24
CHRISTOPH MOSER AXEL DREHER Do Markets Care about Central Bank Governor Changes? Evidence from Emerging Markets Based on a new daily data set for 20 emerging markets over the period 1992–2006, we examine the reactions of foreign exchange markets, do- mestic stock markets, and sovereign bond spreads to central bank governor changes. We find that the replacement of a central bank governor negatively affects financial markets on the announcement day, which is in line with the hypothesis that newly appointed central bank governors suffer from a systematic credibility problem at the beginning of their tenure. We also find some evidence that changes in perceived central bank independence affect markets. JEL codes: F30, F34, G14, H63 Keywords: central bank governor turnover, monetary policy, emerging markets, risk premium. “After arguing behind the scenes with his central bank governor over the direction of interest rates, Prime Minister Thaksin Shinawatra of Thailand ... dismissed the banker ... brought a sharp reaction of financial markets, where it cast doubts over the political independence of the Thai central bank.” (The New York Times [“Chief of Thai Bank Is Dismissed Over Rates,” May 30, 2001, Source: Proquest]) We thank two anonymous referees and the editors, Robert DeYoung and Deborah Lucas, for helpful comments. Furthermore, we are grateful to Christian Bjørnskov, Ricardo Caballero, Christian Conrad, Etienne Farvaque, Martin Gassebner, Ashok Kaul, Silke Rath, Jan-Egbert Sturm, Dieter Urban, participants at the First BBQ Conference, the Verein f¨ ur Socialpolitik, the KOF Research Seminar, the Verein f¨ ur Socialpolitik: Research Committee Development Economics, the Central Banking Conference “Does Central Bank Independence Still Matter?” at the Bocconi University 2007, the Brown Bag Seminar at the University of Mainz, the Annual Meeting of the Austrian Economics Association (NOeG), the Macroeconomics Research Meeting 2007, and in particular Helge Berger for suggestions and discussion. We thank Simon Holzhammer, Stefan Keitel, Michaela Lischer, Elisabeth M¨ unch, Nadja P¨ anzer, and Christoph Woodli for excellent research assistance; Jan Schopen for help in compiling the stock market and foreign exchange market data; and Hendrik van Broekhuizen for excellent proofreading. CHRISTOPH MOSER is at the ETH Zurich, Swiss Federal Institute of Technology, KOF Swiss Economic Institute (E-mail: [email protected]). AXEL DREHER is a Faculty of Economic Sciences, Georg-August University Goettingen, KOF Swiss Economic Institute, Switzerland, and IZA and CESifo, Germany (E-mail: [email protected]). Received October 26, 2007; and accepted in revised form July 12, 2010. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Vol. 42, No. 8 (December 2010) C 2010 The Ohio State University

Do Markets Care about Central Bank Governor Changes? Evidence from Emerging Markets

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Do Markets Care about Central Bank Governor Changes? Evidence from Emerging Markets

CHRISTOPH MOSER

AXEL DREHER

Do Markets Care about Central Bank Governor

Changes? Evidence from Emerging Markets

Based on a new daily data set for 20 emerging markets over the period1992–2006, we examine the reactions of foreign exchange markets, do-mestic stock markets, and sovereign bond spreads to central bank governorchanges. We find that the replacement of a central bank governor negativelyaffects financial markets on the announcement day, which is in line withthe hypothesis that newly appointed central bank governors suffer from asystematic credibility problem at the beginning of their tenure. We also findsome evidence that changes in perceived central bank independence affectmarkets.

JEL codes: F30, F34, G14, H63Keywords: central bank governor turnover, monetary policy, emerging

markets, risk premium.

“After arguing behind the scenes with his central bank governor over the directionof interest rates, Prime Minister Thaksin Shinawatra of Thailand . . . dismissed thebanker . . . brought a sharp reaction of financial markets, where it cast doubts over thepolitical independence of the Thai central bank.” (The New York Times [“Chief of ThaiBank Is Dismissed Over Rates,” May 30, 2001, Source: Proquest])

We thank two anonymous referees and the editors, Robert DeYoung and Deborah Lucas, for helpfulcomments. Furthermore, we are grateful to Christian Bjørnskov, Ricardo Caballero, Christian Conrad,Etienne Farvaque, Martin Gassebner, Ashok Kaul, Silke Rath, Jan-Egbert Sturm, Dieter Urban, participantsat the First BBQ Conference, the Verein fur Socialpolitik, the KOF Research Seminar, the Verein furSocialpolitik: Research Committee Development Economics, the Central Banking Conference “DoesCentral Bank Independence Still Matter?” at the Bocconi University 2007, the Brown Bag Seminarat the University of Mainz, the Annual Meeting of the Austrian Economics Association (NOeG), theMacroeconomics Research Meeting 2007, and in particular Helge Berger for suggestions and discussion.We thank Simon Holzhammer, Stefan Keitel, Michaela Lischer, Elisabeth Munch, Nadja Panzer, andChristoph Woodli for excellent research assistance; Jan Schopen for help in compiling the stock marketand foreign exchange market data; and Hendrik van Broekhuizen for excellent proofreading.

CHRISTOPH MOSER is at the ETH Zurich, Swiss Federal Institute of Technology, KOF SwissEconomic Institute (E-mail: [email protected]). AXEL DREHER is a Faculty of EconomicSciences, Georg-August University Goettingen, KOF Swiss Economic Institute, Switzerland,and IZA and CESifo, Germany (E-mail: [email protected]).

Received October 26, 2007; and accepted in revised form July 12, 2010.

Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Vol. 42, No. 8 (December 2010)C© 2010 The Ohio State University

Page 2: Do Markets Care about Central Bank Governor Changes? Evidence from Emerging Markets

1590 : MONEY, CREDIT AND BANKING

THE DYNAMIC INCONSISTENCY of low-inflation monetary policycan be overcome by delegating monetary policy to independent and conservativecentral bankers (Rogoff 1985). While many countries have recently granted theircentral banks legal independence, the experience of some countries suggests limitedactual independence, with the head of the central bank frequently being replaced atshort notice and outside the legal schedule. How do financial markets react to changesof central bank governors?1 We expect them to react to such changes if changes conveynew information about future monetary policy. Economic theory suggests that theinflationary bias is determined by the degree of central bank independence and thedegree of the bank’s conservatism.2 Hence, if market participants’ perceptions changewith respect to one of these two dimensions, asset prices should change to the extentof their sensitivity to inflation. There are two transmission channels. First, when thegovernment interferes in the replacement procedure, irregular turnovers are likelyto affect markets’ perceptions about the central bank’s independence. Second, if theperceived inflation aversion of the new central bank governor differs from that of thepredecessor’s, this will alter expected financial market returns.

The literature has shown that the identity of central bank council members hasimportant bearing on economic outcomes. Drawing on a sample of 15 industrializedcountries, Kuttner and Posen (2010) conclude that markets do care about who chairsthe central bank. Central bank governor changes apparently convey new informationabout the future monetary policy, thereby affecting exchange rates and domesticbond yields. Kuttner and Posen (2010) do not, however, find evidence of a genericcredibility problem, that is, a systematic (at least) transitory increase in inflationexpectations at the beginning of a central bank governor’s tenure. This is hardlysurprising, since central bank governor turnovers are mostly predictable and highlydeveloped institutions are likely to reduce the individual governor’s influence inadvanced countries. By contrast, replacing the central bank governor is among themost sensitive decisions for emerging market governments, as these policymakersplay a crucial role in communicating with international markets (Santiso 2003).Credibility is more likely to be an issue here. Surprisingly, whether and to whatextent central bank governor changes in transition countries affect financial marketshas so far not been investigated.

This paper examines the impact of central bank governor changes on domestic andinternational financial markets in emerging economies. Based on a new daily dataset on 20 emerging markets over the period 1992–2006, we study whether foreignexchange rates, domestic stock market indices, and sovereign bond spreads react to theannouncement of a change at the helm of a central bank and whether new governorshave systematic credibility problems. Moreover, we investigate whether changes in

1. We call the heads of the central bank “governors” independent of whether their actual job title is“governor,” “director,” or “president.”

2. By “conservatism” we mean that the central bank has a stronger bias against inflation than thegovernment.

Page 3: Do Markets Care about Central Bank Governor Changes? Evidence from Emerging Markets

CHRISTOPH MOSER AND AXEL DREHER : 1591

perceived central bank independence or changes in the perceived conservatism of thecentral banker affect markets.

To foreshadow our main results, we find that the replacement of a central bankgovernor negatively affects financial markets on the announcement day. Overall, ourresults are in line with the hypothesis that incoming governors in emerging marketsface a credibility problem. Furthermore, we find evidence that the negative effecton financial markets is primarily driven by central bank governor changes that occurbefore the officially scheduled end of tenure, indicating reactions to perceived changesin central bank independence.

The remainder of the paper is structured as follows. Section 1 derives our hy-potheses, while Section 2 describes the data set. Section 3 discusses the methodologyused, derives the empirical specifications, and describes the results. The final sectionconcludes.

1. HYPOTHESES

Evidence on the impact of who is in charge of economic policies on economicoutcomes is scarce. It is only very recently that studies have started analyzing thisissue. Among them, Jones and Olken (2005) demonstrate that national leaders matterfor economic growth. Dreher et al. (2008) show that the educational and professionalbackground of a head of government matters for the implementation of reforms. Fora sample of Latin American countries, Moser (2006) finds that changing the financeminister had the effect of increasing sovereign bond spreads due to a perceivedworsening of the fiscal policy stance.

