43
Economic Outlook, Prospects, and Policy Challenges CHAPTER 01 1.1 INTRODUCTION A political mandate for reform and a benign external environment have created a historic moment of opportunity to propel India onto a double-digit growth trajectory. Decisive shifts in policies controlled by the Centre combined with a persistent, encompassing, and creative incrementalism in other areas could cumulate to Big Bang reforms. As the new government presents its first full-year budget, a momentous opportunity awaits. India has reached a sweet spot—rare in the history of nations—in which it could finally be launched on a double-digit medium-term growth trajectory. This trajectory would allow the country to attain the fundamental objectives of “wiping every tear from every eye” of the still poor and vulnerable, while affording the opportunities for increasingly young, middle-class, and aspirational India to realize its limitless potential. This opening has arisen because facts and fortune have aligned in India’s favour. The macro-economy has been rendered more stable, reforms have been launched, the deceleration in growth has ended and the economy appears now to be recovering, the external environment is benign, and challenges in other major economies have made India the near-cynosure of eager investors. Daunting challenges endure, which this Survey will not ignore, but the strong political mandate for economic change has imbued optimism that they can be overcome. India, in short, seems poised for propulsion. Any Economic Survey has to grapple with prioritization, to navigate the competing pitfalls of being indiscriminatorily inclusive and contentiously selective. Accordingly, this Survey will focus on the two broad themes—creating opportunity and reducing vulnerability—because they are the two pressing themes of the day and which between them encompass the many key policy challenges that the new government must address. The outline for this volume of the Economic Survey is as follows. A brief macroeconomic review and outlook will set the context for the broader thematic and policy discussions that follow. The importance of economic growth, both for lifting up those at the bottom of the income and wealth distribution, and providing opportunities for everyone in that distribution, cannot be overstated. 1 Rapid, sustainable, and all-encompassing growth requires a strong macroeconomic foundation, key to which is fiscal discipline and a credible medium term fiscal framework. These prerequisites are discussed in Sections 1.2 and 1.6. But “wiping every tear from every eye” also requires proactive support from the government in the form of a well-functioning, well-targeted, leakage-proof safety net that will both provide (minimum income) and protect (against adverse shocks). This is also true in rural India where economic conditions for farmers and labourers are under stress. The policy issue now is no longer whether but how best to “provide and protect,” and technology-based direct benefit transfers will play an important role in this regard (discussed in Section 1.7. 1 Bhagwati, J. and Arvind Panagariya, “Why Growth Matters: How Economic Growth in India Reduced Poverty and the Lessons for Other Developing Countries”, 2013, A Council on Foreign Relations Book, Public Affairs Books.

Economic Outlook, Prospects, and€¦ · budget, a momentous opportunity awaits. India has reached a sweet spot—rare in the history of nations—in which it could finally be launched

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    1

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Economic Outlook, Prospects, and€¦ · budget, a momentous opportunity awaits. India has reached a sweet spot—rare in the history of nations—in which it could finally be launched

Economic Outlook, Prospects, andPolicy Challenges CHAPTER

011.1 INTRODUCTION

A political mandate for reform and a benignexternal environment have created a historicmoment of opportunity to propel India ontoa double-digit growth trajectory. Decisiveshifts in policies controlled by the Centrecombined with a persistent, encompassing,and creative incrementalism in other areascould cumulate to Big Bang reforms.

As the new government presents its first full-yearbudget, a momentous opportunity awaits. Indiahas reached a sweet spot—rare in the history ofnations—in which it could finally be launched on adouble-digit medium-term growth trajectory. Thistrajectory would allow the country to attain thefundamental objectives of “wiping every tear fromevery eye” of the still poor and vulnerable, whileaffording the opportunities for increasingly young,middle-class, and aspirational India to realize itslimitless potential.

This opening has arisen because facts and fortunehave aligned in India’s favour. The macro-economyhas been rendered more stable, reforms have beenlaunched, the deceleration in growth has endedand the economy appears now to be recovering,the external environment is benign, and challengesin other major economies have made India thenear-cynosure of eager investors. Dauntingchallenges endure, which this Survey will not ignore,but the strong political mandate for economicchange has imbued optimism that they can beovercome. India, in short, seems poised forpropulsion.

Any Economic Survey has to grapple withprioritization, to navigate the competing pitfalls ofbeing indiscriminatorily inclusive and contentiouslyselective. Accordingly, this Survey will focus onthe two broad themes—creating opportunity andreducing vulnerability—because they are the twopressing themes of the day and which betweenthem encompass the many key policy challengesthat the new government must address.

The outline for this volume of the Economic Surveyis as follows. A brief macroeconomic review andoutlook will set the context for the broaderthematic and policy discussions that follow. Theimportance of economic growth, both for liftingup those at the bottom of the income and wealthdistribution, and providing opportunities foreveryone in that distribution, cannot be overstated.1Rapid, sustainable, and all-encompassing growthrequires a strong macroeconomic foundation, keyto which is fiscal discipline and a credible mediumterm fiscal framework. These prerequisites arediscussed in Sections 1.2 and 1.6.

But “wiping every tear from every eye” alsorequires proactive support from the governmentin the form of a well-functioning, well-targeted,leakage-proof safety net that will both provide(minimum income) and protect (against adverseshocks). This is also true in rural India whereeconomic conditions for farmers and labourers areunder stress. The policy issue now is no longerwhether but how best to “provide and protect,”and technology-based direct benefit transfers willplay an important role in this regard (discussed inSection 1.7.

1 Bhagwati, J. and Arvind Panagariya, “Why Growth Matters: How Economic Growth in India Reduced Poverty andthe Lessons for Other Developing Countries”, 2013, A Council on Foreign Relations Book, Public Affairs Books.

Page 2: Economic Outlook, Prospects, and€¦ · budget, a momentous opportunity awaits. India has reached a sweet spot—rare in the history of nations—in which it could finally be launched

2 Economic Survey 2014-15

Perspiration and inspiration, investment andefficiency, respectively, determine long-run growth.But the Indian private investment climate is cloudedby the experience of the last decade. Acombination of factors—weak corporate balancesheets, an impaired banking system, difficulty ofexit, the deficiencies of the public privatepartnership (PPP) model in infrastructure—couldhold back private investment going forward.Private investment must remain the main engine oflong-run growth. But, in the short to medium term,as the near-intractable problems get slowlyresolved, public investment, especially by therailways, will have to play a catalytic role. Theseissues and how the banking system can play asupportive role are the focus of discussions insections 1.8 and 1.9.2

Manufacturing and trade have been the engines ofgrowth in the post-war period for most economies,especially in Asia. The validity of that experiencefor India, which acquires salience in the context ofthe ‘Make in India’ initiative, is the focus of section1.10. The following section then takes upchallenges related to trade.

Sections 1.12 and 1.13—on climate change andgender equality respectively— deal with issueswhich India cannot and must not ignore. Theseare central to the challenges of growth,development and equality of opportunity. Theobjective of protecting the vulnerable mustspecifically take account of the fact that while Indiais increasingly young, middle-class, andaspirational, it is still persistently stubbornly male.

All these policy issues and challenges areelaborated in Chapters 2-10 in this volume. Thelast section deals with what is a dramatic re-shapingof Centre-State fiscal relations. It provides apreliminary analysis of the key implications of therecommendations of the Fourteenth FinanceCommission.

Given the expectations surrounding the upcomingbudget, one question needs to be addressed head-on: Does India need Big Bang reforms? Much

of the cross-country evidence of the post-waryears suggests that Big Bang reforms occur duringor in the aftermath of major crises. Moreover, BigBang reforms in robust democracies with multipleactors and institutions with the power to do, undo,and block, are the exception rather than the rule.India today is not in crisis, and decision-makingauthority is vibrantly and frustratingly diffuse.

Not only are many of the levers of power verticallydispersed, reflected in the power of the states,policy-making has also become dispersedhorizontally. The Supreme Court and theComptroller and Auditor General have all exerteddecisive influence over policy action and inaction.

Moreover, some important reforms such asimprovements to tax administration or easing thecost of doing business, require persistence andpatience in their implementation, evoked in MaxWeber’s memorable phrase, “slow boring of hardboards”.

Hence, Big Bang reforms as conventionallyunderstood are an unreasonable and infeasiblestandard for evaluating the government’s reformactions.

Equally though, the mandate received by thegovernment affords a unique window of politicalopportunity which should not be foregone. Indianeeds to follow what might be called “a persistent,encompassing, and creative incrementalism”but with bold steps in a few areas that signal adecisive departure from the past and that are aimedat addressing key problems such as ramping upinvestment, rationalizing subsidies, creating acompetitive, predictable, and clean tax policyenvironment, and accelerating disinvestment.

Thus, Weber’s wisdom cannot be a licence forinaction or procrastination. Boldness in areaswhere policy levers can be more easily pulled bythe center combined with that incrementalism inother areas is a combination that can cumulate overtime to Big Bang reforms. That is the appropriatestandard against which future reforms must beassessed.

2 Financial sector issues were discussed extensively in last year’s Survey.

Page 3: Economic Outlook, Prospects, and€¦ · budget, a momentous opportunity awaits. India has reached a sweet spot—rare in the history of nations—in which it could finally be launched

3Economic Outlook, Prospects, and Policy Challenges

1.2. MACROECONOMIC REVIEW AND

OUTLOOK

Macroeconomic fundamentals havedramatically improved for the better, reflectedin both temporal and cross-countrycomparisons.

Start first with the changing macro-economiccircumstances. The changing fortunes of India havebeen nothing short of dramatically positive (Figure1.1). Inflation has declined by over 6 percentagepoints since late 2013, and the current accountdeficit has shrivelled from a peak of 6.7 percentof GDP (in Q3, 2012-13) to an estimated 1.0percent in the coming fiscal year. Foreign portfolioflows (of US$ 38.4 billion since April 2014) havestabilized the rupee, exerting downward pressureon long-term interest rates, reflected in the yieldon 10-year government securities, and contributedto the surge in equity prices (31 percent since Aprilin rupee terms, and even more in US dollars,ranking it the highest amongst emerging markets).In a nearly 12-quarter phase of deceleration,economic growth averaged 6.7 percent but since2013-14 has been growing at 7.2 percent onaverage, the later based on the new growthestimates (see Box 1.1 on how to interpret them).

As a result of these improvements, India’smacroeconomic position now comparesfavourably with other countries. Figure 1.2 depictsan overall macro-vulnerability index (MVI) thatcombines a country’s fiscal deficit, current accountdeficit, and inflation. The index is thus comparableacross countries and across time. In 2012, Indiawas the most vulnerable country as measured byits index value of 22.4, comprising an inflationrate of 10.2 percent, a budget deficit of 7.5 percentand a current account deficit of 4.7 percent ofGDP, well above that in the other countries. Turkeyin 2014 surpassed India because of high current

account deficit (of nearly 8 percent). Today, India’sfortunes have improved dramatically and Indiademonstrated the greatest improvement in theMVI while many others maintained the status quoor showed only a marginal improvement ordeteriorated dramatically (Russia). India is stillmore vulnerable than the mean of countries in itsinvestor rating category (BBB) but is less so thanmany of its larger emerging market peers.

If macro-economic stability is one key element inassessing a country’s situation/potential, its growth-actual and prospective- is another. A simple waytherefore to compare the relative economicsituation is to supplement the macro-economicvulnerability index with a “Rational Investor RatingsIndex (RIRI).”3 In assessing the risks and rewardsof competing destinations, rational investors takeinto account not just macroeconomic stability(which proxies for risks) but also growth whichcrucially determines rewards and returns.

In figure 1.3 this index is depicted for India and anumber of comparator countries, including theBRICS, other major emerging markets (Turkey)as well as countries in India’s investor ratingcategory (BBB) and category (A) that is aboveIndia’s. Regardless of whether Indian growth ismeasured according to the old methodology orthe new methodology (see Box 1.1), India exhibitsa dramatic improvement in the index.

India ranks amongst the most attractive investmentdestinations, well above other countries. It rankswell above the mean for its investment gradecategory, and also above the mean for theinvestment category above it (on the basis of thenew growth estimates). Amongst BRICS (andother comparable countries) only China scoresabove India. The reality and prospect of high andrising growth, combined with macroeconomicstability, is the promise of India going forward.

3The RIRI is computed by averaging a country’s GDP growth rate and its macro-economic indicators; the lattermeasured as the average of the fiscal deficit, current account deficit, and inflation (all with negative signs). Thus,equal weight is given to growth and macroeconomic stability. The greater the number, the better should be itsinvestor rating. Since, updated WEO forecasts are not publicly available for all countries, data are from Citi Groupand have been updated in January assuming an oil price in the range of US$ 58-60 per barrel for 2015. Data from othersources yield very similar estimates for the RIRI.

Page 4: Economic Outlook, Prospects, and€¦ · budget, a momentous opportunity awaits. India has reached a sweet spot—rare in the history of nations—in which it could finally be launched

4 Economic Survey 2014-15

Sources: Office of Economic Adviser, Department of Industrial Policy and Promotion, Central Statistics Office, ReserveBank of India and National Stock Exchange

Page 5: Economic Outlook, Prospects, and€¦ · budget, a momentous opportunity awaits. India has reached a sweet spot—rare in the history of nations—in which it could finally be launched

5Economic Outlook, Prospects, and Policy Challenges

Source: MoF calculations.

1.2A. Macro-economic management andpolicy reforms

Reforms have been initiated in a number ofareas and major ones are on the horizon. Themacroeconomic response to the favourableterms of trade shock has led to anappropriately prudent mix of increasedgovernment savings and private consumption.

