236
Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt A thesis submitted to The University of Manchester for the Degree of Doctor of Philosophy in the Faculty of Humanities 2016 Adams Sorekuong Yakubu Adama Department of Economics, School of Social Sciences

Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    2

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign

Debt

A thesis submitted to The University of Manchester for the Degree of

Doctor of Philosophy

in the Faculty of Humanities

2016

Adams Sorekuong Yakubu Adama

Department of Economics,

School of Social Sciences

Page 2: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

Contents

Abstract 9

Declaration 10

Copyright Statement 11

Dedication 12

Acknowledgments 13

1 Thesis Introduction 15

2 Corruption and Political Turnover in a Sovereign Default Model 22

2.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 22

2.1.1 Related Literature . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 25

2.2 Empirical Observations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 29

2.2.1 Data Sample . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 29

2.2.2 Model Specification . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 34

2.2.3 Results . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 35

2.2.4 Discussion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 39

2.3 The Theoretical Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 41

2.3.1 The Government’s Decision Problem . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 41

2.3.2 Solution . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 44

2.3.3 Bond Price . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 46

2.3.4 Equilibrium . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 47

1

Page 3: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

2.4 Results . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 48

2.4.1 Calibration . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 48

2.4.2 Corruption, Political Risk and Default Risk . . . . . . . . . . . 49

2.4.3 Corruption, Welfare and Consumption . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 58

2.4.4 Characteristics of Debt and Spread around Defaults . . . . . . . 59

2.4.5 Output and Default . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 62

2.4.6 Corruption, Political Turnover and Business Cycle Statistics . . 63

2.5 Conclusion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 69

2.6 Appendix A . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 70

2.6.1 Computational Method . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 70

2.6.2 Consumption Equivalent Welfare Loss . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 71

2.7 Appendix B . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 71

2.7.1 List of Tables . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 71

3 Limited Contract Enforcement and Firm Financing 77

3.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 77

3.2 Empirical Observations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 81

3.2.1 Data and Methodology . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 82

3.2.2 Results . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 85

3.3 The Investment Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 87

3.3.1 The Financial Contract . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 87

3.3.2 The General Equilibrium Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 92

3.3.3 Calibration and Results . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 100

3.4 Concluding Remarks . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 115

3.5 Appendix A . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 117

3.5.1 Household Optimisation Problem . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 117

3.5.2 Consumption-good Producing Firms . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 118

3.5.3 The Entrepreneur . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 118

3.5.4 Optimal contract . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 119

3.5.5 Consumption Equivalent Welfare Loss . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 120

2

Page 4: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

3.5.6 Steady State . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 121

3.6 Appendix B . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 124

3.6.1 Tables . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 124

3.6.2 Figures . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 126

4 Thesis Conclusion 131

Bibliography 133

A Computer Codes 149

A.1 Chapter 2 Computer Codes . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 149

A.1.1 STATA CODES . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 149

A.1.2 FORTRAN CODES . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 152

A.1.3 MATLAB CODES . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 216

A.2 Chapter 3 Computer Codes . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 228

A.2.1 STATA CODES . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 228

A.2.2 DYNARE CODES . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 231

3

Page 5: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

List of Tables

2.4.1.1 Calibration . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 50

2.4.3.1 Average Consumption Equivalent Welfare Loss . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 59

2.4.5.1 Fraction of Default Episodes above Long-Run Mean . . . . . . . . . . . 63

2.4.6.1 Business Cycle Statistics . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 66

2.4.6.2 Default Risk Statistics . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 68

2.7.1.1 Sample of Defaulting and Debt Rescheduling Countries Used for Panel

Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 72

2.7.1.2 Variables for Empirical Work . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 73

2.7.1.3 Summary Statistics . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 74

2.7.1.4 Probit models; dependent variable: Default - (excluding lagged default) 74

2.7.1.5 Probit models; dependent variable: Default - (excluding lagged default) 75

2.7.1.6 Probit models; dependent variable: Default - (including lagged default) 75

2.7.1.7 Mean Number of Defaults Given Change in Type . . . . . . . . . . . . 76

3.3.3.1 Calibration . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 101

3.3.3.2 Productivity Shock . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 113

3.3.3.3 One-Time Wealth Transfer . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 114

3.3.3.4 Welfare loss . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 114

3.3.3.5 Effect of Limited Enforcement and Monitoring Cost on Output . . . . . 115

3.6.1.1 Countries for Empirical Work . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 124

3.6.1.2 Continuation of Countries for Empirical Work . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 125

3.6.1.3 Summary statistics . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 125

3.6.1.4 Fixed and Random Effects Regression for Full Sample(57 Countries) . . 127

4

Page 6: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

3.6.1.5 Fixed and Random Effects Regression for Full Sample(57 Countries) . . 128

3.6.1.6 Fixed and Random Effects Regression(34 Countries) . . . . . . . . . . . 129

3.6.1.7 Fixed and Random Effects Regression (34 Countries) . . . . . . . . . . . 130

5

Page 7: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

List of Figures

2.4.2.1 Value functions in a stable economy under less and more corrupt govern-

ments . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 52

2.4.2.2 Default space against bond issuance and endowment . . . . . . . . . . . 53

2.4.2.3 Bond price for less corrupt government . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 55

2.4.2.4 Objective function of a less corrupt government . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 57

2.4.2.5 Optimal bond issuance . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 58

2.4.4.1 Average issuance level before and after a default . . . . . . . . . . . . . 60

2.4.4.2 Bond price faced by a more corrupt government . . . . . . . . . . . . . 61

2.4.4.3 Average spread before and after a default . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 62

3.2.1.1 Scatter Plot of Real GDP, Credit Information and Contract Enforcement 83

3.2.1.2 Scatter: Standard Deviation of GDP and Contract Enforcement . . . . 84

3.3.3.1 Impulse responses from a positive technology shock. The vertical axis

measures percentage deviations from the steady state. The horizontal

axis measures time in quarters. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 103

3.3.3.2 Relationship between expected leverage, expected risk premium and lim-

ited enforcement in response to productivity shocks. . . . . . . . . . . . 104

3.3.3.3 Impulse responses from a positive technology shock. The vertical axis

measures percentage deviations from the steady state. The horizontal

axis measures time in quarters. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 105

3.3.3.4 Relationship between expected investment and limited enforcement in

response to productivity shocks. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 106

6

Page 8: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

3.3.3.5 Impulse responses from a negative shock to net worth. The vertical axis

measures percentage deviations from the steady state. The horizontal

axis measures time in quarters. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 108

3.3.3.6 Relationship between expected leverage, expected risk premium and lim-

ited enforcement in response to net worth shocks. . . . . . . . . . . . . 109

3.3.3.7 Impulse responses from a negative shock to net worth. The vertical axis

measures percentage deviations from the steady state. The horizontal

axis measures time in quarters. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 110

3.3.3.8 Relationship between expected investment and limited enforcement in

response to net worth shocks. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 111

3.6.2.1 Scatter: Standard Deviation of GDP and Contract Enforcement . . . . 126

7

Page 9: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

Listings

A.1 Stata Do File . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 149

A.2 Value Function Iteration . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 152

A.3 Simulation of Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 172

A.4 Main Program: Driver for Iteration and Simulation . . . . . . . . . . . 179

A.5 Grid Construction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 182

A.6 Model Tools . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 187

A.7 Data Output . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 191

A.8 Array Tools . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 205

A.9 Input Parameters . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 214

A.10 Matlab Codes for plots and statistics . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 216

A.11 Matlab function for importing simulated data for plots . . . . . . . . . 226

A.12 Stata Do file . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 228

A.13 Dynare code . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 231

Word Count: 40,093

8

Page 10: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

Abstract

The University of Manchester

Adams Sorekuong Yakubu Adama

Doctor of Philosophy (PhD) in Economics

Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and SovereignDebt

24th October 2016

This thesis explores the effects of institutions on macroeconomic performance. Itdoes so in two main chapters, a summary of each of which is given below. In the firstmain chapter of the thesis, the interactions between government spending, governmentborrowing, political corruption and political turnover were examined. Incorporatingthese factors in a sovereign default model, we show how sovereign default decisions andbusiness cycle fluctuations are affected by the level of corruption. In particular, we showthat when there is turnover, corruption can generate higher risks of default and highercredit spreads when there is enough stability. Intuitively, we establish that a changein power from a less corrupt to a more corrupt government is more likely to causedefault than the reverse. The results also shows that households suffer welfare lossesas a result of corruption. As regards business cycles, the general effect of corruption isto alter business cycle statistics. Further, we estimate an empirical model using dataon sovereign default, corruption, political stability and other macroeconomic variablesfor a sample of emerging economies. The results of this provide strong evidence ofa positive relationship between both corruption and political stability and sovereigndefault.

The second main chapter of the thesis looks at the effects of limited financialcontract enforcement in a dynamic stochastic general equilibrium framework wherefirms have access to both internal and external means of finance. The results showshow limited enforceability affects fluctuations in key macroeconomic variables (e.g.,output, employment and price) through its impact on key financial variables (e.g.,interest rates, risk premium, default risk and leverage). In particular, we find thatweaker enforcement tends to amplify the effects of shocks, creating greater volatility,as well as lowering small firm funding. We provide some empirical evidence to supportour results. Using cross-country data on measures of financial market imperfections,we find that limited enforcement has a negative effect on output and that this effect isexacerbated by poor credit information. We also find that weaker contract enforcementis associated with higher output volatility.

9

Page 11: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

Declaration

I, Adams Sorekuong Yakubu Adama, hereby declare that no portion of the work re-

ferred to in the thesis has been submitted in support of an application for another

degree or qualification of this or any other university or other institute of learning.

10

Page 12: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

Copyright Statement

i. The author of this thesis (including any appendices and/or schedules to this

thesis) owns certain copyright or related rights in it (the “Copyright”) and he

has given The University of Manchester certain rights to use such Copyright,

including for administrative purposes.

ii. Copies of this thesis, either in full or in extracts and whether in hard or electronic

copy, may be made only in accordance with the Copyright, Designs and Patents

Act 1988 (as amended) and regulations issued under it or, where appropriate,

in accordance with licensing agreements which the University has from time to

time. This page must form part of any such copies made.

iii. The ownership of certain Copyright, patents, designs, trademarks and other in-

tellectual property ( the “Intellectual Property” ) and any reproductions of copy-

right works in the thesis, for example graphs and tables ( “Reproductions” ),

which may be described in this thesis, may not be owned by the author and may

be owned by third parties. Such Intellectual Property and Reproductions cannot

and must not be made available for use without the prior written permission of

the owner(s) of the relevant Intellectual Property and/or Reproductions.

iv. Further information on the conditions under which disclosure, publication and

commercialisation of this thesis, the Copyright and any Intellectual Property

and/or Reproductions described in it may take place is available in the Uni-

versity IP Policy (see http://www.documents.manchester.ac.uk/DocuInfo.aspx?-

DocID=487), in any relevant Thesis restriction declarations deposited in the

University Library, The University Library’s regulations (see http://www.man-

chester.ac.uk/library/aboutus/regulations ) and in The University’s policy on

Presentation of Theses.

11

Page 13: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

Dedication

To the loving memory of my late God-father, Alhaji Abdul-Rahman Musah

a.k.a Mba Musah (Wilhem)

&

To the loving memory of my late father, Naa Adama Saaka.

12

Page 14: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

Acknowledgments

Pursuing a doctoral degree in economics is a long and sometimes a tough journey. I

would first and foremost thank the Almighty God for His guidance throughout this

Ph.D journey. I would also like to thank all those who made this journey a joyful one.

In particular, I am greatly indebted to my supervisors, Professor Keith Blackburn, Dr.

Macnamara and Dr. Michele Berardi, for their constructive comments, suggestions,

support and guidance throughout my research. I would also like to thank them for

their time and energy spent reading through the draft copies of this thesis. I wish also

to thank the School of Social Sciences and the Economics Department for funding my

Ph.D programme.

I must also express my profound gratitude to all my friends at the Department

of Economics, the University of Manchester for all the insightful discussions we shared.

Special thanks go to Dr. Zeeshan Atiq and Dr. Johnson Gwatipedza for their invaluable

input and comments on the final draft of the thesis. I especially want to also thank

Dr. Abdilahi Ali for always being there for me whenever I needed him.

Indeed, many friends not from the Department of Economics, the University of

Manchester also contributed to the success of my Ph.D programme. Thanks go to

Dr. Justice Bawole, Dr. Hamza Bukari, Mr. Anthony Kumasey and Dr. Francis

Sanyare for their supports and inspirations during the challenging and great moments

we shared together as Ph.D candidates. I will also like to thank my neighbours at

Manchester; Sister Fatima Momori and her family, Mujeeb Iddrisu and his family, and

most especially Mr. Juda of Global African Limited for their support throughout my

Ph.D programme. I also say thank you to some important people in my life: Alhaji

Issifu Ali, Maulvi Gaffar and his family, Maulvi Bin Salih and his family, Mr. Nasir

Moomin, Mrs. Zainab Moomin, Hon. Godfred Bayon Tangu, Hon. Alhaji Adams

Mahama Issahaku (Okonkwo), Mr. Kassim Tangu Seidu, Mr. Theophilus Ofei Tetteh,

Mr. Adamu Jighi, Auntie Fati Seidu, Sister Ramatu Imoru Seidu, Mr. Simms Mensah

Kyei and his family, Dr. Samuel K. Annim and Dr. Pattick Asuming.

During my Ph.D programme, I had the opportunity to present my research (in-

cluding two of the chapters in this thesis) at international conferences including the

International the CSAE 26th Conference on Economic Development in Africa (Univer-

13

Page 15: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

sity of Oxford), 2nd Annual International Interdisciplinary Conference on Challenges

to Development in Africa (Catholic University, Nairobi, Kenya), the Royal Economic

Society (RES) 2015 conference. I also presented my work in a number of seminars

at the University of Manchester, especially the Center for Growth and Business Cycle

Research (CGBCR) and Macroeconomics RAG seminar series. I wish to acknowledge

the suggestions, critics and comments I received from the participants.

Last but not the least, I would like to thank my lovely wife, Zulaiha Abdulai

Sorekuong-Adama, and my lovely son, Angsomwine Ramiz Sorekuong-Adama, for their

love and sacrifices.

I wish to pay tribute to my late father, Naa Adama Saaka and my God-father,

the late Alhaji Abdul-Rahman Musah a.k.a Mba Musah (Wilhelm) for being a great

source of inspiration to me. This thesis is dedicated to them.

And to everyone who has supported me either directly or indirectly, have my

heartfelt gratitude.

14

Page 16: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

Chapter 1

Thesis Introduction

North (1989) defines institutions as “rules, enforcement characteristics of rules, and

norms of behaviour that structure repeated human interaction” (p.1321). In other con-

text, institutions are defined as humanly devised constraints that shape interaction

between people (see North (1990)). Fundamentally, in North’s view, the quality of

these institutions improves with limitations imposed on executive power. Generally,

institutional quality consists of certain key scopes such as voice and accountability,

political stability, rule of law, control of corruption, ease of doing business, regulatory

quality amongst others.

The importance of institutions in determining economic performance cannot be

underrated . By establishing clear and enforceable property rights, that minimise trans-

action costs and reduce the threat of coercion, good quality institutions can be decisive

in an economy’s prospects for growth and development. The importance of institutions

is well documented as is the diversity in institutional quality across different states (see

Knack and Keefer (1995); Rodrik et al. (2004); Hall and Jones (1999a)). Rodrik et al.

(2004) claim that good institutions is one of the most important factors to economic

development whilst Hall and Jones (1999a) find that cross-country differences in insti-

tutional quality are a major source of cross-country differences in capital accumulation,

productivity and per capita output.

The state is expected to provide the legal framework, infrastructure and stability

that is necessary for the creation of a favourable institutional environment. In many

15

Page 17: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

instances, however, the state often fails in this role, leaving room for rent-seeking

activities (see Elliott (1997); Infante and Smirnova (2009); Treisman (2003); Ofer

(2003)). There is empirical evidence that rent-seeking is related (positively) to in-

stitutional weakness (see Mauro (1995); Acemoglu and Johnson (2004)). Interestingly,

rent-seeking could represent a mechanism that might improve economic performance

in the presence of weak institutions. This is the so-called “speed money” hypothesis,

according to which bribes paid to public officials may be a means of circumventing

cumbersome rules and regulations (red tape) that impede business efficiency. From a

different perspective, it has been argued that rent-seeking may be the necessary price to

pay for correcting institutional weaknesses. In other words, society may face a trade-off

between government failure and market failure (see Acemoglu and Verdier (1998, 2000);

Djankov et al. (2003); Acemoglu and Johnson (2004); Infante and Smirnova (2009)).

Acemoglu et al. (2003) in their study of the effect of institutions on macroeconomic

policies observed that there are deeper institutional causes of economic instability and

poor macroeconomic performance, such as law and order.

One manifestation of weak institutions is corruption. Though there is no one

acceptable definition of corruption, Transparency International, generally, defines cor-

ruption as the abuse of entrusted power for private gain, by especially public sector

officials. Public sector corruption is defined by Blackburn et al. (2006) as “the abuse of

authority by bureaucratic officials who exploit their powers of discretion, delegated to

them by the government, to further their own interests by engaging in illegal, or unau-

thorised, rent-seeking activities” (p.2448). It is in this light that the World Bank1 ar-

gues that corruption is “the single greatest obstacle to economic and social development.

It undermines development by distorting the rule of law and weakening the institutional

foundation on which economic growth depends”. The relationship between corruption

and other macroeconomic variables has been studied extensively in the literature (see

Mauro (1995); Knack and Keefer (1995); Li et al. (2000); Dreher and Herzfeld (2005)).

Mauro (1995) conducts an empirical investigation into the relationship between corrup-

1http://www.worldbank.org/

16

Page 18: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

tion and economic growth, concluding that corruption has a significant negative impact

on investment. Knack and Keefer (1995) and Li et al. (2000) find similar results, as do

Dreher and Herzfeld (2005) who calculated that an increase in International Country

Risk Guide (ICRG) index of corruption by one point reduces growth by 0.13% points

and GDP per capita by US$ 425. Corruption can also have distributional effects, with

several studies identifying a positive correlation between the level of corruption and

the degree of income inequality (see Li et al. (2000)).

One of the major channels through which corruption can affect growth is its im-

pact on public policy. There are many ways in which this might occur, some more direct

than others. On one side of the government’s balance sheet, corruption can cause a

misallocation of public expenditures away from growth-promoting areas (such as edu-

cation and health) towards bribe-generating areas (such as military and defence) (see

Gupta et al. (2001); Mauro (1998); Tanzi and Davoodi (1997)). For the same reason,

expenditures may be misallocated away from the most to the least cost-effective means

of public procurement, producing inefficient and inflated levels of spending (see Black-

burn et al. (2011)). On the other side of the balance sheet, corruption can lead to a

loss of tax revenues and other public funds, as evidenced in a number of studies (see

Tanzi and Davoodi (2000, 1997); Ghura (1998); Imam and Jacobs (2014)). This may

compromise the delivery of pro-growth social programmes and, in doing so, weaken in-

dividuals’ incentives to save and invest (see Blackburn and Sarmah (2008)). It may also

force the government to raise taxes or to seek additional means of distortionary finance,

including inflationary finance (see Al-Marhubi (2000); Blackburn and Powell (2011b)).

In a different vein, corruption in regulation can cause a dilution of property rights and

an escalation of the costs of doing business, each of which may impede innovation and

entrepreneurship (see Hall and Jones (1999b); North (1990); Sarte (2000)).

Beyond public policy, there are other ways in which corruption can affect eco-

nomic performance. One of these is by inducing a misallocation of talent away from

productive (entrepreneurial) activities towards non-productive (rent-seeking) activities

(see Ehrlich and Lui (1999); Murphy et al. (1991)). Another is by imposing deadweight

17

Page 19: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

losses on society through the costs of trying to conceal and expose corrupt behaviour

(see Blackburn et al. (2006); Blackburn and Forgues-Puccio (2007)).

Corruption can affect other macroeconomic variables and other aspects of mac-

roeconomic policy. Of particular interest to this thesis is the effect of corruption on

government finance especially when the government relies heavily on borrowing. Cor-

rupt public officials may confiscate loaned funds or block other sources of government

income, thereby limiting the government’s ability to meet its debt obligation. For in-

stance in Russia more than US$4 billion in IMF loans was believed to have disappeared

shortly before Russia’s default in 1998 (see Ciocchini et al. (2003)). Work by Haque

and Sahay (1996), Tanzi and Davoodi (1997), and Johnson et al. (1999) shows that

higher levels of corruption are associated with lower tax revenue, which could other-

wise be used by the government to repay its debt. Ciocchini et al. (2003) investigate

the effect of corruption on sovereign bond spreads, observing that higher levels of cor-

ruption are associated with higher spreads. The same authors observe that corrupt

governments require high liquidity which induces them to borrow even under very high

spreads. Transparency International reported that corruption was one of the triggers

of the Greek2 debt crisis (see Corruption triggered Greek Debt Crisis-Transparency

International).

Another issue that is particularly relevant to this thesis is the effect of institutional

weaknesses on the functioning of financial markets. Good legal institutions (rule of law

in the form of quality of property rights, contract enforcement, the police, and the

courts etc.) are generally argued to be essential for fostering financial development.

Such institutions play a vital role in protecting investors through the enforcement of

property rights and contractual arrangements. This creates room for risk sharing and

a willingness of investors to supply funds to firms (see La Porta et al. (1997); Lopez de

Silanes et al. (1998); La Porta et al. (2000)). Albuquerque and Hopenhayn (2000)

argue that better enforcement of contracts has serious implication for the funding of

small firms and growth. Yet, the inability of these legal institutions to enforce financial

2http://www.spiegel.de/international/europe/european-debt-crisis-greek-corruption-booming-says-transparency-international-a-681184.html

18

Page 20: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

contracts is what we refer to as weak (limited or imperfect) contract enforcement. That

is to say, limited contract enforcement is the difficulty with which lenders can recover

defaulted loans. Others, including the World Bank, have likened (limited) contract

enforcement to the time and cost for resolving commercial dispute through courts–cost

of contract enforcement.

In light of the foregoing discussion, this thesis is broadly concerned with the rela-

tionship between institutional quality, government debt and firm funding together with

the implications of this for macroeconomic outcomes. The thesis seeks to contribute to

the (theoretical) literature on sovereign default by studying specifically the influence

of corruption and political turnover on sovereign default decisions. It does so within

the context of a Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium (DSGE) model which allows

for the random political turnover of alternative types of government that have differ-

ent propensities to be corrupt. We contribute to the empirical literature of sovereign

default by analysing the influence that corruption and political factors could exert on

sovereign default risk. We distinguish between corruption and political stability (which

is not done in the literature (see Chapter (2) for details) in order to investigate the

influence that each independently exerts on sovereign default. We contribute to lit-

erature on financial development by studying the upshot of limited financial contract

enforcement (institutions) on financial markets and macroeconomic outcomes. Spe-

cifically, our first line of contribution is to the literature on agency costs, asymmetric

information and financial development where we study the role of limited contract en-

forcement in a Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium (DSGE) framework. We do

so by allowing for the possibility of the firm being able to default on bank loans when

it is still solvent, though a defaulting firm faces the prospect of being punished if it

is caught. Empirically, we contribute to the literature on macroeconomic performance

and financial development by using data that has current trends covers a wide range of

countries. The thesis consists of two main essays; a summary of which is given below.

In the first essay we study sovereign borrowing and sovereign default risk in a

dynamic general equilibrium model of corruption and political turnover. Many govern-

19

Page 21: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

ments across the world borrow to finance their budget deficits. An obvious question

is why do some governments borrow more than others and why do some governments

default more than others? Evidence suggests that weak institutions in the form of

corruption may be the answer. We provide an explanation for this by demonstrating

how corruption (modelled as the embezzlement of public funds) may influence sover-

eign borrowing and default decisions on the part of alternating incumbent governments

with different propensities to be corrupt. We show that when there is turnover between

governments with different governments, corruption can generate high default risk and

high credit spreads, but only when there is enough stability. We establish that a change

in power from a less corrupt to a more corrupt government is more likely to increase this

default risk than the reverse. We also find that welfare loss to households is increasing

with the level of corruption. As motivation and support for our analysis, we present

some empirical evidence to show that corruption is, indeed, associated with higher risks

of default. The empirical evidence also shows a strong positive relationship between

political stability and risks of default.

In the second essay we study financial intermediation and firm financing in a

dynamic general equilibrium model of capital market imperfections resulting from in-

stitutional weaknesses. The legal enforcement of contracts plays an important role

when contractual issues cannot be solved amicably between lenders and borrowers es-

pecially in emerging economies. Yet the legal institutions required for this are often

very weak or non-existent implying that contract enforcement is limited. We explore

the implications of this by considering the effect of poor quality institutions (imperfect

contract enforcement) on firms’ financial arrangements with lenders, firms’ decisions

to default and firms’ access to working capital.

We establish a pro-cyclical risk premium following a positive aggregate productiv-

ity shock. However, we find that a shock to net worth in the form of one-time wealth

transfer from entrepreneurs to households results in a counter-cyclical risk premium.

This transfer reduces entrepreneurial net worth and causes a fall in the supply of cap-

ital which then pushes up the price of capital. The fall in net worth also results in

20

Page 22: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

increasing demand for external finance which in turn causes a rise in the probability of

default and the lending rate. The risk premium depends on the probability of default,

the price of capital, the lending rate and and the strength of contract enforcement.

Overall, the lending rate, the risk premium and the default probability are increasing

in the degree of limited contract enforcement. This risk premium provides the key

mechanism through which the effects of shocks are amplified by limited contract en-

forcement; the latter which also results in greater output volatility. Consequently, high

degree of limited contract enforcement imposes a negative effect (in the form of high

lending rate) on small firms (which are forced to rely more on external finance) seeking

to borrow in order to finance investment. This is particularly onerous for smaller firms,

the growth of which is therefore impeded. As motivation and support for our analysis,

we present some empirical evidence which shows that a weaker enforcement (or higher

cost of enforcement) of financial contracts is associated with a lower level, lower growth

rate and higher volatility of output.

The rest of the thesis is organised as follows. In Chapter (2), we investigate

the influence that corruption and political turnover (risk) have on sovereign default

decisions. We study the effect of limited financial contract enforcement on macroe-

conomic outcomes in Chapter (3). In Chapter (4), we present the conclusion of the

thesis, also highlighting its limitations and directions for further research.

21

Page 23: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

Chapter 2

Corruption and Political Turnover

in a Sovereign Default Model

2.1 Introduction

Business cycles in emerging economies vary from their developed counterparts. Such

economies are typically characterised by relatively high interest rates and interest rate

spreads, high output volatility, low output per capita, weak institutions, high levels of

corruption, high political instability and high frequencies of sovereign default. The last

of these phenomena (like most of the others) has attracted the attention of academics

and policymakers for a long time, and a renewed interest has been ignited by recent

events in the world. This chapter of the thesis seeks to contribute to the literature on

sovereign default by studying specifically the role of corruption in influencing default

decisions. It does so within the context of a Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium

(DSGE) model which allows for the random political turnover of alternative types

of government that have different propensities to be corrupt. Corruption manifests

itself as the embezzlement of public funds. Specifically, public sector corruption is

defined as “the abuse of authority by bureaucratic officials who exploit their powers

of discretion, delegated to them by the government, to further their own interests by

engaging in illegal, or unauthorised, rent-seeking activities” (Blackburn et al. 2006,

p.2448). The results of the analysis highlight the important role that corruption can

22

Page 24: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

play in determining the risk of default, a role that is evidenced by the data.

Sovereign default has been attributed to various causes, both economic and polit-

ical. In their seminal work, Hatchondo et al. (2009) introduce political factors into the

modelling of sovereign default which they claim to have accounted for defaults in Brazil

during 2002 and Argentina during 2001. The authors present a model with political

turnover, where different government types are distinguished in terms of their degree of

impatience which influences their willingness to pay off debt. In turn, this affects the

equilibrium bond spread through a direct impact on each type’s borrowing opportunit-

ies. It is shown that sovereign default may be triggered when the government changes

from a more patient to a less patient type, provided that there is enough political

stability. This suggests that political turnover may have significant implications for

sovereign default decisions. The model also illustrates a non-monotonic relationship

between political stability and default probability which is in line with the political

turnover models of Amador (2003) and Cuadra and Sapriza (2008), where political

stability affects sovereign bond spreads through future utility flows. Though default

episodes have mostly occurred in periods of downturns, there is, nevertheless, evidence

that a considerable number of default episodes occur when output is above its long-run

trend (see Tomz and Wright (2007); Hatchondo et al. (2009)).

The foregoing analyses yield important insights, though one issue that is not ad-

dressed, but which merits attention, is the role of corruption in influencing the risk of

sovereign default. This is particularly pertinent for emerging economies, and there are

good reasons for thinking why corruption may be important for default decisions. For

instance, a corrupt policymaker may be willing to borrow substantial funds even with

high interest rate spreads in order to create opportunities for appropriating resources.

As a result, corruption may lead to a higher incidence of default if loan repayments

become excessive. Ciocchini et al. (2003) studied the effect of corruption on sovereign

bond spreads in emerging economies and observed that high levels of corruption are

associated with high spreads. Importantly, the authors argue that corrupt governments

need liquidity which results in high borrowing even with very high spreads. Further-

23

Page 25: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

more, if corruption leads to a drain on loaned funds and other sources of government

income, then it may limit the government’s ability to meet its debt obligations. For

instance, in Russia more than $4 billion in IMF loans apparently disappeared shortly

before Russia’s default in 1998 (see Ciocchini et al. (2003)). Similarly, Haque and Sahay

(1996), Tanzi and Davoodi (1997), and Johnson et al. (1998) observe that higher levels

of corruption are associated with lower tax revenues, which would in turn lower the

government’s ability to repay its debt. One observation is that most of the countries

that default seem to be the most corrupt. In addition, the data suggests that there is

a strong correlation between sovereign default, corruption and political turnover.

In spite of the above, little or no attempt has been made to explore the inter-

linkages between corruption and the risk of default. This paper seeks to do so. The

analysis is based on a DSGE model in which different government types alternate in

power. Corruption takes the form of a government’s illegal consumption of public

funds, which impacts on the decision to default. The government borrows in order to

smooth household consumption, although it is only partially benevolent in this respect

due to its proclivity towards corruption. A government may be either of two types–a

more corrupt or a less corrupt type–which alternate in power with a certain probab-

ility. The government in office makes a decision about whether or not to default by

trading off the benefits and costs associated with this. The benefits of defaulting are

the avoidance of debt repayments, whilst costs are a loss of output in the following

period. We show how default decisions, together with business cycle fluctuations, are

affected by the level of corruption. We find that more corrupt governments are more

likely to default, conditional on the same endowment and initial debt. Moreover, the

presence of political turnover makes it possible for corruption to generate high default

risk and high credit spreads, but only when there is enough political stability. With

turnover, the less corrupt government pays a premium to lenders to compensate them

for the possibility that the more corrupt government will come into power next period

and default. When there is a lot of instability, the less corrupt government avoids

increasing debt levels to the point where the corrupt government would default, result-

24

Page 26: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

ing in lower credit spreads. However, when there is enough stability, the less corrupt

government is willing to borrow at levels which the more corrupt government would

default. While the probability that the high type comes into power is low, this still

results in higher default risk and higher credit spreads. We also compute the welfare

loss to households as a result of corruption and show that this loss is increasing with

the level of corruption.

To set the scene for our theoretical analysis, we first conduct an empirical invest-

igation into the determinants of sovereign default. Using data on a broad sample of

emerging economies, we find that, amongst other factors, both corruption and political

stability have a significant positive influence on sovereign default.

2.1.1 Related Literature

2.1.1.1 Theoretical literature

This paper is closely related to the models of Cole et al. (1995), Alfaro and Kanczuk

(2005), and Hatchondo et al. (2009). These models study sovereign default with het-

erogeneous borrowers where a patient policymaker is replaced by an impatient poli-

cymaker. Cole et al. (1995) and Alfaro and Kanczuk (2005) focus on equilibria in

which patient policymakers never default and impatient policymakers always default.

Hatchondo et al. (2009) consider a political process similar to the one used by Cole

et al. (1995), and Alfaro and Kanczuk (2005), but differ in the government’s choice of

optimal borrowing level and in both policymakers being able to default. They show

that if there is enough political stability and a patient government also encounters poor

economic condition, a default is likely to be triggered by political turnover. In addi-

tion, they find that the presence of political turnover can result in an increase in the

volatility of the spread paid by patient governments in politically stable economies. We

study sovereign default in an environment similar to that of Hatchondo et al. (2009)

and find that the presence of political turnover results in an increase in the volatility

of spread paid by both types of governments and this increase is greater with the more

corrupt type.

25

Page 27: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

Information on borrower types to lenders in the literature is mixed. Many recent

models of sovereign default with heterogeneous borrowers assume that lenders cannot

directly observe a borrower’s type (see Chatterjee et al. (2007)). Hatchondo et al.

(2009), on the contrary, assume that the type of policymaker in power is public in-

formation to lenders. Hatchondo et al. (2009) also allow policymakers to choose debt

levels from a continuum. We make similar assumptions as Hatchondo et al. (2009).

A number of models (see Cole et al. (1995); Alfaro and Kanczuk (2005)) assume

representation of borrowers with stochastic preferences where borrower types change

over time. Hatchondo et al. (2009), on the other hand, assume a representation of

political processes, similar to Amador (2003), and Cuadra and Sapriza (2008) but

where borrowers of different types alternate in power. Amador (2003), and Cuadra and

Sapriza (2008) in their setup assume that types only differ on the optimal allocation

of resources within each period and receive the same treatment from lenders. They

also assume that political stability affects the equilibrium spread mainly through its

impact on the weight of future utility flows. On the contrary, Hatchondo et al. (2009)

in their setup assume that the two types differ in their willingness to pay. They

equally argue that political stability affects equilibrium spreads mainly through the

direct effect it puts on the borrowing opportunities of a government. In our setup, the

two types differ in their willingness to pay and the risk of being replaced, the latter

effect exacerbated by the propensity of a type to be corrupt. We focus on a single

discount factor case, whilst the other models (see Amador (2003); Cuadra and Sapriza

(2008); Hatchondo et al. (2009)) consider different discount factors as a representation

of types. In our setup, types are represented by their propensity to be corrupt. We

argue that political stability, which is aggravated by how corrupt a type is, affects

equilibrium spreads through its impact on the policymaker’s borrowing opportunities

and how lenders perceive types.

Earlier studies (see Aguiar and Gopinath (2006); Chatterjee et al. (2007)) have

used shocks to endowment growth rate and shocks to borrower’s discount factor as

tools to smooth out the equilibrium bond price function faced by the borrower and as a

26

Page 28: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

mechanism in generating a higher spread and higher spread volatility. The introduction

of political turnover in the Hatchondo et al. (2009) model serves as the mechanism

through which smoother bond price functions are delivered. In our setup, building on

Hatchondo et al. (2009), political turnover impacts on the bond price function and also

amplifies the effect of corruption in the model.

2.1.1.2 Empirical literature

The empirical literature on the determinants of debt crisis is broad (see Schimmelp-

fennig et al. (2003); Lausev et al. (2011)). Earlier studies (see Frank and Cline (1971))

have made findings on the possibility of predicting debt crisis. On the contrary, other

studies (see McFadden et al. (1985)) have found that predicting debt crises might be

difficult. McFadden et al. (1985) in their study on finding probabilities of debt crisis

using data for 93 countries over the period 1970-1982, conclude that predicting debt

crises in advance might be difficult even though an econometric model can help to

explain sovereign debt problems. To this effect, they find debt burden, the level of per

capita income and real GDP growth, to mention few, as significant predictors of debt

crisis.

Commonly included in the econometric models are short-term financial variables

like debt-GDP ratio and long term variables like GDP growth. Specifically, Schimmelp-

fennig et al. (2003) as cited in Lausev et al. (2011) find high external debt to GDP ratio

and short term debt to be highly associated with debt rescheduling. Detragiache and

Spilimbergo (2001a) find the importance of liquidity factors such as short-term debt,

debt service, and the level of international reserves as determinants of debt crises. They

do not only identify countries that are more open as in a better position to service their

debt, but find inverse relationship between liquidity of a country and the probability

of default. Edwards (1984), Min (1998), and Rowland and Torres (2004) recognise the

importance of various macroeconomic variables in determining credit spreads.

Besides economic variables, political risk and institutional variables have often

27

Page 29: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

been considered to play an important role in predicting sovereign debt crises among

emerging market countries. Balkan (1992), one of the earliest attempted studies on this

issue, finds an inverse relationship between probability of rescheduling and the level of

democracy for a country, on the one hand, and a direct relationship between probab-

ility of rescheduling and political instability, on the other hand. Furthermore, Verma

(2002) finds that more democratic countries tend to default more, whilst Bordo and

Oosterlinck (2005) observe that half of the default incidents during 1880-1913 occurred

around periods of political turnovers. Citron and Nickelsburg (1987) and more recently

Georgievska et al. (2008) uphold the importance of political factors in determining debt

rescheduling probabilities. According to Baldacci et al. (2011), higher political risk is

also associated with higher spreads. A number of recent studies have also stressed the

significance of such political variables in determining sovereign default and debt res-

cheduling (see Ul Haque et al. (1998); Reinhart et al. (2003); Santiso (2003); Van Rijck-

eghem and Weder (2004); Sturzenegger and Zettelmeyer (2006); Moser (2007); and

Lausev et al. (2011)).

Kraay and Nehru (2006), one of the earliest attempted studies on debt crisis and

institutions, find the quality of institutions and policies to have major effect on debt

rescheduling. Similarly, Butler and Fauver (2006) identify the quality of a country’s

legal and political institutions as having a major role play in determining sovereign

credit ratings. In addition, Ciocchini et al. (2003) study the effect of corruption on

sovereign bond spreads in emerging economies and observe that high levels of corruption

are associated with high spreads.

The impact of past debt repayment records on current and future rescheduling

have been investigated in a number of studies. Specifically, McFadden et al. (1985),

Li (1992), Aylward and Thorne (1998), and most recently Lausev et al. (2011) have

found debt repayment history as a strong determinant of future debt crisis.

We contribute to the empirical literature by analysing the influence that corrup-

tion and political factors could exert on sovereign default risk. We distinguish between

corruption and political stability (which is not done in the literature (see Balkan (1992);

28

Page 30: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

Li (1992); Verma (2002); Bordo and Oosterlinck (2005) and Lausev et al. (2011)) in

order to investigate the influence that each independently exerts on sovereign default.

We find a result that is puzzling. Using data on a broad sample of emerging economies

over the period 1984-2008, we find that, amongst other factors, both corruption and

political stability have a significant positive effect on sovereign default. We contribute

to the theoretical literature by studying how corruption together with political turnover

can affect sovereign default decision in a dynamic general equilibrium setting. The rest

of the paper is organised as follows. In Section (2.2), we present the empirical analysis

of the determinants of sovereign default. In Section (2.3), we set out the theoretical

model that we use to study the relationship between sovereign default and corruption.

The theoretical model is intended to find solution to the problems, such as endogeneity,

that our empirical model might run into. In Section (2.3.2), we solve the model. In

Section (2.4), we calibrate the model and present our main results. In Section (2.5),

we make some concluding remarks.

2.2 Empirical Observations

This section looks empirically at the influence that corruption and political factors have

on sovereign default. Our main objective is to evaluate the extent to which corruption

and political factors have direct or indirect effects on the risk of default. Taken together,

our results suggest that there is a significant positive association between sovereign

default and both corruption and political stability, controlling for other important

determinants of default. This central finding remain fairly robust to a battery of

sensitivity analyses, including alternative specifications.

2.2.1 Data Sample

We use annual data on sovereign default and rescheduling episodes and possible predict-

ors of sovereign default and rescheduling over the period 1984-2008. Our own empirical

investigation is based on data from the World Bank Development Indicators, World

Bank–Global Development Finance (1991, 2006, 2012), Standard and Poors, Moodys

29

Page 31: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

and the International Country Risk Guide by the Political Risk Services (PRS). We

consider the following variables as potential predictors of sovereign default: corruption,

political stability and various controls such as external debt, annual GDP growth and

logarithm of GDP Per Capita. We focus on emerging economies, where the selection

of countries is based on the availability of data and also controlling for outliers. Vari-

ables used in the estimation and the summary statistics are detailed in Table (2.7.1.2)

and Table (2.7.1.3), respectively. Among these variables, GDP per Capita is the most

volatile followed by political stability and then corruption. That is volatility of 2.411,

1.891 and 1.039, respectively.

2.2.1.1 Dependent Variable

Existing studies on sovereign debt crisis show that there is no laid down definition of a

sovereign debt crisis, a sovereign default episode, or a sovereign debt rescheduling event

(see for example Kraay and Nehru (2006); Schimmelpfennig et al. (2003); Lausev et al.

(2011) and Ciarlone and Trebeschi (2005)). Generally, sovereign default or sovereign

debt rescheduling is any failure by a nation to meet its debt obligations. This may

involve either missing a scheduled payment of principal or interest. Specifically, the

IMF and the World Bank have considered rescheduling agreements on external debt

as sovereign defaults. In our context the dependent variable is sovereign default. We

consider a country as having defaulted if there was an outright default of debt or if

there was reported reschedule of the principal or interest, as is reported in Standard and

Poors, Moodys, World Bank Development Indicators, the IMF and World Bank–Global

Development Finance (1991, 2006, 2012). Using this data, we establish the following

criterion for determining the dependent variable (default): A default is registered if a

country defaults or reschedules its debt or the interest on its debt in a given year. As

argued in the literature rescheduling could be inability on the part of the borrower to

settle the terms of the contract and can be treated as a proxy for default. We look at

sovereign default episodes for emerging economies over the period 1984-2008. We use

30

Page 32: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

25 countries after controlling for outliers as displayed in Table (2.7.1.1).

2.2.1.2 Independent Variables

We undertake our analysis using macroeconomic variables, otherwise known as solvency

variables, as controls and institutional variables that normally explain a country’s

sovereign debt rescheduling or default risk. These variables can be put into the following

categories: (a) institutional variables, (b) macroeconomic/solvency variables, (c) past

variables (past default record, past of institutional variables and past macroeconomic

variables).

