33
Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2009 Lecture 15

Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2009 Lecture 15

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2009 Lecture 15

Econ 522Economics of Law

Dan Quint

Fall 2009

Lecture 15

Page 2: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2009 Lecture 15

2

HW2 due Tuesday (11 a.m. sharp)

Second midterm next Thursday (Nov 5)

Logistics

Page 3: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2009 Lecture 15

3

On the topic of illegal contracts…

Page 4: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2009 Lecture 15

4

Let’s recap ourstory so far…

Page 5: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2009 Lecture 15

5

Efficiency Maximizing total surplus realized by everyone in society Scarce resources are owned by whoever values them most Actions are taken if social benefit exceeds social cost

Design a legal system that leads to efficient outcomes Once we set up the rules, we don’t expect people to act based on

what’s efficient We expect people to do whatever’s in their own best interest So the goal is set up the rules such that people acting in their

own best interest will naturally lead to efficiency

Our story so far

Page 6: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2009 Lecture 15

6

Coase gives us one way to do that As long as property rights are clearly defined and tradeable, and there

are no transaction costs, people have incentive to trade until each resource is efficiently owned

So initial allocation of rights doesn’t matter for efficiency But if there are transaction costs, we may not get efficiency this way

Led us to two normative views of the legal system: 1. Minimize transaction costs (“lubricate” private exchange) 2. Allocate rights as efficiently as possible

Tradeoff between injunctive relief and damages

Our story so far

Page 7: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2009 Lecture 15

7

Property law works well for simultaneous trade

Contracts allow for non-simultaneous trade

Contract law can… Enable cooperation Encourage efficient disclosure of information Secure optimal commitment to performance Secure efficient reliance Supply efficient default rules and regulations Foster enduring relationships

Our story so far

Page 8: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2009 Lecture 15

8

Property law works well when transaction costs are low enough to get voluntary trade

Contract law works well when transaction costs are low enough that we can agree to a contract, but high enough that we may not want to renegotiate the contract later

What about when transaction costs are too high to agree to anything in advance?

This is tort law

Our story so far

Page 9: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2009 Lecture 15

9

Tort law

Page 10: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2009 Lecture 15

10

Tort, noun. from French word meaning injury

Contract law: situations where someone harms you by breaking a promise they had made

Tort law: situations where someone harms you without having made any promises

“If someone shoots you, you call a cop. If he runs his car into yours, you call a lawyer.”

Tort law

Page 11: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2009 Lecture 15

11

Question: how to structure the law to get people to behave in a way that leads to efficient outcomes?

Deliberate harms: make punishment severe (criminal law)

Accidental harms: trickier Goal isn’t “no accidents”; goal is “efficient number of accidents”

Tort law

Page 12: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2009 Lecture 15

12

Question: how to structure the law to get people to behave in a way that leads to efficient outcomes?

Deliberate harms: make punishment severe (criminal law)

Accidental harms: trickier Goal isn’t “no accidents”; goal is “efficient number of accidents”

Unlike nuisance law, injunctive relief is not an option

Unlike contract law, no agreement ahead of time

Cooter and Ulen: essence of tort law is “the attempt to make injurers internalize the externalities they cause, in situations where transaction costs are too high to do this through property or contract rights”

Tort law

Page 13: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2009 Lecture 15

13

Plaintiff – person who brings a lawsuit

Defendant – person who is being sued

In a nuisance case, the defendant caused a nuisance, plaintiff was bothered by it, might be asking for injunction or damages

In a contract case, defendant breached a contract or violated its terms

In a tort case, defendant caused some harm to plaintiff, plaintiff is asking for damages

Plaintiff is the victim; defendant is the injurer

Cast of characters

Page 14: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2009 Lecture 15

14

Harm

Causation

Breach of Duty

“Classic” legal theory of torts

Page 15: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2009 Lecture 15

15

For a tort to exist, the plaintiff needs to have been harmed

“Without harm, there is no tort” Gas company sold gas with a defective additive

Dangerous for cars with turbocharged carburetors You have a car with normal carburetors You might be angry; but you weren’t harmed, so you can’t sue

Similarly, no compensation for exposure to risk Manufacturer exposed workers to some chemical Exposure will cause 15% of them to develop cancer later in life Can’t sue now – have to wait, see who gets cancer, then they can sue

Element 1: Harm

Page 16: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2009 Lecture 15

16

Element 1: Harm

Money

Health

Perfect compensation restores victim to original level of well-being generally done through money damages

Page 17: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2009 Lecture 15

17

Perfect Compensation

• Emotional harm• Pain and suffering• Loss of companionship

• Medical costs• Lost income• Damaged property

Intangible harmsTangible harms

Historically, courts less willing to compensate for intangible or hard-to-measure losses

Over time, American courts have started compensating for more intangible harms Pro: closer liability is to actual harm done, better incentives for avoidance of

these harms Con: disparity in award sizes, unpredictability

Page 18: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2009 Lecture 15

18

Harm

Causation

Breach of Duty

“Classic” legal theory of torts

Page 19: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2009 Lecture 15

19

For a tort to exist, the defendant needs to have caused the harm to the plaintiff

Cause-in-fact “But for the defendant’s actions, would the harm have occurred?”

