69
Decision-making context Karl M. Rich, Lab 863 s.r.o. & Norwegian University of Life Sciences Jarkko K. Niemi, Natural Resources Institute Finland (Luke) This presentation was developed within the frame of the NEAT project, funded with support from the European Commission under the Lifelong Learning Programme (Grant no. 527 855). Please attribute the NEAT network with a link to www.neat-network.eu . Except where otherwise noted, this presentation is licensed under a

Decision-making context Karl M. Rich, Lab 863 s.r.o. & Norwegian University of Life Sciences Jarkko K. Niemi, Natural Resources Institute Finland (Luke)

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Decision-making context Karl M. Rich, Lab 863 s.r.o. & Norwegian University of Life Sciences Jarkko K. Niemi, Natural Resources Institute Finland (Luke)

Decision-making context

Karl M. Rich, Lab 863 s.r.o. & Norwegian University of Life Sciences

Jarkko K. Niemi, Natural Resources Institute Finland (Luke)

This presentation was developed within the frame of the NEAT project, funded with support from the European Commission under the Lifelong Learning Programme (Grant no. 527 855). Please attribute the NEAT network with a link to www.neat-network.eu. Except where otherwise noted, this presentation is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-ShareAlike 4.0 International License.

Page 2: Decision-making context Karl M. Rich, Lab 863 s.r.o. & Norwegian University of Life Sciences Jarkko K. Niemi, Natural Resources Institute Finland (Luke)

Chapter 4

Leaning objectives for this module

To understand the decision-making context

How is decision-making described in economics? Which factors determine decisions by different stakeholders? How do interactions between stakeholders influence decisions?

To be able to identify how economics analyses decisions

2

Page 3: Decision-making context Karl M. Rich, Lab 863 s.r.o. & Norwegian University of Life Sciences Jarkko K. Niemi, Natural Resources Institute Finland (Luke)

1. Introduction

Economics focuses on people and their decision-making

3

Page 4: Decision-making context Karl M. Rich, Lab 863 s.r.o. & Norwegian University of Life Sciences Jarkko K. Niemi, Natural Resources Institute Finland (Luke)

Chapter 4

Introduction

Economics is the study of how scarce resources are or should be allocated (Black 1997, A dictionary of economics)

Decisions are needed to allocate resources

Economics highlights how and why people make choices under conditions of scarcity and the results of such choices on society.

Economics is about TRADEOFFS: Our needs are endless, but decisions to satisfy these needs are constrained by resource availability

Economics is about behavior and incentives, and how those influence choice

4

Page 5: Decision-making context Karl M. Rich, Lab 863 s.r.o. & Norwegian University of Life Sciences Jarkko K. Niemi, Natural Resources Institute Finland (Luke)

Chapter 4

There are different economic actors (see lesson 1)

How do we study “how resources should be allocated”?

Who are the actors – who make the decisions? What do these actors care about – i.e. how/why do they value (see

previous lectures) different things? Which options are there? Which constraints are there?

How do we do that in the context of animal health?

Who are the actors, what are their values and goals, what can or cannot be chosen by them and why?

5

Page 6: Decision-making context Karl M. Rich, Lab 863 s.r.o. & Norwegian University of Life Sciences Jarkko K. Niemi, Natural Resources Institute Finland (Luke)

Chapter 4

An example

Your car needs to be taken for service. Spend a few minutes by discussing in groups

Which actors are there in the process of getting the service? From which options (services, service providers) can you choose? How do you value different characteristics of service? When you make your choice, which factors constrain your choice?

Next, think of yourself as a service provider (i.e. garage owner)

What kind of goals could you have as an entrepreneur? Which factors affect what you can or cannot offer to a customer coming

to your garage?

6

Page 7: Decision-making context Karl M. Rich, Lab 863 s.r.o. & Norwegian University of Life Sciences Jarkko K. Niemi, Natural Resources Institute Finland (Luke)

Chapter 4

Scarcity, the basic economic problem

People have endless needs but only limited (scarce) resources

Because of scarcity, decisions must be made to allocate resources efficiently

How does a person determine efficiency?