(a) Institutional Variables

(i) Corruption

Corruption has been identified as a major political risk factor (see Political Risk Services

(PRS1)). This risk in corruption results from the fact that at some point in time some

major scandal could be revealed, which has the propensity to provoke tension and cause

a fall or overthrow of the government. This could further bring about a readjustment in

the country’s political institutions, a breakdown in law and order, making the country

unstable and ungovernable (see PRS). In an assessment of corruption, PRS (2008)

has identified “financial corruption in the form of demands for special payments and

bribes connected with import and export licenses, exchange controls, tax assessments,

police protection, or loans” (p.31) as the most common form of corruption encountered

by business. We use the International Country Risk Guide Index (ICRG) measure of

corruption by PRS which uses a scale of 0-6 (6 is the highest rank of transparency)

that we convert to 0-6 (to capture the level of corruption than transparency), where 6

is the highest rank of corruption.

1http://www.prsgroup.com/

31

Page 33: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

The (Un)reliability of Measures of Corruption

Corruption data has been used widely in empirical studies. Nevertheless, the reliabil-

ity of it measurement still remains an issue in empirical studies. A reliable measure of

corruption should be one that objectively quantifies the frequency and the magnitude

of corruption over time and across countries, which is often impossible (see Swaleheen

(2011)). However, as a result of the lack of objective measure of corruption, current

empirical studies on corruption mostly use subjective measures by Transparency In-

ternational (TI), the World Bank (WB) and Political Risk Services (PRS). Whilst the

TI and WB measures of corruption are composite indices based on individual surveys

of corruption, the PRS measure is an expert rankings by a specialised institution. It

measures corruption that exists within the political system which has the ability to

affect foreign investment through distortion in the economic, financial and business en-

vironment. Among the subjective measures available, the ICRG measure of corruption

by PRS is widely accepted as being reflective of the frequency and magnitude of cor-

ruption. Data for this measure is available from 1984. Also due to its broad coverage

of countries, it has had wide usage (see Knack and Keefer (1995); Braun and Di Tella

(2004); Dreher and Siemens (2003); Dal Bo and Rossi (2007); Swaleheen (2011) and

Lausev et al. (2011)).

(ii) Political Stability

In our attempt to examine the effect of political turnover on sovereign default risk,

we use the Political Rights Index (PR) from Freedom House as a measure of political

stability. This measure has been used by Verma (2002) as a proxy for democracy

which the author argues is sometimes equated with political stability. The PR is

measured on a scale of 1-7 which we convert to 0-10, where 10 represents the best rating

of political rights. Freedom House (https://freedomhouse.org) recognises that “Free

elections provide long-term political stability and allow citizens to peacefully replace

ineffective or corrupt leaders. And independent media provide a check on government,

32

Page 34: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

verifying official claims of success and exposing abusive practices”. It is in the light

of this that we use the Political Rights Index as a proxy for political stability in our

work.

It must be pointed out that the measures of corruption and political stability,

especially the ICRG measures, do not include sovereign default risk (the dependent

variable) in country ratings. By this, we avoid a possible double counting problem

that would result from having the dependent variable regressed on a variable that

include itself.

(b) Macroeconomic/Solvency Variables

Several macroeconomic variables which may predict sovereign default are used as con-

trols in our estimation. Included amongst these are external debt-GDP ratio, logarithm

of GDP per Capita and the annual growth rate of GDP. Data on all of these are taken

from the World Development Indicators (WDI).

GDP growth rate which captures the current economic performance of a country

has been argued to have a negative impact on the probability of default (see Lausev

et al. (2011)). Similarly, GDP per Capita which captures the level of development

of a country has been argued in the literature to have a negative relationship with

the sovereign default probability (see Feder and Just (1977) as cited in Lausev et al.

(2011)). In related studies (see Williams (2014)), GDP per Capita and growth of

GDP per Capital have both been used to control for differences in financial system

development and economic cycle effects. It is also argued that a country that increases

its external debt in relation to its GDP is likely to have unsustainable debt which could

in turn increase the probability of default. Accordingly, a positive relationship between

external debt-GDP ratio and the probability of default is expected.

33

Page 35: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

(c) Past Default/Rescheduling Records and Past of Current Explanatory Variables

Previous studies on sovereign debt have found evidence of past debt repayment records

having positive effect on future default (see McFadden et al. (1985); Aylward and

Thorne (1998); Li (1992) and Lausev et al. (2011) etc.). Following these findings,

we include past default record as an explanatory variable. Similarly, the inclusion of

the past of explanatory variables is to capture the impact of the previous state of the

economy on the current one (see McFadden et al. (1985); Balkan (1992) and Pestova

(2015)). McFadden et al. (1985) argue that the reason for the inclusion of the lagged

explanatory variables is to reduce the problem of simultaneity.

2.2.2 Model Specification

A probit model is used to test the correlations of the macroeconomic and political

predictor variables with default of debtor country. Our empirical specification amongst

other is in line with Rahnama-Moghadam (1995) and Balkan (1992). To define a probit

model, consider a country i observed over T periods of time t, where t = 1, ..., T and

i = 1, ..., N . We think of an unobservable random variable, y∗it, as the underlying latent

propensity that an observable binary outcome, yit, will be such that

yit =

1 if y∗it > 0

0 otherwise

Since we are interested in default occurrence rather than the amount of debt defaulted,

the dependent variable (default) is a discrete random variable that takes the value 0 if

a country does not default during a given year and 1 if it does.

In our setting, the independent variables may be either continuous or discrete.

The dependent variable y∗it is a function of explanatory variable(s) xit, a constant α and

random error term uit. The probit model used to test our prediction is summarised as:

34

Page 36: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

y∗it = α +m∑j=1

βjxjit + uit (2.2.2.1)

where yit = 1 if country i has rescheduled or defaulted on its debt payments in year

t and 0 if otherwise, and xjit is the jth macroeconomic or political variable of country

i in year t. We interpret the coefficients β1, β2..., βm as the partial derivatives of the

probability of default with respect to the independent variables, x1i, x2i..., xmi. In this

light, given the macroeconomic or political characteristics, x1i, x2i..., xmi, the binary

response model determines the probability that country i will default or reschedule its

debt, against the alternative that country i will not. We estimate the model in Stata

and code is provided in Appendix (A.1).

2.2.3 Results

The central argument of this paper is that there is a significant relationship between

corruption, political risk and sovereign default risk. The analysis will centre on the

variables of interest (corruption and political variables). We first report the results

(with the marginal effects) of our baseline probit model where we regress default on

current explanatory variables. Table (2.7.1.4) reports these findings. Column 1 of Table

(2.7.1.4) shows our results when we include external debt-GDP ratio and real GDP

growth as control variables. The coefficient on corruption has the expected positive sign

and insignificant. The coefficient on political stability is significant at 5%. Using the

corresponding marginal effect in column 4 of Table (2.7.1.4), the estimated probability

effects of corruption and political stability are 0.028 and 0.025, insignificant at 10%

and significant at 5%, respectively. This implies that a unit change in corruption will

increase the probability of default by 3%, similarly a unit change in political stability

will increase the probability of default by 3%. The model specification in column

2 of Table (2.7.1.4) shows our result when we include external debt-GDP ratio and

GDP per Capita as control variables. The coefficient on corruption has the expected

positive sign and significant at 10% whilst the coefficient on political stability is positive

35

Page 37: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

and significant at 5%. Using the corresponding marginal effect in column 5 of Table

(2.7.1.4), the estimated probability effects of corruption and political stability are 0.036

and 0.025, significant at 10% and 5%, respectively. This implies that a unit change

in corruption will increase the probability of default by 4%, similarly a unit change in

political stability will increase the probability of default by 3%. The model specification

in column 3 of Table (2.7.1.4) shows our results when we include external debt-GDP

ratio, real GDP growth and GDP per Capita as control variables. The coefficient on

corruption has the expected positive sign and significant at 10% whilst the coefficient

on political stability is positive and significant at 5%. Using the corresponding marginal

effect in column 6 of Table (2.7.1.4), the estimated probability effects of corruption and

political stability are 0.036 and 0.025, significant at 10% and 5%, respectively. This

implies that a unit change in corruption will increase the probability of default by 4%,

similarly a unit change in political stability will increase the probability of default by

3%.

The existing empirical literature (see Balkan (1992); Li (1992); Verma (2002);

Bordo and Oosterlinck (2005) and Lausev et al. (2011)) on sovereign default and polit-

ical risks do not distinguish between corruption and political (in)stability. We distin-

guish between the two in order to investigate the influence that each (corruption and

political stability) independently exerts on sovereign default. We find a result that

may seem puzzling. We find that the coefficient on corruption is positive in all cases

which continues to indicate that higher corruption is associated with a higher sovereign

default probability. Also, we observe a positive coefficient for political stability in all

cases. It would be generally thought that political instability is conducive to sovereign

default but our results indicate otherwise. The reason for the positive effect of polit-

ical stability on default risk lies in its ability to create room for more borrowing. We

therefore argue that the positive sign is consistent with findings in the literature (see

Verma (2002); Bordo and Oosterlinck (2005)) that suggest that political stability or

democracy has positive influence on sovereign default. Also, the findings from our the-

oretical model show that higher political stability increases default probability because

36

Page 38: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

the former creates an enabling environment for more borrowing, a mechanism similar

to Hatchondo et al. (2009).

2.2.3.1 Robustness Analyses

We test the sensitivity of our baseline results to other specifications of the model. In

particular, we check for robustness by specifying the model with lagged explanatory

variables and by including lagged dependent variable as an explanatory variable. As

we have argued earlier these specifications with lagged explanatory variables (including

lagged dependent variable) is supported by the literature (see McFadden et al. (1985);

Balkan (1992); Li (1992); Aylward and Thorne (1998); Lausev et al. (2011) and Pestova

(2015)).

Our first check for robustness involves running a probit model of current default

on past explanatory variables. Table (2.7.1.5) reports our findings. Column 1 of Table

(2.7.1.5) shows our result where we include past external debt-GDP ratio and past real

GDP growth as control variables. The result shows that the coefficient on corruption

is positive and significant at 10%. The general conclusion to be drawn is that higher

levels of corruption are associated with greater risks of sovereign default, as our baseline

results suggest. The coefficients on political stability is positive, significant at 1% and

consistent with our baseline results. Using the corresponding marginal effect in column

4 of Table (2.7.1.5), the estimated probability effects of corruption and political stability

are 0.036 and 0.030, significant at 10% and 1%, respectively. This implies that a unit

change in corruption will increase the probability of default by 4%, similarly a unit

change in political stability will increase the probability of default by 3%. In column

2 of Table (2.7.1.5) is our result when we include past external debt-GDP ratio and

past GDP per Capita as control variables. The result shows that the coefficient on

corruption is positive and significant at 10% whilst the coefficient on political stability

is positive, significant at 1% and consistent with our baseline results. By including

past GDP per Capita as a control variable, the effect of past corruption on default is

37

Page 39: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

bigger than when we include past real GDP growth as a control variable. Using the

corresponding marginal effect column in 5 of Table (2.7.1.5), the estimated probability

effects of corruption and political stability are 0.040 and 0.029, significant at 10%

and 1%, respectively. This implies that a unit change in corruption will increase the

probability of default by 4%, similarly a unit change in political stability will increase

the probability of default by 3%. The result in column 3 of Table (2.7.1.5) displays

our findings where we include past external debt-GDP ratio, past real GDP growth

and past GDP per Capita as control variables. The result shows that the coefficient on

corruption is positive and significant at 5% whilst the coefficient on political stability

is positive, significant at 1%. As we include both past real GDP growth and GDP

per Capita as a control variables, the effect of past corruption on default increases.

Using the corresponding marginal effect column in 6 of Table (2.7.1.5), the estimated

probability effects of corruption and political stability are 0.043 and 0.029, significant at

5% and 1%, respectively. This implies that a unit change in corruption will increase the

probability of default by 4%, similarly a unit change in political stability will increase

the probability of default by 3%.

Finally, we check for robustness by running a probit model of current default

on past default and past explanatory variables. The results in Table (2.7.1.6) reports

our findings. Column 1 of Table (2.7.1.6) shows our result where we include past

default, past external debt-GDP ratio and past real GDP growth as control variables.

The result shows that the coefficient on past default is positive and significant at 1%

whilst the coefficient on corruption is positive but insignificant. The coefficient on

political stability is positive and significant at 5%. Using the corresponding marginal

effect column in 4 of Table (2.7.1.6), the estimated probability effects of corruption and

political stability are 0.031 and 0.026, insignificant and significant at 5%, respectively.

This implies that a unit change in corruption will increase the probability of default

by 3%, similarly a unit change in political stability will increase the probability of

default by 3%. When we include past default, past external debt-GDP ratio and past

GDP per Capita as control variables, as displayed in column 2 of Table (2.7.1.6), the

38

Page 40: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

coefficients on past default and political stability are positive and significant at 1%

and 5% respectively whilst the coefficient on corruption is positive but insignificant.

Using the corresponding marginal effect column in 5 of Table (2.7.1.6), the estimated

probability effects of corruption and political stability are 0.034 and 0.025, insignificant

and significant at 5%, respectively. This implies that a unit change in corruption will

increase the probability of default by 3%, similarly a unit change in political stability

will increase the probability of default by 3%. The result in column 3 of Table (2.7.1.6)

displays our findings where we include past default, past external debt-GDP ratio, past

real GDP growth and past GDP per Capita as control variables. We find that whilst

the coefficients on past default and political stability are positive and significant at

1% and 5% respectively, the coefficient on past corruption is positive and significant

at 10%. Using the corresponding marginal effect column in 6 of Table (2.7.1.6), the

estimated probability effects of corruption and political stability are 0.038 and 0.025,

significant at 10% and 5%, respectively. This implies that a unit change in corruption

will increase the probability of default by 4%, similarly a unit change in political

stability will increase the probability of default by 3%.

The coefficients on corruption and political stability are positive in all cases, an

indication that higher corruption and political stability are associated with a higher

sovereign default probability. The general conclusion to be drawn is that this not

only implies that there is a positive association with sovereign default and, corruption

and political stability, but that there is persistence in this relationship. In particular,

past default, corruption, political stability and macroeconomic variables tend to have

a significant positive influence on current default–a result which is in line with other

findings (see McFadden et al. (1985); Balkan (1992); Li (1992); Aylward and Thorne

(1998); Lausev et al. (2011) and Pestova (2015)).

2.2.4 Discussion

Taken together, our results suggest that there is a significant positive association

between sovereign default and political risk, controlling for other important determ-

39

Page 41: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

inants of default. This central finding remain fairly robust to a battery of sensitivity

analyses, including additional controls and various specifications. However, it should

be emphasised that our results do not imply causality. The reason for this is that there

could be endogeneity (e.g. measurement issues, simultaneity etc.) in the specifications

we adopted above. Unfortunately, the nature of our sample (e.g. emerging markets)

and dataset mean that this issue cannot be effectively resolved. The main challenge

we face relates to the issue of finding suitable instruments for political risk indicat-

ors, including corruption (i.e. institutional quality). Fortunately enough, our model

specifications are consistent with many studies (see Balkan (1992); Li (1992); Verma

(2002) and Lausev et al. (2011)), on this area, which have not used instruments for

institutional variables.

This paper provides empirical evidence about the importance of corruption and

political factors on predicting sovereign default probabilities of emerging economies.

Emerging economies have become an important investment destination in recent times.

Estimating models that can provide sign of sovereign default probabilities would be of

interest to investors. Overall, our results show that emerging economies that want to

reduce their probabilities of default, the cost of borrowing and improve access to credit,

should generally:

1) Control and reduce corruption, attract more Foreign Direct Investments and

stimulate GDP growth.

2) Have a good repayment habit by reducing the size of the external debt-GDP

ratio and avoid sovereign default on debt resulting from unwillingness rather than

inability to repay.

One recommendation for future research concerns the specification of the econo-

metric model itself. We could improve the model by including more specific political

risk factors as explanatory variables, such as number of armed conflicts in the country

during the sample period and/or the number of political turnovers of the government.

Finally, we could include more financial market variables to improve the accuracy of

the models.

40

Page 42: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

2.3 The Theoretical Model

We consider an economy with infinitely-lived households and alternating types of gov-

ernment. The basic structure of our model follows that of Eaton and Gersovitz (1981),

as used recently by Arellano (2008), Yue (2006), Aguiar and Gopinath (2006) and

Hatchondo et al. (2009). Our model differs from those frameworks by incorporating

government expenditures and government corruption into the analysis of sovereign de-

fault. The theoretical model intends to replicate the main empirical observations.

The basic assumption is that the central government borrows from the inter-

national financial market to smooth consumption of households through trading of

non-contingent bonds. There is a single tradable good and a stochastic endowment

stream of income. The government has an opportunity to default on its debt and

thereby avoid making debt repayments. However, doing this is costly as it leads to a

loss in output in the following period.

Corruption takes the form of a government’s pilfering of public funds raised

through high taxes. There exist two types of political rulers which alternate in power

and which differ according to their propensity to be corrupt. Both types are partially

benevolent in the sense that they care about the utility of households and also extract

corrupt consumption. At the beginning of period a corrupt ruler in power observes

the current state of the economy and borrows to smooth consumption of households.

During this period, ruler observes the realisations of shocks and the level of debt, and

decides whether or not to default. If default is chosen, the economy subsequently suffers

an output loss and lower bond prices. At the end of the period, there is an exogenous

probability that the ruler will be replaced by the alternative government.

2.3.1 The Government’s Decision Problem

There is a single tradable good in the economy. The economy receives a stochastic en-

dowment y, which follows an AR(1) around a long run mean µy, and evolves according

to

41

Page 43: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

log(yt) = (1− ρ)µy + ρy log(yt−1) + εt

|ρy| < 1, and εt ∼ N(0, σ2ε).

The government finances its budget through taxes on output. In addition to tax income,

the government has access to financial assets in the form of one-period non-contingent

bonds.

We differ from Cole et al. (1995), Alfaro and Kanczuk (2005), and Hatchondo et al.

(2009) in assuming that two types of policymakers with different levels of corruption

alternate in power. When in power, the objective of the policymaker is to maximise

the present discounted value of future utility flows, on behalf of the households. There

is a probability πj that at the end of every period the type of policymaker in power will

change. Unlike Hatchondo et al. (2009), in our model the value of πj is state dependent,

where j ∈ {L,H} denotes the government type. More corrupt policymakers are able

to loot cgH from the state coffers whilst at the same time face a probability of πH of

being replaced. The less corrupt policymakers are able to loot cgL from the state coffers

whilst at the same time face a lesser probability of πL of being replaced, where cgH > cgL

and πH > πL.

Thus far, this set-up helps compare our model to recent models of political in-

stability and sovereign default, but also illustrates the crucial role played by corruption

as a determinant of sovereign default. The policymaker in power determines how much

to borrow for the following period and whether to pay back previously issued debt. Fin-

ancial assets available to the policymaker are in the form of one-period non-contingent

bonds. A bond issued in the current period delivers one unit of the good in the next

period if no default. At the beginning of the period, the economy has bond position

denoted by b. In the previous period if the country was an issuer of bonds, the value

of b is negative.

Following others (see Aguiar and Gopinath (2006); Hatchondo et al. (2009)), we

consider defaulting to be costly because it imposes a direct output loss on the economy

in the future. This assumption that countries suffer an output loss following a default is

meant to capture any disruptions in economic activity resulting from a default decision.

42

Page 44: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

We denote this output loss by λ percent2.

Information on the type of government and the economy’s endowment is perfectly

available to lenders. There is a continuum of risk-neutral lenders in the international

financial market and lenders can borrow or lend at the risk-free rate r. The bond price

is determined when the government determines how many bonds to issue and sells to

the lender that offers the highest price. We denote as qjd(y, b′) the price offered when

ruler j issues a total of −b′ of bonds. This price depends on whether the country

currently has defaulted (d), current endowment realisation y and asset choice b′ but

does not depend on default decisions in previous periods because we assume that the

effect of a default on output only lasts for one period and lenders are forward looking.

We specify how this price is determined later in Section (2.3.3).

The government’s budget constraint in a given period is summarised by:

c+ cgj + qjd(y, b′)b′ ≤ (1− hλ)y + (1− d)b (2.3.1.1)

where c is household consumption and cgj is ruler j′s corrupt consumption. y is output,

b is existing assets (negative if borrowing) and d is default. d = 1 if the government

is defaulting on its existing debt, otherwise it is 0. h is the history of default, where

h = 1 if the government defaulted in the previous period, and 0 otherwise. qjd(y, b′) is

the bond price for ruler j in power. This price depends on whether the country cur-

rently has defaulted (d), current endowment realisation y and asset choice b′. Corrupt

consumption cgj is expressed as:

cgj = τj(1− hλ)y

2

Some of the earliest papers (see Aguiar and Gopinath (2006)) on sovereign default assumed thatλ is the output lost in autarky given that a country is excluded from the financial market afterdefault for stochastic number of periods. Rose (2005) finds evidence that following the initiation ofdebt renegotiation by a country, bilateral trade flows declines by 8% a year. However, some recentpapers such as Hatchondo et al. (2007), Hatchondo et al. (007a), and Hatchondo et al. (2009) thatassume non-exclusion from the financial market, argue that output loss occurs period after default.They argue generally that the assumption of output-loss after default decision is meant to captureany disruptions in economic activity that will be caused by a default. They posit further that asovereign default decreases private sector financing and will thus reduce aggregate output. Alsoas argued in Hatchondo et al. (2007) whether we specify the output loss to be stochastic or onlyone period after default would not make difference. However, we assume in our model it followsthe period after default for simplicity reasons.

43

Page 45: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

where τj is the tax rate of ruler j. This assumption of the tax rate being affected

by corruption is grounded in public capital and corruption, and tax avoidance and

corruption literature (see Chen (2003); Coppier et al. (2006); Ellis and Fender (2006);

Attila (2008)). The specification is to capture the effect of corruption consumption,

borrowing and welfare, through taxation and corrupt consumption.

The ruler in power uses the available resources, after corrupt consumption, to

maximise life time utility subject to Equation (2.3.1.1), by choosing c and b′. Flow

utility of government j is CRRA utility u(c) = c1−ϕ−11−ϕ , where ϕ is the risk aversion

parameter.

At the beginning of the period ruler j in power observes the economy’s endowment

realisation and accordingly makes a default decision on previously issued debt. The

ruler issues an amount −b′j0(b, y, h) of bonds if the decision is not to default. Otherwise,

the ruler issues an amount −b′j1(y, h) of bonds. The type of ruler in power changes

with a probability of turnover rate πj or otherwise sticks to power at the rate (1− πj),

before the next period. In our setting, the probability of turnover is allowed to depend

on the type of government in power. In light of this, the more corrupt ruler faces an

economy with higher political instability than the less corrupt ruler. As stated earlier,

in the follow-up period after a default, the economy suffers an output loss of λ percent.

Ruler j in power compares the value functions Vj1(y, h), if a default is declared

in the current period and Vj0(b, y, h), if a default is not declared in the current period;

where y is the current endowment realisation, and h the credit history.

2.3.2 Solution

We use the value function iteration method to solve the dynamic problem. Let Vj(y, b, h)

denote the value function of a government of type j at the beginning of period t when

in power. Similarly, let Vj(y, b, h) denote the value function of a government of type j

at the beginning of period t when it is not in power. Finally, let πj denote the probab-

ility of political turnover of a government of type j. When deciding whether to default,

the government in power compares two continuation values, Vj1(y, h) and Vj0(y, b, h).

44

Page 46: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

Vj1(y, h) is the value the government would receive if the type j government defaults in

the current period. Vj0(y, b, h) is the value the government would receive if it did not

default in the current period. Since the two government types may differ, the value

functions Vj and Vj do not need to coincide.

The value of a type-j government of defaulting in the current period is given by:

Vj1(y, h) = maxc, b′{u(c) + βE[πjVj(y

′, b′, 1) + (1− πj)Vj(y′, b′, 1)|y]}

(2.3.2.1)

subject to

c+ cgj + qj1(y, b′)b′ = (1− hλ)y

where cgj = τj(1− hλ)y

Since the government is defaulting, d = 1 in Equation (2.3.1.1). The government then

chooses c and b′ subject to this budget constraint. The associated policy functions are

cj1(y, h) and b′j1(y, h).

The value of a type-j government of not defaulting in the current period is given by:

Vj0(y, b, h) = maxc, b′{u(c) + βE[πjVj(y

′, b′, 0) + (1− πj)Vj(y′, b′, 0)|y]}

(2.3.2.2)

subject to

c+ cgj + qj0(y, b′)b′ = (1− hλ)y + b

where cgj = τj(1− hλ)y

Since the government is not defaulting, d = 0 in Equation (2.3.1.1). The government

then chooses c and b′ subject to this budget constraint. The associated policy functions

are cj0(y, b, h) and b′j0(y, b, h).

The value function of the government in power, Vj(y, b, h) is then computed as follows:

Vj(y, b, h) = max(Vj1(y, h), Vj0(y, b, h)) (2.3.2.3)

where d = 1 if Vj1(y, h) ≥ Vj0(y, b, h) (government defaults). Otherwise d = 0. Let

dj(y, b, h) denote the associated policy function:

45

Page 47: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

dj(y, b, h) =

1 if Vj1(y, h) ≥ Vj0(y, b, h)

0 if Vj1(y, h) < Vj0(y, b, h)

(2.3.2.4)

Remaining policy functions are:

cj(y, b, h) =

cj1(y, h) if dj(y, b, h) = 1

cj0(y, b, h) if dj(y, b, h) = 0

b′j(y, b, h) =

b′j1(y, h) if dj(y, b, h) = 1

b′j0(y, b, h) if dj(y, b, h) = 0

The value function of government of type j when it is not in power depends

on the optimal behaviour of the other government, denoted by −j. The value of a

policymaker of type j when it is not in power can be more concisely written as:

Vj(y, b, h) = u(c−j(y, b, h))+

βE[π−jVj(y′, b′−j(y, b, h), d−j(y, b, h))+

(1− π−j)Vj(y′, b′−j(y, b, h), d−j(y, b, h))|y]

(2.3.2.5)

When policymaker j is not in power, it receives no corrupt consumption, but it still

derives utility from household consumption (which is chosen by the other policymaker).

Next period, with probability π−j, policymaker j will become the government in power,

in which case it’s initial state will depend on the actions of the current government.

With probability 1 − π−j, policymaker j will still be out of power. In that case, its

state is still determined by the actions of the government in power.

2.3.3 Bond Price

We define pdefj (y, b′, h′) to be the probability that the type-j government (if it is in

power next period) will default on the debt b′ tomorrow with history h′ given current

endowment realisation y.

46

Page 48: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

pdefj (y, b′, h′) =

∫dj(y

′, b′, h′)f(y′|y)dy′

where f(y′|y) is the probability density function for y′.

The bond price qjd(y, b′) satisfies the lender’s zero-profit condition.

qjd(y, b′) =

1

1 + r[1− πjpdef−j (y, b′, d)− (1− πj)pdefj (y, b′, d)] (2.3.3.1)

Bond prices today depend on the credit history the future government will inherit (h′)

because defaulting in the current period reduces future output. The credit history h′

just reflects the current default decision (i.e. h′ = d). This price qjd(y, b′) reflects two

things. First, with probability πj, the other government will be in power and it will

default with probability pdef−j (y, b′, d). However, with probability (1 − πj), the current

government will remain in power, and it will default with probability pdefj (y, b′, d).

2.3.4 Equilibrium

Governments act sequentially when choosing current levels of taxes, corrupt consump-

tion and debt with foresight. Drawing on the works of Krusell and Smith Jr (2003),

Klein et al. (2008), and Ortigueira et al. (2012) we will concentrate on differentiable

Markov-perfect equilibria of this economy. However, as it is shown in Krusell and

Smith Jr (2003) there is a problem of indeterminacy of Markov-perfect equilibria in

an economy with infinite horizon. Hatchondo et al. (2009) argue that the problem is

avoided analysing the equilibrium that arises as the limit of the finite-horizon economy

equilibrium.

A Markov-perfect equilibrium is defined as:

(1) the set of value functions Vj(y, b, h), Vj0(y, b, h), Vj1(y, h) and Vj(y, b, h) for all

j = L,H

(2) the policy functions cj0, cj1, b′j0(y, b, h), b′j1(y, h) and the default decision rule

dj(y, b, h) for all j = L,H

47

Page 49: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

(3) and the bond price qjd(y, b′) for all j = L,H,

such that

(a) the value functions Vj(y, b, h), Vj0(y, b, h), Vj1(y, h) and Vj(y, b, h) satisfy the func-

tional Equations in (2.3.2.1), (2.3.2.2), (2.3.2.3), (2.3.2.4), (2.3.2.5) and (2.3.3.1).

(b) the policy functions cj0, cj1, b′j0(y, b, h), b′j1(y, h) and dj(y, b, h) solve the dynamic

programming problem specified in Equations (2.3.2.1), (2.3.2.2), (2.3.2.3), (2.3.2.4),

(2.3.2.5) and (2.3.3.1).

(c) the bond price qjd(y, b′) satisfies the lenders’ zero profit condition in Equation3

(2.3.3.1).

2.4 Results

We show that all defaults may be strategic. In addition, we find that in the presence

of corruption and political turnover, the model performs better in many ways. First,

the model is able to generate the moderate correlation between output and default

decisions as it is documented by Tomz and Wright (2007), the latter also influenced

by the level of corruption. Second, the model helps in generating lower issuance levels

after a default episode. Third, the model is able to generate higher but volatile spreads.

Overall, both corruption and political turnover are important in order for the model

to generate higher credit spreads, higher default rates and more volatile interest rates.

2.4.1 Calibration

We solve the model using value function iteration in Fortran 90 (see Appendix (2.6)

for details and Appendix (A.1) for the codes). We calibrate the model to match a typ-

ical emerging economy that is known for corruption and also has history of sovereign

default. Our calibration is summarised in Table (2.4.1.1) and most calibrated para-

meters are based on Hatchondo et al. (2009). The output loss parameter associated

with default is taken to be 8.3%. The risk-free interest rate is set at 1% whilst we

3As in the literature (see Hatchondo et al. (2007); Hatchondo et al. (2009)), we assume the risk-freeinterest rate is such that β(1 + r) < 1.

48

Page 50: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

choose a discount factor of 0.90 equal to the discount factor used by Hatchondo et al.

(2009) for a patient type, and greater than the discount factor (0.80) used by Aguiar

and Gopinath (2006).

We calibrate the tax rates of the less corrupt and more corrupt rulers to be 22%

and 50%, respectively. In our case, the degree of political stability is state dependent

(unlike Hatchondo et al. (2009)), and as such, varies with the level of corruption. The

more corrupt government stays in power for an average duration of 4 years and 3 years,

respectively, under stable and unstable economies. On the other hand, the less corrupt

government stays in power for an average duration of 8 years and 6 years, respectively,

under stable and unstable economies.

2.4.2 Corruption, Political Risk and Default Risk

Our first line of inquiry concerns the question of whether changes in the political

environment associated with changes in the level of corruption can trigger sovereign

default. Cole et al. (1995); Alfaro and Kanczuk (2005); Hatchondo et al. (2009) show

that political circumstances can trigger sovereign default. Hatchondo et al. (2009)

argue that sovereign default is likely to be caused by political turnover4 if there enough

political stability in the economy. We add to their findings by showing that corruption

could be a trigger for sovereign default not only when there is political turnover but

without political turnover. We simulate the model for 1,500,000 periods (1,000 samples

of 1,500 observations each) using the calibrations in Table (2.4.1.1) in order to show

our results.

We show that when there is political stability but a possibility of political turnover,

a change in regime from a less corrupt government to a more corrupt government is

more likely to trigger default than a change in regime from a more corrupt government

to a less corrupt government. In the economy with high political stability, changes from

4

Government turnover rate is the probability with which a government is replaced. Political/Gov-ernment stability on the other hand, is how big or small a turnover rate is. For instance a smallerturnover rate will mean more stability. In the extreme case 0 will mean no turnover but moststability.

49

Page 51: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

Table

2.4.1.1.:

Cal

ibra

tion

Des

crip

tion

Par

amet

erV

alue

Ris

kA

vers

ion

ϕ2

Inte

rest

Rat

er

1%A

uto

corr

elat

ion

Coeffi

cien

tρy

0.95

Sta

ndar

dD

evof

Innov

atio

ns

σε

2.7%

Outp

ut

Los

8.3%

Dis

count

Fac

tor

β0.

90M

ean

(Log

)O

utp

ut

µy

−1 2σ

2 ε

Tax

Rat

eof

Les

sC

orru

pt

Gov

ernm

ent

τ L22

%T

axR

ate

ofM

ore

Cor

rupt

Gov

ernm

ent

τ H50

%Sta

ble

Eco

nom

y’s

Turn

over

Rat

efo

rL

ess

Cor

rupt

Gov

ernm

ent

πs L

3.1%

Unst

able

Eco

nom

y’s

Turn

over

Rat

efo

rL

ess

Cor

rupt

Gov

ernm

ent

πu L

4.4%

Sta

ble

Eco

nom

y’s

Turn

over

Rat

efo

rM

ore

Cor

rupt

Gov

ernm

ent

πs H

7.0%

Unst

able

Eco

nom

y’s

Turn

over

Rat

efo

rM

ore

Cor

rupt

Gov

ernm

ent

πu H

10%

50

Page 52: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

a less corrupt to a more corrupt government triggers default 95.5% of the time, whereas

in an unstable economy, default happens only 2% of the time (see Table (2.7.1.7)). In

the stable economy, it is more likely that the less corrupt policy maker will choose high

debt levels which would lead to a more corrupt policy maker to default.

We have to make certain specific assumptions about certain variables in order to

be able to present some of our results in two-dimensional charts. However, the results

will not change much under alternative assumptions.

There are combinations of debt levels and endowment realisations at which a

more corrupt type defaults and a less corrupt type does not default. For a combina-

tions of debt levels and endowment realisations where the less corrupt type chooses to

default, the more corrupt type will also choose to default. Figure (2.4.2.1) depicts the

value of default and the value of not defaulting for the less corrupt and more corrupt

governments. The value of default does not depend on debt, and is therefore depicted

by horizontal lines, because initial debt becomes zero after a government defaults. The

upward sloping curves depict the expected utility of both governments. They show

that the expected utility decreases with debt when governments do not default. The

line depicting the value of not defaulting for the less corrupt government lies above

the line depicting the value of not defaulting for the more corrupt government. This

implies that there are debt levels (between 0.06 and 0.098) at which the more corrupt

government defaults and less corrupt government does not.

51

Page 53: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

−0.12 −0.1 −0.08 −0.06 −0.04 −0.02 00.12

0.14

0.16

0.18

0.2

0.22

Valu

e f

un

cti

on

fo

r

τL

b

−0.12 −0.1 −0.08 −0.06 −0.04 −0.02 00.14

0.16

0.18

0.2

0.22

0.24

Valu

e f

un

cti

on

fo

r

τH

No de faul t, τL

No de faul t, τH

Defaul t, τL

Defaul t, τH

Figure 2.4.2.1.: Value functions in a stable economy under less and more corruptgovernments. The figure assumes the case where the endowment realisation coincideswith unconditional mean of its distribution, and where the government inherits agood credit history (h = 0).

The optimal default decision of the two types of government is also illustrated in

Figure (2.4.2.2). Figure (2.4.2.2) plots default space against debt and endowment real-

isation for more corrupt and less corrupt governments. The dark area shows combina-

tions of bond positions and endowment realisations at which a more corrupt government

defaults and a less corrupt government does not default. The grey area shows com-

binations of bond positions and endowment realisations at which both types default.

The white area shows combinations of bond positions and endowment realisations at

which neither the less corrupt nor the more corrupt government will default. It shows

that default is more likely with more debt and lower endowment realisations. That

is for any given level of corruption and endowment realisation, the risk of default is

52

Page 54: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

greater with more debt. Similarly, for any given level of debt and corruption, any type

of government is more likely to default when endowment realisation is low than when

endowment realisation is high. The figure shows that the risk of default is greater with

more corruption; at the same level of debt and endowment realisation, default risk is

higher with more corruption.

Figure 2.4.2.2.: Default space against bond issuance and endowment for less andmore corrupt governments, where they inherit a good credit history (h = 0).

This implies that a more corrupt government is more likely to default on lower level

of debt than a less corrupt government will do. Given enough political stability, the

less corrupt policymaker borrows more and the more corrupt policymaker defaults

upon assumption of office. Another reason is that low corruption reduces government

consumption and this in turn increases private consumption. On the other hand, high

corruption leaves less resources for private consumption and the government has a

53

Page 55: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

greater incentive to default and keep the money for itself.

The shape of the bond price function that a government in power faces is affected

by the optimal default strategies of types. Figure (2.4.2.3) presents a plot of the

bond price for less corrupt government under stable and unstable economies, and the

economy without political turnover. The bond price received by the government for

bonds issued is affected by the probability of default the following period, the level

of corruption and the political turnover of the government. As a result, the bond

price functions in economies with political turnover shows three steps. Drawing from

Hatchondo et al. (2009), the right step shows “low” issuance region, where debt issued

is so low that any type of government will surely pay back the following period. Due

to the less risky nature of debt in this region, investor charge the risk-free rate which

results in high bond prices. The middle step shows the “intermediate” issuance region.

In this region, the more corrupt type would default in the following period if he comes

into power, whilst the less corrupt type will choose to pay the debt back if he remains

in power. In this region lenders charge positive spread which depends on the turnover

rate (which is dependent on the government type). This is to say that the more corrupt

government is charged higher spreads than the less corrupt government, for instance,

in a politically stable economy. For a given level of corruption, the spread is higher

in the unstable economy than the stable economy. However, the higher the level of

corruption the higher the spread for each type of economy.

The third step is the “high” issuance region, where both types will default next

period when in power. Consequently, lenders offer low price for bonds issued in this re-

gion. Figure (2.4.2.3) shows that in the “intermediate” region of issuance the better the

price, the more politically stable the economy is. With chances that the more corrupt

assumes power the following period and declares default, the less corrupt government

issuing bonds in this region would have to compensate lenders for default contingency.

An increase in the probability of this contingency results in a decrease in bond price

in the “intermediate” region and the vice versa. The bond price does not feature the

“intermediate” step where there is no turnover and only the less corrupt government

54

Page 56: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

remains in power.

−0.09 −0.08 −0.07 −0.06 −0.05 −0.04 −0.030.94

0.95

0.96

0.97

0.98

0.99

1

b’

Bond p

rice

No turnove r

πs

L= 3.1%

πu

L= 4.4%

1−πu

L

1+ r

1−πs

L

1+ r

1

1+ r

Figure 2.4.2.3.: Bond price for less corrupt government (τL) in stable and unstableeconomies and in economies without political turnover. The figure assumes thecase where the government has not defaulted today and the endowment realisationcorresponds with the unconditional mean of its distribution.

Figure (2.4.2.4) is a plot of objective function of the less corrupt government as

a function of bond issuance. The shape of this objective function of the government

is related to the shape of the bond price function discussed above. Just as in the

bond price function, the objective function increases at “low” issuance levels, whilst in

transition to the second step from the first step of the bond price function, it decreases.

This accounts for the right local maxima. The objective function begins to increase

again once the second step of the bond price function is reached. As the “high” bond

issuance region of the bond price function is reached, the objective function begins

to decline and remain low, which explains the left local maxima. As explained in

55

Page 57: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

Hatchondo et al. (2009) the increasing portions of the objective function are as a result

of the differences between the rate at which future utility flows are discounted and

the interest rate, whilst the decreasing portions are explained by the decline in bond

price as a result of increasing issuance levels. In the politically stable economy, the

optimal borrowing level may occur at the left local maximum, whilst in the politically

unstable economy the optimal borrowing levels may occur at the right local maximum.

The optimal borrowing levels of the less corrupt policymaker in the politically stable

economy is higher and attractive than in the politically unstable economy because as

instability decreases, the less policymaker is charged a lower spread by lenders. This

low spread in a politically stable economy might induce less corrupt policymakers to

choose borrowing levels in the intermediate region which then makes default more likely

when there is change in power to the more corrupt policymaker.

The results in Table (2.4.6.2) displays the expected probabilities of default. It

is observed that, in the stable economy, the probability of default given that the less

corrupt government in power today5 is about 11.13%, whereas the probability of de-

fault given that the more corrupt government in power today is about 0.44%. However,

in the politically unstable economy, the probability of default given that the less cor-

rupt government in power today is about 0.32%, while the probability of default given

that the more corrupt government in power today is about 0.48%. Similarly, in the

politically stable economy, the average number of defaults given that the less corrupt

government is in power today is about 0.20%, while the average number of defaults

given that the more corrupt government in power today is about 0.84%. In the polit-

ically unstable economy, however, the average number of defaults given that the less

corrupt government is in power today is about 0%, while the average number of defaults

given that the more corrupt government in power today is about 0.48%. Overall, the

higher credit spreads faced by the low type in the stable economy reflect the probability

that the high type will come into power next period and default.

5This probability takes into account the possibility that the more corrupt government might bein power tomorrow, but also that the less corrupt government will most likely still be in powertomorrow.

56

Page 58: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

−0.1 −0.09 −0.08 −0.07 −0.06 −0.05 −0.04 −0.03 −0.02 −0.01 04.49

4.5

4.51

4.52

4.53

4.54

4.55

b’

Obje

cti

ve f

uncti

on w

hen π

s L=

3.1

%

−0.1 −0.09 −0.08 −0.07 −0.06 −0.05 −0.04 −0.03 −0.02 −0.01 04.49

4.5

4.51

4.52

4.53

4.54

4.55

Obje

cti

ve f

uncti

on w

hen π

u L=

4.4

%

πs

L= 3.1%

πu

L= 4.4%

Figure 2.4.2.4.: Objective function of a less corrupt government (τL) in the stable andunstable economies. The figure assumes the case where the government has chosennot to default and the endowment realisation corresponds with the unconditionalmean of its distribution, and where the government inherits a good credit history(h = 0).

Figure (2.4.2.5) shows that a less corrupt policymaker chooses intermediate bor-

rowing levels if it encounters intermediate endowment realisations. The right end of the

graph is where the endowment realisation is at its highest and where the less corrupt

policymaker chooses low borrowing level. In other words, when a less corrupt poli-

cymaker faces good economic conditions, political turnover might not trigger default.

The left end of the graph is where the endowment realisation is at its lowest and where

both types of policymakers are likely to default when in power. As the policymaker

defaults and resets its debt level to zero in this low endowment region, it then borrows

less because it has low borrowing needs.