Turning to central banks, Gohlmann and Vaubel (2007) provide recent empiricalevidence that the educational qualifications and professions of the central bank’sgoverning council members matter for its effectiveness when attempting to controlinflation. Kuttner and Posen (2010) find that changing a central bank governor conveyssignals about the future course of monetary policy, thereby affecting exchange ratesand financial market returns. However, the direction of these effects subsequent tosuch announcement is not obvious a priori. What are the channels by which turnoversaffect markets and are market reactions positive or, instead, negative? Policymakerscannot credibly commit themselves to low-inflation policy (Kydland and Prescott1977). One approach to overcome this time-inconsistency problem is to establishreputation (Backus and Driffill 1985). While the public may not know central bankers’preferences, policymakers’ behavior conveys information about their characteristics,and the public will adapt their expectations about inflation accordingly. Cukiermanand Meltzer (1986) emphasize the importance of uncertainty about the underlyingpreferences of governors. A less conservative governor (dovish) has an incentive tomimic the behavior of the more conservative one (hawkish) for a while, but sooner orlater, it becomes optimal to behave opportunistically. Uncertainty can be expected tobe highest at the beginning of a governor’s tenure. In a similar vein, Schaumburg and

Page 4: Do Markets Care about Central Bank Governor Changes? Evidence from Emerging Markets

1592 : MONEY, CREDIT AND BANKING

Tambalotti (2007) and Kara (2007) state that newly appointed central bank governorssuffer from a systematic credibility problem: while incumbent governors can committo policies during their own administration, their successors might deviate and pursuediscretionary policies. We therefore hypothesize the following:

Hypothesis 1. Investors react negatively to central bank governor changes due to asystematic credibility problem at the start of new governors’ tenure.

One way to remedy the inconsistency problem is proposed by Rogoff (1985) andentails the delegation of monetary policy to a conservative central bank. Eijffinger andHoeberichts (1998) and Berger, de Haan, and Eijffinger (2001) develop an argumentin the spirit of Rogoff. The government seeks to minimize the following loss function,representing the preferences of society:

LGov = 1

2π2

t + χ

2(yt − y∗

t )2,

where π t is the rate of inflation at day t, yt is output, y∗t denotes desired output, and

χ is the government’s weight on output stabilization (χ > 0). The loss function ofthe central banker is expected to differ from that of the government in one importantaspect:

LC B = 1 + ε

2π2

t + χ

2(yt − y∗

t )2,

where ε denotes the additional inflation aversion of the central bank governor, that is,his conservatism. Furthermore, Eijffinger and Hoeberichts (1998) argue that centralbankers’ preferences only matter to the extent to which they can pursue monetarypolicy without (much) government interference. This can be captured in the followingway:

Mt = γ LC B + (1 − γ ) LGov,

where γ and Mt denote the degree of central bank independence and monetarypolicy, respectively. Assuming that output is determined by a simplified Lucas supplyfunction and assuming rational expectations, inflation turns out to be:

πt = χy∗t − χ

χ + 1μt and πt = χ

1 + γ εy∗

t − χ

1 + γ ε + χμt .

The equation on the left (right) represents the inflation outcome without (with)delegation of monetary policy.3 Comparing these two outcomes, it becomes clearthat it is the product of central bank independence and conservatism that mattersfor monetary policy. We label this product “effective conservatism” of monetary

3. μt denotes a random shock with zero mean and variance σμ and is part of the simplified Lucassupply function.

Page 5: Do Markets Care about Central Bank Governor Changes? Evidence from Emerging Markets

CHRISTOPH MOSER AND AXEL DREHER : 1593

policy. For positive values of γ and ε, any increase of either the degree of centralbank independence or the central bank governor’s conservatism will decrease theinflationary bias, ceteris paribus. The same level of monetary policy can be achievedthrough various combinations of the two dimensions.

From the above, changing the central bank governor might affect financial marketexpectations along these two dimensions. First, changes at the head of the central bankmay carry signals about the future stance of the incumbent government on the centralbank’s independence. If central bank governors’ resignations are politically motivatedand/or incoming governors lack political independence, financial markets are likelyto react negatively. Second, a newly appointed central bank governor’s attitude towardinflation might deviate from that of her predecessor. If the new governor is perceivedto be more conservative than the old one, market reactions should be positive. Fromthis, we derive the following two hypotheses:

Hypothesis 2. Investors react to central bank governor changes due to changes inperceived conservatism.

Hypothesis 3. Investors react to central bank governor changes due to changes inperceived central bank independence.

We employ various characteristics of outgoing and newly appointed governors andtheir nominating governments to distinguish between these two channels.4,5

Clearly, governor changes might affect exchange markets, stock markets, and bondmarkets to different degrees and even in different directions. We address each ofthese markets in turn. We implicitly assume that the semistrong form of the efficientmarket hypothesis holds. Under this hypothesis, security prices are assumed to reflectall public information and to adjust swiftly to the arrival of such information. In thisvein, if markets fully anticipate a change of governor, prices will not react on theofficial announcement day.

1.1 Foreign Exchange Markets

Following Kuttner and Posen (2010), our starting point for analyzing the impact ofcentral bank governor changes on the exchange rate is uncovered interest rate parity:

Et�et+1 = i∗t − it ,

4. In the working paper version of this paper, we also investigated whether markets react to personalcharacteristics of the incoming central bank governor. We test whether incoming governors educated inthe United States or United Kingdom are perceived to be more conservative and credible than thosewithout such education, since investors can better anticipate their preferences. We also analyzed incominggovernors with a history in their central bank (insiders) and those without (outsiders). Moreover, weinvestigated whether market reactions depend on the central bank’s degree of independence.

5. To the best of our knowledge, the only other study that seeks to disentangle the two Rogoffdimensions is Berger and Woitek (2005). They find that conservatism does matter for Germany, where theBundesbank enjoyed a virtually unchanged high degree of independence in the postwar period.

Page 6: Do Markets Care about Central Bank Governor Changes? Evidence from Emerging Markets

1594 : MONEY, CREDIT AND BANKING

with e being the log of the foreign exchange rate (foreign currency/domestic cur-rency), i being the domestic interest rate, and i∗ being the foreign interest rate.Solving forward, we obtain

et = Et

[T −1∑s=0

(it+s − i∗t+s) + eT

],

where eT , the nominal exchange rate at some future date T , can be thought of asthe expected equilibrium exchange rate, determined by—for large enough values ofT—purchasing power parity. Hence, expected changes in monetary policy can affectthe foreign exchange rate either through expected changes in the nominal interest ratedifferentials and/or changes in the expected long-run exchange rate. For an increasein effective conservatism, that is, either an increase in central bank independence orconservatism, we expect the foreign exchange rate to appreciate. Alternatively, thedomestic currency might depreciate during a period of financial crisis (Caballero andKrishnamurthy 2001, 2002).

1.2 Domestic Stock Markets

The effect of a change in the expected monetary policy on stock markets is lessobvious than for exchange markets. Following Campbell et al. (1997), the stock pricecan be expressed as the expected value of future dividends (D) out to the infinitefuture, discounted at a constant rate (R).

Pt = Et

[ ∞∑i=1

(1

1 + R

)i

Dt+i

].

For this classic “Gordon growth model,” changes in monetary policy expectationscan affect stock prices through two different channels. Policy expectations mightsimply affect the discount rate or more subtly affect the expected future dividendstream. In summary, while the direct effect of higher expected inflation on stockprices is ambiguous, to the extent that it is associated with greater economic turmoil,investors may demand a higher risk premium.

1.3 Foreign-Currency-Denominated Bond Markets

The classical approach to model sovereign bond yields dates back to Edwards(1984), where the spread is denoted as a function of the probability of default (pd)and the risk-free interest rate (i*)

s = pd

1 − pd(1 + i∗).

Since our bond data are restricted to foreign-currency-denominated public or pub-licly guaranteed debt, bonds are not sensitive to changing inflation expectations andany possible transmission channel is of an indirect nature via the changing perception

Page 7: Do Markets Care about Central Bank Governor Changes? Evidence from Emerging Markets

CHRISTOPH MOSER AND AXEL DREHER : 1595

of the probability of default. News that increases the sovereign’s perceived defaultprobability is expected to lower bond prices and, hence, increase sovereign bondspreads.6

2. DATA

Our analysis is based on several types of data. Our main selection criterion isthe availability of reliable daily data on the foreign exchange, and stock and bondmarkets for emerging countries. The resulting sample spans the period 1992–2006for the following 20 economies: Argentina, Brazil, Chile, China, Colombia, Egypt,Hungary, Malaysia, Mexico, Morocco, Pakistan, Peru, Philippines, Poland, Russia,South Africa, South Korea, Thailand, Turkey, and Venezuela. The number of obser-vations varies, however, across countries. The exact data availability and summarystatistics are provided in Appendices A and B.

