15
ECONOMICS I ACADEMIC YEAR 2017-2018 TUTORIAL 3 Government intervention, taxation, economic welfare TA: ANDREA VENEGONI EXERCISE 1. Consumer and Producer Surplus, Price Floors and Ceilings (14 pts) Suppose that in the Malaysian market of coconuts the demand function is Qd= 110-P and the supply function is Qs= -90+3P a. Calculate equilibrium price and quantity, consumer surplus, producer surplus and total economic welfare. Now suppose the government imposes a floor price of $60. b. Under the price floor how many coconuts will be sold? What will happen to consumer, producer surplus and overall economic welfare compared to the levels previously computed? Solutions: a) Recalling the equilibrium condition that wants Qd=Qs we can equate the two functions deriving the equilibrium price. 110-P=-90+3P 200=4P P*=50 By substituting the equilibrium price in either the demand or supply function we can compute the equilibrium quantity. For sake of computation simplicity we choose the demand function obtaining: Q*=110-50=60 To graph the outcome we have to compute the intercepts between the two curves and the axes. We start with the demand equation: To compute the intercept between the curves and the vertical (Y) axis we have to set Q=0 In this way we obtain: Demand: 0=110-P, and so, by taking P on the right side: P=110 Supply: 0=-90+3P , and so, by taking -90 on the right side: 90=3P, P=90/3=30 To compute the intercept between the curves and the vertical (Y) axis we have to set P=0 In this way we obtain: Demand: Q=110-0, and so, Q=110 Supply: Q=-90+0 , and so, Q=-90

ECONOMICS I ACADEMIC YEAR 2017-2018 TUTORIAL 3 ...my.liuc.it/MatSup/2017/A20030/tutorial 3 answers.pdfDEMAND: Qd=110-P Qd=110-60=50 SUPPLY: Qs=-90+3P Qs=-90+3*60=-90+180=90 So, to

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    4

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: ECONOMICS I ACADEMIC YEAR 2017-2018 TUTORIAL 3 ...my.liuc.it/MatSup/2017/A20030/tutorial 3 answers.pdfDEMAND: Qd=110-P Qd=110-60=50 SUPPLY: Qs=-90+3P Qs=-90+3*60=-90+180=90 So, to

ECONOMICS I – ACADEMIC YEAR 2017-2018

TUTORIAL 3 – Government intervention, taxation, economic welfare

TA: ANDREA VENEGONI

EXERCISE 1. Consumer and Producer Surplus, Price Floors and Ceilings (14 pts)

Suppose that in the Malaysian market of coconuts the demand function is Qd= 110-P and the supply

function is Qs= -90+3P

a. Calculate equilibrium price and quantity, consumer surplus, producer surplus and total economic

welfare.

Now suppose the government imposes a floor price of $60.

b. Under the price floor how many coconuts will be sold? What will happen to consumer, producer

surplus and overall economic welfare compared to the levels previously computed?

Solutions:

a) Recalling the equilibrium condition that wants Qd=Qs we can equate the two functions

deriving the equilibrium price.

110-P=-90+3P

200=4P

P*=50

By substituting the equilibrium price in either the demand or supply function we can

compute the equilibrium quantity. For sake of computation simplicity we choose the

demand function obtaining:

Q*=110-50=60

To graph the outcome we have to compute the intercepts between the two curves and the

axes. We start with the demand equation:

To compute the intercept between the curves and the vertical (Y) axis we have to set Q=0

In this way we obtain:

Demand: 0=110-P, and so, by taking P on the right side: P=110

Supply: 0=-90+3P , and so, by taking -90 on the right side: 90=3P, P=90/3=30

To compute the intercept between the curves and the vertical (Y) axis we have to set P=0

In this way we obtain:

Demand: Q=110-0, and so, Q=110

Supply: Q=-90+0 , and so, Q=-90

Page 2: ECONOMICS I ACADEMIC YEAR 2017-2018 TUTORIAL 3 ...my.liuc.it/MatSup/2017/A20030/tutorial 3 answers.pdfDEMAND: Qd=110-P Qd=110-60=50 SUPPLY: Qs=-90+3P Qs=-90+3*60=-90+180=90 So, to

b) To compute the new quantities demanded and supplied after the introduction of the price

floor of 90, it is sufficient to substitute, both in the demand and supply equation, the new

price level.