Focus on consuming goods which can provide the highest value per resource (e.g. value for money)

7

Page 8: Decision-making context Karl M. Rich, Lab 863 s.r.o. & Norwegian University of Life Sciences Jarkko K. Niemi, Natural Resources Institute Finland (Luke)

Chapter 4

Some key concepts – review from the previous lessons

Utility refers to how much happiness or satisfaction a person gets from consuming a set of goods

It is an abstract concept: there are no ”utility meters”! Utility is a way of representing preferences and tradeoffs It allows us to combine the happiness obtained by consuming different

goods such as apples and bananas To fulfill our needs, we make decisions on which needs are satisified

and which are not ( tradeoffs).

Opportunity cost is the value of the second-best alternative that has to be given up to choose the first-best alternative

8

Page 9: Decision-making context Karl M. Rich, Lab 863 s.r.o. & Norwegian University of Life Sciences Jarkko K. Niemi, Natural Resources Institute Finland (Luke)

Chapter 4

Preferences – review

9

Less happiness More happiness

10 €/kg

Preferences refer to the ordering of alternatives. For example:

Do you like more apples than bananas? Do you like more red than green apples? Do you like more beef than pork? Do you like more beef at €8 per kg than pork at €2 per kg?

Preferences are based on the amount of happiness that a person can get from consuming a good. An example of someone’s preferences

8 €/kg 2 €/kg

Page 10: Decision-making context Karl M. Rich, Lab 863 s.r.o. & Norwegian University of Life Sciences Jarkko K. Niemi, Natural Resources Institute Finland (Luke)

Chapter 4

Factors affecting preferences - review

Tastes

Cultural factors, religion, norms, habits (e.g. seasonal demand for certain goods)

Biological factors: e.g. age, gender, physical characteristics

Social factors: e.g. education, occupation, marital status (e.g. singles and married persons have different needs)

Other factors

10

Page 11: Decision-making context Karl M. Rich, Lab 863 s.r.o. & Norwegian University of Life Sciences Jarkko K. Niemi, Natural Resources Institute Finland (Luke)

Chapter 4

An example of a tradeoff: work and leisure

11

Wag

e r

ate

€/h

Hours worked

The more you work, the higher you value leisure

Higher compensation is required for you to exchange one hour of leisure to an additional hour of working

Working at weekends may carry a higher cost (opportunity cost) than working during office days because you have to give up more valuable time, such as time with your family or friends

Page 12: Decision-making context Karl M. Rich, Lab 863 s.r.o. & Norwegian University of Life Sciences Jarkko K. Niemi, Natural Resources Institute Finland (Luke)

2. The maximisation problem

Economic actors strive for a goal

Profit maximisation

In sections 2 and 3 we will consider two groups (producers and consumers) which have different decision-making contexts

12

Page 13: Decision-making context Karl M. Rich, Lab 863 s.r.o. & Norwegian University of Life Sciences Jarkko K. Niemi, Natural Resources Institute Finland (Luke)

Chapter 4

Economic actors can have different objectives

Important: your client may have different goals than you!

Maximise health

Minimise costs, e.g. if only a limited quantity can be produced

Maximise profit (=revenues minus costs)

Maximising production or health may not maximise profit!

Maximise utility, i.e. happiness that one can get by consuming goods, given their resources (e.g. income) available to get the goods

To maximise utility, one makes tradeoffs between goods (e.g. give up a holiday in Spain to be able to spend a holiday in Italy)

Tradeoffs are made because resources are scarce

13

Page 14: Decision-making context Karl M. Rich, Lab 863 s.r.o. & Norwegian University of Life Sciences Jarkko K. Niemi, Natural Resources Institute Finland (Luke)

Chapter 4

Veterinarians and clients affect each other’s business

Recall lesson 3: A vet’s effort to improve animal health can be regarded as an input

It is a cost to the clientIt can cause changes in the client’s outputs and revenues Hence the question: Is the vet able to increase a client’s revenues

by more than the costs of the vet’s activity? Note that the vet’s fee and prescribed medicine can be only a part

of the cost. The advice of a vet can affect the consumption of other inputs as well!

Think how much value-added your advice can provide to the client?

