24
1 Do Governments Pay Efficiency Wages? Evidence from a Selection of Countries Paper presented at the 2009 International Public Service Motivation Research Conference, Bloomington, Indiana, June 7-9 2009. Dr Jeannette Taylor Political Science and International Relations (M259) The University of Western Australia Stirling Highway Crawley Western Australia 6009 Australia Email: [email protected] Dr Ranald Taylor Murdoch Business School-Economics Murdoch University South Street Murdoch Western Australia 6150 Australia Email: [email protected]

Do Governments Pay Efficiency Wages

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    2

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Do Governments Pay Efficiency Wages

1

Do Governments Pay Efficiency Wages? Evidence from a Selection of Countries

Paper presented at the 2009 International Public Service Motivation Research

Conference, Bloomington, Indiana,

June 7-9 2009.

Dr Jeannette Taylor

Political Science and International Relations (M259)

The University of Western Australia

Stirling Highway

Crawley

Western Australia 6009

Australia

Email: [email protected]

Dr Ranald Taylor

Murdoch Business School-Economics

Murdoch University

South Street

Murdoch

Western Australia 6150

Australia

Email: [email protected]

Page 2: Do Governments Pay Efficiency Wages

2

Do Governments Pay Efficiency Wages? Evidence from a Selection of Countries

Abstract

The issue of how much to pay government employees without risking a drop in their

public service motivation (PSM) levels is a complex one. On one hand, it is argued

that government employees are generally less motivated by high wages than their

private sector counterparts. Governments too are constrained in their ability to offer

high wages to their employees. There is also the proposition that high wages,

particularly performance-based wages, can reduce or ‘crowd out’ intrinsic motivation.

On the other hand, it is common knowledge that most people do not seek employment

without expecting some sort of remuneration for their effort. Wages can satisfy both

lower-order and higher-order needs, and can be used to indicate achievement and

recognition for one’s effort. This paper argues for the significance of ‘PSM-adjusted

wage’, the level which ensures high effort without undermining PSM levels in the

public sector. It draws upon the efficiency wage theory and the PSM literature to

construct a model for PSM-adjusted wage, which is then piloted on the 2005 ISSP

dataset of fifteen countries that include USA, Great Britain, and Australia.

Page 3: Do Governments Pay Efficiency Wages

3

Introduction

The issue of how much to pay government employees in order to ensure maximum

effort levels and without risking a drop in their public service motivation (PSM)

levels is a complex one. Efficiency wage theory dictates that paying employees above

the market clearing rate or a wage premium guarantees maximum effort (Solow

1979). The literature of PSM presents a different perspective. It states that employees

with high PSM levels are more motivated by a desire to serve the public interest than

by obscenely large sums of monies (Perry and Hondeghem 2008; Perry and Wise

1990). But the fact that these high performing employees are strongly driven to pursue

the common good should not be taken to imply that employers can get away with

paying them extremely low or minimum wages. After all, most people choose to work

because of their desire and/or need to earn an income (Latham and Locke 1992). In

short, wages can satisfy both lower-order and higher-order needs (Pinder 1984;

Rainey 1991).

This paper’s exploration of the complex relationships between effort, wages and

PSM in the public sector will address four specific questions. First, are governments

in selected countries paying their public sector workforce efficiency wages? Second,

what is the relationship between efficiency wages and effort? How much do these

governments need to pay in order to raise the effort levels of their public sector

workforce according to the efficiency wage specification? Third, what is the

association between PSM and effort? How much change in PSM is associated with

effort change? In combination, the second and third questions allow us to find out

which of these two factors – wages or PSM – accounts for a larger change in the

Page 4: Do Governments Pay Efficiency Wages

4

public sector workforce’s effort levels. Fourth, what is the relationship between

‘PSM-adjusted wages’ and effort? How much change in wages is related to a change

in effort when PSM is taken into account? This article makes a distinction between

efficiency wages and ‘PSM-adjusted wages’. An efficiency wage is the level of wage

that is higher than the prevailing market rate, which elicits maximum effort. A ‘PSM-

adjusted wage’, on the other hand, is defined as the amount that is associated with a

high effort level without undermining the PSM level.

We will begin this article by reviewing the literature on the significance of wages

as a way to raise employees’ effort in the public sector. Two perspectives will be

presented: Solow’s (1979) efficiency wage model, and the PSM literature. A simple

framework will then be formulated to explain the relationships between effort, wages

and PSM. We will pilot this model with the 2005 ISSP dataset. Fifteen countries in

the dataset are selected for the analysis. They include USA, Canada, Great Britain,

Australia, New Zealand, several countries in Europe (e.g., Denmark and France) and

Asia (Japan and Taiwan), Israel, and Russia.