DEMAND: Qd=110-P Qd=110-60=50

SUPPLY: Qs=-90+3P Qs=-90+3*60=-90+180=90

So, to summarize, by recalling that the equilibrium quantity before the implementation of

the price floor was equal to 60, we have that such an intervention makes the quantity

demanded drop by 10 and the quantity supply increase by 30. This generates a surplus

(calculated as Qs-Qd) equal to 90-50= 40.

Y

DA

S

D

110

30

60

50

CS

PS

Page 3: ECONOMICS I ACADEMIC YEAR 2017-2018 TUTORIAL 3 ...my.liuc.it/MatSup/2017/A20030/tutorial 3 answers.pdfDEMAND: Qd=110-P Qd=110-60=50 SUPPLY: Qs=-90+3P Qs=-90+3*60=-90+180=90 So, to

Y

DA

S

D

110

30

50

60

PRICE FLOOR

50 90

SURPLUS

CS

PS DWL

46.6

60

Page 4: ECONOMICS I ACADEMIC YEAR 2017-2018 TUTORIAL 3 ...my.liuc.it/MatSup/2017/A20030/tutorial 3 answers.pdfDEMAND: Qd=110-P Qd=110-60=50 SUPPLY: Qs=-90+3P Qs=-90+3*60=-90+180=90 So, to

EXERCISE 2.

The US government is concerned about the high incidence of heart diseases among the

population.

Soft drinks demand in US is given by: Qd = 60 - 3P.

Soft drinks supply in US is given by: Qs =-20 + 5P.

To curtail junk food consumption, it is considering imposing a 2 dollars tax on soft drinks, the so

called sugar-tax.

a. (4 pts.) Calculate the market clearing price per pack and packs sold prior to the imposition

of the tax.

b. (6 pts.) Calculate the market clearing price and quantity after the imposition of the 10 euros

tax. Graph the outcome with and without the tax. What is the price that buyers pay and the

price that sellers receive with the tax?

c. (4 pts.) From your answers to (a) – (b) above, what is the incidence of the tax on consumers

versus producers, i.e. what proportion of the tax will consumers vs. producers pay?

d. (2 pts.) From your answer to (c ) above, what do you deduct about the relative elasticities of

buyers versus producers of liquors in US?

e. (4 pts.) Now calculate the incidence of the tax on buyers and sellers using the “pass

through” formula. (Hint: First calculate the elasticity of demand and supply at the market

equilibrium without the tax).

f. (4 pts.) Calculate total tax revenues to the US government from the tax and Dead Weight

Loss (DWL) associated with the tax and show them on the graph.

g. (4 pts.) Is the DWL larger or smaller than the tax? Discuss the implications of your findings.

Is this an effective tax? Why or why not? What considerations you believe are excluded

from this type of analysis.

Answer:

a. The market equilibrium price absent the tax is given by finding the P that equates Qd and Qs:

40 – P = -10 + 4P

50= 5P

P* = 10

The equilibrium quantity is given by plugging the equilibrium price into the Qd or Qs equation:

Qd = 40 –10 = 30

b. The tax of 2$ creates a wedge between the price buyers pay (Pb) and the price sellers

receive (Ps). Note that it does not matter to the market equilibrium whether the tax is

imposed on buyers or sellers of cigarettes.

Pb = Ps + 10

The demand and supply equations become:

Qd = 40 – Pb = 40 - (Ps + 2) = 40 – Ps - 2

Qs = -10 + 4Ps

The new market equilibrium will occur where Qd = Qs

40 - Ps - 2= -10 + 4Ps

48 = 5Ps

Ps = 9.6. This is the price sellers receive.

Pb = Ps + 2 = 9.6 + 2 = 11.6. This is the price buyers pay.