The policy reforms of the new government—actualand prospective—have attracted worldwide

attention. The cumulative impact of these reformson reviving investment and growth could besignificant. Equally important though has beenmacro-economic management which needs to beassessed in simple analytical terms.Since June 2014, India has experienced a veryfavourable terms-of-trade shock as a result of a50-55 percent decline in the price of crude-oil andother commodities. The accepted injunction fromthe standard macroeconomic manual is thatresponses to terms-of-trade shocks should be

Page 6: Economic Outlook, Prospects, and€¦ · budget, a momentous opportunity awaits. India has reached a sweet spot—rare in the history of nations—in which it could finally be launched

6 Economic Survey 2014-15

Box 1.1 : Revised Estimates of GDP and GDP growthNotwithstanding the new estimates, the balance of evidence and caution counsel in favour of viewing India asa recovering rather than surging economy.

On January 30, the Central Statistics Office released a new GDP series that entailed shifting the base year from 2004-05 to 2011-12 but also using more data and deploying improved methodologies (Chapter 1 in the second volume ofthe Survey provides greater details). New estimates for GDP have been provided for the years 2011-12 to 2014-15.

How should one view these estimates? First, the improvement in data and methods puts India on par with internationalstandards of GDP estimation. India is perhaps unique in that GDP revisions result in lower numbers rather than thetypically high upward revision seen in many countries. The key estimate for the level of GDP for 2011-12, which isthe new base year, is actually 2 percent lower than previously estimated.

However, the growth estimates warrant further reflection. On the one hand, directionally the growth estimate for2014-15 relative to that for 2013-14 seems plausible and consistent with the fact of improving investor sentiment andreform actions.

On the other, both directionally and in level terms, the growth estimate for 2013-14 is puzzling. According to the newestimates, growth at market prices in 2013-14 apparently accelerated by 1.8 percentage points to 6.9 percent (1.5percentage points for growth at basic prices).

These numbers seem difficult to reconcile with other developments in the economy. 2013-14 was a crisis year—capital flowed out, interest rates were tightened, there was consolidation—and it is difficult to see how an economy’sgrowth rate could accelerate so much in such circumstances. Also, imports of goods in 2013-14 apparently declinedby 10 percent, which, even accounting for the squeeze on gold imports, is high. Growth booms are typicallyaccompanied by import surges not import declines. This boom was one over-reliant on domestic demand becausethe contribution of net external demand was substantially negative.

This growth surge also appears to have been accompanied by dramatic declines in savings and investment ratios.For example, gross fixed capital formation declined from 33.6 percent in 2011-12 to 29.7 percent in 2013-14 whilegross domestic savings declined from 33.9 percent to 30.6 percent. The implication is that the growth surge in thecrisis year of 2013-14 was also a massive productivity surge, reflected in an incremental capital ratio that declinedby about 30 percent, and total factor productivity growth that improved by over 2 percentage points. The datashow that private corporate investment increased robustly in 2013-14 which seems at odds with stressed balancesheets and the phenomenon of stalled projects.

Some clues to understanding the new series are provided in the chart below which decomposes the differencesbetween the new series into those relating to real GDP growth and those to the deflator. This decomposition isshown sectorally.

The largest discrepancies between the two series arise in 2013-14 and relate to real GDP growth for the manufacturingsector, where the magnitude is 6 percentage points! Even in 2012-13 the divergence between the two series inmanufacturing is 5 percentage points. Jumps in the level of the manufacturing share of GDP can be attributed to thenew methodology but it is still unclear why the rate of growth should diverge so much from previous estimates andfrom other indicators of manufacturing growth (viz. the index of industrial production). Even allowing for the factthat the latter is a volume index and the former a valued-added index, the discrepancy remains large. Clearly, theseissues need to be examined in greater detail.

Until a longer data series is available for analysis and comparisons, and until the changes can be plausibly ascribedto the respective roles of the new base, new data, and improved methodology, the growth narrative of the last fewyears may elude a fuller understanding. Regardless, the latest numbers will have to be the prism for viewing theIndian economy going forward because they will be the only ones on offer. But, the balance of evidence andcaution counsel in favour of an interpretation of a recovering rather than surging Indian economy.

Page 7: Economic Outlook, Prospects, and€¦ · budget, a momentous opportunity awaits. India has reached a sweet spot—rare in the history of nations—in which it could finally be launched

7Economic Outlook, Prospects, and Policy Challenges

Source: Central Statistics Office.

determined by their nature: a positive shock thatis perceived to be permanent should lead to largerconsumption increases because the country’spermanent income has increased; on the otherhand, temporary positive shocks should lead togreater savings. What has India done?

Given the uncertainty about the nature of theshock, India has appropriately hedged. Figure 1.4below compares the decline in international crude-oil prices with the corresponding decline indomestic retail prices of petrol and diesel. Sinceend-June 2014, the international price declinedby about 50 percent. Of this, about 17 percent(representing about 34 percent of the overalldecline) was passed on to consumers while thegovernment retained the rest. In other words, 66percent of the terms of trade shock went into thegovernment’s savings with the rest being passedon to consumers. (As detailed in section 1.12, thegovernment’s actions in this regard are also helpingin form of a de-facto carbon tax.) Accounting foruncertainty about the future movement of prices,the macro-economic response has appropriatelybalanced savings and consumption, and byfavouring the former, provided a necessary cushionto absorb the effects of higher oil prices in thefuture.

1.2B OUTLOOK FOR GROWTH

In the short run, growth will receive a boostfrom lower oil prices, from likely monetarypolicy easing facilitated by lower inflationand lower inflationary expectations, andforecasts of a normal monsoon. Medium-termprospects will be conditioned by the “balancesheet syndrome with Indian characteristics,”which has the potential to hold back rapidincreases in private sector investment.In the coming year, real GDP growth at marketprices is estimated to be about 0.6-1.1 percentagepoints higher vis-a-vis 2014-15. This increase iswarranted by four factors. First, the governmenthas undertaken a number of reforms and is planningseveral more (Box 1.2). Their cumulative growthimpact will be positive.A further impetus to growth will be provided bydeclining oil prices and increasing monetary easingfacilitated by ongoing moderation in inflation.Simulating the effects of tax cuts, declining oil priceswill add spending power to households, therebyboosting consumption and growth. Oil is also asignificant input in production, and declining priceswill shore up profit margins and hence balancesheets of the corporate sector. Declining input costsare reflected in the wholesale price index whichmoved to deflation territory in January 2015.

Page 8: Economic Outlook, Prospects, and€¦ · budget, a momentous opportunity awaits. India has reached a sweet spot—rare in the history of nations—in which it could finally be launched

8 Economic Survey 2014-15

Further declines in inflation and the resultingmonetary easing will provide policy support forgrowth both by encouraging household spendingin interest-sensitive sectors and reducing the debtburden of firms, strengthening their balance sheets.The final favourable impulse will be the monsoonwhich is forecast to be normal compared to lastyear4. Using the new estimate for 2014-15 as thebase, this implies growth at market prices of 8.1-8.5 percent in 2015-16.

The power of growth to lift all boats will dependcritically on its employment creation potential. Thedata on longer-term employment trends aredifficult to interpret because of the bewilderingmultiplicity of data sources, methodology andcoverage (see Box 1.3). One tentative conclusionis that there has probably been a decline in longrun employment growth in the 2000s relative tothe 1990s and probably also a decline in the

employment elasticity of growth: that is, a givenamount of growth leads to fewer jobs created thanin the past. Given the fact that labour force growth(roughly 2.2-2.3 percent) exceeds employmentgrowth (roughly about 1½ percent), the challengeof creating opportunities will remain significant.

1.2C Outlook for reforms

In the months ahead, several reforms will helpboost investment and growth. The budget shouldcontinue the process of fiscal consolidation,embedding actions in a medium-term framework.India’s overall revenue-to-GDP ratio (for thegeneral government) for 2014 is estimated at 19.5percent by the IMF. This needs to move towardlevels in comparator countries—estimated at 25percent for emerging Asian economies and 29percent for the emerging market countries in theG-20. At the same time, expenditure control should

Source: PPAC, Ministry of Petroleum & Natural Gas and PIB, Govt. of India.Note: Prices for petrol and diesel are all India average.

4.http://www.skymetweather.com/content/weather-news-and-analysis/el-nino-scare-abandoned-normal-indian-monsoon-likely-in-2015/

Page 9: Economic Outlook, Prospects, and€¦ · budget, a momentous opportunity awaits. India has reached a sweet spot—rare in the history of nations—in which it could finally be launched

9Economic Outlook, Prospects, and Policy Challenges

Box 1.2 : Reform Actions of the New GovernmentSince assuming office in May 2014, the new government has undertaken a number of new reform measureswhose cumulative impact could be substantial.

These include:

• Deregulating diesel prices, paving the way for new investments in this sector;

• Raising gas prices from US$ 4.2 per million British thermal unit to US$ 5.6, and linking pricing, transparentlyand automatically, to international prices so as to provide incentives for greater gas supply and therebyrelieving the power sector bottlenecks;

• Taxing energy products. Since October, taking advantage of declining oil prices, the excise tax on diesel andcoal was increased four times. In addition to resulting in collections of about ̀ 70,000 crore (on an annualizedbasis), this action will have positive environmental consequences, as explained in section 1.12;

• Replacing the cooking gas subsidy by direct transfers on a national scale;

• Instituting the Expenditure Management Commission, which has submitted its interim report for rationalizingexpenditures;

• Passing an ordinance to reform the coal sector via auctions;

• Securing the political agreement on the goods and services tax (GST) that will allow legislative passage of theconstitutional amendment bill;

• Instituting a major program for financial inclusion—the Pradhan Mantri Jan Dhan Yojana under which over12.5 crore new accounts have been opened till mid-February 2014;

• Continuing the push to extending coverage under the Aadhaar program, targeting enrollment for 1 billionIndians; as of early February, 757 million Indians had been bio-identified and 139-Aadhaar linked bank accountscreated;

• Increasing FDI caps in defense;• Eliminating the quantitative restrictions on gold;

• Passing an ordinance to make land acquisition less onerous, thereby easing the cost of doing business, whileensuring that farmers get fair compensation;

• Facilitating Presidential Assent for labour reforms in Rajasthan, setting an example for further reform initiativesby the states; and consolidating and making transparent a number of labour laws; and

• Passing an ordinance increasing the FDI cap in insurance to 49 percent. Commencing a program ofdisinvestments under which 10 percent of the government’s stake in Coal India was offered to the public,yielding about ̀ 22,500 crore, of which ̀ 5,800 crore was from foreign investors;

• Passing the Mines and Minerals (Development and Regulation) (MMDR) Amendment Ordinance, 2015 is asignificant step in revival of the hitherto stagnant mining sector in the country. The process of auction forallotment would usher in greater transparency and boost revenues for the States.

be consolidated while ensuring that there isswitching from public consumption to publicinvestment, with a focus on eliminating leakagesand improving targeting in the provision of subsidies.

To provide legal certainty and confidence toinvestors, the ordinances on coal, insurance, andland need to be translated into legislation approvedby Parliament. At the same time, the constitutionalamendment bill to implement the goods andservices tax (GST) also needs to be enshrined in

legislation first by Parliament followed byratification by the States. A single GST rate (acrossStates and products) set at internationallycompetitive levels with limited exemptions wouldmaximize its pro-growth, pro-compliance, andpro-single market creating potential.

While the framework for a modern andcomprehensive indirect tax system is being put inplace with the GST, parallel efforts are required

Page 10: Economic Outlook, Prospects, and€¦ · budget, a momentous opportunity awaits. India has reached a sweet spot—rare in the history of nations—in which it could finally be launched

10 Economic Survey 2014-15

Box 1.3: Employment Growth and Employment Elasticity: What is the Evidence?Estimates of employment growth and its elasticity relative to economic growth vary widely. However, tentatively,one might say that employment growth and elasticity have declined in the 2000s compared to the 1990s. Sincelabour force growth is in excess of employment growth, labour absorption will be a challenge. Reforms andfaster economic growth will be central to meeting it.

If the new GDP estimates have raised questions about our understanding of recent economic developments,deciphering patterns of employment growth is no less a challenge. There is almost a bewildering variety of estimateson employment growth in India. Data come from multiple sources, for different time periods, coverage and samplesizes, with varying methodologies. These are described in the table below.

What do these sources tell us about employment growth and the elasticity of employment growth with respect toGDP growth for the 1990s and 2000s?1 The results are summarized in the table below.

All establishmentsincluding the unorganizedsector and excluding cropproduction, plantation,public administration,defence and compulsorysocial security.

All factories registeredunder Sections 2m(i) and2m(ii) of the Factories Act,1948 + all electricityundertakings engaged ingeneration, transmissionand distribution ofelectricity registered withthe Central ElectricityAuthority (CEA)

Notes: 1. Census classifies employed as main and marginal.2. NSS accounts for both principal and subsidiary status of employment.

3. From the Labour Bureau survey, we estimate population for the age group 15 and above.4. For ASI data from 2000-01 to 2003-04, the census field was modified to include units employing 100 and more

workers instead of 200 and more workers. Therefore post 2000-01 data are not strictly comparable with that ofprevious rounds.