57

Page 59: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

−0.05 0 0.05 0.1 0.15 0.20

0.01

0.02

0.03

0.04

0.05

0.06

0.07

Current Productivity

Borr

ow

ing

b = −0.060

Figure 2.4.2.5.: Optimal bond issuance of a less corrupt government (τL) in a stableeconomy. The government inherits a good credit history (h = 0) and a debt level of−0.0385. Issuance decision is determined after an optimal default decision is madeby the type.

2.4.3 Corruption, Welfare and Consumption

Corruption in our model has important implications for welfare and consumption of

the households. We show that corruption has the propensity to negatively affect the

welfare and consumption of the households. Following the seminal work of Lucas

(1987), we estimate welfare loss (consumption equivalent) as the percentage decrease in

consumption in the non-corrupt economy which makes households indifferent between

the corrupt economy and the non-corrupt economy. Table (2.4.3.1) shows the average

household consumption equivalent welfare loss (in percentage terms) for the less and

more corrupt (see Appendix (3.5.5) for detailed derivation of welfare loss). Again,

the results indicate that welfare loss increases with the level of corruption. In other

58

Page 60: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

words, the results show how much households are willing to pay (and this amount is

more when a more corrupt policymaker is in office) in order to have corruption-free

consumption. On the whole, the results show that households are willing to give up

(43%) of consumption in the non-corrupt economy when a more corrupt policymaker

is in office and (28%) of consumption in the non-corrupt economy when a less corrupt

policymaker is in office, in order to have corruption-free consumption.

Table 2.4.3.1.: Average Consumption Equivalent Welfare Loss

Level of Corruption Consumption Equivalent Welfare LossτL 28%τH 43%

2.4.4 Characteristics of Debt and Spread around Defaults

We define two types of defaults. The first is a “non-political default”, which is any

default that is not triggered by a change in government. The second, “political default”,

are all the defaults which are triggered by a change in government (see Hatchondo et al.

(2009)). It is argued that during political default, post-default issuance levels are lower

than pre-default issuance levels, whilst in a non-political default there are no differences

between pre-default and post-default issuance levels (see Hatchondo et al. (2009)).

We show results that are consistent with the literature. Figure (2.4.4.1) shows the

differences between pre-default issuance levels and post-default issuance levels under

political and non-political defaults.

Hatchondo et al. (2009) find that if the same government remains in power after

a non-political default, there should not be difference between pre-default and post-

default issuance levels. We find a similar result. We argue that once the type of

borrower (less corrupt government or more corrupt governments) does not change and

is common knowledge to lenders, there is no need to charge different (higher) spreads

which then results in no change in issuance levels. Around political defaults, however,

we find that post-default issuance levels are lower than pre-default issuance levels. We

argue that as the less corrupt government (whose optimal borrowing is in the interme-

diate region) is replaced by the more corrupt government (whose optimal borrowing

59

Page 61: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

should be the low issuance region as discussed earlier), post-default issuance levels will

be lower than pre-default issuance levels. As the next policymaker (more corrupt)

prefers to borrow in the low issuance region, we expect lenders to charge low spreads

in the period immediately following a default.

−4 −3 −2 −1 0 1 2 3 40.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

0.6

0.7

0.8

0.9

1

1.1

1.2

Period

Chan

ge

in I

ssuan

ce o

f B

onds

Political default

Non−political default

Figure 2.4.4.1.: Average issuance level before and after a default episode in an eco-nomy with high political stability. The default period is 0. Political defaults arewhere less corrupt government is replace by more corrupt government, and non-political defaults are where only a less corrupt government is in power.

Figure (2.4.4.2) shows why more corrupt policymaker might choose lower issuance

volumes. The bond price faced by the more corrupt depicts three steps just as the less

corrupt policymaker. If a more corrupt policymaker is in office today, it is very likely

the next policymaker will also be more corrupt. Following our previous assertion that

the more corrupt policymaker defaults at intermediate debt levels, lenders charge high

spread for intermediate borrowing levels. This accordingly, explains why the bond

60

Page 62: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

price in the intermediate region is close to zero. Bond price in the low issuance region

is higher than that in the intermediate region which explains why the more corrupt

policymaker will borrow in the low issuance region.

−0.1 −0.09 −0.08 −0.07 −0.06 −0.05 −0.040

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

0.6

0.7

0.8

0.9

1

b’

Bond p

rice

πs

H= 7%

πu

H= 10%

Figure 2.4.4.2.: Bond price faced by a more corrupt government (τH) in the stableand unstable economies. The figure assumes the case where the government hasdefaulted today and the endowment realisation corresponds with the unconditionalmean of its distribution.

Figure (2.4.4.3) shows plots of pre-default and post-default average spread levels.

In political default, post-default spreads are lower than pre-default spreads. Less cor-

rupt policymakers choose intermediate borrowing levels before political default, and as

a result are charged intermediate spreads. The more corrupt replaces the less corrupt

and after a default is declared the more corrupt borrows in the low issuance region

and lenders respond by charging low spreads in the period immediately following a

default. However, if default is non-political, post-default spreads are not different than

61

Page 63: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

pre-default spreads because as the type of government does not change, lenders do not

see the need to charge different spreads for the two periods.

−4 −3 −2 −1 0 1 2 3 40

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1

1.2

1.4

Period

Change i

n s

pre

ad

Political default

Non−political default

Figure 2.4.4.3.: Average spread before and after a default episode in an economywith high political stability. The default period is 0. Political defaults are whereless corrupt government is replace by more corrupt government, and non-politicaldefaults are where only a less corrupt government is in power.

2.4.5 Output and Default

Tomz and Wright (2007) in their studies using data set with 169 default cases, report

that 38% of default episodes in their sample occurred in years when the output level in

the defaulting country was above the trend value. However, the inability to replicate

the weak correlation observed in the data, they argue is as a result of the absence of

turnover in their baseline model. To illustrate this, Hatchondo et al. (2009) report

that only 3% and 7% of default episodes occur where all policymakers are patient and

impatient respectively, in periods where the output level is above its long-run mean and

62

Page 64: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

when there is no turnover. Table (2.4.5.1) illustrates our findings. We find that only

6% of defaults episodes occur in periods where the output level is above its long-run

mean when all policymakers are less corrupt. This percentage decreases to 5.3% when

all policymakers are more corrupt.

Introducing political turnover into their model, Hatchondo et al. (2009) find that

in an economy with high political stability, 38% of default episodes occur in periods

where output is above its long-run mean and this decreases to 7% in an unstable

political economy. We find that in a politically stable economy when less corrupt poli-

cymakers are in power, 3.57% of defaults episodes occur in periods where the output

level is above its long-run mean. This increases to 46.85% when more corrupt policy-

makers are in power. In politically unstable economy when less corrupt policymakers

are in power, we find that 0% of defaults episodes occur in periods where the output

level is above its long-run mean. This percentage increases to 7.45% when more corrupt

policymakers are in power. Overall, we find that in a stable political economy, 45.93%

of default episodes occur in periods where output is above its long-run mean and this

decreases to 7.45% in an unstable political economy.

Table 2.4.5.1.: Fraction of Default Episodes above Long-Run Mean

τL only τH only πsL = 3.1% πsH = 7.0% πuL = 4.4% πuH = 10%6.00% 5.30% 3.57% 46.85% 0.00 % 7.45%

All Stable All Unstable

- - 45.93% 7.45%

Default episodes that occur when output is above its long-run mean.

2.4.6 Corruption, Political Turnover and Business Cycle Statistics

We now look at the implications of corruption for business cycles in the economy.

Most studies of sovereign default place emphasis on the ability of quantitative sov-

ereign default model to replicate the macroeconomic characteristics of emerging eco-

nomies before a default. We discuss how the predictions of our baseline model change

when we introduce political turnover. To show this, we simulate economies without

turnover–where the type of policymaker in power does not change (i.e. π = 0)–and

compare these simulations with economies with political turnover (i.e. π > 0 ).

63

Page 65: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

To compare quarterly simulated data to that of Nigeria for the period 1993Q1-

2000Q4, we simulate the model for 1,000 samples each with 1,500 observations (quar-

ters). Nigeria is used as a benchmark because of its long history of corruption and

political disturbance. In addition, Nigeria has reportedly defaulted as many as five

times6 (in 1982, 1986, 1992, 2001 and 2004). We compare data from this period with

data from simulation samples where only less corrupt policymakers are in power. Ad-

ditionally, we also show simulation results for an economy with only more corrupt

policymakers. Further, we present simulation results with political turnover and ex-

tract the first 1,000 samples with 32 quarters, when the type of government in power

is either the less corrupt or the more corrupt. Finally, we present unconditional results

using the first 1000 samples with 32 quarters without imposing any restriction on the

type of policymakers in power.

High, volatile, and countercyclical interest rates; highly volatile relative consump-

tion; countercyclical net exports are some of the stylised facts of emerging economies.

Table (2.4.6.1) documents our results. We present trade balance as a fraction of output

(TB/Y ), annual interest rate spread Rs, logarithm of income (y), logarithm of con-

sumption (c), mean probability of default Pr(D), mean number of defaults E(D) and

average spread E(Rs). We HP filter all series with a quarterly smoothing parameter,

1, 600. Standard deviations denoted by σ are reported in percentages. We denote cor-

relations by ρ. The second column of Table (2.4.6.1) shows the moments in the data.

In the third column of the table we present the average business cycle moments in an

economy with only less corrupt policymakers, whilst in the fourth column we present

average moments in an economy with only more corrupt policymakers. In the fifth

column are the average business cycle moments under a less corrupt policymaker in a

stable economy with turnover rate of πsL = 3.1%. The sixth column reports the aver-

age business cycle moments under a less corrupt policymaker in an unstable economy

6 As is reported in Standard and Poors, Moodys, World Bank Development Indicators, the IMF and

World Bank–Global Development Finance (1991, 2006, 2012).

64

Page 66: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

with turnover rate of πuL = 4.4%. Finally, the seventh and eighth columns display the

unconditional average business cycle moments in a stable economy and an unstable

economy, respectively.

The moments of the data as reported in Table (2.4.6.1) display the striking fea-

tures of a developing economy like Nigeria: counter-cyclicality of net exports (-0.21 )

and interest rate spreads (-0.64); and the pro-cyclicality of consumption (0.15). An-

other striking feature of the business cycles of Nigeria as displayed in the data is the high

volatility of output (1.40%), consumption (5.60%) and interest rate spreads (11.62%),

which are typical stylised facts of developing economies. In particular, these features

about interest rate spreads including their high volatility have been observed by others

including Perri and Neumeyer (2004) to be true for many emerging economies.

In the presence of political turnover and corruption, the ability of the model to

generate high spreads is improved. The average spread observed when less corrupt

policymaker is in office in the politically stable economy is 12.86%, compared with

0.37% in the politically unstable economy. When we compare this to the case when

only less corrupt policymakers are in office, the average spread is 0.33%. As we argued

above, in the politically stable economy, the less corrupt optimally will borrow in the

high issuance region which leads to default when the more corrupt policymaker takes

office. Consequently, lenders charge the less corrupt higher spreads in the politically

stable economy than in the politically unstable economy.

In the stable economy, average spread observed by the less corrupt policymaker

(12.86%) is higher than the average spread observed by the less corrupt policymaker

(0.33%) and the more corrupt policymaker (0.33%), when political turnover is absent.

In the economy where all governments are less corrupt, the average spread is 0.33%.

Similarly, in the economy where all governments are more corrupt, the average spread

is 0.33%. Corruption and political turnover act as the mechanism through which the

model generates a higher average spread. In the model, political turnover amplifies

the effect of corruption because with a low turnover rate, less corrupt governments

are willing to pay the premium for the possibility that a more corrupt government

65

Page 67: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

Table

2.4.6.1.:

Busi

nes

sC

ycl

eSta

tist

ics

Eco

nom

y

Sta

tist

icD

ata

No

Turn

over

No

Turn

over

Sta

ble

Unst

able

Sta

ble

Unst

able

τ Lon

lyτ H

only

τ Lτ L

Unco

ndit

ional

Unco

ndit

ional

σ(y

)1.

403.

183.

183.

163.

153.

183.

18σ

(c)

5.60

3.27

3.27

3.23

3.20

8.25

9.65

σ(TB/Y

)0.

600.

150.

10.

160.

110.

330.

11σ

(Rs)

11.6

20.

180.

170.

470.

322.

020.

26ρ(c,y

)0.

151.

001.

001.

001.

000.

340.

31ρ(TB/Y,y

)-0

.21

-0.3

6-0

.36

-0.2

8-0

.27

-0.1

1-0

.26

ρ(Rs,y)

-0.6

4-0

.1-0

.09

-0.1

5-0

.14

-0.0

6-0

.07

ρ(Rs,TB/Y

)0.

10-0

.04

-0.1

0-0

.12

-0.1

7-0

.05

-0.0

9E(Rs)

9.60

0.33

0.33

12.8

60.

376.

690.

37E(D

)-

0.24

0.23

0.20

0.00

5.91

0.28

Pr(D

)-

0.32

0.33

11.1

30.

325.

820.

37

Mom

ents

from

the

mod

elar

eav

erag

esu

sin

g1,0

00

sam

ple

sof

32

per

iod

sea

ch.

Inco

lum

ntw

ow

eu

sed

ata

for

Nig

eria

from

1993Q

1-2

000Q

4.

Exce

pt

corr

elat

ion

coeffi

cien

ts,

all

stat

isti

csare

inp

erce

nta

ges

.

E(D

)is

mea

nnu

mb

erof

def

ault

sp

eran

nu

m.

Pr(D

)is

mea

np

rob

abil

ity

ofd

efau

ltp

eran

nu

m.

Ave

rage

spre

ad,E(Rs)

and

vola

tili

tyof

spre

ad

(Rs)

are

per

an

nu

m.

Res

tof

stat

isti

csar

equar

terl

y.

66

Page 68: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

will default. Also, political turnover impacts on the ability of the model to generate

a higher average spread because it smoothes out the bond price function Hatchondo

et al. (2009).

The smoother bond price function results in a larger increase in the issuance level

when there is a decrease in the bond price. Given that corrupt policymakers have the

incentive to issue more debt, lower bond prices make it attractive for them to do so

and pay a higher spread. Tables (2.4.6.1) and (2.4.6.2), display the non-monotonic

relationship between the degree of political stability and both the average spread and

default probability. Starting with column 3 in Table (2.4.6.1), where a less corrupt

policymaker is in power in the first period and where turnover is absent; i.e. π = 0, an

increase in the turnover rate to πsL = 3.1% increases the average spread from 0.33% to

12.86%. The average spread decreases to 0.37% when turnover rate increases to πuL =

4.4%. Similarly, starting with the case of no turnover in Table (2.4.6.2), an increase in

the turnover rate to πsL = 3.1% increases the average probability of default from 0.32%

to 11.13% which decreases to 0.32% when turnover rate increases to πuL = 4.4%. Does

it mean that default is likely to occur in an unstable economy and under more corrupt

policymakers? Using the average spreads discussed above as a proxy for default, the

answer will likely be no. The average spreads and probabilities of default in Tables

(2.4.6.1) and (2.4.6.2) appear to be higher in the politically stable economy than in

the politically unstable economy. In the stable economy, less corrupt governments pay

high spreads than in the unstable case, despite the fact they are less likely to default.

However, as can be seen from Table (2.4.6.2), less corrupt governments pay higher

spreads to compensate lenders for the possibility that a more corrupt government will

come into power next period and default. Similarly, in the stable economy, the average

probability of default is higher when a less corrupt government is in power. However,

in a stable economy, the average default episodes are higher when a more corrupt

policymaker is in power than when a less corrupt policymaker is in power, but smaller

than the unconditional case (see Table (2.4.6.2)).

As we argued above, corruption affects the outcome of our model in many ways

67

Page 69: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

Table 2.4.6.2.: Default Risk Statistics

Economy

StatisticNo Turnover No Turnover Stable Unstable

τL only τH only - -E(Rs) 0.33% 0.33% 6.69% 0.37%E(Rs|τL is in Power) 0.33% - 12.86% 0.37%E(Rs|τH is in Power) - 0.33% 0.43% 0.46%E(D) 0.24% 0.23% 5.91% 0.28%E(D|τL is in Power) 0.24% - 0.20% 0.00%E(D|τH is in Power) - 0.23 % 0.84% 0.48%Pr(D) 0.32% 0.33% 5.82% 0.37%Pr(D|τL is in Power) 0.32% - 11.13% 0.32%Pr(D|τH is in Power) - 0.33% 0.44% 0.48%

E(D) is mean number of defaults per annum.

Pr(D) is mean probability of default per annum.

E(Rs) is expected spread per annum.

including the ability to raise the turnover rate, π, reducing households disposable

income and welfare. Political turnover, on the other hand, as observed by Hatchondo

et al. (2009) works through two forces to impact on the mean spread. Firstly, an

increase in both corruption and turnover results in an increase in the spread paid at

intermediate borrowing levels. Secondly, an increase in turnover and corruption makes

the intermediate borrowing levels less attractive to policymakers. When turnover is low,

policymakers choose intermediate borrowing levels and therefore changes in turnover,

π, are more effective in affecting the spread when turnover, π, is small to begin with.

When turnover, π, is large to begin with, the second effect of turnover and corruption

dominates, as the intermediate region becomes less attractive.

Further more, Table (2.4.6.1) displays the volatility of the model. In the presence

of political turnover, the model is able to generate higher spread volatility. When a

less corrupt policymaker is in office, the standard deviation of the spread is 0.47% in

the economy with high political stability, whereas in the economy with low political

stability the standard deviation of spread is 0.32%. In contract, in the economies

without political turnover, the standard deviation of spread is 0.18% where only less

corrupt governments are in office and 0.17% where only more corrupt governments are

in office. Yet, spread is most volatile, (2.02%), in the politically stable economy without

68

Page 70: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

any restriction on the type of government in power. Consumption appears to be most

volatile in the politically stable and unstable economies (columns 7 and 8 of Table

(2.4.6.1)) without restriction on the type of government in power. Similarly, trade

balance is most volatile in the politically stable economy (column 7 of Table (2.4.6.1))

without restriction on the type of government in power. However, the introduction

of corruption and political turnover do not significantly affect some business cycle

moments including output. Both the level of corruption and political turnover play

a major role in generating higher volatility in the model. Additionally, we observe a

very strong (positive) correlation between output and consumption in the cases with

turnover, when a less corrupt government is in power and for the cases without turnover

(when only a less corrupt policymaker or only a more corrupt policymaker is in office).

However, the correlation between output and consumption is weaker when there is

turnover without restriction on the type in power. Also, we find a counter-cyclical

relationship between output and trade balance. Finally, we find a weak and counter-

cyclical relationship between spread and both output and trade balance.

2.5 Conclusion

The principal aim of this paper is to explain how the incidence of corruption might

impact on sovereign borrowing and default decisions. Our empirical analysis provides

strong evidence that higher levels of corruption and political stability are conducive to

higher risks of default, and our theoretical analysis shows that corruption can generate

significant risks of default and credit spreads when there is enough political stability

We establish that a change in power from a less corrupt to a more corrupt government

is more likely to cause default than the reverse. We establish that welfare loss to

households increases in the level of corruption. The policy implication of the paper is

that corruption and government spending have important roles to play in explaining

sovereign default. Efforts by international organisations to prevent sovereign debt crises

should not only involve assistance in the design of better fiscal policies, but also tackle

the root cause of the problem which is corruption.

69

Page 71: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

2.6 Appendix A

2.6.1 Computational Method

This section describes the computational method we have used to solve the model. We

solve the government’s problem by value function iteration using grid search technique

over 200 grid points for bond position and 30 grid points for the endowment shock. In

the model simulation, we use 1, 000 samples of 1, 500 periods each. To approximate

output we use the Tauchen (1986) approximation process. The computation is done in

Fortran 90.

We discretise the asset space into 200 grid points [b, b] and endowment space into

30 grid points [y, y] . We choose a relative error tolerance level, ε = 10−6. We start

with an initial guess for the value functions: value of being in power V (0), value of

default V(0)d , value of no default V

(0)nd , and value of being in opposition V 0. We use grid

search over the endowment and asset grids to locate the maximum values and update

the value functions of being in power: V (1), V(1)d and V

(1)nd . Given these updates we

then also update the policy functions and bond price. Then using the updated value

functions, policy functions and bond price, we update the value of not being in power

V 1.

Finally, we compute the distance, d, between V (0) and V (1); and d, between V 0

and V 1. We then evaluate whether the maximum absolute deviation between the new

and previous continuation values is below the relative error tolerance level ε = 10−6. If

it is, a solution has been found. Otherwise, the optimisation procedure is repeated until

the maximum absolute deviation between the new and previous continuation values is

below 10−6.

Using the results from the iteration we simulate the model for 1, 000 samples of

1, 500 observations each. See Appendix (A.1.2) for details of the code.

70

Page 72: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

2.6.2 Consumption Equivalent Welfare Loss

Let λ denote the consumption equivalent of welfare loss, the fraction of consumption

one would be willing to give up in each period in the the economy ruled by a non-corrupt

policymaker.

E(V non-corruptt (λ)) = Et

∞∑t=0

βt

[((1 + λ)ct)

1−ϕ − 1

1− ϕ

]λ shows up every period and we assume it is deterministic and this reduces to:

E(V non-corruptt (λ)) = (1 + λ)1−ϕE

(V non-corruptt +

1

(1− ϕ)(1− β)

)− 1

(1− ϕ)(1− β)

Then we want to find the λ that equates this with expected welfare in a corrupt

economy (with less corrupt and more corrupt policymakers). We have:

(1 + λ)1−ϕ(EV non-corrupt

t +1

(1− ϕ)(1− β)

)− 1

(1− ϕ)(1− β)= E(V corrupt

t )

Then

λ =

E(V corruptt ) + 1

(1−ϕ)(1−β)(E(V non-corrupt

t ) + 1(1−ϕ)(1−β)

) 1

1−ϕ

− 1

If we take the economy with no corrupt policymaker to have higher welfare, then

λ < 0. This means households are willing to give up consumption in the high welfare

economy (with no corrupt policymaker) to have the same welfare as an economy with

lower welfare (with a corrupt economy).

2.7 Appendix B

2.7.1 List of Tables

2.7.1.1 Data Sample and Description of Terms Used in Regression

71

Page 73: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

Table 2.7.1.1.: Sample of Defaulting and Debt Rescheduling Countries Used for PanelModel

Country Period Examined Rescheduling+Default

Argentina 1984-2008 9Algeria 1984-2008 1Cote D’ivore 1984-2008 8Cameroon 1984-2008 9Costa Rica 1984-2008 5Dominican Republic 1984-2008 11Ecuador 1984-2008 11Ethiopia 1984-2008 6Gabon 1984-2008 8Gambia 1984-2008 4Indonesia 1984-2008 5Kenya 1984-2008 3Kazakhstan 1992-2008 2Moldova 1992-2008 6Nigeria 1984-2008 10Pakistan 1984-2008 3Paraguay 1984-2008 2Peru 1984-2008 8Russia 1992-2008 6Sri Lanka 1984-2008 1South Africa 1984-2008 2Tanzania 1984-2008 6Uruguay 1984-2008 5Venezuela 1984-2008 6Zambia 1984-2008 11Total 1984-2008 148

The final sample is comprised of 25 countries.

587 observations.

72

Page 74: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

Table

2.7.1.2.:

Var

iable

sfo

rE

mpir

ical

Wor

k

Var

iable

Des

crip

tion

Sou

rce

Eff

ect

Def

ault

Sov

erei

gnD

efau

lt/R

esch

edule

Wor

ldB

ank

Dev

elop

men

tIn

dic

ator

s

logG

DP

PC

Log

arit

hm

ofG

DP

per

Cap

ita

Wor

ldB

ank

Dev

elop

men

tIn

dic

ator

s(-

+)

corr

ICR

GIC

RG

mea

sure

ofco

rrupti

onP

olit

ical

Ris

kSer

vic

es(+

)

Pol

ista

bilit

yP

olit

ical

Sta

bilit

yF

reed

omH

ouse

Inte

rnat

ional

(+)

Extd

ebtr

atio

Exte

rnal

Deb

tto

GD

Pra

tio

Wor

ldB

ank

Dev

elop

men

tIn

dic

ator

s(+

)

GD

Pgr

owth

Rea

lG

DP

Gro

wth

Wor

ldB

ank

Dev

elop

men

tIn

dic

ator

s(-

)

ICR

Gis

Inte

rnat

ion

alC

ountr

yR

isk

Gu

ide

GD

Pp

erC

apit

ais

con

stan

t20

00U

Sd

olla

rs

73

Page 75: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

2.7.1.2 Empirical Model Results

Table 2.7.1.3.: Summary Statistics

Variable Mean Std. Dev. Min. Max. NDefault 0.252 0.435 0 1 587corrICRG 3.428 1.039 0 6 584Polistability 6 1.891 3 9 575logGDPPC 10.737 2.411 6.726 16.03 581GDPgrowth 0.035 0.044 -0.171 0.183 582Extdebtratio 0.708 0.475 0.032 4.149 573

Table 2.7.1.4.: Probit models; dependent variable: Default - (excluding laggeddefault)

VariableProbit Models: Coefficients Marginal Effects

PROB I PROB II PROB III mfx I mfx II mfx IIIcorrICRGt 0.087 0.113 0.114 0.028 0.036 0.036

[0.065] [0.067]* [0.067]* [0.021] [0.021]* [0.021]*Polistabilityt 0.082 0.079 0.079 0.026 0.025 0.025

[0.035]** [0.035]** [0.035]** [0.011]** [0.011]** [0.011]**Extdebtratiot 0.593 0.602 0.599 0.188 0.190 0.189

[0.127]*** [0.126]*** [0.128]*** [0.040]*** [0.040]*** [0.040]***GDPgrowtht -0.099 -0.203 -0.032 -0.064

[1.318] [1.315] [0.419] [0.416]logGDPPCt -0.037 -0.037 -0.012 -0.012

[0.025] [0.025] [0.008] [0.008]Constant -1.896 -1.584 -1.577

[0.404]*** [0.471]*** [0.473]***Observations 557 556 556 557 556 556

Standard errors in brackets

* p<10%, ** p<5%, *** p<1%

74

Page 76: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

Table 2.7.1.5.: Probit models; dependent variable: Default - (excluding laggeddefault)

VariableProbit Models: Coefficients Marginal Effects

PROB I PROB II PROB III mfx I mfx II mfx IIIcorrICRGt−1 0.113 0.128 0.138 0.036 0.040 0.043

[0.066]* [0.068]* [0.068]** [0.021]* [0.021]* [0.021]**Polistabilityt−1 0.097 0.094 0.094 0.030 0.029 0.029

[0.035]*** [0.035]*** [0.035]*** [0.011]*** [0.011]*** [0.011]***Extdebtratiot−1 0.583 0.616 0.587 0.183 0.193 0.183

[0.125]*** [0.124]*** [0.125]*** [0.039]*** [0.039]*** [0.039]***GDPgrowtht−1 -1.908 -2.006 -0.599 -0.627

[1.305] [1.302] [0.410] [0.407]logGDPPCt−1 -0.031 -0.032 -0.010 -0.010

[0.025] [0.025] [0.008] [0.008]Constant -2.018 -1.820 -1.746

[0.410]*** [0.479]*** [0.481]***Observations 556 555 555 556 555 555

Standard errors in brackets

* p<10%, ** p<5%, *** p<1%

Table 2.7.1.6.: Probit models; dependent variable: Default - (including laggeddefault)

VariableProbit Models: Coefficients Marginal Effects

PROB I PROB II PROB III mfx I mfx II mfx IIIDefaultt−1 0.666 0.646 0.649 0.225 0.217 0.218

[0.131]*** [0.131]*** [0.131]*** [0.046]*** [0.047]*** [0.047]***corrICRGt−1 0.102 0.112 0.123 0.031 0.034 0.038

[0.067] [0.069] [0.070]* [0.021] [0.021] [0.021]*Polistabilityt−1 0.083 0.081 0.081 0.026 0.025 0.025

[0.036]** [0.036]** [0.036]** [0.011]** [0.011]** [0.011]**Extdebtratiot−1 0.462 0.500 0.468 0.142 0.154 0.144

[0.128]*** [0.126]*** [0.128]*** [0.039]*** [0.039]*** [0.039]***GDPgrowtht−1 -2.027 -2.110 -0.625 -0.648

[1.326] [1.323] [0.409] [0.406]logGDPPCt−1 -0.025 -0.027 -0.008 -0.008

[0.026] [0.026] [0.008] [0.008]Constant -2.002 -1.853 -1.774

[0.417]*** [0.489]*** [0.490]***Observations 556 555 555 556 555 555

Standard errors in brackets

* p<10%, ** p<5%, *** p<1%

75

Page 77: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

2.7.1.3 Theoretical Model Results

Table 2.7.1.7.: Mean Number of Defaults Given Change in Type

Economy

Stable UnstableExpected Number of Defaults Given Change to Less Corrupt 0.00% 0.00%Expected Number of Defaults Given Change to More Corrupt 95.5% 2%

Mean number of defaults per annum.

76

Page 78: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

Chapter 3

Limited Contract Enforcement and

Firm Financing

3.1 Introduction

The role that financial factors and financial development play in economic activity has

long been documented in the business cycle literature (see Gertler (1988); Carlstrom

and Fuerst (1997, 1998)). However, this role (such as smoothing fluctuations and en-

hancing productive efficiency) hinges crucially on the existence of good institutions

where financial contracts are well enforced. Hence, when the market for loans has an

imperfection such that agents can choose to default on their debt at an exogenous cost

governed by the quality of institutions, economic development becomes undermined.

Levine et al. (2000) find that contract enforcement promotes financial development,

while the latter is conducive to economic growth. In particular, developing economies

do not only have weak legal institutions to enforce contracts but are also character-

ised by high lending rates, unavailability of capital and a generally risky investment

environment.

There is a broad literature on asymmetric information and agency costs associated

with financial markets (see Bernanke et al. (1999); De Fiore et al. (2011); Carlstrom and

Fuerst (1998, 2001); Carlstrom et al. (2010)). Recent models of agency costs normally

assume that borrowers possess private information which lenders can gain access to

77

Page 79: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

only after paying some monitoring or verification cost. This paper seeks to contribute

to the literature on agency costs, asymmetric information and financial development

by studying the role of limited contract enforcement1 in a Dynamic Stochastic General

Equilibrium (DSGE) framework. We do so by allowing for the possibility of the firm

being able to default on bank loans when it is still solvent. At the same time, a

defaulting firm faces the prospect of being punished if it is caught. This punishment

involves the confiscation of some fraction of a firm’s capital output, where the size of

this fraction depends on the quality of legal institutions. Given limited enforcement,

an entrepreneur may decide to default even though its solvent. The results of the paper

emphasise the role that limited enforcement plays in determining the default risk and

access to funding by small firms.

The growth of firms depends on the level of access to external financing which

in turn depends largely on the informational asymmetries and the contractual ar-

rangements between investors and entrepreneurs. In a dynamic general equilibrium

framework, Amaral and Quintin (2010) find that the average scale of production in-

creases with the quality of enforcement and that the importance of limited enforcement

rises with the importance of capital in production2. Whilst imperfect information cre-

ates uncertainty about the default risk of borrowers, limited enforceability of financial

contracts reflects how much lenders loose in the event that borrowers default.

The above analysis yields interesting insights although one issue that is not looked

at is the effect of limited enforcement on firm funding and default risk. Costly contract

enforcement means that lenders will receive less compensation when firms default which

will impact on default risk. In turn, this will alter contract arrangements and vice versa.

Imperfect information can have important implications for borrowing and lending,

especially when there is limited enforcement of contracts.

Limited enforceability of contracts is especially important for new and smaller

firms who face working capital constraints and collateral problems which mean that

1Limited contract enforcement refers to the difficulty with which lenders can recover defaulted loans.Also, the World Bank have likened (limited) contract enforcement to the time and cost for resolvingcommercial dispute through courts.

2That is to say bad enforcement results in self-financing of production and on a small scale.

78

Page 80: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

they rely mostly on external (as opposed to internal) financing. This has implications

not only for the growth of small firms but also for aggregate growth and welfare. It

is argued by Albuquerque and Hopenhayn (2000) that strong enforceability can help

explain the growth of small and new firms. Amaral and Quintin (2010) find that weak

enforceability has a negative effect on small firms’ access to finance, arguing that such

firms are forced to rely mainly on self-funding and to operate on a small scale because

of credit constraints which deny them of external funding. Additionally, Steinberg

(2013) argued that in countries with imperfect financial markets, productive firms are

mostly financially constrained. As a result, firms are impaired from borrowing enough

to reach their optimal sizes.

In spite of the above, little research has been conducted–especially within the

context of a DSGE framework–on exploring the interlinkages between limited contract

enforcement, asymmetric information, financial intermediation and firm funding. The

present paper seeks to do this. In particular, we study the implications of limited

enforcement for financial intermediation, small firm funding, economic growth and

welfare in a DSGE framework. We do this by modifying the models of Carlstrom and

Fuerst (1997) to allow for the imperfect enforcement on loan contracts. In doing so,

we draw upon the works of Khan and Ravikumar (2001), Marcet and Marimon (1992),

Castro et al. (2004), Quintin (2000), Cooley et al. (2003), Boedo et al. (2011), Bernanke

et al. (1999), De Fiore et al. (2011), and Amaral and Quintin (2010). Our work relates

with Cooley et al. (2003) on the assumption that firms which default in one period

are not excluded from the financial market in subsequent periods. We make the same

assumption, but also assume that firms can use funds from defaulting in next period

production. Marcet and Marimon (1992) argue that better investor protection in the

form of better contract enforcement leads to better risk sharing which creates a greater

supply of loanable funds. This results in a greater demand for capital which leads

to a higher interest rate but which also raises the income of households; at the same

time, there is a reduction in entrepreneurs’ income, a reduction in current savings and

79

Page 81: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

a reduction in next period capital3. Their central conclusion is that better contract

enforcement results in less growth. We challenge this conclusion by arguing that better

contract enforcement helps in the transfer of resources to lenders (households) which

is accessed via banks by small firms to finance investment projects.

We show that business cycle fluctuations and the volatility of output are affected

by the degree of limited contract enforcement. Specifically, we establish that limited

enforcement amplifies the effects of shocks on the economy. We also find that limited

enforcement coupled with the ability of firms to default when solvent creates a problem

for the establishment and growth of smaller firms as a result of over accumulation of

internal funds by larger firms. Finally, given that firms are able to default when

solvent, and that households provide loanable funds, we also demonstrate that limited

enforcement is associated with welfare loss to households.

As indicated earlier, our work follows Bernanke et al. (1999), De Fiore et al.

(2011), Carlstrom and Fuerst (1998, 2001), and Carlstrom et al. (2010) on asymmetric

information in financial markets. To engage in investment opportunities, risk neutral

entrepreneurs have the potential to access funds from lenders. However, this funding

is constrained because of the agency costs involved. Lenders are risk averse households

who offer loans to entrepreneurs through the Capital Market Fund (CMF)/Bank. A

key feature of our model is the distinction between the monitoring cost and enforcement

cost, in the event that an entrepreneur defaults on its loan. We show how a high degree

of limited enforcement results in a loss of welfare to households and the economy in

general. We find that a high degree of limited contract enforcement reduces the supply

of funds and impedes small firms’ access to working capital which has implications for

the growth of the economy. We establish that the probability of default, risk premium

and the resulting cost of borrowing increase monotonically with the degree of limited

contract enforcement. We also show that the effects of both aggregate productivity and

wealth transfer shocks are amplified by an increase in the degree of limited contract

enforcement.

3A supply side effect works through the demand effect. When the supply side effect is stronger, thestricter the restrictions on capital flows (Castro et al. (2004)).

80

Page 82: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

As a motivation for our theoretical analysis, we first conduct an empirical in-

vestigation into the effect of limited enforcement and poor depth of credit information

on output. Depth of credit information in our empirical work relates closely to the

monitoring cost in our theoretical model. In a similar vein, limited enforcement in our

empirical work proxies for the degree of limited enforcement in our theoretical model,

which pertains to the “cost” that lenders have to incur (through the legal system e.g.

legal fees) in order to recover any “hidden capital from defaulting firms. Using data on

a broad sample of countries, we find that limited enforcement affects output negatively.

Also, we find that poor credit information has negative impact on output. This results

are robust to various sensitivity tests.

The rest of the paper is organised as follows. In Section (3.2), we present the

empirical analysis of the effect of limited enforcement on output. In Section (3.3), we

set out the theoretical model that we use to study the relationship between firm funding

and limited enforcement of contracts and provide the solution. We then calibrate the

model and present our findings. In Section (3.4), we make some concluding remarks.

3.2 Empirical Observations

As a prelude to our theoretical analysis, we first conduct an empirical investigation

into the relationship between financial contract enforcement and aggregate economic

activity. Specifically, we seek to obtain evidence about the extent to which limited

enforcement4 has influence on both the level and volatility of output either directly

or indirectly. The literature on contract enforcement have stressed it importance in

economic growth (see Monge-Naranjo (2009); Steinberg (2013)). Using data on credit

information and enforcement costs, Steinberg (2013) finds that the latter exacerbates

the effects of poor depth of credit information on total factor productivity. Addition-

ally, their finding is consistent with other studies on the effect of credit bureaus and

borrowers’ information on access to credit, in countries with limited contract enforce-

4 We use a measure of limited enforcement different than the one used by Cooley et al. (2003).

81

Page 83: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

ment (see Djankov et al. (2007); Jappelli and Pagano (2002); Brown et al. (2009)).

Further to this, Monge-Naranjo (2009) finds countries where the legal system gives

priority to creditors to have better-developed banks and improved private sector credit

as a ratio of GDP, than countries where laws do not give a high priority to creditors.

3.2.1 Data and Methodology

We use data from the World Bank’s Development Indicators and the World Bank’s

Doing Business Index from 2004 to 2012 for a sample of 57 countries (including both

developed and developing countries). A list of these countries is given in Appendix

(3.6). Our measure of output is logarithm of real GDP, whilst we proxy for imperfect

contract enforcement using the contract enforcement cost index. Djankov et al. (2002)

developed the methodology used by the World Bank for constructing the contract

enforcement cost index. Typically, the index captures the cost, as a fraction of the

claim (total amount of loans defaulted upon), that a lender (complainant) may incur

in order to enforce a contract. Accordingly, therefore, a higher value of this index

means that contracts will be more costly to enforce. A higher value of the contract

enforcement measure means that enforcement is more costly. For present purposes,

we convert this to the fraction of defaulted debt recovered by lenders after default is

announced. An increase in the value of this is then understood to mean an improvement

in contract enforcement.

As an additional measure of financial market imperfections, we also include the

depth of credit information (improvements in which are indicated on a scale from 0

to 6). The methodology used by the World Bank to construct the depth of credit

index was developed by Djankov et al. (2007). This index measures the coverage,

scope and accessibility of information about the credit histories of individuals and

firms. Depth of credit information could be related to monitoring and verification cost

in our theoretical model. Accordingly, bad depth of credit information implies high

monitoring and verification cost and low output, in the theoretical model (see Table

(3.3.3.5)). Table (3.6.1.3) reports the summary statistics of these variables. Depth

82

Page 84: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

of credit information is the most volatile variable followed by output and contract

enforcement. This implies volatility of 2.048, 1.031 and 0.395, respectively.

Figure (3.2.1.1) presents the scatter plots of output, contract enforcement and

depth of credit information. Figure (3.2.1.1) shows that output is positively correlated

with both contract enforcement and credit information.

91

01

11

21

3lo

g(re

alG

DP

)

−.5 0 .5 1Contract Enforcement

91

01

11

21

3lo

g(re

alG

DP

)

0 2 4 6Credit information

Figure 3.2.1.1.: Scatter Plot of Real GDP, Credit Information and ContractEnforcement

Figure (3.2.1.2) presents the scatter plots of output volatility and contract enforcement.

Figure (3.2.1.2) shows that the volatility of output is negatively correlated with contract

enforcement.

83

Page 85: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

.05

.1.1

5.2

.25

.3S

tan

da

rd D

evia

tio

n o

f G

DP

)

−.5 0 .5 1Contract Enforcement

Figure 3.2.1.2.: Scatter: Standard Deviation of GDP and Contract Enforcement

The foregoing casual inspection of the data is supplemented with an economet-

ric investigation in which we estimate the following equation adopted from Steinberg

(2013):

logRealGDPit =

γ + α1CONENFit + α2CREINFOit+

α3CONENF ∗ CREINFOit + ηi + µt + εit

where i is the country index and t is time. The dependent variable is the logarithm of

real GDP. The variable CONENFit measures the amount of debt recovered through

contract enforcement after default by firms. In other words it shows how much investors

are able to recoup, through the legal system, from firms that declare bankruptcy. The

84

Page 86: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

variable CREINFOit denotes the depth of credit information. The credit inform-

ation of a country is ascertained from data on firms, individuals, utility companies

and financial institutions in the form of their credit history which is available to all

parties. CONENF ∗ CREINFOit, is the interaction between contract enforcement

and credit information. The intuition behind this interaction term is to capture the

effect of contract enforcement on output given credit information or the effect of credit

information on output given the degree of contract enforcement. By doing this we are

able to mimic the outcome of the interaction between the monitoring/verification cost

parameter (which proxies depth of credit information) and the limited enforcement

parameter in our theoretical model. The country and time fixed effects are ηi and µt

respectively while εit is the error term. The model is estimated in Stata and the code

is provided in Appendix (A.2).

3.2.2 Results

The results of the estimation are presented in this section. We use both fixed effects

(FE) and random effects (RE). There are no significant differences between the FE

and RE estimates. Given this, we prefer the random effect specification because it is

more efficient. The results in Table (3.6.1.4) are for both time and country FE and

RE. The coefficient on contract enforcement has the expected (positive) sign and is

significant at 1% in all specifications (columns). The coefficients from the RE models

are, however, larger than the FE models. Similarly, the depth of credit information

has the expected (positive) sign and significant at 1% as well. The coefficient on the

interaction term is negative and significant at 5%.

Table (3.6.1.5) displays the results for country FE and RE. Consistent with the

results in Table (3.6.1.4), we find that the coefficients on contract enforcement and

depth of credit information have positive sign and significant at 1% in all specifications.