Page 5: ECONOMICS I ACADEMIC YEAR 2017-2018 TUTORIAL 3 ...my.liuc.it/MatSup/2017/A20030/tutorial 3 answers.pdfDEMAND: Qd=110-P Qd=110-60=50 SUPPLY: Qs=-90+3P Qs=-90+3*60=-90+180=90 So, to

The new equilibrium quantity Q* is determined by substituting the new price paid by buyers Pb of

11.6 in the Qd equation or the new price received by sellers Ps= 9.6 in the Qs equation:

Qd = 40 – 11.6 = 28.4

Or alternatively,

Qs = -10 + 4(9.6) = 28.4

P

S

11.6

10 Old equilibrium without tax

9.6

D

28.4 30 Q

c. To calculate the proportion of the tax borne by buyers, we have to compare the price paid by

buyers with and without the tax. As a result of the tax, the market price went up by 1.6, from 10 to

11.6. Therefore consumers bear 1.6 of the 2 dollars of the tax or 80% of the tax. To calculate the

proportion of the tax paid by sellers, we have to compare the price received by sellers before and

after the tax. As a result of the tax, the price received by sellers fell from 10 to 9.6. Therefore,

sellers bear the remaining 0.4 dollars of the tax or 20% of it.

d. From (c ) above, buyers bear a significantly larger proportion of the tax than sellers. This implies

that the demand of buyers is less elastic (with regard to price) than the supply of sellers.

e. Pass-through formula: Es/(Es – Ed).

where Es = Elasticity of supply and Ed = elasticity of demand

It measures the incidence of the tax borne by buyers.

Ed = Q/ΔP * P/Q = -1 (10/30) = -10/30 = -1/3

Es = Q/ΔP * P/Q = 4 (10/30) = 40/30 = 4/3

Therefore Es/(Es-Ed) = (4/3)/(4/3 – (-1/3)) = (4/3)/(5/3) = 4/3 *3/5 = = 4/5 = .8

Thus, 80% of the tax is borne by buyers and 20% of the tax is borne by sellers.

f. Tax revenues are 28.4 * 2 = 56.8. Dead weight loss associated with the tax = 1.5 given by

[(30 – 28.4) * 2]/2= 1.5 million pesos/month.

Page 6: ECONOMICS I ACADEMIC YEAR 2017-2018 TUTORIAL 3 ...my.liuc.it/MatSup/2017/A20030/tutorial 3 answers.pdfDEMAND: Qd=110-P Qd=110-60=50 SUPPLY: Qs=-90+3P Qs=-90+3*60=-90+180=90 So, to

P

S

11.6

10 Old equilibrium without tax

9.6

D

28.4 30 Q

g. DWL is somewhat less than tax revenue from the tax. This would indicate that the tax is

effective in raising tax revenue and with causing only a little distortion in the market (in the form of

DWL). .

However, excluded from these calculations are the potential benefits to society from reduced soft

drink consumption which are not measurable with this type of static analysis. For example: the tax

revenues could be used for information campaigns, health care costs which may have benefits that

are greater over time than the size of the tax revenues themselves. Also, we may argue that the loss

in consumer surplus and producer surplus associated with reduced consumption/sale of an

unhealthy good is not an appropriate way of evaluating this type of market.

Tax

Revenue

DWL

Page 7: ECONOMICS I ACADEMIC YEAR 2017-2018 TUTORIAL 3 ...my.liuc.it/MatSup/2017/A20030/tutorial 3 answers.pdfDEMAND: Qd=110-P Qd=110-60=50 SUPPLY: Qs=-90+3P Qs=-90+3*60=-90+180=90 So, to

EXERCISE 3

In the market for apples, the demand curve is Q = 50-3P and the supply curve

is Q = 2P. The Government decides to raise revenue by taxing consumers 2 for

every apple purchased.

a) Graph the supply and demand curves. Calculate the pre-tax and after-tax equilibrium

quantities and prices.

b) Calculate the change in consumer and producer surplus from the tax.

c) Calculate the burden of the tax borne by each party.

d) Calculate elasticity of demand and supply at the equilibrium and use the

elasticity formula to check your calculations at point b).

e) Calculate the amount of revenues raised by the Government and the loss of

efficiency for the society (DWL)

f) Intuitively, why is there dead-weight loss from a tax? That is, what exactly

does deadweight loss represent?

SOLUTIONS:

a) Graph the supply and demand curves. Calculate the pre-tax and after-tax

equilibrium quantities and prices.

b) Calculate the change in consumer and producer surplus from the tax.

To compute the pre-tax equilibrium lets recall the equilibrium condition Qd=Qs.