Table : Periodicity, Coverage and Population size of different Data SourcesSl. Data Source Periodicity Sector Coverage Population/Sample

1 Census Decadal All Population

2 Labour Bureau (LB) Annual All Sample (1.37 lakh households,6.80 lakh persons in 2013-14survey)

3 National Sample Quinquennial All Sample (1.02 lakh households,Survey (NSS) 4.57 lakh persons in 2011-12

round)

4 Economic Census (EC) No fixed periodicity Sample (25 lakh households,56 million establishments in2014 EC)

5 Annual Survey of Annual 2.17 lakh factories in 2012-13Industries (ASI) survey

Page 11: Economic Outlook, Prospects, and€¦ · budget, a momentous opportunity awaits. India has reached a sweet spot—rare in the history of nations—in which it could finally be launched

11Economic Outlook, Prospects, and Policy Challenges

Table : Employment Growth And Employment Elasticities

CENSUS NSS LABOUR ECONOMIC ASIBUREAU CENSUS

1991 2001 1993-94 1999-00 2011-12 1990 1998 1990-91 2003-04to to to 1999- to to to to to to

2001 2011 2000 2011-12 2013-14 1998 2014 1998-99 2012-13Change in Employment 88.4 79.2 25.5 73.4 9.15 12.9 44.4 0.43 5.07(million)Employment Growth 2.5 1.8 1.1 1.4 1.0 2.1 2.7 0.6 5.7GDP Growth 5.7 7.7 6.8 7.3 4.6 6.1 6.6 5.5 10.7Employment Elasticity 0.44 0.24 0.16 0.19 0.22 0.35 0.41 0.12 0.54

on the direct tax side. The objective should be tocreate a competitive, predictable, clean, andexemptions-light tax policy regime that will lowerthe cost of capital, incentivize savings, and facilitatetaxpayer compliance.

The government and the RBI need to concludethe monetary policy framework agreement toconsolidate the recent gains in inflation control andcodify into an institutional arrangement what hasbecome the de facto practice. This would signal

that both government and RBI jointly share theobjectives of low and stable inflation.

Reforms of labor and land laws and reducing thecosts of doing business will need to be a jointendeavor of the States and Center (see Box 3 ofthe Mid-Year Economic Analysis 2014-15 foran elaboration). The game-changing potential ofimplementing the GST and moving to technology-enabled Direct Benefit Transfers— which we callthe JAM (Jan Dhan-Aadhaar-Mobile) NumberTrinity solution-should not be underestimated.

A few very tentative conclusions can be drawn from what are fairly noisy estimates. Aggregateemployment growth has been above 2 percent in the 1990s. The Census and Economic Census arefairly close to each other in this regard, although the NSS data paints a different picture. Employmentgrowth declines to between 1.4 and 1.8 percent in the 2000s according to both the Census and NSS.In contrast, employment growth in organized industry exhibits the opposite temporal pattern, withsubstantially higher employment growth in the 2000s compared with the 1990s.

A similar pattern is suggested for the employment elasticity of growth: higher elasticity of about 0.35-0.44 in the 1990s and a drop to close to 0.2 in the 2000s. The most recent data from the LabourBureau indicates that since 2011-12 too, the employment elasticity has remained low. Employmentabsorption was evidently less successful in the last decade.

Regardless of which data source is used, it seems clear that employment growth is lagging behindgrowth in the labour force. For example, according to the Census, between 2001 and 2011, laborforce growth was 2.23 percent (male and female combined). This is lower than most estimates ofemployment growth in this decade of closer to 1.4 percent. Creating more rapid employmentopportunities is clearly a major policy challenge.1In computing the employment elasticity, consistency of coverage between the employment and growth data isensured to the extent possible. For example, for EC data, manufacturing GDP is used as the relevant base; while forASI data gross value addition (deflated by Manufacturing GDP) is used as the base in the computations.References: Misra, Sangita and Anoop K Suresh “Estimating Employment Elasticity of Growth for the Indian Economy”,

2014, RBI Working Paper Series 6.

Mehrotra, Santosh “Explaining Employment Trends in the Indian Economy: 1993-94 to 2011-12”, 2014,Economic and Political Weekly, XLIX(32).

Page 12: Economic Outlook, Prospects, and€¦ · budget, a momentous opportunity awaits. India has reached a sweet spot—rare in the history of nations—in which it could finally be launched

12 Economic Survey 2014-15

1.3 INFLATION AND MONEY

Structural shifts in the inflationary processare underway caused by lower oil prices anddeceleration in agriculture prices and wages.These are simultaneously being reflected indramatically improved household inflationexpectations. The economy is likely to over-perform on the RBI’s inflation target byabout 0.5-1.0 percentage point, opening upthe space for further monetary policy easing.

As elaborated in the Mid-Year EconomicAnalysis 2014-15, the evolution in inflation hassurprised market participants and policy makers,including the RBI. The momentum, measured asthe three month average seasonally adjusted andannualized, has declined from nearly 15 percentto below 5 percent (Figure 1.5).5 Interestingly, themomentum of food prices has declined even moreand is at levels below overall inflation.

Going forward, this momentum is likely to persistbecause of three striking developments in threeareas that signal a structural shift in the inflationaryprocess in India: crude-oil, agriculture, andinflation expectations.

Crude-oil prices are expected to remain benign inthe coming months. Indeed, the average ofestimates by the IMF for (crude spot) and by theUS Energy Information Administration (EIA) forBrent and West Texas Intermediate crude indicatesthat oil prices will be about 29 percent lower in2015-16 compared with 2014-15 (US$ 59 versusUS$ 82) (Figure 1.6).

The risk that the decline in oil prices will reverseitself always exists because of unpredictable geo-political developments. However, the persistenceof moderated oil prices seems highly probable forat least three reasons: weaker global demand,increased supplies, and the global monetary andliquidity environment.

Demand will remain soft because of slow growthin major areas of the world economy, includingChina and Europe. Supply shifts are occurringrelated to the increase in crude-oil and shale gasproduction in the US and the concomitant declinein the oligopolistic power of OPEC, notably itsswing producer, Saudi Arabia (which decided notto react to the increase in supply from othersources). Going forward, prices could increasinglybe determined by the marginal cost of shaleproduction estimated at around US$ 60-65 perbarrel.6

Finally, the anticipated end to the abnormally lowinterest cycle in the US and the prospect of futurerate increases will favour extraction of oil overkeeping it in the ground, thereby further boostingsupply and keeping prices soft. Higher rates willalso lead to financial asset-reallocation away fromcommodities, especially oil, as a class into USfinancial instruments.

One lesson of the 2000s is instructive. This decadewitnessed an across-the-board increase incommodity prices partly on account of excessliquidity, created by synchronized monetary policyeasing in the advanced countries. Thatsynchronization has been broken by the divergingmacro-economic paths of the United States, whererecovery will lead to a reversion to normal monetarypolicy, on the one hand, and Europe and Japan,on the other, where policies may remain loose. Ofcourse, if China starts slowing and respondsthrough a combination of cheaper credit and adepreciating exchange rate, global liquidity couldsurge again but the US will still be in tighteningmode.

Second, in addition to oil prices, India’s inflationwill be shaped by pressures from agriculture,foreign and domestic. According to World Bankprojections, global agricultural prices will remainmuted- a likely decline of 4.8 percent in 2015

5 Figure 1.5 is based on the new, re-based (from 2010 to 2012) CPI index.6 Arezki, R & Olivier Blanchard, “The 2014 oil price slump: Seven key questions”, January 2015 accessed at

http://www.voxeu.org/article/2014-oil-price-slump-seven-key-questions.

Page 13: Economic Outlook, Prospects, and€¦ · budget, a momentous opportunity awaits. India has reached a sweet spot—rare in the history of nations—in which it could finally be launched

13Economic Outlook, Prospects, and Policy Challenges

Source: CSO.

Source: Thomson Reuters.

Page 14: Economic Outlook, Prospects, and€¦ · budget, a momentous opportunity awaits. India has reached a sweet spot—rare in the history of nations—in which it could finally be launched

14 Economic Survey 2014-15

relative to 2014. This will likely have a key impactin moderating increases in domestic supportprices.7

The most dramatic structural change relates to wagepressures. As shown in Figure 1.7, wage growthhas declined to about 3.6 percent from over 20percent. If these trends continue, rural wage growthcan continue to decelerate, further moderatinginflationary pressures.

The third factor relates to inflation expectations.Until recently, household surveys of inflationexpectation conducted by the RBI showed thatexpectations have been stubbornly persistent andat levels well above actual inflation. But in the mostrecent survey they dropped by nearly 7-8percentage points over all horizons (Figure 1.8).If this change conveys some information, inflation

expectations will increasingly be anchored at morereasonable levels, moderating wage setting.

In sum, the structural shift that was argued in theMid-Year Economic Analysis 2014-15 seemswell under way. Consumer price inflation which islikely to print at 6.5 percent for 2014-15 is likelyto decline further. Our estimate for 2015-16 is forCPI inflation to be in 5.0-5.5 percent range andfor the GDP deflator to be in the 2.8-3.0 percentrange. The implication is that the economy willover-perform on inflation which would clearthe path for further monetary policy easing.

Trends in financial markets suggest that there hasbeen a gradual easing of deposit rates in recentfew months as yields on 10 year government bondshave been falling consistently during this period(Figure 1.9). Declining yields could trigger

Source: Labour Bureau.

7 The domestic production of oilseeds and pulses is likely to be below target, but greater imports could help dampeninflationary impulses from this sector.

Page 15: Economic Outlook, Prospects, and€¦ · budget, a momentous opportunity awaits. India has reached a sweet spot—rare in the history of nations—in which it could finally be launched

15Economic Outlook, Prospects, and Policy Challenges

reduction in lending rates by banks in the comingmonths. With the easing of inflationary conditions,the RBI has already signalled a shift in the monetarypolicy stance when it cut policy repo rates by 25basis points to 7.75 percent in January 2015. Insome ways, further monetary policy easing wouldentail the policy rate catching up with market rates.

Liquidity conditions have remained broadlybalanced so far during 2014-15. Theimplementation of a revised liquidity managementframework has helped in reducing volatility in theovernight inter-bank segment and better anchoringthe call rate near the policy rate. With the fiscaldeficit to remain under control and the new liquiditymanagement framework in place, liquidityconditions are expected to remain comfortable in2015-16.

1.4 EXTERNAL SECTOR

The outlook is favourable for the currentaccount and its financing. A likely surfeit,rather than scarcity, of foreign capital willcomplicate exchange rate management. Risksfrom a shift in US monetary policy andturmoil in the Eurozone need to be watchedbut could remain within control.

The outlook for the external sector is perhaps themost favourable since the 2008 global financialcrisis, and especially compared to 2012-13, whenelevated oil and gold imports fuelled a surge in thecurrent account deficit. Global crude petroleumprices averaged about US$ 47/ bbl in January2015 and about US$ 90/bbl for the year as a whole(April 2014-January 2015). Assuming a furthermoderation in average annual price of crudepetroleum and other products, the current accountdeficit is estimated at about 1.3 per cent of GDPfor 2014-15 and less than 1.0 per cent of GDP in2015-16.

A rule of thumb is that a US$10 reduction in theprice of oil helps improve the net trade and hencecurrent account balance by US$ 9.4 billion.Moderated gold imports will also help sustain amanageable current account deficit. Since theelimination of restrictions on gold in November,gold imports have fallen well below the elevatedlevels seen in 2013. Declining internationalprices as well as moderating inflation have meantthat gold imports averaged US$ 1.3 billion inDecember 2014 and US$ 1.6 billion in January2015 compared with US$ 4.2 billion in October2014 and US$ 5.6 billion in November 2014.

Source: RBI.

Page 16: Economic Outlook, Prospects, and€¦ · budget, a momentous opportunity awaits. India has reached a sweet spot—rare in the history of nations—in which it could finally be launched

16 Economic Survey 2014-15

The outlook for external financing iscorrespondingly favourable, and surfeit rather thanscarcity may pose the greater challenge. Financialflows in 2014-15 are likely to be in excess of US$55 billion, leading to a sizeable accretion toreserves by about US$ 26 billion, to about US$340 billion (Figure 1.10). This has been facilitatedby extensive RBI exchange market intervention.These inflows are likely to continue through a largepart of 2015-16. A key implication is that if thecurrent account deficit is lower, a given level ofcapital inflows will create greater upward pressureon the rupee.

One source of concern is muted export growthand rising non-oil, non-gold imports which couldbe affected by India’s deterioratingcompetitiveness, reflected in the appreciation ofthe real effective exchange rate by 8.5 per centsince January 2014. The interesting fact here isthat higher inflation in India relative to tradingpartners is contributing only 2.3 percentage points,with the remaining 6.2 percentage points accountedfor by the rupee strengthening in nominal termsagainst other currencies. In other words, surgingcapital inflows, notwithstanding the intervention by

the RBI both in spot and forward markets,accounts for the bulk of the deterioratingcompetitiveness.

Reconciling the benefits of these flows with theirimpact on exports and the current account remainsan important challenge going forward. The RBI,in other words, will be on the trident of the macro-economic trilemma, struggling to reconcile capitalaccount openness and surging inflows, monetarypolicy independence, and the economy’scompetitiveness.

Four factors pose risks to the external situation:

• renewed financial market volatility inresponse to US Federal Reservemonetary tightening which is expectedlater this year;

• possible turmoil if the viability of theEurozone were to come into questionin the event of a Greek exit;

• a spike in oil prices related togeopolitical events; and

• a slowly deteriorating internationaltrade environment.

Source: Bloomberg.

Page 17: Economic Outlook, Prospects, and€¦ · budget, a momentous opportunity awaits. India has reached a sweet spot—rare in the history of nations—in which it could finally be launched

17Economic Outlook, Prospects, and Policy Challenges

Two points are worth noting on the risks emanatingfrom the Fed and Eurozone.

First, India may be vulnerable because a substantialportion of the foreign flows since March 2014 areinterest sensitive. Of the total portfolio cumulativeflows (US$ 38.4 billion), about US$ 23.8 billionhave been portfolio debt flows. The decline in yieldson government and corporate bonds shown inFigure 1.9 reflects these flows. Fed tighteningcould lead to reversal of some of these inflows,placing downward pressure on the rupee.

However, India is more resilient today than in 2014or 2013 not only because of greater reserves, butmore importantly, due to a healthier macro-economic position. While complacency is neverwarranted, over-anxiety should also be kept atbay. In the medium-term, it is perhaps the tradechallenge that is a greater source of concern (seesection 1.11 below).