An efficiency wage perspective on wages and effort

The central argument in Solow’s (1979) efficiency wage model is that unless

employers offer wages higher than the prevailing market rate, or efficiency wages,

employees will engage in unproductive activities, such as shirking, and ultimately

switch jobs.1 A low wage relative to the prevailing market wage can contribute to

dissatisfaction, and other negative attitudes amongst employees (e.g., outrage and a

desire for revenge), thereby leading to an increase in shirking or sabotage activities

Page 5: Do Governments Pay Efficiency Wages

5

(Akerlof and Yellen 1986). In a Walrasian labor market, employees are indifferent to

their jobs because there are similar paying jobs available in the labor market. As a

result of this indifference to jobs, employees are less likely to exert high effort and are

more likely to shirk. In the worst case scenario, if they are fired from their jobs for

substandard performance or shirking activities, this will have a minimum impact on

them because they can always find another job in a Walrasian labor market (Wood

1993).

Shirking occurs because of asymmetric information. Unlike employees, employers

do not have complete information about their employees’ work habits and practices,

and how much effort the employees have put forth to achieve the organization’s goals.

The fact that a typical employment contract can specify the number of hours that

employees need to work per day means that an organization can buy employees’ time,

but not employees’ effort. The fact that labor quality cannot be observed by

employers prior to employment, as alluded to by moral hazard and adverse selection

problems, suggests that it pays to offer higher relative wages in order to minimize the

risk of taking on less productive employees.

Organizations which pay more than the market-clearing wage or a wage premium

can raise the costs to workers of shirking (Shapiro and Stiglitz 1984). Employees who

are paid wages that are higher than their peers in comparable jobs may place more

value on their jobs than those in less-paid positions. These employees perceive that

they will have more to lose if they are caught shirking and consequently lose their

jobs. Even if there is a chance that they will not be caught if they engage in shirking,

they may still wish to minimize or avoid shirking and instead choose to exert higher

Page 6: Do Governments Pay Efficiency Wages

6

effort levels because of the heightened importance placed on their efficiency wages.

In addition, the ‘gift exchange’ analysis undertaken by Akerlof (1982) and Kaufman

(1984) explains that high relative wages can increase employees’ identification with

their organization. High relative wages, it is argued raise employees’ general

willingness to cooperate and reciprocate in the employment relationship in that ‘My

employer treats me well so I will return the favor’.2

If one takes the view that the quality of a workforce affects the effort of the

workforce, then high relative wages may arguably ensure a high quality workforce

through recruitment and retention (Stiglitz 1996, 1974; Weiss 1980). Efficiency wage

theory explains why most organizations believe that they can fill their vacancies more

quickly with high quality workers if they raise their relative wages. Cable and Judge

(1994) suggested that wage is a signalling device for recruits. Wage premiums also

affect retention. They reduce turnover and the disruption caused by turnover (Stiglitz

1974). Henry Ford was perhaps the first modern employer to use efficiency wages to

reduce workers’ turnover during the production of the Model T. By paying $5 above

the market prevailing wage, labor turnover was reduced significantly, resulting in a

large increase in the production of the Ford Model T, making it the highest selling

automobile during the early 1900s (Raff and Summers 1987). Efficiency wage theory

clearly points to a significant association between high relative wages and effort. The

next section will present an alternative perspective on this relationship.

Page 7: Do Governments Pay Efficiency Wages

7

A PSM perspective on wages and effort

The importance of PSM on effort, or more specifically, performance, has been raised

in the literature: ‘High performance is central to the theory of PSM’ (Brewer and

Selden 1998, p. 425). Past research has demonstrated that employees’ PSM is related

to how well they perform their jobs (Alonso and Lewis 2001; Brewer and Selden

1998; Bright 2000; Naff and Crum 1999). Drawing from job design research findings,

Perry and Wise (1990) propose that job characteristics can have a motivating impact

on effort. Attributes in the public service that are likely to appeal to those with high

PSM levels include those that provide opportunities to address questions of social

equity, pursue social programs, advocate a valued special interest, and express loyalty

to country. Wright (2004) clarifies that if government employees, who are motivated

to make a worthwhile contribution to society, perceive that their work is important to

accomplishing organizational goals that benefit society, then they will exert higher

effort levels.

