52
CPB Document No 160 March, 2008 Two Quantitative Scenarios for the Future of Manufacturing in Europe Arjan Lejour, Gerard Verweij

CPB Document - Purdue University

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    1

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: CPB Document - Purdue University

CPB Document

No 160

March, 2008

Two Quantitative Scenarios for the Future of

Manufacturing in Europe

Arjan Lejour, Gerard Verweij

Page 2: CPB Document - Purdue University

2

CPB Netherlands Bureau for Economic Policy Analysis

Van Stolkweg 14

P.O. Box 80510

2508 GM The Hague, the Netherlands

Telephone +31 70 338 33 80

Telefax +31 70 338 33 50

Internet www.cpb.nl

ISBN 978-90-5833-356-8

Page 3: CPB Document - Purdue University

3

Abstract in English

This paper presents two scenarios for the future of manufacturing in Europe with varying trends

in globalisation, technological progress and energy efficiency. From these scenarios, we

conclude that the trend towards a services economy is likely to continue with employment

shifting away from manufacturing towards services. However, manufacturing production still

grows and is important for trade in Europe. The sectors which are already the most open ones

for international trade are also the ones mostly affected by this trend. These include chemicals,

rubber and plastics, the combined machinery and equipment sectors, textiles and wearing

apparel, and wood and other manufacturing. R&D policies and internal market policies in

Europe can have strong positive impact on manufacturing. These policies do not alter the trend

that Europe’s share in global production and trade will continue to decline, but they do mitigate

the overall decline, in particular in the chemicals, rubber and plastics, and combined machinery

and equipment sectors.

Key words: Scenarios, Manufacturing, Industrial policy, Europe

JEL code: L60, C68

Abstract in Dutch

Dit document presenteert twee scenario’s voor de toekomst van de industrie in Europa met

verschillende trends voor globalisering, technologische vooruitgang en energie-efficiëntie. We

concluderen dat de verschuiving naar een diensteneconomie zich waarschijnlijk voortzet met

een bijbehorende verschuiving van de werkgelegenheid. De industriële productie blijft echter

toenemen en blijft belangrijk voor de handel in Europa. De industriesectoren die het meest

internationaal georiënteerd zijn, worden ook het meest beïnvloed. Dit zijn chemie, rubber en

plastic, machines en apparaten, textiel en kleding en hout en overige industrie. R&D-beleid en

interne-marktbeleid in Europa kunnen een significante positieve invloed op industriële

productie hebben. Dit beleid verandert niet de trend van Europa’s dalende aandelen in de

wereld productie en handel, maar zwakt deze daling wel af. Dit geldt in het bijzonder voor de

chemie, rubber en plastic en machines en apparaten.

Steekwoorden: scenario’s, industriesectoren, industriebeleid, Europa

Een uitgebreide Nederlandse samenvatting is beschikbaar via www.cpb.nl.

Page 4: CPB Document - Purdue University

4

Page 5: CPB Document - Purdue University

5

Contents

Preface 7

Summary 9

1 Introduction 11

2 Quantification of the scenarios 13

3 Framework policies and the macro impact on manufacturing 21

4 Manufacturing in Cosy at Home 27

5 Manufacturing in Adventuring in the World 35

6 Conclusions 43

References 45

Common characteristics in the scenarios 47

Page 6: CPB Document - Purdue University
Page 7: CPB Document - Purdue University

7

Preface

Manufacturing in Europe is affected by a changing world. Globalisation, EU integration,

shifting demand and progress in science and technology, and innovation will all have a major

impact on how the manufacturing landscape in Europe in terms of location, production,

distribution of labour and physical appearance will manifest itself in the near and longer-term

future. Change creates opportunities but also challenges. This is true for European citizens and

European firms, but also for national governments and the European Union.

This study investigates the future of manufacturing in Europe using a scenario approach. The

purpose of this long-term scenario study is twofold: to provide policy makers, decision makers

and others with two long-term scenario-based views on the future of European manufacturing,

and to explore the scope for EU policies to affect this future positively.

The development of these two scenarios has been requested by the European Commission and

carried out within the Framework Service Contract B2/ENTR/05/091 – FC. The main results

are summarized in the Competitiveness Report 2007 published by the European Commission

(2007b), November 2007. This document provides more details of the study, in particular on the

quantification of the scenarios. CPB and TNO collaborated in this study. Arjan Lejour and

Gerard Verweij co- authored this paper. They benefited from comments by the commission, in

particular by Emmanuelle Maincent and Ronald MacKay, who supervised the project, and Felix

Brandes and Frans van der Zee from TNO.

Coen Teulings

Director CPB

Page 8: CPB Document - Purdue University

8

Page 9: CPB Document - Purdue University

9

Summary

Is there a future for manufacturing in Europe and can framework policies help to improve this

future? The glory time for manufacturing as steering engine for Europe’s economy and provider

of employment for the majority of its labour force is over. The share of manufacturing in

employment as well as in value added decreases in the OECD countries, including Europe,

already for decades. However, three quarters of all trade is trade in goods, and its productivity

still increases much faster than productivity in services. This document provides a quantitative

scenario study showing that the trend of a declining manufacturing sector is likely to continue

over the next decades and that Asia will become the world’s most important provider of

manufacturing goods. It also shows that framework policies can help to mitigate this decline,

but not reverse it. This does not mean that there is no future for manufacturing in Europe. In

2025 Europe’s share in the overall global manufacturing production and trade will still be about

20%, and manufacturing will still contribute more than 15% to value added in Europe. A further

strengthening of the internal market and adequate R&D and innovation policies can have a

substantial impact on these shares; both are within reach of EU policy-making. We do not want

to imply however that these policies have to be pursued. These facilitate growth in

manufacturing but these policies are not necessary optimal to stimulate welfare or economic

growth in Europe.

The literature indicates that globalisation, technological progress, business models, ageing and

the availability of energy and sustainability of the environment are among the main drivers for

the future of manufacturing in Europe. The future trends of these drivers are uncertain. In order

to assess Europe’s future in manufacturing two scenarios have been developed with varying

quantitative trends in globalisation, technological progress and energy efficiency. From these

scenarios, we conclude that the trend towards a services economy is likely to continue, with

employment shifting away from manufacturing towards services and with manufacturing

contributing less to the European economy in terms of employment and value added. However,

manufacturing production still grows and is important for trade in Europe. In the Adventuring

the World scenario in which globalisation and technological progress thrive, production grows

quickly, but the geographical centre of global manufacturing production shifts to Asia. In the

Cosy at Home scenario with less globalisation and technological progress, production grows

more slowly and the European share in global production is relatively larger.

A number of interesting conclusions on the future of manufacturing in Europe can be drawn.

The increase in trade and, more generally, globalisation appears to be one of the most important

drivers. The manufacturing sectors which are already most open for international trade are also

the ones mostly affected by this trend. These include textiles and wearing apparel, wood and

other manufacturing, chemicals, rubber and plastics, electronic equipment, transport equipment

Page 10: CPB Document - Purdue University

10

and other machinery and equipment. Overall, the sectors food products and pulp, paper and

publishing are less affected. These are sectors which are more domestically oriented, less R&D

intensive and face less technological progress. Europe has no comparative advantages in textiles

and wearing apparel, electronic equipment and basic metals. These disadvantages will further

manifest themselves in the oncoming twenty years. This in particular applies to electronic

equipment which – while in the past a relative big sector - will decline even further. Textiles

and wearing apparel is an already small sector in terms of value added and employment, which

means that an even less prosperous future for this sector will also have less overall impact.

Chemicals, rubber and plastics, transport equipment and other transport and equipment will

remain important manufacturing sectors in Europe, although the comparative advantages in the

other machinery and equipment sector will slide away.

It has to be noted that the developments may also differ within the ten manufacturing sectors

identified. In most of these aggregate sectors one can distinguish between basic and specialized

manufacturing. Basic manufacturing will on average be more affected by international

competitiveness than specialized manufacturing. Possible intra-sector shifts from basic to

specialized manufacturing are not analysed here, but are certainly relevant.

Of the framework policies analysed in this study, R&D and innovation policies and

strengthening the internal market have the strongest and most positive impact on

manufacturing. These are also the most ambitious in terms of policy formulation and

implementation, but potentially very effective in supporting manufacturing because of their

R&D intensive and open-to-trade nature. Improving skills, reducing the administrative burden

and increasing energy efficiency have the least impact on manufacturing. The framework

policies do not alter the trend that Europe’s share in global production and trade will continue to

decline, but they do mitigate the overall decline, in particular in the chemicals, rubber and

plastics, and combined machinery and equipment sectors.

Page 11: CPB Document - Purdue University

11

1 Introduction

Manufacturing in Europe is affected by a changing world. Firstly, in 2004 ten countries joined

the EU, in 2007 followed by Bulgaria and Rumania. Most of the new Member States have a

different economic structure and other comparative advantages than the ‘old’ EU-15, in

particular in labour-intensive industries. This is also the case for the candidate Member States in

the Balkan countries and Turkey. Enlargement hence not only offers opportunities in terms of a

larger domestic EU market, but also in terms of specialisation and - associated - economies of

scale and scope.

Secondly, there is the new wave of globalisation, which is unprecedented both in scale and

in speed. This process of economic integration - with resources becoming more mobile,

economies becoming increasingly interdependent and financial markets becoming increasingly

international – has important implications for the future of manufacturing. This also holds for

the integration of China and India in the world economy, home to about 35 percent of the world

population. Both countries are leading and highly competitive exporters, India in software and

IT-enabled services, and China in skill-intensive manufactures. Especially China has emerged

as the new locomotive of the Asian region, and has in less than 20 years become the main

world’s manufacturing and trade platform. Globalisation has also impacted European

manufacturing in another way: lower production costs and the potential of huge new consumer

markets have caused European manufacturers to increase the quality and design of their

products and have led to international sourcing of (parts of their) production.

Thirdly, consumer demand in Europe itself is changing. As its citizens are becoming richer,

they demand more services and make more requirements on manufactured goods.

Demographics (ageing) might strengthen this change.

Finally, the pace of technological change appears to have sped up, in view of globalisation

and increasing international competition. Globalisation, EU integration, shifting demand and

progress in science and technology, and innovation – whether disruptive or not – will all have a

major impact on how the manufacturing landscape in Europe in terms of location, production,

distribution of labour and physical appearance will manifest itself in the near and longer-term

future. Change creates opportunities but also challenges. This is true for European citizens and

European firms, but also for national governments and the European Union.