14

Page 15: Decision-making context Karl M. Rich, Lab 863 s.r.o. & Norwegian University of Life Sciences Jarkko K. Niemi, Natural Resources Institute Finland (Luke)

Chapter 4

Firms operate in the market

Most people enter business to make profit

To make profit, a firm must be able to sell its products, while the costs (monetary + non-monetary) of producing the good must be less than the sale price

Usually we assume that markets are perfectly competitive

There are many buyers and sellers which sell standardized products Buyers and sellers know which opportunities there are Firms are typically price takers, i.e. the price offered in the market is

“take it or leave it”. If the price is too high, the buyer can go to another seller. No one firm in the market can influence the price of goods sold in the market.

15

Page 16: Decision-making context Karl M. Rich, Lab 863 s.r.o. & Norwegian University of Life Sciences Jarkko K. Niemi, Natural Resources Institute Finland (Luke)

Chapter 4

Profit

Profit = revenue – cost

The farmer’s revenue is determined by the market prices (p) of inputs and output(s) and his/her production technology: f(x1, x2, x3, …), where

x1, x2, x3, … are different inputs into production (labor, feed, capital, etc.)

f(x1, x2, x3, …) describes how much output (e.g. milk) farmer can produce with certain amount of inputs

Each of these inputs has a cost associated with them i.e. x1 costs w1, x2 costs w2, etc.

16

Page 17: Decision-making context Karl M. Rich, Lab 863 s.r.o. & Norwegian University of Life Sciences Jarkko K. Niemi, Natural Resources Institute Finland (Luke)

Chapter 4

Profit maximisation

Total profit (π) for the farmer is

π= maximise(Poutput* f(x1, x2, x3, …) – w1x1-w2x2 – w3x3 )

The costs and the revenues of production increase when production is increased, but in the relevant range the costs per unit of output usually increase more than the revenues per unit of output.

The law of diminishing returns: if the amount of one input is increased (while other inputs are held constant), amount of output added per unit of variable input will decrease

The profits are maximized where marginal (or additional) revenues equal to marginal (or additional) costs

17

x1, x2, x3

Page 18: Decision-making context Karl M. Rich, Lab 863 s.r.o. & Norwegian University of Life Sciences Jarkko K. Niemi, Natural Resources Institute Finland (Luke)

Chapter 4Profit maximisation – example 1 (adapted from Frank and Bernanke 2008)

Page 19: Decision-making context Karl M. Rich, Lab 863 s.r.o. & Norwegian University of Life Sciences Jarkko K. Niemi, Natural Resources Institute Finland (Luke)

Chapter 4

Economics and decision-making: different actors

Profit maximisation – example 1

Page 20: Decision-making context Karl M. Rich, Lab 863 s.r.o. & Norwegian University of Life Sciences Jarkko K. Niemi, Natural Resources Institute Finland (Luke)

Chapter 4Relationship between marginal cost, marginal revenue and average costs in example 1

Page 21: Decision-making context Karl M. Rich, Lab 863 s.r.o. & Norwegian University of Life Sciences Jarkko K. Niemi, Natural Resources Institute Finland (Luke)

Chapter 4

21

Profit maximisation – illustrative example 2

Profits are maximized where marginal (or additional) revenues equal to marginal (or additional) costs

Page 22: Decision-making context Karl M. Rich, Lab 863 s.r.o. & Norwegian University of Life Sciences Jarkko K. Niemi, Natural Resources Institute Finland (Luke)

Low-hanging fruit

“Low-hanging fruit”: in expanding production, first use those resources with the lowest cost before using those with higher costs

First focus on business activities where you are able to get the highest reward (e.g. the highest return (%) on the capital invested)

22

Page 23: Decision-making context Karl M. Rich, Lab 863 s.r.o. & Norwegian University of Life Sciences Jarkko K. Niemi, Natural Resources Institute Finland (Luke)

Constraints can prevent your client from acting

Vet’s clients make decisions under constraints

They have limited resources: money, time, skills etc.

Even if clients would like to take actions for the benefit of their animals’ health, they may not have enough resources to do it!

