.C. Berkeley

Page 2: Executive Compensation in Widely-Held US Firms ESNIE 2007 Jesse Fried Boalt Hall School of Law U.C. Berkeley

Overview of Presentation

Why study U.S. CEO pay? 2 conflicting views

classical “optimal contracting” “managerial power” approach

Managerial power approach: in depth Sources of power “Outrage Constraint” & “Camouflage” Costs to shareholders Policy implications

Page 3: Executive Compensation in Widely-Held US Firms ESNIE 2007 Jesse Fried Boalt Hall School of Law U.C. Berkeley

A picture is worth 1000 words

Page 4: Executive Compensation in Widely-Held US Firms ESNIE 2007 Jesse Fried Boalt Hall School of Law U.C. Berkeley

Why study U.S. CEO pay? Economic importance

Amounts Incentive effects

Managerial effort Decision-making

Window into functioning of U.S. corporate governance system generally

Theoretical interest Setting for testing agency/governance/labor market

theories Good data (public firms)

Interaction among economics/social norms /political & legal institutions

Public fascination

Page 5: Executive Compensation in Widely-Held US Firms ESNIE 2007 Jesse Fried Boalt Hall School of Law U.C. Berkeley

Two views of CEO pay Optimal contracting approach

E.g., Murphy (1999); Core, Guay & Larcker (2001); Gabaix & Landier (2007); Kaplan (2007)

Managerial power approach E.g. Bebchuk & Fried (2002,03,04,05);

Yermack (1997); Bertrand & Mullainathan (2001); Blanchard & Lopez-de-Silanes & Shleifer (1994)

Page 6: Executive Compensation in Widely-Held US Firms ESNIE 2007 Jesse Fried Boalt Hall School of Law U.C. Berkeley

Shared premise of both views Managerial agency problem

Managers of widely-held public firms have significant power

Berle & Means (1932) Jensen & Meckling (1976): “agency problem”

Managers use power to benefit selves Empire building (Jensen, 1974; Williamson, 1964) Failure to distribute excess cash (Jensen, 1986) Entrenchment (Shleifer & Vishny, 1989)

Page 7: Executive Compensation in Widely-Held US Firms ESNIE 2007 Jesse Fried Boalt Hall School of Law U.C. Berkeley

Optimal K Approach Classical financial economic view Executive pay is remedy to agency

problem Boards design pay scheme to

Compensate and retain executives Incentivize managers to increase

shareholder value Main flaw: due to political limitations on

pay amounts, CEOs pay may be insufficiently high powered Jensen & Murphy, 1990; Kaplan 2006

Page 8: Executive Compensation in Widely-Held US Firms ESNIE 2007 Jesse Fried Boalt Hall School of Law U.C. Berkeley

Managerial Power Approach

Executive compensation is potential remedy to managerial agency problem

But it is also part of the agency problem itself Managers use their positional power to get

pay excessive too decoupled from own performance

weakens incentives to generate shareholder value perverts incentives

Arrangements deviate from optimal K

Page 9: Executive Compensation in Widely-Held US Firms ESNIE 2007 Jesse Fried Boalt Hall School of Law U.C. Berkeley

Managerial power approach

Sources of Managerial Power “Outrage constraint” “Camouflage” Pay Distortions Going forward: what should be

done

Page 10: Executive Compensation in Widely-Held US Firms ESNIE 2007 Jesse Fried Boalt Hall School of Law U.C. Berkeley

Sources of Managerial Power (1)

Optimal K assumes arm’s length bargaining b/w board & CEO

But why? if they assume executives not “hard-

wired” to serve shareholders, why should they presume directors will automatically seek to do so?

Page 11: Executive Compensation in Widely-Held US Firms ESNIE 2007 Jesse Fried Boalt Hall School of Law U.C. Berkeley

Sources of Managerial Power (2)

CEOs have power over directors Economic Incentives

directorship: $200K, perks, prestige, connections Until now, CEOs control renomination to board

Social factors Collegiality Loyalty Cognitive dissonance (directors are current/former

executives) Personal costs of favoring executives are

small

Page 12: Executive Compensation in Widely-Held US Firms ESNIE 2007 Jesse Fried Boalt Hall School of Law U.C. Berkeley

Result of Managerial Power

Managers want pay that is Higher More decoupled from performance (easier to

get)

Boards routinely approve executive pay deals that do not serve shareholders Pay likely too high Pay decoupled from performance