The future of manufacturing is assessed using two scenarios. The purpose of the scenarios is

twofold: to provide policy makers, decision makers and others with two long-term scenario-

based views on the future of European manufacturing, and to explore the scope for EU policies

to positively address and influence the future. The scenarios have been developed in three

consecutive stages, consisting of (i) a survey of existing futures studies, (ii) the drafting of

qualitative scenarios, and (iii) a quantification of the scenarios using WorldScan, a dynamic

applied general equilibrium model for the world economy (Lejour et al., 2006).

Page 12: CPB Document - Purdue University

12

The survey of futures studies (Van der Zee and Brandes, 2007) served two goals: to help

identifying the relevant main drivers and trends that from our current perspective and

knowledge can be seen as key to the future of manufacturing in Europe, and to explore what

other expert groups and think tanks regard as possible manufacturing futures.

These drivers and trends have been translated in two scenarios and are extensively described

in Brandes et al. (2007). In this study scenarios are conceived as feasible and consistent views

of the future. They do not aim to predict the future, but rather to sketch alternative futures.

These future states of the world then form the background against which strategic decisions can

be explored. The uncertainty is reflected by sketching different developments in the

fundamental drivers for the future of manufacturing in Europe.

This document concentrates on the quantification of the scenarios and less on the qualitative

scenarios. The scenarios are quantified for three main reasons. The first is that the model

ensures that the scenarios are consistent in several respects, since economic variables conform

to identities, constraints and the current knowledge about interactions in the economy.

Secondly, the quantification gives a feel for the relative importance of various developments for

the future well-being of society. Thirdly, the model offers also the possibility to assess the

impact of framework policies and their relative importance. These two scenarios differ from the

CPB scenarios in the Four Futures (FF) study (De Mooij and Tang, 2003). First, the scenarios

developed here focus on manufacturing. Much more manufacturing sectors are distinguished

and described than in the FF study. Second, the future trends are based upon the survey of Van

der Zee and Brandes (2007). Third, the FF study develops four scenarios around two key

uncertainties: the degree of international cooperation and the mix of public and private

responsibilities. The two manufacturing scenarios do not take account of the latter key

uncertainty. Fourth, this study focuses on the enlarged EU of 27 Member States, while the FF

study concentrates mainly on EU15.

The contents of this study are as follows. Section 2 provides a numerical illustration of the

macroeconomic developments in the scenarios using WorldScan. Section 3 analyses the impact

of framework policies in support of manufacturing developments in Europe. Section 4 focuses

on the developments in European manufacturing in the Cosy at Home scenario. Similarly,

section 5 discusses the results of the Adventuring the World scenario. Section 6 concludes.

Page 13: CPB Document - Purdue University

13

2 Quantification of the scenarios

This section provides a numerical illustration of the two scenarios until 2040, but with a focus

on the period until 2025. It foremost illustrates scenario trends related to economic growth and

economic integration which are at the heart of the WorldScan model (Lejour et al. , 2006). The

two scenarios exemplify two explicit but ‘moderate extremes’. In Cosy at Home, inward-

looking, risk-averse, indecisive behaviour in the public as well as in the private realm dominate.

In this scenario, technical progress is low, transport and communications costs do not decline,

trade barriers remain in place and energy efficiency does not improve drastically. These

elements are quantified below. In Adventuring the World outward-looking (resulting in a further

opening-up), risk-loving and pro-active behaviour are prime. New technologies succeed each

others quickly, trade barriers are slashed down and transport and communication possibilities

improve. Moreover, energy use is becoming more and more efficient. Brandes et al. (2007) give

a more extensive description of the qualitative scenarios.

Worldscan

WorldScan is a multi-sector, multi-region Applied General Equilibrium (AGE) model. The model builds upon neoclassical

theory, and solves for the equilibrium that maximizes welfare across the entire economy, subject to technological

constraints, greenhouse gas limitations, etc.). Producers maximise their profits and consumers maximise their utility.

Production technologies relate output to inputs, so a potential increase in the output of a sector leads to extra demand

for inputs. This links output to input markets. Moreover, trade flows between countries, and in particular two-way intra-

industry trade, are well modelled. The integration of national goods and services markets and of capital markets creates

the possibility to analyse spillovers between countries. Another advantage is that these models distinguish several

sectors in the economy. This model version inhibits endogenous R&D decisions and spillovers and with imperfect

competition. It distinguishes 15 regions and 20 sectors. Seven large EU countries are modelled separately, and two

aggregates for the other old and new member states. Also United States, Japan, China, India South-East Asia and the

rest of the world are distinguished. The sectors are agriculture, energy, ten manufacturing sectors and seven services

sectors. The last sector is the R&D sector.

This section presents the variation in exogenous inputs between the scenarios and the outcomes.

Table 2.1 gives an overview of the scenario-specific trends. These trends determine the

variation between the scenarios in two ways: directly, because the exogenous trends differ

between the scenarios; and indirectly, because these differences imply also the variation in the

model outcomes. Both scenarios have also common characteristics. These are presented in the

appendix.

The exogenous trends are subdivided into three categories: Labour productivity (includes

unemployment), Global trade relations, and Capital (including savings) and Energy markets.

Each category is discussed separately in one of the succeeding sections.

Page 14: CPB Document - Purdue University

14

Table 2.1 Variation in exogenous inputs

Trend Cosy at Home Adventuring the World

Labour productivity EU low high

Unemployment rate constant over time declining

Global trade barriers high low

Energy efficiency low high

Savings policy no yes

Capital mobility low high

Note that the terms low and high are used to describe the development of a trend in one scenario compared with the development in the

other scenario. It is not meant to characterise differences between various trends in one scenario.

2.1 Labour productivity

Adventuring the World is the globalisation scenario represented by successful trade-

liberalisation rounds and increasing capital mobility. Economic growth is high in Adventuring

the World because of more technology spillovers and a more rapid catching up of the

developing countries (represented in higher TFP growth). Table 2.2 presents the annual average

growth rates in labour productivity for the sub-periods 2006-2025 and 2025-2040. The growth

in labour productivity is heavily based on the growth in TFP and the capital-labour ratio.

Adventuring the World focuses on a smooth functioning of national and international goods and

services markets. Innovation and fierce competition spur labour productivity all over the world.

The twelve new EU members and Asia catch-up fast with the EU-15 and the rest of the OECD.

The growth in labour productivity in the Rest of the World is much lower than in these

catching-up regions.

Table 2.2 Labour productivity growth, annual averages 2006-2040 by region

Cosy at Home Adventuring the World

2006-2025 2025-2040 2006-2025 2025-2040

EU27 1.5 1.2 2.5 2.7

EU-15 1.3 1.0 2.4 2.5

EU-12 3.1 2.2 4.7 3.8

Rest OECD 1.3 0.9 2.0 2.0

Asia 3.3 2.8 4.6 4.2

Rest of the World 1.9 1.8 2.9 2.8

Source: WorldScan.

Page 15: CPB Document - Purdue University

15

In Cosy at Home, labour productivity growth is lower than in Adventuring the World: the

difference is about 1 %. No important innovations spur economic growth. This is the case for

all regions.

Table 2.2 shows that the spread for the EU-27 between labour productivity growth rates is

1.5%-point. As we see below, that explains a large part of the variation in GDP growth. From

the table, it also follows for the EU-27 that labour productivity growth differs in Cosy at Home

about 0.3%-points and in Adventuring the World 0.2%-points between the period 2006-2025

and the period 2025-2040. However, sectoral TFP growth is constant over time.1 Two

mechanisms explain this apparent contradiction. First, the economy shifts from manufacturing

towards services. Macro labour productivity growth is the aggregate of sectoral growth, and

service sectors inhibit productivity growth less than the former sectors. Second, the growth of

the capital-labour ratio also affects labour productivity growth.

Table 2.2 also reveals the pattern of catching up. Labour productivity growth in poorer

regions, i.e. the EU-12 members and the non-OECD, exceeds that in the EU-15, the United

States and Japan. This process will, in time, narrow the gap in GDP per capita between regions.

The developments in labour productivity and employment growth determine GDP growth.

Table 2.3 GDP growth, annual averages 2006-2040 by region

Cosy at Home Adventuring the World

2006-2025 2025-2040 2006-2025 2025-2040

EU27 1.3 0.7 2.5 2.3

EU-15 1.2 0.7 2.4 2.3

EU-12 2.6 0.9 4.4 2.6

Rest OECD 1.5 1.2 2.3 2.3

Asia 4.6 3.3 6.1 4.8

Rest of the World 3.3 2.5 4.5 3.6

World 2.3 1.9 3.4 3.1

Source: WorldScan.

The pattern of GDP growth in Table 2.3 is similar to that of labour productivity growth.

Therefore, 0.1% between 2006 and 2025, which results in a slightly lower GDP growth

compared with labour productivity growth. Between 2025 and 2040, this effect becomes

stronger for the EU-15: employment declines with about 0.2% to 0.3% resulting in a lower

GDP growth compared with labour productivity growth. The decline in employment for the

EU-15 consists of a declining population growth and participation rate. For the new EU-27

members, the differences between GDP growth and labour productivity growth are more

pronounced. Between 2006 and 2025 employment declines with 0.3% or 0.5% and between

2025 and 2040 with 1.2% or 1.3%. The large differences between 2006-2025 and 2025-2040

1 Except for the transition path between current TFP growth in 2006 and scenario specific TFP growth 2010.

Page 16: CPB Document - Purdue University

16

are mainly due to a fall in participation rate over time. Therefore, GDP growth is relatively low

in comparison with the labour productivity growth for the new EU-27 members.

2.2 A redirection of trade

In Adventuring the World, global trade-liberalisation is successful and leads to a reduction in

tariffs and NTBs between 2006-2015 (Doha round) and 2021-2030 (post-Doha round). The

Doha round leads worldwide to a reduction of tariffs in manufacturing and services with 50%

and in agriculture, food and raw materials with 25%. Also the NTBs are reduced with 25%. The

post-Doha round encompasses a further reduction of tariffs in the manufacturing and services

sectors with 50% and in agriculture, food and raw materials with 25%. Again, the NTBs are

reduced with 25%. In Cosy at Home, global trade liberalisation fails.

In Adventuring the World, we furthermore assume that the costs of international trade are

gradually reduced with 80%. This will facilitate international trade. In Cosy at Home, the

situation is quite different; for the EU-15 members the costs of international trade are reduced

with only 50%, while outside the EU-15 international trade costs are even increased with 50%.

The variation in regional and global trade policies leads to a diverse picture of openness in

the scenarios. Table 2.4 presents the openness of the EU-27 and the other regions. Openness is

measured as the average value of imports and exports divided by national income. It also

includes intra EU-27 trade, which is an important share of total trade, as we will see below. In

the Cosy at Home scenario openness is about constant over time for the EU-15 and the rest

OECD, but decreases with 5 to 10% for the other regions. The shift to services in the latter

regions which are less open for cross border trade is the main reason for the overall drop in

openness. This is completely different in Adventuring the World, which features liberalised

global trade. Not only are tariffs and non-tariff barriers lowered or even eliminated, but also

trade is facilitated by more transparent and uniform customs procedures. The degree of

openness increases by about 10%-points and for Asia by even 25%-points compared to Cosy at

Home.