In contrast to effort, wages are reported to be not significantly related to PSM

(Crewson 1997; Houston 2000; Perry and Wise 1990). Most public-private sector

studies maintain that public sector employees are less motivated by the extrinsic

aspects of their work, and more motivated by the intrinsic features, particularly an

opportunity to help others (Lawler 1971; Rainey 1982, 1991; cf. Gabris and Simo

1995). Similarly, various studies show that students who aspire to enter this sector

have less interest in monetary rewards than their counterparts who intend to join the

private sector (Chetkovich 2003; Taylor 2005). According to Frey and associates

(Frey 1997; Frey and Jegen 2001), high amounts of extrinsic rewards, such as high

Page 8: Do Governments Pay Efficiency Wages

8

wages, can have a ‘crowding-out’ effect on employees’ intrinsic motivation. For

example, when employees perceive the wages to be controlling, their self-

determination and self-esteem can suffer, and they can respond by lowering their

intrinsic motivation.

But these findings do not deny the relevance of offering wages to government

employees in order to raise their effort levels. People can have different motives for

serving the public interest, and they include rational motives (Rainey 1982; Perry and

Wise 1990). In her study of Australian government employees, Taylor (2007) found

the rational motives in the PSM construct to be significantly associated with

organizational commitment. Although wage did not occupy the top five positions of

employees’ preferences, it was found to be an important factor for recruitment and

retention in a government-commissioned survey of graduate employees in the

Australian federal government (Management Advisory Committee 2003). Taylor’s

(2005) survey of university graduates found that whilst the respondents who favored

the private sector were more motivated by a high wage than their counterparts who

were attracted to the public sector, the latter group was more concerned about a

comparable wage than the former group. Frey (1997) stated that wages which are

perceived as fair will support work morale, and have a ‘crowding-in’ effect on

employees’ intrinsic motivation. This implies that the public sector should aim to

achieve a balance between providing adequate economic rewards without

undercutting the service needs of government employees (Crewson 1997; Le Grand

2003). In particular, consideration should be given to paying employees wages at a

level that encourages them to put forth greater effort without risking a drop in PSM.

This level is proposed as the ‘PSM-adjusted wage’.

Page 9: Do Governments Pay Efficiency Wages

9

The research framework

This research framework is divided into two parts. We begin our analysis with the

efficiency wage model, followed by the PSM-adjusted wage model. Under the

efficiency wage model, effort (E) per employee (i) is a function of the employee’s

wage inside the organization (Wn) relative to the expected prevailing wage outside the

organization (We). Employees will work harder if they are convinced that they are

being treated relatively well (Akerlof 1983; Akerlof and Yellen 1990; Shapiro and

Stiglitz 1984). This relationship between effort and wages can be summarized in the

equation below.

Ei = e (Wn/We) e1, e2 > 0 and e11, e22 < 0 (1)

where e is the elasticity of effort, and e1 and e2 are the first derivatives, and e11 and e22

are the second derivatives of equation (1).

The second derivatives in equation (1) suggest that wages are subject to

diminishing returns. The relationship between wages and effort follows an inverted U-

shaped curve. Figure 1 indicates that at point A, the wage paid is W0 and effort is E0.

An increase in wages raises the effort level of employees. This will continue until

point B which represents the optimal level of effort En*. At this point, the wage is at

Wn*, which is the efficiency wage. Beyond point B, subsequent increases in wages

will cause effort to fall. An increase in wages from Wn* to Wn will result in a decline

in effort from En* to En.

Page 10: Do Governments Pay Efficiency Wages

10

Figure 1: The relationship between effort and wage

Ei = e(Wn)

B

0

W0 Wn* Wn

E0

En*

A

Effort

Wages

Two possible reasons are presented to explain why an increase in wage beyond

Wn* will lead to a reduction in effort. The first is derived from the backward bending

labor supply curve (Gravelle and Rees 2004). Orthodox labor supply models tend to

predict a positive labor supply reaction to increases in wages. Employees would

substitute labor with leisure, and vice versa. They would supply more labor when

wages are high, and consume more leisure when wages are low (Lucas and Rapping

1969). Although this prediction is straightforward, it is difficult to verify and not

universally accepted. For instance, Camerer et al. (1997) found negative elasticities on

the labor supply of New York cabdrivers, which suggests the existence of a backward

labor supply curve in the New York cab industry. Once cabdrivers met their daily

income target, they quit working. This implies a particular work/leisure preference

function where the negative income effect outweighs the substitution effect of a wage

rise. This is always an empirical question for a particular type of labor supplied.

Similarly, in his writing on happiness, Frey (2008) stated that although a higher

income can make people happy, the higher utility derived from material goods will

Page 11: Do Governments Pay Efficiency Wages

11

wear off as people adapt to the higher income level. He reasoned that satisfaction

comes from change, and disappears with continued consumption.

