28
Deep Integration: Free trade agreements heterogeneity and its impact on bilateral trade Séminaire DIAL Jaime Ahcar Olmos Under the supervision of : Jean-Marc Siroën PSL Université Paris-Dauphine Laboratoire LEDa-DIAL 24 avril, 2014 1 Contents 1) Introduction 2) Methodology and Data 3) Results 4) Conclusions 5) References

Deep Integration: Free trade agreements heterogeneity and its impact on bilateral trade Séminaire DIAL Jaime Ahcar Olmos Under the supervision of : Jean-Marc

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

1

 Deep Integration: 

Free trade agreements heterogeneity and its impact on bilateral trade

Séminaire DIAL 

Jaime Ahcar OlmosUnder the supervision of :

Jean-Marc Siroën

PSL Université Paris-Dauphine Laboratoire LEDa-DIAL

24 avril, 2014

Contents1) Introduction2) Methodology and Data3) Results4) Conclusions 5) References

2

Introduction

• International trade economists have apparently successfully dealt with the question : does free trade agreements increase trade flows?

Rose (2004), Baier & Bergstrand (2007), Martinez et al. (2009)

• This has been done neglecting thorny issues like heterogeneity and the concept of deep integration.

3

Introduction : Questions

• So we now try to answer new questions :• Are all free trade agreements equal? What happens

if not ?• Does a deeper free trade agreement really increase

trade more than a shallow agreement ?• What would be a good indicator of deep integration

like ?• Are other provisions related to trade but out of the

traditional WTO framework of negotiation really important to expand trade ?

4

Introduction : Importance

• Preferential Trade Agreements PTA heterogeneity little explored

• Indicators of heterogeneity• Implications for the interpretation of PTA

coefficients• Implications for our understanding of the limits

of trade liberalization

5

Literature review

• Bourgeois, Dawar & Evnenett (2007). A Comparative Analysis of Selected Provisions in Free Trade Agreements.

• Magee (2008) controlled for some levels of trade integration.

• Vicard (2009) on the depth of the agreements found that their trade creation effect does not statistically differ according to the depth of the RTA.

• Vicard, V (2011) By using interactions terms found that large, similar and close countriesn benefit more from RTA. This approach doesn’t care about their dose or their design.

6

Literature Review

• Horn, Mavroidis & Sapir (2010) and non-traditional WTO provisions in the analysis and explored legal enforcement effects, but ramained on the descriptive approach.

• Orefice & Rocha (2013) carried out empirical analysis from Horn et al. observarions and found positive evidence.

• Dür, Baccini & Elsig (2014) enlarged the database and introduced latent trade analysis.

7

Database

• Two different classification of agreements databases:

1) WTO (2011) Research division for the World Trade Report 2) Design of Trade Agreements DESTA-WTI (2014)

Then, we introduce this information in our gravity model unbalanced panel data set which encompasses 153 countries and 613.030 bilateral trade flows from 1980 to 2012.

8

Databases and methodology :

• Following (Horn et al. 2010) approach:• 1) WTO+ provisions: topics under the competence of

the WTO agreements. • 2) WTO-X provisions: topics outside the current

mandate of the WTO.”• This database is exploited by Orefice & Roche (2013)• Their regressions account for 66 PTA from 1980–

2007. We include in our calculations 103 PTA including agreements for Peru & Colombia from 1980-2012.

9

Database variables

Source: Orefice & Rocha (2013), Horn et al. (2010). WTO ( 2011) Research division for the World Trade Report

Anti-dumping Countervailing Measures

GATS General Agreement on Trade in Services

Public Procurement Sanitary and Phytosanitary MeasuresState Aid (Subventions)State Trading Enterprises Technical Barriers to Trade Trade Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights TRIPs TRIMs Trade-Related Investment Measures

WTO+ Policy Areas Negociated in PTAs

10

Database variables

Source: Orefice & Rocha (2013), Horn et al. (2010). WTO ( 2011) Research division for the World Trade Report

Agriculture Innovation policies

Anti-corruption Investment measures

Approximation of Legislation IPR

Audiovisual Labour market regulation

Competition policy Mining

Consumer protection Money laundering

Cultural cooperation Movement of capital

Data protection Nuclear safety

Economic policy dialogue Political dialogue

Education and training Public administration

Energy Regional cooperation

Environmental laws Research and technology

Financial assistance SMEs

Health Social matters

Human rights Statistics

Illegal immigration Taxation

Illicit drugs Terrorism

Industrial cooperation Visa and asylum

Information society

WTO-X Provisions Negociated in PTAs

11

Methodology

• Probit approach• We put forward two main kinds of indicators

to try to capture deep integration.• They depend on a set of variables (provisions)

that characterize PTA texts. • 1) Additive indicators• 2) Distilled indicators taken from PCA related

methodologies.