Table 2.4 Openness of the various regions in 2040

2005 Cosy at Home Adventuring the World

EU-27 34.1 33.3 39.3

EU-15 32.2 31.7 37.1

EU-12 63.5 51.0 62.8

Rest OECD 10.4 11.5 19.4

Asia 30.3 22.8 47.3

Rest of the World 22.8 17.7 31.9 Source: WorldScan; all aggregates include intra trade

Page 17: CPB Document - Purdue University

17

Changes in the openness of regions and differences in regional growth patterns affect also the

size and direction of trade flows. The direction of trade changes drastically in both scenarios as

shown in Figure 2.1.

Figure 2.1 Direction of EU-27 exports flows in 2005 and 2025

0%

20%

40%

60%

80%

100%

2005 Cosy at Home Adventuring in the World

EU-27 rest OECD South East Asia rest of the World

Asia will become a more important trading partner for Europe during the coming decades in

Cosy at Home and Adventuring the World, in particular. This is triggered by high economic

growth in Asia. This redirection of trade goes at the expense of the internal EU-27 trade share.

Also the Rest of the World, as Figure 2.1 shows, becomes a more important trading partner for

the EU-27, although less pronounced as South East Asia. In general, the redirection of trade is

stronger in Adventuring the World, with its high GDP per capita growth and trade liberalisation,

than in Cosy at Home.

2.3 Capital and energy markets

In the globalisation scenario Adventuring the World, we assume that capital market integration

will increase. In this scenario, it will become easier for the EU-27 to attract capital from abroad

in order to finance investment, given the decreasing macro saving rates due to ageing.

Moreover, we assume that governments in the EU-27, and also in the US and Japan, are active

in increasing savings by eliminating budget deficits and by stimulating private savings. This is

reflected by higher macro savings rates of about 2%-points in 2020 and 2040.

Page 18: CPB Document - Purdue University

18

Figure 2.2 Savings as share of national income in the EU

12

14

16

18

20

22

24

2000 2005 2010 2015 2020 2025 2030 2035 2040

% o

f nat

iona

l inc

ome

Cosy at Home Adventuring in the World

Governments do not follow these policies in Cosy at Home, and saving rates are subsequently

lower. Besides that, in the fragmented world of Cosy at Home, capital mobility is even reduced.

Irrespective of these differences, Figure 2.2 shows that saving rates in the EU decline in both

scenarios because of the aging population (see Lejour et al., 2006).

Savings depend on GDP per capita growth, demographic characteristics and savings policies.

Higher GDP growth stimulates savings, while ageing hinders it. As a result, savings are highest

in Adventuring the World and lowest in Cosy at Home (as confirmed in Table 2.5). Even in

Adventuring the World, national savings in the EU-27 decline (as a share of national income) by

3%-points. The effect of ageing on savings dominates the effects of higher GDP growth and a

savings policy. In South East Asia, savings decline by about 6%-points. The savings in the rest

OECD also decline, but somewhat less than in the EU.

Table 2.5 National savings (as ratio of national income)

Past Cosy at Home Adventuring in the World

2005 2025 2040 2025 2040

EU-27 20.5 18.2 15.0 20.9 17.9

EU-15 20.3 18.2 15.2 21.2 18.3

EU-12 23.3 17.7 12.3 18.2 12.8

Rest OECD 19.8 16.5 15.7 18.7 18.0

South East Asia 30.2 29.7 24.3 30.0 24.6

Non-OECD 20.7 21.1 19.1 21.3 19.4

Source: WorldScan

Page 19: CPB Document - Purdue University

19

The international capital markets play only a minor role in determining the sectoral production

structure, because the capital inputs are distributed quite homogenous across sectors. Despite

this homogeneity, some spread in capital shares exists across sectors. As can be seen in the

appendix, table a.3, relatively high physical capital shares in value added are found for the

sectors energy carriers (62%), food products (53%) and other business services (51%).

However, savings do not only flow to the international markets for physical capital: they are

also used nationally to finance R&D investments. After adding up physical and R&D capital

inputs, the sectors electronic equipment (45%), transport equipment (40%) and chemicals

(45%) also reveal substantial capital input shares.

Besides the supply of capital, also the demand for capital determines the behaviour of the

capital markets. The demand for capital will largely depend on the growth in GDP; more GDP

growth corresponds to a larger demand for capital. We will not expand further on these issues,

because the capital markets are not the main drivers in the scenarios.

The Adventuring the World scenario is characterised by relatively fast technological growth.

This process also shows up in the energy-specific technology, which improves with 1.5% per

annum. An increase in energy efficiency will result in a reduced demand for the energy carriers

in the production process. However, the rise in energy efficiency also makes the production

price decline, especially in the energy intensive sectors. As a consequence, the demand for

energy intensive products will rise, as will the demand for energy inputs. These two opposing

effects will lead to a net decline in energy demand.

In the Cosy at Home scenario, less technological growth is assumed. Therefore, the

improvements in energy-specific technology are assumed to be only 0.5% per annum, which is

modest in comparison with the 1.5% in the Adventuring the World scenario. Consequently, the

shifts in sectoral production as described above for the Adventuring the World scenario are less

pronounced.

The results for energy efficiency improvements should be analysed with some caution,

because the WorldScan version we have used to analyse the scenarios does not attach any costs

to the development and implementation of these energy technologies.

Page 20: CPB Document - Purdue University

20

Page 21: CPB Document - Purdue University

21

3 Framework policies and the macro impact on manufacturing

The question is whether the trends in manufacturing could be affected by policies. We do not

explicitly think of targeting and subsidizing specific industries but concentrate on frame work

policies which could affect the environment in which industrial production takes place in

Europe. For both scenarios we will analyse the impact of fostering good framework policies,

supporting the development of manufacturing in Europe (see sections 4 and 5). This section

presents the macroeconomic impact of conducting these policy packages and describes the

imputed framework policies.

According to EC (2005) framework policies could include upgrading skills, better regulation

and less administrative burdens for firms, R&D and innovation policies, A strong competitive

Single Market, including competition, environmental policies, supporting energy policies and

global trade policy. Although most of these policies will affect the manufacturing sectors in

general, the outcomes will be sector specific. For energy-intensive sectors, energy policy has

much more impact than on energy extensive sectors. This will also be the case for developments

of skills or R&D. There are two caveats here. First, global trade policy is already one of the

elements in Adventuring the World because the degree of globalisation was identified as one of

the most important driving forces for the future of manufacturing. It is not possible to consider

this policy in the policy package because trade is already much liberalised in Adventuring the

World. The second caveat is that this version of the model focuses on sectoral detail in

manufacturing and not on energy sectors. It is not possible to model the development of

alternative energy carriers, emission trading, or more competition in specific energy sectors. We

model energy efficiency in production and more integration of the aggregated energy sector is

part of a stronger internal market.

3.1 Overall effects of framework policies

Table 3.1 presents the macro outcomes on GDP , the volume of consumption and exports for

the EU as a whole in 2025 for both scenarios. The effects on the manufacturing sectors are

discussed in sections 4 and 5. All results are presented as relative changes compared to the

respective baseline in 2025. From the results, it appears that GDP could increase by 8% in the

EU, consumption by about 9% and exports by 40%. The differences between the two scenarios

are minor. In Adventuring the World the GDP increase is slightly larger than in Cosy at Home,

mainly because of the large impact of R&D and Internal market policies. The increase in

exports is higher in Cosy at Home. This is a composition effect because a higher share of total

exports is destined to other European countries in Cosy at Home. An increase in intra-EU

exports due to new single market policies has thus a larger effect on total exports. R&D and

Page 22: CPB Document - Purdue University

22

innovation policies have the largest impacts. These ambitious policies are responsible for about

40% of the total GDP effect. The reduction in administrative burden adds about 1.5% to GDP

and internal market policies about 2%. Skills contribute less, but in time if the whole labour

force has been educated the effects will be larger, see Gelauff and Lejour (2006). The

(ambitious) internal market policies have a substantial effect on trade. The export numbers

reflects total EU exports. Intra EU trade effects will be about twice as large.

Table 3.1 Macro effects of framework policies in EU27

EU

Skills

R&D

Administrative

burden

Internal

market

Energy

Total

Cosy at Home

GDP 0.5 3.0 1.5 1.7 0.9 7.7

Consumption 0.5 1.6 1.4 5.5 0.9 9.8

Exports 0.5 4.8 1.4 40.6 1.8 49.0

Adventuring the World

GDP 0.6 3.5 1.6 2.3 0.8 8.8

Consumption 0.5 1.6 1.4 5.2 0.8 9.4

Exports 0.6 5.9 1.6 29.0 1.5 38.5

Source: WorldScan simulations. The results are % changes from the baseline in 2025.

The remaining sub-sections describe these five framework policies in more detail.

3.2 Skills

As part of the Lisbon process, the Barcelona summit of 2002 endorsed common objectives for

education and training in Europe. The May 2003 Council agreed on five targets (European

Commission, 2004b) by 2010:

• An EU average rate of no more than 10% early school leavers should be achieved.2

• At least 85% of 22 year olds in the European Union should have completed upper secondary

education or higher.

• The percentage of low-achieving 15 year olds in reading literacy in the European Union should

have decreased by at least 20% compared to the year 2000.

• The European Union average level of participation in Lifelong Learning should be at least

12.5% of the adult working age population (25-64 age group).

• The total number of graduates in mathematics, science and technology (MS&T) in the European

Union should increase by at least 15% by 2010 while at the same time the level of gender

imbalance should decrease.

2 It was not possible to implement this target separately in the analysis, see Gelauff and Lejour (2006).

Page 23: CPB Document - Purdue University

23

To compute the impact of reaching the targets on education and training, Jacobs (2005)

developed a small, independent ‘satellite model’ to WorldScan, which incorporates various

aspects of skill-formation needed to simulate the targets. The satellite model also contains a

stylised cohort model to compute the impact of reaching the targets in 2010 on the skill

structure of the labour force in the period 2010-2040. The cohort model takes into account that

it takes many years before the skill structure of the labour force has adjusted to the higher

educated cohorts that leave formal education. The satellite model calculates a time path of the

increase of labour efficiency that originates from Europe reaching the skill targets in 2010. This

increase in labour efficiency is subsequently inserted in the WorldScan model, which computes

the general equilibrium effects of the education and training policies.