Dilutes incentives Distort incentives

Page 13: Executive Compensation in Widely-Held US Firms ESNIE 2007 Jesse Fried Boalt Hall School of Law U.C. Berkeley

Only a slight exaggeration…

Page 14: Executive Compensation in Widely-Held US Firms ESNIE 2007 Jesse Fried Boalt Hall School of Law U.C. Berkeley

Evidence of power-pay effects CEO pay higher, less performance-

based when board weaker

Larger board, more “independent” directors appt’d by CEO, directors serving on multiple boards, CEO is board chair (Core, Holthausen & Larcker, 1999)

no large outside shareholder eg Lambert, Leicker, Weigelt 1993

fewer “pressure-resistant” institutional shareholders

David, Kochar, Levitas 1998 more anti-takeover provisions

Borokhovich, Brunarski, Parrino 1997

Page 15: Executive Compensation in Widely-Held US Firms ESNIE 2007 Jesse Fried Boalt Hall School of Law U.C. Berkeley

Constraints on Managerial Power? (1)

Corporate law? State corporate law defers to board

compensation decisions under “business judgment rule” (e.g. Disney)

Takeover market discipline?

Staggered boards Courts allow “poison pills”

Hostile takeovers expensive, rare

Page 16: Executive Compensation in Widely-Held US Firms ESNIE 2007 Jesse Fried Boalt Hall School of Law U.C. Berkeley

Constraints on Power? (2) Election of new directors?

Corporation sends out proxy materials with names of board nominees

Check “yes” or “withhold” Send proxy back to company to be voted “yes” or

“withhold” Unless competing proxy, 1 “yes” vote gets director

elected under “plurality voting rule” Don’t need approval of majority of votes, just plurality

No competing proxies Costs of mailing competing proxy high

Managers won’t release shareholder list Collective action problem

Result: 99% elections uncontested

Page 17: Executive Compensation in Widely-Held US Firms ESNIE 2007 Jesse Fried Boalt Hall School of Law U.C. Berkeley

“Outrage Constraint”

Outrage Constraint

Boards’ main constraint: adverse publicity and “outrage”

Outrage imposes social and economic costs embarrassment shareholders more likely to support (rare)

challenge to management Evidence of publicity’s effect

Thomas & Martin (1999) Dyck & Zingales (2004) Wu (2004)

Page 18: Executive Compensation in Widely-Held US Firms ESNIE 2007 Jesse Fried Boalt Hall School of Law U.C. Berkeley

“Camouflage”

Fear of outrage leads firms to “camouflage” pay

Pay designers try to obscure and legitimize

amount of pay performance-insensitivity

Page 19: Executive Compensation in Widely-Held US Firms ESNIE 2007 Jesse Fried Boalt Hall School of Law U.C. Berkeley

Camouflage pre-1992: An SEC official describes the pre-1992 state of affairs

as follows:

“The information [in the executive compensation section] was wholly unintelligible . . . .

Depending on the company’s attitude toward disclosure, you might get reference to a $3,500,081 pay package spelled out rather than in numbers. ……….

Someone once gave a series of institutional investor analysts a proxy statement and asked them to compute the compensation received by the executives covered in the proxy statement. No two analysts came up with the same number. The numbers that were calculated varied widely.”[1]

[1].Linda C. Quinn, Executive Compensation under the New SEC Disclosure Requirements, 63 U. Cin. L. Rev. 769, 770-71 (1995).

Page 20: Executive Compensation in Widely-Held US Firms ESNIE 2007 Jesse Fried Boalt Hall School of Law U.C. Berkeley

1992: Summary Pay Table (SEC)

Firms required to clearly report most forms of compensation in tables with dollar amounts Salary Bonus Stock options (number) Long-term incentive compensation

Comp table became focus of Media, economists, shareholders

Page 21: Executive Compensation in Widely-Held US Firms ESNIE 2007 Jesse Fried Boalt Hall School of Law U.C. Berkeley

Post 1992 Camouflage

Pay designers began relying heavily on

forms of compensation not reportable in any column in comp table

post-exit payments (e.g. pensions, golden parachutes) low-interest loans (Worldcom: $400 million)

performance-insensitive compensation that

can be reported as something other than “salary”

E.g.: “guaranteed bonus”

Page 22: Executive Compensation in Widely-Held US Firms ESNIE 2007 Jesse Fried Boalt Hall School of Law U.C. Berkeley

Other CEO pay distortions (1)