The second reason for the drop in effort with an increase in wages beyond the

optimum point can be drawn from the body of literature on the negative impact of

high levels of extrinsic rewards on intrinsic motivation, as mentioned earlier in the

PSM literature. High levels of wages have been reported to undermine or ‘crowd-out’

intrinsic motivation (Deci 1971, 1972; Frey 1997). They are argued to undercut

employees’ PSM levels (Crewson 1997; Le Grand 2003), which can drive down their

effort levels.

The relationship between effort and PSM can be described as

ef = PSM/Ei ef1, ef2 > 0, and ef11, ef22 > 0 (2)

where ef = the elasticity of effort with respect to PSM, and Ei = Wn/We. High

PSM raises effort (Alonso and Lewis 2001; Brewer and Selden 1998; Bright 2000),

and reduces the dependence of wages on effort based on the argument that high wages

can undermine PSM (Crewson 1997; Frey 1997; Le Grand 2003).

To find the optimum efficiency wage (e) and PSM-adjusted wage (ee), the

equation below is utilized.

e = Ei /Wn = 1, and ee = PSM/Wn = 1 (3)

Page 12: Do Governments Pay Efficiency Wages

12

Operationalizing equation (3) is done by taking logarithms of the variables (∂log

Wn/∂log Ei and ∂log PSM/∂log Wn). The relationship between PSM and effort is

captured by the elasticity of PSM with respect to effort (ef = ∂log PSM/∂log Ei).

Method

Sample

This study utilizes the 2005 International Social Survey Programme (ISSP): Work

Orientations dataset in fifteen countries. They consist of USA, Canada, Great Britain,

Denmark, France, Germany, Spain, Bulgaria, Slovenia, Russia, Israel, Japan, Taiwan,

Australia, and New Zealand. Only respondents who participated full-time in the labor

market, and those working in the public sector and private sector are taken into

account. The private sector respondents include self-employed individuals. The

sectoral division permits relative wage to be determined. The total number of

respondents was 9,742. The mean age of the respondents was 41.7 years. A majority

of them were males (57%), and married (63%), held higher than secondary school

qualifications (26%), and worked an average of 40 hours per week (32%) in the

private sector (70%).

Measures

The ISSP dataset provides two measures:

Page 13: Do Governments Pay Efficiency Wages

13

1. Wages. This is derived from the respondents’ annual income (expressed in the

country’s currency). A mean wage is then calculated for each country by

sector.

2. PSM index. This is estimated from two items: ‘A job that allows someone to

help other people’; and ‘A job that is useful to society’. On a 5-point Likert

scale, ranging from ‘not at all important’ (1) to ‘very important’ (5), the

respondents indicated the importance they personally placed on the existence

of each item in a job. An average score of the two items is calculated for each

respondent. Factor analysis (principal component, varimax rotation) of the two

items measuring the PSM index revealed a single construct. Cronbach’s alpha

= 0.79

The above data are used to estimate efficiency wage ratio (government wages/ private

sector wages), the elasticity of effort with respect to wages (e), the elasticity of PSM

with respect to effort (ef), and ‘PSM-adjusted wages’(ee), as specified in equation (3).

Findings

The findings are presented in Table 1. The first column in the table shows an average

efficiency wage ratio above unity, which conforms to the efficiency wage

specification. The value of 1.03 implies that most governments in the 15 countries,

such as Australia and New Zealand, were paying their public sector employees

slightly above the market rate or efficiency wages at that time. The exceptions were

USA, Denmark, France, Bulgaria and Russia. Public sector employees in these

countries were paid below the prevailing market wages.

Page 14: Do Governments Pay Efficiency Wages

14

On average, the elasticity of effort with respect to wages, e, was estimated to be

0.25. This implies that governments in the selected countries which wish to increase

their employees’ effort by 1 per cent will need to increase their public sector wages by

0.25 per cent. The comparatively high e value in some countries, such as that in

Bulgaria and Spain, implies that these governments will need to pay higher wages in

order to bring about a similar rise in effort of 1 per cent amongst their public sector

workforce. The smaller the value of e, the smaller the governments will need to pay

their public sector workforce to raise their effort. Countries which show relatively

small e values are Denmark and USA.