From the analysis in Gelauff and Lejour (2006), we know that it takes a long time before the

benefits of the efforts for improving skills can be reaped. The macroeconomic gains will be

substantially higher in 2040 than in 2025 because in the latter year a large part of the labour

force has been educated in a period before the Lisbon reforms were introduced. Therefore, it is

important to formulate new skill policies in time and not to wait until the full benefits of these

policies are realized. Although it is difficult to attain the targets formulated above in 2010, these

target are not very ambitious. In order to guarantee sufficient supply of skilled workers for

manufacturing, it seems prudent to formulate more ambitious policies for the decades after

2010.

Because the WorldScan model does not distinguish MS&T workers we are not able to

evaluate the effect of policies to stimulate the supply of these workers, but this does not imply

that increasing the number of MS&T workers is not important for manufacturing in Europe.

3.3 Less red tape in Europe

Firms often complain about the time and costs involved to deal with administrative activities.

To implement the reduction of administrative cost in WorldScan, we assume that these costs

largely consist of wages for workers that firms need to hire to comply with government

regulations and to provide the government with information. Reducing the administrative

burden implies that some of these workers can contribute directly to production. The reduction

therefore takes the form of an increase in labour efficiency: fewer workers are needed, while

production is not affected directly. Furthermore, we assume that the cost reduction is achieved

by making the administrative process more efficient; it does not undermine government

regulations.

The Netherlands is one of the very few countries which currently has detailed information

on the administrative burden of government regulations. For 2002, the administrative burden in

the Netherlands is equivalent to 3.7% of GDP (of which about 40% is due to EU regulation) and

is projected to fall with 25%, e.g. with 0.9% of GDP. Therefore, we use the key figures for the

Netherlands as a benchmark for the other member states of the European Union. To arrive at a

Page 24: CPB Document - Purdue University

24

meaningful international comparison, Kox (2005) combined the Dutch data on the total

administrative burden with the Djankov et al. (2002) data on inter-country differences in firm-

start-up costs to obtain estimates of the administrative burden per country.

This study does not assess the effectiveness of reducing red tape by 25%. A part of the

administrative burden could be overdone and therefore reduced without any harmful effects, but

another part of the administrative burden is inevitable and necessary. A part of the regulation

has to aim to check for example the quality of products and services or to protect the well being

of employees. These issues are not addressed within the policy package. It seems clear that the

administrative burden for firm could be reduced because the whole burden is a stack of non-

integrated regulations which seems to cumulate over time. For a careful analysis, more detailed

information on the administrative burden is necessary. In recent years, some initiatives came up

to improve the monitoring and registration of the administrative burden. This detailed

information could be useful to assess the necessity of reducing the administrative burden.

3.4 Research and Development

Research and Development (R&D) is a key factor for technological change, and consequently

economic growth. New technologies can boost productivity and raise incomes. The European

Council agreed to raise these R&D expenditures from 1.9% in 2004 to 2.7% of GDP in 2010. In

the WorldScan simulations, we assume that the targets are reached in 2010 9iwth some

exceptions). We do not claim that this assumption is realistic. In particular in the new member

states, current R&D expenditures are less than 1% percent. It is very difficult to increase these

expenditures substantially within a few years and to attract or train sufficient researchers in such

a relatively short period of time. Although a fruitful R&D climate in Europe can be a

comparative advantage for manufacturing, it is questionable whether a further increase in R&D

spending on top of the Lisbon target is effective. Ample availability of knowledge workers, and

clustering of innovation activities to increase interaction and a good diffusion of new ideas and

technologies could be more important.

We take account of some of the policy costs of achieving the R&D target by using a national

R&D subsidy to reduce the investment price for R&D. This probably underestimates the costs

for two reasons. First, we assume that the subsidy is spent effectively leading to more R&D

expenditure. The literature suggests this is not the case, a part of the subsidies carry a

deadweight loss. Second, the subsidy is paid by a lump-sum transfer from the domestic

households. In practice, most taxes are proportional such as the income tax, so we abstract from

the excess-burden of proportional taxes.

R&D also generates international spillovers: R&D in one country has an external effect on

productivity in the country itself as well as for its trading partners. WorldScan distinguishes

domestic spillovers from other sectors in the economy, and of foreign sectors to reflect

international spillovers.

Page 25: CPB Document - Purdue University

25

3.5 A stronger Single market

EC (2006) proposes to integrate services markets in Europe. Until now, cross border trade and

FDI remains limited due to the level of and differences in regulation in services between

member states. Also with respect to goods markets, Europe can integrate further. The principle

of mutual recognition does not work satisfactory and EC (2007a) proposes to improve the

functioning of this principle. Moreover, in public procurement, only a tiny fraction is awarded

by foreign firms (Ilzkovitz et al., 2007). This suggest that goods and services markets can be

integrated further. The European Commission aims also to integrate energy markets further. We

increase trade in services, energy and manufacturing by reducing NTB in cross border trade

between the member states, see also Gelauff and Lejour (2006) on opening up services markets.

We lower the NTBs is intra-EU services and energy trade by 20% points and in goods and

agriculture by 10% points. The 20% reduction in NTBs for services trade is in the range

suggested by De Bruijn et al. (2008) to analyse the impact of the Services directive. Kox and

Lejour (2006) argue that the implementation of the Services directive will not remove all

barriers in services trade within the EU. Also Dekker et al. (2007) argue that the internal market

is for from complete and further integration could enhance welfare in the EU.

3.6 Environmental policy

We assume that Europe promotes energy efficiency in order to slow down the depletion of

fossil fuels and to cut carbon emissions. By promoting R&D in clear technologies, public

campaigns to change conduct and regulation, firms produce more environmental friendly and

fossil fuels are saved. The reduced necessity for fossil fuels reduces production costs and

stimulates production, in particular for energy-intensive firms. We increase energy efficiency in

production in all sectors (except the energy sector itself) by 1% per year. However, we are not

able to incorporate the costs of developing more energy efficient technologies. Moreover, we

want to remind that the analytical framework to assess the future of manufacturing in Europe

does not inhibit sufficient details to model carefully energy and environmental policies such as

stimulating renewables, biomass and biofuels, environmental taxes and emission trading

schemes. By definition, environmental policy is very rudimentary modelled here.

Page 26: CPB Document - Purdue University

26

Page 27: CPB Document - Purdue University

27

4 Manufacturing in Cosy at Home

This section presents the future of European manufacturing in the Cosy at Home scenario. First

we consider the manufacturing sector in a broad perspective. We present developments in value

added and shares in global production and trade. We also discuss the impact of the framework

policies. After the broad picture of European manufacturing is sketched in section 4.1, section

4.2 concentrates on particular manufacturing sectors characterised by various levels of

technology and R&D intensity and labour skill intensity. For these sectors, we also assess the

impact of framework policies. The developments in Adventuring the World are presented in

section 5.

4.1 Manufacturing in a broad perspective

Consumer demand for services will increase relatively to the demand for commodities. This

drives the trend towards a services economy. The share of manufacturing in Europe decreases

from 22.9% to 20.1% of value added between 2005 and 2025 and the share of services increases

from 72.2% to 74.6%. The share of primary industry including energy remains more or less the

same. In comparison with the twentieth century, the speed of structural changes seems to slow

down.

Manufacturing production shifts from the traditional developed regions to Asia from 21.2 to

33.2 % of global production as is shown in Figure 4.1. In 2025, Asia will produce the largest

share of manufacturing goods. Europe’s share decreases from 26.6% to 19.7% and the share of

the Rest of the OECD decrease by about 8% points. The change for the rest of the world is

modest. If the EU puts its framework policies in place, Europe produces still 22.5% of all

manufacturing in 2025. This is 2.8% points higher than without framework policies. Although a

smaller share of all manufacturing production will take place in Europe within two decades, this

decline is smaller with supporting framework policies.

Figure 4.1 Regional shares in the world production of manufacturing for Cosy at Home

Without framework policies

0%

20%

40%

60%

80%

100%

2005 2010 2015 2020 2025

European Union Rest OECD South East Asia Rest of the World

With framework policies

0%

20%

40%

60%

80%

100%

2005 2010 2015 2020 2025

European Union Rest OECD South East Asia Rest of the World

Page 28: CPB Document - Purdue University

28

For trade shares, we see a similar pattern. Europe’s share in global manufacturing trade

decreases from 22.7% to 17.3% in 2025.3 Also for the rest of the OECD countries, the global

trade share decrease substantially. China, India and the South-East Asia increase their market

share from 26.7% to 34.8% as can be seen in Figure 4.2. The implementation of framework

policies mitigate Europe’s decline in manufacturing trade shares. In 2025, the global trade share

is still 19.2% which is about 2% point higher than without framework policies. Interestingly,

the trade and production share of the rest of the world remain more or less constant. It is solely

the rise of Asia which reduces Europe’s market shares.

Figure 4.2 Regional shares in the world exports of manufacturing for Cosy at Home

Without framework policies

0%

20%

40%

60%

80%

100%

2005 2010 2015 2020 2025

European Union Rest OECD South East Asia Rest of the World

With framework policies

0%

20%

40%

60%

80%

100%

2005 2010 2015 2020 2025

European Union Rest OECD South East Asia Rest of the World

4.2 Manufacturing in a detailed perspective

Labour productivity growth hides some important differences between sectors. In particular,

some sectors will experience faster growth than others, while the relative performance of

sectors differs across the scenarios. Table 4.1 presents growth in production volumes by sector

and the impact of the framework policies. The production increases are fuelled by the

assumptions on TFP growth (see appendix). TFP growth is high in agriculture, transport

services and communication and production growth is also relatively high in these sectors. On

average, TFP growth is higher in manufacturing than in the services sectors, but the effects on

sectoral production growth are less clear. Here the degree of international competition in

manufacturing comes in as determining factor. In electronic equipment, production does not

even increase the next two decades and in basic metals and other machinery and equipment

production growth is significantly below average. Also in textiles and wearing apparel,

production growth is relatively low.

Although the framework policies are not sector specific, these policies have a large effect on

manufacturing sectors. In particular for electronic equipment, production growth is now 2%

higher per annum. In sectors like transport equipment, other machinery and equipment,

chemicals, rubber and plastics, and textiles it is about 1% per year.