A larger issue on the external front is geo-strategic.If power used to flow from the barrel of a gun, inan increasingly inter-dependent economic world,

Source: RBI.

Source: RBI.

Page 18: Economic Outlook, Prospects, and€¦ · budget, a momentous opportunity awaits. India has reached a sweet spot—rare in the history of nations—in which it could finally be launched

18 Economic Survey 2014-15

hard and soft power derive from a war-chest offoreign exchange reserves. China’s abundantreserves have highlighted this fact. Reservesprovide a cushion against shocks, creatingeconomic and financial resilience. But they alsocreate geo-political influence.

Today, China has de-facto become one of thelenders of last resort to governments experiencingfinancial troubles. It has also become one of thebigger providers of development assistance bothbilaterally and plurilaterally. China, in its ownheterodox and multiple ways, is assuming the rolesof both an International Monetary Fund and aWorld Bank as a result of its reserves. Theacquisition of reserves is not costless because itrequires a policy of mercantilism and consequentialdistortion of financial and exchange markets. Butthere is a cost-benefit analysis that needs to beundertaken. The question for India, as a risingeconomic and political power, is whether it tooshould consider a substantial addition to itsreserves, preferably its own reserves acquiredthough running cumulative current accountsurpluses, possibly targeting a level of US$ 750billion- 1 trillion over the long run.

1.5 AGRICULTURE

The First Advance Estimate of Kharif crops (July-September 2014) indicates lower productioncompared to the last year. However, the estimateis generally revised upwards. The Rabi crops datareleased by the Directorate of Economics andStatistics recently indicates that although the totalarea coverage has declined, area under wheat hasgone down marginally by 2.9 per cent.Nevertheless, for 2014-15, the CSO has estimateda positive growth rate of 1.1 per cent for agriculturedespite lower rainfall that was only 88 per cent oflong-period average, and following a bumper yearin 2013-14. The CSO estimate is value-addedwhile agricultural production data are volume

based, hence positive agricultural GDP growth isnot inconsistent with volume declines because inputcosts have declined sharply.

But perhaps a deeper shift in agriculture may beunder way which calls for greater attention to thissector. The decade long shift in the terms of tradetoward agriculture may have come to an end asglobal agricultural prices have peaked. This isillustrated in figure 1.12 which plots the terms oftrade for agriculture according to two differentmeasures. Both show a slow decline after 2010-11, following several years of improvement.8

As the terms of trade deteriorate and as ruralincomes come under pressure (see also Figure1.7), the political pressure for support will increase.Already, there have been proposals to raise tariffsin a number of sectors like oilseeds and pulsesand to provide export subsidies in sugar.

One response in the short run must be to enhancetargeted support for the vulnerable in agriculture,namely the small farmer and agricultural labourer.The MGNREGA program has the virtue of beingreasonably well-targeted. The challenge here is tobuild on this feature and use the program to buildassets such as rural roads, micro-irrrigation andwater management, while also shoring up ruralincomes.

In the medium-term, the time is ripe for a morebroad-based response to the challenges inagriculture and to ensure that agriculture grows atabout 4 percent on a sustained basis.

One of the most striking problems is howunintegrated and distortions-ridden are ouragricultural markets (see chapter 8 of this volume,which also offers possible solutions). India needsa national common market for agriculturalcommodities by making the Agricultural ProduceMarket Committees (APMCs) just one among

8 The TOT indices are based on the following formulae adopted by the Group (WG) in May 2012 under thechairmanship of Professor S. Mahendra Dev.

100InvestmentCapitalandnConsumptioFinalInputs,FarmforPaidPrice ofIndex

ProductsFarmforReceived Price ofIndexTrade of Terms ofIndex (1) X

100InvestmentCapitalandnConsumptioFinalInputs,FarmforPaidPrice ofIndex

WagesalAgricultur and ProductsFarmforReceived Price ofIndexTrade of Terms ofIndex (2) X

Page 19: Economic Outlook, Prospects, and€¦ · budget, a momentous opportunity awaits. India has reached a sweet spot—rare in the history of nations—in which it could finally be launched

19Economic Outlook, Prospects, and Policy Challenges

many options available for the farmers to sell theirproduce.

Rationalisation of subsidies and better targeting ofbeneficiaries through direct transfers wouldgenerate part of the resources for the publicinvestment that is essential in research, education,extension, irrigation, water-management, soiltesting, warehousing and cold-storage. Distortionsemerging from various policies, including,exempting user charges for electricity and waterneed to be reduced, though better targeting andeliminating leakages.

The recommendations of the Shanta KumarCommittee provide useful suggestions for the futureroad-map of food-policy. The functioning of theFood Corporation of India needs to be revampedsubstantially.

There are also wide differences in the yields withinstates. Even the best of the states have much loweryield in different crops when compared to the bestin the world. This is evident from the Table 1.1below.

Vast amounts of cropped area (approximately 41percent) are still unirrigated. Providing irrigationcan improve yields substantially. For a shift in theunderlying production function, investment in basicresearch will be necessary. This provides ample

opportunity to increase production by bridging theyield-gap to the extent feasible within the climaticzone. Institutionally, the time may be ripe for re-assessing the role of the Indian Council ofAgricultural Research (ICAR), its relationshipswith the state agricultural universities as well aswith individual institutes (say the Indian AgriculturalResearch Institute or the National Dairy ResearchInstitute), and whether research, education, andextension should be separated.

To provide efficient advance price-discovery tofarmers and enable them to hedge price risks theForward Markets Commission is beingstrengthened. The concern that there may beunnecessary speculation should be addressedthough more effective regulation along the lines ofthe recommendations made by the Financial SectorLegislative Reforms Commission (FSLRC).

1.6 THE GROWTH-FISCAL POLICY

CHALLENGE

India can balance the short-term imperativeof boosting public investment to revitalizegrowth with the need to maintain fiscaldiscipline. Expenditure control andexpenditure switching, from consumption toinvestment, both in the upcoming budget andin the medium term will be key.

Source: Refer to footnote 8.

Page 20: Economic Outlook, Prospects, and€¦ · budget, a momentous opportunity awaits. India has reached a sweet spot—rare in the history of nations—in which it could finally be launched

20 Economic Survey 2014-15

The Medium-Term Fiscal Framework

Notwithstanding the challenging nature of the2014-15 budget, elaborated in the Mid-YearEconomic Analysis 2014-15, the Government willadhere to the fiscal target of 4.1 per cent of GDP.Despite weakness in revenue collection anddelayed disinvestment, new excises on diesel andpetrol (revenue yield of about ̀ 20,000 crores),reduced subsidies, and expenditure compressionwill ensure the commitment to discipline.

India can reconcile the requirements of fiscalconsolidation and the imperative of boosting publicinvestment to revive growth and crowd-in privateinvestment provided the right lessons are learnt.How so?

Since this is the first full budget of the newgovernment, and especially in light of the far-reaching recommendations of the FourteenthFinance Commission, the time is ripe for reviewingthe medium-term framework and setting targetsfor the upcoming year against that background andtaking account of the lessons of recent history(Figure 1.13).

Three phases marked recent fiscal history. In thefirst (2002-08), rapid growth improved all fiscalaggregates, flows and stocks. But failure to controlexpenditure, especially revenue expenditure,towards the end of that phase, combined withexcessive counter-cyclical policies in the secondphase (2009-12) led to a loss of fiscal control thatcontributed to the near-crisis of 2013. A casualtyhas been low and stagnating capital expenditure.In the third phase (2013-today), a modicum of

fiscal stability has been restored. This historysuggests the following strategy going forward.

First, in the medium term, India must meet itsmedium-term target of 3 percent of GDP. Thiswill provide the fiscal space to insure against futureshocks and also to move closer to the fiscalperformance of its emerging market peers. It mustalso reverse the trajectory of recent years andmove toward the ‘golden rule’ of eliminatingrevenue deficits and ensuring that, over the cycle,borrowing is only for capital formation.

Second, the way to achieve these targets will beexpenditure control and expenditure switching fromconsumption to investment. And the secular declinein capital expenditure in the last decade hasundermined India’s long run growth potential. From2016-17, as growth gathers steam and as the GSTis implemented, the consequential tax buoyancywhen combined with expenditure control will ensurethat medium term targets can be comfortably met.This buoyancy is assured by history because overthe course of the growth surge in the last decade,the overall tax-GDP ratio increased by about 2.7percentage points, from 9.2 percent in 2003-04to 11.9 per cent in 2007-08 even without radicaltax reform.

Third, the medium-term commitment to disciplinecannot result in an Augustinian deferment of actions.In the upcoming year, too, fiscal consolidation mustcontinue. However, the need for accelerated fiscalconsolidation has lessened because macro-economic pressures have significantly abated withthe dramatic decline in inflation and turnaround inthe current account deficit. In these circumstances,

Table 1.1: Crop Yield Comparison: India versus the WorldCrop India Highest Yield (State) World Highest YieldPaddy Punjab - 3952 China - 6661Wheat Punjab - 5017 UK - 7360Maize Tamil Nadu - 5372 USA - 8858Chickpeas Andhra Pradesh - 1439 Ethiopia - 1663Cotton Punjab - 750 Australia - 1920Rapeseed/Mustard Seed Gujarat - 1723 UK - 3588

Note: Figures are in yield/kg/hectare and pertain to 2012.

Page 21: Economic Outlook, Prospects, and€¦ · budget, a momentous opportunity awaits. India has reached a sweet spot—rare in the history of nations—in which it could finally be launched

21Economic Outlook, Prospects, and Policy Challenges

Source: Budget Documents and CSO.Note: Numbers for 2013-14 and 2014-15 are revised estimates and budget estimates, respectively.

especially if the economy is recovering rather thansurging, pro-cyclical policy is less than optimal.

Debt dynamics also remain favourable goingforward, ensuring a steady strengthening of publicsector balance sheets. Further, accelerated fiscalconsolidation will have to be conditioned in theupcoming fiscal year by a number of new andexceptional factors, such as implementing therecommendations of the Fourteenth FinanceCommission, clearing the compensation obligationsto the states for the reduction in the central salestax in 2007-08 and 2008-09, and the need toincrease public investment.

Nevertheless, to ensure fiscal credibility, andconsistency with the medium-term goals, theupcoming budget should initiate the process ofexpenditure control to reduce both the fiscal andrevenue deficits. At the same time, the quality ofexpenditure needs to be shifted from consumption,by reducing subsidies, toward investment. Broadlyspeaking, the additional space opened up, includingthrough a reduction in subsidies and higherdisinvestment proceeds, should be occupied bypublic investment. Increases in the tax-GDP ratio,

stemming from the excise tax increases onpetroleum products, will also help achieve bothshort and medium term fiscal goals.

1.7 WIPING EVERY TEAR FROM EVERY

EYE: THE JAM NUMBER TRINITY SOLUTION

The debate is not about whether but how bestto provide active government support to thepoor and vulnerable. Cash-based transfersbased on the JAM number trinity—Jan Dhan,Aadhaar, Mobile— offer exciting possibilitiesto effectively target public resources to thosewho need it most. Success in this area willallow prices to be liberated to perform theirrole of efficiently allocating resources andboosting long-run growth.

Sixty eight years after Independence, povertyremains one of India’s largest and most pressingproblems. No nation can become great when thelife chances of so many of its citizens are benightedby poor nutrition, limited by poor learningopportunities, and shrivelled by genderdiscrimination (discussed in section 1.13). The

Page 22: Economic Outlook, Prospects, and€¦ · budget, a momentous opportunity awaits. India has reached a sweet spot—rare in the history of nations—in which it could finally be launched

22 Economic Survey 2014-15

recent Annual Survey of Education Report (ASER),which shows stagnation in learning outcomes overthe past decade, makes for sobering reading (seeBox in Volume 2, Chapter 9).

Economic growth is good for the poor, bothdirectly because it raises incomes and because itgenerates resources to invest in the public servicesand social safety nets that the poor need. Growth– and the prospects and opportunities that it brings– also encourages individuals to invest in their ownhuman capital. A recent study found strikingly thatmerely informing families in villages outsideBangalore that call centres were hiring educatedwomen increased the likelihood that adolescentgirls in those villages completed school9.

However, growth must be complemented witheffective state-delivered programs that raise theliving standards of the most vulnerable in society.To be successful, anti-poverty programs mustrecognise that policies shape the incentives ofindividuals and firms, and also acknowledge thelimited implementation capacity of the state totarget and deliver public services to the poor.

Both the central and state governments subsidisea wide range of products with the expressedintention of making these affordable for the poor.Rice, wheat, pulses, sugar, kerosene, LPG,naphtha, water, electricity, fertiliser, iron ore,railways – these are just a subset of the productsand services that the government subsidises. Theestimated direct fiscal costs of these (select)subsidies are about ̀ 378,000 crore or about 4.2percent of GDP. This is roughly how much it wouldcost to raise the expenditure of every householdto that of a household at the 35th percentile of theincome distribution10 (which is well above thepoverty line of 21.9 percent11 ). Table 1.2 below

presents some rough, illustrative estimates of thecost of these subsidies and who benefits from them.

Price subsidies, no doubt provide help, but theymay not have a transformative effect on theeconomic lives of the poor. For many subsidies,only a small fraction of the benefits actually accrueto the poor. For example, electricity subsidiesbenefit mainly the (relatively wealthy) 67.2 percentof households that are electrified12. A large fractionof subsidies allocated to water utilities are spenton subsidising private taps when 60 percent ofpoor households get their water from public taps13.

Moreover, the implementation of subsidies can befiendishly complex. In the case of fertilizers, theyare firm-specific and import-consignment specific,they vary by type of fertilizer, and some are on afixed-quantity basis while others are variable.

