Democratic Change in the Arab world by Eric Chaney

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 8/2/2019 Democratic Change in the Arab world by Eric Chaney

    1/35

    Democratic Change in the Arab World, Past andPresent

    Eric Chaney

    March 10, 2012

    Abstract

    Will the Arab Spring lead to long-lasting democratic change? To explore

    this question I examine the determinants of the Arab worlds democratic decit

    in 2010. I nd that the percent of a countrys landmass that was conquered

    by Arab armies following the death of the prophet Muhammad statistically

    accounts for this decit. Using history as a guide, I hypothesize that this

    pattern reects the long-run inuence of control structures developed under

    Islamic empires in the pre-modern era and nd that the available evidence is

    consistent with this interpretation. I also investigate the determinants of the

    recent uprisings. When taken in unison, the results cast doubt on claims that

    the Arab-Israeli conict or Arab/Muslim culture are systematic obstacles to

    democratic change in the region and point instead to the legacy of the regions

    historical institutional framework.

    Department of Economics, Harvard University. This paper was prepared for the Brookings

    Panel on Economic Activity, March 22-23, 2012. I thank George Akerlof, Pol Antrs, Lisa Blaydes,

    Edward Glaeser, David Romer, Andrei Shleifer and Justin Wolfers for helpful discussions and

    comments. I also thank Gallup for sharing their data. Any remaining errors are mine.

    1

  • 8/2/2019 Democratic Change in the Arab world by Eric Chaney

    2/35

  • 8/2/2019 Democratic Change in the Arab world by Eric Chaney

    3/35

    a possible explanation for why countries such as Azerbaijan, Chad, Iran, Tajikistan,

    Turkmenistan and Uzbekistan share the Arab Leagues democratic decit today

    whereas Muslim-majority countries such as Albania, Bangladesh, Guinea, Indone-

    sia, Malaysia or Sierra Leone do not. I hypothesize that the former countries were

    more exposed to the control structures that developed following the Arab conquests

    than the latter. These historical arrangements, in turn, have had enduring eects

    that help explain the geographic clustering of non-democracies detailed in gure 1.

    To investigate the empirical relevance of this hypothesis, I calculate the percent-

    age of a countrys landmass that was conquered by Arab armies in the centuries

    following the death of the prophet Muhammad. I then show that from a statistical

    standpoint this variable accounts for the Arab Leagues democratic decit today.

    This empirical pattern is interesting, in part, because it provides an opportunityto distinguish between a number of competing theories regarding the determinants of

    the Arab worlds democratic decit on the eve of the recent uprisings. For example,

    the fact that the Arab worlds democratic decit is shared by 10 non-Arab countries

    that were conquered by Arab armies casts doubt on the importance of the role of

    Arab culture in perpetuating the democratic decit. Hypotheses stressing the role of

    Muslim theology also do not receive empirical support. Once one accounts for the 28

    countries conquered by Arab armies, the evolution of democracy in the remaining 15

    Muslim-majority countries since 1960 largely mirrors that of the rest of the developing

    world.

    Alternative views attribute the regions democratic decit to the eects of oil

    or to the Israeli-Palestinian conict. But if one omits oil exporters and countries

    that are in close geographic proximity to Israel the results are almost identical to

    those obtained when these countries are included. Consequently, my reading of the

    evidence provides little support for these hypotheses.

    A nal group of hypotheses, which I believe provides the best explanation for the

    empirical patterns I document, is the institutional persistence hypothesis (Ace-

    moglu et al. 2001, 2002; Nunn 2008, 2009; Dell 2010). Many scholars maintain thatthe roots of the Arab worlds democratic decit are to be found in the regions history

    of unrelieved autocracy (Lewis 1993b) which date[s] back to the early ninth cen-

    3

  • 8/2/2019 Democratic Change in the Arab world by Eric Chaney

    4/35

    tury (Khashan 1998). This view builds on a distinguished line of scholarship going

    back at least to Montesqueiu (1989 [1748]) suggesting that historical developments

    in the Islamic Middle East have made the region particularly prone to autocratic

    rule.

    If the Arab Leagues democratic decit today can be traced to the long-term ef-

    fects of the regions institutions, what institutional developments following the Arab

    conquests had such enduring an enduring impact? Although data limitations pre-

    clude an investigation of the precise channel(s) of causality generating this empirical

    relationship, I use history and recent scholarship as a guide (Blaydes and Chaney

    2011, Kuran 2011, Chaney 2012) to suggest that this pattern reects the long-run

    inuence of control structures developed under Islamic empires in the pre-modern

    era. This literature suggests that these historic control structures have left a legacyof weak civil societies where political power is concentrated today in the hands of

    military and religious leaders that work to perpetuate the status quo. One empirical

    prediction that arises from this literature is that the governments share of GDP

    should be higher in areas conquered by Arab armies. One would also expect regimes

    in these areas to prevent the emergence of independent centers of political power

    and to undermine the inuence of trade unions. I nd that the available data is

    consistent with these predictions.

    Have the numerous structural changes over the past century (Rauch and Kostyshak

    2009) helped lessen the weight of history, making Arab states fertile ground for sus-

    tained democratic change? Since data limitations again preclude a systematic in-

    vestigation of the channels through which the regions autocratic institutions have

    persisted, my strategy in this section is simply to investigate the characteristics of

    countries that experienced uprisings in 2011. The most robust nding that emerges

    is that countries that experienced uprisings witnessed signicantly lower levels of

    self-reported well being in the year before the uprisings. This result suggests that

    the Arab Spring shares characteristics with other popular movements that have led

    to stable democratic institutions (Acemoglu and Robinson 2006).On the one hand, the results provide reasons to be cautiously optimistic that the

    Arab Spring will lead to sustained democratic change. For example, they cast doubt

    4

  • 8/2/2019 Democratic Change in the Arab world by Eric Chaney

    5/35

    on claims that Muslim theology, the Israeli-Palestinian conict or Arab culture are

    systematic obstacles to democracy. On the other, they provide sobering evidence

    that the regions democratic decit has deep historical roots. While such impedi-

    ments to democratic change may have been weakened by structural changes over the

    past decades, it is also possible that they remain in place today. In this sense, the

    interpretation that I believe best explains the empirical patterns I observe echoes

    recent studies suggesting that the regions democratic decit is more a product of its

    unique political equilibrium than its cultural, ethnic or religious characteristics (e.g.

    Stepan and Robertson 2003, Jamal and Tessler 2008).

    Inasmuch as the regions institutional history is useful for forecasting the future, it

    suggests that democracy is less likely to emerge where political power remains largely

    divided between religious leaders and the military (e.g. Egypt or Yemen). Wherepopular support for secular and religious leaders is more balanced (e.g. Tunisia)

    Islamist groups may play an important role in sustaining democratic institutions by

    constraining (and being constrained by) rival political groups. Since recent history

    suggests that Islamists are just as likely to establish autocratic rule as other groups

    in the absence of checks on their power, popular support for Islamists may undermine

    democratic eorts if such groups are not checked by other contenders for power.

    Finally, it is important to stress that while this paper provides new empirical evi-

    dence for the reasons behind the Arab worlds democratic decit, our understanding

    of the determinants of democracy in the region remains incomplete. This provides

    both an impetus for future research and reasons to be cautious about the evidence

    we have regarding democratic change in the Arab world, at least as a guide for future

    policy decisions.

    5

  • 8/2/2019 Democratic Change in the Arab world by Eric Chaney

    6/35

    1 Arab Conquest and Democracy: the Empirical

    Evidence

    This section presents the main results.3 To measure the extent to which countries

    were persistently exposed to the institutional framework developed in the early Is-

    lamic world I dene the variable ArabConquest as the proportion of a country that

    was ruled by Muslim dynasties in the year 1100 CE, interacted with dummy equal

    to one if at least half of the countrys landmass was controlled by Muslim dynasties

    in both 1500 and 1900 CE.4 This interaction term removes countries such as Spain

    that lost the relevant institutional framework centuries ago. Since the majority of

    the lands under the control of Muslim dynasties in 1100 CE were conquered by Arab

    armies, for expositional simplicity I use Arab conquest to refer to early incorporationinto the Islamic world throughout the paper.5

    In table 2 I investigate the extent to whichArabConquest can statistically account

    for the democratic decit in the Muslim world in general and the Arab League

    specically. To do this I estimate a regression of the form:

    Democracyic = 1Muslimic+2ArabLeagueic+3ArabConquestic+0X+"ic (1)

    where Democracyic is the normalized polity score of country i on continent c in 2010

    (where the normalized polity score lies on the interval [0,1] with higher values denot-

    ing more democratic institutions), Muslimic is an indicator variable equal to one if

    at least half of a countrys population is Muslim, ArabLeagueic is an indicator equal

    to one if a country is a member of the Arab League, ArabConquestic is as dened

    above and X is a vector of covariates including continent dummies and an indicator

    equal to one if Rauch and Kostyshak (2009) dene a country as fuel-endowed.6

    3 For expositional ease I leave the description of the majority of the data used in the paper to

    the appendix.4

    In addition, I set the variableArabConquest

    equal to zero for Israel.5 The results presented in the paper are robust to a variety of alternative measures of early

    incorporation into the Islamic world.6 The Arab League is dened in Rauch and Kostyshak (2009, p. 165) as consist[ing] of all

    6

  • 8/2/2019 Democratic Change in the Arab world by Eric Chaney

    7/35

    In column (1) of table 1 I provide an estimate of 1

    omitting all other covari-

    ates. The point estimate shows that Muslim majority countries are 0.31 normalized

    polity points (over one standard deviation) less democratic than the rest of the world.