A central component of our daily data set is the unique sample of exact announce-ment dates of changes of central bank governors, which we have identified through afull-text analysis of the Economist, the Wall Street Journal, and the Financial Times,using the database LexisNexis.7 Overall, this procedure yields 65 events, compris-ing 44 resignations and 21 appointments at the head of a central bank. Appendix Cpresents the number of events per country in our sample, with Argentina and Brazilshowing the greatest number of turnovers.8

We have cautiously sought to infer from newspaper articles whether and to whatextent the respective changes had been anticipated. If the change was largely an-ticipated by the markets, we would expect a softer reaction in market movements.While we can be confident about the hard facts, that is, the name and position of thegovernor and his date of departure, the soft facts about the surprise content should beinterpreted more cautiously. Appendix D gives a precise listing of the timing, nature,and reason of central bank governor changes. We complete our sample with data onthe partisanship of the nominating government, drawn from the Database of PoliticalInstitutions (see Beck et al. 2001).

Our sovereign bond spread data are denominated in U.S. dollars and drawn fromJ.P. Morgan. The Emerging Market Bond Index (EMBI) sovereign bond spreads are

6. We can think of two different channels along which central bank governor changes affect theperceived probability of default. First, if the change at the head of the central bank is interpreted as a signof political interference, investors will be expected to demand a higher yield. A less independent centralbanker (for any given level of conservatism) makes it more likely that fiscal policy ultimately dominatesmonetary policy, driving up public debt and the probability of default. Second, a more conservativeresponse to excess inflation raises (for given level of independence) expected real interest rates, reducingexpected investment and growth rates. This in turn will worsen the debt sustainability, increasing theprobability of default and, hence, the sovereign bond spread. Alternatively, one can argue once more inline with Caballero and Krishnamurthy (2001, 2002).

7. These three financial newspapers are backed by other press sources available through LexisNexis,where necessary. We also compared the dates of resignation with official sources, most of which are listedin the database of central bank governor turnovers provided in Dreher, Sturm, and de Haan (2010); seehttp://www.kof.ethz.ch/centralbankgovernors.

8. Neither the exclusion of Brazil nor Argentina would qualitatively change the results below.

Page 8: Do Markets Care about Central Bank Governor Changes? Evidence from Emerging Markets

1596 : MONEY, CREDIT AND BANKING

calculated as the yield difference between the (basket of a country’s) emerging marketbond(s) and a comparable U.S. bond.9 These country indices are closely monitoredindicators for perceived country risk in emerging markets and can be interpretedas a default premium charged by investors above the risk-free interest rate. Onlysovereign bonds that comply with well-defined liquidity requirements are eligible forJ.P. Morgan’s bond indices.

Turning to stock markets, we use Morgan Stanley Capital International (MSCI)local market indices, obtained from Datastream. The MSCI data used here are dailyreturns of indices, excluding dividends, and measured in local currency. The in-dices measure market performance for selected securities, capturing the market-capitalization-weighted return of all constituents included.10

The exchange rate data is obtained from Bloomberg. Daily foreign exchange ratesvis-a-vis the U.S. dollar are employed, whereby an increasing foreign exchange ratemeans a depreciation of the domestic currency vis-a-vis the U.S. dollar.

We also employ a number of control variables. We control for U.S. financial marketindicators using the yield of 10-year U.S. Treasury bonds and 3-month U.S. T-bills.Both variables are widely used to control for international liquidity. Finally, we addthe Volatility Index (VIX) of the Chicago Board Options Exchange (CBOE). TheVIX measures the implied volatility from option contracts on the Standard & Poor’s100 (S&P 100) index and, hence, can be interpreted as a forward-looking indicatorof global risk aversion.

3. METHOD AND RESULTS

To test for the effects of central bank governor changes on financial markets, weemploy three different dependent variables: sovereign bond spreads, stock marketindices, and foreign exchange rates vis-a-vis the U.S. dollar.

We start by considering the average market reaction of our variables of interest (�y)to news announcements, following Kuttner and Posen (2010). As the volatility of ourdependent variables varies over time and country, we normalize �y by dividing it byits estimated standard deviation σ over the 90 days preceding the announcement. Thestatistic we use is thus zi ≡ (�yt )/σ . Under the null hypothesis that news regardingthe change of the central bank governor contains no relevant information, �y followsthe preannouncement distribution with zero mean and unit variance (Kuttner andPosen 2010). We test whether the average change in our normalized dependentvariables significantly differs from zero on days where the replacement of a governoris announced. We thus assume that the effect of a governor change materializes on that

9. Henceforth, the notion EMBI is used synonymously for EMBI, Emerging Markets Bond Index PlusEMBI+, and Emerging Markets Bond Global EMBIG. We mainly rely on the EMBI+ due to its largecoverage, its liquidity requirements, and its up-to-date record. Bond spread data from the early 1990s areobtained from EMBI. For Chile and Uruguay, only EMBIG data are available.

10. Note that the returns on MSCI and the respective country index are highly correlated (Pantzalis,Stangeland, and Turtle 2000).

Page 9: Do Markets Care about Central Bank Governor Changes? Evidence from Emerging Markets

CHRISTOPH MOSER AND AXEL DREHER : 1597

TABLE 1

AVERAGE MARKET REACTION TO EVENTS

Sample Exchange rate Bond yield Stock price

CB resignation (all) Avg. change 0.493 0.297 −0.225N 41 44 44p-value 0.001 0.049 0.136

CB resignation (irregular) Avg. change 0.770 0.248 −0.272N 32 34 34p-value 0.000 0.148 0.113

CB resignation (regular) Avg. change −0.493 0.462 −0.063N 9 10 10p-value 0.139 0.144 0.842

Partisanship Avg. change 0.797 0.097 −0.294N 8 9 9p-value 0.024 0.771 0.378

CB appointment Avg. change 3.217 −0.263 0.766N 20 21 21p-value 0.000 0.228 0.000

NOTES: The table evaluates whether the mean change of our variables of interest (�y) over the sample period, normalized by dividingit by its estimated standard deviation σ over the 90 days preceding the announcement, equals their mean change on the event days. Wetest whether the average change in our normalized dependent variables significantly differs from zero on days where the replacement of agovernor is announced. CB resignation refers to the announcement day of the resignation of a central bank governor, whereby a resignationis coded as irregular if the central bank governor change occurred before the expiration of the central bank’s tenure and as regular otherwise.Partisanship indicates that the current nominating government is less conservative than the government that nominated the previous governor.CB appointment denotes the announcement day of the appointment of a central bank governor.

same day. The average dependent variables are approximately normally distributedwith variance 1/N, where N is the number of events in our sample.11

Table 1 shows the value of the z-statistics, indicating the respective levels ofsignificance. As can be seen, the results show some interesting patterns. Resignationsincrease bond spreads at the 5% level of significance and lead to an exchange ratedepreciation at the 1% level.12 Relating these results to our hypotheses, investors doindeed react to central bank governor changes. In line with Hypothesis 1, the averagemarket reaction to the announcement of the resignation of the central bank governor isnegative in two out of the three financial markets. On average, emerging markets thusseem to react differently than markets in advanced countries. While Kuttner and Posen(2010) report that markets do react significantly to governor changes for their sampleof 15 industrialized countries, their results do not follow a unidirectional pattern:domestic-currency-denominated bond yields do not, on average, rise, nor does theexchange rate depreciate, in response to the announcement of a new governor. Kuttnerand Posen thus reject the widely held belief that markets might react due to a lack ofcredibility at the start of a governor’s tenure. This is contrary to our own results.

The appointments of new governors do not affect bond spreads significantly butlead, on average, to a depreciation of the exchange rate and an increase in stock prices

11. In the working paper version of this paper, we provide two further simple methods, which producequalitatively similar results.

12. In a test for robustness, we increased the event period to include 1 day prior and 1 day after theannouncement day. Our results are sensitive to this change to some extent. While our findings on theexchange rate effects remain very similar, bond spreads are no longer significantly affected.

Page 10: Do Markets Care about Central Bank Governor Changes? Evidence from Emerging Markets

1598 : MONEY, CREDIT AND BANKING

(at the 1% level of significance).13 The stock market reaction can be interpreted in linewith Brown, Harlow, and Tinic (1988) who show that the resolution of uncertaintyleads to positive market reactions, on average. Once the successor is announced,pending uncertainty about the new head of the central bank is resolved.

What about the impact of effective conservatism on financial markets? Turning tothe first dimension of effective conservatism, we draw on the Database of PoliticalInstitutions (Beck et al. 2001) to construct a proxy for perceived conservatism. Thedatabase classifies the partisanship of an incumbent government as left, center, orright. Our variable takes a value of 1 when partisanship of the government nominat-ing the current governor is to the left of the government who nominated the previousgovernor, –1 when the nominating government is more conservative than the previousone, and 0 if the government’s degree of conservatism remains unchanged. In con-structing this proxy for the central bank governor’s conservatism, we follow Bergerand Woitek (2005), who assume that right-wing governments tend to nominate moreinflation-averse central bank governors, and vice versa. Arguably, the assumptionthat the nominating governments’ political color corresponds to those of the gover-nor is debatable. We therefore checked our coding by employing full-text analysisin LexisNexis. While exclusive reliance on LexisNexis would reduce the number ofevents and would not allow meaningful econometric analysis, those cases where wecould identify the relative conservatism of an incoming governor largely confirm thevalidity of our coding (see Appendix E).