3 Note that intra-EU trade is excluded from these figures.

Page 29: CPB Document - Purdue University

29

Table 4.1 EU production growth by sector for Cosy at Home (annual growth in % for 2005-2025)

Sector No framework policies Framework policies

Agriculture, oil and minerals 1.8 1.8

Energy carriers 2.0 2.1

Food products 1.3 1.4

Textiles and wearing apparel 1.0 1.8

Wood and other manufacturing 1.6 2.1

Pulp, paper and publishing 1.2 1.4

Chemicals, rubber and plastics 1.3 2.2

Non-metallic minerals 1.1 1.4

Basic metals 0.8 1.4

Electronic equipment − 0.1 2.1

Transport equipment 1.2 2.4

Other machinery and equipment 0.5 1.3

Research and development 0.1 2.6

Transport services 1.9 2.2

Construction 0.9 1.3

Trade services 1.1 1.3

Communication 1.7 1.7

Financial services 1.2 1.2

Other business services 1.2 1.3

Other services 1.2 1.4

Source: WorldScan

The strengthening of the internal market has a substantial effect on trade in manufacturing

sectors like textiles, and the combined machinery and equipment sectors as is presented in

Table 4.2. These sectors are together with chemicals and wood products the most open for

trade. The increase in manufacturing production draws resources from the services sectors. As a

result services production declines in spite of the increased trade opportunities in services.

Trade in services is more stimulated than trade in goods within this policy. Due to the openness

of manufacturing sectors, it has much more effect on production in these sectors. This does not

imply that opening up services markets is of no use. If services trade within the EU was not

stimulated by this policy the adverse affects of stimulating good trade on services output would

be bigger.

The increase in R&D benefits the most R&D intensive industries, like electronic and transport

equipment, other machinery and equipment and chemicals. Also non-metallic minerals and

basic metals benefit more than the R&D-extensive service sectors. R&D does not only affect

the sectors directly but also indirectly by the spillovers between domestic sectors and the

international spillovers.

More energy efficiency seems to increase production in most sectors. In particular the energy-

intensive sectors, like the chemical industry and transport services, benefit. For the energy

Page 30: CPB Document - Purdue University

30

sector itself it has a negative impact due to reduced energy demand. Non-metallic minerals

benefits because it is energy-intensive, a manufacturing sectors like transport equipment benefit

because equipment is more demanded by the increase in transport services.

Table 4.2 Production volume changes per sector due to framework policies in 2025, Cosy at Home

Skills

R&D

Administra-

tive burden.

Internal

market

Energy

Total

Agriculture, oil and minerals 0.3 0.7 1.0 − 2.3 0.3 0.0

Energy carriers 0.3 2.1 1.2 2.2 − 3.3 2.4

Food products 0.2 1.2 0.9 0.2 0.7 3.1

Textiles and wearing apparel 0.6 0.7 1.9 13.1 0.9 17.3

Wood and other manufacturing 0.5 1.7 1.7 5.3 1.5 10.8

Pulp, paper and publishing 0.5 1.9 1.4 − 1.1 0.9 3.5

Chemicals, rubber and plastics 0.5 9.1 1.6 4.4 3.2 18.9

Non-metallic minerals 0.4 3.7 1.4 − 0.9 1.2 5.9

Basic metals 0.6 5.1 1.9 3.7 − 0.2 11.1

Electronic equipment 0.7 24.6 2.4 24.9 0.6 53.2

Transport equipment 0.6 11.6 1.8 9.8 1.2 25.0

Other machinery and equipment 0.7 6.1 2.0 9.9 0.0 18.8

Research and development 1.1 54.9 2.2 5.2 0.2 63.6

Transport services 0.4 0.8 1.2 0.5 4.2 7.2

Construction 0.4 2.3 1.4 2.9 0.7 7.7

Trade services 0.4 1.3 1.2 0.1 0.5 3.5

Communication 0.5 0.7 1.3 − 1.1 0.1 1.5

Financial services 0.5 0.3 1.3 − 1.9 0.1 0.3

Other business services 0.4 1.1 1.3 − 0.8 0.3 2.3

Other services 0.5 0.7 1.4 1.5 0.4 4.4 Source: WorldScan. The numbers represents relative changes in production compared to the baseline (=scenario without framework

policies) in 2025. The totals are the aggregates of the five separate policies and are also reflected by the differences in annual production

growth in Table 6.1.

From Figure 4.1, we know that Europe’s share in global manufacturing declines by about 7%

points. Table 4.3 shows that this decline is larger in electronic equipment and other machinery

and equipment. For food products and wood and other manufacturing and pulp, paper and

publishing it is much lower. Also in services, Europe’s share in production decreases, although

on average the changes are smaller reflecting a shift towards services in production in Europe.

Framework policies such as formulated in section 4, counteract this decline. In particular in

electronic equipment, the effects are staggering. The sector benefits extremely from subsidising

R&D activities and the strengthening of the internal market.4 Also in transport equipment,

chemicals, rubber and plastics and textiles and wearing apparel, Europe increases its share in

global production by more than 2% points compared to a lack of these policies. Between 2005

4 We do not present here the effects of the five separate policies. We have done this for the changes in production growth by

sector in Table 4.2. The impact of the policies on production is representative for the impact on other variables.

Page 31: CPB Document - Purdue University

31

and 2025, the share in production still decreases but at a much slower pace than without

supporting policies.

Table 4.3 EU production as share of world production by sector for Cosy at Home, 2025

2005 2025 2025

Sector No framework policies Framework policies

Agriculture, oil and minerals 14.3 11.6 11.9

Energy carriers 19.2 16.5 17.8

Food products 26.9 22.7 23.5

Textiles and wearing apparel 19.3 13.9 16.2

Wood and other manufacturing 25.6 21.8 23.8

Pulp, paper and publishing 27.8 23.4 24.4

Chemicals, rubber and plastics 27.7 20.7 23.5

Non-metallic minerals 28.6 21.5 22.7

Basic metals 26.2 19.0 20.8

Electronic equipment 22.1 12.9 19.0

Transport equipment 29.3 23.5 27.6

Other machinery and equipment 28.5 19.0 22.1

Research and development 22.5 18.9 29.8

Transport services 25.5 22.0 23.1

Construction 24.8 19.3 20.9

Trade services 23.4 20.0 21.5

Communication 24.8 20.6 21.8

Financial services 21.7 18.7 19.7

Other business services 29.1 26.2 27.7

Other services 28.1 23.8 25.8

Source: WorldScan

In 2005, the EU has the highest production shares in medium-high technology sectors and in

other business services. In the high technology sector, electronic equipment, Europe’s market

share is relatively low and in time this process is reinforced.

Table 4.4 complements these conclusions by presenting the shift of Europe’s trade shares in

global trade, represented by exports. Europe’s exports reflect external trade. In electronic

equipment, Europe’s exports share is already low in 2005 and it decreases over time. This is

also the case for textiles and wearing apparel. In wood and other manufacturing, Europe’s trade

share increases, and for food products it remains constant. In other machinery and equipment,

the decline in market shares is substantial and framework policies do not have much impact

here. For transport equipment, the framework policies are helpful in maintaining market shares

the next two decades. Europe’s market shares in most services sectors increase somewhat,

although the framework policies do not contribute to that increase. The reason is that these

policies are more supportive for manufacturing because of the R&D intensity and trade

openness. As a result, these sectors draw resources away from services.

Page 32: CPB Document - Purdue University

32

Table 4.4 EU export flows as share of world export flows by sector for Cosy at Home

2005 2025 2025

Sector No framework policies Framework policies

Agriculture, oil and minerals 4.9 5.9 5.1

Energy carriers 10.3 22.4 19.5

Food products 26.0 26.6 24.9

Textiles and wearing apparel 12.4 9.5 9.7

Wood and other manufacturing 20.6 23.5 23.8

Pulp, paper and publishing 25.2 22.8 20.4

Chemicals, rubber and plastics 30.9 24.9 28.7

Non-metallic minerals 30.6 28.6 26.6

Basic metals 19.8 16.2 15.0

Electronic equipment 12.5 7.4 10.7

Transport equipment 27.5 22.2 27.5

Other machinery and equipment 25.9 16.8 17.5

Transport services 29.0 31.4 28.4

Construction 43.2 50.1 46.3

Trade services 31.1 38.0 31.8

Communication 31.0 24.6 18.8

Financial services 39.1 39.8 33.3

Other business services 36.2 37.3 31.3

Other services 30.5 31.6 24.6

Source: WorldScan

The share of electronic equipment and other machinery and equipment in total exports reduces

over time. Overall the share of manufacturing in EU exports decreases from 65.6% to 54.1% in

2025. For services its aggregate share in exports increase by about 8.7%. The framework

policies limit these changes by about 50%.

Table 4.5 shows the so-called revealed comparative advantages of the various sectors in the EU.

It measures the exports of a particular sector in total exports relative to the average export share

of that sector in other countries (and multiplied by 100).5 Hence, if a sector features an index

higher than 100, then it is said that a region specialises its exports in that sector (i.e. it has a

comparative advantage in that sector relative to other regions). From Table 4.5, we learn that

the EU-27 specialises today in the exports of food products, paper products, chemicals and non-

metallic minerals, transport equipment, other machinery and equipment and services.6

According to Cosy at Home, the EU-27 maintains its comparative advantage in most of these

sectors. Only in other machinery and equipment, the comparative advantage disappears, but it

increases in wood and other manufacturing. In services, comparative advantages even increases

for every sector.

5 Also here, only extra EU exports are included in the analysis. 6 Export of construction is small en not discussed further.

Page 33: CPB Document - Purdue University

33

Europe has no comparative advantage in textiles and wearing apparel, basic metals and

electronic equipment. This will not change over time and its competitiveness is only slightly

affected by the framework policies.

Table 4.5 Revealed comparative advantage in the EU-27 for Cosy at Home

2005 2025 2025

Sector No framework policies Framework policies

Agriculture, oil and minerals 21 29 25

Energy carriers 44 110 96

Food products 112 130 122

Textiles and wearing apparel 53 46 48

Wood and other manufacturing 89 115 117

Pulp, paper and publishing 109 111 100

Chemicals, rubber and plastics 133 122 141

Non-metallic minerals 132 140 130

Basic metals 85 79 74

Electronic equipment 54 36 53

Transport equipment 119 108 135

Other machinery and equipment 112 82 86

Transport services 125 153 139

Construction 186 245 227

Trade services 134 186 156

Communication 134 120 92

Financial services 169 195 164

Other business services 156 182 154

Other services 132 154 121

Source: WorldScan

Page 34: CPB Document - Purdue University

34

Page 35: CPB Document - Purdue University

35

5 Manufacturing in Adventuring in the World

This section presents the future of European manufacturing in Adventuring the World. It has a

similar structure as section 4. First, the overall developments of European manufacturing are

discussed by presenting changes in value added and shares in global production and trade. The

macroeconomic impact of the framework policies is also assessed. Section 5.2 concentrates on

specific manufacturing sectors characterised by different of technology, R&D intensity, skill

intensity, and trade openness. We focus on production growth, shares in global production and

trade, and revealed comparative advantages by sector. For each sector, we also assess the

impact of the framework policies.