Subsidies are also susceptible to the brutal logicof self-perpetuation. In the case of sugar, to protectsugar cane producers high support prices areawarded; to offset this tax on mill owners, theyare supported through subsidized loans and exportsubsidies; and then they are again taxed by placingrestrictions on sales of molasses that are producedas a by-product.

Different subsidies also interact to hurt the poor.For example, fertiliser manufacturers do not havethe incentive to sell their product in hard-to-accessregions, since price controls mean that prices aresimilar everywhere, so freight subsidies on railwayshave been introduced to incentivise manufacturersto supply their produce widely. But those subsidiesare sometimes insufficient, since freight rates areamong the highest in the world, and intentionallyso, to cross-subsidise artificially low passengerfares. This is an example of how a mesh of well-meaning price controls distort incentives in a waythat ultimately hurt poor households.

9 Jensen, Robert, “Do Labor Market Opportunities Affect Young Women’s Work and Family Decisions? ExperimentalEvidence from India” 2012, Quarterly Journal of Economics.

10 Economic Survey of India 2014-15, Vol. I, Chapter 3.11 Planning Commission, July 2013, reporting on the Tendulkar Commission (http://planningcommission.nic.in/

news/pre_pov2307.pdf)12 Census of India (2011), Source of Lighting.13 Do Current Water Subsidies reach the poor?, MIT and World Bank working paper (http://web.mit.edu/

urbanupgrading/waterandsanitation/resources/pdf-files/WaterTariff-4.pdf)

Page 23: Economic Outlook, Prospects, and€¦ · budget, a momentous opportunity awaits. India has reached a sweet spot—rare in the history of nations—in which it could finally be launched

23Economic Outlook, Prospects, and Policy Challenges

Table 1.2 : How much do subsidies benefit the poorProduct Producer Consumer Fiscal Fiscal What share of benefits accrue

subsidy subsidy expenditure expenditure to the poor? (Cr.) (percent of

2011-12GDP)Railways N/A Subsidised ` 51,000 0.57 The bottom 80 percent of

passenger households constitute onlyfares¹ 28.1 percent of total passenger

through fare on railwaysLiquefied N/A Subsidy ` 23,746 0.26 The bottom 50 percent ofpetroleum gas (now via DBT) households only consume 25

percent of LPGKerosene N/A Subsidy via PDS ` 20,415 0.23 41 percent of PDS kerosene

allocation are lost as leakage, andonly 46 percent of the remainder isconsumed by poor households

Fertiliser & Firm and nutrient Maximum ` 73,790 0.82 Urea and P&K manufacturersnitrogenous specific subsidies derive most economic benefitcommodities to manufacturers. from the subsidy, since farmers,

Import of urea especially poor farmers, haveregulated by elastic demand for fertiliserthe government

Rice (paddy) 15 percent of PDS rice is lost asleakage. Households in thebottom 3 deciles consume 53percent of the remaining 85 percentthat reaches households

Wheat 54 percent of PDS wheat is lost asleakage. Households in the bottom3 deciles consume 56 percent of theremaining 46 percent that reacheshouseholds

Pulses Price floor Subsidy via ` 158 0.002 The bottom 3 deciles consume(MSP) PDS 36 percent of subsidised pulses

Electricity Subsidy Capped below ` 32,300 0.36 Average monthly consumptionmarket price of bottom quintile = 45 kWh vs top

quintile = 121 kWh. Bottom quintilecaptures only 10 percent of the totalelectricity subsidies, top quintilecaptures 37 percent of subsidy

Water N/A Subsidy ` 14,208 0.50 Most water subsidies are allocatedto private taps, whereas 60 percentof poor households get their waterfrom public taps

Sugar Minimum price Subsidy via ` 33,000 0.37 48 percent of PDS sugar is lostfor sugar PDS as leakage. Households in thecane farmers, bottom 3 deciles consumesubsidy to 44 percent of the remainingmills 52 percent that reaches householdsTotal ` 377,616 4.24

All expenditure deciles are based on data from the household expenditure module of the 68th Round of the NSS (2011-12)Railways – www.ncaer.org/free-download.php?pID=111 , p107 & NSS 68th roundLPG – Computations from the 68th Round of the NSS (2011-12)Kerosene – Economic Survey of India 2014-15, Vol. I ,Chapter 3.Fertiliser – Agricultural Input Survey, http://inputsurvey.dacnet.nic.in/nationaltable3.aspxRice & wheat – Economic Survey of India 2014-15,Vol. I, Chapter 3.Pulses – Computations from the 68th Round of the NSS (2011-12)Water – Report by MIT and World Bank http://web.mit.edu/urbanupgrading/waterandsanitation/resources/pdf-files/WaterTariff-4.pdf , p2Sugar – Department of Food & Public Distribution (http://dfpd.nic.in/fcamin/sugar/Notice1.pdf)

Price floor Subsidy via(minimum PDSsupport price)

` 129,000 1.14

Page 24: Economic Outlook, Prospects, and€¦ · budget, a momentous opportunity awaits. India has reached a sweet spot—rare in the history of nations—in which it could finally be launched

24 Economic Survey 2014-15

Fertiliser subsides illustrate another difficulty withusing price subsidies as a core anti-povertystrategy. The true economic incidence of a subsidydepends on the relative elasticities of demand andsupply, with the party less responsive to pricechanges benefiting more from a subsidy. Theultimate aim of subsidising fertiliser is to providefarmers with access to cheap fertilisers toincentivise usage and cultivation of high-yieldingvarieties. Yet because it is likely that farmers’demand for fertiliser is more sensitive to prices14

than fertiliser manufacturers’ supply, the largershare of economic benefits from the price subsidyprobably accrue to the fertiliser manufacturer andthe richer farmer who accounts for a larger shareof fertiliser consumption, not the beneficiary mostin need, namely the poor farmer.High minimum support for rice and wheat distortcrop choice, leading to water-intensive cultivationin areas where water tables have been droppinglike a stone, and ultimately induce greater pricevolatility in non-MSP supported crops which hurtsconsumers, especially poor households who havevolatile incomes and lack the assets to weathereconomic shocks. High MSPs also penalise risk-taking by farmers who have ventured into non-traditional crops.At first glance, kerosene seems a good candidatefor price subsidies as it is popularly conceived tobe consumed mostly by the poor, and yet workdone in this Survey (Chapter 3) based on NSSdata show that only 59 percent of subsidisedkerosene allocated via the PDS is actuallyconsumed by households, with the remainder lostto leakage, and only 46 percent of totalconsumption is by poor households. Even in thecase of the food distributed via the PDS, leakagesare very high (about 15 percent for rice and 54percent for wheat, with most of these leakagesconcentrated in the APL segment).

This illustrates the importance of basing anti-poverty policy on data rather than popularperception. It also underscores the need forpolicymakers to acknowledge as a first-orderconcern the state’s own constraints in implementingeffective, well-targeted programs.

Technology is increasingly affording better meansfor the government to improve the economic livesof the poor. The JAM Number Trinity– Jan DhanYojana, Aadhaar and Mobile numbers— mightwell be a game changer because it expands theset of welfare and anti-poverty policies that thestate can implement in future. These technologicalinnovations have renewed academic interest in thepotential of direct cash transfers to help the poor.Recent experimental evidence documents thatunconditional cash transfers – if targeted well –can boost household consumption and assetownership and reduce food security problems forthe ultra-poor.15

Cash transfers can also augment the effectivenessof existing anti-poverty programs, like theMGNREGA. A recent study16 reported evidencefrom Andhra Pradesh where MGNREGA andsocial security payments were paid throughAadhaar-linked bank accounts. Householdsreceived payments faster with the new Aadhaar-linked DBT system, and leakages decreased somuch that the value of the fiscal savings – due toreduced leakages – were 8 times greater than thecost of implementing the program. Much of theleakage reduction resulting from biometricidentification stems from fewer ghost beneficiaries.Indeed, the government is already realizing thegains from direct benefit transfers areas by payingcooking gas subsidies directly into the bankaccounts of 9.75 crore recipients.

For the agriculture sector which is currently understress, this evidence creates possibilities. The virtue

14 One estimate suggests that farmers’ demand for fertiliser falls by nearly 6.4 percent for a 10 percent increase infertiliser prices. Dholakia, R.H. and Jagdip Majumdar, “Estimation of Price Elasticity of Fertilizer Demand inIndia”, 2006, Working Paper.

15 Johannes Haushofer & Jeremy Shapiro, “Household Response to Income Changes: Evidence from anUnconditional Cash Transfer Program in Kenya”, 2013, Working Paper.

16 Karthik Muralidharan, Paul Niehaus & Sandip Sukhtankar, “Building State Capacity: Evidence from BiometricSmartcards in India”, 2014, Working Paper.

Page 25: Economic Outlook, Prospects, and€¦ · budget, a momentous opportunity awaits. India has reached a sweet spot—rare in the history of nations—in which it could finally be launched

25Economic Outlook, Prospects, and Policy Challenges

of MGNREGA, for all its deficiencies, is that it isself-targeting. If the program could lead to thecreation of rural assets such as rural roads, micro-irrigation and water management infrastructure,and if leakages could be minimized through theJAM number trinity, rural India could witness boththe creation of opportunity and protection of thevulnerable.Today there are about 125.5 million Jan Dhan bankaccounts17, 757 million Aadhaar numbers, andapproximately 904 million mobile phones18. It ispossible to envisage that when the JAM trinitybecomes linked, the goal of periodic and seamlessfinancial transfers to bank accounts afteridentification through the Aadhaar number can beimplemented with immeasurable benefits to helpingthe lives of the poor. The heady prospect for theIndian economy is that, with strong investments instate capacity, that Nirvana today seems withinreach. It will be a Nirvana for two reasons—thepoor will be protected and provided for; and manyprices in India will be liberated to perform theirrole of efficiently allocating resources and boostinglong-run growth. Even as it focuses on second andthird generation reforms in factor markets, Indiawill then be able to complete the basic firstgeneration reforms. This will be the grand bargainin the political economy of Indian reforms.

1.8 GROWTH, PRIVATE AND PUBLIC

INVESTMENT

“The balance sheet syndrome with Indiancharacteristics” creates a web of difficultchallenges that could hold back privateinvestment. Private investment must remainthe primary engine of long-run growth. Butin the interim, to revive growth and to deepenphysical connectivity, public investment,especially in the railways, will have animportant role to play.

Since the new government assumed office, a slewof economic reforms has led to a partial revival of

investor sentiment. Tentative signs that the worstis over are evident for example in data that showsthat the rate of stalled projects has begun to declineand that the rate of their revival is inching up(Figure 1.14).

But increasing capital flows are yet to translateinto a durable pick-up of real investment, especiallyin the private sector. This owes to at least fiveinterrelated factors that lead to what the Mid-YearEconomic Analysis called the “balance sheetsyndrome with Indian characteristics.”

First, hobbled by weak profitability and weigheddown by over-indebtedness, the Indian corporatesector is limited in its ability to invest going forward(the flow challenge). One key indicator ofprofitability—the interest cover ratio, which if lessthan one implies firms’ cash flows are not sufficientto pay their interest costs—has also worsened inrecent years (Figure 1.15). Further, as the Figure1.16 shows, the debt-equity ratios of the top 500non-financial firms have been steadily increasing,and their level now is amongst the highest in theemerging market world.

Second, weak institutions relating to bankruptcymeans that the over-indebtedness problem cannotbe easily resolved (the stock and ‘difficulty-of-exit’ challenge). This is reflected in the persistenceof stalled projects which have been consistentlyaround 7 to 8 percent of GDP in the last four years.

Third, even if some of these problems were solved,the PPP model at least in infrastructure will needto be re-fashioned to become more viable goingforward (the institutional challenge).

Fourth, since a significant portion of infrastructurewas financed by the banking system, especiallythe public sector banks, their balance sheets havedeteriorated.19 For example, the sum of non-performing and stressed assets has risen sharply,and for the PSBs they account for over 12 percent

17 Pradhan Mantri Jan-Dhan Yojana progress report (http://www.pmjdy.gov.in/account-statistics-country.aspx)18 http://www.trai.gov.in/WriteReadData/WhatsNew/Documents/Presspercent20Release-TSD-Mar,14.pdf.19 According to RBI’s Financial Stability Report, December 2014, the contribution of mining, iron and steel, textiles,aviation and other infrastructure to total advances stands at 28 percent whereas their contribution in stressedassets is 54 percent.

Page 26: Economic Outlook, Prospects, and€¦ · budget, a momentous opportunity awaits. India has reached a sweet spot—rare in the history of nations—in which it could finally be launched

26 Economic Survey 2014-15

Source: CMIE.

of total assets (Figure 1.17). Uncertainty aboutaccounting and valuation, and indeed the historyof banking difficulties across time and space,counsel in favor of over- rather than under-recognizing the severity of the problem. Whenbanks’ balance sheets are stressed they are lessable to lend, leading to reduced credit for theprivate sector (the financing challenge).20

Finally, in a peculiarly Indian twist, this financingproblem is aggravated by generalized risk-aversion(the challenge of inertial decision-making). For thepublic sector banks in particular, which areexposed to governmental accountability andoversight, lending in a situation of NPAs is not easybecause of a generic problem of caution, afflictingbureaucratic decision-making.

Actions being undertaken by the government toenhance the supply of critical inputs such as coaland gas, as well as regulatory reform, will alleviatesome of these constraints, especially in the publicsector where the data identify them as beingregulatory in character (clearances and landacquisition). Steps are being taken to address theinstitutional problem, by creating a betterframework for PPPs and for infrastructure

investment in general. The RBI is making effortsto get banks to recognize their bad loan problems,and address them. But the impact of these initiativeshas so far been limited. The stock of stalled projectsremains extraordinarily high; firm profitability,especially for firms working in the infrastructuresector, remains low. So, questions on the pace andstrength of recovery of private sector investmentremain open.