Table 1 reports results for a sample of resignations where the government nomi-nating the incoming governor has a different political partisanship than the one thatappointed the previous governor. More specifically, the table shows market reactionswhen central bank governors are appointed by less conservative governors, as de-fined above. As argued in Hypothesis 2, markets react to changes in the governors’perceived conservatism. When a governor resigns and the incumbent government onthe announcement day is less conservative than the one that nominated the outgo-ing governor, markets should thus react negatively. As can be seen, we find such anegative reaction in favor of Hypothesis 2 only for the inflation sensitive exchangerate. Note, however, that the very small number of (a maximum of nine) observationsmakes this finding rather tentative.

We also gain insight into Hypothesis 3 by separating regular from irregular res-ignations. While irregular events apparently drive the negative announcement effecton the exchange rate, the effects are marginally insignificant for the bond and stockmarket. We do not find evidence for significant market reactions to regular resig-nations. If markets were primarily concerned about the incoming governor lackingcredibility, we would expect regular and irregular events to be equally likely to affectmarkets. If, however, central bank independence is perceived to be at risk, irregularchanges of central bank governors should drive the results. Hence, irregular events

13. Note, however, that the very small sample size might drive the insignificant effect of appointmentson bond spreads.

Page 11: Do Markets Care about Central Bank Governor Changes? Evidence from Emerging Markets

CHRISTOPH MOSER AND AXEL DREHER : 1599

can be expected to alter perceived central bank independence, which is one of thetwo key determinants of inflationary bias.14

Arguably, stock markets and U.S. dollar-denominated sovereign bonds are ratherinsensitive to changes in expected inflation. This might explain why we cannot findevidence in favor of Hypothesis 3 for these financial markets. However, note onceagain that these conclusions rest on a very small number of observations, and are thusonly tentative.

As a next step, we conduct panel data analysis. Our baseline regression is estimatedby pooled ordinary least squares (OLS) with robust standard errors clustered at thecountry level15 and takes the following form:

�Yi,t = α + λ�Yi,t−1 + βRESIGNi,t + γ APPOINTi,t + η�Xi,t

+ νw Dw + εi,t , (1)

where the subscripts i and t indicate country and time, respectively. Yi,t representsthe respective dependent variables denoted in log-differences. The one-period laggedvalue of the dependent variable also enters the equation as a covariate. Our coefficientsof interest are β and γ , accounting for the impact of resignations, RESIGNi,t, and newappointments, APPOINTi,t, at the head of the central bank.16 The two announcementvariables are 1 on the day of the change and 0 otherwise. We denote the error termεi,t and employ dummy variables Dw, running from Monday to Thursday, in order tocontrol for day-of-the-week effects.

The matrix Xi,t includes the three U.S. financial market indicators introduced above.We employ (log) changes of the volatility index, and (log) changes in 10-year U.S.Treasury bond yields and 3-month U.S. T-bill yields, defined as 100 × log (1 + it,US).

By definition, fixed exchange rate regimes do not allow for daily market reactionsto the announcement of the turnover. For this reason, we interact the resignation orappointment variable with a dummy variable that takes the value of 1 when there is aflexible exchange rate (or at least not a fully pegged exchange rate) and 0 otherwise.17

Finally, as one potential caveat to the analysis, central bank governors might bedismissed as a consequence of economic crises, giving rise to endogeneity. Whengovernors are dismissed due to economic shocks, market reactions might reflect theseshocks rather than the exogenous change in who governs the central bank. While thisargument appears reasonable for quarterly or yearly data, endogeneity is unlikelyto be an issue when data frequency is daily, as is the case in our study. Even if

14. In coding the dummy for irregular changes, we follow Kuttner and Posen (2010) and also classifycases in which the incumbent governor was eligible for reappointment, but did not receive it, as irregular.Note that these kinds of irregular changes constitute a very small number of all irregular resignations.

15. We do not include fixed country effects as they are not jointly significant at conventional levels.Our key results are not changed by their exclusion.

16. On average, the new central bank governor is announced 10 days after the resignation of hispredecessor. We only measure appointments when they constitute an independent event.

17. We code an exchange rate regime as flexible as long as at least some market reactions are observablein the weeks around the day of the event.

Page 12: Do Markets Care about Central Bank Governor Changes? Evidence from Emerging Markets

1600 : MONEY, CREDIT AND BANKING

TABLE 2

FINANCIAL MARKETS AND GOVERNOR CHANGES, 20 COUNTRIES, 1992–2006

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)Stock price Stock price IV Exchange rate Bond yield Bond yield IV

� log y, lagged 0.1062∗∗∗ 0.1854∗∗∗ 0.0249 −0.1925∗∗∗ 0.5765∗∗∗(6.55) (3.12) (0.53) (3.38) (14.23)

CB resignation −0.0042∗ −0.0045∗∗ 0.0097∗∗∗ 0.0047 0.0152∗∗∗(1.96) (2.23) (2.89) (1.43) (4.23)

CB appointment 0.0140 0.0129 −0.0073 0.0002 −0.0086(1.40) (1.36) (0.72) (0.02) (0.83)

� log volatility index (VIX) −0.0534∗∗∗ −0.0538∗∗∗ 0.0053∗∗ 0.0825∗∗∗ 0.0801∗∗∗(4.66) (4.70) (2.62) (5.45) (5.44)

� log U.S. T-bond 10 years 0.0682∗∗∗ 0.0658∗∗ 0.0176∗ −0.9960∗∗∗ −0.9299∗∗∗(3.94) (3.73) (1.97) (4.09) (3.91)

� log U.S. T-bill 3 months 0.0158 0.0167 −0.0043 −0.1355 −0.2050∗∗(1.01) (1.01) (0.77) (1.71) (2.22)

Observations 51,423 51,422 51,423 51,399 51,375R2 0.04 0.03 0.003 0.07 —

NOTES: The dependent variable is the (log) change in y. Results are based on clustered standard errors. (absolute) values of t-statistics inparentheses. Week-day effects and a constant are estimated but not reported. The instrumental variable (IV) estimation in columns (2) and(5) uses the second lag of the dependent variable as instrument for the lagged dependent variable. Testing for first-order autocorrelation inthe error term indicates no first-order auto correlation.∗∗∗ , ∗∗ , ∗denote 1%, 5%, 10% level of significance.

the governor is fired as a consequence of macroeconomic crisis, such crises usuallyunfold over a longer period of time, so that daily data can still be used to identify thecausal impact of the turnover itself on market reactions. Endogeneity is thus unlikelyto be an issue here. Still, the effect of central bank governor turnovers might bedifferent during times of crisis, a matter to which we return below.

Table 2 reports the results of the panel data analysis. Column (1) reports thebase specification while the potential bias introduced by the correlation between thelagged dependent variable and the error term is addressed in column (2). We thereforeinstrument the (highly significant) lagged dependent variable with its second lag(Anderson and Hsiao 1982). Our results are hardly changed by this. Column (3)shows the results for the exchange rate. Finally, results for bond spreads are reportedin columns (4) and (5). The lagged dependent variable is completely insignificantin column (3) and we therefore do not instrument it. While the lagged dependentvariable is highly significant according to the OLS specification of column (4), witha negative coefficient, it becomes significantly positive once instrumented (column(5)).

Turning to our variables of interest, Table 2 again shows some support for our hy-potheses and, specifically, that financial markets do react to the resignation of centralbankers. By contrast, the announcement of the appointment of a governor has nosignificant impact. Overall, the results regarding appointments are thus weaker thanthose reported earlier in Table 1. We base our conclusions on the more stringent re-gression analysis. As can be seen in the table, domestic stock markets react negativelyto central bank governor resignations. The estimated coefficients in columns (1) and

Page 13: Do Markets Care about Central Bank Governor Changes? Evidence from Emerging Markets

CHRISTOPH MOSER AND AXEL DREHER : 1601

(2) imply a small decline in returns of about 0.5 percentage points. While being farfrom a dramatic crash of markets, this effect is, arguably, economically relevant. Thestock market announcement effect is about five times higher than the one triggeredby changes in sovereign ratings and sovereign rating outlooks in emerging markets(Kaminsky and Schmukler 2002).18

Column (3) shows that the resignation of a central banker leads to a depreciation ofthe exchange rate, at the 1% level of significance.19 The estimated coefficient impliesa depreciation of almost 1 percentage point following the resignation of a centralbanker. Finally, columns (4) and (5) show that bond spreads do not increase followingthe resignation of the head of the central bank according to the OLS regressions butdo increase (at the 1% level of significance) once the lagged dependent variable isinstrumented. According to the coefficient, the resignation of a central bank governorincreases bond spreads by more than 1.5 percentage points.

Based on our results, we cannot reject Hypothesis 1, stressing the credibility prob-lem at the start of a governor’s tenure. As potential objection to this interpretation, thenegative market reactions might, of course, simply reflect the presence of a financialcrisis, indicated by the resignation of the governor. We therefore include interactionterms between our proxies for crises and changes of central bank governors. Thefollowing specification accounts for financial crises:

�Yi,t = α + λ�Yi,t−1 + β1RESIGNi,t + β2RESIGNi,t ∗ CRISISi,t

+ γ1APPOINTi,t + γ2APPOINTi,t ∗ CRISISi,t + η�Xi,t + νw Dw

+φCRISISi,t + εi,t , (2)

where our variable CRISISi,t takes the value of 1 in case of an ongoing currencycrisis in country i in month t and 0 otherwise. We follow Kaminsky and Reinhart(1999) and compute a foreign exchange market pressure index as an average ofthe rate of change of the exchange rate and of international reserves, weighted bytheir standard deviations.20 Following Dreher, Herz, and Karb (2006), a country isdefined to be in a currency crisis when its index deviates from the index mean for thatcountry by at least one standard deviation. According to this definition, 11 centralbankers from nine countries have been dismissed during a currency crisis in oursample.