Again, we find that the coefficients from the RE models are, however, larger than the

FE models. Additionally, we observe that, generally, the country effects models have

larger coefficients than the time and country effects models. Finally, the coefficient

85

Page 87: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

on the interaction term is negative and significant at 1% in the country FE and RE

models.

The results in Table (3.6.1.6) are for both time and country FE and RE for sub-

sample of 34 countries. Table (3.6.1.6) (see in appendix (3.6)) report the results for

a sub-sample of 34 countries which display most variation in their time series data.

Consistent with the results in Table (3.6.1.4), we find that the coefficients on contract

enforcement have positive sign and significant at 1% in all specifications. Depth of

credit information has positive and significant coefficients in all specifications except

in column 8 in Table (3.6.1.6). We find that the coefficients from the RE models are,

however, larger than the FE models. Surprisingly too, the coefficient on the interaction

term is negative and insignificant.

Table (3.6.1.7) displays the results for country FE and RE for sub-sample of 34

countries. We find that the coefficients on contract enforcement and depth of credit

information have positive sign and significant at 1% in all specifications. We find that

the coefficients from the RE models are, however, larger than the FE models. Also, we

observe that, generally, the country effects models have larger coefficients than the time

and country effects models. Contrary to the results in Table (3.6.1.6), the coefficient

on the interaction term is negative and significant at 1% in the country FE and RE

models in Table (3.6.1.7).

The positive and significant coefficient on contract enforcement indicates that

output increases when the cost of contract enforcement is low meaning that investors

are able to recoup a larger amount of debt when firms default. Similarly, the positive

and significant coefficient on the depth of credit information implies that when credit

information on borrowers is more available, investors are more capable of identifying

firms with good prospects and allocating loans towards these firms. In sum, the coeffi-

cients on contract enforcement and the depth of credit information indicate that both

measures of financial development are positively related to output. The negative and

significant coefficient on the interaction term means that, given an economy with weak

contract enforcement, a deterioration of the existing level of credit information is likely

86

Page 88: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

to dampen the fall in output (or alternatively, given low depth of credit information,

a deterioration in contract enforcement is likely to dampen the fall in output). In

other words, the effect of contract enforcement on output is smaller when the depth of

credit information is higher (or alternatively, when contract enforcement is higher the

effect of depth of credit information on output is smaller) and vice versa. Either way,

the result suggests that different types of financial market imperfection tend to show

negative synergy between them–they are inhibiting each other.

Our result also indicates that the effect of contract enforcement on output depends

on credit information, which is consistent with the prediction of our theoretical model

(see Table (3.3.3.5)). Table (3.3.3.5) also shows that output increases with better

credit information (lower monitoring cost) and better contract enforcement (lower cost

of enforcement).

3.3 The Investment Model

The model is based on Carlstrom and Fuerst (1997), extended to allow for imperfect

contract enforcement. The model economy consists of a continuum of agents of unit

mass, a fraction (1 − η) of which are risk averse households and a fraction η are risk

neutral entrepreneurs (or capital producing firms). Households who own (shares in) the

consumption-good producing firms also supply labour and rent capital to these firms,

invest in capital and advance intra-period loans via Capital Market Fund (CMF)/Bank

to entrepreneurs. Entrepreneurs produce capital goods using net worth and external

funds in the form of loans from the CMF/Bank.

3.3.1 The Financial Contract

In this section we discuss the financial contract in a partial equilibrium setting. It is

one period in length, negotiated at the beginning of the period and resolved by the

end of the same period. The contract involves the entrepreneur and the lender both of

87

Page 89: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

which are risk neutral5. The lender has resources that he can lend to entrepreneur with

some positive net worth. Each entrepreneur is endowed with a stochastic technology

that transforms i consumption goods into ωi units of capital, where ω is idiosyncratic

technology shock. The shock ω, is i.i.d. across time and across entrepreneurs, with cu-

mulative distribution function Φ and probability density function φ. We assume ω has

mean E[ω] = 1, standard deviation σω, and is privately observed by the entrepreneur,

but others can privately observe ω only after paying the monitoring cost of µi capital

units. The monitoring cost denominated in terms of capital is proportional to i and

independent of the realisation of ω. To ensure that the asymmetric information in the

model is important, we assume that net worth is sufficiently small so that entrepreneurs

would like to receive some external financing to finance investment. Otherwise, entre-

preneurs would not need to borrow to finance investment. To finance the investment

i, the entrepreneur uses its net worth n and borrows (i − n) consumption goods and

agrees to repay (1 + rk)(i−n) capital goods to the lender, where rk is the lending rate.

Entrepreneur defaults at the end of the period if the realisation of ω is low. However,

if the entrepreneur defaults, it can “hide” a fraction ζ of the capital. The inability of

lenders to recover this “hidden” capital due to weakness in legal institutions is what

we refer to as limited contract enforcement. While monitoring cost (µi capital units)

pertains to the cost of monitoring borrowers, limited enforcement involves the “cost”

that lenders have to incur (which is equivalent to volume of this “hidden” capital) in

order to recover the “hidden capital. Therefore, if the entrepreneur does not default,

it receives:

ωi− (1 + rk)(i− n) (3.3.1.1)

5 In the general equilibrium setting, risk-averse households are the source of loanable funds to

entrepreneurs. However, in terms of the financial contract, they will be effectively risk neutral

because (1) there will be no aggregate uncertainty over the duration of the contract and (2)

households can diversify away all idiosyncratic risk.

88

Page 90: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

capital goods, which it can then sell at the price q (the price of aggregate capital). If

the entrepreneur defaults, however, it receives:

ζωi (3.3.1.2)

Comparing Equations (3.3.1.1) and (3.3.1.2), the entrepreneur will default if and only

if

(1− ζ)ωi < (1 + rk)(i− n)

This is equivalent to Carlstrom and Fuerst (1997) when ζ = 0.

It is then possible to define a default threshold ω such that the entrepreneur will

default for ω < ω and not default for ω ≥ ω. This threshold is determined by:

(1− ζ)ωi = (1 + rk)(i− n) (3.3.1.3)

If ω ≥ ω, the entrepreneur does not default and he receives ωi − (1 + rk)(i − n). If

ω < ω, the entrepreneur defaults and he receives ζωi. In both cases, the entrepreneur

can then sell the capital it has at the price q. Therefore, expected entrepreneurial

income is given by

q

[∫ ω

0

ζωidΦ(ω) +

∫ ∞ω

[ωi− (1 + rk)(i− n)

]dΦ(ω)

]Using Equation (3.3.1.3) to substitute for (1 + rk)(i− n), this becomes:

qi

∫ ω

0

ωdΦ(ω) +

∫ ∞ω

ωdΦ(ω)− (1− ζ)ω(1− Φ(ω))

]

Therefore, as a result of this contract, the entrepreneur expects to receive qif(ω), where

f(ω) is the the fraction of the expected capital output received by the entrepreneur.

This is defined to be:

89

Page 91: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

f(ω) = 1− (1− ζ)

[∫ ω

0

ωdΦ(ω) + ω(1− Φ(ω))

](3.3.1.4)

Similarly, for the lender, if ω ≥ ω, the entrepreneur does not default and the

lender receives (1 + rk)(i − n) in capital units. If ω < ω, the entrepreneur defaults

and the lender receives ((1− ζ)ω−µ)i capital units. Then expected lender’s income is

given by

q

[∫ ω

0

((1− ζ)ω − µ)idΦ(ω) +

∫ ∞ω

(1 + rk)(i− n)dΦ(ω)

]

Again, using Equation (3.3.1.3), the expected lender’s income simplifies to

qi

[(1− ζ)

{∫ ω

0

ωdΦ(ω) + ω(1− Φ(ω))

}− µΦ(ω)

]

As a result of this contract, the lender expects to receive qig(ω), where g(ω) is

the fraction of the expected capital output received by the lender. This is defined to

be:

g(ω) = (1− ζ)

[∫ ω

0

ωdΦ(ω) + ω(1− Φ(ω))

]− µΦ(ω) (3.3.1.5)

Moreover, using Equations (3.3.1.4) and (3.3.1.5) we arrive at

f(ω) + g(ω) = 1− µΦ(ω) (3.3.1.6)

This implies that, on average, monitoring results in the destruction of some of the pro-

duced capital, and the remainder of this capital is then split between the entrepreneur

and the lender.

The optimal contract is given by the pair (i, ω) (taking as given net worth n and

capital price q) which solves:

maxi, ω

qif(ω)

90

Page 92: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

subject to

qig(ω) ≥ i− n Lender’s Participation constraint

qif(ω) ≥ n Entrepreneur’s Participation constraint, which is always satisfied

The solution6 to the optimal contract is the following:

q

[1− µΦ(ω)− µφ(ω)f(ω)

(1− ζ)(1− Φ(ω))

]= 1 (3.3.1.7)

This can also be written as:

q

[1− µΦ(ω) + µφ(ω)

f(ω)

f ′(ω)

]= 1

This implicitly defines a function ω(q). Then, given ω(q), we can solve for optimal

investment using the participation constraint of the lender:

i(q, n) =n

1− qg(ω(q))(3.3.1.8)

Substituting in ω(q), this gives us the function i(q, n), which represents the optimal

amount of consumption goods placed into the capital-producing technology (given q

and net worth n). Expected capital output is then given by:

Is(q, n) ≡ i(q, n) [1− µΦ(ω(q))]

This can be interpreted as the investment supply function. This implies that the

supply function of entrepreneurs aggregates. Aggregate investment depends only on

the economy-wide price of capital q and aggregate net worth. It can then be shown

that ∂Is/∂q > 0 and ∂Is/∂n > 0.

An entrepreneur who receives loan of one unit of consumption good from house-

hold (via CMF/bank) expects to make a risky return of q(1 + rk) consumption good

6See Appendix (3.5.4) for detailed derivation.

91

Page 93: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

at the end of the investment period. Therefore, the risk premium of the model is

q(1 + rk)− 1. Substituting for (1 + rk) using Equation (3.3.1.3), the risk premium can

also be written as:

q(1 + rk)− 1 = q(1− ζ)ωi

i− n− 1

Finally, we may define leverage z, of the entrepreneur as the ratio of external

funding (i− n) to net worth n of the entrepreneur. This is given by

z =i− nn

Then using Equation (3.3.1.8) this can be re-written as:

z =qg(ω(q))

1− qg(ω(q))

3.3.2 The General Equilibrium Model

We now embed the contracting problem into a standard RBC model. We further

assume that, using consumption goods, new capital is created at the end of the period

with a non-stochastic one-to-one transformation rate. The newly produced capital is

then utilised in the next period. We use the same timing in this model. The one-

to-one transformation assumption is replaced with the contracting problem so that a

household who wants to purchase capital, must first fund the production of capital (an

entrepreneurial project), which is subject to agency problems.

The economy consists of a continuum of agents of unit mass, a fraction (1 − η)

of which are households and a fraction η are entrepreneurs. Firms produce the single

consumption good, but it is assumed that these consumption-producing firms are not

subject to any agency problems.

92

Page 94: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

3.3.2.1 Households

Households are infinitely lived, with preferences:

E0

[∞∑t=0

βtU(ct, 1− Lt)

]

where U(ct, 1 − Lt) = ln(ct) + ν(1 − Lt) is the instantaneous utility function, E is

the expectation operator conditional on period 0 information, β ∈ (0, 1) is the dis-

count factor, ct is household consumption, Lt is labour. Households supply labour to

consumption-producing firms at wage rate wt, rent their accumulated capital holdings

to consumption-producing firms at rental rate rt, purchase consumption from these

firms at the price 1 (note that consumption is the numeraire), and purchase new cap-

ital goods at a price of qt. Within the period, households also lend to entrepreneurs

(through the CMF/Bank) to help finance the production of capital. Households who

own (shares in) the consumption-good producing firms then purchase capital goods at

the end of the period with the assistance of CMF/Bank.

The budget constraint faced by the household is then:

ct + qt[kht+1 − (1− δ)kht

]= wtLt + rtk

ht

where kht is the stock of capital owned by the representative household. The profits of

the CMF/bank are not included here, because they will be zero.

Optimal consumption-labour decision is determined by the following:

wt =UL(ct, 1− Lt)Uc(ct, 1− Lt)

Also, optimal7 household consumption-investment decision is determined by the fol-

lowing:

qtUc(ct, 1− Lt) = βEt {Uc(ct+1, 1− Lt+1) [qt+1(1− δ) + rt+1]}

7See Appendix (3.5.1) for detailed derivation.

93

Page 95: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

3.3.2.2 Consumption-good Producing Firms

There are a continuum of consumption-producing firms in the economy who utilise a

standard production function8 with Constant Returns to Scale (CRS) specified as:

Yt = AtF (Kt, Ht, Het )

where Yt is aggregate output of the consumption good, Kt is the aggregate capital

stock (including entrepreneurial capital), Ht is aggregate supply of household labour,

and Het is the aggregate supply of entrepreneurial labour. At is stochastic aggregate

productivity and evolves according to log(At) = (1− ρA)A + ρA log(At−1) + εt, where

εt is a serially uncorrelated, i.i.d. and normally distributed shock; and ρA is the auto-

correlation coefficient. This consumption-good producing technology is assumed to

be Cobb-Douglas (details to be discussed in Section (3.3.3)). Perfect competition in

factor markets ensures that factor prices are equal to their respective marginal products:

rt = AtF1(Kt, Ht, Het ), wt = AtF2(Kt, Ht, H

et ), and wet = AtF3(Kt, Ht, H

et ), where wet is

the wage rate for entrepreneurial labour. As explained in Carlstrom and Fuerst (1997),

the assumption of entrepreneurial labour income is to ensure that each entrepreneur

has a non-zero level of net worth. This is because the financial contracting problem

will not be well defined for any zero levels of net worth.

3.3.2.3 Entrepreneurs

Entrepreneurs are long-lived and risk-neutral. Without any restrictions, entrepreneurs

will want to accumulate enough capital so that they are completely self-financed and

avoid agency costs by postponing consumption. To prevent this, we follow on Carlstrom

and Fuerst (1997) and assume that entrepreneurs discount the future more heavily

than households9. Following the risk neutrality assumption, entrepreneurs maximise

8We specify the production function as Yt = AtKαKt HαH

t Heαet

9In the earlier working paper version of their paper, Carlstrom and Fuerst (1997) assumed that aconstant fraction of the entrepreneurs died each period, and sold their accumulated capital stockto households. In terms of consumption, this is equivalent to assuming that the entrepreneursconsume a constant fraction of their capital holdings each period.

94

Page 96: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

the following objective function:

E0

[∞∑t=0

(βγ)tcet

](3.3.2.1)

where cet is entrepreneurial consumption, and γ ∈ (0, 1) denotes the additional rate

of discounting for entrepreneurs to ensure that βγ < β. At the beginning of the

period the entrepreneur rents his previously accumulated capital and also inelastically

supplies labour, which we assume to be unity, to consumption good producing firms.

The entrepreneur then sells his remaining un-depreciated capital to households for

consumption goods. The net worth of the entrepreneur (in terms of consumption) at

the end of the transactions period is given by:

nt = wet + ket [qt(1− δ) + rt]

where ket refers to the capital holdings of the individual entrepreneur at the beginning

of the period. To undertake investment, the entrepreneur uses this net worth to form

the basis for any loan agreement that he will enter into with the lender. Risk neutrality

and the high internal return ensures the entrepreneur pours his entire net worth into the

capital-producing technology and borrows from the household (via the CMF/Bank).

Given the financial contract from Section (3.3.1), the entrepreneur chooses it = i(qt, nt),

where i(q, n) is defined in Equation (3.3.1.8). There is also an associated cutoff ωt =

ω(qt), where ω(q) is implicitly defined by Equation (3.3.1.7), given this investment. Let

xt denote the realised payoff (in terms of capital) to the entrepreneur given by:

x =

ωi− (1 + rk)(i− n) = ωi− (1− ζ)ωi = (ω − (1− ζ)ω)i if ω ≥ ω

ζωi if ω < ω

Then, given x, the entrepreneur makes the consumption decision:

cet + qtket+1 = qtxt

95

Page 97: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

Let cet denote average entrepreneurial consumption. Then ηcet is aggregate entrepren-

eurial consumption. Aggregating across the budget constraints of all entrepreneurs, we

get:

ηcet + qtKet+1 = qt

Nt

1− qtg(ω(qt))f(ω(qt))

where Ket+1 is aggregate entrepreneurial capital stock and Nt is aggregate entrepren-

eurial net worth. Aggregate net worth is Nt = ηwet +Ket (qt(1− δ) + rt). Re-arranging,

tomorrow’s aggregate entrepreneurial capital stock (Ket+1) is given by:

Ket+1 = [ηwet +Ke

t (qt(1− δ) + rt)]f(ω(qt))

1− qtg(ω(qt))− ηcet

qt(3.3.2.2)

Dividing through by η (the mass of entrepreneurs), we get:

ket+1 = ntf(ω(qt))

1− qtg(ω(qt))− cetqt

where nt = wet + ket [qt(1− δ) + rt] is average entrepreneurial net worth and ket = Ket /η

is the average stock of capital owned by entrepreneurs.

Maximising the entrepreneur’s utility in Equation (3.3.2.1) subject to the aggregate

entrepreneurial capital stock in Equation (3.3.2.2) (see Appendix (3.5.3) for detailed

derivation) gives the entrepreneur’s Euler equation:

qt = βγEt{

[qt+1(1− δ) + rt+1]qt+1f(ωt+1)

1− qt+1g(ωt+1)

}

The first term (in brackets) represents the market return on capital whilst the second

term denotes the additional return on internal funds.

96

Page 98: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

3.3.2.4 Capital Market Fund (CMF)/Bank

The CMF/Bank lends (it(qt, nt)−nt) consumption goods to each entrepreneur with net

worth nt (measured in consumption units). Let Nt denote aggregate entrepreneurial

net worth. Since the investment function in Equation (3.3.1.8) is linear in net worth,

aggregate lending is(

qtg(ω(qt))1−qtg(ω(qt))

)Nt, denominated in terms of consumption units.

At the end of the period, ω is realised for all firms and the expected proceeds from

each individual entrepreneur is qti(qt, nt)g(ω(qt)). Given that i(qt, nt) is linear in nt, this

aggregates. Therefore, the total proceeds to the CMF/Bank are Nt1−qtg(ω(qt))

qtg(ω(qt)).

Comparing aggregate lending to total proceeds of the CMF/Bank, its profits are zero.

This is because, in the optimal contracting problem, the lender’s participation con-

straint holds with equality.

3.3.2.5 Market Clearing Conditions

We close the model with the market-clearing conditions. The economy is characterised

by four markets: two labour markets, a consumption-goods market, and a capital goods

market. Labour market clearing for the consumption-goods sector ensures:

Ht = (1− η)Lt

Het = η

Consumption-good market clearing implies:

(1− η)ct + ηcet + ηit = Yt

where ct is the representative household’s consumption, cet is average entrepreneurial

consumption, and it is average entrepreneurial investment. Finally, the capital goods

market clearing implies:

97

Page 99: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

Kt+1 = (1− δ)Kt + ηit [1− µΦ(ωt)]

where aggregate capital Kt = (1− η)kht + ηket includes both household and entrepren-

eurial capital.

3.3.2.6 Recursive Competitive Equilibrium

A recursive competitive equilibrium consists of the following decision rules: kht+1, ket+1,

Kt+1, Ket+1, qt, nt, it, ωt, c

et , ct, rt, wt, w

et , Ht, H

et , Lt, and Yt, such that these decision rules

are stationary functions of (Kt, Ket , At) and the following conditions are satisfied:

(1) Optimality conditions for household labour supply:

UL(ct, 1− Lt)Uc(ct, 1− Lt)

= wt

(2) Optimality conditions for household investment:

qtUc(ct, 1− Lt) = βEtUc(ct+1, 1− Lt+1) [qt+1(1− δ) + rt+1]

(3) Market clearing for capital good market:

Kt+1 = (1− δ)Kt + ηit [1− µΦ(ωt)]

(4) Market clearing for consumption:

(1− η)ct + ηcet + ηit = Yt

(5) First Order Conditions defining ωt = ω(qt):

qt

[1− µΦ(ωt) + µφ(ωt)

f(ωt)

f ′(ωt)

]= 1

(6) Average investment it set optimally (given average net worth nt):

98

Page 100: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

it = i(qt, nt) =nt

1− qtg(ωt)

(7) Average entrepreneurial net worth nt:

nt = wet + ket [qt(1− δ) + rt]

(8) Next period’s average entrepreneurial capital ket+1:

ket+1 = ntf(ωt)

1− qtg(ωt)− cetqt

(9) Next period’s aggregate entrepreneurial capital Ket+1:

Ket+1 = [ηwet +Ke

t (qt(1− δ) + rt)]f(ω(qt))

1− qtg(ω(qt))− ηcet

qt

(10) First Order Conditions for entrepreneurial consumption:

qt = βγEt{

[qt+1(1− δ) + rt+1]qt+1f(ωt+1)

1− qt+1g(ωt+1)

}(11) Aggregate capital:

Kt+1 = (1− η)kht+1 + ηket+1

(12) Labour market clearing for the consumption-goods sector:

Ht = (1− η)Lt

Het = η

(13) Factor markets:

99

Page 101: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

rt = AtF1(Kt, Ht, Het )

wt = AtF2(Kt, Ht, Het )

wet = AtF3(Kt, Ht, Het )

3.3.3 Calibration and Results

We simulate and solve the model in Dynare (see Appendix (A.2) for details). To

simulate the model, we first need to calibrate it. The calibration is at the non-stochastic

steady state. As noted earlier, we assume that utility is logarithmic in consumption

and linear in leisure. Following Carlstrom and Fuerst (1997), we choose ν, disutility

of labour supply parameter, to be 2.52 so that L = 0.3. We normalise η, fraction of

entrepreneurs, to be 10%.

The Cobb-Douglas consumption-good producing technology has 36% as share of

capital and 63.99% as share of household labour. Drawing on Carlstrom and Fuerst

(1997) and Carlstrom and Fuerst (1998), we set as 0.01% the share of entrepreneurial

labour. As stated earlier, this is also to, purposely, ensure that each entrepreneur always

has positive level of net worth. The autocorrelation coefficient ρA of the stochastic

aggregate productivity is set to 0.95 following standard RBC calibration. The non-

stochastic steady state value of aggregate productivity A is set to 1 while we set the

standard deviation of the innovation to aggregate productivity shock to σA = 1%.

In order to understand the impact of wealth redistribution in the economy, we

consider a one-time shock to the distribution of wealth in the form of transfer of

capital from entrepreneurs to households (lenders). To do this, we restate the net

worth equation in the model bloc as nt = wet + ket [qt(1− δ) + rt] − σnεn,t, where εn,t

is a serially uncorrelated shock to the redistribution of wealth, and σn is the standard

deviation of this shock.

There is enormous controversy over the verification cost parameter µ (see Carl-

strom and Fuerst (1997, 1998, 2001); Levin et al. (2004); De Fiore et al. (2011)) but

100

Page 102: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

we set it to 0.15.

The distribution of the idiosyncratic productivity shock is i.i.d. and follows a

log-normal distribution, and as noted earlier, with mean 1 and standard deviation of

σω. Following Carlstrom and Fuerst (1997), we calibrate this standard deviation of the

distribution of the idiosyncratic productivity shock to σω = 20.7%, and the steady-

state additional discount rate for entrepreneurs to about γ = 91% so as to generate a

quarterly steady-state credit spread of about 0.5% and a quarterly bankruptcy rate of

about 1%. We also calibrate β (the discount factor of households) to 0.99 to match a

quarterly nominal interest rate of 1%.

Table 3.3.3.1.: Calibration

Description Parameter ValueContract Enforcement ζ (0,1)Verification Cost µ 0.15Discount Factor β 0.99Labour Supply Disutility ν 2.52Productivity Parameter A 1.00Persistence in Aggregate Technology Shock ρA 0.95Depreciation Rate of Capital δ 2%Share of Capital in Production αK 36%Share of Entrepreneurial Labour in Production αe 0.01%Share of Household Labour in Production αH 63.99%Additional Discount Rate for Entrepreneurs γ 91%Fraction of Entrepreneurs η 10%Standard Deviation of Φ(ω) σω 20.7%Standard Deviation of Net Worth Shock σn 10%Standard Deviation of Aggregate Productivity Shock σA 1%

The recovery rate, (1 − ζ), is the fraction of capital that the lenders are able

to recoup after a default is announced by the entrepreneurs. One presumes that this

would depend positively on the strength of contract enforcement as determined by

the quality of legal institutions. The better is the legal system the greater is the

enforceability of contracts, and the larger is the recovery rate. Following Steinberg

(2013), who calibrates the recovery rate to 23% for an average country with limited

enforcement, and the Doing Business index of World Bank (as used in Section (3.2)),

we look at three scenarios of limited enforcement in our analysis. We calibrate ζ to

101

Page 103: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

70%, meaning a recovery rate, (1 − ζ), of 30% for an average country with limited

enforcement, ζ to 40%, indicating a recovery rate, (1 − ζ), of 60% for an average

country with moderately good enforcement, and ζ to 0 for an average country with

perfect enforcement. The case of ζ = 0 coincides with agency costs models with no

limited enforcement problems as in Carlstrom and Fuerst (1997) and Carlstrom and

Fuerst (1998).

3.3.3.1 Aggregate Technology Shocks

Figures (3.3.3.1) and (3.3.3.3) show the impulse responses to a 1% positive aggregate

technology shock for the baseline model, for three cases of limited enforcement (i.e.

ζ = 0% (perfect enforcement), ζ = 40% (limited enforcement) and ζ = 70% (imperfect

enforcement)). The positive productivity shock increases output, household consump-

tion and net worth on impact. The increase in output and net worth results in an

increased demand for capital which pushes the price of capital up. As the price of

capital rises, the demand for investment falls which dampens the initial increase in

output. As demand for investment falls, it boosts household consumption which in

turn reduces household labour supply and dampens the increase in output. Though

there is an increase in net worth, because the positive shock increases wages (including

entrepreneurial wages) and rental income, the high price of capital makes the initial

increase sluggish.

Increasing returns to entrepreneurial internal funds additionally increases net

worth as the risk-neutral entrepreneur takes advantage of the rising price of capital by

reducing their consumption. As the price of capital returns to its steady-state level,

net worth attains it maximum before returning to the steady state. The increasing

in demand for investment and value of net worth leads to an increase in demand for

external funds. This pushes up the default threshold and the probability of default on

impact of the shock. Following from the rise in the probability of default, lending rate

rises on impact of the shock.

102

Page 104: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

0 10 20 301

1.01

1.02

1.03

Quarters

Output

0 10 20 301

1.005

1.01

1.015

Quarters

Households Consumption

0 10 20 300.998

1

1.002

1.004

1.006

Quarters

Household Labour

0 10 20 300.96

0.98

1

1.02

1.04

Quarters

Entrepreneurial Consumption

0 10 20 300.995

1

1.005

1.01

1.015

Quarters

Price of Capital

Agency Cost Only

ζ=40%

ζ=70%

0 10 20 301

1.05

1.1

Quarters

Entrepreneurial Capital

Figure 3.3.3.1.: Impulse responses from a positive technology shock. The vertical axismeasures percentage deviations from the steady state. The horizontal axis measurestime in quarters.

103

Page 105: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.95

10

15

Ris

k p

rem

ium

(in

per

cen

t)

Zeta (ζ)

0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.90

1

2

Lev

erag

e

Risk premium

Leverage

Figure 3.3.3.2.: Relationship between expected leverage, expected risk premium andlimited enforcement in response to productivity shocks.

Additionally, the increase in value of internal funds, profit and the resulting increase

in demand for external funds contributes to an increase in leverage.

The amplification effect of limited contract enforcement in the model is displayed

by the three different lines corresponding to the different cases of contract enforceability.

The growth in investment is dampened by limited enforcement. With higher degree of

limited enforcement, the risk premium and the probability of default are much more

sensitive to increases in borrowing. As displayed in Figure (3.3.3.2), increases in degree

of limited enforcement (ζ) results in an increase in the risk premium and a decrease in

leverage. Figure (3.3.3.4) also shows that the rate of investment falls with the degree

of limited enforcement.

104

Page 106: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

0 10 20 301

1.05

1.1

1.15

Quarters

Investment

0 10 20 300.99

1

1.01

1.02

1.03

Quarters

Probability of Default

0 10 20 300.99

1

1.01

1.02

1.03

Quarters

Lending Rate

0 10 20 300.995

1

1.005

1.01

1.015

Quarters

Risk Premium

0 10 20 301

1.05

1.1

1.15

Quarters

Entrepreneurial Net Worth

0 10 20 300.9

1

1.1

1.2Leverage

Quarters

Agency Cost Only

ζ=40%

ζ=70%

Figure 3.3.3.3.: Impulse responses from a positive technology shock. The vertical axismeasures percentage deviations from the steady state. The horizontal axis measurestime in quarters.

105

Page 107: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

Therefore, given a productivity shock, with higher degree of limited enforcement, it

is more difficult for entrepreneurs to use their net worth to expand investment (hence

the lower growth in investment in Figure (3.3.3.3)). Output responds to investment by

displaying higher growth when the degree of limited enforcement is at its lowest level.

When the degree of limited enforcement is at its highest level, the growth in output is

at its lowest level. This reaction of aggregate output to the shock is consistent with

the findings of Cooley et al. (2003) and Amaral and Quintin (2010). The negative

effect of the limited enforcement on investment amplifies the increases in household

consumption which in turn reduces household labour supply. The reduction in labour

input is highest when the degree of limited enforcement is highest.

0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.92.18

2.2

2.22

2.24

2.26

2.28

2.3

2.32

2.34

2.36

2.38

Zeta (ζ)

Inv

estm

ent

Investment

Figure 3.3.3.4.: Relationship between expected investment and limited enforcementin response to productivity shocks.

As limited enforcement worsens, the price of capital rises. This is as a result of

106

Page 108: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

the rise in risk premium and a fall in the supply of capital resulting from the dampened

growth in investment. As a result of this rise in price of capital, both entrepreneurial

capital and net worth increase the most when the degree of limited enforcement is

highest. As earlier discussed, weak enforceability also exacerbates the effect of the

shock on the probability of default, the lending rate and leverage. On impact of the

shock, the probability of default rises by 2% when the degree of limited enforcement is

70% (i.e. when a firm can walk away with 70% of its output after default), 1% when

the degree of limited enforcement is 40% (i.e. when a firm can walk away with 40% of

its output after default) and 0.6% when there is “perfect” enforcement. The impact

of the probability of default is reflected in the lending rate rising by 1.6%, 0.5% and

0.2%, respectively, when the degree of limited enforcement is 70%, 40% and 0%. As

lending rate and net worth increase following an increase in the degree of enforcement,

external funding is reduced resulting in leverage being lowest when the degree of limited

enforcement is highest.

3.3.3.2 Shocks to Net Worth

Figures (3.3.3.5) and (3.3.3.7) display the impulse responses to a shock to net worth,

for three cases of limited enforcement (i.e. ζ = 0% (perfect enforcement), ζ = 40%

(limited enforcement) and ζ = 70% (imperfect enforcement)). This shock will be a one-

time transfer of capital from entrepreneurs to households (lenders). The redistribution

is 20% of the steady-state capital stock. This transfer increases household capital and

reduces entrepreneurial net worth. This reduction in entrepreneurial net worth raises

the demand for external financing and thus raising agency costs of investment. The

decrease in net worth reduces investment which in turn decreases the supply of capital,

therefore raising the equilibrium price of capital. This decrease in investment also

leads to higher household consumption which serves as an incentive for households to

decrease their labour input.

107

Page 109: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

0 10 20 300.8

0.9

1

1.1

1.2

Quarters

Entrepreneurial Net Worth

0 10 20 300.96

0.98

1

1.02

Quarters

Output

0 10 20 300.995

1

1.005

1.01

1.015

Quarters

Households Consumption

0 10 20 300.985

0.99

0.995

1

1.005

Quarters

Household Labour

0 10 20 300.85

0.9

0.95

1

1.05

Quarters

Entrepreneurial Consumption

0 10 20 300.99

1

1.01

1.02

1.03 Price of Capital

Quarters

Agency Cost Only

ζ=40%

ζ=70%

Figure 3.3.3.5.: Impulse responses from a negative shock to net worth. The verticalaxis measures percentage deviations from the steady state. The horizontal axismeasures time in quarters.

108

Page 110: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

The total impact is therefore a reduction in output. The decrease in value of net

worth and demand for investment and the subsequent increase in demand for external

funds increases the probability of default. Following the rise in the probability of

default, lending rate rises. Additionally, the fall in the value of internal funds leads to

an increase in demand for external funds which in turn contributes to an increase in

leverage.

The amplification effect of limited contract enforcement in the model is displayed

by the three different lines corresponding to the different cases of contract enforceability.

As earlier argued, higher degree of limited enforcement results in the risk premium and

the probability of default being more sensitive to increases in borrowing.

0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.95

10

15

Ris

k p

rem

ium

(in

per

cen

t)

Zeta (ζ)

0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.90

1

2

Lev

erag

e

Risk premium

Leverage

Figure 3.3.3.6.: Relationship between expected leverage, expected risk premium andlimited enforcement in response to net worth shocks.

109

Page 111: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

0 10 20 300.7

0.8

0.9

1

1.1

Quarters

Investment

0 10 20 300.98

1

1.02

1.04

1.06

Quarters

Probability of Default

0 10 20 300.98

1

1.02

1.04

Quarters

Lending Rate

0 10 20 300.99

1

1.01

1.02Risk Premium

Quarters

0 10 20 300.9

0.95

1

1.05

1.1 Entrepreneurial Capital

Quarters0 10 20 30

0.8

1

1.2

1.4

1.6Leverage

Quarters

Agency Cost Only

ζ=40%

ζ=70%

Figure 3.3.3.7.: Impulse responses from a negative shock to net worth. The verticalaxis measures percentage deviations from the steady state. The horizontal axismeasures time in quarters.

110

Page 112: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

As displayed in Figure (3.3.3.2), increases in degree of limited enforcement (ζ) results

in an increase in the risk premium and a decrease in leverage. Figure (3.3.3.4) also

shows that the rate of investment falls with the degree of limited enforcement. A one-

time wealth transfer to households instantaneously reduces net worth. Therefore, given

a higher ζ, it is even much more difficult for entrepreneurs to use their net worth to

expand investment (hence the lower growth in investment in Figure (3.3.3.7)).

0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.92.15

2.2

2.25

2.3

2.35

2.4

Zeta ( ζ )

Inv

estm

ent

Investment

Figure 3.3.3.8.: Relationship between expected investment and limited enforcementin response to net worth shocks.

Output is at its lowest when the the degree of limited enforcement is at its highest

level but highest when the degree of limited enforcement is lowest. The negative effect

of the limited enforcement on investment further amplifies the increase in household

consumption which in turn reduces household labour supply. The reduction in labour

input is highest when the degree of limited enforcement is highest. The negative impact

111

Page 113: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

of limited enforcement on both household labour supply and investment results in the

effect of the shock on output being equally amplified. The fall in net worth, investment

and output results in entrepreneurial capital also falling and attaining its lowest level

when the degree of limited enforcement is highest.

As the degree of limited enforcement increases, the effect of the transfer on the

probability of default, the lending rate and the degree of leverage is amplified. For

instance, after the shock, the probability of default rises by 3.3% when the cost of en-

forcement is 70% (i.e. when a firm can walk away with 70% of its output after default),

2.5% when when the cost of enforcement is 40% (i.e. when a firm can walk away with

40% of its output after default) and 2.5% when there is “perfect” enforcement10.

The impact of the probability of default is reflected in the lending rate rising by 3%,

1.1% and 0.7%, respectively, when the degree of limited enforcement is 70%, 40% and

0%. As lending rate increases and net worth decreases following an increase in the

degree of limited enforcement, external funding is reduced resulting in the degree of

leverage being lowest when the degree of limited enforcement is highest.

3.3.3.3 Sensitivity Analysis: Limited Enforcement, Output and Net Worth

In Table (3.3.3.2), following a positive productivity shock, an increase in the degree of

limited enforcement, from 0% to 40%, is associated with a decrease in output volatility

from 2.37% to 2.20% whilst an increase in the degree of limited enforcement from 0% to

70%, is associated with a decrease in output volatility from 2.37% to 2.05%. Similarly,

expected output decreases as the degree of limited enforcement increases. In contrast,

we find that as the degree of limited enforcement increases, expected net worth and its

volatility follow similar trends. In a similar vein, expected lending rate and its volatility

increase with the degree of limited enforcement. Our results are consistent with other

studies (see Quintin (2000); Cooley et al. (2003)) which made similar findings on the

10In the second quarter, for instance, the probability of default is 1.9%, 1% and 0.6% when the costof enforcement is 70%, 40% and 0%, respectively.

112

Page 114: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

impact of limited contract enforcement on output.

Table 3.3.3.2.: Productivity Shock

Cost of Enforcement 0% 40% 70% 0% 40% 70%Statistic Mean Volatility

Output 1.01 1.00 0.99 2.37% 2.20% 2.05%Net Worth 0.91 1.41 1.80 7.10% 10.36% 12.44%Lending Rate 0.47% 1.36% 6.22% 0.11% 0.30% 1.16%

We measure volatility by standard deviations expressed in percentages.

Table (3.3.3.3) presents our findings following a one-time wealth transfer from

entrepreneurs to households (lenders). One interesting finding in the data (see our em-

pirical findings in Section (3.2)) is that countries with more limited contract enforce-

ment tend to exhibit more volatility in output. Result from our model with one-time

wealth transfer is able to reproduce this observation. Whist expected output decreases,

volatility of output increases as the degree of limited enforcement increases. Similarly,

both expected net worth and its volatility increase as the degree of limited enforcement

increases. Things are not different when it comes to the lending rate. Expected lending

rate and its volatility increase as the degree of limited enforcement rises.

This result may be seen as being especially pertinent for the case of small firms

that use their net worth as collateral and rely largely on external finance for production.

New entrants and smaller firms may be credit constrained and find the cost of loans

expensive as the degree of limited enforcement increases. The result suggests that

limited contract enforcement may be particularly an issue for the growth of such firms

and, with this, the growth of the economy as a whole, as argued by Amaral and Quintin

(2010) and Albuquerque and Hopenhayn (2000).

3.3.3.4 Sensitivity Analysis: Welfare Consequences of Limited Contract

Enforcement

A very important issue worth commenting on is the effect of limited enforcement on

household welfare, the presumption being that weaker enforcement reduces welfare.

113

Page 115: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

Table 3.3.3.3.: One-Time Wealth Transfer

Cost of Enforcement 0% 40% 70% 0% 40% 70%Statistic Mean Volatility

Output 1.01 1.00 0.99 2.28% 2.32% 2.19%Net Worth 0.91 1.41 1.80 18.49% 18.46% 18.92%Lending Rate 0.47% 1.36% 6.22% 0.36% 0.62% 1.87%

We measure volatility by standard deviations expressed in percentages.

Following Lucas (1987), we estimate welfare loss (consumption equivalent) as the per-

centage decrease in households consumption in the economy with perfect enforcement

which makes households indifferent between the economy with limited enforcement

and the economy perfect enforcement (see Appendix (3.5.5) for detailed derivation of

welfare loss). In the context of the present model, when enforceability is poor, invest-

ment responds positively. In light of this, in response to a positive productivity shock,

households consumption increases which results in household labour supply falling.

This leads to household welfare increasing accordingly. However, the initial increase in

welfare is dampened when enforcement worsens. The result displayed in Table (3.3.3.4)

provides an additional support for the effect of limited enforcement on household wel-

fare, when there is a positive productivity shock. The result shows that as the degree

of limited enforcement increases from 40% to 70%, the average household consumption

equivalent welfare loss increases from 0.86% to 1.84%.

Table 3.3.3.4.: Welfare loss

Cost of Enforcement 40% 70% 40% 70%Statistic productivity shock wealth transfer

Consumption Equivalentof Welfare Loss 0.86% 1.84% 0.9% 1.89%

Welfare consequences of productivity shock and one-time wealth transfer

In response to a one-time transfer of wealth from entrepreneurs to households,

consumption of the latter increases which then results in labour supply falling. This

leads to household welfare increasing, on impact of the shock. However, as the the

transfer is one-time the initial increase in welfare is short-lived. In Table (3.3.3.4) we

114

Page 116: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

present the results of the impact of the wealth transfer on households. We show that as

the degree of limited enforcement increases from 40% to 70%, the average consumption

equivalent welfare loss increases from 0.9% to 1.89%.

3.3.3.5 Limited Enforcement, Monitoring Cost and Output

Table (3.3.3.5) displays the effect of changes in monitoring cost and the degree of

limited enforcement on output.

Table 3.3.3.5.: Effect of Limited Enforcement and Monitoring Cost on Output

Monitoring and Verification Cost

µ = 5% µ = 10% µ = 15% µ = 20% µ = 25%

Degree of Enforcement Percentage Change in Output

ζ = 0% 1.82% 1.71% 1.66% 1.62% 1.59%ζ = 40% 0.90% 0.89% 0.88% 0.88% 0.86%ζ = 70% −0.42% −0.19% −0.10% −0.04% 0.00%

Smaller µ means better credit information. Smaller ζ means better contract enforcement.

Percentage change in output relative to the steady state output when ζ = 70%

It is observed that as monitoring cost fall (i.e. as credit information improves),

its effect on output increases. Similarly, as enforcement improves, its impact on output

increases. This findings is consistent with our empirical result, particularly, where we

establish that both poor depth of credit information and limited enforcement have

negative effect on output.

3.4 Concluding Remarks

This paper has presented a dynamic stochastic general equilibrium model of asym-

metric information and limited contract enforcement in financial markets. The first

of these features–a fairly standard way of incorporating capital market frictions into

macroeconomic models–is reflected in the idea of costly state verification by finan-

cial intermediaries. The second feature–a much less standard way of capturing such

frictions–is reflected in the notion of institutional weaknesses in holding defaulters to

115

Page 117: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

account. It is this second aspect on which our interest has been focused and in which

the contribution of the analysis is mainly found.

We have shown how limited contract enforcement may affect fluctuations in key

macroeconomic variables (e.g. output, employment and investment) through its impact

on key financial variables (e.g. interest rates, risk premium, default risk and leverage).

Our results are particularly relevant for developing countries, where institutions are

often weak, fragile and fragmented because of poor quality of governance. Our analysis

suggests that improving such quality has the potential to improve the prospects of such

countries.