If the weakness of private investment offers onenegative or indirect rationale for increased publicinvestment, there are also more affirmativerationales. India’s recent PPP experience hasdemonstrated that given weak institutions, theprivate sector taking on project implementationrisks involves costs (delays in land acquisition,environmental clearances, and variability of inputsupplies, etc.). In some sectors, the public sectormay be better placed to absorb some of these risks.Further, there continue to remain areas ofinfrastructure – rural roads and railways thatprovide basic physical connectivity- in whichprivate investment will be under-supplied. Oneirony is that while financial and digital connectivityare surging ahead, basic physical connectivityappears to lag behind.

20 Suggestions on how capital markets can play a greater role in infrastructure financing are elaborated in last year’sEconomic Survey.

Page 27: Economic Outlook, Prospects, and€¦ · budget, a momentous opportunity awaits. India has reached a sweet spot—rare in the history of nations—in which it could finally be launched

27Economic Outlook, Prospects, and Policy Challenges

Source: Bloomberg and J.P. Morgan.

Source: Credit Suisse (sample of 3,700 listed companies).

Therefore, as emphasized in the Mid YearEconomic Analysis 2014-15 it seems imperativeto consider the case for reviving targeted publicinvestment as an engine of growth in the short runnot to substitute for private investment but tocomplement it and indeed to crowd it in. The twochallenges of raising public investment relate tofinancing and capacity. Financing issues wereaddressed in section 1.6.Public sector implementation capacity in India isvariable. But the analysis in chapter 6 of this volumesuggests that the Indian Railways could be the nextlocomotive of growth. Greater public investment

in the railways would boost aggregate growth andthe competitiveness of Indian manufacturingsubstantially. In part, these large gains derive fromthe current massive under-investment in therailways. For example, China and India had similarnetwork capacities in until the mid-1990s butbecause it invested eleven times as much as Indiain per-capita terms, China’s capacity andefficiency have surged (Figure 1.18). In contrast,stagnant investment has led to congestion, strainedcapacity, poor services, weak financial health, anddeteriorating competitiveness of logistics-intensivesectors, typically manufacturing. Congestion has

Page 28: Economic Outlook, Prospects, and€¦ · budget, a momentous opportunity awaits. India has reached a sweet spot—rare in the history of nations—in which it could finally be launched

28 Economic Survey 2014-15

Source: World Bank.

Source: RBI.

effectively led to the railways ceding a significantshare in freight traffic to the roads sector. This isnot a welcome development since rail transport istypically more cost and energy efficient. The profitsgenerated by freight services have cross-subsidisedpassengers services and Indian freight rates (PPPadjusted) remain among the highest in the world.

What the previous NDA government did for roads,the present government could do for the railways,

strengthening the physical connectivity of the Indianpopulation, with enormous benefits in terms ofhigher standards of living, greater opportunities,and increased potential for human fulfillment.

1.9 THE BANKING CHALLENGE

Banking is hobbled by policy, which createsdouble financial repression, and by structuralfactors, which impede competition. The

Page 29: Economic Outlook, Prospects, and€¦ · budget, a momentous opportunity awaits. India has reached a sweet spot—rare in the history of nations—in which it could finally be launched

29Economic Outlook, Prospects, and Policy Challenges

solution lies in the 4 Ds of deregulation(addressing the statutory liquidity ratio (SLR)and priority sector lending (PSL)),differentiation (within the public sectorbanks in relation to recapitalisation,shrinking balance sheets, and ownership),diversification (of source of funding withinand outside banking), and disinterring (byimproving exit mechanisms).Discussions of banking in India have recentlyfocused on the problem of stressed andrestructured assets, the challenges in acquiring theresources to meet the looming Basel IIIrequirements on capital adequacy, including therespective contributions of the government andmarkets, and the need for governance reformreflected in the 2013 Nayak Committee Report.Stepping back from these proximate issues allowsa deeper analytical diagnosis of the problems ofIndian banking which in turn provide the basis formore calibrated solutions.A first question that arises is whether India is credit-addled and overbanked.

One way to assess this is to see whether Indianbanks were unusually imprudent in the boomphase.21 Figure 1.19 plots the domestic credit toGDP of a number of countries, as defined by theWorld Bank, during their period of rapid growth(these periods vary across countries) since the yearof “takeoff”. It shows that while the boom yearsof the last decade both spawned and were fed bya credit boom, originating in the public sectorbanks, irrationally exuberant behaviour was notout of line with similar experiences in othercountries. Indian credit grew no more rapidly thanelsewhere. For example, the Japanese and Chinesefinancial systems lent much more during their take-off years.

On the question of India being over-banked, weassess the share of banks in total credit for a cross-section of countries (Figure 1.20). The figure plotsthe ratio of banking credit to total credit in theeconomy less the government, which includes firmsand household22, against the level of development,as measured by the log of GDP per capita in PPP

Source: World Bank. Notes: Years of takeoff- Brazil, Japan and Korea: 1961, China: 1978, India: 1979.21 In Chapter 5 of this volume, we also test for how credit-addled India is based on other cross-sectional and time-series comparisons.22 As defined by the Bank for International Settlements, this includes credit to non-financial corporations (bothprivate-owned and public-owned), households and non-profit institutions serving households as defined in theSystem of National Accounts 2008.

Page 30: Economic Outlook, Prospects, and€¦ · budget, a momentous opportunity awaits. India has reached a sweet spot—rare in the history of nations—in which it could finally be launched

30 Economic Survey 2014-15

terms. The chart shows that India is not an outlier:that is for its level of development, the share ofbank credit is neither unusually high nor low. Ofcourse, if India grows at 8 percent a year for thenext twenty years, a rapid shift in the compositionof India’s financial sector away from banking maybe necessary and desirable.

Where then does the problem lie? The problemsin the Indian banking system lie elsewhere and fallinto two categories: policy and structure.

The policy challenge relates to financial repression.The Indian banking system is afflicted by what mightbe called “double financial repression” whichreduces returns to savers and banks, and mis-allocates capital to investors. Financial repressionon the asset side of the balance sheet is createdby the statutory liquidity ratio (SLR) requirementthat forces banks to hold government securities,and priority sector lending (PSL) that forcesresource deployment in less-than-fully efficientways23. Financial repression on the liability sidehas arisen from high inflation since 2007, leading

to negative real interest rates, and a sharp reductionin household savings. As India exits from liability-side repression with declining inflation, the timemay be appropriate for addressing its asset-sidecounterparts.

The structural problems relate to competition andownership. First, there appears to be a lack ofcompetition, reflected in the private sector banks’inability to increase their presence. Indeed, one ofthe paradoxes of recent banking history is that theshare of the private sector in overall bankingaggregates barely increased at a time when thecountry witnessed its most rapid growth and onethat was fuelled by the private sector. It was ananomalous case of private sector growth withoutprivate sector bank financing. Even allowing forthe over- exuberance of the PSBs that financedthis investment-led growth phase, the reticence ofthe private sector was striking (see Figure 1.21).

Second, there is wide variation in the performanceof the public sector banks measured in terms ofprudence and profitability. Figure 1.22 plots the

23 More details can be found in Chapter 5 of this volume.

Source: Bank for International Settlements.

Page 31: Economic Outlook, Prospects, and€¦ · budget, a momentous opportunity awaits. India has reached a sweet spot—rare in the history of nations—in which it could finally be launched

31Economic Outlook, Prospects, and Policy Challenges

Leverage Ratio and Return on Assets of publicsector and private sector banks24. In addition itplots (as dotted lines) the variation within the publicsector banks. In terms of actual numbers ofleverage ratios, taking a three year average, themost prudent PSB was 1.7 times more capitalisedthan the most imprudent one.

Despite the significant variation in public sectorbanks, it is also striking that on these measures,the best public sector banks perform well belowprivate sector banks on average, recognising ofcourse that PSBs may be burdened with greatersocial obligations that places them at a competitivedisadvantage relative to the private banks. Thesubtler problem with public sector ownership isthat exit from debt difficulties is proving verydifficult. If that is so, there is extra reason to worryabout public sector ownership ex-ante.

The diagnosis above (and in chapter 5) leads to afour-fold policy response captured in 4 Ds:deregulate, differentiate, diversify, and disinter.

Source: RBI.

As the banking sector exits the financial repressionon the liability side, aided by the fall in inflation,this is a good opportunity to consider relaxing theasset side repression. Easing SLR requirementswill provide liquidity to the banks, depth to thegovernment bond market, and encourage thedevelopment of the corporate bond market.Second, PSL norms too can be re-assessed. Thereare two options: one is indirect reform bringingmore sectors into the ambit of PSL, until in thelimit every sector is a priority sector; and the otheris to redefine the norms to slowly make PSL moretargeted, smaller, and need-driven.

There must be differentiation between the PSBsand the recent approach to recapitalization adoptedby the government is a step in the right direction.One size fits all approaches such as governancereform cannot be the most appropriate.Differentiation will allow a full menu of options suchas selective recapitalization, diluted governmentownership, and exit.

24 Leverage ratio is defined by the RBI as ratio of total assets to total capital (Tier 1 + Tier 2), the internationaldefinition, for example as laid out by the Bank for International Settlements, is typically the inverse. For the purposeof this volume we will use the international definition. Return on Assets (ROA) is a profitability ratio which indicatesthe net profit (net income) generated on total assets. It is computed by dividing net income by average total assets.

Page 32: Economic Outlook, Prospects, and€¦ · budget, a momentous opportunity awaits. India has reached a sweet spot—rare in the history of nations—in which it could finally be launched

32 Economic Survey 2014-15

‘‘Diversify’’ implies that there must be greatercompetition within the banking system, includingliberal licensing of more banks and different typesof banks. There must also be greater competitionfrom capital, especially bond, markets. Facilitatingthat will require exiting from asset side repression,namely the phasing down of the SLRs which wouldalso help develop bond markets.

‘‘Disinter’’ implies that exit procedures mustbecome more efficient. Debt Recovery Tribunalsare over-burdened and under-resourced, leadingto tardy resolution. The ownership structure andefficacy of Asset Restructuring Companies, inwhich banks themselves have significant stakes ofbanks, creates misaligned incentives. TheSecuritization and Reconstruction of FinancialAssets and Enforcement of Security Interest(SARFAESI) Act seems to be implemented mostvigorously against the smallest borrowers andMSEs. Mechanisms for distributing pain efficientlyamongst promoters, creditors, consumers, andtaxpayers without creating moral hazard incentivesfor imprudent lending by banks are necessary. Oneimportant lesson is that the clean-up is as importantas the run-up.

1.10 MANUFACTURING, SERVICES AND THE

CHALLENGES OF ‘‘MAKE IN INDIA’’Transformational sectors could be inregistered manufacturing or services. Raisingeconomy-wide skills must complement effortsto improve the conditions for manufacturing.

The Prime Minister has made the revival of Indianmanufacturing a top priority, reflected in his “Makein India” campaign and slogan. The objective is aslaudable as the challenges it faces are dauntingbecause Indian manufacturing has been stagnantat low levels, especially when compared with theEast Asian successes25.

Two questions arise. Is manufacturing the sectorthat Make in India focus on? What instrumentsshould be deployed to realize the objective?Consider each in turn.

New academic work suggests that there is acomplementary way of thinking abouttransformational sectors in and for development.Growth theory suggests that transformationalsectors should be assessed in light of theirunderlying characteristics and not just in terms of

Source: RBI.

25 The recent upward revisions to the level of manufacturing share in GDP are to some extent statistical rather than“real”. Moreover, even the revised data do not change the pattern of trend decline in this share. What hashappened is the statistical opposite of the technological change which Jagdish Bhagwati [“Splintering andDisembodiment of Services and Developing Nations”, 1984, The World Economy, 7(2)] referred to as ‘splintering’services from goods.

Page 33: Economic Outlook, Prospects, and€¦ · budget, a momentous opportunity awaits. India has reached a sweet spot—rare in the history of nations—in which it could finally be launched

33Economic Outlook, Prospects, and Policy Challenges

the traditional manufacturing-services distinction(Table 1.3). Five such important characteristicscan be identified.

High levels of productivity, so that incomescan increase;

Rapid rate of growth of productivity inrelation to the world frontier (internationalconvergence) as well as rapid growthtoward the national frontier (domesticconvergence);

A strong ability of the dynamic sector toattract resources, thereby spreading thebenefits to the rest of the economy;

Alignment of the dynamic sector with acountry’s underlying resources, whichtypically tends to be unskilled labor; and

Tradability of the sector, because thatdetermines whether the sector can expandwithout running into demand constraints,a feature that is important for a largecountry like India.

In India, it is important to remember that whenthinking about manufacturing as a transformationalsector it is registered or formal manufacturing that

possesses some of the critical prerequisites suchas high productivity and rapid growth inproductivity. Unregistered manufacturing cannotbe a transformational sector. Thus, efforts toencourage formalization will be critical.

The Indian evidence is that some sub-sectors inservices such as telecommunications and financeare like registered manufacturing in being highlyproductive and dynamic. However, these sectors,like registered manufacturing, have not been ableto attract large amounts of unskilled labour, limitingthe benefits of the underlying dynamism. In otherwords, the dynamic sectors have tended to be skill-intensive sectors in which India does notnecessarily have comparative advantage. Anexception is construction which is unskilled labour-intensive and which has been fairly dynamic.Construction, however, is not a tradable sector,which also limits its potential as a transformationalsector.