    Throughout table 2 heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors are given in parenthe-

    ses whereas standard errors clustered by UN regions are given in brackets to address

    potential concerns of spatial correlations in the error terms.7 In column (2) I add an

    indicator variable equal to one if the country was a member of the Arab League in

    2010. When this indicator is added, the coecient on Muslim decreases in absolute

    value although it remains negative and statistically signicant. The coecient on

    ArabLeague is also negative and statistically signicant. These results are consistent

    with previous studies that have found both Arab and Muslim democratic decits.

    In column (3), I add the variable ArabConquest. When this variable is added, thepoint estimates on the variables Muslim and ArabLeague drop sharply in absolute

    value and become statistically insignicant. In column (4) I add continent dummies

    and a dummy variable equal to one if the country is fuel-endowed. The results do

    not qualitatively change and show that from a statistical standpoint ArabConquest

    explains both the Arab and Muslim democratic decits found in previous studies.

    In columns (5)-(8) I limit the sample to Muslim majority countries. In columns

    (5)-(7) I use all countries who have Muslim population shares greater than or equal

    to 0.5. These results show that within the Muslim-majority world, the Arab Leagues

    democratic decit is shared by countries that were conquered by Arab armies. In

    column (8) I show that the result continues to hold when one increases the cuto to

    only include countries whose Muslim shares exceed 0.8.

    countries in which (a dialect of) Arabic is the spoken language of the majority. See table 1 for a

    list of the member states of the Arab League in 2010.7 Since the clustered standard errors and heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors are almost

    identical throughout the paper, in subsequent tables I only report the heteroskedasticity-robust

    standard errors. The UN regions are: Eastern Africa, Middle Africa, Northern Africa, Southern

    Africa, Western Africa, Caribbean, Central America, South America, North America, Central Asia,

    Eastern Asia, Southern Asia, South-Eastern Asia, Western Asia, Eastern Europe, Northern Europe,Southern Europe, Western Europe, Australia/ New Zealand and Melanesia. The countries in each

    of these regions are detailed at: http://unstats.un.org/unsd/methods/m49/m49regin.htm

    7

  • 8/2/2019 Democratic Change in the Arab world by Eric Chaney

    8/35

    1.1 The Emergence of the Democratic Decit

    The evidence presented so far documents that countries conquered by Arab armies

    experienced a democratic decit in 2010. When did this decit emerge? To examinethis question, gure 2 plots the average polity score by countries in three groups

    since 1960 (before this date, small sample sizes limit the analysis). The rst group

    contains countries conquered by Arab armies. The second group contains Muslim

    majority countries that were not conquered by Arab armies. The third group contains

    developing countries that neither possess Muslim majorities nor were conquered by

    Muslim armies.8

    In the year 1960 -when the majority of the developing world had been decolonized-

    both Muslim-majority non-Arab conquest and non-Muslim developing countries had

    (normalized) polity scores of roughly 0.4. The scores in countries that were conquered

    by Arab armies were signicantly lower at around 0.2. Until around 1990 this gap

    of around 0.2 points remained roughly constant. After 1990 the non-Muslim devel-

    oping world experienced a wave of democratization that was followed by the non-

    Arab-conquest Muslim countries with a lag of roughly ten years. Although countries

    conquered by Arab armies have seen a slow trend towards increasing political open-

    ness since 1990, the levels of democracy in this region in 2010 remained well below

    that of the rest of the developing world.

    In sum, the democratic decit of countries that were conquered by Arab armiesdates back at least to 1960. Although systematic statistical analyses are not possible

    before this date, the average normalized polity score remains approximately constant

    prior to 1960 in the two Arab-conquest countries where these scores go back to 1800.9

    This result is consistent with the claim that the regions democratic decit has deep

    historical roots.

    8 I dene developing countries as those that were not members of the OECD before 1980. The

    qualitative implications of the analysis are robust to alternative denitions.9 These countries are Iran and Turkey.

    8

  • 8/2/2019 Democratic Change in the Arab world by Eric Chaney

    9/35

    2 Hypotheses and Explanations for the Arab Worlds

    Democratic Decit

    In this section I examine the extent to which existing hypotheses for the Arab worlds

    democratic decit on the eve of the Arab Spring are consistent with the empirical

    evidence presented above.

    2.1 The Culture Hypothesis

    The culture hypothesis claims that the Arab Leagues democratic decit is a prod-

    uct of the regions culture. One version of this hypothesis is that Arab culture is

    inimical to the emergence of democratic institutions (Sharabi 1988, Noland 2008).

    The empirical evidence presented so far is not consistent with this hypothesis. Of

    the 28 countries that were conquered by Arab armies in the sample, 18 are members

    of the Arab League today whereas 10 are not. Within countries conquered by Arab

    armies, there is no evidence that member states of the Arab League have systemati-

    cally lower polity scores. Since membership in the Arab League is generally used as

    a proxy for Arab culture, this result casts doubt on the importance of Arab culture

    in perpetuating the observed democratic decit.

    Results in table 3 demonstrate this point in a more formal manner (that com-

    plements the inclusion of the Arab dummy in the previous section). In column (1) Ipresent regression output from a regression similar to equation (1) using the entire

    sample. In column (2) I run the same regression omitting the member states of the

    Arab League. The results show that the omission of the Arab League states has al-

    most no eect on the point estimate on the variable Arab conquest. In other words,

    the eect of Arab conquest on democratic outcomes today seems to be independent

    of Arab culture.

    Another version of the culture hypothesis suggests that Muslim religious beliefs

    are responsible for the regions democratic decit (Huntington 1996, Lako 2004).In column (3) I omit all countries that were conquered by Arab armies. When this

    is done, the results show that the coecient on Muslim majority is small and not

    9

  • 8/2/2019 Democratic Change in the Arab world by Eric Chaney

    10/35

    statistically signicant. This result is not consistent with claims that Muslim theol-

    ogy or gender norms in the Islamic world are responsible for the regions democratic

    decit (Fish 2002).10

    Have Islamic religious beliefs put down stronger roots in the areas that were

    conquered by Arab armies? To investigate this hypothesis, I gather data on alcohol

    consumption across the world. If stronger religious beliefs are driving the result, one

    would expect the inclusion of per-capita alcohol consumption to signicantly aect

    the point estimate on Arab conquest when limiting the sample to Muslim countries

    since Islam prohibits the consumption of alcohol. Results in column (4) show that

    this is not the case. In the appendix I provide additional evidence showing that

    religious beliefs do not seem to be abnormally strong in regions conquered by Arab

    armies. Together with the ndings presented in column 3, these results cast doubton Islam as the primary obstacle to democracy.11

    2.2 The Conict/Resource Curse Hypotheses

    Another group of studies stresses the importance of the Arab-Israeli conict (Stepan

    and Robertson 2003; El Badawi and Makdisi 2007; Diamond 2010). Such studies,

    however, explicitly claim that any negative eects on democratic outcomes should be

    limited to the Arab world. However, as I have shown above, the regions democratic

    decit extends to a sizeable number of countries outside of the Arab League. Inaddition, in column (5) of table 3 I present results omitting Israel and the neighboring

    Arab counties (i.e. Egypt, Jordan, Lebanon and Syria). Since these countries have

    experienced the conict most directly, one would expect these countries to drive the

    conict results if they existed. However, the results in column (5) show that the

    point estimates are almost identical when these countries are removed. Thus, when

    taken in unison these results cast doubt on the importance of the Arab-Israeli conict

    as a systematic obstacle to democratic change across the region.

    10 In the appendix I provide additional evidence supporting this claim.11 And thus echo the conclusions of recent analyses such as Stepan and Robertson (2003) or Jamal

    and Tessler (2008).