In this way we can equate the demand and supply equations obtaining: 50-3P=2P

Solving for P we have: 50=5P P*=10

To compute the equilibrium quantity (Q*) we have to substitute P* in the demand or the

supply equation. Choosing the supply equation we have Q*=2*10=20

So, to summarize: P*=10, Q*=20

To compute the after tax equilibrium we have to remind, besides the equilibrium

condition (Qd=Qs) that still holds, that now we are going to have two prices: a price of

the buyers and a price of the sellers, that are related by the following equations:

Pb=Ps+tax

Ps=Pb-tax

Knowing this we can rewrite the demand and supply equations as:

Qd=50-3Pb

Qs=2Ps

Using now one of the two equations (free to choose which) that describe the relation

between Pb and Ps we obtain:

Qd=50-3Pb

Qs=2(Pb-tax)=2(Pb-2)

Equating as usual this two expressions: 50-3Pb=2(Pb-2)

Solving for Pb: 50-3Pb=2Pb-4

54=5Pb

Page 8: ECONOMICS I ACADEMIC YEAR 2017-2018 TUTORIAL 3 ...my.liuc.it/MatSup/2017/A20030/tutorial 3 answers.pdfDEMAND: Qd=110-P Qd=110-60=50 SUPPLY: Qs=-90+3P Qs=-90+3*60=-90+180=90 So, to

Pb=10.8

Ps=10.8-2=8.8

To obtain quantity we can substitute Pb in demand function or Ps in the supply

function. Beware that now we have two prices, so we have to carefully aassociate

the price to the right equation!

Choosing for sake of simplicity Ps, we substitute its value in the supply equation:

Qs=2*8.8=17.6

So the introduction of the tax (recalling that in the pre-tax equilibrium P*=10, Q*=20)

makes quantity decrease, price of buyers increase and price of suppliers decrease.

To graph the equilibrium we need to compute the intercepts between the axes and the

curves.

We start with the demand equation:

To compute the intercept between the curves and the vertical (Y) axis we have to set

Q=0

In this way we obtain:

Demand: 0=50-3P, and so, by taking P on the right side: 3P=50 P=50/3=16.6

Supply: 0=2P , and so P=0

To compute the intercept between the curves and the vertical (Y) axis we have to set P=0

In this way we obtain:

Demand: Q=50-0, and so, Q=50

Supply: Q=2*0 , and so, Q=0

Y

DA

S

D

16.6

10

20

CS

PS

Page 9: ECONOMICS I ACADEMIC YEAR 2017-2018 TUTORIAL 3 ...my.liuc.it/MatSup/2017/A20030/tutorial 3 answers.pdfDEMAND: Qd=110-P Qd=110-60=50 SUPPLY: Qs=-90+3P Qs=-90+3*60=-90+180=90 So, to

As is possible to observe we are able to spot two areas of economic significance. The

upper triangle indicates the consumer surplus, while the lower the producer surplus.

To calculate the consumer surplus (CS) the procedure is the following. You have to

multiplicate the difference between the highest price possibly paid by customers (the

intercept between the demand curve and the vertical axis) and the equilibrium price

times the equilibrium quantity. All divided by 2: CS= (16.6−10)∗20

2=

6.6∗20

2 =132/2= 66

For the producer surplus the reasoning is analogous: you have to multiply the difference

between the equilibrium price and the lowest price at which suppliers can sell the good

(the intercept between the supply curve and the vertical axis) times the equilibrium

quantity. All divided by 2: 𝑃𝑆 = (10−0)∗20

2=

200

2= 100.

To compute again consumer and producer surpluses after the introduction of the tax the

procedure is the same, but now when considering consumer surplus we have to take into

account Pb and for producer surplus Ps.

𝐶𝑆 =(16.6 − 10.8) ∗ 17.6

2= 51,04

𝑃𝑆 =(8,8 − 0) ∗ 17.6

2= 77,44

Now we are able to compute the variation in CS and PS after the introduction of the tax

𝛥𝐶𝑆 = 𝐶𝑆𝑎𝑓𝑡𝑒𝑟−𝑡𝑎𝑥 − 𝐶𝑆𝑝𝑟𝑒−𝑡𝑎𝑥 = 51,04 − 66 = −14,96

𝛥𝑃𝑆 = 𝑃𝑆𝑎𝑓𝑡𝑒𝑟−𝑡𝑎𝑥 − 𝑃𝑆𝑝𝑟𝑒−𝑡𝑎𝑥 = 77,44 − 100 = −12,56

c) Calculate the burden of the tax borne by each party.