The third column in Table 1 shows a mean elasticity of PSM with respect to

effort, ef, of 0.62. This implies that, for every one percent increase in the effort level

of the public sector workforce in the 15 countries, PSM contributed 0.62 per cent to

that one per cent. A higher ef value suggests the greater importance placed on PSM to

bring about a change in effort. For instance, on average, a 0.68 per cent increase in

PSM levels amongst the American public sector workforce contributed to a 1 per cent

rise in their effort level. In comparison, a similar rise in effort level amongst the

Japanese counterparts is derived from a 0.58 per cent increase in their PSM levels.

The finding also points to the significance of PSM amongst the public sector

workforce in the 15 countries in bringing forth a rise in effort relative to wages, as

evident by the higher ef values compared to the e values for every country.

The last column in Table 1 reports on the ‘PSM-adjusted wage’ (ee). It

demonstrates that when PSM is taken into account, government employers require a

smaller increase in wages to bring about a rise in effort. On average, a 1 per cent

Page 15: Do Governments Pay Efficiency Wages

15

change in effort is associated with 0.25 per cent change in efficiency wages, relative

to 0.16 per cent change in PSM-adjusted wages. This trend of lower PSM-adjusted

wages than efficiency wages to bring about a similar rise in effort applies to all 15

countries, even in those that show an inclination for a higher than average PSM-

adjusted wage increase, such as Spain and Bulgaria.

Discussion

This paper attempts to develop a model to explain the complex relationships between

wages, PSM and effort amongst the public sector workforce. The model, which was

piloted on 15 countries, presents four prominent findings. First, many governments

are found to be paying their public sector workforce efficiency wages. Countries that

failed to meet the efficiency wage specification in the public sector are USA,

Denmark, France, Bulgaria and Russia. According to wage efficiency theory,

employees who receive wages that are higher than the prevailing market wages are

likely to be exerting an optimum level of effort. If this is true, then one could expect

the public sector employees in most of the countries studied to put forth high levels of

effort in their work.

Second, the elasticity of PSM with respect to effort, ef, is estimated to be greater

than the elasticity of effort with respect to wages, e. This would suggest that a more

cost-effective way to raise government employees’ effort is through their PSM levels.

The findings confirm the significance of PSM in shaping effort (Alonso and Lewis

2001; Brewer and Selden 1998; Bright 2000; Naff and Crum 1999).

Page 16: Do Governments Pay Efficiency Wages

16

Third, the PSM-adjusted wage (ee) is found to be lower than e for all 15 countries.

On average, a 1 per cent change in effort is associated with 0.25 per cent change in

efficiency wages, relative to 0.16 per cent change in PSM-adjusted wages. In short,

when the employees’ PSM is considered, one would require a smaller increase in

wages, or one that is lower than the amount proposed by efficiency wage theory, to

bring about a rise in effort. The finding downplays the significance of wages in

driving effort amongst government employees with high PSM levels, and is supported

by earlier research (Perry and Hondeghem 2008; Perry and Wise 1990).

Fourth, there are some countries which registered unique characteristics. The fact

that the Spanish public sector paid their employees one of the highest wage premiums

(1.22) amongst the 15 countries, but registered one of the highest e value (0.33) might

suggest that the public sector wage level in this country has risen beyond the level

required to achieve an optimum effort level, as discussed earlier in Figure 1. Despite

being paid a large wage premium, Spanish government employees required higher

than average increase in their efficiency wages to bring about a rise in effort similar to

those of their international counterparts. Their PSM-adjusted wage is much smaller

than their efficiency wage at 0.20, though it is still above average. It is likely that

these employees placed a greater importance on wages than their international

counterparts. The variance in the values of e and ee across the 15 countries highlights

the differing emphasis placed on the importance of wages across different countries.

Government employees in Spain and France, for example, required greater changes in

efficiency and PSM-adjusted wages than those in Denmark and USA in order to

change their effort by a similar amount.

Page 17: Do Governments Pay Efficiency Wages

17

The results for American government employees are worthy of special mention.

Although they received wages that were lower than those of their private sector

counterparts, they required a comparatively smaller change in wages than that of their

foreign counterparts in order to raise their effort by 1 percent. Although PSM is one of

the contributing factors, this article does not discount the possibility of other factors at

play in affecting effort levels. Further research should consider other factors in the

analysis, such as the work environment (Moynihan and Pandey 2007; Perry 2000),

and job attributes (Grant 2007, 2008; Taylor 2008).

This study is subject to a few caveats. The first relates to the small sample size.

This model was piloted on a small group of full-time public sector employees. The

second involves the use of cross-sectional data, which cannot be subjected to time

series analysis. The third pertains to the reliance on pre-existing survey research data.

This implies that the findings are constrained by the items used to determine PSM.