116

Page 118: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

3.5 Appendix A

3.5.1 Household Optimisation Problem

Households maximise expected life time utility

E0

[∞∑t=0

βtU(ct, (1− Lt))

]subject to

ct + qt[kht+1 − (1− δ)kht

]= wtLt + rtk

ht

where U(ct, (1− Lt)) = ln(ct) + ν(1− Lt)

Lagrange for the problem:

L = E0

[∞∑t=0

βt [ln(ct) + ν(1− Lt)]

]

+E0

[∞∑t=0

βt[λt(wtLt + rtk

ht − ct − qt(kht+1 − (1− δ)kht )

)]]First Order Conditions from household maximisation problem:

c : Uc(ct, 1− Lt)− λt = 0 (3.5.1.1)

kht+1 : −qtλt + βEt [λt+1 (rt+1 + qt+1(1− δ))] = 0 (3.5.1.2)

L : UL(ct, 1− Lt) + λtwt = 0 (3.5.1.3)

Equation (3.5.1.3) implies λt = νWt

Note that Uc(ct, 1− Lt) = c−1t ; UL(ct, 1− Lt) = −ν. Then

wt =UL(ct, 1− Lt)Uc(ct, 1− Lt)

c−1t

(3.5.1.4)

Equation (3.5.1.4) implies:

ct =

wt

)−1

=(wtν

)

117

Page 119: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

Using Equations (3.5.1.1) and (3.5.1.2) we can write the Euler Equation as:

qtUc(ct, 1− Lt) = βEt [Uc(ct+1, 1− Lt+1) (rt+1 + qt+1(1− δ))] (3.5.1.5)

Equation (3.5.1.5) is then simplified as:

qtc−1t = βEt

[c−1t+1 (rt+1 + qt+1(1− δ))

]

3.5.2 Consumption-good Producing Firms

We specify the production function as:

Yt = AtKαKt HαH

t Heαet

Perfect competition in factor markets implies the following factor prices:

rt = AtF1(Kt, Ht, Het ) = αKAtK

αK−1t HαH

t Heαet =

YtKt

wt = AtF2(Kt, Ht, Het ) = αHAtK

αKt HαH−1

t Heαet =

YtHt

wet = AtF3(Kt, Ht, Het ) = αeAtK

αKt HαH

t Heαe−1t =

YtHet

3.5.3 The Entrepreneur

Entrepreneurs maximise their expected life time utility

E0

[∞∑t=0

(βγ)tcet

](3.5.3.1)

subject to

118

Page 120: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

Ket+1 = (ηwet +Ke

t [qt(1− δ) + rt])f(ω(qt))

1− qtg(ω(qt))− cetqt

(3.5.3.2)

Lagrange for the problem:

L = E0

∞∑t=0

βt(cet )+E0

∞∑t=0

βt[λt

((ηwet +Ke

t [qt(1− δ) + rt])f(ω(qt))

1− qtg(ω(qt))− cetqt−Ke

t+1

)]

cet : uce (t)− λt/qt = 0

λt = qt

Ket+1 : −λt + (βγ)Et{λt+1(qt+1(1− δ) + rt+1)

f(ω(qt+1))

(1− qt+1g(ω(qt+1)))} = 0

qt = (βγ)Et[(qt+1(1− δ) + rt+1)

qt+1f(ω(qt+1))

(1− qt+1g(ω(qt+1)))

](3.5.3.3)

3.5.4 Optimal contract

The optimal contract is given by the pair (i, ω) (taking as given net worth n and capital

price q) which solves:

maxi, ω

qif(ω)

subject to

qig(ω) ≥ i− n Lender’s Participation constraint

qif(ω) ≥ n Entrepreneur’s Participation constraint, always satisfied

Technically, only the first constraint binds.

Lagrangian for this problem:

119

Page 121: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

L = qif(ω) + λ [qig(ω)− i+ n]

The First Order Conditions:

∂L∂i

= qf(ω) + λ [qg(ω)− 1] = 0 (3.5.4.1)

∂L∂ω

= qif ′(ω) + λqig′(ω) = 0 (3.5.4.2)

∂L∂λ

= qig(ω)− i+ n = 0 (3.5.4.3)

Re-arranging Equation (3.5.4.1):

q

[1

λf(ω) + g(ω)

]= 1

λ = −f′(ω)

g′(ω)

Then, re-arranging Equation (3.5.4.2), we get

1

λ=

g′(ω)

−f ′(ω)=

(1− ζ)(1− Φ(ω))− µφ(ω)

(1− ζ)(1− Φ(ω))= 1− µφ(ω)

(1− ζ)(1− Φ(ω))

Then, combined with Equation (3.3.1.6), we have the following condition:

q

[1− µΦ(ω)− µφ(ω)f(ω)

(1− ζ)(1− Φ(ω))

]= 1 (3.5.4.4)

This can also be written as:

q

[1− µΦ(ω) + µφ(ω)

f(ω)

f ′(ω)

]= 1

3.5.5 Consumption Equivalent Welfare Loss

Let λ denote consumption equivalent welfare loss, the fraction of consumption one

would be willing to give up each period in the economy with perfect enforcement.

120

Page 122: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

E(V perfect enforcementt (λ)) = E

[(ln(ct(1 + λ)) + ν(1− Lt)) + βEt

[V perfect enforcementt+1

]]

λ shows up every period and we assume it is deterministic and this reduces to:

E(V perfect enforcementt (λ)) =

1

1− β(1 + λ)+

E[(ln(ct) + ν(1− Lt)) + βEt

[V perfect enforcementt+1

]]

The term in brackets is then:

E(V perfect enforcementt (λ)) =

1

1− β(1 + λ) + E(V perfect enforcement

t )

Then we want to find the λ that equates this with expected welfare in an economy

with limited enforcement. We have:

E(V perfect enforcementt (λ)) = E(V limited enforcement

t )

Or1

1− β(1 + λ) + E(V perfect enforcement

t ) = E(V limited enforcementt )

Then

λ = exp[(1− β)× (E(V limited enforcement

t )− E(V perfect enforcementt ))

]− 1

If we take the economy with perfect enforcement to have higher welfare, then λ <

0. This means you would be willing to give up consumption in the high welfare economy

to have the same welfare as an economy with lower welfare (limited enforcement).

3.5.6 Steady State

The steady state of the model is characterised by:

121

Page 123: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

qss =1

[1− µΦss + ωssφssµ fss

f ′ss]

qss =1− (βeγ)rssf ss

[(βeγ)f ss(1− δ) + gss]

Y ss = AssKssαKHssαHHsseαe

Y Kss = Y ss/Kss

rss = αKY Kss

wss = αHYss/Hss

wess = αeYss/Hess

Y Kss =1

αK[1− qssgss

γβf ss− qss(1− δ)]

We calibrate γ such that the steady state internal return is γqssfss

1−qssgss = 1 . Then Y Kss

becomes

Y Kss =1

αK[qss

β− qss(1− δ)]

Kss =

(Y Kss

AssHssαHHessαe

) 1αK−1

Css = ηcess + (1− η)css

Css/Y ss = CY ss

CY ss = 1− δ

Y Kss(1− Φssµ))

iss =δKss

(1− Φssµ)

nss = (1− qssgss) δKss

(1− Φssµ)

kess =nss − ηwess

(qss(1− δ) + rss)=

β

qss(nss − ηwess)

122

Page 124: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

ν = wsscss(−1)

cess =qss(f ssiss − kess)

η

css = CY ssY ss

φss = φ(ωss)

Φss = Φ(ωss)

f ss = f(ωss)

gss = g(ωss)

f′ss = f

′(ωss)

123

Page 125: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

3.6 Appendix B

3.6.1 Tables

Table 3.6.1.1.: Countries for Empirical Work

CountryAustraliaAustriaBangladeshBelgiumBeninBrazilBurkina FasoCambodiaCentral African RepublicChinaComorosCongo, Dem. Rep.Congo, Rep.DenmarkEthiopiaFinlandFranceGermanyGhanaHungaryIcelandIndonesiaMalawiMaliMozambiqueNigerNigeriaNorwayPapua New GuineaRwandaSierra LeoneSpain

124

Page 126: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

Table 3.6.1.2.: Continuation of Countries for Empirical Work

CountrySerbiaPortugalRomaniaSingaporeSlovak RepublicSloveniaSwitzerlandTurkeyUkraineUnited KingdomUnited StatesVietnamZimbabweBhutanBurundiEstoniaGeorgiaIraqKenyaLatviaPhilippinesNetherlandsNew ZealandMacedonia, FYRMoldova

We used data for 57 countries

Table 3.6.1.3.: Summary statistics

Variable Mean Std. Dev. Min. Max. NReal GDP 10.675 1.031 8.57 13.153 513Contract Enforcement 0.552 0.395 -0.518 0.999 510Depth of Credit Info 2.936 2.048 0 6 513

125

Page 127: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

3.6.2 Figures

Figure 3.6.2.1.: Scatter: Standard Deviation of GDP and Contract Enforcement

Australia

Austria

Burkina Faso

Cambodia

Denmark

Iceland

MalawiMozambique

Rwanda

Zimbabwe

BhutanBurundi

Estonia

Georgia

Iraq

Kenya Latvia

Macedonia

Moldova

Netherlands

New Zealand

Philippines

Portugal

Romania

Serbia

Singapore

Slovakia

Slovenia

Switzerland

Turkey

Ukraine

UK USA

Vietnam

.05

.1.1

5.2

.25

.3 S

tandard

Devia

tion o

f G

DP

−.5 0 .5 1Contract Enforcement

126

Page 128: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

Table

3.6.1.4.:

Fix

edan

dR

andom

Eff

ects

Reg

ress

ion

for

Full

Sam

ple

(57

Cou

ntr

ies)

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

(7)

(8)

RE

FE

RE

FE

RE

FE

FE

RE

Rea

lG

DP

Con

trac

tE

nfo

rcem

ent

0.08

40.

080

0.08

10.

077

0.08

80.

091

[0.0

18]*

**[0

.018

]***

[0.0

18]*

**[0

.018

]***

[0.0

18]*

**[0

.019

]***

Dep

thof

Cre

dit

Info

0.00

80.

008

0.00

80.

008

0.01

70.

017

[0.0

02]*

**[0

.002

]***

[0.0

02]*

**[0

.002

]***

[0.0

04]*

**[0

.004

]***

CO

NE

NF

*DE

PT

HC

RE

DIN

FO

-0.0

15-0

.014

[0.0

06]*

*[0

.006

]**

Con

stan

t10

.560

10.5

6410

.584

10.5

8510

.541

10.5

4710

.547

10.5

41[0

.126

]***

[0.0

11]*

**[0

.112

]***

[0.0

07]*

**[0

.113

]***

[0.0

12]*

**[0

.012

]***

[0.1

14]*

**O

bse

rvat

ions

511

511

513

513

511

511

511

511

Tim

ean

dC

ountr

yF

Ean

dR

E

Sta

nd

ard

erro

rsin

bra

cket

s

*p

¡10%

,**

p¡5

%,

***

p¡1

%

127

Page 129: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

Table

3.6.1.5.:

Fix

edan

dR

andom

Eff

ects

Reg

ress

ion

for

Full

Sam

ple

(57

Cou

ntr

ies)

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

(7)

(8)

RE

FE

RE

FE

RE

FE

FE

RE

Rea

lG

DP

Con

trac

tE

nfo

rcem

ent

0.10

50.

096

0.09

00.

081

0.10

50.

113

[0.0

29]*

**[0

.029

]***

[0.0

27]*

**[0

.026

]***

[0.0

27]*

**[0

.027

]***

Dep

thof

Cre

dit

Info

0.03

00.

029

0.02

90.

028

0.04

80.

047

[0.0

03]*

**[0

.003

]***

[0.0

03]*

**[0

.003

]***

[0.0

06]*

**[0

.006

]***

CO

NE

NF

*DE

PT

HC

RE

DIN

FO

-0.0

33-0

.032

[0.0

09]*

**[0

.009

]***

Con

stan

t10

.618

10.6

2610

.589

10.5

9110

.542

10.5

5110

.549

10.5

40[0

.125

]***

[0.0

16]*

**[0

.112

]***

[0.0

09]*

**[0

.112

]***

[0.0

16]*

**[0

.016

]***

[0.1

13]*

**O

bse

rvat

ions

511

511

513

513

511

511

511

511

Cou

ntr

yF

Ean

dR

E

Sta

nd

ard

erro

rsin

bra

cket

s

*p

¡10%

,**

p¡5

%,

***

p¡1

%

128

Page 130: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

Table

3.6.1.6.:

Fix

edan

dR

andom

Eff

ects

Reg

ress

ion(3

4C

ountr

ies)

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

(7)

(8)

RE

FE

RE

FE

RE

FE

FE

RE

Rea

lG

DP

Con

trac

tE

nfo

rcem

ent

0.09

20.

091

0.09

10.

089

0.09

60.

097

[0.0

17]*

**[0

.017

]***

[0.0

18]*

**[0

.017

]***

[0.0

18]*

**[0

.019

]***

Dep

thof

Cre

dit

Info

0.00

60.

006

0.00

60.

005

0.01

40.

013

[0.0

03]*

*[0

.002

]**

[0.0

02]*

*[0

.002

]**

[0.0

08]*

[0.0

09]

CO

NE

NF

*DE

PT

HC

RE

DIN

FO

-0.0

13-0

.011

[0.0

12]

[0.0

12]

Con

stan

t10

.529

10.5

3210

.566

10.5

6810

.515

10.5

2010

.517

10.5

13[0

.152

]***

[0.0

12]*

**[0

.121

]***

[0.0

09]*

**[0

.122

]***

[0.0

13]*

**[0

.013

]***

[0.1

23]*

**O

bse

rvat

ions

305

305

306

306

305

305

305

305

Tim

ean

dC

ountr

yF

Ean

dR

E

Sta

nd

ard

erro

rsin

bra

cket

s

*p

¡10%

,**

p¡5

%,

***

p¡1

%

129

Page 131: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

Table

3.6.1.7.:

Fix

edan

dR

andom

Eff

ects

Reg

ress

ion

(34

Cou

ntr

ies)

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

(7)

(8)

RE

FE

RE

FE

RE

FE

FE

RE

Rea

lG

DP

Con

trac

tE

nfo

rcem

ent

0.11

60.

112

0.10

40.

099

0.12

60.

129

[0.0

26]*

**[0

.026

]***

[0.0

25]*

**[0

.024

]***

[0.0

25]*

**[0

.026

]***

Dep

thof

Cre

dit

Info

0.02

30.

023

0.02

20.

022

0.05

30.

051

[0.0

03]*

**[0

.003

]***

[0.0

03]*

**[0

.003

]***

[0.0

11]*

**[0

.011

]***

CO

NE

NF

*DE

PT

HC

RE

DIN

FO

-0.0

48-0

.044

[0.0

16]*

**[0

.016

]***

Con

stan

t10

.578

10.5

8210

.572

10.5

7510

.512

10.5

2010

.512

10.5

05[0

.152

]***

[0.0

17]*

**[0

.120

]***

[0.0

10]*

**[0

.121

]***

[0.0

17]*

**[0

.017

]***

[0.1

22]*

**O

bse

rvat

ions

305

305

306

306

305

305

305

305

Cou

ntr

yF

Ean

dR

E

Sta

nd

ard

erro

rsin

bra

cket

s

*p

¡10%

,**

p¡5

%,

***

p¡1

%

130

Page 132: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

Chapter 4

Thesis Conclusion

This thesis explores the broad issue of the effects of institutions on macroeconomic per-

formance. The study of the relationship between institutions including the operations

of financial markets, and economic performance has a long history in economics (see

Beck and Levine (2008)). The importance of well-functioning institutions has been

widely documented and is generally accepted (see Knack and Keefer (1995); Rodrik

et al. (2004); Hall and Jones (1999a)). Rodrik et al. (2004) and Hall and Jones (1999a)

observe that good quality institutions is one of the most important factors in raising

per capita output and promoting economic development. Against this background,

we study two areas of institutional imperfection–limited governance of corruption and

limited enforcement of financial contracts. We do so in two main chapters, a brief

summary of each of which is given below.

In the first chapter we study the effects of corruption on sovereign debt decisions.

First, we empirically investigate the determinants of sovereign default. Using various

specifications we find that political stability and corruption increase sovereign default

risk. Second, we setup a dynamic stochastic general equilibrium model to investigate

theoretically the effects of corruption and political risk on sovereign default decisions,

and the implications for macroeconomic activity. Consistent with our empirical results,

we find that corruption can generate high default risk and high credit spreads, but only

when there is enough political stability. In the stable economy with political turnover,

the less corrupt policymakers choose debt levels that would induce a more corrupt

131

Page 133: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

policymaker to default. This results in higher credit spreads and higher overall default

rates compared to the case of no turnover or less stability. A seemingly intuitive result

is that a change in power from a less corrupt to a more corrupt government leads to

a greater likelihood of default. This is because of the high level of borrowing by a less

corrupt government, which saddles the more corrupt government with high levels of

debt on which it is induced to default. Our analysis also demonstrates the amplification

effects of corruption on macroeconomic fluctuations, together with the negative effects

of corruption on welfare.

In the second main chapter we study limited contract enforcement in financial

markets and the impact of this on firm financing and aggregate outcomes. As a motiv-

ation, we empirically investigate the effects of limited contract enforcement on output

using panel data. We find that limited enforcement has a negative effect on output and

that this effect is inhibited by poor credit information, although poor credit informa-

tion has negative effect on output. We also find that high costs of contract enforcement

are associated with high output volatility. We then present a dynamic stochastic gen-

eral equilibrium model of asymmetric information and limited contract enforcement

to study the issue theoretically. We show that limited enforcement has effect on a

number of finance variables, such as the leverage of firms, the lending rate and the risk

premium. These effects, all of which are positive, are due to the higher probability

of default when contract enforcement is weaker. An implication is that firms are sub-

ject to tighter credit constraints, the impact of which is most significant for relatively

small firms. Through these channels, we demonstrate how limited enforcement affects

macroeconomic variables, such as output, employment and price. Consistent with our

empirical observations, we find that a higher cost of contract enforcement is associated

with a greater volatility of output.

On the whole, our results indicate that imperfectly-functioning institutions tend

to impede on macroeconomic performance. These results are particularly relevant for

developing countries, where institutions are often weak, fragile and fragmented because

of poor quality of governance. Our analysis suggests that improving such quality has

132

Page 134: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

the potential to improve the prospects of such countries.

The current study is limited in many respects. The inability to find suitable

instrumental variables to solve a possible endogeneity problem, in the empirical work

of Chapter (2), is a limitation to the study. In Chapter (2), though the empirical

study could not make use of all possible control variables, the study could still face

limitation for not including for instance external factors as controls. Also, including

more control variables, in the empirical work of the thesis, could enrich our empirical

findings. Though the current study has enriched our understanding of institutions

and macroeconomic performance, possible effects of institutions on key macroeconomic

variables such as monetary policy has not been adequately addressed. The existing

models on institutions (see Huang and Wei (2003, 2006)) find that weak institutions

do not only make monetary policy ineffective but also have serious consequences for

monetary policy targets. We recommend that our model on corruption and sovereign

default be extended to incorporate the monetary policy sector. By this we will be

able to study monetary and fiscal policy interactions in a weak institutional setting

and their consequence on macroeconomic outcomes. Incorporating monetary policy

into the model on limited contract enforcement will improve our understanding of how

effective or ineffective monetary policy will be under limited contract enforcement.

Also introducing habit formation into the utility function will smooth consumption

and enable us understand the behaviour of households towards consumption, in the

present context.

133

Page 135: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

BIBLIOGRAPHY

Acemoglu, D. and Johnson, S. (2004). “Institutions as Fundamental Cause of Long-Run

Growth”. NBER Working Papers Series 10481.

Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., Robinson, J., and Thaicharoen, Y. (2003). “Institutional

causes, macroeconomic symptoms: volatility, crises and growth”. Journal of monet-

ary economics, 50(1):49–123.

Acemoglu, D. and Verdier, T. (1998). “Property Rights, Corruption and Allocation of

Talent: A General Equilibrium Approach”. The Economic Journal 450, 1381–1403.

Acemoglu, D. and Verdier, T. (2000). “The Choice Between Market Failures and

Corruption”. The American Economic Review 1, 194–211.

Aguiar, M. and Gopinath, G. (2006). “Defaultable Debt, Interest Rates and the Current

Account”. Journal of International Economics 69 (June): 64–83.

Al-Marhubi, F. A. (2000). “Corruption and inflation”. Economics Letters, 66(2):199–

202.

Albuquerque, R. and Hopenhayn, H. (2000). “Optimal dynamic lending contracts with

imperfect enforceability”. In AFA 2001 New Orleans Meetings, pages 00–10.

Alfaro, L. and Kanczuk, F. (2005). “Sovereign Debt as a Contingent Claim: A Quant-

itative Approach”. Journal of International Economics 65 (March): 297–314.

Amador, M. (2003). “A Political Economy Model of Sovereign Debt Repayment”.

Stanford University mimeo.

Amaral, P. S. and Quintin, E. (2010). “Limited enforcement, financial intermediation,

and economic development: A quantitative assessment”. International Economic

Review, 51(3):785–811.

134

Page 136: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

Arellano, C. (2008). “Default Risk and Income Fluctuations in Emerging Economies”.

American Economic Review 98 (June): 690–712. 19.

Attila, J. (2008). “Corruption, taxation and economic growth: theory and evidence”.

CERDI working paper E 2008.29.

Aylward, M. L. and Thorne, M. R. (1998). “An econometric analysis of countries’ re-

payment performance to the International Monetary Fund”. International Monetary

Fund.

Baldacci, E., Gupta, S., and Mati, A. (2011). “Political and fiscal risk determin-

ants of sovereign spreads in emerging markets”. Review of Development Economics,

15(2):251–263.

Balkan, E. M. (1992). “Political instability, country risk and probability of default”.

Applied Economics, 24(9):999–1008.

Barro, R. (1990). “Government Spending in a Simple Model of Endogenous Growth”.

Journal of Political Economy 98, s103-s117.

Beck, T. and Levine, R. (2008). Legal institutions and financial development. In

Handbook of new institutional economics, pages 251–278. Springer.

Bernanke, B. S., Gertler, M., and Gilchrist, S. (1999). “The financial accelerator in a

quantitative business cycle framework”. Handbook of macroeconomics, 1:1341–1393.

Blackburn and Forgues-Puccio (2010). “Financial Liberalisation, Bureaucratic Corrup-

tion and Economic Development”. Journal of International Money and Finance.

Blackburn, K., Bose, N., and Haque, M. E. (2006). “The incidence and persistence of

corruption in economic development”. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control,

30(12):2447–2467.

Blackburn, K., Bose, N., and Haque, M. E. (2011). “Public Expenditures, Bureaucratic

Corrruption and Economic Development”. The Manchester School, 79(3):405–428.

135

Page 137: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

Blackburn, K. and Forgues-Puccio, G. F. (2007). “Distribution and Development in a

Model of Misgovernance”. European Economic Review, 51(6):1534–1563.

Blackburn, K. and Forgues-Puccio, G. F. (2009). “Why is corruption less harmful in

some countries than in others”? Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization,

72(3):797–810.

Blackburn, K. and Powell, J. (2011a). “Corruption, Inflation and Growth”. Centre

for Growth and Business Cycles Research, Department of Economics, University of

Manchester, UK.

Blackburn, K. and Powell, J. (2011b). “Corruption, inflation and growth”. Economics

Letters, 113(3):225–227.

Blackburn, K. and Sarmah, R. (2008). “Corruption, development and demography”.

Economics of Governance, 9(4):341–362.

Boedo, H. J. M., Senkal, A., and D’Erasmo, P. (2011). “Misallocation, Informality

and Human Capital”. In 2011 Meeting Papers, number 881. Society for Economic

Dynamics.

Bordo, M. and Oosterlinck, K. (2005). “Do political changes trigger debt default? And

do defaults lead to political changes”? In Conference on the Political Economy of

International Finance PEIF.

Braun, M. and Di Tella, R. (2004). “Ination, ination variability, and corruption”.

Economics and Politics, 16(1):77100.

Brown, M., Jappelli, T., and Pagano, M. (2009). “Information sharing and credit:

Firm-level evidence from transition countries”. Journal of Financial Intermediation,

18(2):151–172.

Butler, A. W. and Fauver, L. (2006). “Institutional environment and sovereign credit

ratings”. Financial Management, 35(3):53–79.

136

Page 138: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

Carlstrom, C. T. and Fuerst, T. S. (1997). “Agency costs, net worth, and business

fluctuations: A computable general equilibrium analysis”. The American Economic

Review, pages 893–910.

Carlstrom, C. T. and Fuerst, T. S. (1998). “Agency costs and business cycles”. Eco-

nomic Theory, 12(3):583–597.

Carlstrom, C. T. and Fuerst, T. S. (2001). “Monetary shocks, agency costs, and busi-

ness cycles”. In Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, volume 54,

pages 1–27. Elsevier.

Carlstrom, C. T., Fuerst, T. S., and Paustian, M. (2010). “Optimal monetary policy in

a model with agency costs”. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 42(s1):37–70.

Castro, R., Clementi, G. L., and MacDonald, G. (2004). “Investor protection, op-

timal incentives, and economic growth”. The Quarterly Journal of Economics,

119(3):1131–1175.

Castro, R., Clementi, G. L., and MacDonald, G. (2009). “Legal institutions, sec-

toral heterogeneity, and economic development”. The Review of Economic Studies,

76(2):529–561.

Chatterjee, S., Corbae, D., and Rios-Rull, J.-V. (2007). “Credit scoring and competitive

pricing of default risk”. Manuscript, University of Texas at Austin.

Chen, B.-L. (2003). “Tax evasion in a model of endogenous growth”. Review of Eco-

nomic Dynamics, 6(2):381–403.

Ciarlone, A. and Trebeschi, G. (2005). “Designing an early warning system for debt

crises”. Emerging Markets Review, 6(4):376–395.

Ciocchini, F., Durbin, E., and Ng, D. T. (2003). “Does corruption increase emerging

market bond spreads”? Journal of Economics and Business, 55(5):503–528.

Citron, J.-T. and Nickelsburg, G. (1987). “Country risk and political instability”.

Journal of Development Economics, 25(2):385–392.

137

Page 139: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

Cole, H. L., Dow, J., and English, W. B. (1995). “Default, Settlement, and Signalling:

Lending Resumption in a Reputational Model of Sovereign Debt”. International

Economic Review 36 (May): 365–85.

Cooley, T., Marimon, R., and Quadrini, V. (2003). “Aggregate consequences of limited

contract enforceability”. Technical report, National Bureau of Economic Research.

Coppier, R. et al. (2006). “Corruption, tax revenue and growth: a non linear relation-

ship”. Rivista di Politica Economica, 96(5/6):243.

Cuadra, G. and Sapriza, H. (2008). “Sovereign Default, Interest Rates and Political

Uncertainty in Emerging Markets”. Journal of International Economics 76 (Septem-

ber): 78–88.

Cule, M. and Fulton, M. (2005). “Some Implications of the Unofficial Economy-

Bureaucratic Corruption Relationship in Transition Countries”. Economics Letters

89, 207–211.

Dal Bo, E. and Rossi, M. A. (2007). “Corruption and inefficiency: Theory and evidence

from electric utilities”. Journal of Public Economics, 91(5):939–962.

De Fiore, F., Teles, P., and Tristani, O. (2011). “Monetary policy and the financing of

firms”. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 3(4):112–142.

D’Erasmo, P. N. and Moscoso Boedo, H. J. (2012). “Financial structure, informality

and development”. Journal of Monetary Economics, 59(3):286–302.

Detragiache, E. and Spilimbergo, A. (2001a). “Crises and liquidity: evidence and

interpretation”. IMF Working Paper.

Detragiache, E. and Spilimbergo, A. (2001b). “Short-term debt and crises”. Interna-

tional Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.

Dixit, A. and Londregan, J. (2000). “Political Power and the Credibility of Government

Debt”. Journal of Economic Theory 94 (September): 80–105.

138

Page 140: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

Djankov, S., Glaeser, E., La Porta, R., Lopez-de Silanes, F., and Shleifer, A. (2003).

“The New Comparative Economics.”. NBER Working Papers Series 9608.

Djankov, S., McLiesh, C., and Shleifer, A. (2007). “Private credit in 129 countries”.

Journal of financial Economics, 84(2):299–329.

Djankov, S., Porta, R. L., Lopez-de Silane, F., and Shleifer, A. (2002). “Courts: The

lex mundi project”. Technical report, National Bureau of Economic Research.

Dreher, A. and Herzfeld, T. (2005). “The economic costs of corruption: A survey and

new evidence”. Public Economics, 506001.

Dreher, A. and Siemens, L. (2003). “The intriguing nexus between corruption and

capital account restrictions”. Economics Working Paper Archive at WUSTL.

Eaton, J. and Gersovitz, M. (1981). “Debt with Potential Repudiation: Theoretical

and Empirical Analysis”. Review of Economic Studies 48 (April): 289–09.

Economist., T. (1999). “Argentina’s Next Steps”. The Economist.

Economist, T. (2005). “Argentina’s Debt Restructuring. Tough Deal”. The Economist.

Edwards, S. (1984). “LDC’s foreign borrowing and default risk: an empirical investig-

ation”. National Bureau of Economic Research Cambridge, Mass., USA.

Ehrlich, I. and Lui, F. T. (1999). “Bureaucratic corruption and endogenous economic

growth”. Journal of Political Economy, 107(S6):S270–S293.

Elliott, J. E. (1997). “The role of institutional change in post-Communist transition”.

International Journal of Social Economics, 24(7/8/9):859–872.

Ellis, C. J. and Fender, J. (2006). “Corruption and transparency in a growth model”.

International Tax and Public Finance, 13(2-3):115–149.

Esfahani, H. (2000). “Institutions and Government Controls”. Journal of Development

Economics 63, 197–229.

139

Page 141: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

Farida, M. and Ahmadi-Esfahani, F. (2007). “Modelling Corruption in a Cobb-Douglas

Production Function Framework”. Australian Agricultural and Resource Economics

society, 51 st Annual Conference. February 13, 2007.

Feder, G. and Just, R. E. (1977). “A study of debt servicing capacity applying logit

analysis”. Journal of Development Economics, 4(1):25–38.

Frank, C. R. and Cline, W. R. (1971). “Measurement of debt servicing capacity: An

application of discriminant analysis”. Journal of International Economics, 1(3):327–

344.

Ganuza, J.-J. and Hauk, E. (2000). “Economic integration and corruption: The corrupt

soul of the European Union”. Universitat Pompeu Fabra Working Paper.

Gelos, R. G., Sahay, R., and Sandleris, G. (2004). “Sovereign Borrowing by Developing

Countries: What Determines Market Access”? IMFWorking Paper 04/221.

Georgievska, A., Georgievska, L., Stojanovic, A., and Todorovic, N. (2008). “Sovereign

rescheduling probabilities in emerging markets: a comparison with credit rating

agenciesı¿œ ratings”. Journal of Applied Statistics, 35(9):1031–1051.

Gertler, M. (1988). “Financial structure and aggregate economic activity: An over-

view”. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 20(3).

Ghura, M. D. (1998). “Tax Revenue in Sub-Saharan Africa-Effects of Economic Policies

and Corruption”. Number 98-135. International Monetary Fund.

Gomes, J. F., Yaron, A., and Zhang, L. (2003). “Asset prices and business cycles with

costly external finance”. Review of economic Dynamics, 6(4):767–788.

Gupta, S., Davoodi, H., and E, T. (2001). “Corruption and the Provision of Health Care

and Education Services”. In: Jain, A. (Ed.), The Political Economy of Corruption.

Routledge Publishers, London.

Gyimah-Brempong, K. (2002). “Corruption, economic growth, and income inequality

in Africa”. Economics of Governance, 3(3):183–209.

140

Page 142: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

Gyimah-Brempong, K., Camacho, D., and Munoz, S. (2006). “Corruption, Growth,

and Income Distribution: Are there Regional Differences”. Economics of Gov-

ernance, 7(3).

Hall, R. E. and Jones, C. I. (1999a). “Why Do Some Countries Produce so much more

Output Per Worker than Others”? The Quarterly Journal of Economics.

Hall, R. E. and Jones, C. I. (1999b). “Why do some countries produce so much more

output per worker than others”? Technical report, National bureau of economic

research.

Haque, N. U. and Sahay, R. (1996). “Do Government Wages Cuts Close Budget

Deficits? The Cost of Corruption”. IMF Staff Papers, Vol. 43, No 4. December, pp.

754-778.

Hatchondo, J. C. and Martinez, L. (2009). “Long-Duration Bonds and Sovereign

Defaults”. Journal of International Economics 79 (September): 117–25.

Hatchondo, J. C. and Martinez, L. (2010.). “The Politics of Sovereign Defaults”.

Economic Quarterly—Volume 96, Number 3—Third Quarter 2010—Pages 291–317.

Hatchondo, J. C., Martinez, L., and Sapriza, H. (2007). “Quantitative models of

sovereign default and the threat of financial exclusion”. Economic Quarterly-Federal

Reserve Bank of Richmond, 93(3):251.

Hatchondo, J. C., Martinez, L., and Sapriza, H. (2007a). “The Economics of Sovereign

Default”. Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly 93 (Spring): 163–

87.

Hatchondo, J. C., Martinez, L., and Sapriza, H. (2009). “Heterogeneous Borrowers

in Quantitative Models of Sovereign Default”. International Economic Review 50

(October): 1,129–51.

Hill, I. D. (1973). “Algorithm AS 66: The normal integral”. Journal of the Royal

Statistical Society. Series C (Applied Statistics), 22(3):424–427.

141

Page 143: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

Huang, H. and Wei, S.-J. (2003). “Monetary Policies for Developing Countries: The

Role of Corruption”. IMF WORKING PAPER WP/03/183.

Huang, H. and Wei, S.-J. (2006). “Monetary Policies for Developing Countries: The

Role of Institutional Quality”. Journal of International Economics.

Imam, P. A. and Jacobs, D. (2014). “Effect of Corruption on Tax Revenues in the

Middle East”. Review of Middle East Economics and Finance Rev. Middle East

Econ. Fin., 10(1):1–24.

IMF. “The IMF and Argentina, 1991–2001”. Independent Evaluation Office Re-

port.Washington, D.C.: IMF.

IMF (2002a). “Sovereign Debt Restructurings and the Domestic Economy Experience

in Four Recent Cases”. Washington, D.C.: IMF (February 21).

IMF (2003). “Lessons from the Crisis in Argentina”. Washington, D.C.: IMF (March

24). IMF. 2004.

Infante, D. and Smirnova, J. (2009). “Market Failures Within Poor Institutions: The

Effects of Bureaucrats Rent-Seeking Activity”. In: Salvadori, N. (Ed.), Institutional

and Social Dynamics of Growth and Distribution. Edward Elgar, pp. 94–116.

Jappelli, T. and Pagano, M. (2002). “Information sharing, lending and defaults: Cross-

country evidence”. Journal of Banking & Finance, 26(10):2017–2045.

Johnson, S., Kaufmann, D., and Shleifer, A. (1997). “The unofficial economy in trans-

ition”. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 2: 159-221.

Johnson, S., Kaufmann, D., and Zoido-Lobaton, P. (1998). “Corruption, Public Fin-

ances and the Unofficial Economy”. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper

Series 2169.

Johnson, S., Kaufmann, D., and Zoido-Lobaton, P. (1999). “Corruption, public finances

and the unofficial economy”., volume 2169. World Bank Publications.

142

Page 144: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

Kalliomaki, M. (2012). “Determinants of Sovereign Defaults”.

https://lup.lub.lu.se/student-papers/search/publication/2338226.

Kauppi, H. and Saikkonen, P. (2008). “Predicting US recessions with dynamic binary

response models”. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 90(4):777–791.

Keith, B., Neanidis Kyriakos, C., and Emranul, H. M. (2008). “Corruption, seigniorage

and growth: theory and evidence”. Technical report, CESinfo Working Paper Series.

Munich: CESifo Group.

Khan, A. and Ravikumar, B. (2001). “Growth and risk-sharing with private informa-

tion”. Journal of Monetary Economics, 47(3):499–521.

Klein, P., Krusell, P., and Rios-Rull, J.-V. (2008). “Time-consistent public policy”.

The Review of Economic Studies, 75(3):789–808.

Knack, S. and Keefer, P. (1995). “Institutions and Economic Performance: Cross-

Country Tests Using Alternative Institutional Measures”. Economics and Politics,

vol. 7, no. 3, pp. 207-227.

Kraay, A. and Nehru, V. (2006). “When is external debt sustainable”? The World

Bank Economic Review, 20(3):341–365.

Krusell, P. and Smith Jr, A. A. (2003). “Consumption–savings decisions with quasi–

geometric discounting”. Econometrica, 71(1):365–375.

La Porta, R., Lopez-de Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., and Vishny, R. (2000). “Investor

protection and corporate governance”. Journal of financial economics, 58(1):3–27.

La Porta, R., Lopez-de Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., and Vishny, R. W. (1997). “Legal

determinants of external finance”. National bureau of economic research.

Lausev, J., Stojanovic, A., and Todorovic, N. (2011). “Determinants of debt reschedul-

ing in Eastern European countries”. Economic Annals, 56(188):7–31.

143

Page 145: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

Levin, A. T., Natalucci, F. M., and Zakrajsek, E. (2004). “The magnitude and cyclical

behavior of financial market frictions”.

Levine, R., Loayza, N., and Beck, T. (2000). “Financial intermediation and growth:

Causality and causes”. Journal of monetary Economics, 46(1):31–77.

Li, C. A. (1992). “Debt arrears in Latin America: Do political variables matter”? The

Journal of Development Studies, 28(4):668–688.

Li, H., Xu, L. C., and Zou, H.-f. (2000). “Corruption, income distribution, and growth”.

Economics & Politics, 12(2):155–182.

Lopez de Silanes, F., La Porta, R., Shleifer, A., and Vishny, R. (1998). “Law and

finance”. Journal of political economy, 106:1113–1155.

Lucas, R. E. (1987). “Models of business cycles”, volume 26. Basil Blackwell Oxford.

Marcet, A. and Marimon, R. (1992). “Communication, commitment, and growth”.

Journal of Economic Theory, 58(2):219–249.

Mauro, P. (1995). “Corruption and Growth”. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 3,

681–712.North, D.C., 1997. The contribution of the new institutional economics to

an understanding of the transition problem. WIDER Annual Lectures, p. 1.

Mauro, P. (1996). “The Effects of Corruption on Growth, Investment, and Government

Expenditure”. IMF WORKING PAPER.

Mauro, P. (1997a). “The Effects of Corruption on Growth, Investment, and Gov-

ernment Expenditure: A Cross–Country Analysis. Corruption and the Global Eco-

nomy”. Washington D.C, Institute for International Economics: 83–107.

Mauro, P. (1997b). “Why Worry About Corruption”. Washington D.C., International

Monetary Fund.

Mauro, P. (1998). “The effects of corruption on growth, investment, and government

expenditure: a cross-country analysis”. In: Elliott, K.A. (Ed.), Corruption and the

Global Economy. Institute for International Economics, Washington D.C.

144

Page 146: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

McFadden, D., Eckaus, R., Feder, G., Hajivassiliou, V., and O’Connell, S. (1985). “Is

there life after debt? An econometric analysis of the creditworthiness of developing

countries”. International debt and the developing countries, pages 179–209.

Min, H. G. (1998). “Determinants of emerging market bond spread: do economic

fundamentals matter”? Number 1899. World Bank Publications.

Monge-Naranjo, A. (2009). “Entrepreneurship and firm heterogeneity with limited

enforcement”. Annals of Finance, 5(3-4):465–494.

Moser, C. (2007). “The impact of political risk on sovereign bond spreads-evidence

from Latin America”. In Proceedings of the German Development Economics Con-

ference, Gottingen 2007, number 24. Verein fur Socialpolitik, Research Committee

Development Economics.

Murphy, K., Shleifer, A., and Vishny, R. (1991). “The Allocation of Talent: Implica-

tions for Growth”. The Quarterly Journal of Economics.

Ng, E. C. (2012). “Forecasting US recessions with various risk factors and dynamic

probit models”. Journal of Macroeconomics, 34(1):112–125.

North, D. C. (1989). “Institutions and economic growth: An historical introduction”.

World development, 17(9):1319–1332.

North, D. C. (1990). “Institutions, institutional change and economic performance”.

Cambridge university press.

Nyberg, H. (2010). “Dynamic probit models and financial variables in recession fore-

casting”. Journal of Forecasting, 29(1-2):215–230.

Ofer, G. (2003). “Transition and Development Economies: Comparing the Quality of

Governments”. In:Campos, N., Fidrmuc, J. (Eds.), Political Economy of Transition

and Development. Kluwer Academic Publishers, pp. 69–96.

Ortigueira, S., Pereira, J., and Pichler, P. (2012). “Markov-perfect optimal fiscal policy:

the case of unbalanced budgets”.

145

Page 147: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

Perri, F. and Neumeyer, A. (2004). “Emerging Market Business Cycles: The Role of

Interest Rates”. NBER working paper, 10387.

Pestova, A. (2015). “Leading Indicators of the Business Cycle: Dynamic Logit Models

for OECD Countries and Russia”. Higher School of Economics Research Paper No.

WP BRP, 94.

PRS (2008). “A Business Guide to Political Risk for International De-

cisions”.International Country Risk Guide (ICRG).Part II. 2008.

Quintin, E. (2000). “Limited enforcement and the organization of production”. Un-

published manuscript, Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas.

Rahnama-Moghadam, M. (1995). “Debt rescheduling in less-developed countries: world

or regional crisis”. The Journal of Developing Areas, pages 11–22.

Reinhart, C. M., Rogoff, K. S., and Savastano, M. A. (2003). “Debt intolerance”.

Technical report, National Bureau of Economic Research.

Rodrik, D., Subramanian, A., and Trebbi, F. (2004). “Institutions rule: the primacy

of institutions over geography and integration in economic development”. Journal

of economic growth, 9(2):131–165.

Rose, A. K. (2005). “One reason countries pay their debts: renegotiation and interna-

tional trade”. Journal of development economics, 77(1):189–206.

Rowland, P. and Torres, J. (2004). “Determinants of spread and creditworthiness for

emerging market sovereign debt: a panel data study”. Im Internet: http://www.

banrep. gov. co/docum/ftp/borra295. pdf (abgerufen am 22.03. 08).