Potential for a conflict between vet’s view and clients’ view

23

Page 24: Decision-making context Karl M. Rich, Lab 863 s.r.o. & Norwegian University of Life Sciences Jarkko K. Niemi, Natural Resources Institute Finland (Luke)

3. The consumer

Utility maximisation

24

Page 25: Decision-making context Karl M. Rich, Lab 863 s.r.o. & Norwegian University of Life Sciences Jarkko K. Niemi, Natural Resources Institute Finland (Luke)

Chapter 4

Consumer’s perspective

Consumers consume to get more utility

Consumption decisions are constrained by the scarcity of resources (e.g. income the budget constraint)

Consumption should be increased until the marginal benefit is smaller than the marginal cost

Diminishing marginal utility means that the extra utility from consuming something falls after a certain point

Consider an example where you spend all you income on two goods: milk and eggs

25

Page 26: Decision-making context Karl M. Rich, Lab 863 s.r.o. & Norwegian University of Life Sciences Jarkko K. Niemi, Natural Resources Institute Finland (Luke)

Chapter 4

26

My budget constraint: Price of eggs* quantity of eggs+ Price of milk * quantity of milk = Income

Eggs

Milk

Page 27: Decision-making context Karl M. Rich, Lab 863 s.r.o. & Norwegian University of Life Sciences Jarkko K. Niemi, Natural Resources Institute Finland (Luke)

Chapter 4

27

My preferences represented through indifference curves. The curve shows how much I am willing to trade eggs for milk and still remain at the same level of happiness (utility)

Eggs

Milk

Page 28: Decision-making context Karl M. Rich, Lab 863 s.r.o. & Norwegian University of Life Sciences Jarkko K. Niemi, Natural Resources Institute Finland (Luke)

Chapter 4

28

1

3A

B

Indifference curves show tradeoffs. To stay at the same level of happiness moving from point A to point B, I have to get 3 portions of milk in return for giving up 1 egg.

Eggs

Milk

Page 29: Decision-making context Karl M. Rich, Lab 863 s.r.o. & Norwegian University of Life Sciences Jarkko K. Niemi, Natural Resources Institute Finland (Luke)

Chapter 4

29

More happiness (utility) as indifference curves move to the right

Eggs

Milk

Page 30: Decision-making context Karl M. Rich, Lab 863 s.r.o. & Norwegian University of Life Sciences Jarkko K. Niemi, Natural Resources Institute Finland (Luke)

Chapter 4

30

Choose the product mix where marginal benefits equal marginal cost or where indifference curve meets the budget constraint

In other words, the marginal utility per euro of each good should be the same.

Eggs

Milk

Page 31: Decision-making context Karl M. Rich, Lab 863 s.r.o. & Norwegian University of Life Sciences Jarkko K. Niemi, Natural Resources Institute Finland (Luke)

4. A group of actors is analysed differently from an individual actorMarkets can play an important role in animal health issues

31

Page 32: Decision-making context Karl M. Rich, Lab 863 s.r.o. & Norwegian University of Life Sciences Jarkko K. Niemi, Natural Resources Institute Finland (Luke)

Chapter 4

Market prices transmit information

If we take all farmers and consumers in the economy together, we get supply and demand curves.

Supply curves show the opportunity cost of supplying to the market

At higher prices, more people are willing to forgo other activities to supply a good to the market

Supply is determined by production technology, prices etc.

Demand curves show the willingness to pay for a good

At higher prices, only those with a high willingness to pay will buy Demand is determined by income, prices etc.

32

Page 33: Decision-making context Karl M. Rich, Lab 863 s.r.o. & Norwegian University of Life Sciences Jarkko K. Niemi, Natural Resources Institute Finland (Luke)

Chapter 4

33Quantity of milk

Price of milk

Supply

Demand

Page 34: Decision-making context Karl M. Rich, Lab 863 s.r.o. & Norwegian University of Life Sciences Jarkko K. Niemi, Natural Resources Institute Finland (Luke)

Chapter 4

34

A disease can increase production costs and cause the supply curve to shift to the left, raising prices and reduce quantity supplied and consumed

Supply

Demand

Quantity of milk

Price of milk

Page 35: Decision-making context Karl M. Rich, Lab 863 s.r.o. & Norwegian University of Life Sciences Jarkko K. Niemi, Natural Resources Institute Finland (Luke)

Quantity of milk

Price of milk

A disease can also cause the supply curve to shift to the right. This can happen e.g. if the disease does not reduce animal stock but reduces international trade. In this case, there would be a greater supply of meat in domestic markets

Page 36: Decision-making context Karl M. Rich, Lab 863 s.r.o. & Norwegian University of Life Sciences Jarkko K. Niemi, Natural Resources Institute Finland (Luke)

Chapter 4

36

Supply

Demand

Changes in preferences, income, or other markets can shift the demand curve. For instance, a zoonotic disease can make animal products less attractive. Then less would be consumed at the same price as earlier and the prices will be lower.