    10

  • 8/2/2019 Democratic Change in the Arab world by Eric Chaney

    11/35

    Another inuential literature argues that large amounts of oil wealth are inimical

    to the development of democratic institutions (Ross 2001). Are the results driven by

    oil rich countries? To investigate this possibility, I have included a dummy variable

    denoting fuel-endowed countries as dened in Rauch and Kostyshak (2009) in the

    regressions above and shown that the inclusion of this variable does not qualitatively

    aect the results. As a further robustness check, in column (6) of table 3 I present

    the results of regression (1) omitting all fuel-endowed countries. Again, the omission

    of these countries does not aect the point estimate on ArabConquest in a signicant

    way. In other words, the data do not support the hypothesis that oil wealth drives

    the Arab Leagues democratic decit.12

    2.3 The Institutional Persistence Hypothesis

    The institutional persistence hypothesis attributes the Arab Leagues democratic

    decit today to the long-term inuence of the control structures developed in the

    centuries following the Arab conquests. The view that the region has a propensity

    toward autocratic institutions that is rooted in historical events goes back at least

    to Montesqueiu (1989 [1748]) and was echoed by prominent Arab thinkers in the

    19th century (Hourani 1962). Following decolonization, many saw the failure of the

    parliamentary-democratic form of government as the legacy of the regions historical

    institutional framework (Issawi 1956, p. 27). More recently, scholars such as BernardLewis (1993b) and Kedourie (1994) have emphasized that a unique set of institutions

    developed in the areas conquered by Arab armies and that these historical institutions

    have had enduring political impacts.

    Historical evidence supports the notion that an abnormally autocratic political

    equilibrium developed in the Arab-conquest regions. In the ninth century, rulers

    12 I do nd evidence later in the paper, however, consistent with the claim that popular pressures

    for democratization are more muted in oil-rich counties. Consequently, the results in the paper

    are not inconsistent with the hypothesis that oil wealth discourages the emergence of democratic

    institutions. Rather, they suggest that oil wealth cannot account for the entire regions democratic

    decit.

    11

  • 8/2/2019 Democratic Change in the Arab world by Eric Chaney

    12/35

    across this region began to use slave armies -as opposed to native populations- to

    sta their armies. Blaydes and Chaney (2011) argue that the widespread use of

    these slave armies allowed rulers to achieve independence from local military and

    civilian groups and helped remove constraints on the sovereign in pre-modern Islamic

    societies. In this autocratic environment, religious leaders emerged as the only check

    on the power of the sovereign (Chaney 2011).

    The historic division of power between the military (i.e. the sovereign backed

    by his army of slaves) and religious leaders did not produce democratic institutions.

    Instead, both religious and military elites worked together to develop and perpet-

    uate a classical institutional equilibrium. This institutional framework -which is

    often referred to as Islamic law- seems to have been designed with the interest of

    both military and religious leaders in mind (Kuran 2011, Chaney 2012). Althoughreligious leaders devised equilibrium institutions to protect the interests of the

    general population to a degree, both the military and religious elites worked to resist

    the emergence of rival centers of political power such as merchant guilds that could

    have facilitated institutional change (Lapidus 1984, pp. 103-104). Concentration of

    political power in the hands of a few groups and weak civil societies are thought to

    be the long-term legacy of this historical institutional framework (e.g. Kuran 2011,

    p. 301).

    Areas incorporated into the Islamic world after the era of Arab conquests had

    ended did not adopt this classical framework in its entirety (Lapidus 1988, p. 252).

    For example, in regions conquered by non-Arab Muslim armies such as India and

    the Balkans, local elites remained in power and perpetuated previous institutional

    arrangements (Lapidus 1988, pp. 247-248). Where Islam spread by conversion (e.g.

    Indonesia, Malaysia or sub-Saharan Africa) institutions were shaped by a local

    elite which preserved its political and cultural continuity (Lapidus 1988, p. 249).

    Consequently, an institutional divide arose within the Muslim world between areas

    that had been incorporated into the Muslim world by Arab conquest and those that

    were incorporated in later periods.These institutional divisions within the Islamic world have proven remarkably

    resilient. For example, although Egypt was conquered by the Ottoman Empire in

    12

  • 8/2/2019 Democratic Change in the Arab world by Eric Chaney

    13/35

    1517 CE, remnants of the local elite eventually reestablished themselves and contin-

    ued to rely on slave armies to support their positions until the arrival of Napoleon

    in Egypt in 1798 CE. Despite the many changes that Arab-conquered regions have

    undergone over the subsequent 200 years, both colonizers and native rulers follow-

    ing independence seem to have worked to perpetuate the historic concentration of

    political power in the hands of the ruler. This point is stressed by Bernard Lewis

    (1993b) who notes that [m]odernization in the nineteenth century, and still more in

    the twentieth, far from reducing this [historic] autocracy, substantially increased it.

    Contemporary observers have also noted that the present day political equilibrium

    bears more than a passing resemblance to the historical equilibrium. For example,

    some Arab critics have called their rulers Mamelukes, alluding to the slave-soldiers

    who exercised unrestrained and arbitrary power in those countries (Kedourie 1994,p. 92) and Sonbol (2000, p. xxvi) notes that that the military [in Egypt...] prac-

    tice[s] prerogatives similar to those enjoyed by the [slave soldiers]. This autocratic

    environment has led religious leaders to again emerge in their historical role as the

    primary check on the power of the state (al-Sayyid Marsot 1984, Chaney 2011).

    2.3.1 Institutions or Geographic Endowments?

    Is the Arab Leagues democratic decit today a product of institutional persistence?

    An alternative explanation for the empirical patterns I observe is that countriesdominated by desert terrain selected into Arab conquest and that the results are

    picking up the long-run eects of desert institutions (Haber and Menaldo 2010) or

    even a direct eect of desert terrain on democracy today.

    To investigate this possibility, in the upper graph of gure 3 I detail the re-

    lationship between desert terrain and democracy in the entire sample. Although

    the negative relationship between desert terrain and democratic outcomes in 2010

    is striking, it is entirely driven by countries conquered by Arab armies (which are

    denoted with grey boxes). Once these countries are removed from the sample, the re-

    lationship between desert terrain and democracy is no longer statistically signicant

    and is given in the lower graph.

    13

  • 8/2/2019 Democratic Change in the Arab world by Eric Chaney

    14/35

    In columns (7)-(9) of table 3 I demonstrate this point in a more formal manner.

    In these specications I add controls for desert terrain to regression (1). In column

    (7) I use the percent of a countrys current landmass that is occupied by desert

    terrain. In columns (8) and (9) I use the logarithm of a countrys average rainfall

    in both a linear and cubic specication as suggested by Haber and Menaldo (2010).

    Although the roughly 50% increase in the standard errors is a product of the fact that

    Arab conquest and desert terrain are highly correlated, the point estimates on the

    variable Arab conquest do not substantially change when measures of desert terrain

    are added to the regression and these estimates remain statistically signicant. The

    coecients on desert terrain, in turn, are small in absolute value and statistically

    insignicant. Thus, the available evidence provides little support for the hypothesis

    that desert terrain has eects on democratic outcomes today that are independentof Arab conquest.13

    If the only way desert terrain impacts democratic outcomes today is through

    institutional developments that followed Arab conquest, then desert terrain should

    be a valid instrument for Arab conquest in equation (1). In table 4, I present results

    instrumenting for Arab conquest with desert terrain. I do this for two reasons.

    First, if Arab conquest is a noisy measure of treatment with the relevant historical

    institutions then IV results can help address biases caused by this measurement error.

    Second, overidentication tests provide an additional test of the hypothesis that

    desert terrain only inuences democratic outcomes today through Arab conquest.

    Why do I expect desert terrain and Arab conquest to be statistically related?

    It is well known that Arab armies had signicant military advantages in areas that

    were dominated by desert terrain. Bernard Lewis sums up this point by noting

    that [t]he strategy employed by the Arabs in the great campaigns of conquest was

    determined by the use of desert-power [...] [t]he desert was familiar and accessible to

    the Arabs and not to their enemies (1993a, p. 54). Similarly, Kennedy (2007, p. 371)

    notes that bedouin armies were particularly able in the barren and inhospitable

    milieus that constituted much of the territory conquered by Arab armies, while Hill13 In the appendix I provide further evidence in support of this claim.

    14

  • 8/2/2019 Democratic Change in the Arab world by Eric Chaney

    15/35

    (1975) suggests that the Arab use of the camel greatly facilitated conquest on or

    near desert terrain. Consequently, areas with desert terrain should have been more

    likely to select into conquest by Arab armies.14

    In table 4 I present the relevant results in four panels. In panel A I present the

    IV (2SLS) estimates. In panel B I present the rst-stage for Arab conquest. In

    panel C I provide the OLS results and in panel D I provide the p-value from the

    overidentication tests when relevant. The rst three columns use the entire sample

    and the nal three columns limit the sample to countries with Muslim majorities.

    In columns (1) and (4), I instrument for Arab conquest with the distance of

    the geographical center of a country (i.e. its centroid) from Mecca. Panel B shows

    that there is a strong rst stage relationship between distance from Mecca and Arab

    conquest. In both specications the point estimates and standard errors on Arabconquest roughly double.