Santiso, J. (2003). “The political economy of emerging markets: Actors, institutions

and financial crises in Latin America”. Palgrave Macmillan.

Sarte, P.-D. G. (2000). “Informality and rent-seeking bureaucracies in a model of

long-run growth”. Journal of Monetary Economics, 46(1):173–197.

146

Page 148: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

Schimmelpfennig, M. A., Roubini, N., and Manasse, P. (2003). “Predicting sovereign

debt crises”. Number 3-221. International Monetary Fund.

Steinberg, J. B. (2013). “Information, Contract Enforcement, and Misallocation”. Job

Market Paper.

Sturzenegger, F. and Zettelmeyer, J. (2006). “Debt defaults and lessons from a decade

of crises”. MIT press.

Swaleheen, M. (2011). “Economic growth with endogenous corruption: an empirical

study”. Public Choice, 146(1-2):23–41.

Tanzi, V. (1998). “Corruption Around the World: Causes, Consequences, Scope, and

Cures”. Working Paper No. 63 (Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund).

Tanzi, V. and Davoodi, H. (1997). “Corruption, Public Investment and Growth”. IMF

Working paper.

Tanzi, V. and Davoodi, H. (2000). “Corruption, growth, and public finances”. IMF

Working Paper.

Tauchen, G. (1986). “Finite state markov-chain approximations to univariate and

vector autoregressions”. Economics letters, 20(2):177–181.

Tomz, M. and Wright, M. L. J. (2007). “Do Countries Default in Bad Times”? Journal

of the European Economic Association 5: 352-60.

Treisman, D. (2003). “Postcommunist corruption”. Political Economy of Transition

and Development: Institutions, Policies and Politics, pages 201–26.

Ul Haque, N., Mark, N. C., and Mathieson, D. J. (1998). “The relative importance of

political and economic variables in creditworthiness ratings”. IMF working paper.

Van Rijckeghem, C. and Weder, B. (2004). “The politics of debt crises”. CEPR

Discussion Paper.

147

Page 149: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

Verma, S. (2002). “Determinants of Sovereign Defaults: What Does the Empirical

Evidence Tell Us”? Economic and Political Weekly, pages 4817–4822.

Wei, S.-J. (1997). “Why is Corruption so much more Taxing than Tax?. Arbitrariness

Kills”. NBER Working Paper 6255, November.

Williams, A. and Siddique, A. (2008). “The use (and abuse) of governance indicators

in economics: a review”. Economics of Governance, 9(2):131–175.

Williams, B. (2014). “Bank risk and national governance in Asia”. Journal of Banking

& Finance, 49:10–26.

Yue, V. Z. (2006). “Sovereign Default and Debt Renegotiation”. Manuscript, New

York University.

148

Page 150: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

Appendix A

Computer Codes

A.1 Chapter 2 Computer Codes

A.1.1 STATA CODES

This Stata code is used for the empirical results of this chapter of the thesis.

Listing A.1: Stata Do File

// import data// use sove r e i gn . dta ” , c l e a regen id = group ( country )x t s e t id year

// i c r g c= measure o f co r rupt i on// prr = measure p o l i t i c a l s t a b i l i t y// lgdppc= log GDP per cap i ta//gdpgww= GDP growth// extdebtperc= e x t e r n a l debt−GDP r a t i o// de f= d e f a u l t

// i c r g c 1= one per iod lag o f co r rupt i on// prr1 = one per iod lag o f p o l i t i c a l s t a b i l i t y// lgdppc1= one per iod lag o f l og GDP per cap i ta//gdpgww1= one per iod lag o f GDP growth// extdebtperc1= one per iod lag o f e x t e r n a l debt−GDP r a t i o// de f1= one per iod lag o f d e f a u l t

//CORRELATIONSc o r r t e x de f i c r g c prr lgdppc gdpgww extdebtperc ,

//SUMMARY STATISTICSsutex de f i c r g c prr lgdppc gdpgww extdebtperc , minmax

149

Page 151: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

////CURRENT EXPLANATORY VARIABLES ONLYprob de f i c r g c prr extdebtperc gdpgwwe s t s t o PROB1

prob de f i c r g c prr extdebtperc lgdppce s t s t o PROB2

prob de f i c r g c prr extdebtperc gdpgww lgdppce s t s t o PROB3

//mfxprob de f i c r g c prr extdebtperc gdpgwwmfxe s t s t o mfx1

prob de f i c r g c prr extdebtperc lgdppcmfxe s t s t o mfx2

prob de f i c r g c prr extdebtperc gdpgww lgdppcmfxe s t s t o mfx3

//WITH LAGGED DEFAULT

prob de f de f1 i c r g c 1 prr1 extdebtperc1 gdpgww1e s t s t o PROB1

prob de f de f1 i c r g c 1 prr1 extdebtperc1 lgdppc1e s t s t o PROB2

prob de f de f1 i c r g c 1 prr1 extdebtperc1 gdpgww1 lgdppc1e s t s t o PROB3

prob de f de f1 i c r g c 1 prr1 extdebtperc1 gdpgww1mfxe s t s t o mfx1

prob de f de f1 i c r g c 1 prr1 extdebtperc1 lgdppc1mfxe s t s t o mfx2

prob de f de f1 i c r g c 1 prr1 extdebtperc1 gdpgww1 lgdppc1mfxe s t s t o mfx3

150

Page 152: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

//ONLY LAGGED EXPLANATORY VARIABLES; NO LAGGED DEFAULT

prob de f i c r g c 1 prr1 extdebtperc1 gdpgww1e s t s t o PROB1

prob de f i c r g c 1 prr1 extdebtperc1 lgdppc1e s t s t o PROB2

prob de f i c r g c 1 prr1 extdebtperc1 gdpgww1 lgdppc1e s t s t o PROB3

//MFX

prob de f i c r g c 1 prr1 extdebtperc1 gdpgww1mfxe s t s t o mfx1

prob de f i c r g c 1 prr1 extdebtperc1 lgdppc1mfxe s t s t o mfx2

prob de f i c r g c 1 prr1 extdebtperc1 gdpgww1 lgdppc1mfxe s t s t o mfx3

151

Page 153: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

A.1.2 FORTRAN CODES

We use fortran to solve the theoretical model by value function iteration. corruption-

model.f90 is the main program which drives the value function iteration (vfi module.f90)

and the simulation (sim module.f90). The code makes use of the fortran library (func-

tion) alnorm by Hill (1973) to compute the cumulative density function of the standard

normal distribution (https://people.sc.fsu.edu/˜jburkardt/f77 src/asa066/asa066.html

for code). To run these programs we also need other modules which include:

i. grid construction.f90 which constructs the grids for the programs.

ii. model tools.f90 which creates and save the parameters for solving the programs.

iii. data output.f90, a module for saving data from the programs.

iv. array tools.f90 for sorting arrays and array structures.

v. input param.txt; this contains the parameter values to be used by the variousprograms.

Listing A.2: Value Function Iteration

module v f i module

use mode l too l s

use omp lib

i m p l i c i t none

type s o l u t i o n v a r s

r e a l (8 ) : : va l ! opt imal va lue

r e a l (8 ) : : bn so l ! b ’ cho i c e

i n t e g e r : : b n s o l i d x ! index f o r b ’

r e a l (8 ) : : c s o l ! consumption cho i c e

end type s o l u t i o n v a r s

conta in s

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗! subrout ine v a l f c n i t e r

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗

152

Page 154: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

subrout ine v a l f c n i t e r ( n b , n y , b gr id , y gr id , Py , &

Py cdf ,pm, q , p d , ystar , d po l i cy , c p o l i c y , &

bn po l i cy , b n i d x p o l i c y )

i m p l i c i t none

in t ege r , i n t e n t ( in ) : : n b , n y

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( n b ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : b g r i d

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( n y ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : y g r i d

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( n y , n y ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : Py

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( n y , n y ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : Py cdf

type ( params ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : pm

! p o l i c y f u n c t i o n s ( output )

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( n b , n y , 2 , 2 ) , i n t e n t ( out ) : : q

! q (b ’ , y , d , type ) , q schedu le

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( n b , n y , 2 , 2 ) , i n t e n t ( out ) : : p d

! p d (b ’ , y , h ’ , type ’ ) , d e f a u l t p r o b a b i l i t y

in t ege r , dimension ( n b , 2 , 2 ) , i n t e n t ( out ) : : y s ta r

! y∗(b ’ , h ’ , type ’ ) , d e f a u l t t h r e s h o l d s

l o g i c a l , dimension ( n b , n y , 2 , 2 ) , i n t e n t ( out ) : : d p o l i c y

! d (b , y , h i s t , type ) , d e f a u l t p o l i c y

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( n b , n y , 2 , 2 ) , i n t e n t ( out ) : : c p o l i c y

! d (b , y , h i s t , type ) , d e f a u l t p o l i c y

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( n b , n y , 2 , 2 ) , i n t e n t ( out ) : : bn po l i cy

! b ’ ( b , y , h i s t , type ) , debt p o l i c y

in t ege r , dimension ( n b , n y , 2 , 2 ) , i n t e n t ( out ) : : b n i d x p o l i c y

! b ’ ( b , y , h i s t , type ) , debt p o l i c y ( index )

! %%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%

! l o c a l a r rays

! %%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%

! make a l l o c a t a b l e , to avoid memory problems

r e a l ( 8 ) , a l l o c a t a b l e , dimension ( : , : , : , : ) : : v , v0

! v (b , y , h , type )

r e a l ( 8 ) , a l l o c a t a b l e , dimension ( : , : , : , : ) : : vhat , vhat0

! vhat (b , y , h , type )

r e a l ( 8 ) , a l l o c a t a b l e , dimension ( : , : , : ) : : vd , vd0

! v d (y , h , type ) , va lue o f d e f a u l t

r e a l ( 8 ) , a l l o c a t a b l e , dimension ( : , : , : , : ) : : vnd , vnd0

153

Page 155: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

! v nd (b , y , h , type ) , va lue o f not d e f a u l t i n g

r e a l ( 8 ) , a l l o c a t a b l e , dimension ( : , : , : , : ) : : cv

! cv (b ’ , y , d , type ) , cont inuat i on va lue s

! l o c a l v a r i a b l e s

in t ege r , parameter : : MAX ITER = 1000

r e a l ( 8 ) , parameter : : TOL = 1.0 d−6

r e a l (8 ) : : e r r v , e r r vha t

i n t e g e r : : i t e r , e f l a g

i n t e g e r : : i b , i y , i type , i h

l o g i c a l : : de f

type ( s o l u t i o n v a r s ) : : so l nd , s o l d

! A l l o ca t e l o c a l a r rays

a l l o c a t e ( v ( n b , n y , 2 , 2 ) , v0 ( n b , n y , 2 , 2 ) , &

vhat ( n b , n y , 2 , 2 ) , vhat0 ( n b , n y , 2 , 2 ) )

a l l o c a t e ( vnd ( n b , n y , 2 , 2 ) , vnd0 ( n b , n y , 2 , 2 ) )

a l l o c a t e ( vd ( n y , 2 , 2 ) , vd0 ( n y , 2 , 2 ) )

a l l o c a t e ( cv ( n b , n y , 2 , 2 ) )

! i n i t i a l i z e i t e r a t i o n

e f l a g = 0

i t e r = 0

! i n i t i a l i z e va lue f u n c t i o n s

c a l l i n i t v f i ( n b , n y , pm, v0 , vnd0 , vd0 , vhat0 )

do whi l e ( e f l a g == 0)

! compute bond p r i c e schedule , d e f a u l t c u t o f f s and prob o f

! d e f a u l t

c a l l c a l c b o n d p r i c e s c h e d u l e ( n b , n y , vnd0 , vd0 ,&

Py cdf ,pm, q , p d , y s ta r )

! compute cont inuat i on values , CV(b ’ , y , d , j )

! b ’ == debt choice , y = cur rent y , d = d e f a u l t cho i c e today ,

! j = type today

c a l l c a l c c v ( n b , n y , v0 , vhat0 , Py , pm, cv )

154

Page 156: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

! then compute optimal cho i ce s , update vd , vnd , v and p o l i c y

! r u l e s

! loop over y f i r s t to take advantage o f OpenMP

! $omp p a r a l l e l do p r i va t e ( i type , i h , i y , i b , def ,&

so l d , s o l nd )

do i y = 1 , n y ! endowment y

do i t y p e = 1 ,2 ! gov type , c u r r e n t l y in power

do i h = 1 ,2 ! cur r ent h i s t o r y h

! compute value o f d e f a u l t i n g

de f = . t rue .

i b = 1

! s e t i b = 1 ( sove r e i gn i s d e f a u l t i n g anyway )

c a l l s o l v e g r i d s e a r c h ( n b , n y , i b , i y , i h ,&

i type , def , b gr id , y gr id , q , cv , pm, s o l d )

vd ( i y , i h , i t y p e ) = s o l d%va l

do i b = 1 , n b ! debt / a s s e t s b

! compute value o f not d e f a u l t i n g

de f = . f a l s e .

c a l l s o l v e g r i d s e a r c h ( n b , n y , i b , i y ,&

i h , i type , def , b gr id , y gr id , q , cv ,&

pm, so l nd )

vnd ( i b , i y , i h , i t y p e ) = so l nd%val

i f ( s o l nd%val >= s o l d%val ) then

d p o l i c y ( i b , i y , i h , i t y p e ) =&

. f a l s e .

c p o l i c y ( i b , i y , i h , i t y p e ) =&

so l nd%c s o l

bn po l i cy ( i b , i y , i h , i t y p e)=&

so l nd%bn so l

b n i d x p o l i c y ( i b , i y , i h , i t y p e )&

= so l nd%b n s o l i d x

v ( i b , i y , i h , i t y p e ) = &

so l nd%val

155

Page 157: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

e l s e

d p o l i c y ( i b , i y , i h , i t y p e )= &

. true .

c p o l i c y ( i b , i y , i h , i t y p e )= &

s o l d%c s o l

bn po l i cy ( i b , i y , i h , i t y p e)=&

s o l d%bn so l

b n i d x p o l i c y ( i b , i y , i h ,&

i t y p e ) = s o l d%b n s o l i d x

v ( i b , i y , i h , i t y p e ) =&

s o l d%va l

end i f

end do

end do

end do

end do

! $omp end p a r a l l e l do

! now update value when not in government

c a l l update vhat ( n b , n y , Py , v0 , vhat0 , d po l i cy ,&

c p o l i c y , bn idx po l i cy , pm, vhat )

! compute convergence e r r o r

e r r v = maxval ( abs ( v − v0 ) / abs ( v0 ) ) ;

e r r vha t = maxval ( abs ( vhat − vhat0 ) / abs ( vhat0 ) ) ;

i f (mod( i t e r , 10) == 0) then

p r i n t ∗ , ” i t e r = ” , i t e r , ” e r r = ” , max( er r v , &

e r r vha t )

end i f

! a l l r e tu rn s t rue i f a l l e lements in the array are t rue

i f ( a l l ( abs (v−v0 ) <= TOL∗abs ( v0 ) ) . and . a l l (&

abs ( vhat−vhat0 ) <= TOL∗abs ( vhat0 ) ) ) then

e f l a g = 1 ;

end i f

i t e r = i t e r + 1 ;

156

Page 158: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

i f ( i t e r >= MAX ITER) then

p r i n t ∗ , ”Maximum I t e r a t i o n s Reached”

e f l a g = 2 ;

end i f

! update guess

v0 = v ;

vnd0 = vnd

vd0 = vd

vhat0 = vhat

end do

! save r e s u l t s

c a l l s a v e v f i r e s u l t s ( n b , n y , b gr id , y gr id , v , vnd,&

vd , vhat , d po l i cy , c p o l i c y , q , bn po l i cy )

end subrout ine v a l f c n i t e r

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗! subrout ine i n i t v f i

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗subrout ine i n i t v f i ( n b , n y , pm, v0 , vnd0 , vd0 , vhat0 )

i m p l i c i t none

in t ege r , i n t e n t ( in ) : : n b , n y

type ( params ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : pm

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( n b , n y , 2 , 2 ) , i n t e n t ( out ) : : v0

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( n b , n y , 2 , 2 ) , i n t e n t ( out ) : : vnd0

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( n y , 2 , 2 ) , i n t e n t ( out ) : : vd0

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( n b , n y , 2 , 2 ) , i n t e n t ( out ) : : vhat0

l o g i c a l : : l o a d i n i t i a l g u e s s

i n t e g e r : : i n f i l e = 109

l o a d i n i t i a l g u e s s = ( . not . pm%new v0 )

i f ( l o a d i n i t i a l g u e s s ) then

157

Page 159: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

open ( i n f i l e , f i l e = ” r e s u l t s / guess v0 . txt ”)

read ( i n f i l e , ∗ ) v0

rewind ( i n f i l e )

c l o s e ( i n f i l e )

open ( i n f i l e , f i l e = ” r e s u l t s / guess vnd0 . txt ”)

read ( i n f i l e , ∗ ) vnd0

rewind ( i n f i l e )

c l o s e ( i n f i l e )

open ( i n f i l e , f i l e = ” r e s u l t s / guess vd0 . txt ”)

read ( i n f i l e , ∗ ) vd0

rewind ( i n f i l e )

c l o s e ( i n f i l e )

open ( i n f i l e , f i l e = ” r e s u l t s / guess vhat0 . txt ”)

read ( i n f i l e , ∗ ) vhat0

rewind ( i n f i l e )

c l o s e ( i n f i l e )

e l s e

vd0 = 0 .0

vnd0 = 0 .0

v0 = 0 .0 ! equal to max( vd0 , vnd0 )

vhat0 = 0 .0

end i f

end subrout ine i n i t v f i

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗! subrout ine update vhat

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗subrout ine update vhat ( n b , n y , Py , v0 , vhat0 , d po l i cy ,&

c p o l i c y , bn idx po l i cy , pm, vhat )

i m p l i c i t none

in t ege r , i n t e n t ( in ) : : n b , n y

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( n y , n y ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : Py

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( n b , n y , 2 , 2 ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : v0

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( n b , n y , 2 , 2 ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : vhat0

158

Page 160: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

l o g i c a l , dimension ( n b , n y , 2 , 2 ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : d p o l i c y

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( n b , n y , 2 , 2 ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : c p o l i c y

in t ege r , dimension ( n b , n y , 2 , 2 ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : &

b n i d x p o l i c y

type ( params ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : pm

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( n b , n y , 2 , 2 ) , i n t e n t ( out ) : : vhat

! l o c a l a r rays

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( n y ) : : vnext

! l o c a l v a r i a b l e s

i n t e g e r : : i t , i h , i y , i b

i n t e g e r : : i t o t h e r , i d o t h e r , bn idx othe r

r e a l (8 ) : : c o ther , u , cv hat va l , p i t u r n o t h e r

l o g i c a l : : d e f o t h e r

! now , g iven updated p o l i c y funct i ons , update value o f

! government not in power

do i t = 1 ,2 ! government type

i f ( i t == 1) then

i t o t h e r = 2 ! HIGH type i s in power

p i t u r n o t h e r = pm%piH /0 .4

e l s e

i t o t h e r = 1 ! LOW type i s in power

p i t u r n o t h e r = pm%piL /0 .9

end i f

do i h = 1 ,2 ! cur r ent h i s t o r y h

do i y = 1 , n y ! endowment y

do i b = 1 , n b ! debt / a s s e t s b

! get consumption o f other government

c o t he r = c p o l i c y ( i b , i y , i h , i t o t h e r )

! c a l c u l a t e u t i l i t y f l ows to gov ’ t out o f power

u = c a l c u t i l i t y ( c other , pm)

! get d e f a u l t p o l i c y o f other government

d e f o t h e r = d p o l i c y ( i b , i y , i h , i t o t h e r )

159

Page 161: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

i f ( d e f o t h e r ) then

i d o t h e r = 2

e l s e

i d o t h e r = 1

end i f

! get b ’ p o l i c y ( index ) o f other government

bn idx othe r = b n i d x p o l i c y ( i b , i y , i h , i t o t h e r )

! compute cont inuat i on value

! with prob p i tu rn o the r , t h i s type t r a n s i t i o n s

! i n to power and r e c e i v e s v0

! with prob 1−p i tu rn o the r , t h i s type s tays out

! o f pwer and r e c e i v e s vhat0

vnext = p i t u r n o t h e r ∗ v0 ( bn idx other , : , i d o t h e r , i t )&

+ (1− p i t u r n o t h e r )∗ vhat0 ( bn idx other , : , i d o t h e r , i t )

c v h a t v a l = DOT PRODUCT( Py( i y , : ) , vnext )

vhat ( i b , i y , i h , i t ) = u + pm%beta ∗ c v h a t v a l

end do

end do

end do

end do

end subrout ine update vhat

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗! subrout ine c a l c u t i l i t y

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗f unc t i on c a l c u t i l i t y ( c , pm) r e s u l t (u)

i m p l i c i t none

r e a l ( 8 ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : c

type ( params ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : pm

r e a l (8 ) : : u ! output

i f (pm%sigma == 1) then

u = log ( c )

e l s e

160

Page 162: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

u = c∗∗(1−pm%sigma ) / (1−pm%sigma )

end i f

end func t i on c a l c u t i l i t y

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗! subrout ine ca lc consumpt ion

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗f unc t i on ca lc consumpt ion ( n b , n y , i b , i y , i h , i t ,&

i bn , def , b gr id , y gr id , q , pm) r e s u l t ( c )

i m p l i c i t none

in t ege r , i n t e n t ( in ) : : n b , n y , i b , i y , i h , i t , i bn

l o g i c a l : : de f

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( n b ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : b g r i d

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( n y ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : y g r i d

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( n b , n y , 2 , 2 ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : q

type ( params ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : pm

r e a l (8 ) : : c , bn val , b val , tau , h val , q va l

i n t e g e r : : i d

! d e f a u l t d e c i s i o n

i f ( de f ) then

i d = 2

e l s e

i d = 1

end i f

! get b ’ cho i c e

bn val = b gr id ( i bn )

! tax ra t e depends on cur rent government type

i f ( i t == 1) then

tau = pm%tauL

e l s e

tau = pm%tauH

end i f

161

Page 163: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

! cu r r ent h i s t o r y

i f ( i h == 1) then

h va l = 0 .0

e l s e

h va l = 1 .0

end i f

! bond p r i c e

q va l = q ( i bn , i y , i d , i t ) ! i d = 1 ( no d e f a u l t ) ,

! i d == 2 ( d e f a u l t )

! compute consumption

c = (1−tau ) ∗ (1−h va l ∗pm%lambda )∗ exp ( y g r i d ( i y ) ) −&

q va l ∗bn val

i f ( . not . de f ) then

b va l = b gr id ( i b )

c = c + b va l

end i f

end func t i on ca lc consumpt ion

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗! subrout ine c a l c v a l

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗f unc t i on c a l c v a l ( n b , n y , i b , i y , i h , i t , i bn , def , &

b gr id , y gr id , q , cv , pm) r e s u l t ( va l )

i m p l i c i t none

in t ege r , i n t e n t ( in ) : : n b , n y , i b , i y , i h , i t , i bn

l o g i c a l : : de f

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( n b ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : b g r i d

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( n y ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : y g r i d

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( n b , n y , 2 , 2 ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : q

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( n b , n y , 2 , 2 ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : cv

type ( params ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : pm

r e a l (8 ) : : va l ! output

r e a l (8 ) : : q va l , c , u , d val , tau , h val , bn val , b val , &

cv va l

162

Page 164: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

i n t e g e r : : i d

! d e f a u l t d e c i s i o n

i f ( de f ) then

i d = 2

e l s e

i d = 1

end i f

! compute consumption

c = calc consumpt ion ( n b , n y , i b , i y , i h , i t , i bn ,&

def , b gr id , y gr id , q , pm)

i f ( c > 0 . 0 ) then

! c a l c u l a t e u t i l i t y from consumption

u = c a l c u t i l i t y ( c , pm)

! get cont inuat i on value

cv va l = cv ( i bn , i y , i d , i t )

! compute value o f not d e f a u l t

va l = u + pm%beta ∗ cv va l

e l s e

va l = −huge ( va l )

end i f

end func t i on c a l c v a l

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗! subrout ine s o l v e g r i d s e a r c h

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗subrout ine s o l v e g r i d s e a r c h ( n b , n y , i b , i y , i h , i t ,&

def , b gr id , y gr id , q , cv , pm, s o l )

i m p l i c i t none

in t ege r , i n t e n t ( in ) : : n b , n y , i b , i y , i h , i t

l o g i c a l , i n t e n t ( in ) : : de f

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( n b ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : b g r i d

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( n y ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : y g r i d

163

Page 165: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( n b , n y , 2 , 2 ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : q

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( n b , n y , 2 , 2 ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : cv

type ( params ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : pm

type ( s o l u t i o n v a r s ) , i n t e n t ( out ) : : s o l

! l o c a l a r rays

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( n b ) : : v a l g r i d

! l o c a l v a r i a b l e s

i n t e g e r : : i bn , b n s o l i d x

i n t e g e r : : dbg f l a g = 0

i n t e g e r : : ou t un i t = 96

! compute val nd , va l d f o r each b ’ on g r id

do i bn = 1 , n b

v a l g r i d ( i bn ) = c a l c v a l ( n b , n y , i b , i y , i h , i t , &

i bn , def , b gr id , y gr id , q , cv , pm)

end do

i f ( dbg f l ag > 0) then

c a l l o p e n d a t a f i l e ( out un i t , ” o b j f u n c t i o n . txt ”)

c a l l s ave a r ray 1d ( out un i t , ” va l ” , n b , v a l g r i d )

c a l l s ave a r ray 1d ( out un i t , ” b g r i d ” , n b , b g r i d )

c a l l c l o s e d a t a f i l e ( ou t un i t )

end i f

! s o l v e f o r optimal b ’

b n s o l i d x = maxloc ( v a l g r i d , dim=1 )

! save s o l u t i o n

s o l%b n s o l i d x = b n s o l i d x

s o l%bn so l = b gr id ( b n s o l i d x )

s o l%va l = v a l g r i d ( b n s o l i d x )

s o l%c s o l = ca lc consumpt ion ( n b , n y , i b , i y , i h ,&

i t , bn so l i dx , def , b gr id , y gr id , q , pm)

end subrout ine s o l v e g r i d s e a r c h

164

Page 166: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗! subrout ine c a l c b o n d p r i c e s c h e d u l e

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗subrout ine c a l c b o n d p r i c e s c h e d u l e ( n b , n y , vnd0 , vd0 ,&

Py cdf , pm, q , p d , y s ta r )

i m p l i c i t none

in t ege r , i n t e n t ( in ) : : n b , n y

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( n b , n y , 2 , 2 ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : vnd0

! v nd (b , y , h , type ) , va lue o f not d e f a u l t i n g

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( n y , 2 , 2 ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : vd0

! v d (y , h , type ) , va lue o f d e f a u l t

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( n y , n y ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : Py cdf

! Py cdf (y , y ’ ) , cd f o f p r o b a b i l i t y t r a n s i t i o n matrix

type ( params ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : pm

! p o l i c y f u n c t i o n s ( output )

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( n b , n y , 2 , 2 ) , i n t e n t ( out ) : : q

! q (b ’ , y , d , type ’ ) , q schedu le

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( n b , n y , 2 , 2 ) , i n t e n t ( out ) : : p d

! p d (b ’ , y , h ’ , type ’ ) , d e f a u l t p r o b a b i l i t y

in t ege r , dimension ( n b , 2 , 2 ) , i n t e n t ( out ) : : y s ta r

! y∗(b ’ , h ’ , type ’ ) , d e f a u l t t h r e s h o l d s

i n t e g e r : : y s

i n t e g e r : : i bn , i hn , i tn , i t , i y

i n t e g e r : : i t o t h e r

l o g i c a l : : y s f ound

r e a l (8 ) : : pd val

r e a l (8 ) : : pd curr , pd other , p i turn , q va l

! −−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−! f i r s t , compute d e f a u l t t h r e s h o l d s and d e f a u l t p r o b a b i l i t i e s

! −−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−

do i t n = 1 ,2 ! type ’ ( tomorrow ’ s type )

do i hn = 1 ,2 ! h ’ ( h i s t o r y tomorrow )

do i bn = 1 , n b ! b ’ ( debt tomorrow )

165

Page 167: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

! Find y∗ such that

! country does NOT DEFAULT f o r y >= y∗! country does DEFAULT f o r y < y∗ ( or y <= y∗−1)

! i f y∗ == 1 , then country doesn ’ t d e f a u l t f o r any y

! i f y∗ = n y + 1 , then country d e f a u l t s f o r a l l y

y s = 0

y s found = . f a l s e .

do whi l e ( . not . y s found )

y s = y s + 1

! check whether country does NOT DEFAULT f o r t h i s y

i f ( vnd0 ( i bn , y s , i hn , i t n ) >= &

vd0 ( y s , i hn , i t n ) ) then

y s found = . t rue .

e l s e i f ( y s == n y ) then

! only reach t h i s i f

! vnd0 (b ’ , y ’ , h ’ , type ’ ) < vd0 (y ’ , h ’ , type ’ ) f o r a l l y ’

y s found = . t rue .

y s = n y + 1

end i f

end do

! save d e f a u l t th r e sho ld

ys ta r ( i bn , i hn , i t n ) = y s

! compute d e f a u l t p r o b a b i l i t i e s

do i y = 1 , n y

i f ( y s == 1) then

pd val = 0d+0

e l s e i f ( y s == n y + 1) then

pd val = 1 .0 d+0

e l s e

pd val = Py cdf ( i y , y s−1)

end i f

p d ( i bn , i y , i hn , i t n ) = pd val

166

Page 168: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

end do ! cur rent y loop

end do

end do

end do

! −−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−! second , compute bond p r i c e schedu le

! −−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−

do i t = 1 ,2 ! type TODAY

do i hn = 1 ,2 ! d , d e f a u l t d e c i s i o n TODAY ( i . e . , h ’ )

do i y = 1 , n y ! y , cur r ent y

do i bn = 1 , n b ! b ’ , next per iod ’ s debt cho i c e

! get index f o r other type

i f ( i t == 1) then

i t o t h e r = 2

! other type i s the high type

p i t u rn = pm%piL / 0 . 9 ! prob o f turnover

e l s e

i t o t h e r = 1

! other type i s the low type

p i t u rn = pm%piH /0 .4 ! prob o f turnover

end i f

! cu r r ent type ’ s d e f a u l t p r o b a b i l i t y

pd curr = p d ( i bn , i y , i hn , i t )

! o ther type ’ s d e f a u l t p r o b a b i l i t y

pd other = p d ( i bn , i y , i hn , i t o t h e r )

! compute bond p r i c e

q va l = 1 − p i t u rn ∗ pd other − (1−p i t u rn )&

∗ pd curr

q va l = q va l / (1 + pm%r )

! save p r i c e

q ( i bn , i y , i hn , i t ) = q va l

167

Page 169: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

end do

end do

end do

end do

end subrout ine c a l c b o n d p r i c e s c h e d u l e

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗! subrout ine c a l c c v

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗subrout ine c a l c c v ( n b , n y , v0 , vhat0 , Py , pm, cv )

i m p l i c i t none

in t ege r , i n t e n t ( in ) : : n b , n y

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( n b , n y , 2 , 2 ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : v0

! v (b , y , h , type ) , va lue o f gov ’ t in power

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( n b , n y , 2 , 2 ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : vhat0

! vhat (b , y , h , type ) , va lue o f gov ’ t out o f power

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( n y , n y ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : Py

! Py(y , y ’ ) , p r o b a b i l i t y t r a n s i t i o n matrix

type ( params ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : pm

! p o l i c y f u n c t i o n s ( output )

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( n b , n y , 2 , 2 ) , i n t e n t ( out ) : : cv

! cv (b ’ , y , d , type ) , cont inuat i on va lue s

! l o c a l array

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( n y ) : : vnext

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension (2 ) : : p i g r i d

i n t e g e r : : i bn , i y , i d , i t

r e a l (8 ) : : cv va l , p i t u rn

p i g r i d (1 ) = pm%piL / 0 . 9 ;

p i g r i d (2 ) = pm%piH / 0 . 4 ;

do i t = 1 ,2 ! cur r ent type , TODAY

do i d = 1 ,2

! d e f a u l t dec i s i on , TODAY (= h i s t o r y tomorrow )

168

Page 170: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

do i y = 1 , n y ! output y , TODAY

do i bn = 1 , n b ! b ’ cho i c e

! next per iod :

! with prob . pi , type i t w i l l be out o f power−−r e c e i v e vhat0

! with prob . 1−pi , type i t w i l l s t i l l be in power−r e c e i v e v0

vnext = p i g r i d ( i t ) ∗ vhat0 ( i bn , : , i d ,&

i t ) +(1−p i g r i d ( i t ) ) ∗ v0 ( i bn , : , i d , i t )

! compute cont inuat i on value

cv va l = DOT PRODUCT( Py( i y , : ) , vnext )

! save value

cv ( i bn , i y , i d , i t ) = cv va l

end do

end do

end do

end do

end subrout ine c a l c c v

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗! subrout ine s a v e v f i r e s u l t s

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗subrout ine s a v e v f i r e s u l t s ( n b , n y , b gr id , y gr id , v,&

vnd , vd , vhat , d po l i cy , c p o l i c y , q , bn po l i cy )

i m p l i c i t none

in t ege r , i n t e n t ( in ) : : n b , n y

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( n b ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : b g r i d

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( n y ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : y g r i d

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( n b , n y , 2 , 2 ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : v

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( n b , n y , 2 , 2 ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : vnd

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( n y , 2 , 2 ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : vd

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( n b , n y , 2 , 2 ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : vhat

l o g i c a l , dimension ( n b , n y , 2 , 2 ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : d p o l i c y

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( n b , n y , 2 , 2 ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : c p o l i c y

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( n b , n y , 2 , 2 ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : bn po l i cy

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( n b , n y , 2 , 2 ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : q

169

Page 171: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

! l o c a l v a r i a b l e s

i n t e g e r : : v f i o u t = 232

! save r e s u l t s

c a l l o p e n d a t a f i l e ( v f i o u t , ” r e s u l t s / v f i d a t a . txt ” ) ;

c a l l s ave a r ray 1d ( v f i o u t , ” b g r i d ” , n b , b g r i d )

c a l l s ave a r ray 1d ( v f i o u t , ” y g r i d ” , n y , y g r i d )

c a l l s ave a r ray 4d ( v f i o u t , ”v ” , n b , n y , 2 , 2 , v )

c a l l s ave a r ray 4d ( v f i o u t , ”vnd ” , n b , n y , 2 , 2 , vnd )

c a l l s ave a r ray 3d ( v f i o u t , ”vd ” , n y , 2 , 2 , vd )

c a l l s ave a r ray 4d ( v f i o u t , ”vhat ” , n b , n y , 2 , 2 , vhat )

c a l l s ave a r ray 4d ( v f i o u t , ”d” , n b , n y , 2 , 2 , d p o l i c y )

c a l l s ave a r ray 4d ( v f i o u t , ”c ” , n b , n y , 2 , 2 , c p o l i c y )

c a l l s ave a r ray 4d ( v f i o u t , ”q ” , n b , n y , 2 , 2 , q )

c a l l s ave a r ray 4d ( v f i o u t , ”bn” , n b , n y , 2 , 2 , bn po l i cy )

c a l l c l o s e d a t a f i l e ( v f i o u t )

! save v , vnd , vd , vhat in s epara t e f i l e s

open ( un i t=v f i o u t , f i l e =” r e s u l t s / guess v0 . txt ” , a c t i on=&

” wr i t e ” , s t a t u s=”r e p l a c e ”)

wr i t e ( v f i o u t , ∗ ) v

c l o s e ( v f i o u t )

open ( un i t=v f i o u t , f i l e =” r e s u l t s / guess vnd0 . txt ” , a c t i on=&

” wr i t e ” , s t a t u s=”r e p l a c e ”)

wr i t e ( v f i o u t , ∗ ) vnd

c l o s e ( v f i o u t )

open ( un i t=v f i o u t , f i l e =” r e s u l t s / guess vd0 . txt ” , a c t i on=&

” wr i t e ” , s t a t u s=”r e p l a c e ”)

wr i t e ( v f i o u t , ∗ ) vd

c l o s e ( v f i o u t )

open ( un i t=v f i o u t , f i l e =” r e s u l t s / guess vhat0 . txt ” , &

ac t i on=”wr i t e ” , s t a t u s=”r e p l a c e ”)

170

Page 172: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

wr i t e ( v f i o u t , ∗ ) vhat

c l o s e ( v f i o u t )

end subrout ine s a v e v f i r e s u l t s

end module v f i module

171

Page 173: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

Listing A.3: Simulation of Model

module sim module

use mode l too l s

i m p l i c i t none

conta in s

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗! subrout ine s imulate

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗subrout ine s imulate ( n b , n y , b gr id , y gr id , Py cdf , &

mu y cdf , Pt , Pt cdf , mu t cdf , q , p d , d po l i cy , &

c p o l i c y , bn po l i cy , bn idx po l i cy , pm)

i m p l i c i t none

in t ege r , i n t e n t ( in ) : : n b , n y

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( n b ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : b g r i d

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( n y ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : y g r i d

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( n y , n y ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : Py cdf

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( n y ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : mu y cdf

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( 2 , 2 ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : Pt

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( 2 , 2 ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : Pt cd f

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( 2 ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : mu t cdf

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( n b , n y , 2 , 2 ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : q

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( n b , n y , 2 , 2 ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : p d

l o g i c a l , dimension ( n b , n y , 2 , 2 ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : d p o l i c y

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( n b , n y , 2 , 2 ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : c p o l i c y

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( n b , n y , 2 , 2 ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : bn po l i cy

in t ege r , dimension ( n b , n y , 2 , 2 ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : b n i d x p o l i c y

type ( params ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : pm

! l o c a l a r rays (make a l l o c a t a b l e to avoid memory problems )

in t ege r , a l l o c a t a b l e , dimension ( : , : ) : : s im type

! s imulated type ( = 1 , low type , = 2 , high type )

in t ege r , a l l o c a t a b l e , dimension ( : , : ) : : s im y

! t h i s i s j u s t the index f o r output

r e a l ( 8 ) , a l l o c a t a b l e , dimension ( : , : ) : : s im output

172

Page 174: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

! t h i s i s a c tua l s imulated output

r e a l ( 8 ) , a l l o c a t a b l e , dimension ( : , : ) : : s im b

! s imulated b ’

in t ege r , a l l o c a t a b l e , dimension ( : , : ) : : s im b idx

! s imulated b cho i c e ( index )

in t ege r , a l l o c a t a b l e , dimension ( : , : ) : : s im h

! s imulated h i s t o r y ( =1 i f no d e f a u l t prev per iod , . .