Table 3 shows the results. As can be seen, currency crises never enter significantlyin any of our regressions. Similarly, the interaction of crises and dismissals is notsignificant at conventional levels in any specification, and with the exception of

18. This comparison can only be made for the U.S. dollar-denominated MSCI index (results notshown).

19. Note that this result remains when the insignificant lagged dependent variable is omitted from theregression.

20. Ideally, we would also like to include interest rates that monetary authorities can use to defendparities. However, this leaves us with a drastically reduced sample, and so, following Kaminsky andReinhart (1999), we do not include interest rates.

Page 14: Do Markets Care about Central Bank Governor Changes? Evidence from Emerging Markets

1602 : MONEY, CREDIT AND BANKING

TABLE 3

FINANCIAL MARKETS, GOVERNOR CHANGES, AND FINANCIAL CRISES, 20 COUNTRIES, 1992–2006

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)Stock price Stock price IV Exchange rate Bond yield Bond yield IV

� log y, lagged 0.1060∗∗∗ 0.1851∗∗∗ 0.0221 −0.1926∗∗∗ 0.5766∗∗∗(6.52) (3.13) (0.52) (3.38) (14.2)

CB resignation [1] −0.0051∗ −0.0054∗∗ 0.0090∗∗ 0.0051 0.0136∗∗∗(1.97) (2.23) (2.54) (1.44) (4.19)

CB resignation (crisis) [2] 0.0046 0.0046 0.0044 −0.0027 0.0089(0.82) (0.85) (0.37) (0.44) (0.59)

CB appointment [3] 0.0080 0.0075 0.0048 −0.0119 −0.0172(1.68) (1.50) (1.51) (1.12) (1.51)

CB appointment (crisis) [4] 0.0314 0.0284 −0.0607 0.0635∗∗ 0.0451∗(0.68) (0.65) (1.46) (2.75) (1.88)

� log volatility index (VIX) −0.0534∗∗∗ −0.0538∗∗∗ 0.0053∗∗ 0.0824∗∗∗ 0.0801∗∗∗(4.67) (4.70) (2.64) (5.44) (5.44)

� log U.S. T-bond 10 years 0.0682∗∗∗ 0.0658∗∗∗ 0.0176∗ −0.9961∗∗∗ −0.9299∗∗∗(3.93) (3.73) (1.97) (4.09) (3.91)

� log U.S. T-bill 3 months 0.0156 0.0165 −0.0042 −0.1357 −0.2051∗∗(1.01) (1.00) (0.76) (1.71) (2.22)

Currency crisis period −0.0001 −0.0001 −0.0003 −0.0002 −0.0003(1.01) (0.40) (1.49) (0.33) (1.14)

Joint significance [1] + [2] 0.16 0.10 0.03 0.36 0.00Joint significance [3] + [4] 0.19 0.25 0.16 0.04 0.16Observations 51,423 51,422 51,423 51,399 51,375R2 0.04 0.03 0.006 0.07 —

NOTES: The dependent variable is the (log) change in y. Results are based on clustered robust standard errors. The (absolute) values oft-statistics are in parentheses. Week-day effects and a constant are estimated but not reported. The instrumental variable (IV) estimation incolumns (2) and (5) uses the second lag of the dependent variable as instrument for the lagged dependent variable. The coefficients [2] and [4]represent the respective interaction with our crisis dummy. Testing for first-order autocorrelation. The in the error term indicates no first-ordercorrelation. p-values for test of joint significance are reported.∗∗∗ , ∗∗ , ∗denote 1%, 5%, 10% level of significance.

the bond market, the same is true regarding the interaction of appointments andcrises. We actually do find some statistically weak evidence that appointments areperceived more negatively by sovereign bond holders during currency crises than intranquil times. Note, however, that while the point estimates for the stock market,foreign exchange, and bond markets marginally change when we control for financialcrises, overall, there is neither evidence for an increased sensitivity to central bankturnovers in crisis times nor for an additional risk premium following turnovers duringcrises.21

Coming back to Hypothesis 1, we conclude that our results do not reflect a riskpremium. However, the negative market reactions are also in line with a decreasein perceived effective conservatism. Given the results in Table 2, we cannot knowwhether Hypothesis 1 or, alternatively, Hypotheses 2 or 3 hold true. In order to

21. Note that the coefficient on central bank appointments is marginally insignificant in column (1).This is even though the t-statistic of 1.68 with more than 50,000 observations might suggest otherwise.However, the standard errors are clustered at the country level, so the number of clusters (M) becomesthe relevant dimension to determine the degrees of freedom. The confidence values Stata 11 reports whenclustering standard errors are based on (more conservative) critical values from a Student’s t-distributionwith M–1 degrees of freedom.

Page 15: Do Markets Care about Central Bank Governor Changes? Evidence from Emerging Markets

CHRISTOPH MOSER AND AXEL DREHER : 1603

disentangle the two dimensions of “effective conservatism” we estimate the followingequation:

�Yi,t = α + λ�Yi,t−1 + β1RESIGNi,t + β2RESIGNi,t ∗ PARTISANi,t

+β3RESIGNi,t ∗ IRREGi,t + γ APPOINTi,t + η�Xi,t

+ νw Dw + εi,t , (3)

where PARTISANi,t is our proxy for the governor’s perceived conservatism describedabove and IRREGi,t is a dummy variable that takes the value of 1 when the centralbank governor change occurred before the expiration of the central bank governor’stenure and 0 otherwise.22 According to the results (not shown in a table), almostno coefficient of interest is significant at conventional levels. There is one importantexception, however. Irregular turnovers lead to a depreciation of the exchange rate,with a coefficient significant at the 5% level. This provides some evidence thatinvestors are indeed worried about central bank independence when central bankgovernors resign before the end of their tenure.

4. CONCLUSION

Central bank governor changes in emerging markets may convey important signalsabout future monetary policy. Based on a new daily data set on 20 countries over the1992–2006 period, this paper has examined the reactions of foreign exchange markets,domestic stock market indices, and sovereign bond spreads to the announcement ofa central bank governor change.

Our results show, first, that the resignation of a central bank governor negativelyaffects financial markets on the announcement day, with average market reactionsbetween 0.5 and 1.5 percentage points. By contrast, we find little evidence thatappointments of new governors convey relevant news to investors.

Second, comparing our results with those found in the existing literature, we findthat our results for emerging market economies are distinct from industrialized coun-tries in an interesting and important way. Newly appointed central bank governorsapparently suffer from a systematic credibility problem at the beginning of theirtenure. In contrast to their counterparts in industrialized countries, emerging marketgovernors initially have to face (at least) a transitory rise in inflation expectations,because investors are uncertain about the true type of the central bank governor(hawkish versus dovish).

Third, the negative announcement effect for resignations is mainly driven by irreg-ular changes, that is, changes occurring before the scheduled end of tenure. Foreign

22. Note that we cannot include PARTISAN and IRREG individually, as they, by definition, can onlybe observed when the governor changes. We do not interact the appointment dummy with changes inpartisanship, since the incumbent government’s partisanship, and hence potential changes in ideologyvis-a-vis the government nominating the previous central bank governor, are already priced in on theresignation day.

Page 16: Do Markets Care about Central Bank Governor Changes? Evidence from Emerging Markets

1604 : MONEY, CREDIT AND BANKING

exchange market participants are apparently sensitive to signals about perceivedcentral bank independence, expecting higher inflationary bias.

Finally, we find little evidence that the governor’s degree of conservatism mattersfor market reactions. Still, this lack of significance might well be due to the verylimited number of observations for changes in conservatism.

Overall, our study complements Santiso (2003), pointing out that key policymakersin emerging markets are crucial for building credibility in international financialmarkets in one important aspect. Investors are apparently sensitive to the way inwhich an incumbent government handles the replacement of key policymakers. Withrespect to central bank governor changes, investors seem to care most about perceivedcentral bank independence. Future research to further disentangle the two dimensionsof effective conservatism is clearly desirable.