12

Methodology Contributions : Additive indicators

• Does an additive indicator tell us something about the depth of the agreement?

• Reasonably yes. One can expect that more comprehensive agreements are deeper.

• Isn’t the magnitude of the reduction on tariffs the main indicator of depth? Maybe not, as nontariff barriers can play a major role to block trade.

Jean-Marc
pas clair

13

Methodology Contributions : Distilled indicators

• We calculate a Multiple Correspondence Analysis MCA indicator for deep integration:

• MCA is a technique that can be applied to obtain an indicator that summarizes in just one dimension the variability of a set of variables related with the content and design of PTA, and then with the depth of the integration.

14

Limits of the analysis

• “Europe’s single market is probably the best example globally of successful deep integration” Claar S. & Nölke A. (2010).

• Nevertheless, because of methodology consistency requirements, Dür et al. (2014) additive indicator give UE 1992 single market agreement a 5 while Colombia - USA receive a 7

• Orefice & Rocha gives 6-11 to EU27 but 9-27 to EU-Chile.• Enforceability of the agreements. Too subjective, it

implies going into the nuances of the language in PTA texts.

15

Methodological Limits

• Due to the large size of our data set, we can not completely control for multilateral resistance in all specifications. Anderson and Van Wincoop (2003); Baldwin & Taglioni (2006)

• We try to minimize this setback by introducing time fixed effects and time invariant fixed effects for importers and exporters countries.

16

Theoretical Model

xij is export from region i to region j, σ is the elasticity of substitution between all goods, tij is a trade cost factor between i and j; yi and yj are GDP in region i and region j; yW is world nominal income; k is a constant, (1 – σ) and (1 – σ)ρ are coefficients.

17

Probit model with single EV for the median rta coeffient on some WTO+ provisions

brtamed brtamed brtamed brtamed brtamed brtamed brtamed brtamed brtamed

sps 0.071(0.252)

tbt 0.206(0.282)

ste -0.268(0.248)

ad 0.096(0.319)

cvm 0.077(0.275)

publicprocurement -0.226(0.250)

trims -0.074(0.247)

gats -0.219(0.273)

trips -0.132(0.253)

Constant -0.031 -0.140 0.145 -0.066 -0.043 0.140 0.050 0.168 0.092(0.196) (0.242) (0.174) (0.288) (0.233) (0.187) (0.177) (0.230) (0.196)

Observations 103 103 103 103 103 103 103 103 103

r2_p 0.000555 0.00375 0.00823 0.000634 0.000552 0.00576 0.000625 0.00454 0.00192

Standard errors in parentheses*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1

(1)

18

Probit model with single EV for the median rta coeffieient on WTO-X provisions

brtamed brtamed brtamed

consumerprotection -0.599*(0.330)

environmentallaws -0.520**(0.252)

labourmarketregulation -0.496*(0.276)

Constant 0.120 0.244 0.155(0.137) (0.168) (0.147)

Observations 103 103 103r2_p 0.0238 0.0302 0.0228

Standard errors in parentheses*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1

19

Results

• On a probit model regression with single EV. No evidence that the presence of any particular provision under WTO+ would increase trade above the median level, which PTAs are supposed to do.

• Only 3 out of 36 WTO-X provisions show significant estimators : environmental laws, labour market regulation and consumer protection. All three show a negative coefficient.

• It could open the door to the possibility of PTA that deters trade rather than promote it.

20

Results

• Robustness. Possible bias in the estimation of the individual PTA coefficients and colinearity between provisions.

• A better way could be capture the whole variability of the provisions in just one indicator.

• This indicator would give us a clue about the depth of the integration.

21

Specification to estimate with PPML : Control for large zero value flow observations in GM data sets and gives consistent estimates.

(Silva & Tenreyro, 2006; 2011)

22

Deep integration: Latent trait analysis (Rasch) indicator Dur and al (2014) and additive indicator on levels and logs. DESTA.

xij xij xij xij

dp_D_ra0 0.129***

(0.006)

lndp_D_ra00001 0.027***(0.001)

deep_DE_ad 0.085***(0.003)

ln_dp_d_ad 0.033***(0.001)

lnPIBi 0.730*** 0.729*** 0.746*** 0.729***(0.024) (0.024) (0.024) (0.024)

lnPIBj 0.647*** 0.645*** 0.662*** 0.642***(0.023) (0.023) (0.023) (0.022)

lndist -0.803*** -0.792*** -0.775*** -0.759***(0.009) (0.009) (0.009) (0.009)

Constant -6.577*** -5.617*** -6.215*** -5.424***

(0.864) (0.863) (0.845) (0.850)