Y

DA

S

D

16.6

10

10.8

10

8.8

10

20

10

17.6

10

CS

PS

DWL Tax

Revenues

Page 10: ECONOMICS I ACADEMIC YEAR 2017-2018 TUTORIAL 3 ...my.liuc.it/MatSup/2017/A20030/tutorial 3 answers.pdfDEMAND: Qd=110-P Qd=110-60=50 SUPPLY: Qs=-90+3P Qs=-90+3*60=-90+180=90 So, to

The burden of the tax borne by each party (consumers and producers) is defined as the

portion of the tax paid by either of the two in the form of price variation compared to the

pre-tax equilibrium price. Given that the tax introduction causes a price increase for the

consumers and a price decrease for the suppliers, the burden of the tax results in the amount

of such price variation compared to the level of the tax.

In formula:

TAX BURDEN BORNE BY CONSUMERS: 𝑃𝑟𝑖𝑐𝑒 𝑜𝑓 𝑐𝑜𝑛𝑠𝑢𝑚𝑒𝑟𝑠 𝑎𝑓𝑡𝑒𝑟 𝑡ℎ𝑒 𝑡𝑎𝑥−𝑝𝑟𝑒 𝑡𝑎𝑥 𝑝𝑟𝑖𝑐𝑒

𝑇𝐴𝑋

TAX BURDEN BORNE BY PRODUCERS: |𝑃𝑟𝑖𝑐𝑒 𝑜𝑓 𝑠𝑢𝑝𝑝𝑙𝑖𝑒𝑟𝑠 𝑎𝑓𝑡𝑒𝑟 𝑡ℎ𝑒 𝑡𝑎𝑥−𝑝𝑟𝑒 𝑡𝑎𝑥 𝑝𝑟𝑖𝑐𝑒|

𝑇𝐴𝑋

To compute them is now easy, we have just to substitute data in the above formulas:

TAX BURDEN BORNE BY CONSUMERS: 10.8−10

2=

0.8

2= 0.4 = 40%

TAX BURDEN BORNE BY PRODUCERS: |8.8−10|

2=

1.2

2= 0.6 = 60%

Please bear in mind that the sum of the two must be equal to 1 (or, if you prefer, 100%)!!

(in the second formula, the one used to calculate the tax burden borne by producers, we consider, at

the numerator, the absolute value of the difference between the post-tax and the pre-tax prices, as

we are concerned about the amount of tax burden borne by suppliers, that surely is a positive value)

d) Calculate elasticity of demand and supply at the equilibrium and use the

elasticity formula to check your calculations at point b

To compute the tax burden borne by consumers can be employed another formula, the so called

pass-through formula:

PASS-THROUGH FORMULA: 𝜀𝑠/(𝜀𝑠 − 𝜀𝑑)

To use it is necessary to compute the elasticity of demand (𝜀𝑑) and the elasticity of supply(𝜀𝑠):

𝜀𝑑 =𝛥𝑄

𝛥𝑃∗

𝑃

𝑄=

17.6 − 20

10.8 − 10∗

10

20=

−2.4

0.8∗

1

2= −3 ∗

1

2= −

3

2

𝜀𝑠 =𝛥𝑄

𝛥𝑃∗

𝑃

𝑄=

17.6 − 20

8.8 − 10∗

10

20=

−2.4

−1.2∗

1

2= 2 ∗

1

2=

2

2= 1

PASS-THROUGH FORMULA: 𝜀𝑠/(𝜀𝑠 − 𝜀𝑑)= 1

1−(−3

2)

=15

2

=2

5= 0.4 = 40%

This is confirms that the bove calculations were good. The pass-through formula states that the tax

burden borne by customers is the 40%, as we should expect given that the elasticity of demand is

higher than the elasticity of supply. The amount of tax born is higher on the party that displays the

lowest elasticity to price.

e) Calculate the amount of revenues raised by the Government and the loss of efficiency for

the society (DWL)

To compute tax revenues we have to calculate the area of the rectangle that goes from PB to PS in

height and from 0 to the after-tax quantity in length.