Quantity of milk

Price of milk

Page 37: Decision-making context Karl M. Rich, Lab 863 s.r.o. & Norwegian University of Life Sciences Jarkko K. Niemi, Natural Resources Institute Finland (Luke)

5. Additional topics

Things that influence decisions:

Framing

Incentives (information, risk)

37

Page 38: Decision-making context Karl M. Rich, Lab 863 s.r.o. & Norwegian University of Life Sciences Jarkko K. Niemi, Natural Resources Institute Finland (Luke)

Things that influence decision-making,……. but not necessarily at all levels

Risk and uncertainty: Most people are risk-averse. Whenever there is decreasing marginal utility, there is also risk aversion

Asymmetric information: Actors are not equally informed about the situation

Strategic behavior

Externalities: Individual vs. collective benefits and costs. What is best for you may not be the best for your neighbour.

Market failures: Public goods, externalities

Ways to overcome these issues include contracts, insurance, taxes, property rights, etc.

38

Page 39: Decision-making context Karl M. Rich, Lab 863 s.r.o. & Norwegian University of Life Sciences Jarkko K. Niemi, Natural Resources Institute Finland (Luke)

The framing of situations matters

Consider the following two scenarios (from Kahneman and Tversky 1979)

1) Imagine your country is preparing for the outbreak of a disease expected to kill 600 people. There are two alternatives to act:

a) If program A is adopted, exactly 400 people will die.

b) If program B is adopted there is a 1/3 probability that no one will die and a 2/3 probability that 600 people will die.

Which program would you choose?

39

Page 40: Decision-making context Karl M. Rich, Lab 863 s.r.o. & Norwegian University of Life Sciences Jarkko K. Niemi, Natural Resources Institute Finland (Luke)

The framing of situations matters

2) Imagine your country is preparing for the outbreak of a disease expected to kill 600 people. There are two alternatives to act:

a) If program A is adopted, exactly 200 people will be saved.

b) If program B is adopted there is a 1/3 probability that 600 people will be saved and a 2/3 probability that no people will be saved.

Which program would you choose?

40

Page 41: Decision-making context Karl M. Rich, Lab 863 s.r.o. & Norwegian University of Life Sciences Jarkko K. Niemi, Natural Resources Institute Finland (Luke)

The framing of situation matters

On average, both programs results in exactly the same outcome.

Yet people often make different choices depending on how the risk is framed

Most choose B for scenario 1 (they choose to avoid the possibility of 600 deaths)

Most choose A for scenario 2 (they choose to save 200 lives with certainty)

41

Page 42: Decision-making context Karl M. Rich, Lab 863 s.r.o. & Norwegian University of Life Sciences Jarkko K. Niemi, Natural Resources Institute Finland (Luke)

Incentives to maintain biosecurity and report disease

Standard economic analysis assumes perfect information. But what if somebody has more information than another?

Adverse selection (hidden information): one party in a transaction uses information that is disadvantageous the party without the information

Example: a person insures a pet which he/she knows is sick

Moral hazard (hidden action): one party in a transaction takes advantage of asymmetric information and acts in a risky way after the transaction

Example: Not maintaining good biosecurity after having been insured

Solution: an incentive program that encourages both to maintain good biosecurity and to report the disease quickly

42

Page 43: Decision-making context Karl M. Rich, Lab 863 s.r.o. & Norwegian University of Life Sciences Jarkko K. Niemi, Natural Resources Institute Finland (Luke)

6. Concluding remarks

43

Page 44: Decision-making context Karl M. Rich, Lab 863 s.r.o. & Norwegian University of Life Sciences Jarkko K. Niemi, Natural Resources Institute Finland (Luke)

Summary

People have endless needs but only limited resources. Hence, decisions must be made to allocate resources efficiently ( tradeoffs)

Vets and their clients can have different goals and these differences can result in different decisions

Vet’s efforts can be regarded as an input which carries a cost (monetary and non-monetary) and contributes to outputs and revenues. How much value-added does a vet provide to the client?