5.1 Manufacturing in a broad perspective

The trend towards services is stronger in Adventuring the World than in Cosy at Home. The

share of services in value added increase to 76.1% in 2025. This is 1.5% points higher than in

Cosy at Home. The share of manufacturing is correspondingly lower, it is only 18.8% in 2025.

This is a decline of 5% points between 2005 and 2025, but is also indicates that not all

manufacturing will disappear from Europe in spite of the rise of Asia.

The relative decline of manufacturing in Europe is also illustrated in Figure 5.1.

Figure 5.1 Regional shares in the world production of manufacturing for Adventuring in the World

Without framework policies

0%

20%

40%

60%

80%

100%

2005 2010 2015 2020 2025

European Union Rest OECD South East Asia Rest of the World

With framework policies

0%

20%

40%

60%

80%

100%

2005 2010 2015 2020 2025

European Union Rest OECD South East Asia Rest of the World

Europe’s share in global production decreases from 26.6% to 19.4% in 2025. Asia’s share

increases from 21.2% to 37.7%. In Adventuring the World the production shifts are somewhat

larger than in Cosy at Home. The share of the Rest of the OECD decreases by about 11%. The

framework policies mitigate Europe’s decline in manufacturing. In 2025 Europe’s share is still

22.9% which is 3.5% points higher than without framework policies. The impact of the

framework policies is larger in Adventuring the World than in Cosy at Home. The increased

competition in Adventuring the World worsens on average the position of European

manufacturing, but its competitiveness becomes also more sensitive for good policies.

Page 36: CPB Document - Purdue University

36

Figure 5.2 presents the developments in the manufacturing trade shares of the EU, Rest OECD,

Asia and the rest of the world between 2005 and 2025 in Adventuring the World. Also here, the

patterns are presented with and without framework policies. Europe’s share in global

manufacturing trade decreases from 22.7% to 17.3% in 2025, the same decrease as in Cosy at

Home.7 However, the global trade shares of China, India and South-East Asia increase from

26.7 to 36.8%, 2% points higher than in Cosy at Home. This comes at the expense of the Rest

OECD. Framework policies support the future of European manufacturing. The decrease in

trade share of global manufacturing is mitigated to 19.0% in 2025.

Figure 5.2 Regional shares in the world exports of manufacturing for Adventuring in the World

Without framework policies

0%

20%

40%

60%

80%

100%

2005 2010 2015 2020 2025

European Union Rest OECD South East Asia Rest of the World

With framework policies

0%

20%

40%

60%

80%

100%

2005 2010 2015 2020 2025

European Union Rest OECD South East Asia Rest of the World

5.2 Manufacturing in a detailed perspective

Economic growth in Europe and the world is higher in Adventuring the World than in Cosy at

Home (see Table 2.3). This is also reflected in production growth by sector. If we compare

Table 5.1 and Table 4.1 production grows faster in Adventuring the World than in Cosy at

Home for nearly all sectors in Europe, except textiles and wearing apparel and electronic

equipment (comparison based on no framework policies case). These are also sectors in which

Europe has a comparative disadvantage. It seems that increasing globalisation and a faster

technological change reinforces existing specialization patterns.

For most sectors, production growth is about 1% per year higher in Adventuring the World.

For wood and other manufacturing, transport equipment, construction and non-metallic

minerals, it is about 2% higher per year and for chemicals, rubbers and plastics and transport

services about 1.5%.

As is concluded from Cosy at Home, framework policies have a substantial effect on

production growth in manufacturing. The sector electronic equipment grows by 3% per year

extra if these policies are implemented. For chemicals, rubber and plastics, transport equipment

7 Note that intra-EU trade is excluded from these figures.

Page 37: CPB Document - Purdue University

37

the yearly growth increase is about 1.5% and for textiles and wearing apparel and other

machinery and equipment about 1%. Production growth effects in services are much smaller.

Table 5.1 EU production growth by sector for Adventuring in the World (annual growth in % for 2005-

Sector No framework policies Framework policies

Agriculture, oil and minerals 2.7 2.8

Energy carriers 3.4 3.6

Food products 2.1 2.4

Textiles and wearing apparel 0.1 1.1

Wood and other manufacturing 3.8 4.4

Pulp, paper and publishing 2.3 2.5

Chemicals, rubber and plastics 2.7 4.1

Non-metallic minerals 3.1 3.4

Basic metals 2.0 2.7

Electronic equipment − 1.1 2.0

Transport equipment 3.1 4.6

Other machinery and equipment 1.5 2.6

Research and development 0.8 3.7

Transport services 3.4 3.8

Construction 2.8 3.1

Trade services 2.0 2.2

Communication 3.1 3.2

Financial services 2.0 2.0

Other business services 2.2 2.3

Other services 2.0 2.2

Source: WorldScan

Table 5.2 presents the impact of each of the policies: increasing skills, increasing R&D,

reducing the administrative burden, strengthening the internal market and improving energy

efficiency on production. In most services sectors production hardly increases but in

manufacturing some of the production changes are stunning. In electronic equipment production

increases by 80%. In the sectors textiles and wearing apparel, wood and other manufacturing,

chemicals, basic metals, transport equipment and other machinery and equipment production

increases by more than 10% to about 30% in 2025. Key are the R&D and innovation policies

and the strengthening of the internal market. For the R&D-intensive manufacturing sectors

R&D policy and increased trade through the internal market contribute both for nearly 50% to

the overall effect. For R&D-extensive sectors, like textiles, and wood and other manufacturing

only the internal market policy is important. The skills policy, reduction of administrative

burden and more energy efficiency contribute less to manufacturing production. Only energy

efficiency has a substantial effect on the production of chemicals, rubber and plastics. The

impact of the skills policy and the reduction of the administrative burden varies less by sector,

but these policies have more impact on manufacturing than on services on average. These

differences are more pronounced in Adventuring the World than in Cosy at Home.

Page 38: CPB Document - Purdue University

38

Table 5.2 Production volume changes per sector in 2025, Adventuring in the World

Skills

R&D

Administra-

tive burden

Internal

market

Energy

Total

Agriculture, oil and minerals 0.3 0.5 1.0 − 1.9 0.5 0.5

Energy carriers 0.3 2.2 1.1 3.7 − 3.9 3.6

Food products 0.3 1.4 1.1 0.7 0.7 4.2

Textiles and wearing apparel 0.9 -1.6 2.4 17.5 1.1 20.4

Wood and other manufacturing 0.6 0.9 1.8 8.1 1.9 13.4

Pulp, paper and publishing 0.6 1.4 1.6 − 0.4 0.8 4.1

Chemicals, rubber and plastics 0.7 13.8 2.0 10.8 4.4 31.7

Non-metallic minerals 0.5 3.2 1.6 − 0.3 1.3 6.5

Basic metals 0.9 5.1 2.4 9.0 − 2.1 15.3

Electronic equipment 0.9 40.7 3.2 39.7 1.2 85.8

Transport equipment 0.7 16.4 2.0 12.1 1.3 32.4

Other machinery and equipment 1.0 8.0 2.5 13.1 − 0.5 24.0

Research and development 1.4 64.0 2.2 5.4 0.6 73.7

Transport services 0.5 0.8 1.3 0.3 4.4 7.3

Construction 0.4 2.0 1.4 2.4 0.6 6.9

Trade services 0.5 1.5 1.3 0.4 0.4 4.1

Communication 0.5 0.8 1.5 − 0.7 0.2 2.4

Financial services 0.6 0.4 1.4 − 1.7 0.2 0.8

Other business services 0.4 1.3 1.4 − 0.3 0.3 3.1

Other services 0.5 0.5 1.4 1.0 0.3 3.7

Source: WorldScan

Table 5.1 shows that production increases in all sectors, except for electronic equipment

without policy. This does however not imply that manufacturing in Europe keeps the growth

path of manufacturing in other regions. High economic growth in Asia expands manufacturing

production there. The Asian share at the world markets increases, both measured in production

and trade, see Figure 5.1 and Figure 5.2. On average, Europe’s share in production decreases by

about 5.4% points. For electronic equipment, the decline is dramatic from 22% to less than 8%

(see Table 5.3), but also in other machinery and equipment and textiles and wearing apparel the

decline is substantial, about 10% of global production. In chemicals, rubber and plastics and

basic metals, the loss in production share is also substantial, but in wood and other

manufacturing we see a small increase in the share of global production. The pattern of changes

in production shares differs in both scenarios. The average decrease is equal, but the changes

per sector over time are more pronounced in the Adventuring the World.

The framework policies contribute to European’s share of manufacturing production. In all

sectors production share increases most notably for chemicals, rubber and plastics, electronic

equipment and transport equipment. In transport equipment and wood and other manufacturing,

Europe’s production shares even increase compared to 2005.

Page 39: CPB Document - Purdue University

39

Table 5.3 EU-27 production as share of world production by sector for Adventuring in the World

2005 2025 2025

Sector No framework policies Framework policies

Agriculture, oil and minerals 14.3 11.8 12.0

Energy carriers 19.2 18.4 19.8

Food products 26.9 23.0 23.9

Textiles and wearing apparel 19.3 9.7 11.5

Wood and other manufacturing 25.6 25.9 28.7

Pulp, paper and publishing 27.8 24.6 25.6

Chemicals, rubber and plastics 27.7 21.1 26.3

Non-metallic minerals 28.6 24.9 26.2

Basic metals 26.2 18.6 21.0

Electronic equipment 22.1 7.7 13.7

Transport equipment 29.3 24.8 31.0

Other machinery and equipment 28.5 17.7 21.4

Research and development 22.5 18.6 30.8

Transport services 25.5 23.5 24.7

Construction 24.8 21.0 22.5

Trade services 23.4 20.6 22.0

Communication 24.8 20.7 21.8

Financial services 21.7 19.1 20.0

Other business services 29.1 27.5 28.9

Other services 28.1 24.2 26.0

Source: WorldScan

Table 5.4 shows the impact of globalisation and faster technological growth in Adventuring the

World on the share of EU exports in global exports by sector. Already in 2005, Europe’s share

in manufacturing is on average lower than in services, which is not surprising because nearly no

countries export services outside the OECD countries. Only in chemicals, rubber and plastics

and non-metallic minerals, Europe has a similar position as in services. In particular in

electronic equipment and textiles and wearing apparel, Europe’s trade shares are low. Over

time, the trade shares decrease in all manufacturing sectors, except wood and other

manufacturing and non metallic minerals. It increases in nearly all services sectors except

communication and other services. The decline in chemicals, rubber and plastics, and the

combined machinery and equipment sectors is substantial. While in the past mainly unskilled

labour-intensive sectors were affected by increasing international competition, more skilled and

capital-intensive sectors are also affected the coming decades.