    In columns (2) and (5), I instrument for Arab conquest using desert terrain.

    The rst-stage results show that there is also a strong relationship between desert

    terrain and Arab conquest. In panel D I present the p-value testing that the IV

    coecients obtained using Mecca and Desert as instruments are equal. I cannot reject

    the hypothesis that they are equal at conventional levels of statistical signicance.

    In columns (3) and (6), I instrument for Arab conquest using the logarithm of a

    countrys average rainfall. Again, I cannot reject the null hypothesis that the IV

    coecients obtained using Mecca and rainfall as instruments are equal.

    The overidentication tests are useful since they are a direct test of the exclusion

    restriction that desert terrain only aects democratic outcomes today through Arab

    conquest. Although it should be noted that such tests may not lead to a rejection

    if all instruments are invalid but still highly correlated with each other (and thus

    should be treated with some caution), the data support the exclusion restriction

    implied by my approach. Thus, the evidence is consistent with the claim that desert

    terrain aects democratic outcomes today through institutions developed following

    14 See Michalopoulus et al. (2010) for a related discussion of how desert terrain and unequal agri-cultural endowments may have aected the selection of countries into the classical institutional

    framework.

    15

  • 8/2/2019 Democratic Change in the Arab world by Eric Chaney

    16/35

    Arab conquest and not through channels that are unrelated to Arab conquest.15

    2.3.2 Government Share of GDP, Access to Credit, Trade Unions and

    Arab Conquest

    I now turn to the channels through which Arab conquest may continue to aect

    institutional outcomes today. I view this analysis as preliminary and exploratory,

    as data limitations make it dicult to pin down the precise channels underlying

    the observed empirical patterns with any reasonable degree of certainty. Instead,

    I examine the extent to which the available data are consistent with the historical

    evidence.

    The main prediction of the institutional persistence hypothesis as developed above

    is that political power should be abnormally concentrated in areas conquered by Arab

    armies and that civil societies in the region should be unusually weak. Since I do not

    have direct measures of either, I instead use as proxies government share of GDP,

    the extent to which existing institutions facilitate access to credit and the number

    of trade unions normalized by GDP.

    The logic behind the use of the governments share of GDP metric is rooted in

    the regions economic development over the past 60 years. After the end of the

    colonial era, governments worked to impede the emergence of autonomous social

    groups in Arab-conquered regions. For example, the state stymied the emergence ofpolitically powerful merchant groups (Pamuk 2004, Malik and Awadallah 2011). As

    a consequence, government today should be directly involved in an abnormally large

    share of economic production in Arab conquered regions (Kuran 2011, p. 301).

    In table 5 I present results investigating the empirical relevance of this prediction.

    In columns (1)-(3) I present results from a regression similar to equation (1) using

    governments share of GDP in 2010 as the dependent variable. Results in column (1)

    show that countries conquered by Arab armies have government GDP shares that are

    7 percentage points higher than in areas that were not conquered by Arab armies.

    15 In this sense, the results complement recent studies that nd that geography inuences present-

    day outcomes through historical events (e.g. Nunn and Puga 2012).

    16

  • 8/2/2019 Democratic Change in the Arab world by Eric Chaney

    17/35

    In column (2) I show that this result is not driven by the regions democratic decit.

    In column (3) I show that although there is not much evidence that Arab League

    countries are dierent from non-Arab League countries, the results on Arab conquest

    lose statistical signicance when one introduces an Arab League dummy.

    In columns (4)-(6) I examine the extent to which governments in Arab-conquered

    areas continue to resist the development of autonomous social groups today. To do

    this, I use the World Banks Strength of Legal Rights Index as the dependent

    variable. I normalize this index to range from 0 to 1, with higher scores indicating

    that the legal system is better designed to expand access to credit. I expect the legal

    system in countries conquered by Arab armies to be inimical to the expansion of

    credit since the regions historical institutions have both endowed ruling elites with

    unusual levels of political power and have left civil society groups such as merchantsabnormally weak. The results are consistent with this prediction. Namely, the legal

    systems in countries that were conquered by Arab armies are between 0.21 and 0.29

    points (or roughly one standard deviation) less hospitable to the expansion of credit

    than legal systems in other regions.

    Finally, in columns (7)-(9) I present the number of trade unions normalized by

    GDP (measured in billions of dollars). To measure the number of trade unions, I

    use the number of trade unions aliated with the International Confederation of

    Free Trade Unions (ICFTU) per country. The point estimates on Arab conquest

    in columns (7)-(9) shows that areas conquered by Arab armies have between 0.28

    and 0.35 fewer trade unions per billion dollars of GDP (or just over one standard

    deviation). These results do not seem to be driven either by the regions democratic

    decit or by membership in the Arab League. They are, however, consistent with

    the prediction that civil societies are abnormally weak in Arab-conquest areas.

    In sum, although it is dicult to measure the extent to which political power

    is abnormally concentrated and civil societies are weak in areas conquered by Arab

    armies, in this subsection I have presented evidence that is largely consistent with

    this prediction.

    17

  • 8/2/2019 Democratic Change in the Arab world by Eric Chaney

    18/35

    3 The Arab Spring: Past as Prologue?

    The ndings presented in this paper suggest that the democratic decit in the Arab

    League on the eve of the Arab Spring had deep historical roots. However, thisresult does not imply that the Arab Spring will not lead to sustained democratic

    change. Indeed, the numerous structural changes over the past 50 years (Rauch and

    Kostyshak 2009) may have helped to lessen the weight of history, rendering many

    Arab states fertile ground for sustained democratic change today.

    3.1 Advances in Education

    While space considerations limit the extent to which I am able to investigate the

    evolution of the many available indicators in the Arab League over the past decades,in this section I detail the evolution of average education in the region over the past

    60 years. I concentrate on this indicator because a large literature views high levels

    of educational attainment as a prerequisite for democracy.16 In gure 4 I present the

    evolution of the average years of education since 1950 for three groups of countries:

    i. Non-Muslim, developing countries, ii. Muslim, non-Arab conquest countries and

    iii. countries that were conquered by Arab armies. The results show the tremendous

    increases in average education in the countries conquered by Arab armies over the

    past 60 years. They also show that while dierences in education do not seem to

    explain the democratic decit from a statistical standpoint in these countries (see

    the appendix for these results), educational attainment in countries conquered by

    Arab armies has largely converged to the non-Arab-conquest Muslim average.17

    What do such structural changes imply for the future of democracy in the Arab

    world? Unfortunately, data limitations have prevented a systematic investigation of

    the channels through which history continues to aect democratic outcomes today.

    Consequently, it is hard to know the extent to which structural changes have helped

    16 See Acemoglu et al. (2005) for an overview of this literature and Glaeser et al. (2007) for one

    causal mechanism through which higher levels of education may lead to more democratic outcomes.17 In a recent working paper Campante and Chor (2011) argue that such structural changes have

    made political protests more likely and pressures for democratization more acute.

    18

  • 8/2/2019 Democratic Change in the Arab world by Eric Chaney

    19/35

    to remove the historical impediments to democratic change. However, if the litera-

    ture stressing the importance of education for democratization is correct, the large

    increases in education in the Arab conquest countries over the last 60 years suggest

    that the prospects for democracy in the region are brighter today than at any time

    in its history.

    3.2 A Democratic Dawn?

    At some level it is obvious that the structural changes the region has undergone

    over the past 60 years have made the Arab world more fertile ground for sustained

    democratic change today than at any time in the past. For example, the widespread

    protests that swept across the region in 2011 have no precedent in the regions history.

    However, the political equilibrium in many states in the Arab League resembles

    the equilibrium that has accompanied autocratic institutions for centuries. Namely,

    political power appears to be concentrated in the hands of military and religious

    leaders in many areas.

    The regions institutional history suggests that democratic change is less likely

    where political power remains concentrated in such a manner. Although I do not

    observe the extent to which political power is concentrated in the hands of military

    and religious leaders, I do observe popular support for Sharia implementation. To

    the extent that religious leaders derive political power from popular support, supportfor Sharia implementation may be a good proxy for the relative power of religious

    leaders across countries. Thus, I use popular support for the Sharia as a measure of

    the extent to which political power remains concentrated in the hands of religious

    leaders across the Arab world today.18

    Average support for Sharia implementation over the years 2005-2010 in the mem-

    18 The use of this metric is supported by recent election results in Tunisia and Egypt. Although

    Islamist parties won majorities in both countries, these groups seem on the whole less moderate

    and to wield more political power in Egypt than in Tunisia. This is consistent with the results

    from surveys presented in table 6 showing that a larger share of the populace support Sharia

    implementation in Egypt than in Tunisia.