Element 2: Causation

Page 20: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2009 Lecture 15

20

For a tort to exist, the defendant needs to have caused the harm to the plaintiff

Cause-in-fact “But for the defendant’s actions, would the harm have occurred?”

Proximate cause Immediate cause – defendant’s action can’t be too distant from the harm Palsgraf v Long Island Railway (NY Ct Appeals, 1928):

Guard pushed a passenger to help him onto train, passenger dropped fireworks he was carrying, they went off, explosion knocked down scales at the other end of the platform, which fell on Mrs. Palsgraf

Guard’s actions were not the proximate cause

Element 2: Causation

Page 21: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2009 Lecture 15

21

“A tree fell on a moving trolly, injuring passengers. One of them sued.

He succeeded in demonstrating that in order for the trolly to be where it was when the tree fell on it the driver had to have driven faster than the speed limit at some point during the trip.

Breaking the law is per se negligence, so the driver was legally negligent whether or not his driving was actually unsafe.

If he had not driven over the speed limit, the trolly would not have been under the tree when it fell, so, the plaintiff argued, the driver’s negligence caused the injury.”

Court ruled driver’s negligence “had not caused the accident in the legally relevant sense”

Element 2: Causation

Page 22: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2009 Lecture 15

22

Harm

Causation

Breach of Duty

“Classic” legal theory of torts

Page 23: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2009 Lecture 15

23

Element 3: Breach of Duty

• Harm• Causation• Breach of duty (fault)

• Harm• Causation

NegligenceStrict Liability

When someone breaches a duty he owes to the defendant, and this leads to the harm, the injurer is at fault, or negligent Under a negligence rule, even if I caused you harm, I’m not liable if I

had taken the required standard of care and the accident happened anyway

(Sometimes required, sometimes not)

Page 24: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2009 Lecture 15

24

“A tree fell on a moving trolly, injuring passengers. One of them sued.

He succeeded in demonstrating that in order for the trolly to be where it was when the tree fell on it the driver had to have driven faster than the speed limit at some point during the trip.

Breaking the law is per se negligence, so the driver was legally negligent whether or not his driving was actually unsafe.

If he had not driven over the speed limit, the trolly would not have been under the tree when it fell, so, the plaintiff argued,the driver’s negligence caused the injury.”

Hence the language in the trolly example

Page 25: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2009 Lecture 15

25

If I breach my duty of due care and injure you, I am liable

If I exercise the appropriate level of care but still injure you, I’m not liable

How is the standard of care determined? That is, how careful do I have to be to avoid liability, and who

decides? Is it negligent to drive 40 MPH on a particular road at a particular

time of day? What about 41 MPH? 42?

So under a negligence rule…

Page 26: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2009 Lecture 15

26

Some settings: government imposes safety regulations that set standard for negligence Speed limits for highway driving Requirement that bicycles have brakes Workplace regulations

Some standards are left vague “Reckless driving” may depend on road, time of day, weather… Common law focuses on duty of reasonable care Level of care a reasonable person would have taken (Civil law relies less on “reasonableness” tests, tries to spell out what

level of care is required)

How is the standard of care determined?

Page 27: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2009 Lecture 15

27

Strict liability rule: plaintiff must prove harm and causation

Negligence rule: must prove harm, causation, and negligence

A little history Early Europe: strict liability was usual rule By early 1900s, negligence became usual rule Second half of 1900s, strict liability became more common again,

especially for manufacturer liability in American consumer products U.S. manufacturers now held liable for harms caused by defective

products, whether or not they were at fault

Strict liability versus negligence

Page 28: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2009 Lecture 15

28

Harm

Causation

Breach of Duty

“Classic” legal theory of torts

Page 29: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2009 Lecture 15

29

The law as a setof incentives

Page 30: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2009 Lecture 15

30

Something to remember

distributionbut not

efficiency

efficiency

Page 31: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2009 Lecture 15

31

A physician comes upon an auto accident, stops, and treats an unconscious and badly bleeding victim. A week later the victim receives a bill for services rendered. Must he pay it?

Under current U.S. law the answer is yes.

Consider the following alternatives:

i. The victim need not pay anything

ii. The victim must pay only the value of whatever materials were used up in treating him (bandages, etc.)

iii. The victim must pay the going market rate for comparable medical services

iv. The victim must pay whatever the doctor demands

Which of these do you expect to lead to the most efficient outcomes? Why?

The law as incentives – HW2 Q3(from old midterm)

Page 32: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2009 Lecture 15

32

If we think about payoffs after the fact(after accident, after treatment)…

Suppose value of treatment is $100,000, cost of materials $50, value of doctor’s time $450, market rate $1,000

After the fact, all remedies are equally efficient So this can’t be the right way to think about the problem!

99,50099,50099,50099,500Combined Payoffs

999,500500-450-500Doctor’s Payoff

-$900,000$99,000$99,950$100,000Patient’s Payoff

Whatever Doc Asks

MarketRate

Cost of Materials

PayNothing

Page 33: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2009 Lecture 15

33

Need to think about incentive each rule creates, therefore the behavior it will lead to

Patient pays nothing

Patient pays for materials

Patient pays market rate

Patient pays whatever doctor asks

So what is the right way to think about the problem?