Non-equity pay weakly linked to performance

often driven by luck (e.g. oil company earnings)

bonuses have low “goalposts” often tied to manipulable metrics (accounting

earnings)

Page 23: Executive Compensation in Widely-Held US Firms ESNIE 2007 Jesse Fried Boalt Hall School of Law U.C. Berkeley

Other CEO pay distortions (2) Equity pay

Option plans fail to filter out windfalls Most stock price increases do not reflect

Firm-specific factor CEO’s contribution

Firms could use market/sector-based indexing but don’t

Backdating accentuates windfalls Few restrictions on unwinding

Managers not required to hold shares (diluting incentives)

Can sell on inside information (perverting incentives)

Page 24: Executive Compensation in Widely-Held US Firms ESNIE 2007 Jesse Fried Boalt Hall School of Law U.C. Berkeley

Costs to shareholders Direct

Top-5 pay = 10% of aggregate corporate earnings during 2001-2003

Bebchuk & Grinstein (2005) up from 5% during 1993-1995

Indirect Perverted incentives, e.g

Size justifies pay: incentive to acquire Manipulate earnings to sell at high price

Fannie Mae spent $1 billion cleaning up accounting

Page 25: Executive Compensation in Widely-Held US Firms ESNIE 2007 Jesse Fried Boalt Hall School of Law U.C. Berkeley

Going Forward: What Should Be Done ? (1)

Transparency Outrage constraint currently main check

on managerial power Constraint depends on transparency SEC must track efforts by pay designers

to get around new disclosure rules

Page 26: Executive Compensation in Widely-Held US Firms ESNIE 2007 Jesse Fried Boalt Hall School of Law U.C. Berkeley

2006 Disclosure Rules (SEC)

Improved summary table reporting Annual change in actuarial value of pension Total amount More detail

More transparent reporting of

Outstanding equity Post retirement payouts

More detailed rationale for pay package

Result: harder to camouflage compensation

Page 27: Executive Compensation in Widely-Held US Firms ESNIE 2007 Jesse Fried Boalt Hall School of Law U.C. Berkeley

What should be done (2) Increase shareholder power

Problem: managerial power Must counterbalance with more

shareholder power Should make it easier to replace

directors SEC could make companies turn proxy

material into corporate ballot with both management and shareholder candidates (like political election)

Dramatically lower cost so shareholders can cheaply replace bad directors

Page 28: Executive Compensation in Widely-Held US Firms ESNIE 2007 Jesse Fried Boalt Hall School of Law U.C. Berkeley

Some setbacks 2003: SEC chair supports

“shareholder access” to proxy statement Business execs pressure White House,

SEC chair resigns But fight is not over

Pressure many companies to adopt “majority vote” for individual directors

So shareholders can “punish” individual directors by withholding votes

Hedge funds becoming active

Page 29: Executive Compensation in Widely-Held US Firms ESNIE 2007 Jesse Fried Boalt Hall School of Law U.C. Berkeley

The future Further empowering shareholders

best hope for improving Executive compensation US corporate governance generally

THE END

Page 30: Executive Compensation in Widely-Held US Firms ESNIE 2007 Jesse Fried Boalt Hall School of Law U.C. Berkeley
Page 31: Executive Compensation in Widely-Held US Firms ESNIE 2007 Jesse Fried Boalt Hall School of Law U.C. Berkeley
Page 32: Executive Compensation in Widely-Held US Firms ESNIE 2007 Jesse Fried Boalt Hall School of Law U.C. Berkeley
Page 33: Executive Compensation in Widely-Held US Firms ESNIE 2007 Jesse Fried Boalt Hall School of Law U.C. Berkeley

Boards behaving better

CEO pay increases moderating Kaplan, 2007

CEO turnover increasing Kaplan & Minton, 2007

Page 34: Executive Compensation in Widely-Held US Firms ESNIE 2007 Jesse Fried Boalt Hall School of Law U.C. Berkeley

Congress

1993: Tax: Section 162(m)

2002: Sarbox Prohibition on loans Clawback

Page 35: Executive Compensation in Widely-Held US Firms ESNIE 2007 Jesse Fried Boalt Hall School of Law U.C. Berkeley

1993: IRC Section 162(m) Outcry in early 1990s that pay decoupled

from performance

Congress: “Non-performance” pay over $1m not deductible by company At-the-money options qualify as performance pay

Problem: does not address managerial

power Some managers continue to get more than $1m

salary Who is hurt?