    19

  • 8/2/2019 Democratic Change in the Arab world by Eric Chaney

    20/35

    ber states of the Arab League is presented in column (1) of table 6. In table 6,

    countries that experienced unrest in 2011 are marked in bold. The results show that

    in countries such as Egypt and Yemen popular support for Sharia implementation

    is high. In countries such as Syria and Tunisia it is much lower. However, with the

    exception of Lebanon nowhere in the Arab League does popular support for Sharia

    implementation approach the low levels of Turkey which is widely seen as a demo-

    cratic model for the region. These results suggest that religious leaders will wield

    greater political power in countries such as Yemen and Egypt than in others such

    as Tunisia. History suggests that the emergence of stable democratic institutions is

    less likely in areas where religious leaders face fewer political rivals.

    3.3 Measuring the Propensity for Unrest

    One prominent model of democratic change links economic downturns and popular

    discontent with democratizations (Acemoglu and Robinson 2006).19 To both inves-

    tigate and quantify the extent to which popular discontent helped drive the Arab

    spring, in columns (2)-(4) of table 6, I detail the evolution of self-reported well-being

    in the Arab world in 2009, 2010 and 2011 using Gallups World Poll data. In each

    column, I provide the mean number of respondents who were self-reportedly thriv-

    ing by countries. The level of self-reported well-being in 2010 is the only variable I

    have found that robustly predicts unrest in 2011 from a statistical standpoint.This result suggests that the level of subjective well-being in 2011 may help

    predict the propensity for further unrest across the Arab League. To the extent that

    this is the case, oil-rich gulf countries such as Saudi Arabia, Kuwait or the United

    Arab Emirates seem unlikely to experience widespread unrest in the near future. It

    should be noted, however, that the sharp drop in well-being in Bahrain between 2009

    and 2011 from a relatively high base suggests that even countries with high levels of

    self-reported well-being may be more susceptible to unrest than the results in table

    6 suggest.

    While the regions history reminds us that democratizations might prove eeting

    19 For a recent empirical investigation of this hypothesis, see Brckner and Ciccone (2011).

    20

  • 8/2/2019 Democratic Change in the Arab world by Eric Chaney

    21/35

    in the absence of competing interest groups, the results also show that popular

    discontent with the status quo helped drive the protests. This result suggests both

    that the Arab Spring seems to share important characteristics with other successful

    democratizations and that such discontent seems to have helped to unify protestors

    in pursuit of change.

    4 Conclusion

    In this paper I have provided evidence suggesting that the Arab Leagues democratic

    decit on the eve of the Arab Spring has deep historical roots. These results cast

    doubt on claims that Muslim theology, Arab culture, the Arab-Israeli conict or

    oil wealth are systematic obstacles to democractic change. Instead, the availableevidence suggests that the regions democratic decit is a product of the long-run

    inuence of control structures developed under Islamic empires in the pre-modern

    era.

    Will the Arab Spring end the regions long history of autocratic rule and usher in

    long-lasting democratic change? Unfortunately, data limitations prohibit a detailed

    investigation of the channels through which the regions historical institutional equi-

    librium continues to aect outcomes today. Consequently, I am unable to measure

    the extent to which these channels continue to aect political developments.

    Despite these limitations, at some level the structural changes the region has

    undergone over the past 60 years have made the Arab world more fertile ground

    for sustained democratic change today than at any time in the past. Indeed, the

    widespread protests that swept across the region in 2011 have no precedent in the

    regions history. That having been said, in some countries of the Arab world (e.g.

    Egypt or Yemen) the present-day political equilibrium seems more similar to the

    historical equilibrium that has accompanied autocratic institutions than in others

    (e.g. Tunisia). In this sense, history suggests that democracy is less likely to emerge

    in the former group of countries than in the latter.What, then, are the implications of the preceding analysis for the current policy

    21

  • 8/2/2019 Democratic Change in the Arab world by Eric Chaney

    22/35

    environment? Although the results suggest that the Arab Leagues democratic decit

    on the eve of the Arab Spring has deep historical roots, this decit does not appear

    to be rooted in religious beliefs. However, the regions institutional history shows

    that overwhelming popular support for Islamists may undermine democratic eorts

    by concentrating political power in the hands of these groups. Indeed, the recent past

    shows that Islamists are just as likely to establish autocratic rule as other groups

    in the absence of checks on their power. Thus, unless other interests groups -such

    as labor unions or commercial interests- check their power, Islamists may replace

    secular rulers and usher in a new wave of autocracy in some Arab countries.

    In closing, it should be stressed that these conclusions are largely based on an

    implicit model of the regions institutional history. While this conceptual framework

    might be consistent with the available data and may help explain the past, if therehas been a regime shift (statistically speaking) predictions based on this framework

    will be poor. Thus, there are many reasons to be cautious about using the evidence

    we have regarding democratic change in the Arab world as a guide for future policy

    decisions.

    References

    Acemoglu, D., S. Johnson, and J. A. Robinson. 2001. The Colonial Ori-

    gins of Comparative Development: An Empirical Investigation. American Economic

    Review, 91 (5): 1369-1401.

    Acemoglu, D., S. Johnson, and J. A. Robinson. 2002. Reversal of Fortune:

    Geography and Institutions in the Making of the Modern World Income Distribu-

    tion. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117(4): 1231-1294.

    Acemoglu, D., S. Johnson, J. A. Robinson and P. Yared. 2005. From

    Education to Democracy?. American Economic Review, 95(2): 44-49.

    Acemoglu, D. and J. A. Robinson. 2006. Economic Origins of Dictatorship

    and Democracy. New York: Cambridge University Press.El Badawi, I. and S. Makdisi 2007. Explaining the democracy decit in the

    22

  • 8/2/2019 Democratic Change in the Arab world by Eric Chaney

    23/35

    Arab World. The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance, 46(5): 813-831.

    Blaydes, L. and E. Chaney. 2011. The Feudal Revolution and Europes Rise: In-

    stitutional Divergence in the Christian and Muslim Worlds before 1500 CE. Mimeo.

    Brckner, M. and A. Ciccone. 2011. Rain and the Democratic Window of

    Opportunity. Econometrica, 79(3): 923-947.

    Campante, F. and D. Chor. 2011. The People Want the Fall of the Regime:

    Schooling, Political Protest, and the Economy. Mimeo.

    Chaney, E. 2011. Revolt on the Nile: Economic Shocks, Religion and Political

    Power. Mimeo.

    Chaney, E. 2012. Separation of Powers and the Medieval Roots of Institutional

    Divergence between Europe and the Islamic Middle East. Mimeo.

    Dell, M. 2010. The Persistent Eects of Perus Mining Mita. Econometrica, 78(6):1863-1903.

    Diamond, L. 2010. Why are there no Arab Democracies. Journal of Democracy,

    21 (1): 93-104.

    Fish, M. S. 2002. Islam and Authoritarianism. World Politics, 55: 4-37.

    Glaeser, E., G. Ponzetto and A. Shleifer. 2007. Why does Democracy need

    Education?. The Journal of Economic Growth, 12: 77-99.

    Haber, S. and V. Menaldo 2010. Rainfall and Democracy. Mimeo.

    Hill, D. R. 1975. The Role of the Camel and the Horse in the Early Arab Con-

    quests. in V.J. Parry and M.E. Yapp (eds.) War, Technology and Society in the

    Middle East, 32(1): 32-43.

    Hourani, A. 1962. Arabic Thought in the Liberal Age. New York: Oxford University

    Press.

    Huntington, S. 1996. The Clash of Civilizations and the Remaking of World Order.

    New York: Simon & Schuster.

    Issawi, I. 1956. Economic and Social Foundations of Democracy in the Middle

    East. International Aairs, 32(1): 27-42.

    Jamal, A. and M. Tessler. 2008. Attitudes in the Arab World. Journal ofDemocracy, 19(1): 97-110.

    23

  • 8/2/2019 Democratic Change in the Arab world by Eric Chaney

    24/35

    Kedourie, E. 1994. Democracy and Arab Political Culture. Portland: Frank Cass

    & Co. LTD.

    Kennedy, H. 2007. The Great Arab Conquests. London: Weidenfeld & Nicolson.

    Khashan, H. 1998. The Arab Worlds Travails: Historys Burden. Middle East

    Quarterly, March: 41-48.

    Kuran, T. 2011. The Long Divergence. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Lako, S. 2004. The Reality of Muslim Exceptionalism. Journal of Democracy,

    15(4): 133-139.

    Lapidus, I. 1984. Muslim Cities in the Later Middle Ages. New York: Cambridge

    University Press.

    Lapidus, I. 1988. A History of Islamic Societies. New York: Cambridge University

    Press.Lewis, B. 1993a. The Arabs in History. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Lewis, B. 1993b. Islam and Liberal Democracy. The Atlantic Monthly, 271(2):

    89-98.

    Malik, A. and B. Awadallah. 2011. The Economics of the Arab Spring.

    Mimeo.