Future research should be conducted with a larger sample size, across time, and with

stronger and established measures of PSM, notably Perry’s PSM instrument (Coursey

and Pandey 2007; Perry 1996, 1997; Vandenabeele 2008). Nevertheless, the findings

in this small pilot study support the descriptive literature and empirical studies

containing assertions on the significance of PSM in the workplace. In particular, it

suggests that PSM not only reduces the reliance on wages to raise effort, but it also

accounts for a larger change in effort than wages.

Page 18: Do Governments Pay Efficiency Wages

18

References

Adams. J. Stacey. 1965. Inequity in Social Change. In Advances in Social Psychology,

Vol. 2, edited by L. Berkowitz, 267-299. New York: Academic Press.

Akerlof, George A. 1982. Labor Contracts as Partial Gift Exchange. Quarterly

Journal of Economics 97: 543-569.

Akerlof, George A. and Janet L. Yellen. 1986. Efficiency Wage Models of the Labor

Market. New York: Cambridge University Press.

Alonso, Pablo, and Gregory B. Lewis. 2001. Public Service Motivation and Job

Performance. American Review of Public Administration 31(4): 363-80.

Baker, Wayne E. and Jason B. Jimerson. 1992. The Sociology of Money. American

Behavioral Scientist 35(6): 678-93.

Brewer, Gene A. and Sally C. Selden. 1998. Whistle Blowers in the Federal Civil

Service: New Evidence of the Public Service Ethic. Journal of Public

Administration Research and Theory 8(3): 413-39.

Bright, Leonard. 2007. Does Person-Organization Fit Mediate the Relationship

Between Public Service Motivation and the Job Performance of Public

Employees? Review of Public Personnel Administration 27(4): 361-79.

Cable, Daniel and Timothy A. Judge. 1994. Pay Preferences and Job Search

Decisions: A Person-Organization Fit Perspective. Personnel Psychology 47(2):

317-48.

Camerer, Colin, Linda Babcock, George Loewenstein, and Richard Thaler. 1997.

Labor Supply of New York City Cabdrivers: One Day at A Time. Quarterly

Journal of Economics May: 407-41.

Chetkovich, Carol. 2003. What’s in a Sector? The Shifting Career Plans of Public

Policy Students. Public Administration Review 63(6): 660-74.

Coursey David H. and Sanjay K. Pandey. 2007. Public Service Motivation

Measurement: Testing an Abridged Version of Perry’s Proposed Scale.

Administration & Society 39(5): 547-68.

Cowherd, Douglas M. and Levine, David. 1992. Product Quality and Pay Equity

Between Lower-Level Employees and Top Management: An Investigation of

Distributive Justice Theory. Administrative Science Quarterly 37(2): 302-20.

Page 19: Do Governments Pay Efficiency Wages

19

Coyle-Shapiro, Jacqueline A.M.and Ian Kessler. 2003. The Employment Relationship

in the U.K. Public Sector: A Psychological Contract Perspective. Journal of Public

Administration Research and Theory 13(2): 213-30.

Crewson, Philip E. 1997. Public-Service Motivation: Building Empirical Evidence of

Incidence and Effect. Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory 7(4):

499-518.

Deci, Edward L. 1971. Effects of Externally Mediated Rewards on Intrinsic

Motivation. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 18: 105-15.

Deci, E.L. 1972. Effects of Contingent and Non-Contingent Rewards and Controls on

Intrinsic Motivation. Organizational Behavior and Human Performance 8: 217-

29.

Duesenberry, James S. 1949. Income, Savings and the Theory of Consumer Behavior.

Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard University Press.

Furnham, Adrian and Michael Argyle. 1998. The Psychology of Money. London:

Routledge.

Frey, Bruno S. 1997. On the Relationship Between Intrinsic and Extrinsic Work

Motivation. International Journal of Industrial Organization 15: 427-39.

Frey, Bruno S. 2008. Happiness: A Revolution in Economics. MIT Press, Cambridge,

Massachusetts.

Frey, Bruno S. and Reto Jegen. 2001. Motivation Crowding Theory. Journal of

Economic Surveys 15: 589-611.

Frey, Bruno S and Alois Stutzer. 2002. Happiness and Economics. Princeton

University Press, Princeton.

Gabris, Gerald T. and Gloria Simo. 1995. Public Sector Motivation as an Independent

Variable Affecting Career Decisions. Public Personnel Management 24(1): 33-

51.

Grant, Adam M. 2007. Relational Job Design and the Motivation to Make a Prosocial

Difference. Academy of Management Review 32: 393-417.