Page 40: CPB Document - Purdue University

40

Table 5.4 EU export flows as share of world export flows by sector for Adventuring in the World

2005 2025 2025

Sector No framework policies Framework policies

Agriculture, oil and minerals 4.9 8.2 7.4

Energy carriers 10.3 26.0 24.3

Food products 26.0 24.6 23.8

Textiles and wearing apparel 12.4 9.5 9.1

Wood and other manufacturing 20.6 26.9 27.7

Pulp, paper and publishing 25.2 23.4 21.6

Chemicals, rubber and plastics 30.9 23.0 27.8

Non-metallic minerals 30.6 32.1 30.9

Basic metals 19.8 15.9 15.1

Electronic equipment 12.5 6.5 9.1

Transport equipment 27.5 22.2 27.7

Other machinery and equipment 25.9 15.9 16.5

Transport services 29.0 39.1 37.3

Construction 43.2 52.1 48.6

Trade services 31.1 39.9 34.5

Communication 31.0 28.3 23.1

Financial services 39.1 41.0 35.7

Other business services 36.2 37.2 32.5

Other services 30.5 29.7 23.7

Source: WorldScan

The changes in EU trade shares are more or les comparable in both scenarios. Differences are

found inn the increases in wood and other manufacturing and non metallic minerals in

Adventuring the World. The framework policies support some EU manufacturing export shares,

but not in food products, textiles and wearing apparel, pulp, paper and publishing non metallic

minerals and basic metals. These are R&D-extensive manufacturing sectors, but also

framework policies do not offset the decline of the R&D intensive sectors over time in the EU.

The positive effect of framework policies on the R&D intensive sectors in Europe comes at the

relative expense of services.

In the composition of the EU exports, the share of other manufacturing and equipment

declines. The share of sectors like food products, wood and other manufacturing, pulp, paper

and printing, basic metals, and non-metallic minerals increases somewhat. Overall, the changes

in the export composition are less pronounced in Adventuring the World than in Cosy at Home.

With framework policies, the changes are even smaller. The share of manufacturing products in

EU exports decreases only by 2% points between 2005 and 2025.

Despite these similarities, the developments in comparative advantages vary substantially

among the scenarios. In general, the revealed comparative advantages change most in

Adventuring the World, where markets become more integrated. Europe looses competitiveness

in textiles and wearing apparel, basic metals, and electronic equipment. These are already

Page 41: CPB Document - Purdue University

41

sectors in which Europe did not specialize. It looses its comparative advantage in other

machinery and equipment. The comparative advantages in wood and other manufacturing and

non-metallic minerals and services increases with and without framework policies. For

chemicals, rubber and plastics, framework policies are necessary to keep the competitive

advantage of 2005.

Table 5.5 Revealed comparative advantage in the EU-27 for Adventuring in the World

2005 2025 2025

Sector No framework policies Framework policies

Agriculture, oil and minerals 21 40 36

Energy carriers 44 128 118

Food products 112 121 115

Textiles and wearing apparel 53 47 44

Wood and other manufacturing 89 133 134

Pulp, paper and publishing 109 115 105

Chemicals, rubber and plastics 133 113 134

Non-metallic minerals 132 158 149

Basic metals 85 78 73

Electronic equipment 54 32 44

Transport equipment 119 110 134

Other machinery and equipment 112 79 80

Transport services 125 192 181

Construction 186 257 235

Trade services 134 196 167

Communication 134 139 112

Financial services 169 202 173

Other business services 156 183 157

Other services 132 146 115

Source: WorldScan

Page 42: CPB Document - Purdue University

42

Page 43: CPB Document - Purdue University

43

6 Conclusions

Is there a future for manufacturing in Europe and can framework policies help to improve this

future? The answer to these questions can be analysed from different perspectives. The glory

time for manufacturing as steering engine for Europe’s economy and provider of employment

for the majority of its labour force is over. This is already the case for a long time. The share of

manufacturing in employment as well as in value added decreases in the OECD countries,

including Europe, already for decades on end, although its share in trade remains still high and

its productivity still increases. This scenario study shows that the trend of a declining

manufacturing sector is likely to continue over the next decades and that Asia will become the

world’s most important provider of manufacturing goods. Framework policies can help to

mitigate this decline, but not reverse it. This does not mean that there is no future for

manufacturing in Europe. In 2025, Europe’s share in the overall global manufacturing

production and trade will still be about 20%, and manufacturing will still contribute more than

15% to value added in Europe. A further strengthening of the internal market and adequate

R&D and innovation policies can have a substantial impact on these shares.

The literature indicates that globalisation, technological progress, business models, ageing and

the availability of energy and sustainability of the environment are among the main drivers for

the future of manufacturing in Europe. The future trends of these drivers are uncertain. In order

to assess Europe’s future in manufacturing we have developed two scenarios with varying

trends in globalisation, technological progress, business models and energy efficiency. From

these scenarios, we conclude that the trend towards a services economy is likely to continue and

manufacturing contributes less to the European economy in terms of employment and value

added. However, manufacturing production still grows and is important for trade in Europe. In

the Adventuring the World scenario in which globalisation and technological progress thrive,

production grows quickly, but the geographical centre of global manufacturing production shifts

to Asia. In the Cosy at Home scenario with less globalisation and technological progress,

production grows more slowly and the European share in global production is relatively larger.

Within manufacturing, various developments take place. Based on historical productivity

growth paths of manufacturing sectors, their trade openness, R&D intensity, energy efficiency,

and skill intensity, it is highly likely that these (sub)sectors will develop differently over time. It

has to be noted also that the developments may also differ within the ten manufacturing sectors

identified. In most of these aggregate sectors, one can distinguish basic and specialized

manufacturing. Basic manufacturing will on average be more affected by international

competitiveness than specialized manufacturing. Possible intra-sector shifts from basic to

specialized manufacturing are not analysed here, but are certainly relevant. In this study, an

applied general equilibrium framework was used to represent Europe’s relations with other

Page 44: CPB Document - Purdue University

44

regions and to assess the relations between manufacturing and services sectors. This is a very

valuable framework because linkages and spillovers between sectors and countries are very

important for the functioning of economies. However, this choice excludes a further, more

detailed look at manufacturing sectors at a more disaggregated level.

A number of interesting conclusions on the future of manufacturing in Europe can be drawn.

The increase in trade and, more generally, globalisation appears to be one of the most important

drivers. The sectors which are already most open for international trade are also the ones mostly

affected by this trend. These include textiles and wearing apparel, wood and other

manufacturing, chemicals, rubber and plastics, electronic equipment, transport equipment and

other machinery and equipment. Overall, the sectors food products and pulp, paper and

publishing are less affected. These are sectors which are more domestically oriented, less R&D

intensive and face less technological progress. Europe has no comparative advantages in textiles

and wearing apparel, electronic equipment and basic metals. These disadvantages will further

manifest themselves in the oncoming twenty years. This in particular applies to electronic

equipment which – while in the past a relative big sector - will decline even further. Textiles

and wearing apparel is an already small sector in terms of value added and employment, which

means that an even less prosperous future for this sector will also have less overall impact.

Chemicals, rubber and plastics, transport equipment and other transport and equipment will

remain important manufacturing sectors in Europe, although the comparative advantages in the

other machinery and equipment sector will slide away.

Of the framework policies analysed in this study, improving skills, reducing the administrative

burden and increasing energy efficiency, have the least impact on manufacturing. R&D and

innovation policies and strengthening the internal market on the other hand have the strongest

and most positive impact on manufacturing. These are also the most ambitious in terms of

policy formulation and implementation, but potentially very effective in supporting

manufacturing because of their R&D intensive and open-to-trade nature. These policies do not

alter the trend that Europe’s share in global production and trade will continue to decline, but

they do mitigate the overall decline, in particular in the chemicals, rubber and plastics, and

combined machinery and equipment sectors.

Page 45: CPB Document - Purdue University

45

References

Brandes F., A. M. Lejour, G, Verweij, and F. van der Zee, 2007, The future of Manufacturing in

Europe, http://ec.europa.eu/enterprise/enterprise_policy/industry/index_en.htm.

De Bruijn, R., H. Kox and A.M. Lejour, 2008, Economic benefits of an integrated European

market for services, Journal of Policy Modelling, forthcoming.

De Mooij, R.A., and P.J.G. Tang, 2003, Four Futures of Europe, CPB Special Publication, The

Hague.

Dekker, P., A. van der Horst, H. Kox, A. Lejour, B. Straathof, P. Tammes and C. Wennekers, et

al, 2007, Market Place Europe, European Outlook 5, CPB Special Publication 68, CPB & SCP,

The Hague.

Dimaranan, B.V. and R.A. McDougall, 2005, Global Trade, Assistance, and Production: The

GTAP 6 Data Base, Center for Global Trade Analysis, Purdue University.

Djankov, S., R. La Porta, F. Lopez and A. Shleifer, 2002, The regulation of entry, Quarterly

Journal of Economics, vol. 117, no.1, pp. 1-37.

European Commission, 2004a, Proposal for a Directive of the European Parliament and of the

Council on Services in the Internal Market, SEC (2004) 21, Brussels.

European Commission, 2004b, Progress towards the Common Objectives in Education and

Training, Commission Staff Working Paper, SEC, 2004, 73, Brussels.

European Commission, 2005, Implementing the Community Lisbon Programme :a policy

framework to strengthen EU manufacturing - towards a more integrated approach for Industrial

policy, 474 final.

European Commission, 2007a, Proposals for a Regulation of the European Parliament and of

the council laying down procedures relating to the application of certain national technical rules

to products lawfully marketed in another Member State and repealing Decision 3052/95/EC,

Communication COM (2007) 36 final.

European Commission, 2007b, Competitiveness Report 2007, COM(2007)666 and

SEC(2007)1444.

Page 46: CPB Document - Purdue University

46

Eurostat, 2002, Eurostat New National Baseline Population Scenarios, Luxembourg.

Gelauff, G.M.M., and A.M. Lejour, 2006, The New Lisbon Strategy: An estimation of the

economic impact of reaching five Lisbon targets, European Commission, DG Enterprise and

Industry, Industrial Policy and Economic Reforms papers 1, also published as CPB Document

104.

Ilzkovitz, F., A. Dierx, V. Kovacs and N. Sousa, 2007, Steps towards a deeper economic

integration: the Internal Market in the 21st century, A contribution to the Single Market

Review, DG EcFin Economic Papers, 271, Brussels.

Jacobs, B., 2005, Simulating the skills targets in WorldScan, CPB Memorandum 135, The

Hague.

Kox, H., 2005, Intra-EU differences in regulation-caused administrative burden for companies,

CPB Memorandum 136, The Hague.

Kox, H, and A.M. Lejour, 2006, Dynamic effects of European services liberalisation: more to

be gained, In Global Challenges for Europe, Report by the secretariat to the Economic council,

PART 1, Prime Minister’s Office Publications 18/2006, 131-142.