    Michalopoulos, S., A. Naghavi and G. Prarolo. 2010. Trade and Geography

    in the Economic Origins of Islam: Theory and Evidence. Mimeo.

    Montesquieu, C. 1989 [1748]. The Spirit of the Laws. Cambridge: Cambridge

    University Press.

    Noland, M. 2008. Explaining Middle Eastern Political Authoritarianism I: The

    Level of Democracy. Review of Middle East Economics and Finance, 4(1): 1-30.

    Nunn, N. 2008. The Long-Term Eects of Africas Slave Trades. Quarterly Jour-

    nal of Economics, 123(1): 139-176.

    Nunn, N. 2009. The Importance of History for Economic Development. Annual

    Review of Economics, 1: 65-92.

    Nunn, N. and D. Puga. 2012. Ruggedness: The Blessing of Bad Geography in

    Africa. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 94(1): 20-36.Pamuk, S. 2004. Institutional Change and the Longevity of the Ottoman Empire.

    Journal of Interdisciplinary History, 35(2): 225-247.

    24

  • 8/2/2019 Democratic Change in the Arab world by Eric Chaney

    25/35

    Rauch, J. and S. Kostyshak. 2009. The Three Arab Worlds. Journal of

    Economic Perspectives, 23(2): 165-188.

    Ross, M. 2001. Does Oil Hinder Democracy? World Politics, 53: 325-361.

    Sharabi, H. 1988. Neopatriarchy: A Theory of Distorted Change in Arab Society.

    New York: Oxford University Press.

    Stepan, A. and F. Robertson. 2003. An Arab more than Muslim Electoral

    Gap. Journal of Democracy, 14(3): 30-44.

    Al-Sayyid Marsot, A. 1984. Religion or Opposition? Urban Protest Movements

    in Egypt. International Journal of Middle East Studies, 16(4): 541-552.

    Sonbol, A. 2000. The New Mamluks: Egyptian Society and Modern Feudalism.

    Syracuse: Syracuse University Press.

    25

  • 8/2/2019 Democratic Change in the Arab world by Eric Chaney

    26/35

    Figure 1: Arab Conquest and Democracy in 2010More democratic countries are shaded grey and the persistent boundaries

    of the Islamic world in 1100 CE (i.e. Arab conquest) are outlined in black.Democracy data for 2010 are missing for cross-hatched countries.

  • 8/2/2019 Democratic Change in the Arab world by Eric Chaney

    27/35

    0.2.4.6.8StandardizedPolityScore

    1960

    1970

    1980

    1990

    2000

    2010

    ArabConquest

    Non

    Muslim

    Muslim,

    Non

    ArabConquest

    Figure 2: Arab Conquest, Muslim Countries, Developing non-Muslim Countries and Democracy since 1960

  • 8/2/2019 Democratic Change in the Arab world by Eric Chaney

    28/35

    AZE

    MLI

    MRT

    NER

    TCD

    SOM

    MAR

    DZA

    TUN

    L

    BY

    IRN

    T

    UR

    IRQ

    EGY

    SYR

    LBN

    JOR

    SAU

    Y

    EM

    KW

    T BHR

    Q

    ATA

    RE

    OMN

    TKM

    TJK

    UZBP

    AK

    USA

    CAN

    CUB

    HTI

    DOM

    JAM

    TTO

    MEX

    GTM

    HND

    SLV

    NIC

    CRIPAN

    COL

    VEN

    GUY ECU

    PER

    BRA

    BOL

    PRY

    CHL

    ARG

    URY

    GBR

    IRLNLD

    BEL

    FRAC

    HE

    ESP

    PRT

    DEU

    POL

    AUT

    HUN

    CZE

    SVK

    ITAALB

    SRB

    MKD

    HRV

    MON

    SVN

    GRC

    CY

    P

    BGR

    MDA

    ROM

    RUS

    EST

    LVA

    LTU

    UKR

    BLR

    ARMG

    EO

    FINSWE

    NOR

    DNK

    CPV

    GNB

    GNQ

    GMB

    SEN

    BEN

    CIV

    GIN B

    FA

    LBR

    SLE

    GHA

    TGO

    CMR

    NGA

    GAB

    CAF

    COG

    ZAR

    UGA

    KEN

    TZA

    BDI

    RWA

    DJI

    ETH

    ERI

    AGO

    MOZ

    ZMB

    ZWE

    MWI

    ZAF

    NAM

    LSO

    BWA

    SWZ

    MDG

    COM

    MUS

    SDN

    ISR

    KGZ

    KAZ

    CHN

    MNG

    TWN

    PRK

    KOR

    JPN

    IND

    BTN

    BGD

    MMR

    LKA

    NPL

    THA

    KHM

    LAOVNM

    MYS

    SGP

    PHL

    IDN

    AUS

    PNG

    NZL

    SLB

    FJI

    0.2.4.6.81NormalizedPolityScore

    0

    .2

    .4

    .6

    .8

    1

    PercentDesert

    [N=160;b=0.51;se=0.06]

    USA

    CAN

    CUB

    HTI

    DOM

    JAM

    TTO

    MEX

    GTM

    HND

    SLV

    NIC

    CRIPAN

    COL

    VEN

    GUY ECU

    PER

    BRA

    BOL

    PRY

    CHL

    ARG

    URY

    GBR

    IRLNLD

    BEL

    FRAC

    HE

    ESP

    PRT

    DEU

    POL

    AUT

    HUN

    CZE

    SVK

    ITAALB

    SRB

    MKD

    HRV

    MON

    SVN

    GRC

    CY

    P

    BGR

    MDA

    ROM

    RUS

    EST

    LVA

    LTU

    UKR

    BLR

    ARMG

    EO

    FINSWE

    NOR

    DNK

    CPV

    GNB

    GNQ

    GMB

    SEN

    BEN

    CIV

    GIN B

    FA

    LBR

    SLE

    GHA

    TGO

    CMR

    NGA

    GAB

    CAF

    COG

    ZAR

    UGA

    KEN

    TZA

    BDI

    RWA

    DJI

    ETH

    ERI

    AGO

    MOZ

    ZMB

    ZWE

    MWI

    ZAF

    NAM

    LSO

    BWA

    SWZ

    MDG

    COM

    MUS

    SDN

    ISR

    KGZ

    KAZ

    CHN

    MNG

    TWN

    PRK

    KOR

    JPN

    IND

    BTN

    BGD

    MMR

    LKA

    NPL

    THA

    KHM

    LAOVNM

    MYS

    SGP

    PHL

    IDN

    AUS

    PNG

    NZL

    SLB

    FJI

    0.2.4.6.81NormalizedPolityScore

    0

    .2

    .4

    .6

    .8

    1

    PercentDesert

    [N=132;b=0.14;se=0.17]

    Figure 3: Democracy, Arab Conquest and DesertCountries conquered by Arab armies are denoted with grey boxes. The top

    graph includes the entire sample whereas the bottom graph omitscountries conquered by Arab armies.

  • 8/2/2019 Democratic Change in the Arab world by Eric Chaney

    29/35

    024681940

    1960

    1980

    2000

    2020

    ArabConquest

    Non

    Muslim

    Muslim,N

    on

    ArabConquest

    Figure 4: The Evolution of Years of Education since 1950Average years of education in Arab Conquest, Muslim and developing

    non-Muslim countries since 1950.

  • 8/2/2019 Democratic Change in the Arab world by Eric Chaney

    30/35

    Table1:CountryCodes,theArabLeague,ArabConquestandMuslimMajority

    Code

    Country

    Code

    Country

    Code

    Country

    Code

    Country

    AGO

    Angola

    ECU

    Ecuador

    LAO

    Laos

    QAT

    Qatar

    ALB

    Albania

    EGY

    Egypt

    LBN

    Lebanon

    ROM

    Romania

    ARE

    UnitedArabEmirates

    ERI

    Eritrea

    LBR

    Liberia

    RUS

    Russia

    ARG

    Argentina

    ESP

    Spain

    LBY

    Libya

    RWA

    Rwanda

    ARM

    Armenia

    EST

    Estonia

    LKA

    SriLanka

    SAU

    SaudiArabia

    AUS

    Australia

    ETH

    Ethiopia

    LSO

    Lesotho

    SDN

    Sudan

    AUT

    Austria

    FIN

    Finland

    LTU

    Lithuania

    SEN

    Senegal

    AZE

    Azerbaijan

    FJI

    Fiji

    LVA

    Latvia

    SGP

    Singapore

    BDI

    Burundi

    FRA

    France

    MAR

    Morocco

    SLB

    SolomonIslan

    ds

    BEL

    Belgium

    GAB

    Gabon

    MDA

    Moldova

    SLE

    SierraLeone

    BEN

    Benin

    GBR

    UnitedKingdom

    MDG

    Madagascar

    SLV

    ElSalvador

    BFA

    BurkinaFaso

    GEO

    Georgia

    MEX

    Mexico

    SOM

    Somalia

    BGD

    Bangladesh

    GHA

    Ghana

    MKD

    Macedonia

    SRB

    Serbia

    BGR

    Bulgaria

    GIN

    Guinea

    MLI

    Mali

    SVK

    Slovakia

    BHR

    Bahrain

    GMB

    Gambia,The

    MMR

    Myanmar(Burma)