Observations 587,654 587,654 587,654 587,654

R-squared 0.891 0.892 0.900 0.900

Exporter FE YES YES YES YES

Importer FE YES YES YES YES

Country-pair FE NO NO NO NO

Time FE YES YES YES YES

Robust standard errors in parentheses *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1

23

Deep Integration: Additive indicators and its log from WTO+ and WTO-X. PPML estimator. 

xij xij xij xij

ad_ch1 0.058***(0.002)

lnad_ch00001 0.036***(0.001)

ad_x1 0.023***(0.001)

lnad_x100001 0.035***(0.001)

lnPIBi 0.765*** 0.734*** 0.756*** 0.738***(0.024) (0.024) (0.024) (0.024)

lnPIBj 0.679*** 0.647*** 0.671*** 0.650***(0.023) (0.023) (0.024) (0.023)

lndist -0.784*** -0.746*** -0.819*** -0.747***(0.009) (0.009) (0.008) (0.009)

Constant -5.860*** -5.607*** -5.810*** -5.623***(0.886) (0.889) (0.904) (0.886)

Observations 572,657 572,657 575,383 575,383

R-squared 0.900 0.903 0.894 0.903

Exporter FE YES YES YES YES

Importer FE YES YES YES YES

Country-pair FE NO NO NO NO

Time FE YES YES YES YES

Time Varying Exporter FE NO NO NO NO

Time Varying Importer FE NO NO NO NO

Robust standard errors in parentheses *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1

24

Conclusions

• We are now more aware that not all PTA are equal. This would imply that much of previous estimations on the average effect of PTA on trade could be biased.

• Through different indicators we have confirmed that deeper PTAs increase trade more than shallow ones. However these indicators also present limits to their interpretation. A better definition of deep integration continues to be a challenge.

25

Conclusions

• A better deep integration indicator should show EC model as the deepest. Meanwhile, these imperfect indicators present enough power to give us sufficient clues about the direction of the impact of heterogeneity of the agreements on trade.

• Other provisions out of the traditional WTO scope present significant positive impact on trade. Yet, some of them could individually bear a negative impact.

• More research is needed specially to try to identify which provisions or combination of provisions presents a higher impact.

26

Data Set : Sources

PTA provisionas database : WTO ( 2011) Research division for the World Trade Report.http://www.wto.org/english/res_e/publications_e/wtr11_dataset_e.htm

World Trade Institute (2014) . The Design of trade agreements database DESTA.

Bilateral Exports: International Monetary Fund (IMF) Direction of Trade Statistics Database DOTS (2013). Current GDP and population: World Development Indicators (WDI) database, World Bank, (2013) Area, Island and Landlocked, constructed by the author based on the World Factbook from the Central Intelligence Agency of the United States of America (CIA) Weighted distance, contiguity, col45 and comlang_eth9 : CEPII (2013): Head, K., Mayer, T. & Ries, J. (2010), Gravity dataset, obs. till 2006. Regional Trade Agreements: constructed by the author, based on the Regional Trade Agreements Information System (RTA-IS), World Trade Organization WTO (2013)

GATT membership: constructed by the author based on the World Trade Organization WTO information (2013).

CEPII: Head, K., Mayer, T. & Ries, J. (2010), Gravity dataset, obs. Till 2006.

OCDE membership: constructed by the author based on the Organisation de coopération et de développement économiques OCDE (2013) information.

27

References• Horn, H., Mavroidis, P. C. and Sapir, A. (2010), “Beyond the WTO? an anatomy of EU and US preferential trade agreements”, The

World Economy 33(11): 1565-1588• Bourgeois, J., K. Dawar and S.J. evenett. 2007. A Comparative Analysis of Selected Provisions in Free Trade Agreements, Study

commissioned by DG Trade, Brussels: European Commission, mimeo• Claar S. & Nölke A. (2010) Cross-Border Cooperation: Deep integration. http://www.dandc.eu/en/article/even-though-deep-

integration-could-serve-developing-countries-strategy-politically• Dür, A., Baccini, L.& Elsig, M. (2014) The Design of International Trade Agreements: Introducing a New Dataset. The Review of

International Organizations.• Orefice & Rocha (2013) Deep Integration and Production Networks: An Empirical Analysis. The World Economy. John Wiley &

Sons Ltd• Le Roux, B. and H. Rouanet (2010). Multiple Correspondence Analysis. Series Quantitative Applications in Social Sciences. 163.