TAX REVENUES= (10.8 − 8.8) ∗ (20 − 17.6) = 2 ∗ 2.4 = 4.8

Page 11: ECONOMICS I ACADEMIC YEAR 2017-2018 TUTORIAL 3 ...my.liuc.it/MatSup/2017/A20030/tutorial 3 answers.pdfDEMAND: Qd=110-P Qd=110-60=50 SUPPLY: Qs=-90+3P Qs=-90+3*60=-90+180=90 So, to

The dead-weight loss (DWL), i.e. the loss of economic welfare caused by the distortionary effect of

the tax introduction, is described by the area of the triangle at the right of the tax revenues’

rectangle.

To compute it, hence, is necessary to calculate the area of that triangle:

DWL= 𝑇𝑎𝑥∗(𝑝𝑟𝑒 𝑡𝑎𝑥 𝑞𝑢𝑎𝑛𝑡𝑖𝑡𝑦−𝑎𝑓𝑡𝑒𝑟 𝑡𝑎𝑥 𝑞𝑢𝑎𝑛𝑡𝑖𝑡𝑦)

2=

2∗(20−17.6)

2=

2∗2.4

2= 2.4

So we have that Tax revenues are equal to 4.8 while the DWL amounts at 2.4.

So DWL is the 50% of tax revenues: from this we ca argue that the amount of the tax is a little bit

high, as it introduces an appreciable degree of distortion in the market functioning.

Page 12: ECONOMICS I ACADEMIC YEAR 2017-2018 TUTORIAL 3 ...my.liuc.it/MatSup/2017/A20030/tutorial 3 answers.pdfDEMAND: Qd=110-P Qd=110-60=50 SUPPLY: Qs=-90+3P Qs=-90+3*60=-90+180=90 So, to

EXERCISE 4

Suppose that the market for green tea can be described by the following demand and supply

curves (prices are per kg):

Qd = 260 − 5P

QS = 8P

a) Find the market equilibrium in the absence of taxes. Draw the demand and

supply curves, labelling all intercepts and the market equilibrium

b) Draw the curves as in the last item, showing clearly the areas representing the

consumer surplus (CS) and the producer surplus (PS). Calculate their values

and the value of the total surplus (TS).

c) Suppose now that the government decides to tax green tea by $13 per kg.

Calculate the tax equilibrium.

Calculate and show on the graph the values of CS, PS, TAXR, DWL

SOLUTIONS:

a) To compute the pre-tax equilibrium lets recall the equilibrium condition Qd=Qs.

In this way we can equate the demand and supply equations obtaining: 260-5P=8P

Solving for P we have: 260=13P P*=20

To compute the equilibrium quantity (Q*) we have to substitute P* in the demand or the

supply equation. Choosing the supply equation we have Q*=8*20=160

So, to summarize: P*=20, Q*=160

To graph the equilibrium we need to compute the intercepts between the axes and the

curves.

We start with the demand equation:

To compute the intercept between the curves and the vertical (Y) axis we have to set

Q=0

In this way we obtain:

Demand: 0=260-5P, and so, by taking P on the right side: 5P=260 P=260/5=52

Supply: 0=8P , and so P=0

To compute the intercept between the curves and the vertical (Y) axis we have to set P=0

In this way we obtain:

Demand: Q=260-0, and so, Q=260

Supply: Q=8*0 , and so, Q=0

Page 13: ECONOMICS I ACADEMIC YEAR 2017-2018 TUTORIAL 3 ...my.liuc.it/MatSup/2017/A20030/tutorial 3 answers.pdfDEMAND: Qd=110-P Qd=110-60=50 SUPPLY: Qs=-90+3P Qs=-90+3*60=-90+180=90 So, to

b) As is possible to observe we are able to spot two areas of economic significance. The

upper triangle indicates the consumer surplus, while the lower the producer surplus.