Grant, Adam M. 2008. Designing Jobs to do Good: Dimensions and Psychological

Consequences of Prosocial Job Characteristics. Journal of Positive Psychology 3(1):

19-39.

Gravelle, Hugh and Ray Rees. 2004. Microeconomics, 3rd

edn. Prentice Hall: Essex.

Greenberg, Jerald. 1990. Employee Theft as a Reaction to Underpayment of Inequity:

The Hidden Cost of Pay Cuts. Journal of Applied Psychology 75: 561-8.

Page 20: Do Governments Pay Efficiency Wages

20

Harder, Joseph W. 1992. Play for Pay: Effects of Inequity in a Pay-For-Performance

Context. Administrative Science Quarterly 37: 321-35.

Houston, David J. 2000. Public-Service Motivation: A Multivariate Test. Journal of

Public Administration Research and Theory 10(4): 713-27.

Kaufman, Roger T. 1984. On Wage Stickiness in Britain’s Competitive Sector.

British Journal of Industrial Relations 22(1): 101-12.

Latham, Gary P. and Edwin A. Locke. 1992. Goal Setting – A Motivational

Technique That Works. In Management and Motivation, edited by Victor H.

Vroom and Edward L. Deci, 198-205, London: Penguin Books.

Lawler, Edward E. III. 1971. Pay and Organizational Effectiveness: A

Psychological View. New York: McGraw-Hill.

Le Grand, Julian. 2003. Motivation, Agency and Public Policy: Of Knights and

Knaves, Pawns and Queens. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Lucas, Robert E. Jr. and Leonard A. Rapping. 1969. Real Wages, Employment and

Inflation. Journal of Political Economy LXXVII: 721-54.

Management Advisory Committee. 2003. Organisational Renewal. Canberra:

Commonwealth of Australia.

Marshall, Alfred. 1922. Principles of Economics: an Introductory Analysis, 8th

edn.

London: Macmillan.

Mitchell, Terence R. and Amy E. Mickel. 1999. The Meaning of Money: An

Individual Difference Perspective. Academy of Management Review 24(3):

568-78.

Moynihan, Donald P. and Sanjay K. Pandey. 2007. The Role of Organisations in

Fostering Public Service Motivation. Public Administration Review 67(1): 40-53.

Naff, Katherine C., and John Crum. 1999. Working for America: Does Public Service

Motivation Make a Difference? Review of Public Personnel Administration 19(4):

5-16.

Perry, James L. 1996. Measuring Public Service Motivation: An Assessment of

Construct Reliability and Validity. Journal of Public Administration Research and

Theory 6(1): 5-22.

Perry, James L. 1997. Antecedents of Public Service Motivation. Journal of Public

Administration Research and Theory 7(2): 181-97.

Perry, James L. 2000. Bringing Society In: Toward a Theory of Public-Service

Motivation. Journal of Public Administration and Theory 10(2): 471-88.

Page 21: Do Governments Pay Efficiency Wages

21

Perry, James L. and Annie Hondeghem. 2008. Motivation in Public Management: The

Call of Public Service. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Perry, James L. and Lois R. Wise. 1990. The Motivational Bases of Public Service.

Public Administration Review 50(3): 367-73.

Pinder, Craig C. 1984. Work Motivation: Theory, Issues, and Application. Glenview,

Illinios: Scott, Foresman and Company.

Raff, Daniel M.G. and Lawrence H. Summers. 1987. Did Henry Ford Pay Efficiency

Wages? Journal of Labor Economics 5(4): 557-86.

Rainey, Hal G. 1982. Reward Preferences among Public and Private Managers: In

Search of the Service Ethic. American Review of Public Administration 16(4): 288-

302.

Rainey, Hal G. 1991. Understanding and Managing Public Organizations. San

Francisco: Jossey-Bass.

Rousseau, Denise M. and Judi McLean Parks. 1993. The Contracts of Individuals and

Organizations, In Research in Organizational Behavior, vol. 5, edited by Larry L.

Cummings and Barry M. Staw, 1-43, Greenwich, Conn.: JAI Press.

Shapiro, Carl and Joseph E. Stiglitz. 1984. Equilibrium Unemployment as a Worker

Discipline Device. American Economic Review 74(3): 433-44.

Sims, Henry P. Jr., Andrew D. Szilagyi, and Robert T. Keller. 1976. The

Measurement of Job Characteristics. Academy of Management Journal 19: 195-

212.

Solow, Robert. 1979. Another Possible Source of Wage Stickiness. Journal of

Macroeconomics 1(1): 79-82.