One policy conclusion that follows is that effortsto improve the conditions for labor-intensivemanufacturing need to be complemented with rapidskill upgradation because skill-intensive sectors aredynamic sectors in India and sustaining theirdynamism will require that the supply of skills keeps

Table 1.3: Transformational Properties of Different SectorsFeature Registered Trade, Hotels, Transport, Financial Real Estate Construc-

Manufactu- and Storage and Services and and Business tionring Restaurants Communi- Insurance Services, etc.

cations1. High productivity Yes No Not really Yes Yes No2A. Unconditional Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

domesticconvergence

2B. Unconditional Yes, but not No No Yes Yes Yesinternational for Indiaconvergence

3. Converging sector No Somewhat Somewhat No Somewhat Yesabsorbs resources

4. Skill profile matches Not really Somewhat Somewhat No No Yesunderlyingendowments

5. Tradable and/ Yes No Somewhat Yes Somewhat Noor replicable

Page 34: Economic Outlook, Prospects, and€¦ · budget, a momentous opportunity awaits. India has reached a sweet spot—rare in the history of nations—in which it could finally be launched

34 Economic Survey 2014-15

pace with the rising demand for these skills;otherwise even these sectors could becomeuncompetitive. In other words, the PrimeMinister’s Skill India objective should beaccorded high priority along with, and indeed inorder to realize, ‘‘Make in India’’.

We turn next to the means. What policyinterventions can help realize ‘‘Make in India’’They can be placed in three categories indecreasing order of effectiveness and increasingorder of controversy.

The uncontroversial responses consist of improvingthe business environment by making regulationsand taxes less onerous, building infrastructure,reforming labour laws, and enabling connectivity–all these would reduce the cost of doing business,increase profitability, and hence encourage theprivate sector, both domestic and foreign, toincrease investments. Indeed, these measureswould not just benefit manufacturing, they wouldbenefit all sectors.

The next set of responses—what might loosely becalled “industrial policy”— would target thepromotion of manufacturing in particular: providingsubsidies, lowering the cost of capital, and creatingspecial economic zones (SEZs) for some or allmanufacturing activity in particular.

The final set of responses—what might be called“protectionist”—would focus on the tradability ofmanufacturing, and hence consist of actions to:shield domestic manufacturing from foreigncompetition via tariffs and local contentrequirements; and provide export-relatedincentives. The effectiveness of these actions isopen to debate given past experience. Moreover,they would run up against India’s externalobligations under the WTO and other free tradeagreements, and also undermine India’s opennesscredentials.

The risk to avoid is undue reliance on the lattertwo, especially if it leads to detailed micro-intervention, involving sector-specific tariff and tax

changes and sector-specific grant of incentives. Inthis context, an intervention that can be immediatelyimplemented, that can have large impacts, and thatis win-win, is to eliminate the current negativeprotection facing Indian manufacturing (Box 1.4)

1.11 THE TRADE CHALLENGE

Trade outcomes have been stagnating. Thetrading environment is becoming morechallenging as the buoyancy of Indianexports has declined with respect to worldgrowth, and as the negotiation of mega-regional trading arrangements threatens toexclude India.

Rapid and sustained rates of growth are associatedwith rapid rates of export growth. Few countries,if any, have grown at 7 plus growth rates on thebasis of the domestic market alone. Indeed, asOstry et. al. (2006)26 show, sustained growth spurtsare almost always associated with an average risein manufacturing exports to GDP ratios over theirgrowth episodes of about 36 percentage points.India should not expect to be any different.

If that is so, what is the prognosis for India? DuringIndia’s rapid growth phase between 2002-03 and2008-09, the ratio of exports of services to GDPincreased dramatically, from 4.0 percent to nearly9.0 percent. In contrast, manufacturing exportswere less buoyant (Figure 1.23). After the globalfinancial crisis, however, the roles seem to havebeen reversed; manufacturing exports seem to havedone better than services exports. Moreworrisome, however, both have slowed down inthe last five years which does not augur well.

A similar pattern emerges when we compute thebuoyancy of Indian export growth (of goods andservices) with respect to GDP growth of the world(Figure 1.24). In the early 2000s, this buoyancywas high and rising, particularly for services. Every1 percent growth in world GDP was associatedwith a 3 percent growth in Indian exports of servicesin 2001, which rose to over 8 percent a few years

26 Johnson, Simon, Jonathan D. Ostry, and Arvind Subramanian, “The Prospects for Sustained Growth in Africa;Benchmarking the Constraints,” 2007, IMF Working Papers 07/52, International Monetary Fund.

Page 35: Economic Outlook, Prospects, and€¦ · budget, a momentous opportunity awaits. India has reached a sweet spot—rare in the history of nations—in which it could finally be launched

35Economic Outlook, Prospects, and Policy Challenges

Box 1.4: ‘‘Make in India’’ Not by Protecting but by Eliminating Negative Protectionism

Eliminating all the exemptions for the countervailing duty (CVD) will eliminate the negative protection facingIndian manufacturers, and help the ‘‘Make in India’’ initiative, without violating India’s international obligations.

There is one response that would help manufacturing and the “Make in India” initiative without being as difficultas improving the business environment, and as controversial and expensive as the industrial policy or protectionistresponse: eliminating the exemptions in the countervailing duties (CVD) and special additional duties (SAD) leviedon imports. Why will this help?

It is a well-accepted proposition in tax theory that achieving neutrality of incentives between domestic productionand imports requires that all domestic indirect taxes also be levied on imports. So, if a country levies a sales tax,value added tax (VAT), or excise or GST on domestic sales/production, it should also be levied on imports.

India’s current indirect tax system, however, acts sometimes to favour foreign production over domestically producedgoods.

The CVD, which is levied to offset the excise duty imposed on domestic producers, is not applied on a whole rangeof imports. These exemptions can be quantified. The effective rate of excise on domestically-produced non-oilgoods is about 9 percent. The effective collection rate of CVDs should theoretically be the same but is in actual factonly about 6 percent. The difference not only represents the fiscal cost to the government of ̀ 40,000 crore, it alsorepresents the negative protection in favour of foreign produced goods over domestically produced goods.

Three important nuances need to be noted here. First, it might seem that CVD exemptions on inputs help manufacturersby reducing their input costs. But under the current system and in future when the GST is implemented, the CVD oninputs can always be reclaimed as an input tax credit. So, CVD exemptions do not provide additional relief.

The second relates to a situation when both the excise and CVD are both exempted. This may seem apparentlyneutral between domestic production and imports but it is not. The imported good enters the market without theCVD imposed on it; and, because it is zero-rated in the source country, is not burdened by any embedded inputtaxes on it. The corresponding domestic good does not face the excise duty, but since it has been exempted, theinput tax credit cannot be claimed. The domestic good is thus less competitive relative to the foreign good becauseit bears input taxes which the foreign good does not.

Third, the rationale advanced for exempting many imported goods from CVD is that there is no competing domesticproduction. This argument is faulty because the absence of competing domestic production may itself be the resultof not having the neutrality of incentives that the CVD creates. Domestic producers may have chosen not to enterbecause the playing field is not level.

Indian tax policy is therefore effectively penalising domestic manufacturing. How can this anomaly be remedied?Simply by enacting a well-designed GST preferably with one, internationally competitive rate and with narrowlydefined exemptions. In one stroke the penalties on domestic manufacturing would be eliminated because the GST(central and state) would automatically be levied on imports to ensure neutrality of incentives. In effect, India wouldbe promoting domestic manufacturing without becoming protectionist and without violating any of its internationaltrade obligations under the World Trade Organisation (WTO) or under Free Trade Agreements (FTAs).

In the meantime, the effect of the GST can be partially simulated by eliminating the exemptions applied to CVD. Thedefault situation should be an exemptions-free regime. If particular sectors seek relief from the CVD, they should berequired to make their case at the highest political level.

In a sense, India finds itself in a de-facto state of negative protection on the one hand, and calls for higher tariffs onthe other. It is win-win to resist these calls that would burnish India’s openness credentials and instead eliminateunnecessary and costly negative protection.

later, stabilizing at around 5 just prior to the financialcrisis. Thereafter, it has been in steady decline andthe most recent estimate suggests a buoyancy of

one. The pattern is broadly similar for manufacturedexports, although it was less buoyant than servicesin the boom phase.27

27 The declining elasticity of global trade to global growth is documented in Constantinescu, C., A Mattoo and MRuta (2015) “The Global Trade Slowdown: Cyclical or Structural?” World Bank Policy Research WorkingPaper, WPS-7158.

Page 36: Economic Outlook, Prospects, and€¦ · budget, a momentous opportunity awaits. India has reached a sweet spot—rare in the history of nations—in which it could finally be launched

36 Economic Survey 2014-15

Source: IMF, WEO, DGCI&S and RBI.

Note: The buoyancy calculations are based on a three-year moving average. It excludes the year 2009-10 because a dramaticdecline in exports renders the buoyancy calculation difficult to interpret.

Combining the two charts, the message for Indiaseems to be that the external trading environmentis encountering two sets of headwinds: first, aslowdown in world growth which will reduceIndian exports; and second, for any given world

growth, export growth will be even lower becauseof trade’s declining responsiveness.

And, India must be especially watchful aboutservices exports—an engine of growth—whichhave slowed markedly. These headwinds are, of

Page 37: Economic Outlook, Prospects, and€¦ · budget, a momentous opportunity awaits. India has reached a sweet spot—rare in the history of nations—in which it could finally be launched

37Economic Outlook, Prospects, and Policy Challenges

course, in addition to the domestic factors that arecontributing to the slowdown of export growth:weak infrastructure and challenging labour laws inthe case of manufacturing, and rising wages andscarcity of skilled labour in the case of services.

In addition to the deteriorating externalenvironment for trade, India has to contend with arapidly changing policy environment. As the newgovernment prepares to re-invigorate the Indianeconomy, it will encounter that the internationaltrade landscape is substantially changing in threesignificant ways.

First, the phenomenon of global value-addedchains based on fragmenting/unbundling successivestages of production and locating them at lowestcost destinations have become a defining, even ifdeclining, feature of trade, especially in Asia. Indiahas been slowly integrating into these chains, butat lower levels than most other dynamic Asianeconomies.

Second, negotiations on mega-regional agreementshave been seriously initiated. Trade integrationwithin Asia and between Asia and the United Stateswill advance significantly if and when the Trans-Pacific Partnership (TPP) is negotiated and ratified.Similarly, the markets of North American andEurope will be brought together if and when theTrans-Atlantic Trade and Investment Partnership(TTIP) are concluded. Together, these twoagreements will cover about half of world trade.

And third, China, which until recently has beencomfortable with the status quo, may be on theverge of changing from passive bystander to activeparticipant, wanting to engage in, and possiblyshape, the formation of the next round of traderules. This change is a reaction to the domesticimperatives of re-balancing the economy, whichwill require major liberalization of the Chineseeconomy; and to the fear of being excluded byAmerican trade initiatives, including TPP and TTIP.China is also at the center of the RegionalComprehensive Economic Partnership (RCEP)which includes India, the Association of South EastAsian Nations (ASEAN) countries, as well asJapan, Korea, Australia and New Zealand.

How should India react to this global shift in traderealities? It has two choices: measured integration(the status quo and/or RCEP) or ambitiousintegration (via the TPP). Measured integrationwould involve a slow but steady pace of domesticreform dictated by India’s political constraints andcapacity which could only sustain regionalagreements of the kind India has negotiated withAsian partners: relatively few obligations, generousexemptions and exceptions, and lenient timetablesfor implementation.

The risk in the status quo scenario is one of Indiabeing excluded from large integrated marketswith reduced trading possibilities, and becauseof the nature of global value chains in whichtrade, investment, and intellectual property areenmeshed, also reduced investment possibilities.(Joining RCEP might help but not fully since theexpectation is that the overall standards in RCEPwill be weaker than under the TPP and TTIP).There will not only be the standard diversionemanating from Indian exporters having to facehigher tariffs in large, growing markets, butincreasingly they will have to contend withdifferent and higher product and sustainabledevelopment standards, placing them at an evengreater disadvantage. In the context of theslowdown in both world growth and India’sexport buoyancy, any possible exclusion fromthe mega-regionals would be additionallyworrisome.

Ambitious integration would essentially mean Indiajoining, or rather seeking to join, at some futuredate the TPP. There is considerable uncertaintysurrounding this option because the timing andterms of the TPP are still unclear. What is clear,however, is that the substantive liberalizationobligations under any future TPP will be greaterthan those under India’s current FTAs andprobably ahead of India’s planned pace ofdomestic reform. A significant upgrading of Indiantrade capability will be necessary for India to beable to join these mega-regionals should it choseto do so.

Page 38: Economic Outlook, Prospects, and€¦ · budget, a momentous opportunity awaits. India has reached a sweet spot—rare in the history of nations—in which it could finally be launched

38 Economic Survey 2014-15

1.12 CLIMATE CHANGE

India has taken a number of green actions,including imposing significantly highertaxation of petroleum products and re-energizing the renewable energy sector. It canmake a positive contribution to theforthcoming Paris negotiations on climatechange.

Later this year, Heads of States from around theworld will meet in Paris to conclude negotiationson a new agreement under the United NationsFramework Convention on Climate Change(UNFCCC) by December 2015. The expectationis one of action by all countries on climate changefrom 2020 onwards in accordance with theprinciple of common but differentiatedresponsibilities.

The Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change(IPCC) in its recent report – the Fifth AssessmentReport (AR5), published in 2014 — has observedthat, there has been an increasing trend in theanthropogenic emissions of greenhouse gases(GHG) since the advent of the industrial revolution,with about half of the anthropogenic carbon dioxide(CO2) emissions during this period occurring inthe last 40 years. The period 1983-2012 is likelyto have been the warmest 30 year period of thelast 1400 years. CO2 emissions from fossil fuelcombustion and industrial processes contributed

a major portion of total GHG emissions during theperiod 1970 - 2010.