!=2 i f d e f a u l t )

l o g i c a l , a l l o c a t a b l e , dimension ( : , : ) : : s im d

! s imulated d e f a u l t d e c i s i o n

r e a l ( 8 ) , a l l o c a t a b l e , dimension ( : , : ) : : s im c

! s imulated consumption

r e a l ( 8 ) , a l l o c a t a b l e , dimension ( : , : ) : : sim bn

! s imulated b ’ cho i c e

in t ege r , a l l o c a t a b l e , dimension ( : , : ) : : s im bn idx

! s imulated b ’ cho i c e ( index )

r e a l ( 8 ) , a l l o c a t a b l e , dimension ( : , : ) : : sim pd

! s imulated d e f a u l t p r o b a b i l i t y

r e a l ( 8 ) , a l l o c a t a b l e , dimension ( : , : ) : : s im q

! s imulated bond p r i c e

i n t e g e r : : n samples , n pe r i od s

i n t e g e r : : i , t

i n t e g e r : : i b , i y , i h , i t ! cu r r ent s t a t e

i n t e g e r : : i bn , i d ! cur r ent c h o i c e s

l o g i c a l : : de f

i n t e g e r : : s im out = 123

n samples = pm%n samples ! number o f samples in s imu la t i on

n pe r i od s = pm%n per i od s

! number o f pe r i od s f o r each sample in s imu la t i on

! a l l o c a t e memory

a l l o c a t e ( s im type ( n per iods , n samples ) , s im y ( n per iods ,&

n samples ) , s im output ( n per iods , n samples ) )

a l l o c a t e ( sim b ( n per iods , n samples ) , s im b idx ( n per iods ,&

n samples ) , s im h ( n per iods , n samples ) )

a l l o c a t e ( sim d ( n per iods , n samples ) , s im c ( n per iods , &

173

Page 175: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

n samples ) , sim bn ( n per iods , n samples ) )

a l l o c a t e ( s im bn idx ( n per iods , n samples ) , s im q ( n per iods ,&

n samples ) , sim pd ( n per iods , n samples ) )

do i = 1 , n samples

! s imulate types ( a l l at once ) f o r t h i s sample

c a l l gen shocks ( n per iods , 2 , mu t cdf , Pt cdf ,&

s im type ( : , i ) )

! s imulate y ( a l l at once ) f o r t h i s sample

c a l l gen shocks ( n per iods , n y , mu y cdf , Py cdf ,&

sim y ( : , i ) )

! i n i t i a l i z e p o l i c y c h o i c e s

i bn = n b ! max b ’

i d = 1 ! no d e f a u l t

do t = 1 , n pe r i od s

! update i n i t i a l s t a t e from c h o i c e s l a s t per iod

i b = i bn

i h = i d

! update i n i t i a l s t a t e f o r output and type

i t = sim type ( t , i )

i y = sim y ( t , i )

! save s t a t e

sim h ( t , i ) = i h

s im b idx ( t , i ) = i b

sim b ( t , i ) = b gr id ( i b )

s im output ( t , i ) = exp ( y g r i d ( i y ) )

! p o l i c y c h o i c e s

i bn = b n i d x p o l i c y ( i b , i y , i h , i t )

de f = d p o l i c y ( i b , i y , i h , i t )

i f ( de f ) then

i d = 2

e l s e

174

Page 176: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

i d = 1

end i f

! save p o l i c y c h o i c e s

sim d ( t , i ) = de f

s im c ( t , i ) = c p o l i c y ( i b , i y , i h , i t )

sim bn ( t , i ) = bn po l i cy ( i b , i y , i h , i t )

s im bn idx ( t , i ) = i bn

! bond pr i ce , g iven p o l i c y c h o i c e s

sim q ( t , i ) = q ( i bn , i y , i d , i t )

! d e f a u l t p robab i l i t y , g iven p o l i c y c h o i c e s

! p d g i v e s the p r o b a b i l i t y o f de fau l t , g iven the

! type in gov ’ t tomorrow

sim pd ( t , i ) = DOT PRODUCT( Pt ( i t , : ) , p d ( i bn ,&

i y , i d , : ) )

end do

i f (mod( i , 10) == 1) then

p r i n t ∗ , ” sample = ” , i

end i f

end do

! −−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−! save s imu la t i on r e s u l t s

! −−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−

pr in t ∗ , ”∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗”p r i n t ∗ , ” Saving Simulat ion Resu l t s ”

p r i n t ∗ , ”∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗”

c a l l o p e n d a t a f i l e ( sim out , ” r e s u l t s / s im data . txt ” ) ;

c a l l s ave a r ray 2d ( sim out , ” s im type ” , n per iods , &

n samples , s im type )

c a l l s ave a r ray 2d ( sim out , ” s im output ” , n per iods ,&

175

Page 177: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

n samples , s im output )

c a l l s ave a r ray 2d ( sim out , ” sim b ” , n per iods , n samples&

, sim b )

c a l l s ave a r ray 2d ( sim out , ” sim bn ” , n per iods , n samples ,&

sim bn )

c a l l s ave a r ray 2d ( sim out , ” sim q ” , n per iods , n samples ,&

sim q )

c a l l s ave a r ray 2d ( sim out , ” sim pd ” , n per iods , n samples ,&

sim pd )

c a l l s ave a r ray 2d ( sim out , ” sim d ” , n per iods , n samples ,&

sim d )

c a l l s ave a r ray 2d ( sim out , ” s im c ” , n per iods , n samples ,&

s im c )

c a l l c l o s e d a t a f i l e ( s im out )

end subrout ine s imulate

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗! subrout ine gen shocks

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗subrout ine gen shocks ( n per iods , num shocks , mu cdf , &

P cdf , s im shock )

in t ege r , i n t e n t ( in ) : : n per iods , num shocks

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( num shocks ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : mu cdf

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( num shocks , num shocks ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : &

P cdf

in t ege r , dimension ( n pe r i od s ) , i n t e n t ( out ) : : s im shock

r e a l ( 8 ) , a l l o c a t a b l e , dimension ( : ) : : u

i n t e g e r : : t

! a l l o c a t e memory f o r u

a l l o c a t e (u( n pe r i od s ) )

! generate random v ar i a b l e s , which i s uni formly

! d i s t r i b u t e d [ 0 , 1 )

c a l l RANDOMNUMBER(u)

176

Page 178: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

! f i r s t c a l c u a l t e i n i t i a l type

s im shock (1 ) = ca lc markov shock f rom uni fo rm rv (u ( 1 ) , &

num shocks , mu cdf )

! now determine types f o r a l l f u tu r e pe r i od s

do t = 2 , n pe r i od s

s im shock ( t ) = ca lc markov shock f rom uni fo rm rv ( &

u( t ) , num shocks , P cdf ( s im shock ( t −1) , : ) )

end do

d e a l l o c a t e (u)

end subrout ine gen shocks

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗! f unc t i on ca l c markov shock f rom uni fo rm rv

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗f unc t i on ca l c markov shock f rom uni fo rm rv (u , n , P cdf )&

r e s u l t ( j )

i m p l i c i t none

r e a l ( 8 ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : u

in t ege r , i n t e n t ( in ) : : n

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension (n ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : P cdf

i n t e g e r : : j ! output

! l o c a l v a r i a b l e s

l o g i c a l : : done

done = . f a l s e .

j = 0

! u i s uni formly d i s t r i b u t e d over [ 0 , 1 )

! convert i t i n to an index f o r p ro duc t i v i t y

! us ing the cumulat ive p r o b a b i l i t y t r a n s i t i o n matrix

do whi l e ( . not . done )

j = j + 1 ;

! stop i f u < P cdf ( j )

177

Page 179: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

! u has to be l e s s than 1

! P cdf (n) == 1 , so even tua l l y t h i s w i l l be t rue

done = (u < P cdf ( j ) ) ;

end do

end func t i on ca l c markov shock f rom uni fo rm rv

end module sim module

178

Page 180: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

Listing A.4: Main Program: Driver for Iteration and Simulation

program corrupt ion mode l

use mode l too l s

use gr id module

use v f i module

use sim module

i m p l i c i t none

! Var i ab l e s

type ( params ) : : pm

r e a l ( 8 ) , a l l o c a t a b l e , dimension ( : ) : : b g r i d

! b g r id po in t s

r e a l ( 8 ) , a l l o c a t a b l e , dimension ( : ) : : y g r i d

! y g r id po in t s

r e a l ( 8 ) , a l l o c a t a b l e , dimension ( : , : ) : : Py

! prob t r a n s i t i o n matrix f o r y

r e a l ( 8 ) , a l l o c a t a b l e , dimension ( : , : ) : : Py cdf

! prob t r a n s i t i o n matrix f o r y , cd f

r e a l ( 8 ) , a l l o c a t a b l e , dimension ( : ) : : mu y

! inv d i s t r i b u t i o n f o r y

r e a l ( 8 ) , a l l o c a t a b l e , dimension ( : ) : : mu y cdf

! inv d i s t r i b u t i o n f o r y , cd f

r e a l ( 8 ) , a l l o c a t a b l e , dimension ( : , : ) : : Pt

! prob t r a n s i t i o n matrix , government type

r e a l ( 8 ) , a l l o c a t a b l e , dimension ( : , : ) : : Pt cd f

! prob t r a n s i t i o n matrix , government type , cd f

r e a l ( 8 ) , a l l o c a t a b l e , dimension ( : ) : : mu t

! inv d i s t r i b u t i o n f o r government type

r e a l ( 8 ) , a l l o c a t a b l e , dimension ( : ) : : mu t cdf

! inv d i s t r i b u t i o n f o r government type , cd f

r e a l ( 8 ) , a l l o c a t a b l e , dimension ( : , : , : , : ) : : q

! q (b ’ , y , d , type ) , q schedu le

r e a l ( 8 ) , a l l o c a t a b l e , dimension ( : , : , : , : ) : : p d

! p d (b ’ , y , h ’ , type ’ ) , d e f a u l t p r o b a b i l i t y

179

Page 181: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

i n t ege r , a l l o c a t a b l e , dimension ( : , : , : ) : : y s ta r

! y∗(b ’ , h ’ , type ’ ) , d e f a u l t t h r e s h o l d s

l o g i c a l , a l l o c a t a b l e , dimension ( : , : , : , : ) : : d p o l i c y

! d (b , y , h i s t , type ) , d e f a u l t p o l i c y

r e a l ( 8 ) , a l l o c a t a b l e , dimension ( : , : , : , : ) : : c p o l i c y

! c (b , y , h i s t , type ) , consumption p o l i c y

r e a l ( 8 ) , a l l o c a t a b l e , dimension ( : , : , : , : ) : : bn po l i cy

! b ’ ( b , y , h i s t , type ) , debt p o l i c y

in t ege r , a l l o c a t a b l e , dimension ( : , : , : , : ) : : b n i d x p o l i c y

! b ’ ( b , y , h i s t , type ) , debt p o l i c y ( index )

i n t e g e r : : n b , n y

!%%%%% Load parameters

! load parameters

c a l l l oad parameter s (” input params . txt ” , pm)

n b = pm%n b

n y = pm%n y

! save parameters i n to a format that w i l l be e a s i e r . .

! to read in Matlab

c a l l save parameters (pm)

!%%%%% Al lo ca t e memory

! to avoid memory problems , a r rays made a l l o c a t a b l e . . .

! and memory e x p l i c i t l y a l l o c a t e d

a l l o c a t e ( b g r i d ( n b ) , y g r i d ( n y ) )

a l l o c a t e ( Py( n y , n y ) , Py cdf ( n y , n y ) , mu y( n y ) ,&

mu y cdf ( n y ) )

a l l o c a t e ( Pt ( 2 , 2 ) , Pt cd f ( 2 , 2 ) , mu t ( 2 ) , mu t cdf (2 ) )

a l l o c a t e ( q ( n b , n y , 2 , 2 ) , p d ( n b , n y , 2 , 2 ) , d p o l i c y&

( n b ,&n y , 2 , 2 ) , c p o l i c y ( n b , n y , 2 , 2 ) )

a l l o c a t e ( bn po l i cy ( n b , n y , 2 , 2 ) , b n i d x p o l i c y ( n b ,&

n y , 2 , 2 ) )

a l l o c a t e ( y s ta r ( n b , 2 , 2 ) )

!%%%%% Construct g r i d s

180

Page 182: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

c a l l c o n s t r u c t g r i d s (pm, b gr id , y gr id , Py , Py cdf ,&

mu y , mu y cdf , Pt , Pt cdf , mu t , mu t cdf )

p r i n t ∗ , ”∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗”p r i n t ∗ , ”Value Function I t e r a t i o n ”

p r i n t ∗ , ”∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗”

!%%%%% Value Function I t e r a t i o n

c a l l v a l f c n i t e r ( n b , n y , b gr id , y gr id , Py , Py cdf ,&

pm, q , p d , ystar , d po l i cy , c p o l i c y , bn po l i cy , &

b n i d x p o l i c y )

p r i n t ∗ , ”∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗”p r i n t ∗ , ” S imulat ion ”

p r i n t ∗ , ”∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗”

!%%%%% Simulat ion

c a l l s imulate ( n b , n y , b gr id , y gr id , Py cdf ,&

mu y cdf , Pt , Pt cdf , mu t cdf , q , p d , d po l i cy ,&

c p o l i c y , bn po l i cy , bn idx po l i cy , pm)

p r i n t ∗ , ”∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗”p r i n t ∗ , ”Program Done”

p r i n t ∗ , ”∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗”

end program corrupt ion mode l

181

Page 183: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

Listing A.5: Grid Construction

module gr id module

use mode l too l s

use a r r a y t o o l s

i m p l i c i t none

conta in s

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗! subrout ine c o n s t r u c t g r i d s

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗subrout ine c o n s t r u c t g r i d s (pm, b gr id , y gr id , Py , &

Py cdf , mu y , mu y cdf , Pt , Pt cdf , mu t , mu t cdf )

i m p l i c i t none

type ( params ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : pm

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension (pm%n b ) , i n t e n t ( out ) : : b g r i d

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension (pm%n y ) , i n t e n t ( out ) : : y g r i d

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension (pm%n y ,pm%n y ) , i n t e n t ( out ) : : Py

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension (pm%n y ,pm%n y ) , i n t e n t ( out ) : : Py cdf

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension (pm%n y ) , i n t e n t ( out ) : : mu y

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension (pm%n y ) , i n t e n t ( out ) : : mu y cdf

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( 2 , 2 ) , i n t e n t ( out ) : : Pt

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( 2 , 2 ) , i n t e n t ( out ) : : Pt cd f

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( 2 ) , i n t e n t ( out ) : : mu t

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( 2 ) , i n t e n t ( out ) : : mu t cdf

! l o c a l a r rays

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension (pm%n y−1) : : y mid

! l o c a l v a r i a b l e s

i n t e g e r : : n b , n y

i n t e g e r : : i , j

r e a l (8 ) : : y mean

! need to d e c l a r e alnorm func t i on ( conta ined in asa066 . f90 )

r e a l (8 ) : : alnorm ! c a l c u l a t e s normal cd f

182

Page 184: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗

! get number o f g r i d dpo ints

n b = pm%n b

n y = pm%n y

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗! c on s t ruc t g r id po in t s f o r a s s e t s

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗c a l l expspace ( n b , pm%b sca l e , pm%b min , pm%b max , b g r i d )

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗! c on s t ruc t g r id po in t s f o r endowment , y

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗

c a l l l i n s p a c e ( n y , pm%y min , pm%y max , y g r i d ) ;

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗! c on s t ruc t tauchen approximation f o r endowment proce s s

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗

! c on s t ruc t midpoint o f g r id po in t s

do i = 1 , n y−1

y mid ( i ) = 0 . 5∗ ( y g r i d ( i ) + y g r i d ( i +1))

end do

! cons t ruc t Tauchen approximation f o r p r o b a b i l i t y . .

! t r a n s i t i o n matrix

do i = 1 , n y

! mean o f endowment proce s s

y mean = (1−pm%rho )∗pm%mean y + pm%rho ∗ y g r i d ( i )

! us ing f a l s e input , alnorm re tu rn s normal cd f

Py( i , 1 ) = alnorm ( ( y mid (1 ) − y mean ) / pm%sigma e &

, . f a l s e . ) ;

! us ing t rue input , alnorm re tu rn s 1 − cd f

183

Page 185: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

Py( i , n y ) = alnorm ( ( y mid ( n y−1) − y mean ) / pm%sigma e&

, . t rue . ) ;

! compute p r o b a b i l i t i e s f o r remaining g r id po in t s

do j = 2 , n y−1

Py( i , j ) = alnorm ( ( y mid ( j ) − y mean )/pm%sigma e , &

. f a l s e . ) − alnorm ( ( y mid ( j−1) − y mean)/&

pm%sigma e , . f a l s e . )

end do

end do

! cons t ruc t cd f f o r p r o b a b i l i t y t r a n s i t i o n matrix

Py cdf = cumsum( Py , dim=2 )

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗! c on s t ruc t i n v a r i a n t d i s t r i b u t i o n f o r y

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗c a l l c a l c i n v d i s t ( n y , Py , mu y , mu y cdf )

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗! c on s t ruc t p r o b a b i l i t y t r a n s i t i o n matrix f o r

! the type o f government

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗

! c on s t ruc t p r o b a b i l i t y t r a n s i t i o n matrix

Pt (1 , 1 ) = 1−pm%piL / 0 . 9 ; Pt (1 , 2 ) = pm%piL / 0 . 9 ;

Pt (2 , 1 ) = pm%piH / 0 . 4 ; Pt (2 , 2 ) = 1−pm%piH / 0 . 4 ;

! c ons t ruc t cd f f o r prob t r a n s i t i o n matrix

Pt cd f = cumsum( Pt , dim=2 )

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗! c on s t ruc t i n v a r i a n t d i s t r i b u t i o n f o r

! government types

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗c a l l c a l c i n v d i s t (2 , Pt , mu t , mu t cdf )

end subrout ine c o n s t r u c t g r i d s

184

Page 186: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗! subrout ine c a l c i n v d i s t

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗! Compute i n v a r i a n t d i s t r i b u t i o n o f z ’ by i t e r a t i n g on . .

! p r o b a b i l i t y

! t r a n s i t i o n matrix u n t i l convergence .

! Could a l t e r n a t i v e l y c a l c u l a t e t h i s by computing the . .

! e i g e n v e c t o r s

! o f the p r o b a b i l i t y t r a n s i t i o n matrix .

subrout ine c a l c i n v d i s t (n , P, mu, mu cdf )

i m p l i c i t none

in t ege r , i n t e n t ( in ) : : n ! number o f g r id po in t s

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension (n , n ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : P

! t r a n s i t i o n matrix

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension (n ) , i n t e n t ( out ) : : mu

! i n v a r i a n t d i s t r i b u t i o n

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension (n ) , i n t e n t ( out ) : : mu cdf

! cd f o f i n v a r i a n t d i s t r i b u t i o n

r e a l ( 8 ) , parameter : : TOL = 1.0 e−12

in t ege r , parameter : : MAX ITER = 1000

r e a l (8 ) : : e r r

i n t e g e r : : j , i t e r

l o g i c a l : : done

! l o c a l array

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension (n) : : mu0

! s o l v e f o r i n v a r i a n t d i s t r i b u t i o n by i t e r a t i n g

! u n t i l i t converges

mu0 = 1 .0

i t e r = 0 ;

done = . f a l s e .

do whi l e ( . not . done )

! compute next per iod ’ s d i s t r i b u t i o n

mu = matmul ( t ranspose (P) , mu0 ) ;

185

Page 187: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

! compute convergence e r r o r

e r r = maxval ( abs ( (mu − mu0) / mu0 ) , dim=1 )

! stop i f e r r o r has s u f f i c i e n t l y converged

i f ( e r r < TOL) then

done = . t rue .

end i f

! s top i f maximum i t e r a t i o n s reached

i t e r = i t e r + 1 ;

i f ( i t e r >= MAX ITER) then

done = . t rue .

end i f

! update i n i t i a l d i s t r i b u t i o n

mu0 = mu;

end do

! normal ize d i s t r i b u t i o n

mu = mu / sum(mu)

! Now compute cd f

mu cdf = cumsum(mu)

end subrout ine c a l c i n v d i s t

end module gr id module

186

Page 188: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

Listing A.6: Model Tools

module mode l too l s

use data output

i m p l i c i t none

! Def ine s t r u c t u r e to hold parameters

type params

i n t e g e r : : n b

! number o f debt g r id po in t s

i n t e g e r : : n y

! number o f output g r id po in t s

i n t e g e r : : n samples

! number o f samples in s imu la t i on

i n t e g e r : : n pe r i od s

! number o f pe r i od s f o r each sample in s imu la t i on

r e a l (8 ) : : beta ! d i s count f a c t o r

r e a l (8 ) : : sigma ! r i s k ave r s i on

r e a l (8 ) : : r ! r i s k f r e e ra t e

r e a l (8 ) : : rho ! p e r s i s t e n c e o f output

r e a l (8 ) : : s igma e

! std dev o f innovat ion to output

r e a l (8 ) : : lambda ! output l o s s in d e f a u l t

r e a l (8 ) : : tauL ! l e s s cor rupt type , tax

r e a l (8 ) : : tauH ! more corrupt type , tax

r e a l (8 ) : : piL

! p r o b a b i l i t y o f turnover , l e s s cor rupt type

r e a l (8 ) : : piH

! p r o b a b i l i t y o f turnover , more corrupt type

r e a l (8 ) : : b min ! minimum a s s e t l e v e l

r e a l (8 ) : : b max ! maximum a s s e t l e v e l

r e a l (8 ) : : b s c a l e

! c o n t r o l s i n t e r v a l between a s s e t g r id po in t s

r e a l (8 ) : : y width

! ln y in [ mean − width ∗ sd y , mean + width ∗ sd y ]

187

Page 189: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

l o g i c a l : : new v0

! i f = 1 , i n i t i a l i z e va l f c n s to 0 , o therwi s e . . .

! load from f i l e s

! de r ived parameters

r e a l (8 ) : : mean y ! mean o f y

r e a l (8 ) : : sd y ! standard dev i a t i on o f y

r e a l (8 ) : : y min

r e a l (8 ) : : y max

end type params

conta in s

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗! subrout ine load parameter s

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗subrout ine load parameter s ( f i l ename , pm)

i m p l i c i t none

cha rac t e r ( l en =∗) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : f i l ename

type ( params ) , i n t e n t ( out ) : : pm

! l o c a l v a r i a b l e s

i n t e g e r : : i n f i l e , new v0 int

i n f i l e = 54

open ( i n f i l e , f i l e = f i l ename )

read ( i n f i l e , ∗ ) pm%n b

read ( i n f i l e , ∗ ) pm%n y

read ( i n f i l e , ∗ ) pm%n samples

read ( i n f i l e , ∗ ) pm%n per i od s

read ( i n f i l e , ∗ ) pm%beta

read ( i n f i l e , ∗ ) pm%sigma

read ( i n f i l e , ∗ ) pm%r

read ( i n f i l e , ∗ ) pm%rho

188

Page 190: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

read ( i n f i l e , ∗ ) pm%sigma e

read ( i n f i l e , ∗ ) pm%lambda

read ( i n f i l e , ∗ ) pm%tauL

read ( i n f i l e , ∗ ) pm%tauH

read ( i n f i l e , ∗ ) pm%piL

read ( i n f i l e , ∗ ) pm%piH

read ( i n f i l e , ∗ ) pm%b min

read ( i n f i l e , ∗ ) pm%b max

read ( i n f i l e , ∗ ) pm%b s c a l e

read ( i n f i l e , ∗ ) pm%y width

read ( i n f i l e , ∗ ) new v0 int

rewind ( i n f i l e )

c l o s e ( i n f i l e )

! de r ived parameters

pm%sd y = pm%sigma e / s q r t ( 1 − pm%rho ∗∗2 )

! mean o f y :

! y ’ = (1−rho )∗mean y + rho∗ y + eps

pm%mean y = −0.5 ∗ pm%sigma e ∗∗2

! l i m i t s f o r endowment g r id

pm%y min = pm%mean y − pm%y width ∗ pm%sd y

pm%y max = pm%mean y + pm%y width ∗ pm%sd y

i f ( new v0 int > 0) then

pm%new v0 = . t rue .

e l s e

pm%new v0 = . f a l s e .

end i f

end subrout ine load parameter s

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗! subrout ine save parameters

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗subrout ine save parameters (pm)

i m p l i c i t none

189

Page 191: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

type ( params ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : pm

! l o c a l v a r i a b l e s

i n t e g e r : : param out = 37

! save paramters

c a l l o p e n d a t a f i l e ( param out , ” r e s u l t s /params . txt ” ) ;

c a l l s a v e s c a l a r ( param out , ”n b ” , pm%n b )

c a l l s a v e s c a l a r ( param out , ”n y ” , pm%n y )

c a l l s a v e s c a l a r ( param out , ” n samples ” , pm%n samples )

c a l l s a v e s c a l a r ( param out , ” n pe r i od s ” , pm%n pe r i od s )

c a l l s a v e s c a l a r ( param out , ” beta ” , pm%beta )

c a l l s a v e s c a l a r ( param out , ” sigma ” , pm%sigma )

c a l l s a v e s c a l a r ( param out , ” r ” , pm%r )

c a l l s a v e s c a l a r ( param out , ” rho ” , pm%rho )

c a l l s a v e s c a l a r ( param out , ” s igma e ” , pm%sigma e )

c a l l s a v e s c a l a r ( param out , ”lambda ” , pm%lambda )

c a l l s a v e s c a l a r ( param out , ”tauL ” , pm%tauL )

c a l l s a v e s c a l a r ( param out , ”tauH ” , pm%tauH )

c a l l s a v e s c a l a r ( param out , ”piL ” , pm%piL )

c a l l s a v e s c a l a r ( param out , ”piH ” , pm%piH )

c a l l s a v e s c a l a r ( param out , ”b min ” , pm%b min )

c a l l s a v e s c a l a r ( param out , ”b max ” , pm%b max )

c a l l s a v e s c a l a r ( param out , ” y width ” , pm%y width )

c a l l s a v e s c a l a r ( param out , ”mean y ” , pm%mean y )

c a l l s a v e s c a l a r ( param out , ” sd y ” , pm%sd y )

c a l l s a v e s c a l a r ( param out , ”y min ” , pm%y min )

c a l l s a v e s c a l a r ( param out , ”y max ” , pm%y max )

c a l l c l o s e d a t a f i l e ( param out )

end subrout ine

end module mode l too l s

190

Page 192: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

Listing A.7: Data Output

module data output

i m p l i c i t none

i n t e r f a c e s a v e s c a l a r

module procedure s a v e s c a l a r d o u b l e , s a v e s c a l a r i n t ,&

s a v e s c a l a r l o g i c a l

end i n t e r f a c e

i n t e r f a c e save a r ray 1d

module procedure save ar ray 1d doub le , &

s a v e a r r a y 1 d i n t , s a v e a r r a y 1 d l o g i c a l

end i n t e r f a c e

i n t e r f a c e save a r ray 2d

module procedure save ar ray 2d doub le , &

s a v e a r r a y 2 d i n t , s a v e a r r a y 2 d l o g i c a l

end i n t e r f a c e

i n t e r f a c e save a r ray 3d

module procedure save ar ray 3d doub le , s a v e a r r a y 3 d i n t ,&

s a v e a r r a y 3 d l o g i c a l

end i n t e r f a c e

i n t e r f a c e save a r ray 4d

module procedure save ar ray 4d doub le , s a v e a r r a y 4 d i n t ,&

s a v e a r r a y 4 d l o g i c a l

end i n t e r f a c e

conta in s

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗! subrout ine o p e n d a t a f i l e

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗! choose any i n t e g e r f o r ou t un i t > 0 , except 6?

subrout ine o p e n d a t a f i l e ( out un i t , f i l ename )

191

Page 193: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

i n t ege r , i n t e n t ( in ) : : ou t un i t

cha rac t e r ( l en =∗) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : f i l ename

open ( un i t=out uni t , f i l e=f i l ename , ac t i on=”wr i t e ” , s t a t u s=&

” r e p l a c e ”)

end subrout ine o p e n d a t a f i l e

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗! subrout ine c l o s e d a t a f i l e

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗subrout ine c l o s e d a t a f i l e ( ou t un i t )

i m p l i c i t none

in t ege r , i n t e n t ( in ) : : ou t un i t

c l o s e ( ou t un i t )

end subrout ine c l o s e d a t a f i l e

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗! subrout ine s a v e s c a l a r d o u b l e

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗i m p l i c i t none

in t ege r , i n t e n t ( in ) : : ou t un i t

cha rac t e r ( l en =∗) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : name

r e a l ( 8 ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : va l

! r ecord d e t a i l s o f v a r i a b l e

! name , # o f dimensions , 1 x 1 array ( i . e . , s c a l a r )

wr i t e ( out un i t , ∗ ) name , ” 2 1 1”

! save value to f i l e

wr i t e ( out un i t , ∗ ) va l

! add an extra space

wr i t e ( out un i t , ∗ ) ””

192

Page 194: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

end subrout ine s a v e s c a l a r d o u b l e

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗! subrout ine s a v e s c a l a r i n t

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗subrout ine s a v e s c a l a r i n t ( out un i t , name , va l )

i m p l i c i t none

in t ege r , i n t e n t ( in ) : : ou t un i t

cha rac t e r ( l en =∗) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : name

in t ege r , i n t e n t ( in ) : : va l

! r ecord d e t a i l s o f v a r i a b l e

! name , # o f dimensions , 1 x 1 array ( i . e . , s c a l a r )

wr i t e ( out un i t , ∗ ) name , ” 2 1 1”

! save value to f i l e

wr i t e ( out un i t , ∗ ) va l

! add an extra space

wr i t e ( out un i t , ∗ ) ””

end subrout ine s a v e s c a l a r i n t

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗! subrout ine s a v e s c a l a r l o g i c a l

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗subrout ine s a v e s c a l a r l o g i c a l ( out un i t , name , va l )

i m p l i c i t none

in t ege r , i n t e n t ( in ) : : ou t un i t

cha rac t e r ( l en =∗) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : name

l o g i c a l , i n t e n t ( in ) : : va l

i n t e g e r : : va l ou t

! convert va lue to i n t e g e r

i f ( va l ) then

va l ou t = 1

e l s e

193

Page 195: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

va l ou t = 0

end i f

! r ecord d e t a i l s o f v a r i a b l e

! name , # o f dimensions , 1 x 1 array ( i . e . , s c a l a r )

wr i t e ( out un i t , ∗ ) name , ” 2 1 1”

! save value to f i l e

wr i t e ( out un i t , ∗ ) va l ou t

! add an extra space

wr i t e ( out un i t , ∗ ) ””

end subrout ine s a v e s c a l a r l o g i c a l

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗! subrout ine save a r ray 1d doub l e

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗subrout ine save a r ray 1d doub l e ( out un i t , name , n , v a l s )

i m p l i c i t none

in t ege r , i n t e n t ( in ) : : ou t un i t

cha rac t e r ( l en =∗) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : name

in t ege r , i n t e n t ( in ) : : n

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension (n ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : v a l s

! r ecord d e t a i l s o f v a r i a b l e

! name , # o f dimensions , n x 1 vec to r

wr i t e ( out un i t , ∗ ) name , ” 2 ” , n , ” 1”

! save array to f i l e

wr i t e ( out un i t , ∗ ) v a l s

! add an extra space

wr i t e ( out un i t , ∗ ) ””

end subrout ine save a r ray 1d doub l e

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗

194

Page 196: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

! subrout ine s a v e a r r a y 1 d i n t

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗subrout ine s a v e a r r a y 1 d i n t ( out un i t , name , n , v a l s )

i m p l i c i t none

in t ege r , i n t e n t ( in ) : : ou t un i t

cha rac t e r ( l en =∗) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : name

in t ege r , i n t e n t ( in ) : : n

in t ege r , dimension (n ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : v a l s

! r ecord d e t a i l s o f v a r i a b l e

! name , # o f dimensions , n x 1 vec to r

wr i t e ( out un i t , ∗ ) name , ” 2 ” , n , ” 1”

! save array to f i l e

wr i t e ( out un i t , ∗ ) v a l s

! add an extra space

wr i t e ( out un i t , ∗ ) ””

end subrout ine s a v e a r r a y 1 d i n t

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗! subrout ine s a v e a r r a y 1 d l o g i c a l

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗subrout ine s a v e a r r a y 1 d l o g i c a l ( out un i t , name , n , v a l s )

i m p l i c i t none

in t ege r , i n t e n t ( in ) : : ou t un i t

cha rac t e r ( l en =∗) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : name

in t ege r , i n t e n t ( in ) : : n

l o g i c a l , dimension (n ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : v a l s

i n t ege r , a l l o c a t a b l e , dimension ( : ) : : v a l s o u t

i n t e g e r : : i

a l l o c a t e ( v a l s o u t (n ) )

! convert to i n t e g e r s

195

Page 197: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

! where cons t ruc t can cause s tack over f l ow ? !

! where ( v a l s )

! v a l s o u t = 1

! e l s ewhere

! v a l s o u t = 0

! end where

do i = 1 ,n

i f ( v a l s ( i ) ) then

v a l s o u t ( i ) = 1

e l s e

v a l s o u t ( i ) = 0

end i f

end do

! record d e t a i l s o f v a r i a b l e

! name , # o f dimensions , n x 1 vec to r

wr i t e ( out un i t , ∗ ) name , ” 2 ” , n , ” 1”

! save array to f i l e

wr i t e ( out un i t , ∗ ) v a l s o u t

! add an extra space

wr i t e ( out un i t , ∗ ) ””

d e a l l o c a t e ( v a l s o u t )

end subrout ine s a v e a r r a y 1 d l o g i c a l

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗! subrout ine save a r ray 2d doub l e

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗subrout ine save a r ray 2d doub l e ( out un i t , name , n1 , n2 ,&

v a l s )

i m p l i c i t none

in t ege r , i n t e n t ( in ) : : ou t un i t

cha rac t e r ( l en =∗) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : name

in t ege r , i n t e n t ( in ) : : n1

196

Page 198: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

i n t ege r , i n t e n t ( in ) : : n2

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( n1 , n2 ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : v a l s

! r ecord d e t a i l s o f v a r i a b l e

! name , # o f dimensions , n1 x n2 array

wr i t e ( out un i t , ∗ ) name , ” 2 ” , n1 , n2

! save array to f i l e

wr i t e ( out un i t , ∗ ) v a l s

! add an extra space

wr i t e ( out un i t , ∗ ) ””

end subrout ine save a r ray 2d doub l e

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗! subrout ine s a v e a r r a y 2 d i n t

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗subrout ine s a v e a r r a y 2 d i n t ( out un i t , name , n1 , n2 ,&

v a l s )

i m p l i c i t none

in t ege r , i n t e n t ( in ) : : ou t un i t

cha rac t e r ( l en =∗) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : name

in t ege r , i n t e n t ( in ) : : n1

in t ege r , i n t e n t ( in ) : : n2

in t ege r , dimension ( n1 , n2 ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : v a l s

! r ecord d e t a i l s o f v a r i a b l e

! name , # o f dimensions , n1 x n2 array

wr i t e ( out un i t , ∗ ) name , ” 2 ” , n1 , n2

! save array to f i l e

wr i t e ( out un i t , ∗ ) v a l s

! add an extra space

wr i t e ( out un i t , ∗ ) ””

end subrout ine s a v e a r r a y 2 d i n t

197

Page 199: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗! subrout ine s a v e a r r a y 2 d l o g i c a l

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗subrout ine s a v e a r r a y 2 d l o g i c a l ( out un i t , name , n1 , &

n2 , v a l s )

i m p l i c i t none

in t ege r , i n t e n t ( in ) : : ou t un i t

cha rac t e r ( l en =∗) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : name

in t ege r , i n t e n t ( in ) : : n1

in t ege r , i n t e n t ( in ) : : n2

l o g i c a l , dimension ( n1 , n2 ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : v a l s

i n t ege r , a l l o c a t a b l e , dimension ( : , : ) : : v a l s o u t

i n t e g e r : : i1 , i 2

a l l o c a t e ( v a l s o u t ( n1 , n2 ) )

! convert to i n t e g e r s

! where cons t ruc t caus ing s tack over f l ow ? !

! where ( v a l s )

! v a l s o u t = 1

! e l s ewhere

! v a l s o u t = 0

! end where

do i 2 = 1 , n2

do i 1 = 1 , n1

i f ( v a l s ( i1 , i 2 ) ) then

v a l s o u t ( i1 , i 2 ) = 1

e l s e

v a l s o u t ( i1 , i 2 ) = 0

end i f

end do

end do

! record d e t a i l s o f v a r i a b l e

! name , # o f dimensions , n1 x n2 array

198

Page 200: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

wr i t e ( out un i t , ∗ ) name , ” 2 ” , n1 , n2

! save array to f i l e

wr i t e ( out un i t , ∗ ) v a l s o u t

! add an extra space

wr i t e ( out un i t , ∗ ) ””

d e a l l o c a t e ( v a l s o u t )

end subrout ine s a v e a r r a y 2 d l o g i c a l

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗! subrout ine save a r ray 3d doub l e

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗subrout ine save a r ray 3d doub l e ( out un i t , name , n1 , n2 ,&

n3 , v a l s )

i m p l i c i t none

in t ege r , i n t e n t ( in ) : : ou t un i t

cha rac t e r ( l en =∗) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : name

in t ege r , i n t e n t ( in ) : : n1

in t ege r , i n t e n t ( in ) : : n2

in t ege r , i n t e n t ( in ) : : n3

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( n1 , n2 , n3 ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : v a l s

! r ecord d e t a i l s o f v a r i a b l e

! name , # o f dimensions , n1 x n2 x n3 array

wr i t e ( out un i t , ∗ ) name , ” 3 ” , n1 , n2 , n3

! save array to f i l e

wr i t e ( out un i t , ∗ ) v a l s

! add an extra space

wr i t e ( out un i t , ∗ ) ””

end subrout ine save a r ray 3d doub l e

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗

199

Page 201: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

! subrout ine s a v e a r r a y 3 d i n t

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗subrout ine s a v e a r r a y 3 d i n t ( out un i t , name , n1 , n2 , &

n3 , v a l s )

i m p l i c i t none

in t ege r , i n t e n t ( in ) : : ou t un i t

cha rac t e r ( l en =∗) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : name

in t ege r , i n t e n t ( in ) : : n1

in t ege r , i n t e n t ( in ) : : n2

in t ege r , i n t e n t ( in ) : : n3

in t ege r , dimension ( n1 , n2 , n3 ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : v a l s

! r ecord d e t a i l s o f v a r i a b l e

! name , # o f dimensions , n1 x n2 x n3 array

wr i t e ( out un i t , ∗ ) name , ” 3 ” , n1 , n2 , n3

! save array to f i l e

wr i t e ( out un i t , ∗ ) v a l s

! add an extra space

wr i t e ( out un i t , ∗ ) ””

end subrout ine s a v e a r r a y 3 d i n t

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗! subrout ine s a v e a r r a y 3 d l o g i c a l

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗subrout ine s a v e a r r a y 3 d l o g i c a l ( out un i t , name , n1 , n2 , &

n3 , v a l s )

i m p l i c i t none

in t ege r , i n t e n t ( in ) : : ou t un i t

cha rac t e r ( l en =∗) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : name

in t ege r , i n t e n t ( in ) : : n1

in t ege r , i n t e n t ( in ) : : n2

in t ege r , i n t e n t ( in ) : : n3

l o g i c a l , dimension ( n1 , n2 , n3 ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : v a l s

200

Page 202: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

i n t ege r , a l l o c a t a b l e , dimension ( : , : , : ) : : v a l s o u t

i n t e g e r : : i1 , i2 , i 3

a l l o c a t e ( v a l s o u t ( n1 , n2 , n3 ) )

! convert to i n t e g e r s

! where cons t ruc t caus ing s tack over f l ow ? !

! where ( v a l s )

! v a l s o u t = 1

! e l s ewhere

! v a l s o u t = 0

! end where

do i 3 = 1 , n3

do i 2 = 1 , n2

do i 1 = 1 , n1

i f ( v a l s ( i1 , i2 , i 3 ) ) then

v a l s o u t ( i1 , i2 , i 3 ) = 1

e l s e

v a l s o u t ( i1 , i2 , i 3 ) = 0

end i f

end do

end do

end do

! record d e t a i l s o f v a r i a b l e

! name , # o f dimensions , n1 x n2 x n3 array

wr i t e ( out un i t , ∗ ) name , ” 3 ” , n1 , n2 , n3

! save array to f i l e

wr i t e ( out un i t , ∗ ) v a l s o u t

! add an extra space

wr i t e ( out un i t , ∗ ) ””

d e a l l o c a t e ( v a l s o u t )

end subrout ine s a v e a r r a y 3 d l o g i c a l

201

Page 203: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗! subrout ine save a r ray 4d doub l e

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗subrout ine save a r ray 4d doub l e ( out un i t , name , n1 , n2 ,&

n3 , n4 , v a l s )

i m p l i c i t none

in t ege r , i n t e n t ( in ) : : ou t un i t

cha rac t e r ( l en =∗) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : name

in t ege r , i n t e n t ( in ) : : n1

in t ege r , i n t e n t ( in ) : : n2

in t ege r , i n t e n t ( in ) : : n3

in t ege r , i n t e n t ( in ) : : n4

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( n1 , n2 , n3 , n4 ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : v a l s

! r ecord d e t a i l s o f v a r i a b l e

! name , # o f dimensions , n1 x n2 x n3 x n4 array

wr i t e ( out un i t , ∗ ) name , ” 4 ” , n1 , n2 , n3 , n4

! save array to f i l e

wr i t e ( out un i t , ∗ ) v a l s

! add an extra space

wr i t e ( out un i t , ∗ ) ””

end subrout ine save a r ray 4d doub l e

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗! subrout ine s a v e a r r a y 4 d i n t

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗subrout ine s a v e a r r a y 4 d i n t ( out un i t , name , n1 , n2 ,&

n3 , n4 , v a l s )

i m p l i c i t none

in t ege r , i n t e n t ( in ) : : ou t un i t

cha rac t e r ( l en =∗) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : name

in t ege r , i n t e n t ( in ) : : n1

in t ege r , i n t e n t ( in ) : : n2

in t ege r , i n t e n t ( in ) : : n3

202

Page 204: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

i n t ege r , i n t e n t ( in ) : : n4

in t ege r , dimension ( n1 , n2 , n3 , n4 ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : v a l s

! r ecord d e t a i l s o f v a r i a b l e

! name , # o f dimensions , n1 x n2 x n3 x n4 array

wr i t e ( out un i t , ∗ ) name , ” 4 ” , n1 , n2 , n3 , n4

! save array to f i l e

wr i t e ( out un i t , ∗ ) v a l s

! add an extra space

wr i t e ( out un i t , ∗ ) ””

end subrout ine s a v e a r r a y 4 d i n t

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗! subrout ine s a v e a r r a y 4 d l o g i c a l

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗subrout ine s a v e a r r a y 4 d l o g i c a l ( out un i t , name , n1 , n2 ,&

n3 , n4 , v a l s )

i m p l i c i t none

in t ege r , i n t e n t ( in ) : : ou t un i t

cha rac t e r ( l en =∗) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : name

in t ege r , i n t e n t ( in ) : : n1

in t ege r , i n t e n t ( in ) : : n2

in t ege r , i n t e n t ( in ) : : n3

in t ege r , i n t e n t ( in ) : : n4

l o g i c a l , dimension ( n1 , n2 , n3 , n4 ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : v a l s

i n t ege r , a l l o c a t a b l e , dimension ( : , : , : , : ) : : v a l s o u t

i n t e g e r : : i1 , i2 , i3 , i 4

a l l o c a t e ( v a l s o u t ( n1 , n2 , n3 , n4 ) )

! convert to i n t e g e r s

! where cons t ruc t caus ing s tack over f l ow ?

! where ( v a l s )

! v a l s o u t = 1

203

Page 205: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

! e l s ewhere

! v a l s o u t = 0

! end where

do i 4 = 1 , n4

do i 3 = 1 , n3

do i 2 = 1 , n2

do i 1 = 1 , n1

i f ( v a l s ( i1 , i2 , i3 , i 4 ) ) then

v a l s o u t ( i1 , i2 , i3 , i 4 ) = 1

e l s e

v a l s o u t ( i1 , i2 , i3 , i 4 ) = 0

end i f

end do

end do

end do

end do

! record d e t a i l s o f v a r i a b l e

! name , # o f dimensions , n1 x n2 x n3 x n4 array

wr i t e ( out un i t , ∗ ) name , ” 4 ” , n1 , n2 , n3 , n4

! save array to f i l e

wr i t e ( out un i t , ∗ ) v a l s o u t

! add an extra space

wr i t e ( out un i t , ∗ ) ””

d e a l l o c a t e ( v a l s o u t )

end subrout ine s a v e a r r a y 4 d l o g i c a l

end module data output

204

Page 206: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

Listing A.8: Array Tools

module a r r a y t o o l s

i m p l i c i t none

i n t e r f a c e cumsum

module procedure cumsum matrix , cumsum vector

end i n t e r f a c e

conta in s

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗! subrout ine expspace

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗subrout ine expspace ( n x , x s ca l e , x min , x max , x vec )

i m p l i c i t none

in t ege r , i n t e n t ( in ) : : n x

r e a l ( 8 ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : x s ca l e , x min , x max

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( n x ) , i n t e n t ( out ) : : x vec

i n t e g e r : : i

r e a l (8 ) : : s t ep

!−−−−!

! c on s t ruc t g r id po in t s

s tep = ( x max − x min )/ r e a l ( n x−1, kind =8)∗∗ x s c a l e

do i =1,n x−1

x vec ( i ) = x min + step ∗( i −1)∗∗ x s c a l e ;

end do

x vec ( n x ) = x max

end subrout ine expspace

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗! subrout ine l i n s p a c e

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗

205

Page 207: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

subrout ine l i n s p a c e ( n x , x min , x max , x vec )

i m p l i c i t none

in t ege r , i n t e n t ( in ) : : n x

r e a l ( 8 ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : x min , x max

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( n x ) , i n t e n t ( out ) : : x vec

i n t e g e r : : i

r e a l (8 ) : : s t ep

!−−−−!