    SVN

    Slovenia

    BLR

    Byelarus

    GNB

    Guinea-Bissau

    MNG

    Mongolia

    SWE

    Sweden

    BOL

    Bolivia

    GNQ

    EquatorialGuinea

    MON

    Montenegro

    SWZ

    Swaziland

    BRA

    Brazil

    GRC

    Greece

    MOZ

    Mozambique

    SYR

    Syria

    BTN

    Bhutan

    GTM

    Guatemala

    MRT

    Mauritania

    TCD

    Chad

    BWA

    Botswana

    GUY

    Guyana

    MUS

    Mauritius

    TGO

    Togo

    CAF

    CentralAfricanRepublic

    HND

    Honduras

    MWI

    Malawi

    THA

    Thailand

    CAN

    Canada

    HRV

    Croatia

    MYS

    Malaysia

    TJK

    Tajikistan

    CHE

    Switzerland

    HTI

    Haiti

    NAM

    Namibia

    TKM

    Turkmenistan

    CHL

    Chile

    HUN

    Hungary

    NER

    Niger

    TTO

    Trinidadand

    Tobago

    CHN

    China

    IDN

    Indonesia

    NGA

    Nigeria

    TUN

    Tunisia

    CIV

    IvoryCoast

    IND

    India

    NIC

    Nicaragua

    TUR

    Turkey

    CMR

    Cameroon

    IRL

    Ireland

    NLD

    Netherlands

    TWN

    Taiwan

    COG

    Congo

    IRN

    Iran

    NOR

    Norway

    TZA

    Tanzania,UnitedRepublicof

    COL

    Colombia

    IRQ

    Iraq

    NPL

    Nepal

    UGA

    Uganda

    COM

    Comoros

    ISR

    Israel

    NZL

    NewZealand

    UKR

    Ukraine

    CPV

    CapeVerde

    ITA

    Italy

    OMN

    Oman

    URY

    Uruguay

    CRI

    CostaRica

    JAM

    Jamaica

    PAK

    Pakistan

    USA

    UnitedStates

    CUB

    Cuba

    JOR

    Jordan

    PAN

    Panama

    UZB

    Uzbekistan

    CYP

    Cyprus

    JPN

    Japan

    PER

    Peru

    VEN

    Venezuela

    CZE

    CzechRepublic

    KAZ

    Kazakhstan

    PHL

    Philippines

    VNM

    Vietnam

    DEU

    Germany

    KEN

    Kenya

    PNG

    PapuaNewGuinea

    YEM

    Yemen

    DJI

    Djibouti

    KGZ

    Kyrgyzstan

    POL

    Poland

    ZAF

    SouthAfrica

    DNK

    Denmark

    KHM

    Cambodia

    PRK

    NorthKorea

    ZAR

    Zaire

    DOM

    DominicanRepublic

    KOR

    SouthKorea

    PRT

    Portugal

    ZMB

    Zambia

    DZA

    Algeria

    KWT

    Kuwait

    PRY

    Paraguay

    ZWE

    Zimbabwe

    Notes:Cou

    ntriesmarkedinboldwerememberso

    ftheArabLeaguein2010.Countries

    markedwiththesymbol

    hadatleasthalf

    oftheirlandmassconqueredbyArabarmies,whilethosewithMuslim

    majoritiesared

    enotedby

    .Underlinedcountriesarenon

    ArabLeagu

    emembersthathadatleasthalfoftheirlandmassconqueredbyArabarm

    ies.CountriesthathaveMuslim

    majo

    rities

    butwereno

    tconqueredbyArabarmiesandarenotmembersoftheArabLeaguein20

    10areinitalics.Seetextfordetails.

  • 8/2/2019 Democratic Change in the Arab world by Eric Chaney

    31/35

    Table2:Demo

    cracy,IslamandArabConquest

    DependentVariable:NormalizedPolityScorein2010

    (1)

    (2)

    (3)

    (4)

    (5)

    (6)

    (7)

    (8)

    Mu

    slim

    -0.3

    1

    -0.2

    0

    -0.0

    6

    0.0

    5

    (0.05)

    (0.07)

    (0.07)

    (0.07)

    [0.10]

    [0.10]

    [0.07]

    [0.07]

    ArabLeague

    -0.2

    1

    -0.0

    4

    -0.0

    1

    -0.2

    3

    -0.0

    5

    -0.0

    2

    -0.0

    5

    (0.09)

    (0.10)

    (0.10)

    (0.09)

    (0.10)

    (0.10)

    (0.10)

    [0.10]

    [0.10]

    [0.11]

    [0.11]

    [0.10]

    [0.10]

    [0.08]

    ArabConquest

    -0.3

    9

    -0.3

    2

    -0.3

    8

    -0.2

    8

    -0.4

    0

    (0.11)

    (0.12)

    (0.11)

    (0.12)

    (0.13)

    [0.11]

    [0.11]

    [0.11]

    [0.12]

    [0.18]

    N

    160

    160

    160

    160

    43

    43

    43

    32

    Co

    ntrols?

    No

    No

    No

    Yes

    No

    No

    Yes

    Yes

    Sample

    World

    World

    World

    World

    Muslim

    Muslim

    Muslim

    80%

    Notes:Thedependentvariableisthepolityscorein2010normalizedtolieonthe

    interval[0,1](highervaluesindicate

    more

    democratic

    institutions).Muslim

    isanindicator

    variableequaltooneifatleasthalfofthecountryspopulationisMuslim.

    Arab

    LeagueisanindicatorvariableequaltooneifthecountrywasamemberoftheArabLeaguein2010.ArabConquesti

    sthe

    percentage

    ofacountryslandmassthatwasper

    sistentlycontrolledbyIslamicEmpiressinceatleast1100CE.Controlsinclude

    continentd

    ummiesandadummyvariableequa

    ltooneifthecountrywasafuel-en

    dowedeconomyasdefinedinRauch

    and

    Kostyshak

    (2009).Thesamplelabeled80%

    limit

    sthesampletocountrieswhoseMuslim

    populationsharesaregreaterthan

    80%.

    Robuststa

    ndarderrorsaregiveninparentheses

    whereasstandarderrorsclusteredby

    regionaregiveninbrackets.Seetex

    tfor

    details.

  • 8/2/2019 Democratic Change in the Arab world by Eric Chaney

    32/35

    Table3:PossibleExplanations:Culture,Conflict,O

    ilandDesert

    NormalizedPolityScorein2010

    (1)

    (2)

    (3)

    (4)

    (5)

    (6)

    (7)

    (8)

    (9)

    ArabConquest

    -0.3

    2

    -0.3

    3

    -0.3

    5

    -0.3

    4

    -0.3

    1

    -0.2

    9

    -0.2

    9

    -0.3

    0

    (0.09)

    (0.15)

    (0.09)

    (0.10)

    (0.10)

    (0.15)

    (0.14)

    (0.14)

    Muslim

    0.0

    5

    0.0

    5

    0.0

    3

    0.0

    5

    0.0

    5

    0.0

    9

    0.0

    5

    0.0

    5

    (0.07)

    (0.11)

    (0.07)

    (0.07)

    (0.07)

    (0.10)

    (0.07)

    (0.07)

    ln(AlcoholConsumption)

    -0.0

    7

    (0.02)

    %Desert

    -0.0

    5

    (0.15)

    ln(Rain)

    2.0

    2

    0.0

    1

    (1.97)

    (0.04)

    [ln(Rain)]2

    -0.3

    1

    (0.34)

    [ln(Rain)]3

    0.0

    2

    (0.02)

    N

    160

    139

    132

    43

    155

    147

    160

    158

    158

    Controls?

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Sample

    World

    Non-

    Non-

    Muslim

    Non-

    Non-

    World

    World

    World

    Arab

    Conquest

    Conflict

    Oil

    Notes:ArabConquestisthepercentageofacountryslandmassthatwaspersistentlycontrolledbyIslamicEmpiressin

    ceat

    least1100

    CE.Muslim

    isanindicatorvariable

    equaltooneifatleasthalfofthecountryspopulationisMuslim.ln(Alcohol

    Consumpti

    on)isthelogarithm

    ofaverageper-capitaalcoholconsumption.%Desert

    isthepercentageofacountrysland

    mass

    thatiscoveredbydesertterrain.ln(Rain)isthelogarithm

    ofacountrysaveragerainfall.Controlsincludecontinentdum

    mies

    andadum

    myvariableequaltooneifthecountrywasafuel-endowedeconomyasdefinedinRauchandKostyshak(2009).