Page 17: Do Markets Care about Central Bank Governor Changes? Evidence from Emerging Markets

CHRISTOPH MOSER AND AXEL DREHER : 1605

APPENDIX A: DATA AVAILABILITY, EMBI (G), FX TO U.S. DOLLAR, ANDMSCI AVAILABLE

Country Start End

Argentina April 30, 1993 July 31, 2006Brazil January 15, 1992 July 31, 2006Chile May 28, 1999 July 31, 2006China December 31, 1997 July 31, 2006Colombia December 31, 1997 July 31, 2006Egypt July 31, 2001 July 31, 2006Hungary January 1, 1999 July 31, 2006Malaysia December 31, 1997 July 31, 2006Mexico December 31, 1991 July 31, 2006Morocco December 31, 1997 July 31, 2006Pakistan June 29, 2001 July 31, 2006Peru May 30, 1997 July 31, 2006Philippines December 31, 1991 July 31, 2006Poland December 31, 1997 July 31, 2006Russia December 31, 1997 July 31, 2006South Africa December 31, 1997 July 31, 2006South Korea December 31, 1997 July 31, 2006Thailand December 31, 1997 March 31, 2006Turkey December 31, 1997 July 31, 2006Venezuela December 31, 1992 July 31, 2006

APPENDIX B: DESCRIPTIVE STATISTICS

Variable Mean Std. dev. Min Max

(log) Spread 5.68 1.07 0.00 8.88(log) MSCI 5.53 1.06 2.55 8.61(log) Exchange rate 3.09 −2.44 7.82 8.00Central banker change 0.00 0.03 0.00 1.00(log) VIX 2.91 0.32 2.23 3.90(log) U.S. T-bond 10 years 1.94 0.22 1.41 2.35(log) U.S. T-bill 3 months 1.62 0.42 0.59 2.31

APPENDIX C: NUMBER OF CENTRAL BANK GOVERNOR CHANGES BYCOUNTRY

Country Number events Country Number events

Argentina 6 (3) Pakistan 1 (1)Brazil 9 (2) Peru 4 (3)Chile 1 (1) Philippines 2 (1)China 1 (0) Poland 1 (2)Colombia 1 (0) Russia 2 (1)Egypt 2 (1) South Africa 0 (1)Hungary 1 (1) South Korea 2 (0)Malaysia 2 (1) Thailand 2 (0)Mexico 1 (0) Turkey 2 (2)Morocco 1 (0) Venezuela 3 (1)

NOTE: This table reports the number of central bank governor resignations (appointments). Our data are for the period of 1992–2006.

Page 18: Do Markets Care about Central Bank Governor Changes? Evidence from Emerging Markets

1606 : MONEY, CREDIT AND BANKINGA

PPE

ND

IXD

:CE

NT

RA

LB

AN

KG

OV

ER

NO

RC

HA

NG

ES:

LO

CA

TIO

N,D

AT

E,N

AM

E,A

ND

DIF

FER

EN

TN

EW

SC

HA

RA

CT

ER

IST

ICS

(199

2–20

06).

Cou

ntry

Dat

eaN

ame

Irre

gula

r(y

es/n

o)R

easo

nN

ews

char

acte

rN

ews

type

Arg

entin

a19

96R

oque

Fern

ande

zY

esFe

rnan

dez

step

sdo

wn

asgo

vern

orof

the

cent

ralb

ank

tobe

com

eec

onom

ym

inis

ter.

Not

antic

ipat

edR

esig

natio

n

Arg

entin

a19

96Pe

dro

Pou

–Po

uis

anno

unce

das

new

cent

ralb

ank

gove

rnor

.N

otan

ticip

ated

App

oint

men

t

Arg

entin

a20

01Pe

dro

Pou

Yes

Pres

iden

tDe

La

Rua

dism

isse

sPo

uon

alle

ged

bad

adm

inis

trat

ion.

Part

lyan

ticip

ated

Res

igna

tion

Arg

entin

a20

02R

oque

Mac

caro

neY

esM

acca

rone

sudd

enly

resi

gns

and

Mar

ioB

leje

rbe

com

eshi

ssu

cces

sor.

Not

antic

ipat

edR

esig

natio

n

Arg

entin

a20

02M

ario

Ble

jer

Yes

Ble

jer

step

sdo

wn

afte

rre

peat

edly

butti

nghe

ads

with

econ

omy

min

iste

rL

avag

na.

Part

lyan

ticip

ated

Res

igna

tion

Arg

entin

a20

02A

ldo

Pign

anel

li–

Pign

anel

liis

appo

inte

dby

the

pres

iden

t.Pa

rtly

antic

ipat

edA

ppoi

ntm

ent

Arg

entin

a20

02A

ldo

Pign

anel

liY

esPi

gnan

elli

isth

ird

top

bank

erto

resi

gnw

ithin

aye

ar.

Part

lyan

ticip

ated

Res

igna

tion

Arg

entin

a20

02A

lfon

soPr

atG

ay–

Form

erW

allS

tree

tban

ker

Prat

Gay

appo

inte

d.Pa

rtly

antic

ipat

edA

ppoi

ntm

ent

Arg

entin

a20

04A

lfon

soPr

atG

ayY

esPr

esid

entK

irch

ner

ina

surp

rise

mov

ere

plac

esPr

atG

ayby

Mar

tinR

edra

do.

Not

antic

ipat

edR

esig

natio

n

Bra

zil

1992

Fran

cisc

oG

ros

Yes

Gro

sis

succ

eede

dby

Gus

tavo

Loy

ola.

Part

lyan

ticip

ated

Res

igna

tion

Bra

zil

1993

Gus

tavo

Loy

ola

Yes

Loy

ala

resi

gns

alon

gw

ithth

eba

nk’s

who

ledi

rect

orat

e.N

otan

ticip

ated

Res

igna

tion

Bra

zil

1993

Paul

oC

esar

Xim

enes

–Pa

ulo

Ces

arX

imen

esis

tore

plac

eL

oyol

a.N

otan

ticip

ated

App

oint

men

t

Bra

zil

1993

Paul

oC

esar

Xim

enes

Yes

Pedr

oM

alan

repl

aces

Ces

arX

imen

esas

new

Cen

tral

Ban

kgo

vern

oraf

ter

disp

ute

with

Pres

iden

tFra

nco.

Part

lyan

ticip

ated

Res

igna

tion

Bra

zil

1994

Pedr

oM

alan

Yes

Mal

anis

nam

edto

beco

me

finan

cem

inis

ter.

Part

lyan

ticip

ated

Res

igna

tion

Bra

zil

1995

Pers

ioA

rida

Yes

Ari

daab

rupt

lyre

sign

sfo

rpe

rson

alre

ason

s.N

otan

ticip

ated

Res

igna

tion

Bra

zil

1997

Gus

tavo

Loy

ola

Yes

Loy

ola

step

sdo

wn

for

pers

onal

reas

ons

and

isim

med

iate

lyre

plac

edby

Gus

tavo

Fran

co.

Part

lyan

ticip

ated

Res

igna

tion

Bra

zil

1999

Gus

tavo

Fran

coY

esM

arke

tspl

umm

etw

hen

Cen

tral

Ban

kch

ief

Gus

tavo

Fran

coab

rupt

lyre

sign

s.Pa

rtly

antic

ipat

edR

esig

natio

n

Bra

zil

1999

Fran

cisc

oL

opes

Yes

Arm

inio

Frag

are

plac

esL

opes

.N

otan

ticip

ated

Res

igna

tion

(Con

tinu

ed)

Page 19: Do Markets Care about Central Bank Governor Changes? Evidence from Emerging Markets

CHRISTOPH MOSER AND AXEL DREHER : 1607A

PPE

ND

IXD

:CO

NT

INU

ED

Cou

ntry

Dat

eaN

ame

Irre

gula

r(y

es/n

o)R

easo

nN

ews

char

acte

rN

ews

type

Bra

zil

2002

Arm

inio

Frag

aY

esPr

esid

ent-

elec

tspo

kesm

anm

akes

clea

rth

atFr

aga

isno

tto

stay

atth

eC

entr

alB

ank.

Ant

icip

ated

Res

igna

tion

Bra

zil

2002

Hen

riqu

eM

eire

lles

–M

eire

lles

isan

noun

ced

tofo

llow

Frag

a.Pa

rtly

antic

ipat

edA

ppoi

ntm

ent

Chi

le20

03C

arlo

sM

assa

dY

esM

assa

dfin

ally

resi

gns

due

toa

finan

cial

scan

dal.

Part

lyan

ticip

ated

Res

igna

tion

Chi

le20

03V

ittor

ioC

orbo

–C

orbo

isof

ficia

llyno

min

ated

byPr

esid

ent

Lag

os.

Not

antic

ipat

edA

ppoi

ntm

ent

Chi

na20

02D

aiX

iang

long

Yes

Zho

uX

iaoc

huan

isna

med

gove

rnor

ofth

ePe

ople

’sB

ank

ofC

hina

,tak

ing

over

from

Xia

nglo

ng.

Part

lyan

ticip

ated

Res

igna

tion

Col

ombi

a20

04M

igue

lUrr

utia

No

Urr

utia

step

sdo

wn

afte

rhi

sth

ird

4-ye

arte

rm.J

ose

Dar

ioU

ribe

ishi

ssu

cces

sor.

Ant

icip

ated

Res

igna

tion

Egy

pt20

01Is

mai

lHas

san

No

Has

san’

ste

rmen

dsan

dhe

aske

dno

tto

bere

appo

inte

dfo

rpe

rson

alre

ason

s.A

ntic

ipat

edR

esig

natio

n

Egy

pt20

01M

ahm

oud

Abu

el-A

youn

–E

l-A

youn

,afo

rmer

econ

omic

spr

ofes

sor,

isap

poin

ted

tobe

com

ene

wC

entr

alB

ank

gove

rnor

.

Part

lyan

ticip

ated

App

oint

men

t

Egy

pt20

03M

ahm

oud

Abu

el-A

youn

Yes

Pres

iden

tMub

arak

appo

ints

Faro

ukel

-Oqd

aas

gove

rnor

ofth

eC

entr

alB

ank

repl

acin

gE

l-A

youn

.