The change in the climate system is likely to haveadverse impacts on livelihoods, cropping patternand food security. Extreme heat events are likelyto be longer and more intense in addition tochanges in the precipitation patterns. Adverseimpacts are likely to be felt more acutely in tropicalzone countries such as India, and within India, thepoor will be more exposed.

India can make a significant contribution inaddressing climate change. Unlike some countries,it has taken substantial actions to eliminatepetroleum subsidies and gone beyond to imposesubstantial taxes on these products.

These actions have taken India from a carbonsubsidization regime to one of significant carbontaxation regime—from a negative price to animplicit positive price on carbon emissions. Andthe shift has been large. For example, the effect ofthe recent actions since October 2014 has been ade facto carbon tax equivalent to US$ 60 per tonof CO2 in the case of (unbranded) petrol andnearly US$ 42 per ton in the case of (unbranded)diesel. In absolute terms, the implicit carbon tax(US$ 140 for petrol and US$ 64 for diesel) issubstantially above what is now considered areasonable initial tax on CO2 emissions of US$25 per ton (Figure 1.25). India now ranks quite

Source: World Bank estimates.

Page 39: Economic Outlook, Prospects, and€¦ · budget, a momentous opportunity awaits. India has reached a sweet spot—rare in the history of nations—in which it could finally be launched

39Economic Outlook, Prospects, and Policy Challenges

high in terms of taxation of petroleum products.The recent actions alone have significantly burnishedIndia’s green and climate change credentials.

In addition India has increased the coal cess fromRs. 50 per ton to Rs.100 per ton, which isequivalent to a carbon tax of about US$ 1 perton. The health cost of coal for power generationin India is estimated to range from US$ 3.41 perton to US$ 51.11 per ton depending on the valueof statistical life. The average number is US$ 27.26per ton. The health costs of emissions from coalfired power plants include costs associated withpremature cardiopulmonary deaths and illnessesfrom the chronic effects of long-term exposure andthe acute effects of short-term exposure. Highertaxes on coal to offset these purely domesticexternalities would need to be balanced againsttheir implications for power pricing and henceaccess to energy for the 300 million householdsstill without electricity.

This trade-off suggests that alternative paths toenergy access need to be considered, includingrenewables. The Jawaharlal Nehru National SolarMission launched in January 2010 seeks toestablish India as a global leader in solar energyby creating policy conditions for its diffusion acrossthe country. The Twelfth Plan financial outlay forthis scheme is ̀ 8795 crore. The Solar Mission isnow being scaled up five-fold from 20,000megawatts to 100,000 megawatts. This in effectrequires an additional investment of 100 billion USdollars. The aim of this initiative is primarily toprovide energy access to nearly 300 millionhouseholds. The collateral benefit would be lowerannual emissions of CO2 by about 165 milliontonnes.

Reconciling India’s climate change goals andenergy imperatives will require a majortechnological breakthrough to make the burningof coal cleaner and greener. If India is to focus onbecoming green, correspondingly the world mustdevote more resources into coal technologyresearch. That means greater international publicinvestment in R&D for improving coaltechnologies. And if the private sector is to be

incentivized to undertake this research, high andrising carbon pricing by advanced countries mustbecome an immediate priority. (An elaboration ofthe contours of a new type of global deal and therequired contribution from advanced and emergingeconomies can be found in Aaditya Mattooand Arvind Subramanian’s Greenprint: A NewApproach to Cooperation on ClimateChange).

1.13 EMPOWERING WOMEN: UNLEASHINGNAARI SHAKTI

Improving the status and treatment of womenis a major development challenge. In the shortrun, family planning targets and theprovision of incentives are leading to anundesirable focus on female sterilization.On January 22nd, 2015, the Prime Ministerlaunched the Beti Bachao, Beti Padhao campaignfrom Panipat in Haryana. The campaign is aimedat increasing the very low value that Indian societyputs on a girl child. But India is somewhat of aparadox on gender issues. On the one hand, Indiahas had prominent and visible women leaders suchas a female President, a female Prime Minister,several female heads of large political parties atthe national and state levels, several Cabinet rankministers, and several captains of industry(particularly in the banking sector).And yet, according to the UNDP’s latest HumanDevelopment Report (2014), India ranks 135 outof 187 countries on the Human Development Index(HDI) and 127 out of 152 countries on the GenderInequality Index (GII). The GII is a compositemeasure reflecting inequality in achievementbetween women and men in three dimensions:reproductive health, empowerment and the labormarket. This puts India in the bottom 25 percentof all countries on the HDI and even lower—inthe bottom 20 percent on the GII. Furthermore,the child sex ratio—the number of girls to boys atbirth—is relatively low in the world, and moreoverdeclined from 927 girls per 1000 boys in 2001 to918 girls for every 1000 boys in 2011 (Figure1.26). China is one of the few countries with amore adverse child sex ratio.

Page 40: Economic Outlook, Prospects, and€¦ · budget, a momentous opportunity awaits. India has reached a sweet spot—rare in the history of nations—in which it could finally be launched

40 Economic Survey 2014-15

But the November 2014 tragedy in Bilaspur,Chhattisgarh in which 13 young women with veryyoung children lost their lives, and forty-five morewere taken critically ill, highlights a specific andserious problem that needs urgent attention: femalesterilization. The third round of the National FamilyHealth Survey (NFHS-3, 2005-06) reports thateven in developed states like Tamil Nadu andMaharashtra female sterilisation accounts for 90per cent and 76 percent of all contraceptive use,respectively; the median age at sterilisation forwomen was reported at 24.9 years in both TamilNadu and Maharashtra.

There appears to be renewed focus on controllingthe rise in population, directed in particular atwomen, and through means that blur the linesbetween persuasion and coercion. Persuasiontakes the form of incentives offered not just to poorcouples for sterilisation but rewards to local bodiesfor their performance, euphemistically describedas “promotional and motivational” measures,resulting in the organization of mass camps forfemale sterilization. India’s population policy seems

Source: Statistical Yearbook for Asia and the Pacific 2011, UNESCAP.

focused on extending family planning measures,mainly contraceptives for women, leaving themwith little reproductive choice or autonomy.

Of the total sterilisation operations performed in2012-13, tubectomy/laproscopic sterilisationsaccount for 97.4 percent, while male vasectomyoperations, considered less complicated risky,account for only 2.5 percent (Figure 1.27).Government expenditures are also skewed towardfemale sterilization. Out of the budget of Rs 397crores for family planning for 2013-14, 85 percent(` 338 crore) is spent on female sterilization. Bycontrast 1.5 percent of the total budget is spenton spacing methods and 13 percent oninfrastructure and communications.

The negative fallouts of pursuing a population policythat largely focuses on birth control also contributesto declining child sex ratios: if every family is tohave fewer children, there is a greater anxiety thatat least one of them should be male.

In this instance, there may be a case for thegovernment to undo as much as to do for example,

Page 41: Economic Outlook, Prospects, and€¦ · budget, a momentous opportunity awaits. India has reached a sweet spot—rare in the history of nations—in which it could finally be launched

41Economic Outlook, Prospects, and Policy Challenges

by not setting targets (ELAs or expected levels ofachievement), withdrawing incentives for femalesterilization and for mass camps. In addition, thegovernment could:

(i) Review the family planning program inIndia and reorient it such that it isaligned with reproductive health rightsof women, and needs of India’spopulation.

(ii) Increase budgets for quality services,static family planning clinics andquality monitoring and supervision.

(iii) Address youth needs, induct morecounsellors for sexual health, moreyouth-friendly services, and adequatesupply of spacing methods.

1.14 COOPERATIVE FEDERALISM AND THE

RECOMMENDATIONS OF THE FOURTEENTH

FINANCE COMMISSION (FFC)Far-reaching changes for sharing of revenuesbetween the Center and the States, on the onehand, and between the States, on the other,have been recommended by the FFC.Successful implementation will advance the

cause of cooperative federalism that the newgovernment has enthusiastically embraced.

The Fourteenth Finance Commission (FFC) hasrecently submitted its recommendations fordevolution of taxes and other transfers from thecenter to the states, and between the states, forthe period 2015-16 to 2020-21. They are likelyto have major implications for Center-Staterelations, for budgeting by, and the fiscal situationof, the Center and the States. Some of therecommendations are as follows.

The FFC has radically enhanced the share of thestates in the central divisible pool of taxes fromthe current 32 percent to 42 per cent which is thebiggest ever increase in vertical tax devolution. Thelast two Finance Commissions viz. Twelfth (2005-10) and Thirteenth (2010-15) had recommendeda state share of 30.5 per cent (increase of 1percent) and 32 per cent (increase of 1.5 percent),respectively in the central divisible pool.

The FFC has also proposed a new horizontalformula for the distribution of the divisible poolamong the States. There are changes both in thevariables included/excluded as well as the weightsassigned to them. Relative to the Thirteenth Finance

Source: Ministry of Health & Family Welfare, Government of India.

Page 42: Economic Outlook, Prospects, and€¦ · budget, a momentous opportunity awaits. India has reached a sweet spot—rare in the history of nations—in which it could finally be launched

42 Economic Survey 2014-15

Table 1.4 : Additional FFC Transfers (in 2015-16 over 2014-15)State Category Benefits from Benefits Per Benefits as Benefits as

FFC (in crore) capita (`) percent of OTR percent of NSDP1 2 3 4 5 6Andhra Pradesh (united) GCS 14620 1728 27.4 2.2Arunachal Pradesh SCS 5585 40359 1758.1 51.0Assam SCS 7295 2338 95.5 5.8Bihar GCS 13279 1276 105.3 4.9Chhattisgarh GCS 7227 2829 67.5 5.2Goa GCS 1107 7591 44.1 3.0Gujarat GCS 4551 753 10.3 0.8Haryana GCS 1592 628 7.8 0.5Himachal Pradesh SCS 8533 12430 207.7 14.6Jammu & Kashmir SCS 13970 11140 294.4 22.4Jharkhand GCS 6196 1878 89.1 4.8Karnataka GCS 8401 1375 18.1 1.8Kerala GCS 9508 2846 37.0 3.1Madhya Pradesh GCS 15072 2075 55.9 4.5Maharashtra GCS 10682 951 12.2 0.9Manipur SCS 2130 8286 578.7 19.5Meghalaya SCS 1381 4655 198.0 8.6Mizoram SCS 2519 22962 1410.1 33.3Nagaland SCS 2694 13616 886.5 18.7Odisha GCS 6752 1609 50.2 3.2Punjab GCS 3457 1246 18.3 1.4Rajasthan GCS 6479 945 25.5 1.6Sikkim SCS 1010 16543 343.7 10.7Tamil Nadu GCS 5973 828 10.0 0.9Tripura SCS 1560 4247 181.8 6.9Uttar Pradesh GCS 24608 1232 46.8 3.5Uttarakhand SCS 1303 1292 23.2 1.4West Bengal GCS 16714 1831 67.0 3.0Total 204198 1715

Source : Ministry of Finance.GCS : General Category States. SCS : Special Category States.

Commission, the FFC has incorporated two newvariables: 2011 population and forest cover; andexcluded the variable relating to fiscal discipline(see Chapter 10 for greater details.)Implementing these recommendations will movethe country toward greater fiscal federalism,conferring more fiscal autonomy on the States. Forexample, based on assumptions about nominalGDP growth and tax buoyancy and the policymeasures that are contemplated for 2015-16, it isestimated that the additional revenue for the statescould be as much as ` 2 lakh crores relative to2014-15. Of this, a substantial portion representsthe difference that is purely due to the change inthe States’ share in the divisible pool.

Preliminary estimates shown in Table 1.4 suggestthat all States stand to gain from FFC transfersin absolute terms. However, to assess thedistributional effects, the increases should bescaled by population, Net State Domestic Product(NSDP) at current market price, or by States’ owntax revenue receipts. These are shown in columns4-6 of Table 1.4. The biggest gainers when scaledby any of these indicators tend to be the SpecialCategory States (SCS, mostly those in the North-East) and by orders of magnitude. The majorgainers in per capita terms turn out to be ArunachalPradesh, Mizoram and Sikkim for the SCS statesand Kerala, Chhattisgarh and Madhya Pradeshfor other states (GCS or General Category States).

Page 43: Economic Outlook, Prospects, and€¦ · budget, a momentous opportunity awaits. India has reached a sweet spot—rare in the history of nations—in which it could finally be launched

43Economic Outlook, Prospects, and Policy Challenges

Clearly, this increase in taxes to the States issustainable for the center, only if there is a reductionin the central (“Plan”) assistance to the states(CAS). In other words, States will now havegreater autonomy both on the revenue andexpenditure fronts.

It is also possible to tentatively estimate what theFFC recommendations would do to net spendingcapacity of the States, where net refers to thedifference between the extra FFC transfers andthe reduced CAS that will be required by the FFCrecommendations.Broadly, the Special CategoryStates will be the biggest gainers. In addition, thereare nine States among the GCS which are expectedto get more than 25 per cent of their own taxrevenue (for details, see Chapter 10).

A collateral benefit of moving from CAS to FFCtransfers is that overall progressivity will improve;

that is, on average, States with lower per capitaNSDP will receive more than those with a higherper capita NSDP. This results from the fact thatCAS transfers, which tended to be discretionary,were less progressive than Finance Commissiontransfers.

To be sure, there will be transitional costs entailedby the reduction in CAS transfers. But the scopefor dislocation has been minimized because theextra FFC resources will flow broadly to the statesthat have the largest CAS-financed schemes.

In sum, the far-reaching recommendations of theFFC, along with the creation of the NITI Aayog,will further the government’s vision of cooperativeand competitive federalism. The necessary, indeedvital, encompassing of cities and other local bodieswithin the embrace of cooperative and competitivefederalism is the next policy challenge.