Page 36: Executive Compensation in Widely-Held US Firms ESNIE 2007 Jesse Fried Boalt Hall School of Law U.C. Berkeley

Unintended effect of 162(m) Signals acceptability of

Salary up to $1 million Large option grants (Congress deems it

“performance comp”)

Used to justify total pay increase Below $1 million salaries rise to $1 million Option grants skyrocket

Bull market turns options into windfalls

Huge increase in actual non-performance pay

Page 37: Executive Compensation in Widely-Held US Firms ESNIE 2007 Jesse Fried Boalt Hall School of Law U.C. Berkeley

Congress: SarbOx 2002 Prohibition on loans

Outrage over huge, hidden low-cost loans 1920s proposal to ban loans resurrected Effect: disrupts efficient contracting

Clawback provision Return bonuses, stock proceeds

Following earnings misstatement caused by “misconduct”

Shareholder-serving boards should have done this on their own

Not yet applied

Page 38: Executive Compensation in Widely-Held US Firms ESNIE 2007 Jesse Fried Boalt Hall School of Law U.C. Berkeley

End

Page 39: Executive Compensation in Widely-Held US Firms ESNIE 2007 Jesse Fried Boalt Hall School of Law U.C. Berkeley

Pay without Performance

Jesse FriedMarch 7, 2006

Berkeley

For fuller exposition of views on the

subject: Pay without

Performance (Harvard University Press,

2004)

Page 40: Executive Compensation in Widely-Held US Firms ESNIE 2007 Jesse Fried Boalt Hall School of Law U.C. Berkeley

Going Forward: Making Directors More Accountable to Shareholders

We should make it easier for shareholders to replace directors E.g., giving shareholders access to

corporate ballot would reduce costs of challenging current board

Not a panacea – still collective action problem

but increasing probability of shareholder revolt will improve incentives

Page 41: Executive Compensation in Widely-Held US Firms ESNIE 2007 Jesse Fried Boalt Hall School of Law U.C. Berkeley

Making Directors More Accountable

By making boards accountable to shareholders and attentive to their interests, such reform would:

Make reality more like official story of arm’s length negotiations

Improve executive compensation arrangements Improve corporate governance more generally

Page 42: Executive Compensation in Widely-Held US Firms ESNIE 2007 Jesse Fried Boalt Hall School of Law U.C. Berkeley

Decoupling Pay from Performance (1)

Rise in executive compensation has been justified as necessary to strengthen incentives

Financial economists have applauded: Shareholders should care more about incentives than about the amount paid executives.“It’s not how much you pay, but how” (Jensen

& Murphy, 1990) Institutional investors have accepted higher

pay as price of improving managers’ incentives

Page 43: Executive Compensation in Widely-Held US Firms ESNIE 2007 Jesse Fried Boalt Hall School of Law U.C. Berkeley

Decoupling Pay and performance (2)

But the devil is in the details: managers’

compensation is less linked to performance than is commonly appreciated.

Managers’ own performance does not explain much of the cross-sectional variation in managers’ compensation.

Firms could have generated the same increase in incentives at much lower cost, or used the same amount to generate stronger incentives

Page 44: Executive Compensation in Widely-Held US Firms ESNIE 2007 Jesse Fried Boalt Hall School of Law U.C. Berkeley

Decoupling Pay from performance (3)

Factors contributing to the weak link between

pay and managers’ own performance:(1) The historically weak link between bonus

payments and long-term stock returns. (2) The large amounts given through

performance-insensitive retirement benefits.

(3) The large fraction of gains from equity-based compensation resulting from market-wide and industry-wide movements.

Page 45: Executive Compensation in Widely-Held US Firms ESNIE 2007 Jesse Fried Boalt Hall School of Law U.C. Berkeley

Decoupling Pay from Performance (4)

(4) Practices of “back-door re-pricing” and

reload options that enable gains even when long-term stock returns are flat.

(5) Executives’ broad freedom to unload vested options/restricted stock.

(6) “Soft landing” arrangements for pushed out executives that reduce the payoff differences between good performance and failure.

And more …

Page 46: Executive Compensation in Widely-Held US Firms ESNIE 2007 Jesse Fried Boalt Hall School of Law U.C. Berkeley

Paying for performance (1)

Reduce windfalls from equity-based compensation:

Filter out some or all of the gains resulting from market-wide or sector-wide movements.

Can be done in various ways; indexing is only one option.

Move to restricted stock increases windfalls – restricted stock is an option with an exercise price of zero.