Part

lyan

ticip

ated

Res

igna

tion

Hun

gary

2000

Gyo

rgy

Sura

nyi

Yes

Sura

nyi’s

rene

wab

leco

ntra

ctw

illno

tbe

exte

nded

.A

ntic

ipat

edR

esig

natio

n

Hun

gary

2001

Zsi

gmon

dJa

rai

–Ja

rair

ecei

ves

his

offic

iala

ppoi

ntm

entf

rom

Pres

iden

tMad

l.A

ntic

ipat

edA

ppoi

ntm

ent

Mal

aysi

a19

98A

hmad

Moh

amed

Don

Yes

Ahm

adD

onre

sign

sal

ong

with

his

depu

ty.

Part

lyan

ticip

ated

Res

igna

tion

Mal

aysi

a19

98A

liA

bdul

Has

san

–T

hehe

adof

the

Eco

nom

icPl

anni

ngU

nit,

Ali

Abd

ulH

assa

n,is

pick

edas

succ

esso

r.N

otan

ticip

ated

App

oint

men

t

Mal

aysi

a20

00A

liA

bdul

Has

san

No

Zei

tAkh

tar

Azi

zfo

llow

sup

onA

liA

bdul

Has

san’

sco

ntra

ctex

piry

.Pa

rtly

antic

ipat

edR

esig

natio

n

Mex

ico

1997

Mig

uelM

ance

raN

oM

ance

rare

tires

asex

pect

ed,b

utno

min

atio

nof

Fina

nce

Min

iste

rG

uille

rmo

Ort

izco

mes

asa

surp

rise

.

Ant

icip

ated

Res

igna

tion

(Con

tinu

ed)

Page 20: Do Markets Care about Central Bank Governor Changes? Evidence from Emerging Markets

1608 : MONEY, CREDIT AND BANKING

APP

EN

DIX

D:C

ON

TIN

UE

D

Cou

ntry

Dat

eaN

ame

Irre

gula

r(y

es/n

o)R

easo

nN

ews

char

acte

rN

ews

type

Mor

occo

2003

Moh

amed

Sekk

atN

oSe

kkat

isre

plac

edby

Abd

ella

tifJo

uahr

iWal

i.Pa

rtly

antic

ipat

edR

esig

natio

nPa

kist

an20

05Is

hrat

Hus

sain

No

Ishr

atou

tline

spl

ans

afte

rup

com

ing

retir

emen

t.A

ntic

ipat

edR

esig

natio

n

Paki

stan

2005

Sham

shad

Akh

tar

–Sh

amsh

adA

khta

ris

nam

edC

entr

alB

ank

gove

rnor

.Pa

rtly

antic

ipat

edA

ppoi

ntm

ent

Peru

2000

Ger

man

Suar

ez–

Suar

ezis

reap

poin

ted

byPr

esid

entF

ujim

ori.

Part

lyan

ticip

ated

App

oint

men

tPe

ru20

01G

erm

anSu

arez

Yes

Ric

hard

Web

bis

chos

enby

new

Pres

iden

tTo

ledo

.N

otan

ticip

ated

Res

igna

tion

Peru

2003

Ric

hard

Web

bY

esW

ebb

tend

ers

his

resi

gnat

ion

afte

rru

mor

sab

outi

nfigh

ting

ingo

vern

or’s

boar

d.Pa

rtly

antic

ipat

edR

esig

natio

n

Peru

2003

Javi

erSi

lva

Rue

te–

Fina

nce

Min

iste

rSi

lva

Rue

teis

nam

edne

wC

entr

alB

ank

gove

rnor

.Pa

rtly

antic

ipat

edA

ppoi

ntm

ent

Peru

2004

Osc

arD

anco

urt

–D

anco

urtb

ecom

esac

ting

Cen

tral

Ban

kgo

vern

ordu

eto

Silv

a’s

IMF

dire

ctor

ate

appo

intm

ent

Not

antic

ipat

edA

ppoi

ntm

ent

Peru

2004

Javi

erSi

lva

Rue

teY

esSi

lva

step

sdo

wn

afte

rcr

itici

smre

gard

ing

the

inco

mpa

tibili

tyof

his

new

posi

tion

asIM

Fdi

rect

orw

hile

pres

iden

tof

the

Cen

tral

Ban

k.

Part

lyan

ticip

ated

Res

igna

tion

Peru

2006

Osc

arD

anco

urt

Yes

New

pres

iden

tGar

cia

repl

aces

actin

gpr

esid

ent

ofth

eC

entr

alB

ank

Dan

cour

tby

Julio

Vel

arde

.

Not

antic

ipat

edR

esig

natio

n

Phili

ppin

es19

93Jo

seC

uisi

aN

oG

over

nor

Cui

sia

resi

gns

for

pers

onal

reas

ons.

Not

antic

ipat

edR

esig

natio

nPh

ilipp

ines

1993

Gab

riel

Sing

son

–Pr

esid

entR

amos

appo

ints

Sing

son

asne

wC

entr

alB

ank

gove

rnor

.Pa

rtly

antic

ipat

edA

ppoi

ntm

ent

Phili

ppin

es20

05R

afae

lBue

nave

ntur

aN

oPr

esid

entA

rroy

oan

noun

ces

that

Am

ando

Teta

ngco

beco

mes

Cen

tral

Ban

kpr

esid

ent

whe

nB

uena

vent

ura

retir

esin

July

.

Not

antic

ipat

edR

esig

natio

n

Pola

nd19

98H

anna

Gro

nkie

wic

z-W

altz

–Pr

esid

entK

was

niew

skiw

ants

Gro

nkie

wic

z-W

altz

tobe

reap

poin

ted

for

anot

her

6-ye

arte

rm.

Part

lyan

ticip

ated

App

oint

men

t

Pola

nd20

00H

anna

Gro

nkie

wic

z-W

altz

Yes

Gro

nkie

wic

z-W

altz

resi

gns

inor

der

tota

keE

BR

Dvi

ce-p

resi

denc

y.no

tant

icip

ated

resi

gnat

ion

Pola

nd20

00L

esze

kB

alce

row

icz

–Pr

esid

entK

was

niew

skip

ropo

ses

Bal

cero

wic

zto

beco

me

new

Cen

tral

Ban

kgo

vern

or.

Ant

icip

ated

App

oint

men

t

(Con

tinu

ed)

Page 21: Do Markets Care about Central Bank Governor Changes? Evidence from Emerging Markets

CHRISTOPH MOSER AND AXEL DREHER : 1609A

PPE

ND

IXD

:CO

NT

INU

ED

Cou

ntry

Dat

eaN

ame

Irre

gula

r(y

es/n

o)R

easo

nN

ews

char

acte

rN

ews

type

Rus

sia

1998

Serg

eiD

ubin

inY

esD

ubin

inco

nfirm

sth

athe

inte

nds

tore

sign

.Pa

rtly

antic

ipat

edR

esig

natio

nR

ussi

a19

98V

ikto

rG

eras

chen

ko–

Pres

iden

tYel

tsin

prop

oses

Ger

asch

enko

asD

ubin

in’s

succ

esso

r.Pa

rtly

antic

ipat

edA

ppoi

ntm

ent

Rus

sia

2002

Vik

tor

Ger

asch

enko

Yes

Pres

iden

tPut

inac

cept

sG

eras

chen

ko’s

resi

gnat

ion

and

nom

inat

esSe

rgei

Igna

tyev

.N

otan

ticip

ated

Res

igna

tion

Sout

hA

fric

a19

98T

itoM

bow

eni

No

Mbo

wen

iis

anno

unce

dto

follo

wC

hris

Stal

sup

onhi

sre

tirem

enti

n19

99.

Not

antic

ipat

edA

ppoi

ntm

ent

Sout

hK

orea

1998

Lee

Kyu

ng-s

ikY

esC

hon

Cho

l-H

wan

isap

poin

ted

asgo

vern

orof

the

cent

ralB

ank

ofK

orea

byne

wpr

esid

ent

Dae

-Jun

g.

Not

antic

ipat

edR

esig

natio

n

Sout

hK

orea

2002

Cho

nC

hol-

Hw

anN

oPr

esid

entD

ae-j

ung

nam

esPa

rkSe

ung

asgo

vern

orof

the

Ban

kof

Kor

easu

ccee

ding

Cho

l-H

wan

.

Part

lyan

ticip

ated

Res

igna

tion

Tha

iland

1998

Cha

iyaw

atW

ibul

swas

diY

esW

ibul

swas

dian

dse

vera

ltop

depu

ties

resi

gnun

der

polit

ical

pres

sure

.Cha

tum

ongk

olSo

naku

lis

imm

edia

tely

nom

inat

edas

succ

esso

r.

Ant

icip

ated

Res

igna

tion

Tha

iland

2001

Cha

tum

ongk

olSo

naku

lY

esSo

naku

lis

forc

edto

resi

gnby

Prim

eM

inis

ter

Shin

awat

radu

eto

polic

yco

ntro

vers

y.Pr

idiy

atho

rnD

evak

ula

beco

mes

succ

esso

r.

Part

lyan

ticip

ated

Res

igna

tion

Tur

key

2001

Gaz

iErc

elY

esE

rcel

offe

red

his

resi

gnat

ion,

afte

rT

urke

yha

dto

over

haul

anam

bitio

usre

form

prog

ram

.Pa

rtly

antic

ipat

edR

esig

natio

n

Tur

key

2001

Sure

yya

Serd

enge

cti

–Se

rden

gect

itak

esov

eras

gove

rnor

.N

otan

ticip

ated

App

oint

men

tT

urke

y20

06Su

reyy

aSe

rden

gect

iN

oSe

rden

gect

i’s5-

year

term

expi

res.