Summers, Timothy P. and William H. Hendrix. 1991. Modeling the Role of Pay

Equity Perceptions: A Field Study. Journal of Occupational Psychology 64(2):

145-55.

Taylor, Jeannette. 2005. The Next Generation of Workers in Australia: Their Views

on Organizations, Working and Rewards. International Journal of Human

Resource Management 16(10): 1919-33.

Taylor, Jeannette. 2007. The Impact of Public Service Motives on Work Outcomes in

Australia: A Comparative Multi-Dimensional Analysis. Public Administration

85(4): 931-59.

Taylor, Jeannette. 2008. Organizational Influences, Public Service Motivation and

Work Outcomes. International Public Management Journal 11(1): 67-88.

Page 22: Do Governments Pay Efficiency Wages

22

Vandenabeele, Wouter. 2008. Development of a Public Service Motivation

Measurement Scale: Corroborating and Extending Perry's Measurement

Instrument. International Public Management Journal 11(1): 143-67

Walster, Elaine G., William Walster, and Ellen Berscheid. 1978. Equity: Theory and

Research. Boston: Allyn and Bacon.

Weiss, Andrew. 1990. Efficiency Wages: Models of Unemployment, Layoffs and

Wage Dispersion. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

Wood, John Cunningham. 1993. Léon Walrus: Critical Assessments. London:

Routledge.

Wright, Bradley E. 2004. The Role of Work Context in Work Motivation: A Public

Sector Application of Goal and Social Cognitive Theories. Journal of Public

Administration Research and Theory 14(1): 59-78.

Yellen, Janet L. 1984. Efficiency Wage Models of Unemployment. American

Economic Review 74(2): 200-5

Page 23: Do Governments Pay Efficiency Wages

23

Table 1 Efficiency wages, elasticity values and PSM-adjusted wages of full-time government employees in selected countries, 2005

Countries Efficiency wage ratio e ef PSM-adjusted wage (ee)

USA (N = 841) 0.62 0.20 0.68 0.15

Canada (N = 471) 1.07 0.21 0.62 0.13

Great Britain (N = 330) 1.09 0.23 0.61 0.14

Denmark (N = 960) 0.83 0.18 0.62 0.11

France (N = 842) 0.88 0.30 0.59 0.18

Germany (N = 660) 1.20 0.31 0.60 0.18

Spain (N = 493) 1.22 0.33 0.63 0.20

Bulgaria (N = 428) 0.85 0.40 0.65 0.27

Slovenia (N = 496) 1.15 0.18 0.60 0.11

Russia (N = 873) 0.78 0.26 0.61 0.16

Israel (N = 415) 1.14 0.27 0.64 0.17

Japan (N = 379) 1.26 0.28 0.58 0.16

Taiwan (N = 1120) 1.17 0.22 0.61 0.13

Australia (N = 832) 1.08 0.21 0.61 0.13

New Zealand (N = 612) 1.03 0.21 0.61 0.13

Average 1.03 0.25 0.62 0.16

e = elasticity of effort

ef = elasticity of PSM

N = number of respondents.

Page 24: Do Governments Pay Efficiency Wages

24

Notes

1 The significance of considering relative wages in affecting outcomes is supported by

other scholars. Duesenberry (1949) formulated and econometrically tested the relative

income hypothesis which proposed an asymmetric structure of externalities. Frey

(2008) similarly noted that individuals today are faced with extended possibilities for

social comparisons, which can affect their perceptions of the value of income: ‘It is

not the absolute level of income that matters most, but rather one’s position relative to

other people’ (Frey and Stutzer 2002, p.85). Equity theory also raises the idea of

social comparability, which can be applied to wages. It proposes that individuals

evaluate the ratio of their inputs to outcomes for a given task in relation to a

comparative referent (Adams 1965; Harder 1992; Walster et al. 1978). The optimal

point exists when the individuals perceive the ratio as a balanced one, i.e., equal to

one. At this point, they can focus their energies on achieving the organization’s goals

as this will in turn satisfy their personal goals. On the other hand, employees who

perceive that they are undercompensated or treated unfairly can resort to negative

actions, such as theft, reduced output quality, and turnover (Cowherd and Levine

1992; Greenberg 1990; Summers and Hendrix 1991). In his study of professional

basketball and baseball players, Harder (1992) found that under-rewarded players

behaved less cooperatively and more selfishly.

2 This norm of reciprocity in an exchange relationship, such as that of employment,

has also been raised in the psychological contract literature (Coyle-Shapiro and

Kessler 2003; Rousseau and McLean Parks 1993).