Low-hanging fruit: first focus on business activities where you are able to get the highest reward.

Profits are maximized when marginal revenues equal to marginal costs. It is uneconomic to use more inputs than at this point.

44

Page 45: Decision-making context Karl M. Rich, Lab 863 s.r.o. & Norwegian University of Life Sciences Jarkko K. Niemi, Natural Resources Institute Finland (Luke)

Selected readings

Rushton, J. 2009. The Economics of Animal Health and Production. CABI, Wallingford, UK.

Bernanke, B. & Frank, R. H. (2008). Principles of microeconomics, 4th edition. McGraw Hill/Irwin, New York.

Rich, K. M., & Perry, B. D. (2011). The economic and poverty impacts of animal diseases in developing countries: new roles, new demands for economics and epidemiology. Preventive veterinary medicine, 101(3), 133-147.

Rich, K. M., Miller, G. Y., & Winter-Nelson, A. (2005). A review of economic tools for the assessment of animal disease outbreaks. Revue scientifique et technique (International Office of Epizootics), 24(3), 833-845.

Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society, 263-291.

45

Page 46: Decision-making context Karl M. Rich, Lab 863 s.r.o. & Norwegian University of Life Sciences Jarkko K. Niemi, Natural Resources Institute Finland (Luke)

Exercises

1. Stakeholder role play

2. Farm-level decision making: Production costs of disease prevention

3. Farm-level decision making: Poultry production example

46

Page 47: Decision-making context Karl M. Rich, Lab 863 s.r.o. & Norwegian University of Life Sciences Jarkko K. Niemi, Natural Resources Institute Finland (Luke)

Exercise 1. Stakeholder role play

47

Page 48: Decision-making context Karl M. Rich, Lab 863 s.r.o. & Norwegian University of Life Sciences Jarkko K. Niemi, Natural Resources Institute Finland (Luke)

Exercise 1 – Stakeholder role play

Divide into six groups corresponding to

1. Farmers2. Industry3. Government4. Media5. general public6. environmental groups

Describe

1. The ways in which your group interacts with the others2. The ways in which your group can affect an animal disease outbreak 3. The reasons your group behaves as it does 4. Represent your findings to other groups & contrast with their findings

48

Page 49: Decision-making context Karl M. Rich, Lab 863 s.r.o. & Norwegian University of Life Sciences Jarkko K. Niemi, Natural Resources Institute Finland (Luke)

Exercise 2. Farm-level decision making: The cost of disease prevention

49

Page 50: Decision-making context Karl M. Rich, Lab 863 s.r.o. & Norwegian University of Life Sciences Jarkko K. Niemi, Natural Resources Institute Finland (Luke)

Exercise 2 – The cost of disease prevention

Mr. farmer is running a beef cattle farm which is experiencing continuous problems with an animal disease. Currently half of animals are sick. Mr. Farmer estimates that each sick animal is causing him a loss of €200.

The animals are divided into four groups. Each group can be treated separately with a new medicine to reduce the disease. Each group contains 50 animals and the medicine costs €12 per treated animal.

Mr. Veterinarian estimates that each additional group that is treated will reduce the number of sick animals by 20%.

Develop a table which indicates disease prevalence, treatment costs, disease losses and net costs of disease by the number of treated groups (0, 1, 2, 3, or 4). How many groups should be treated?

50

Page 51: Decision-making context Karl M. Rich, Lab 863 s.r.o. & Norwegian University of Life Sciences Jarkko K. Niemi, Natural Resources Institute Finland (Luke)

Fill in the table

51

Number of treated groups

Treatment cost per

animal

Loss per sick

animalPrevalence,

%Disease

lossesTreatment

costs

Net cost of

disease0 12 200 501 12 200 402 12 200 323 12 200 264 12 200 20

Page 52: Decision-making context Karl M. Rich, Lab 863 s.r.o. & Norwegian University of Life Sciences Jarkko K. Niemi, Natural Resources Institute Finland (Luke)

What is the otimal number of treated groups?