Ant

icip

ated

Res

igna

tion

Tur

key

2006

Dur

mus

Yilm

az–

Yilm

az’s

nom

inat

ion

ends

am

onth

ofun

cert

aint

yov

erth

edi

rect

ion

ofm

onet

ary

polic

y.Pa

rtly

antic

ipat

edA

ppoi

ntm

ent

Ven

ezue

la19

94R

uth

deK

rivo

yY

esD

eK

rivo

yan

dot

her

boar

dm

embe

rsre

sign

over

Cen

tral

Ban

kin

depe

nden

ceco

ncer

ns.

Not

antic

ipat

edR

esig

natio

n

Ven

ezue

la19

94A

nton

ioC

asas

Gon

zale

z–

Cas

asis

appo

inte

dby

Pres

iden

tCal

dera

.N

otan

ticip

ated

App

oint

men

t

Ven

ezue

la20

00A

nton

ioC

asas

Gon

zale

zY

esD

iego

Lui

sC

aste

llano

sis

appr

oved

tofo

llow

Cas

asas

Cen

tral

Ban

kpr

esid

ent.

Part

lyan

ticip

ated

Res

igna

tion

Ven

ezue

la20

05D

iego

Lui

sC

aste

llano

sN

oG

asto

nPa

rra

Luz

uard

ois

prop

osed

toas

sum

eth

epo

stof

the

outg

oing

Cen

tral

Ban

kgo

vern

or.

Not

antic

ipat

edR

esig

natio

n

a The

exac

tdat

esar

eav

aila

ble

onre

ques

t.

Page 22: Do Markets Care about Central Bank Governor Changes? Evidence from Emerging Markets

1610 : MONEY, CREDIT AND BANKING

APPENDIX E: CENTRAL BANK GOVERNORS AND CONSERVATISM—SOMEEXAMPLES FROM THE PRESS

Country Date Name

Argentina 2001 Roque Maccarone President De La Rua (of the Alliance forWork, Justice and Education, which isconsidered to be a center party) dismissedPedro Pou on alleged bad administration in2001. The incoming Roque Maccarone wasindeed considered to be less conservativethan Pou (nominated by the conservativePartido Justicialista), as illustrated in TheMiami Herald (April 27, 2001, p. 2):“[Minister of the Economy] Cavallopublicly blamed the current 33-monthrecession on Pou’s failure to loosen liquidityrequirements for banks, saying the policyprevented businesses from obtainingmuch-needed credit. . . . Maccarone said hewill consider changing the level of reservescommercial banks are required to keep ondeposit with the Central Bank.”

Argentina 2002 Mario Blejer Maccarone suddenly resigned in 2002 andMario Blejer became his successor,appointed by the more conservative PartidoJusticialista. Again, the change in ideologyis reflected in the news. According to TheNew York Times (January 18, 2002, p. 1)“Mr. Maccarone’s replacement, MarioBlejer, is a former International MonetaryFund official with a good reputation amonginternational lenders.”

South Africa 1998 Tito Mboweni Another example that fits our coding is theappointment of Tito Mboweni in SouthAfrica in 1998. Being appointed by theAfrican National Congress—defining itselfas force of the left—he is coded to be lessconservative than his predecessor ChristianStals, who was nominated by theconservative National Party in 1989.According to the Guardian (July 7, 1998, p.12) Mboweni was perceived to be “generousto a fault to the unions. He has been heavilydependent on left-wing advisers at the laborministry.”

Turkey 2006 Durmus Yilmaz In Turkey, Durmus Yilmaz followed SureyyaSerdengecti in 2006. Serdengecti had beenappointed by the Democratic Left Party,while Yilmaz was appointed by the moreconservative Justice and Development Party.Consequently, Yilmaz is coded as moreconservative than Serdengecti. According tothe Washington Post (April 19, 2006, p. 5),Yilmaz was indeed perceived to beconservative at the time of his appointment:“Yilmaz’s appointment was seen as anassurance that the bank would not deviatefrom its tight monetary policy.”

Page 23: Do Markets Care about Central Bank Governor Changes? Evidence from Emerging Markets

CHRISTOPH MOSER AND AXEL DREHER : 1611

LITERATURE CITED

Anderson, Theodore, and Cheng Hsiao. (1982) “Formulation and Estimation of DynamicModels Using Panel Data.” Journal of Econometrics, 18, 47–82.

Backus, David, and John Driffill. (1985) “Inflation and Reputation.” American EconomicReview, 75, 530–38.

Beck, Thorsten, George Clarke, Alberto Groff, Philipp Keefer, and Patrick Walsh. (2001)“New Tools in Comparative Political Economy: The Database of Political Institutions.”World Bank Economic Review, 17, 165–76.

Berger, Helge, and Ulrich Woitek. (2005) “Does Conservatism Matter? A Time-Series Ap-proach to Central Bank Behaviour.” Economic Journal, 115, 745–66.

Berger, Helge, Jakob de Haan, and Silvester Eijffinger. (2001) “Central Bank Independence:An Update of Theory and Evidence.” Journal of Economic Surveys, 15, 3–40.

Brown, Keith, William Van Harlow, and Seha Tinic. (1988) “Risk Aversion, Uncertain Infor-mation, and Market Efficiency.” Journal of Financial Economics, 22, 355–85.

Caballero, Ricardo, and Arvind Krishnamurthy. (2001) “International and Domestic CollateralConstraints in a Model of Emerging Market Crises.” Journal of Monetary Economics, 8,513–48.

Caballero, Ricardo, and Arvind Krishnamurthy. (2002) “A Dual Liquidity Model of EmergingMarkets.” American Economic Review, 92, 33–37.

Campbell, John, Andrew Lo, and Craig MacKinlay. (1997) The Econometrics of FinancialMarkets. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

Cukierman, Alex, and Alan Meltzer. (1986) “A Theory of Ambiguity, Credibility, and Inflationunder Discretion and Asymmetric Information.” Econometrica, 54, 1099–1128.

Dreher, Axel, Bernhard Herz, and Volker Karb. (2006) “Is There a Causal Link betweenCurrency and Debt Crises?” International Journal of Finance and Economics, 11, 305–25.

Dreher, Axel, Michael Lamla, Sarah Lein, and Frank Somogyi. (2008) “The Impact of PoliticalLeaders’ Profession and Education on Reforms.” Journal of Comparative Economics, 37,169–93.

Dreher, Axel, Jan-Egbert Sturm, and Jakob de Haan. (2010) “When Is a Central Bank GovernorFired? Evidence Based on a New Data Set.” Journal of Macroeconomics, 32, 766–81.

Edwards, Sebastian. (1984) “LDC Foreign Borrowing and Default Risk: An Empirical Inves-tigation, 1976–80.” American Economic Review, 74, 726–34.

Eijffinger, Sylvester, and Marco Hoeberichts. (1998) “The Trade Off between Central BankIndependence and Conservativeness.” Oxford Economic Papers, 50, 397–411.

Gohlmann, Silja, and Roland Vaubel. (2007) “The Educational and Professional Backgroundof Central Bankers and its Effect on Inflation: An Empirical Analysis.” European EconomicReview, 51, 925–41.

Jones, Benjamin, and Benjamin Olken. (2005) “Do Leaders Matter? National Leadership andGrowth since World War II.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 120, 835–64.

Kara, Hakan. (2007) “Monetary Policy under Imperfect Commitment: Reconciling Theorywith Evidence.” International Journal of Central Banking, 3, 149–77.

Kaminsky, Graciela L., and Carmen M. Reinhart. (1999) “The Twin Crises: The Causes ofBanking and Balance-of-Payments Problems.” American Economic Review, 89, 473–500.

Page 24: Do Markets Care about Central Bank Governor Changes? Evidence from Emerging Markets

1612 : MONEY, CREDIT AND BANKING

Kaminsky, Graciela L., and Sergio Schmukler. (2002) “Emerging Markets Instability: DoSovereign Ratings Affect Country Risk and Stock Returns.” World Bank Economic Review,16, 171–95.

Kuttner, Kenneth N., and Adam S. Posen. (2010) “Do Markets Care Who Chairs the CentralBank?” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 42, 347–71.

Kydland, Finn, and Edward Prescott. (1977) “Rules Rather Than Discretion: The Inconsistencyof Optimal Plans.” Journal of Political Economy, 85, 473–90.

Moser, Christoph. (2006) “The Impact of Political Risk on Sovereign Bond Spreads—Evidencefrom Latin America.” Mimeo, University of Mainz.

Pantzalis, Christos, David Stangeland, and Harry Turtle. (2000) “Political Elections and theResolution of Uncertainty: The International Evidence.” Journal of Banking and Finance,24, 1575–1604.

Rogoff, Kenneth. (1985) “The Optimal Degree of Commitment to an Intermediate MonetaryTarget.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 100, 1169–89.

Santiso, Javier. (2003) The Political Economy of Emerging Markets. Actors, Institutions andFinancial Crises in Latin America. CERI Series in International Relations and PoliticalEconomy. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.

Schaumburg, Ernst, and Andrea Tambalotti. (2007) “An Investigation of the Gains fromCommitment in Monetary Policy.” Journal of Monetary Economics, 54, 302–24.