Page 47: Executive Compensation in Widely-Held US Firms ESNIE 2007 Jesse Fried Boalt Hall School of Law U.C. Berkeley

Paying for performance (2)

Reduce windfalls from bonus compensation:

Filter out some or all of the improvements in accounting performance resulting from market-wide or sector-wide movements.

[E.g., look at increase in earnings relative to peers.]

Page 48: Executive Compensation in Widely-Held US Firms ESNIE 2007 Jesse Fried Boalt Hall School of Law U.C. Berkeley

Paying for performance (3)

Tie equity-based compensation to long-term values:

Separate vesting and freedom to unload: require holding for several years after vesting (even until/after retirement).

Prohibit contractually any hedging or other scheme that effectively unloads some of the exposure to firm returns.

Limit the ability of serving executives to time sales.

Page 49: Executive Compensation in Widely-Held US Firms ESNIE 2007 Jesse Fried Boalt Hall School of Law U.C. Berkeley

Paying for performance (4)Tie the performance-based component of non-

equity compensation to long-term values: Assuming it is desirable to link pay to

improvement in some accounting measures, don’t link to short-term (e.g., annual) changes – can lead to gaming and distortions or at least to decoupling of pay from long-term changes in value.

Claw-back provisions that reverse payments made on the basis of restated financial figures: “if it wasn’t earned it must be returned.”

Page 50: Executive Compensation in Widely-Held US Firms ESNIE 2007 Jesse Fried Boalt Hall School of Law U.C. Berkeley

Paying for Performance (5)

Rethink termination arrangements:

Current arrangements provide “soft landing” in any termination that is not for fault, defined extremely narrowly. This is costly – reduces the payoff difference between good and poor performance.

Consider:-- Broadening the definition of “for cause” termination-- Making the severance payment depend on the

performance during the executive’s service.

Page 51: Executive Compensation in Widely-Held US Firms ESNIE 2007 Jesse Fried Boalt Hall School of Law U.C. Berkeley

Easy for companies to fix: Company should include in annual

proxy statement: increase in value of retirement entitlement

from last year and its current value

Improving Transparency

Page 52: Executive Compensation in Widely-Held US Firms ESNIE 2007 Jesse Fried Boalt Hall School of Law U.C. Berkeley

Improving transparency (2)

Another important instance of opaqueness: deferred compensation arrangements.

Benefit executives by providing tax-free buildup of investment gains.

Outsiders cannot make even a rough approximation of value

Firms can easily make these benefits transparent.

Page 53: Executive Compensation in Widely-Held US Firms ESNIE 2007 Jesse Fried Boalt Hall School of Law U.C. Berkeley

Board Accountability

Recent reforms emphasize strengthening director independence from executives.

Strengthened independence is beneficial but it is an insufficient foundation for board accountability.

For each company, vast number of individuals could be considered “independent directors.” Two key questions

(1) Who is selected from this vast pool? (2) What will their incentives be once appointed?

Strengthened independence eliminates some people from pool, reduces bad incentives for those appointed. But does not fully answer (1) and (2)

Page 54: Executive Compensation in Widely-Held US Firms ESNIE 2007 Jesse Fried Boalt Hall School of Law U.C. Berkeley

Board Accountability (2)

We should make directors not only more independent of executives, but also make them more accountable to shareholders

What we need is reduced insulation from shareholders.

Can be done in a way that does not provide distraction and short-terms focus

Page 55: Executive Compensation in Widely-Held US Firms ESNIE 2007 Jesse Fried Boalt Hall School of Law U.C. Berkeley

Improving Board Accountability

Make shareholder power to remove directors real (even if weak).

Election reform: (1) Adopt procedure for shareholder nomination of directors(2) Provide company reimbursement for shareholders whose nominees receive sufficient shareholder support.

Page 56: Executive Compensation in Widely-Held US Firms ESNIE 2007 Jesse Fried Boalt Hall School of Law U.C. Berkeley

Improving board accountability (2)

Remove charter-based staggered boards, which prevent shareholders from ever replacing a majority of the directors in one vote.

• Evidence staggered boards are associated with 4-5% lower firm value • [ Bebchuk and Cohen, The Costs of

Entrenched Boards, JFE, 2005]

Page 57: Executive Compensation in Widely-Held US Firms ESNIE 2007 Jesse Fried Boalt Hall School of Law U.C. Berkeley

Conclusion

There is much that can be done – and should be done – to link pay more closely to performance.