52

Number of treated groups

Treatment cost per

animal

Loss per sick

animalPrevalence,

%Disease

lossesTreatment

costs

Net cost of

disease0 12 200 50 5000 0 50001 12 200 40 4000 600 46002 12 200 32 3200 1200 44003 12 200 26 2560 1800 43604 12 200 20 2048 2400 4448

Page 53: Decision-making context Karl M. Rich, Lab 863 s.r.o. & Norwegian University of Life Sciences Jarkko K. Niemi, Natural Resources Institute Finland (Luke)

Marginal cost of treating fifth group is larger than the marginal benefit (i.e. reduction in disease loses avoided)

It is optimal to treat four groups

53

4000

4200

4400

4600

4800

5000

5200

1 2 3 4 5

Net

cost

of d

isea

se (€

)

Number of treated groups

Page 54: Decision-making context Karl M. Rich, Lab 863 s.r.o. & Norwegian University of Life Sciences Jarkko K. Niemi, Natural Resources Institute Finland (Luke)

Exercise 3. Farm-level decision making: Poultry production example

54

Page 55: Decision-making context Karl M. Rich, Lab 863 s.r.o. & Norwegian University of Life Sciences Jarkko K. Niemi, Natural Resources Institute Finland (Luke)

Exercise 3 – Poultry house capacity

A livestock producer has a poultry house where he can accommodate a maximum of 75 000 broilers. One-day old chicks are sold in batches of 8000 birds. The producer wonders how many poults he/she should purchase in order to maximise the gross margin of the poultry house. The producer asks for your advice. You study the literature and find that increasing stocking density is likely to decrease average daily weight gain for chicks, and to increase feed consumption and mortality of birds. You estimate that the productivity will change as represented in the next slide.

55

Page 56: Decision-making context Karl M. Rich, Lab 863 s.r.o. & Norwegian University of Life Sciences Jarkko K. Niemi, Natural Resources Institute Finland (Luke)

Exercise 3 – Data

56

The producer faces the following prices at the market:

Meat price is €1.50 per kg cascass weight

Feed price is €0.31 per kg feed

Other variable costs are €0.86 per chick

Meat sales and other costs are estimated € per purchased chick.

Number of chicks purchased

Meat sold kg/chick Feed consumed kg/chick

50,000 1.78 4.23

58,000 1.74 4.24

66,000 1.71 4.27

75,000 1.67 4.31

Page 57: Decision-making context Karl M. Rich, Lab 863 s.r.o. & Norwegian University of Life Sciences Jarkko K. Niemi, Natural Resources Institute Finland (Luke)

Exercise 3 – Cost curves and marginal effects

Based on these presented data:

1. Calculate the costs of each alternative2. Calculate the gross margin of each alternative3. Represent costs and profits graphically as a function of input4. Which option would you choose?5. For some reason, suppose that the cost of feed increases by

10% or decreases by 10%. How does that affect your choice?

57

Page 58: Decision-making context Karl M. Rich, Lab 863 s.r.o. & Norwegian University of Life Sciences Jarkko K. Niemi, Natural Resources Institute Finland (Luke)

Fill in the table by calculating the costs, revenues and the gross margin

58

Meat price is €1.50 per kg cascass weight

Feed price is €0.31 per kg feed

Other variable costs are €0.86 per chick

Number of chicks

Meat sold kg/chick

Feed used kg/chick

A=Sales revenue

B=Feed costs

C=Other costs

B+C=Total costs

A-B-C=Gross margin

50,000 1.78 4.23

58,000 1.74 4.24

66,000 1.71 4.27

75,000 1.67 4.31

Page 59: Decision-making context Karl M. Rich, Lab 863 s.r.o. & Norwegian University of Life Sciences Jarkko K. Niemi, Natural Resources Institute Finland (Luke)

Next, calculate marginal revenue, marginal cost and marginal profit

59

Number of chicks

Sales revenue

Total costs

Gross margin (GM)

Marginal revenue

Marginal costs

Marginal ’profit’ (use GM data)

50,000 133,500 108,565 24,935

58,000 151,380 126,115 25,265

66,000 169,290 144,124 25,166

75,000 187,875 164,708 23,168

Page 60: Decision-making context Karl M. Rich, Lab 863 s.r.o. & Norwegian University of Life Sciences Jarkko K. Niemi, Natural Resources Institute Finland (Luke)

Completed table

60

Number of chicks

Sales revenue

Total costs

Gross margin (GM)

Marginal revenue

Marginal costs

Marginal ’profit’ (use GM data)