! c on s t ruc t g r id po in t s

s tep = ( x max − x min ) / ( ( n x−1))

do i =1,n x

x vec ( i ) = x min + step ∗( i −1);

end do

end subrout ine l i n s p a c e

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗! subrout ine cumsum matrix

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗! Cumsum computes the cumulat ive sum .

!

! After c a l l i n g B = cumsum(A, DIM=1)

!B w i l l conta in the cumulat ive sum of A along each column

! After c a l l i n g B = cumsum(A, DIM=2)

! B w i l l conta in the cumulat ive sum of A along each row

func t i on cumsum matrix (A, dim) r e s u l t (B)

i m p l i c i t none

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( : , : ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : A

in t ege r , i n t e n t ( in ) : : dim

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( s i z e (A, dim=1) , s i z e (A, dim=2)) : : B

i n t e g e r : : i , j

i n t e g e r : : M, N

r e a l (8 ) : : sum val

206

Page 208: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

! get dimensions o f A

M = s i z e (A, dim=1) ! number o f rows

N = s i z e (A, dim=2) ! number o f column

i f (dim == 1) then

! sum a c r o s s dimension 1 ( columns )

do j = 1 ,N

! i n i t i a l i z e cumulat ive sum

sum val = 0 . 0 ;

! loop a c r o s s each row o f C

do i = 1 ,M

sum val = sum val + A( i , j ) ;

B( i , j ) = sum val ;

end do

end do

e l s e i f ( dim == 2) then

! sum a c r o s s dimension 2 ( rows )

! loop a c r o s s each row o f C

do i = 1 ,M

! i n i t i a l i z e cumulat ive sum

sum val = 0 . 0 ;

! loop a c r o s s each column o f C

do j = 1 ,N

sum val = sum val + A( i , j ) ;

B( i , j ) = sum val ;

end do

end do

e l s e

! e r r o r

end i f

end func t i on cumsum matrix

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗

207

Page 209: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

! subrout ine cumsum vector

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗! Cumsum computes the cumulat ive sum .

!

! After c a l l i n g B = cumsum(A)

! B w i l l conta in the cumulat ive sum of A

func t i on cumsum vector (A) r e s u l t (B)

i m p l i c i t none

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( : ) , i n t e n t ( in ) : : A

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension ( s i z e (A) ) : : B

i n t e g e r : : i , N

! get dimensions o f A

N = s i z e (A) ! number o f e lements in A

! c a l c u l a t e cumulat ive sum

i f (N > 0) then

B(1) = A(1)

do i = 2 ,N

B( i ) = B( i −1) + A( i )

end do

end i f

end func t i on cumsum vector

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗! subrout ine s o r t

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗! So r t s an array ar r ( 1 : n ) in to ascending numerica l order , , ,

! us ing the Quicksort a lgor i thm . n i s input ; a r r i s r ep l aced . .

! on output by i t s so r t ed rearrangement .

! Parameters : M i s the s i z e o f subarrays so r t ed by s t r a i g h t

! i n s e r t i o n and NSTACK i s the r equ i r ed a u x i l i a r y s to rage .

! Adapted from Numerical Rec ipes in Fortran Book

subrout ine s o r t (n , a r r )

i m p l i c i t none

208

Page 210: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

i n t ege r , i n t e n t ( in ) : : n

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension (n) : : a r r

i n t ege r , parameter : : M = 7

int ege r , parameter : : NSTACK = 50

i n t e g e r : : i , i r , j , j s t ack , k , l

i n t ege r , dimension (NSTACK) : : i s t a c k

r e a l (8 ) : : a , temp

j s t a c k = 0

l = 1

i r = n

1 i f ( i r−l < M) then

do j = l +1, i r

a = ar r ( j )

do i = j −1, l ,−1

i f ( a r r ( i ) <= a ) goto 2

ar r ( i +1) = ar r ( i )

end do

i = l−1

2 ar r ( i +1) = a

end do

i f ( j s t a c k == 0) re turn

i r = i s t a c k ( j s t a c k )

l = i s t a c k ( j s tack −1)

j s t a c k = j s tack−2

e l s e

k = ( l+i r )/2

temp = arr ( k )

a r r ( k ) = ar r ( l +1)

a r r ( l +1) = temp

i f ( a r r ( l ) > ar r ( i r ) ) then

temp = arr ( l )

a r r ( l ) = ar r ( i r )

a r r ( i r ) = temp

end i f

i f ( a r r ( l +1) > ar r ( i r ) ) then

209

Page 211: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

temp = arr ( l +1)

a r r ( l +1) = ar r ( i r )

a r r ( i r ) = temp

end i f

i f ( a r r ( l ) > ar r ( l +1)) then

temp = arr ( l )

a r r ( l ) = ar r ( l +1)

a r r ( l +1) = temp

end i f

i = l+1

j = i r

a = ar r ( l +1)

3 cont inue

i = i+1

i f ( a r r ( i ) < a ) goto 3

4 cont inue

j = j−1

i f ( a r r ( j ) > a ) goto 4

i f ( j < i ) goto 5

temp = arr ( i )

a r r ( i ) = ar r ( j )

a r r ( j ) = temp

goto 3

5 ar r ( l +1) = ar r ( j )

a r r ( j ) = a

j s t a c k = j s t a c k + 2

i f ( j s t a c k > NSTACK) pause ’NSTACK too smal l in sort ’

i f ( i r−i+1 >= j−l ) then

i s t a c k ( j s t a c k ) = i r

i s t a c k ( j s tack −1) = i

i r = j−1

e l s e

i s t a c k ( j s t a c k ) = j−1

i s t a c k ( j s tack −1) = l

l = i

end i f

end i f

goto 1

end subrout ine s o r t

210

Page 212: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗! subrout ine so r t 2

!∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗∗! So r t s an array ar r ( 1 : n ) in to ascending order us ing

! Quicksort , whi l e making the cor re spond ing rearrangement

! o f the array brr ( 1 : n ) .

! Adapted from Numerical Rec ipes in Fortran Book

subrout ine so r t 2 (n , arr , brr )

i m p l i c i t none

in t ege r , i n t e n t ( in ) : : n

r e a l ( 8 ) , dimension (n) : : a r r

i n t ege r , dimension (n) : : brr

in t ege r , parameter : : M = 7

int ege r , parameter : : NSTACK = 50

i n t e g e r : : i , i r , j , j s t ack , k , l

i n t ege r , dimension (NSTACK) : : i s t a c k

r e a l (8 ) : : a , temp

i n t e g e r : : b , tempb

j s t a c k = 0

l = 1

i r = n

1 i f ( i r−l < M) then

do j = l +1, i r

a = ar r ( j )

b = brr ( j )

do i = j −1, l ,−1

i f ( a r r ( i ) <= a ) goto 2

ar r ( i +1) = ar r ( i )

brr ( i +1) = brr ( i )

end do

i = l−1

2 ar r ( i +1) = a

211

Page 213: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

brr ( i +1) = b

end do

i f ( j s t a c k == 0) re turn

i r = i s t a c k ( j s t a c k )

l = i s t a c k ( j s tack −1)

j s t a c k = j s tack−2

e l s e

k = ( l+i r )/2

temp = arr ( k )

a r r ( k ) = ar r ( l +1)

a r r ( l +1) = temp

tempb = brr ( k )

brr ( k ) = brr ( l +1)

brr ( l +1) = tempb

i f ( a r r ( l ) > ar r ( i r ) ) then

temp = arr ( l )

a r r ( l ) = ar r ( i r )

a r r ( i r ) = temp

tempb = brr ( l )

brr ( l ) = brr ( i r )

brr ( i r ) = tempb

end i f

i f ( a r r ( l +1) > ar r ( i r ) ) then

temp = arr ( l +1)

a r r ( l +1) = ar r ( i r )

a r r ( i r ) = temp

tempb = brr ( l +1)

brr ( l +1) = brr ( i r )

brr ( i r ) = tempb

end i f

i f ( a r r ( l ) > ar r ( l +1)) then

temp = arr ( l )

a r r ( l ) = ar r ( l +1)

a r r ( l +1) = temp

tempb = brr ( l )

brr ( l ) = brr ( l +1)

brr ( l +1) = tempb

end i f

i = l+1

212

Page 214: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

j = i r

a = ar r ( l +1)

b = brr ( l +1)

3 cont inue

i = i+1

i f ( a r r ( i ) < a ) goto 3

4 cont inue

j = j−1

i f ( a r r ( j ) > a ) goto 4

i f ( j < i ) goto 5

temp = arr ( i )

a r r ( i ) = ar r ( j )

a r r ( j ) = temp

tempb = brr ( i )

brr ( i ) = brr ( j )

brr ( j ) = tempb

goto 3

5 ar r ( l +1) = ar r ( j )

a r r ( j ) = a

brr ( l +1) = brr ( j )

brr ( j ) = b

j s t a c k = j s t a c k+2

i f ( j s t a c k > NSTACK) pause ’NSTACK too smal l in sort2 ’

i f ( i r−i+1 >= j−l ) then

i s t a c k ( j s t a c k ) = i r

i s t a c k ( j s tack −1) = i

i r = j−1

e l s e

i s t a c k ( j s t a c k ) = j−1

i s t a c k ( j s tack −1) = l

l = i

end i f

end i f

goto 1

end subrout ine so r t 2

end module a r r a y t o o l s

213

Page 215: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

Listing A.9: Input Parameters

200 n b % number o f a s s e t g r id po in t s

30 n y % number o f endowment g r id po in t s

1000 n samples % number o f samples in s imu la t i on

1500 n pe r i od s % number o f pe r i od s f o r each sample in

%s imu la t i on

0 .90 beta % di scount f a c t o r

2 . 0 sigma % r i s k ave r s i on

0 .01 r % r i s k f r e e ra t e

0 .95 rho % p e r s i s t e n c e o f output

0 .027 s igma e % std dev o f innovat ion to output

0 .083 lambda % output pena l ty i f d e f a u l t

0 .222222 tauL % tax rate , low type

0 .50 tauH % tax rate , high type

0 .040 piL % prob o f turnover , low type

0 .040 piH % prob o f turnover , high type

−0.12 b min % minimum a s s e t p o s i t i o n

0 .0 b max % maximum a s s e t p o s i t i o n

1 .0 b s c a l e % c o n t r o l s i n t e r v a l between a s s e t g r id

% po in t s

3 . 0 y width % range o f y = [ mean − y width∗ sd y ,

5 mean + y width∗ sd y ]

214

Page 216: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

0 new v0 % i f = 1 , i n i t i a l i z e va lue f u n c t i o n s

%with 0 , i f = 0 , i n i t i a l i z e va l

% gues s v ∗ . tx t f i l e s

215

Page 217: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

A.1.3 MATLAB CODES

These Matlab codes then use the data from the value function iteration and the

model simulation to do the various plots and estimation of statistics. The code

plot results statistics.m uses the Matlab function read data.m to import the data.

Listing A.10: Matlab Codes for plots and statistics

%SELECT 1000SAMPLES OF 32 PERIODS FROM 1500 PERIODS TO MATCH. .

% NIGERIA. No r e s t r i c t i o n on d e f a u l t

%This code c a l c u l a t e s the s t a t i s t i c s used in the second . . . . .

%chapter o f the t h e s i s

c l e a r a l l

c l o s e a l l

c l c

% get parameters

p = read data ( ’ params . txt ’ ) ;

% get va lue f u n c t i o n s and p o l i c y f u n c t i o n s

v = read data ( ’ v f i d a t a . txt ’ )

% get s imu la t i on data

d = read data ( ’ s im data . txt ’ )

fn = 0 ;

% value func t i on : v (b , y , h , type )

[ n b , n y , n h , n t ] = s i z e ( v . v ) ;

%samples and pe r i od s

[ n per iods , n sample ] = s i z e (d . sim b ) ;

%PLOT

fn = fn +1; f i g u r e ( fn ) ; c l f ;

i b 2 = round (0 . 5∗ n b ) ;

hold on

p lo t ( v . y gr id , −squeeze ( v . bn( i b2 , : , 1 , 1 ) ) , ’ b− ’ , ’ LineWidth ’ , 2 )

hold o f f

x l a b e l ( ’ endowment , l og y ’ )

216

Page 218: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

y l a b e l ( ’−b ’ ’ ’ )

t i t l e ( ’−b ’ ’ p o l i c y funct ion , h = 0 , low type ’ )

l e g = s p r i n t f ( ’ b = %f ’ , v . b g r i d ( i b 2 ) ) ;

l egend ( l e g )

% be f o r e computing s imu la t i on averages

% drop i n i t i a l 200 obs e rva t i on s f o r each sample

T0 = 200 ;

sim q = d . sim q (T0+1:end , : ) ;

sim pd = d . sim pd (T0+1:end , : ) ;

s im d = d . sim d (T0+1:end , : ) ;

s im type = d . s im type (T0+1:end , : ) ;

n pe r i od s = n pe r i od s − T0 ;

sim y = log (d . s im output (T0+1:end , : ) ) ;

sim bn = d . sim bn (T0+1:end , : ) ;

s im c = log (d . s im c (T0+1:end , : ) ) ;

%c a l c u l a t i n g trade balance

s im tau = ze ro s ( s i z e ( s im type ) ) ;

s im tau ( s im type == 1) = p . tauL ;

s im tau ( s im type == 2) = p . tauH ;

sim yy=(d . s im output (T0+1:end , : ) ) ;

s im cc=(d . s im c (T0+1:end , : ) ) ;

tb y = ((1− s im tau ) . ∗ sim yy − s im cc ) . / sim yy ;

%c a l c u l a t i n g spread

s im r = 1 ./ sim q − 1 ; % i n t e r e s t r a t e

cs = s im r − p . r ; % c r e d i t spread

%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%

%expected d e f a u l t from change in type

ch L to H de f au l t = ( s im type ( 1 : end−1 , : ) == 1 & sim type ( 2 : . . .

end , : ) == 2 & sim d ( 2 : end ,:)== 1 ) ;

ch L to H = ( s im type ( 1 : end−1 , : ) == 1 & sim type ( 2 : . . .

end , : ) == 2 ) ;

ch H to L de f au l t = ( s im type ( 1 : end−1 , : ) == 2 & sim type ( 2 : . . .

end , : ) == 1 & sim d ( 2 : end ,:)== 1 ) ;

ch H to L = ( s im type ( 1 : end−1 , : ) == 2 & sim type ( 2 : . . .

217

Page 219: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

end , : ) == 1 ) ;

num L to H defaults = sum(sum( ch L to H de f au l t ) ) ;

num L to H = sum(sum( ch L to H ) ) ;

L t o H d e f r a t e = num L to H defaults / num L to H

num H to L defaults = sum(sum( ch H to L de f au l t ) ) ;

num H to L = sum(sum( ch H to L ) ) ;

H t o L d e f r a t e = num H to L defaults / num H to L

%S e l e c t data when f o r only l e s s corrupt

f o r j =0:39

h=32;

f o r m=1:1000;

i f s im type ( j ∗h+1:( j +1)∗h ,m)==1

yolo L ( : ,m) =sim y ( j ∗h+1:( j +1)∗h ,m) ;

type L ( : ,m) =sim type ( j ∗h+1:( j +1)∗h ,m) ;

co lo L ( : ,m) =sim c ( j ∗h+1:( j +1)∗h ,m) ;

c s o l o L ( : ,m) =cs ( j ∗h+1:( j +1)∗h ,m) ;

tb yo lo L ( : ,m)=tb y ( j ∗h+1:( j +1)∗h ,m) ;

D L ( : ,m) =sim d ( j ∗h+1:( j +1)∗h ,m) ;

pd L ( : ,m) =sim pd ( j ∗h+1:( j +1)∗h ,m) ;

end

end

end

%S e l e c t data when f o r only more corrupt

f o r j =0:39

h=32;

f o r m=1:1000;

i f s im type ( j ∗h+1:( j +1)∗h ,m)==2

yolo H ( : ,m) =sim y ( j ∗h+1:( j +1)∗h ,m) ;

type H ( : ,m) =sim type ( j ∗h+1:( j +1)∗h ,m) ;

colo H ( : ,m) =sim c ( j ∗h+1:( j +1)∗h ,m) ;

cso lo H ( : ,m) =cs ( j ∗h+1:( j +1)∗h ,m) ;

tb yo lo H ( : ,m)=tb y ( j ∗h+1:( j +1)∗h ,m) ;

D H ( : ,m) =sim d ( j ∗h+1:( j +1)∗h ,m) ;

218

Page 220: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

pd H ( : ,m) =sim pd ( j ∗h+1:( j +1)∗h ,m) ;

end

end

end

%S e l e c t data f o r both types−uncond i t i ona l

f o r j =0:39

h=32;

f o r m=1:1000;

yolo U ( : ,m) =sim y ( j ∗h+1:( j +1)∗h ,m) ;

type U ( : ,m) =sim type ( j ∗h+1:( j +1)∗h ,m) ;

colo U ( : ,m) =sim c ( j ∗h+1:( j +1)∗h ,m) ;

cso lo U ( : ,m) =cs ( j ∗h+1:( j +1)∗h ,m) ;

tb yo lo U ( : ,m)=tb y ( j ∗h+1:( j +1)∗h ,m) ;

D U ( : ,m) =sim d ( j ∗h+1:( j +1)∗h ,m) ;

pd U ( : ,m) =sim pd ( j ∗h+1:( j +1)∗h ,m) ;

end

end

%HP f i l t e r i n g data f o r quar t e r s

lambda = 1600 ;

%l e s s corrupt

y trend L = h p f i l t e r ( yolo L , lambda ) ;

yy dev L = yolo L−y trend L ;

s td y L = mean( std ( yy dev L ) )∗1 0 0 ;

c t r end L = h p f i l t e r ( co lo L , lambda ) ;

c dev L = colo L−c t r end L ;

s td c L = mean( std ( c dev L ) )∗1 0 0 ;

c s t r end L = h p f i l t e r ( cso lo L , lambda ) ;

c s dev L = cso lo L−c s t r end L ;

s t d c s L = mean( std ( cs dev L ) )∗1 0 0 ;

tb t rend L = h p f i l t e r ( tb yo lo L , lambda ) ;

tb dev L = tb yolo L−tb t rend L ;

219

Page 221: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

s td tb L = mean( std ( tb dev L ) )∗1 0 0 ;

%%%%%%c o r r r e l a t i o n s

c o r r y c L=c o r r c o e f ( yy dev L , c dev L ) ;

c o r r y t b L=c o r r c o e f ( yy dev L , tb dev L ) ;

c o r r y c s L=c o r r c o e f ( yy dev L , cs dev L ) ;

c o r r t b c s L=c o r r c o e f ( tb dev L , cs dev L ) ;

%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%

%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%more corrupt

y trend H = h p f i l t e r ( yolo H , lambda ) ;

yy dev H= yolo H−y trend H ;

std y H= mean( std ( yy dev H ) )∗1 0 0 ;

c trend H = h p f i l t e r ( colo H , lambda ) ;

c dev H= colo H−c trend H ;

std c H= mean( std ( c dev H ) )∗1 0 0 ;

c s t rend H = h p f i l t e r ( csolo H , lambda ) ;

cs dev H= csolo H−cs t rend H ;

s td cs H= mean( std ( cs dev H ) )∗1 0 0 ;

tb trend H = h p f i l t e r ( tb yolo H , lambda ) ;

tb dev H= tb yolo H−tb trend H ;

std tb H= mean( std ( tb dev H ) )∗1 0 0 ;

%c o r r e l a t i o n

co r r y c H=c o r r c o e f ( yy dev H , c dev H ) ;

co r r y tb H=c o r r c o e f ( yy dev H , tb dev H ) ;

c o r r y c s H=c o r r c o e f ( yy dev H , cs dev H ) ;

c o r r t b c s H=c o r r c o e f ( tb dev H , cs dev H ) ;

%%%%%%%UNCONDITIONAL

y trend U = h p f i l t e r ( yolo U , lambda ) ;

yy dev U= yolo U−y trend U ;

std y U= mean( std ( yy dev U ) )∗1 0 0 ;

c trend U = h p f i l t e r ( colo U , lambda ) ;

c dev U= colo U−c trend U ;

220

Page 222: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

s td c U= mean( std ( c dev U ) )∗1 0 0 ;

c s t rend U = h p f i l t e r ( csolo U , lambda ) ;

cs dev U= csolo U−cs t rend U ;

s td cs U= mean( std ( cs dev U ) )∗1 0 0 ;

tb trend U = h p f i l t e r ( tb yolo U , lambda ) ;

tb dev U= tb yolo U−tb trend U ;

std tb U= mean( std ( tb dev U ) )∗1 0 0 ;

%%%%%%c o r r r e l a t i o n

co r r y c U=c o r r c o e f ( yy dev U , c dev U ) ;

co r r y tb U=c o r r c o e f ( yy dev U , tb dev U ) ;

c o r r y c s U=c o r r c o e f ( yy dev U , cs dev U ) ;

c o r r t b c s U=c o r r c o e f ( tb dev U , cs dev U ) ;

%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%

%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%

% Credit Spreads

% mean c r e d i t spread , o v e r a l l

% get c r e d i t spreads f o r the types

mean cs = 4∗100∗mean(mean( cso lo U ) ) ; % annual

cs L = cso l o L ;

cs H = cso lo H ;

mean cs L = 4∗100∗mean(mean( cs L ));% annual

mean cs H = 4∗100∗mean(mean( cs H ));% annual

%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%

% Defau l t P r o b a b i l i t i e s

%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%

% mean d e f a u l t p robab i l i t y , o v e r a l l

% d e f a u l t p r o b a b i l i t i e s by type

mean pd = 4∗100 ∗ mean(mean ( ( pd U ))) ;% annual

mean pd L = 4∗100∗mean(mean( pd L ));% annual

mean pd H = 4∗100∗mean(mean( pd H));% annual

%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%

% Avg # of Defau l t Occurrences Every Year

%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%

221

Page 223: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

% mean d e f a u l t s per year (4 pe r i od s per year )

% d e f a u l t s by type

% mean d e f a u l t s per year (4 per year )

mean D = 4∗100 ∗ mean(mean(D U));% annual

mean D L = 4∗100 ∗ mean(mean(D L));% annual

mean D H = 4∗100 ∗ mean(mean(D H));% annual

%s t a t i s t i c s

s t a t s = {} ;

s t a t s . mean cs = mean cs ;

s t a t s . mean cs L = mean cs L ;

s t a t s . mean cs H = mean cs H ;

s t a t s . mean pd = mean pd ;

s t a t s . mean pd L = mean pd L ;

s t a t s . mean pd H = mean pd H ;

s t a t s . mean D = mean D ;

s t a t s . mean D L = mean D L ;

s t a t s . mean D H = mean D H ;

s t a t s

%s t a t i s t i c s l e s s cor rupt

s t a t s L = {} ;

s t a t s L . s td y L = std y L ;

s t a t s L . s td c L = std c L ;

s t a t s L . s t d c s L = 4∗ s t d c s L ;

s t a t s L . s td tb L = std tb L ;

s t a t s L . c o r r y c L = c o r r y c L ( 1 , 2 ) ;

s t a t s L . c o r r y c s L = c o r r y c s L ( 1 , 2 ) ;

s t a t s L . c o r r y t b L = c o r r y t b L ( 1 , 2 ) ;

s t a t s L . c o r r t b c s L = c o r r t b c s L ( 1 , 2 ) ;

s t a t s L

%s t a t i s t i c s more corrupt

s ta t s H = {} ;

s ta t s H . std y H = std y H ;

s ta t s H . std c H = std c H ;

222

Page 224: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

s ta t s H . s td cs H = 4∗ s td cs H ;

s ta t s H . std tb H = std tb H ;

s ta t s H . co r r y c H = cor r y c H ( 1 , 2 ) ;

s ta t s H . c o r r y c s H = c o r r y c s H ( 1 , 2 ) ;

s ta t s H . co r r y tb H = cor r y tb H ( 1 , 2 ) ;

s ta t s H . c o r r t b c s H = c o r r t b c s H ( 1 , 2 ) ;

s ta t s H

%s t a t i s t i c s uncond i t i ona l on type

s ta t s U = {} ;

s ta t s U . std y U = std y U ;

s ta t s U . std c U = std c U ;

s ta t s U . s td cs U = 4∗ s td cs U ;

s ta t s U . std tb U = std tb U ;

s ta t s U . co r r y c U = cor r y c U ( 1 , 2 ) ;

s ta t s U . c o r r y c s U = c o r r y c s U ( 1 , 2 ) ;

s ta t s U . co r r y tb U = cor r y tb U ( 1 , 2 ) ;

s ta t s U . c o r r t b c s U = c o r r t b c s U ( 1 , 2 ) ;

s ta t s U

% c a l c u l a t e d e f a u l t s above long−run mean o f output .

DD L = sim d ( s im type == 1);% type−l e s s corrupt

DD H = sim d ( s im type == 2);% type−more corrupt

%d e f a u l t above long run mean

Y L = sim y ( s im type == 1);% type−l e s s corrupt

Y H = sim y ( s im type == 2);% type−more corrupt

D LA=DD L(Y L>0.0040);% above long−run mean o f output

D LB=DD L(Y L<=0.0040); d e f a u l t s %below mean output

DefLA=(sum(D LA)/sum(DD L))∗100% l e s s co r ruptpercentage

D HA=DD H(Y H>0 .0040) ; %more corrupt d e f a u l t s above mean y

D HB=DD H(Y H<=0.0040);

DefHA=(sum(D HA)/sum(DD H))∗100% percentage

223

Page 225: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

DA=sim d ( sim y >0.0040);% a l l d e f a u l t s above mean output

DefA=(sum(DA)/sum(sum( sim d )) )∗100

%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%

%s e l e t speads be f o r e and a f t e r d e f a u l t

f o r m=1:1000

f o r j =5:1296;

i f s im d ( j ,m)==1

c s s ( : ,m)=cs ( j −4: j +4,m) ;

end

end

end

c s s ( : , a l l ( ˜any ( c s s ) , 1 ) ) = [ ] ;

% removes a l l colums with a l l ze ro

c s s1=mean( c s s ( : , : ) ˜ = 0 ) ;

c s s1=mean( css , 2 ) ;

c s s2=cs s1 . / c s s1 (1 ,1) ;% grow ra t e o f spread

fn = fn +1; f i g u r e ( fn ) ; c l f ;

hold on

p lo t ( c s s2 )

%s e l e t borrowing be f o r e and a f t e r d e f a u l t

f o r m=1:1000

f o r j =5:1296;

i f s im d ( j ,m)==1

bn ( : ,m)=sim bn ( j −4: j +4,m) ;

end

end

end

bn( : , a l l ( ˜any ( bn ) , 1 ) ) = [ ] ;

% removes a l l colums with a l l ze ro

bn1=mean(bn ( : , : ) ˜ = 0 ) ;

bn1=mean(bn , 2 ) ;

bn2=bn1 . / bn1 (1 ,1) ;% grow ra t e o f borrowing

fn = fn +1; f i g u r e ( fn ) ; c l f ;

hold on

p lo t ( bn2 )

224

Page 226: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

%Defau l t space −mesh s i z e o f b i s small , need l a r g e s i z e o f b

dd1 = ( ( v . d ( : , : , 1 , 1 ) ) ) ;

dd2 = ( ( v . d ( : , : , 1 , 2 ) ) ) ;

fn = fn +1; f i g u r e ( fn ) ; c l f ;

hold on

colormap ( [ 1 1 1 ;0 0 0 ] )

s1=mesh ( v . b gr id , v . y gr id , dd1 ’ ) ;

a x i s ( [ min ( v . b g r i d ) ,max( v . b g r i d ) , min ( v . y g r i d ) ,max ( . . .

v . y g r i d ) , 0 , 1 ] ) ;

view ( 0 , 9 0 ) ;

alpha ( s1 , 0 . 5 ) ;%0 .5 i s gray

hold on

s2=mesh ( v . b gr id , v . y gr id , dd2 ’ ) ;

a x i s ( [ min ( v . b g r i d ) ,max( v . b g r i d ) , min ( v . y g r i d ) ,max ( . . .

v . y g r i d ) , 0 , 1 ] ) ;

view ( 0 , 9 0 ) ;

x l a b e l ( ’ Bond ’ , ’ FontSize ’ , 1 2 ) ;

y l a b e l ( ’ Output ’ , ’ FontSize ’ , 1 2 ) ;

alpha ( s2 , 0 .0) ;% 0 i s b lack

hold o f f

225

Page 227: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

Listing A.11: Matlab function for importing simulated data for plots

func t i on [ args ] = read data ( f i l ename )

%READ DATA Reads data from text f i l e .

% READ DATA(FILENAME) re tu rn s a 1x1 c e l l array conta in ing a l l

%the data s to r ed in FILENAME. FILENAME i s assumed to s p e c i f y

%a text f i l e in which the data i s s to r ed in the same format as

%that used by READ DATA.

% Author : Patr i ck Macnamara

% https : // s i t e s . goog l e . com/ s i t e /pmacnama/

i f narg in ˜= 1

e r r o r ( ’ usage : [ a rgs ] = read data ( f i l ename ) ’ ) ;

end

args = {} ;

% fopen r e tu rn s f i d >= 0 i f s u c c e s s f u l , −1 i f not

f i d = fopen ( f i l ename , ’ r ’ ) ;

whi l e f e o f ( f i d ) == 0

% try to read name o f v a r i a b l e and number o f dimensions

C = text scan ( f id , ’%s %d ’ , 1 ) ;

% i f s u c c e s s f u l , then read r e s t o f data f o r t h i s v a r i a b l e

% i f unsucce s s fu l , then the re i s no more data to read

i f f e o f ( f i d ) == 0

% get v a r i a b l e name

arg name = C{1}{1} ;

% get number o f dimensions

nd = C{2} ;

% read r e s t o f i n f o

D = text scan ( f id , ’%d ’ , nd ) ;

d = D{1} ’ ;

% get number o f e lements in array

N = 1 ;

226

Page 228: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

f o r i = 1 : nd

N = d( i ) ∗ N;

end

% read va lues :

row data = text scan ( f id , ’%f ’ , N) ;

i f ( numel ( row data {1}) == N)

a r g v a l = reshape ( row data {1} , d ) ;

e l s e

f c l o s e ( f i d ) ;

e r r o r ( ’ I n v a l i d number o f array e lements stored ’ ) ;

end

% s t o r e v a r i a b l e in s t r u c t

args . ( arg name ) = a r g v a l ;

end

end

% f c l o s e r e tu rn s 0 i f s u c c e s s f u l , −1 i f not

f c l o s e ( f i d ) ;

end

227

Page 229: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

A.2 Chapter 3 Computer Codes

A.2.1 STATA CODES

Stata code used for the empirical results of this chapter of the thesis.

Listing A.12: Stata Do file

// import data l im i t ed en fo r c ement . dta//COUNTRY RE AND FE; f u l l sampleegen id = group ( country )tab year , gen ( yr )x t s e t country yearx t l i n e lnrgdp ENF// s s c i n s t a l l sutex , r e p l a c esutex lnrgdp ENF cred i tdepth , minmax

xtreg lnrgdp ENF, ree s t s t o e s t1

xt reg lnrgdp ENF, f ee s t s t o e s t2

xt reg lnrgdp cred i tdepth , ree s t s t o e s t3

xt reg lnrgdp cred i tdepth , f ee s t s t o e s t4

xt reg lnrgdp ENF cred i tdepth , ree s t s t o e s t5

xt reg lnrgdp ENF cred i tdepth , f ee s t s t o e s t6

xt reg lnrgdp ENF cred i tdepth ENFCREDIT, f ee s t s t o e s t7

xt reg lnrgdp ENF cred i tdepth ENFCREDIT, ree s t s t o e s t8

e s t tab e s t1 e s t2 e s t3 e s t4 e s t5 e s t6 e s t7 e s t8 us ing

//COUNTRY RE AND FE//USING 36 COUNTRIES

228

Page 230: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

// import data l i m i t e d e n f o r c e m e n t s h o r t . dtax t s e t country yearx t l i n e lnrgdp ENF

xtreg lnrgdp ENF, ree s t s t o e s t1

xt reg lnrgdp ENF, f ee s t s t o e s t2

xt reg lnrgdp cred i tdepth , ree s t s t o e s t3

xt reg lnrgdp cred i tdepth , f ee s t s t o e s t4

xt reg lnrgdp ENF cred i tdepth , ree s t s t o e s t5

xt reg lnrgdp ENF cred i tdepth , f ee s t s t o e s t6

xt reg lnrgdp ENF cred i tdepth ENFCREDIT, f ee s t s t o e s t7

xt reg lnrgdp ENF cred i tdepth ENFCREDIT, ree s t s t o e s t8

e s t tab e s t1 e s t2 e s t3 e s t4 e s t5 e s t6 e s t7 e s t8 us ing

//TIME AND COUNTRY RE AND FE// use l im i t ed en fo r c ement . dta ; f u l l samplext reg lnrgdp ENF yr2− yr9 , ree s t s t o e s t1

xt reg lnrgdp ENF yr2−yr9 , f ee s t s t o e s t2

xt reg lnrgdp c r ed i tdepth yr2−yr9 , ree s t s t o e s t3

xt reg lnrgdp c r ed i tdepth yr2−yr9 , f ee s t s t o e s t4

xt reg lnrgdp ENF cred i tdepth yr2−yr9 , re

229

Page 231: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

e s t s t o e s t5

xt reg lnrgdp ENF cred i tdepth yr2−yr9 , f ee s t s t o e s t6

xt reg lnrgdp ENF cred i tdepth ENFCREDIT yr2−yr9 , f ee s t s t o e s t7

xt reg lnrgdp ENF cred i tdepth ENFCREDIT yr2−yr9 , ree s t s t o e s t8

e s t tab e s t1 e s t2 e s t3 e s t4 e s t5 e s t6 e s t7 e s t8

//TIME AND COUNTRY RE AND FE// use l i m i t e d e n f o r c e m e n t s h o r t . dta ” , 36 c o u n t r i e sxt reg lnrgdp ENF yr2−yr9 , ree s t s t o e s t1

xt reg lnrgdp ENF yr2−yr9 , f ee s t s t o e s t2

xt reg lnrgdp c r ed i tdepth yr2−yr9 , ree s t s t o e s t3

xt reg lnrgdp c r ed i tdepth yr2−yr9 , f ee s t s t o e s t4

xt reg lnrgdp ENF cred i tdepth yr2−yr9 , ree s t s t o e s t5xt reg lnrgdp ENF cred i tdepth yr2−yr9 , f ee s t s t o e s t6

xt reg lnrgdp ENF cred i tdepth ENFCREDIT yr2−yr9 , f ee s t s t o e s t7

xt reg lnrgdp ENF cred i tdepth ENFCREDIT yr2−yr9 , ree s t s t o e s t8

e s t tab e s t1 e s t2 e s t3 e s t4 e s t5 e s t6 e s t7 e s t8

230

Page 232: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

A.2.2 DYNARE CODES

We solve the Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium (theoretical) model in Dynare.

In doing this we use the equilibrium conditions in Section (3.3.2.6) and the steady state

in Appendix(3.5.6) as initial values. Below is the Dynare code for the model.

Listing A.13: Dynare code

%=====================================================%

%This s o l v e s the investment model

%=====================================================%

%K i s aggregate c a p i t a l

%ke i s e n t r e p r e n e u r i a l c a p i t a l

%H aggregate i s hou l seho ld labour

%He i s e n t r e n e u r i l a labour

% q i s p r i c e o f c a p i t a l

% n i s net worth

%i i s investment

% d e f a u l t omegabb thre sho ld

% e n t r e n e u r i a l consumption

% household consumption

% Welf i s w e l f a r e

% w i s household wage ra t e

% we i s e n t r e n e u r i a l wage ra t e

% Y aggregate output

%C i s t o t a l consumption

% r r e n t a l r a t e o f c a p i t a l

%Rb i s l end ing ra t e

%rpBANK r i s k premium of l e n d e r s

%l ev l e v e r a g e

%PHI bankruptcy

231

Page 233: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

%f entrepreneur ’ s share o f c a p i t a l output

% g lender ’ s share o f c a p i t a l output

% A pro du c t i v i t y

%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%

%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%

var K ke H He h q n i omegabb ce cc Welf Cc Ce w we Y r I

. . . C Bankrupcy Rb rpBANK lev PHI phi f g A;

varexo eA eN;% shocks

parameters alpha zeta beta de l t a varphi gamma eta S nu

. . mu p M rhoA StdeA StdeN zetaa Ass ;

alpha = 0 . 3 6 ; %share o f c a p i t a l

ze ta = 1−alpha −0.0001; %share o f household labour

beta = 0 . 9 9 ; %di scount ra t e

de l t a = 0 . 0 2 ; %d e p r e c i a t i o n ra t e

gamma = 0 . 9 1 ; % s u r v i v a l r a t e o f ent repreneur

eta = 0 . 1 ;

rhoA = 0 . 9 5 ;

StdeA = 0 . 0 1 ;

StdeN = 0 . 1 ;

S = 0 . 2 0 7 ;

nu = 3;%2.52 ;

mu = 0 . 1 5 0 ; %v e r i f i c a t i o n co s t parameter

p = pi ;

M = −.5∗S ˆ2 ;

rhoStdA = 0 . 8 3 ;

StdeStdA = 0 . 1 9 ;

Ass =1;

232

Page 234: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

varphi =.5 ;

zetaa =0.4;% l i m i t e d enforcement , ze ta

%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%

%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%

%MODEL BLOCK

model ;

q∗ cc ˆ(−1) = beta ∗( cc (+1)ˆ(−1))∗(q(+1)∗(1− de l t a )+r (+1)) ;

%Euler equat ion

cc ˆ(−1) = nu/w;%consumption l e i s u r e

ke = i ∗ f − ce /q ;

n = we + ( ke (−1))∗(q∗(1− de l t a )+r ) − StdeN∗eN ;

K = (1−de l t a )∗K(−1) + I ∗(1−mu∗PHI ) ;

(1− eta )∗ cc + eta ∗ ce + eta ∗ i = Y;

q = ( beta∗gamma) ∗ ( r (+1) + q(+1)∗(1− de l t a ) )∗

. . . ( ( q(+1)∗ f (+1))/(1−q(+1)∗g (+1)) ) ;

q = 1/(1 − mu∗PHI − (mu∗phi )∗ f /(1−PHI)∗(1− zetaa ) ) ;

i = (1/(1−q∗g ) ) ∗ n ;

Y = A∗(K(−1)ˆ alpha )∗ (Hˆ zeta )∗ (Heˆ(1−alpha−zeta ) ) ;

r = alpha∗A∗(K(−1)ˆ( alpha −1))∗(Hˆ zeta )∗ (Heˆ(1−alpha−zeta ) ) ;

w = zeta ∗A∗(K(−1)ˆ alpha )∗ (Hˆ( zeta −1))∗(Heˆ(1−alpha−zeta ) ) ;

we=(1−alpha−zeta )∗A∗(K(−1)ˆ alpha )∗ (Hˆ zeta )∗Heˆ(−( alpha+zeta ) ) ;

H = (1− eta )∗h;%household labour

He = eta ;% e n t r e p r e n e u r i a l labour

Cc = (1− eta )∗ cc ; %household consumption

Ce = eta ∗ ce ; %e n t r e o r e n e u r i a l consumption

C = (1− eta )∗ cc + eta ∗ ce ; %aggregate consumption

I = eta ∗ i ;

Bankrupcy = PHI ;

Rb = ( q∗ i ∗omegabb∗(1− zetaa ) ) / ( i−n);% lend ing ra t e

233

Page 235: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

rpBANK = Rb − 1 ; % r i s k premium of l ende r /bank

l ev = ( i−n)/n ; %l e v e r a g e

l og (A) =rhoA∗ l og (A(−1)) + eA ;

PHI = normcdf ( ( l og ( omegabb)−M)/S ) ;

phi = normpdf ( ( l og ( omegabb)−M)/S) / ( omegabb∗S ) ;

g = (1− zetaa )∗ normcdf ( ( l og ( omegabb)−M)/S − S) − PHI∗mu +

. . . . (1− zetaa )∗(1−PHI)∗omegabb;% lender ’ s share

f = 1−mu∗PHI− g;% entrepreneur ’ s share o f c a p i t a l

Welf = log ( cc)+nu∗(1−h)+beta∗Welf (+1);% w e l f a r e

end ;

%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%

%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%

i n i t v a l ;% i n i t i a l va lue s supp l i ed

omegabb = 0 .603892 ;

PHI = normcdf ( ( l og ( omegabb)−M)/S ) ;

phi = normpdf ( ( l og ( omegabb)−M)/S) / ( omegabb∗S ) ;

g = (1− zetaa )∗ normcdf ( ( l og ( omegabb)−M)/S − S) − PHI∗mu +

. . . (1− zetaa )∗(1−PHI)∗omegabb ;

f = 1−mu∗PHI− g ;

q = 1/(1 − mu∗PHI − (mu∗phi )∗ f /(1−PHI)∗(1− zetaa ) ) ;

r = q∗((1−beta∗(1− de l t a ) )/ beta ) ;

H = . 3 ;

He = eta ;

h = .3/(1− eta ) ;

K = ( alpha / r )ˆ(1/(1− alpha ) )∗Heˆ((1−alpha−zeta )/(1− alpha ) )∗

. . . ( Hˆ( zeta /(1−alpha ) ) ) ;

Y = (Kˆ alpha )∗ (Hˆ zeta )∗ (Heˆ(1−alpha−zeta ) ) ;

i = ( de l t a /( eta∗(1−mu∗0 . 0 1 ) ) )∗K;

234

Page 236: Essays on Institutions, Firm Funding and Sovereign Debt

n = (1−g∗q)∗ i ;

ke = ( beta /q )∗ ( eta ∗n−(1−alpha−zeta )∗Y) ;

ce = q∗( f ∗ i−(ke/ eta ) ) ;

cc = (Y − eta ∗ ce − eta ∗ i )/(1− eta ) ;

A = 1 ;

w = nu∗ cc ;

Welf =−100;% we l f a r e

end ;

steady ;

check ;

shocks ;

var eA ; s t d e r r . 01 ;

%var eN ; s t d e r r 2 ;

end ;

s t o ch s imu l ( order =1, i r f =30, h p f i l t e r =1600);

235