To calculate the consumer surplus (CS) the procedure is the following. You have to

multiplicate the difference between the highest price possibly paid by customers (the

intercept between the demand curve and the vertical axis) and the equilibrium price

times the equilibrium quantity. All divided by 2: CS= (52−20)∗160

2=

32∗160

2 =5120/2= 2560

For the producer surplus the reasoning is analogous: you have to multiply the difference

between the equilibrium price and the lowest price at which suppliers can sell the good

(the intercept between the supply curve and the vertical axis) times the equilibrium

quantity. All divided by 2: 𝑃𝑆 = (20−0)∗160

2=

3200

2= 1600.

c) To compute the after tax equilibrium we have to remind, besides the equilibrium

condition (Qd=Qs) that still holds, that now we are going to have two prices: a price of

the buyers and a price of the sellers, that are related by the following equations:

Pb=Ps+tax

Ps=Pb-tax

Knowing this we can rewrite the demand and supply equations as:

Qd=260-5Pb

Qs=8Ps

Using now one of the two equations (free to choose which) that describe the relation

between Pb and Ps we obtain:

Qd=260-5Pb

Qs=8(Pb-tax)=8(Pb-13)

Equating as usual this two expressions: 260-5Pb=8(Pb-13)

Solving for Pb: 260-5Pb=8Pb-104

364=13Pb

Pb=28

Ps=28-13=15

Y

DA

S

D

52

20

0

260 160

CS

PS

Page 14: ECONOMICS I ACADEMIC YEAR 2017-2018 TUTORIAL 3 ...my.liuc.it/MatSup/2017/A20030/tutorial 3 answers.pdfDEMAND: Qd=110-P Qd=110-60=50 SUPPLY: Qs=-90+3P Qs=-90+3*60=-90+180=90 So, to

To obtain quantity we can substitute Pb in demand function or Ps in the supply

function. Beware that now we have two prices, so we have to carefully associate the

price to the right equation!

Choosing for sake of simplicity Ps, we substitute its value in the supply equation:

Qs=8*15=120

So the introduction of the tax (recalling that in the pre-tax equilibrium P*=20, Q*=160)

makes quantity decrease, price of buyers increase and price of suppliers decrease.

To compute again consumer and producer surpluses after the introduction of the tax the

procedure is the same, but now when considering consumer surplus we have to take into

account Pb and for producer surplus Ps.

𝐶𝑆 =(52 − 28) ∗ 120

2= 1440

𝑃𝑆 =(15 − 0) ∗ 120

2= 900

Now we are able to compute the variation in CS and PS after the introduction of the tax

𝛥𝐶𝑆 = 𝐶𝑆𝑎𝑓𝑡𝑒𝑟−𝑡𝑎𝑥 − 𝐶𝑆𝑝𝑟𝑒−𝑡𝑎𝑥 = 1600 − 2560 = −960

𝛥𝑃𝑆 = 𝑃𝑆𝑎𝑓𝑡𝑒𝑟−𝑡𝑎𝑥 − 𝑃𝑆𝑝𝑟𝑒−𝑡𝑎𝑥 = 900 − 1600 = −700

To compute tax revenues we have to calculate the area of the rectangle that goes from PB to PS in

height and from 0 to the after-tax quantity in length.

TAX REVENUES= (28 − 20) ∗ (160 − 120) = 8 ∗ 40 = 320

The dead-weight loss (DWL), i.e. the loss of economic welfare caused by the distortionary effect of

the tax introduction, is described by the area of the triangle at the right of the tax revenues’

rectangle.

Y

DA

S

D

52

20

28

15

CS

PS

TAX

REVENUES DWL

160 120

Page 15: ECONOMICS I ACADEMIC YEAR 2017-2018 TUTORIAL 3 ...my.liuc.it/MatSup/2017/A20030/tutorial 3 answers.pdfDEMAND: Qd=110-P Qd=110-60=50 SUPPLY: Qs=-90+3P Qs=-90+3*60=-90+180=90 So, to

To compute it, hence, is necessary to calculate the area of that triangle:

DWL= 𝑇𝑎𝑥∗(𝑝𝑟𝑒 𝑡𝑎𝑥 𝑞𝑢𝑎𝑛𝑡𝑖𝑡𝑦−𝑎𝑓𝑡𝑒𝑟 𝑡𝑎𝑥 𝑞𝑢𝑎𝑛𝑡𝑖𝑡𝑦)

2=

13∗(160−120)

2=

13∗40

2= 260

So we have that Tax revenues are equal to 320 while the DWL amounts at 260.

So DWL is the 81.25% of tax revenues (260/320): from this we can argue that the amount of the tax

is excessive, as it introduces a very high degree of distortion in the market functioning.