50,000 133,500 108,565 24,935 NA NA NA

58,000 151,380 126,115 25,265 17,880 17,550 330

66,000 169,290 144,124 25,166 17,910 18,009 -99

75,000 187,875 164,708 23,168 18,585 20,583 -1,998

Please note that marginal figures represent how the outcome would change when 8,000 more birds are purchased in addition to those already mentioned in the first column

Page 61: Decision-making context Karl M. Rich, Lab 863 s.r.o. & Norwegian University of Life Sciences Jarkko K. Niemi, Natural Resources Institute Finland (Luke)

Next, represent your results (costs and profits) in a graph

Represent the number of chicks in the horizontal axis

Represent monetary results in the vertical axis.

61

Page 62: Decision-making context Karl M. Rich, Lab 863 s.r.o. & Norwegian University of Life Sciences Jarkko K. Niemi, Natural Resources Institute Finland (Luke)

62

0

50 000

100 000

150 000

200 000

50 000 58 000 66 000 75 000

Euro

Number of chicks

Revenues Total costs

22 000

23 000

24 000

25 000

26 000

50 000 58 000 66 000 75 000

Euro

Number of chicks

Gross margin

Page 63: Decision-making context Karl M. Rich, Lab 863 s.r.o. & Norwegian University of Life Sciences Jarkko K. Niemi, Natural Resources Institute Finland (Luke)

63

-5 000

0

5 000

10 000

15 000

20 000

25 000

50 000 58 000 66 000

€/80

00 c

hick

s

Number of chicks

Marginal revenue Marginal cost Marginal profit

Page 64: Decision-making context Karl M. Rich, Lab 863 s.r.o. & Norwegian University of Life Sciences Jarkko K. Niemi, Natural Resources Institute Finland (Luke)

Questions

64

Provide some advice for the producer. According to your analysis, how many poults should the producer buy and why?

Examine the costs and profits. When does the marginal profit curve become negative? How does that coincide with gross margin?

Page 65: Decision-making context Karl M. Rich, Lab 863 s.r.o. & Norwegian University of Life Sciences Jarkko K. Niemi, Natural Resources Institute Finland (Luke)

Sensitivity analysis

1. The cost of feed increases by 10%

2. The cost of feed decreases by 10%

=> Calculate gross margins with the new prices.

If one of these changes is realised, does it affect the results?

Does it affect your advice?

65

Page 66: Decision-making context Karl M. Rich, Lab 863 s.r.o. & Norwegian University of Life Sciences Jarkko K. Niemi, Natural Resources Institute Finland (Luke)

Calclulate the gross margins (GM)

66

Number of chicks

GM if feed costs decrease by 10%

Previously calculated GM

GM if feed costs increase by 10%

50,000 24,935

58,000 25,265

66,000 25,166

75,000 23,168

Page 67: Decision-making context Karl M. Rich, Lab 863 s.r.o. & Norwegian University of Life Sciences Jarkko K. Niemi, Natural Resources Institute Finland (Luke)

The impact of price change on gross margin

67

Number of chicks

GM if feed costs decrease by 10%

Previously calculated GM

GM if feed costs increase by 10%

50,000 31,492 24,935 18,379

58,000 32,888 25,265 17,641

66,000 33,902 25,166 16,429

75,000 33,188 23,168 13,147

When an input price increases, it may be rational to decrease the production quantity.

Page 68: Decision-making context Karl M. Rich, Lab 863 s.r.o. & Norwegian University of Life Sciences Jarkko K. Niemi, Natural Resources Institute Finland (Luke)

68

0

5 000

10 000

15 000

20 000

25 000

30 000

35 000

40 000

50,000 58,000 66,000 75,000

€/80

00 c

hick

s

Number of chicks

GM if feed costs decrease by 10%

Previously calculated GM

GM if feed costs increase by 10%

Page 69: Decision-making context Karl M. Rich, Lab 863 s.r.o. & Norwegian University of Life Sciences Jarkko K. Niemi, Natural Resources Institute Finland (Luke)

Contact

Karl M. Rich

Lab 863 s.r.o. & Norwegian University of Life Sciences

[email protected] http://www.neat-network.eu

69

Jarkko K. Niemi

Natural ResourcesInstitute Finland (Luke)

[email protected]://www.neat-network.eu