Sage Publications.• Anderson, J. E. (1979) “A Theoretical Foundation for the Gravity Equation,” American Economic Review 69, 106-16.• Anderson, J & Wincoop, E. (2003) “Gravity with Gravitas: A Solution to the Border Puzzle” American Economic Review, 93 (1), p

170 – 193.• Baier, S & Bergstrand, J. (2007) Do free trade agreements actually increase members’ international trade? Journal of

International Economics. 71, 72-95. • Baldwin, R. & D. Taglioni (2006). ¨Gravity for Dummies and Dummies for gravity equations¨ NBER working paper No.12516,

National Bureau of Economics Research, Inc.• Breusch, T. S., & Pagan, A. R. (1980). The Lagrange multiplier test and its applications to model specification in econometrics.

Review of Economic Studies, 47, 239−253.• Cipollina, M. & Pietrovito, F. (2011) The trade impact of European Union Preferential Policies: A Meta-Analysis if the Literature.

In De Benedictis, L. and Salvatini, L. (2011) The trade impact of European Union Preferential Policies. An Analysis Throug Gravity Models. Springer. 91-109.

• Cipollina, M. & Salvatici, L. (2011) Trade Impact of European Union Preferences. Chp. 6, in: De Benedictis, L. and Salvatini, L. (2011) The trade impact of European Union Preferential Policies. An Analysis Throug Gravity Models. Springer. 111-125

• De Benedictis, L & Vicarelli, C. (2005) Trade Potentials in Gravity Panel Data Models. The B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis & Policy. Topics in Economic Analysis & Policy. V. 5, No. 1.

• De Benedictis, L. and Salvatini, L. (2011) The trade impact of European Union Preferential Policies. An Analysis Throug Gravity Models. Springer.

• Dixit, A. & Stiglitz, J. (1977) Monopolisitic competition and Optimum Product Diversity. American Ecoconomic Review. 67, p 297 – 308.

• Duc, C. Lavallée, E., & Siroën, J-M. (2008/1) The Gravity of Institutions. Economie Internationale. CEPII. No. 113, p 95 -113• Eicher, T and Henn, C. (2011) In Search of WTO trade effects: Preferential trade agreements promote trade strongly, but

unevenly. Journal of International Economics. 83, p 137-153.• Feenstra, R. (2004a) “Border Effects and the Gravity Equation: Consistent Methods for Estimation. Scottish Journal of Political

Economy. 49 (5) p. 491 – 506.

28

References

• Feenstra, R. (2004b) Advanced International Trade. Theory and Evidence. Chap. 5. Increasing Returns and the gravity equation. Princeton University Press. 137 -173.

• Hausman, J. (1978) Specification Tests in Econometrics. Econometrica, Vol. 46, No. 6 (Nov., 1978), pp. 1251-1271. Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/1913827.

• Head, K. Mayer, T., & Ries, J. (2010) The Erosion of colonial linkages after Independence. Journal of International Economics. 81, 1-14.

• Krugman, P. (1979) “Incresing Rerturns, Monopolistic Competition, and International Trade”, Journal of International Economics, 9, pp. 469-479.

• Liu, X., Burridge P., and Sinclair, P. (2002) Relationships between economic growth, foreign direct investment and trade: evidence from China. Applied Economics, 2002, 34, 1433-1440.

• McCallum, J. (1995) "National Borders Matter: Canada-U.S. Regional Trade Patterns."American Economic Review, 85(3), pp. 615-23.

• Martínez-Zarzosoa, I. & Nowak-Lehmann, F. & Horsewood, N. (2009) Are regional trading agreements beneficial? Static and dynamic panel gravity models. North American Journal of Economics and Finance 20 46–65.

• Markusen, J. (2002) Multinational firms and the theory of international trade. Cambridge Etats-Unis : MIT Press.

• Muchielli, J-L. et Mayer, T. (2011) Economie International. Dalloz. 2e Edition. Paris.

• Rose, A (2004) Do we really know that the WTO increases trade? American Economic Review 13 (4), 682–698. • Rose, A. (2005) Which international institutions promote trade? Review of International Economics 13 (4), 682–698. • Rose, A., & Engel, C., (2002) Currency Unions and International Integration, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Blackwell Publishing, vol. 34(4), pp. 1067-89. • Santos Silva, J. & Tenreyro, S. (2006) The log of gravity, The Review of Economics and Statistics, 88, 641-58.

• Santos Silva, J. & Tenreyro, S. (2011) Further simulation evidence on the performance of the Poisson pseudo-maximum likelihood estimator. Economics Letters. Volume 112, Issue 2, August 2011, Pages 220–222.

• Timbergen, J. (1962) Shaping the World Economy: Suggestions for an International Economic Policy, New York : Twentieth Century Fund.

• Trefler, D. (1993) Trade liberalization and the theory of endogenous protection: an econometric study of U.S. import policy. Journal of Political Economy. 101 (1), 138–160.

• Subramanian, A., Wei, S. (2007) The WTO promotes trade strongly, but unevenly. Journal of International Economics 72 (1), 151–175.