    The

    Non-Arab

    sampleomitsmembersoftheArabL

    eague,theNon-Conquestsampleom

    itsArab-conquestcountries,theMuslim

    samplerestrictstheanalysistocountrieswithatleast50%

    Muslim

    populationshares,theNon-ConflictsampleomitsEgypt,

    Israel,Jord

    an,LebanonandSyriaandtheNon-

    Oilsampleomitsthecountriesdefine

    dasfuel-endowedinRauchandKosty

    shak

    (2009).

  • 8/2/2019 Democratic Change in the Arab world by Eric Chaney

    33/35

    Table 4: IV Regressions: The Impact of Arab Conquest on Demo-cratic Outcomes in 2010

    (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

    Panel A: Two-Stage Least SquaresArab Conquest -0.56 -0.36 -0.35 -0.51 -0.47 -0.59

    (0.30) (0.14) (0.14) (0.16) (0.12) (0.10)

    Muslim 0.16 0.07 0.07(0.15) (0.09) (0.09)

    Panel B: First-Stage for Arab ConquestMecca -0.46 -1.13

    (0.12) (0.28)

    %Desert 0.67 0.85(0.11) (0.15)

    ln(Rainfall) -0.17 -0.29(0.02) (0.03)

    Panel C: Ordinary Least SquaresArab Conquest -0.32 -0.32 -0.32 -0.29 -0.29 -0.29

    (0.09) (0.07) ((0.07)) (0.10) (0.10) (0.10)

    Muslim 0.05 0.05 0.05(0.07) (0.07) (0.07)

    Panel D: Overidentification Tests

    [p-value] [0.50] [0.63] [0.82] [0.65]

    N 160 160 158 43 43 43

    Sample World World World Muslim Muslim M uslim

    Notes: The dependent variable in panels A and C is the polity score in 2010 normal-ized to lie on the interval [0,1] (higher values indicate more democratic institutions).The dependent variable in panel B is Arab Conquest: the percentage of a countryslandmass that was persistently controlled by Islamic Empires since at least 1100 CE.Muslim is an indicator variable equal to one if at least half of the countrys popula-tion is Muslim. Mecca is the distance of the countrys centroid to Mecca measuredin tens of thousands of kilometers. %Desert is the percent of a countrys landmassthat is covered by desert terrain. Arab League is an indicator variable equal to one ifthe country was a member of the Arab League in 2010. ln(Rainfall) is the logarithm

    of average annual rainfall in the country. Controls include country dummies and anindicator equal to one if the country was a fuel-endowed economy as defined in Rauchand Kostyshak (2009). Robust standard errors are presented in parentheses.

  • 8/2/2019 Democratic Change in the Arab world by Eric Chaney

    34/35

    Table 5: Governments Share of GDP, Access to Credit, TradeUnions and Arab Conquest

    (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9)

    Govt. Share of GDP Access to Credit Trade UnionsArab Conquest 7.37 9.26 4.53 -0.29 -0.21 -0.24 -0.29 -0.28 -0.35

    (2.73) (3.29) (3.68) (0.10) (0.09) (0.10) (0.13) (0.12) (0.18)Muslim -5.20 -5.46 -5.89 -0.02 -0.03 -0.00 0.21 0.21 0.20

    (2.55) (2.58) (2.47) (0.08) (0.08) (0.08) (0.11) (0.11) (0.10)

    Fuel-Endowed 7.42 8.28 6.16 0.02 0.07 0.04 0.00 0.01 -0.02(3.50) (3.93) (3.24) (0.07) (0.07) (0.08) (0.04) (0.05) (0.05)

    Democracy 5.83 0.28 0.03(5.56) (0.08) (0.07)

    Arab League 5.48 -0.09 0.12(3.50) (0.07) (0.16)

    N 158 158 158 152 152 152 160 160 160

    Notes: The dependent variable in columns (1)-(3) is 100 times the governments share

    of GDP in 2011. In columns (4)-(6) the dependent variable is the World Banksstrength of legal rights index normalized to lie on the interval [0,1] (higher valuesindicate legal systems that greater facilitate access to credit). In columns (7)-(9) thedependent variable is the number of trade unions normalized by GDP measured inbillions of dollars. Arab Conquest is the percentage of a countrys landmass thatwas persistently controlled by Islamic Empires since at least 1100 CE. Muslim is anindicator variable equal to one if at least half of the countrys population is Muslim.Fuel-Endowed is an indicator variable equal to one if the country is a fuel-endowedeconomy as defined in Rauch and Kostyshak (2009). Democracy is the countrys polityscore normalized to lie on the interval [0,1]. Arab League is an indicator variable equalto one if the country was a member of the Arab League in 2010. All regressions includecontinent dummies. Robust standard errors are presented in parentheses.

  • 8/2/2019 Democratic Change in the Arab world by Eric Chaney

    35/35

    Table6:SupportfortheSharia,Well-BeingandtheArabSpring

    (1)

    (

    2)

    (3)

    (4

    )

    Sharia

    Well-Be

    ing(2009)

    Well-Being(2010)

    Well-Being(2011)

    Somalia

    75.37

    18.25

    12.47

    6.51

    (1.41)

    (0

    .89)

    (0.76)

    (0.81)

    SaudiArabia

    71.62

    37.73

    44.56

    51.57

    (1.38)

    (1

    .15)

    (1.19)

    (1.67)

    Egypt

    71.15

    13.80

    11.64

    9.13

    (0.77)

    (0

    .80)

    (0.80)

    (0.73)

    Qatar

    69.87

    48.87

    55.70

    51.35

    (1.51)

    (1

    .25)

    (1.77)

    (1.68)

    Yemen

    66.07

    17.81

    13.04

    10.22

    (1.12)

    (0

    .90)

    (0.81)

    (1.09)

    Jordan

    64.10

    34.50

    30.43

    27.12

    (0.93)

    (1

    .11)

    (1.11)

    (1.50)

    UAE

    56.79

    52.30

    56.27

    60.94

    (1.63)

    (1

    .18)

    (1.18)

    (1.64)

    Palestine

    51.27

    13.90

    16.25

    16.26

    (0.74)

    (0

    .82)

    (0.88)

    (1.26)

    Djibouti

    47.37

    11.59

    18.97

    14.56

    (1.64)

    (0

    .74)

    (1.31)

    (1.19)

    Kuwait

    45.99

    46.29

    47.03

    50.70

    (1.64)

    (1

    .17)

    (1.15)

    (1.64)

    Comoros

    42.13

    3

    .19

    4.32

    4.46

    (1.63)

    (0

    .41)

    (0.48)

    (0.68)

    Libya

    41.93

    24.11

    14.17

    (1.25)

    (1

    .62)

    (1.18)

    Algeria

    37.51

    21.97

    20.99

    20.00

    (1.10)

    (0

    .96)

    (0.94)

    (1.31)

    Mauritania

    36.19

    6

    .99

    13.35

    18.11

    (1.12)

    (0

    .63)

    (0.79)

    (1.28)

    Iraq

    34.98

    9

    .80

    13.70

    14.15

    (1.60)

    (0

    .73)

    (0.84)

    (1.21)

    Morocco

    32.58

    13.80

    11.99

    16.52

    (1.54)

    (0

    .80)

    (0.75)

    (1.23)

    Syria

    29.49

    22.64

    6.27

    2.98

    (1.14)

    (1

    .02)

    (0.61)

    (0.56)

    Tunisia

    25.51

    16.32

    14.23

    17.12

    (1.01)

    (0

    .87)

    (0.80)

    (1.24)

    Sudan

    21.00

    10.46

    11.05

    10.53

    (1.36)

    (0

    .71)

    (0.73)

    (1.01)

    Lebanon

    13.94

    24.39

    22.76

    18.63

    (0.58)

    (1

    .05)

    (1.02)

    (1.33)

    Bahrain

    38.67

    28.69

    8.19

    (1

    .14)

    (1.06)

    (0.97)

    Oman

    52.17

    (1.67)

    Turkey

    10.05

    13.27

    16.57

    (0.55)

    (1

    .13)

    (1.25)

    Notes:Column(1)providetheaverageproportion

    ofindividualsbetween2005and201

    1answeringthatShariamustbethe

    only

    sourceofleg

    islationinresponsetothequestion

    ShariaisanArabicwordwhichmea

    nsIslamsreligiousprinciples.Ingeneral,

    whichofthesestatementscomesclosesttoyourow

    npointofview?Incolumns(2)-(4)

    Ipresenttheproportionofindividuals

    who

    wereself-rep

    ortedlythriving(i.e.doingwell)in

    theyears2009,2010and2011respectively.Countriesmarkedinboldwitnessed

    uprisingsin

    2011.Robuststandarderrorsarepres

    entedinparentheses.