Lejour, A.M.L., P. Veenendaal, G. Verweij, and N.I.M. van Leeuwen, 2006, WorldScan: a

model for international economic policy analysis, CPB Document 111.

United Nations, 2002, World Population Prospects.

World Bank, 2007, World Development Indicators, Washington, DC.

Van der Zee, F.A. and F. Brandes, 2007, Manufacturing Futures for Europe – A Survey of the

Literature, http://ec.europa.eu/enterprise/enterprise_policy/industry/index_en.htm.

Page 47: CPB Document - Purdue University

47

Common characteristics in the scenarios

Several exogenous variables are similar in all scenarios. We have two reasons to do so. The first

is that some trends are common in all scenarios, such as trade liberalisation between the EU-15

and the Central and Eastern European countries (CEEC). The second is that the model is

calibrated on one database, which is scenario independent. Many elasticities and exogenous

variables, such as trade barriers, are determined in the calibration procedure and are therefore

identical in all scenarios.

Our calibration year is 2001. The model is calibrated on the basis of the GTAP database,

version 6 (Dimaranan and McDougall, 2005). Using data of the World Bank (2007), we run the

model from 2001 to 2005 to reproduce GDP per capita and unemployment rates until 2005.

Table A.1 Common trends in the scenarios

Variable Source

Population growth Projections from Eurostat and IPCC

Participation rates Projections based on ILO, Eurostat and UN

Relative sectoral TFP growth Based on historical trends ISDB data (OECD)

Sectoral consumption Based on GTAP data

Substitution elasticities for international trade Based on Hertel et al. (2004), and for services own guess

EU enlargement Elimination all remaining tariffs EU-15- EU-12

Source: Lejour et al. (2006)

Population growth and labour-market participation

The population projection are based on assumptions on fertility, migration and life. Table A.2

shows that population growth in the EU-27 declines in time from 0.2 % per year to zero. For the

new EU-27 members (mainly the Central and Eastern European countries) the population will

even diminish.

Table A.2 Population growth (annual averages 2006-2040) and participation rates (as ratio of population)

Region Population growth Participation rate

2006-2025 2025-2040 2005 2025 2040

EU-27 0.2 0 47.0 43.6 40.6

EU-15 0.3 0.1 47.3 43.3 40.8

EU-12 − 0.3 − 0.5 46.0 44.4 39.3

Rest OECD 0.6 0.4 50.8 47.5 43.6

South East Asia 1.1 0.5 48.4 50.6 50.9

Rest of the World 1.0 0.6 42.7 45.8 46.8

Source: Eurostat (2002) for EU-27, and United Nations (2002) for other regions.

Page 48: CPB Document - Purdue University

48

Outside the EU-27, the population growth is much higher. In the period 2006-2025 the

population of the Rest of the OECD, i.e. the United States and Japan, increases with 0.6% per

year and the population of the non-OECD even with more than 1% per year. In the second

period (2025-2040) of the scenarios, population grows less rapid, but still round 0.5% per year.

Table A.2 shows that participation rates in the EU-27 are declining. The drop in

participation (as a share of total population) in the EU-27 is foremost a result of population

developments, i.e. aging. In 2005 still 47.0% of the total population participates on the labour-

market, while in 2040 this ratio is only 40.6%. The same trend can also be seen in the Rest of

the OECD. Outside the OECD the opposite trend emerges: participation rates are increasing

from 48.4% in 2005 to 50.9% in 2040 for South East Asia and from 42.7% to 46.8% for the

Rest of the World.

Table A.3 Sectoral value added and its components in percentages for the EU-27 in 2001

Sector

Share

value added

Relative

TFP-growth

Low-skilled

labour

High-skilled

labour

Physical

capital

R&D capital

Agriculture, oil and minerals 2.7 1.8 48 6 26 1

Energy carriers a 2.2 1.0 17 16 62 2

Food products 3.4 1.1 31 15 53 1

Textiles and wearing apparel 1.1 1.6 51 18 31 1

Wood and other manufacturing 0.9 1.3 45 18 36 1

Pulp, paper and publishing 1.7 1.1 37 28 34 1

Chemicals, rubber and plastics 3.3 2.3 35 19 30 15

Non-metallic minerals 1.2 1.5 38 19 41 2

Basic metals 2.6 1.7 45 24 29 2

Electronic equipment 1.9 1.7 39 16 21 24

Transport equipment 2.5 1.7 46 14 15 25

Other machinery and equipment 4.7 1.6 37 33 23 7

Research and development 1.3 1.7 13 77 11 0

Transport services 4.2 1.3 43 25 32 0

Construction b 4.7 0.6 60 2 37 0

Trade services 13.0 0.8 42 22 36 0

Communication 2.5 2.5 21 40 39 0

Financial services b 4.1 0.8 23 46 31 0

Other business services b 11.9 0.8 16 32 51 0

Other services 30.3 0.6 28 42 30 0

Source: Lejour et al. (2006). Note that numbers larger (smaller) than 1 imply that sectoral TFP grows faster (slower) than average

(macro) TFP a Relative TFP growth is imposed due to missing data b Relative TFP growth is set equal to that in other services, because underlying data delivered (implausible) negative growth.

Sectoral value added

Sectoral value added is created by the input of labour, physical capital, and R&D capital and the

production technology. The second column of table a.3 shows the share of manufacturing in

macro value added for the EU-27: 23 %. This number is small compared with the 72 % of the

Page 49: CPB Document - Purdue University

49

services sectors. The largest manufacturing sectors are the combined machinery an equipment

sector (9 %) and the chemicals, rubber and plastics sector (3 %).

Table A.3 gives also numbers for the EU-27 on the input shares of value added. Only modest

variation exists across the manufacturing sectors for low-skilled labour (31 % - 51 %), high

skilled labour (14 % -33 %) and physical capital (15 % - 41 %). In contrast, the R&D

endowments are highly concentrated in the sectors electronic and transport equipment, and in

the sector chemicals, rubber and plastics.

In the scenarios, the quantities of the inputs of value added will change and so will value added.

Not only changes in the input quantities, but also changes in the efficiency of the production

technology will determine the change in value added. TFP growth depends on the scenario

characteristics, but we introduce common trends for the relative sectoral TFP growth. These

numbers show that TFP growth is relatively high in telecommunications, agriculture, and most

manufacturing sectors. It is very low or negligible in most service sectors, except transport and

communications.

Energy use by firms

As can be seen in table a.4, the energy intensive sectors are: energy carriers itself (23.2%),

agriculture (5.1%), paper, pulp and publishing (4.1%), chemicals, rubber and plastics (10.5%),

non-metallic mineral products (8%), basic metals (6.0%) and, as is to be expected, transport

services (21.6 %). The output of these sectors is likely to expand as a result of the improvement

in energy efficiency. The other manufacturing sectors are hardly more energy-intensive than the

services sectors (except transport), most notably the machinery and equipment sectors.

Table A.4 Value share of energy costs as % of total production costs in 2001 for the EU-27

Agriculture, oil and minerals 5.1 Transport equipment 0.9

Energy carriers 23.2 Other Machinery and equipment 0.8

Food products 1.9 Research and development 1.2

Textiles and wearing apparel 2.2 Transport services 21.6

Wood and other manufacturing 1.6 Construction 0.4

Pulp, paper and publishing 4.1 Trade services 1.7

Chemicals, rubber and plastics 10.5 Communication 0.9

Non-metallic minerals 8.0 Financial services 0.6

Basic metals 6.0 Other business services 0.9

Electronic equipment 0.6 Other services 1.1

Source: Dimaranan et al. (2005).

Page 50: CPB Document - Purdue University

50

Trade and trade barriers

The sectoral trade pattern for the EU-27 members in the year 2001 can be read from table a.5.

Of all the exports from the EU-27, 77 % originates from the manufacturing sectors and 71 % of

the imports consists of manufacturing, in particular the sectors chemicals, rubber and plastics,

and the combined machinery and equipment sectors. Compared with the agriculture and

services sectors, the manufacturing sectors export large parts of their production output.

Similarly, also large parts of the domestic demand for manufacturing products comes from

imports. Particularly high exports shares (percentage output) and imports shares (percentage

absorption) are found for the sectors textiles and wearing apparel, chemicals, rubbers and

plastics, and the combined machinery and equipment sectors. Changes in this trade pattern will

emerge as a result of differences in trade prices between regions. The elasticity of substitution

determines the sensitivity of the trade patterns for price differences. In table a.5 can be seen,

that relatively high values for the manufacturing sectors are specified, which implies more

intensive price competition on international trade markets for these sectors than for services

sectors.

Table A.5 Characteristics for trade with the EU-27 in 2001

Sector

Substitution

elasticity

Export share in

output

Export share in

total exports

Import share in

absorption

Import share in

total imports

Agriculture, oil and minerals 5.4 15 2.3 30 5.8

Energy carriers 6.9 10 1.7 17 3.0

Food products 5.0 16 5.0 15 4.7

Textiles and wearing apparel 7.5 39 3.8 43 4.8

Wood and other manufacturing 7.1 36 3.0 35 2.9

Pulp, paper and publishing 5.9 20 2.7 19 2.4

Chemicals. rubber and plastics 6.6 42 12.9 38 10.8

Non-metallic minerals 5.8 22 2.0 19 1.7

Basic metals 7.1 26 6.4 26 6.4

Electronic equipment 8.8 48 7.4 53 8.8

Transport equipment 6.3 52 13.1 48 11.1

Other machinery and equipment 8.0 50 18.5 46 15.9

Transport services 3.8 17 6.7 18 6.7

Construction 3.8 2 0.6 2 0.6

Trade services 3.8 4 2.4 4 2.7

Communication 3.8 7 0.7 8 0.7

Financial services 3.8 7 1.7 6 1.6

Other business services 3.8 12 6.4 11 6.5

Other services 3.8 2 2.7 2 2.9

Source: WorldScan

Page 51: CPB Document - Purdue University

51

Import and export prices are determined by the prices of production, although import and export

taxes (both of the tariff and non tariff type) and transport costs also influence import and export

prices. Changes in these taxes and in transport costs will be specific for the scenarios.

The elimination of import and export tariffs resulting from the EU enlargement have been

incorporated in both scenarios. However, import and export tariffs outside the EU-27 remain,

especially for the agricultural and manufacturing sectors. We will introduce various forms of

trade liberalisation on a regional and global scale in the scenarios.

We have incorporated non-tariff barriers (NTBs) in the model. These NTBs are important

not only in services, but also in manufacturing and agriculture. Quantification of the NTBs is

done in a straightforward manner: we assume for 2001 a non tariff barrier of 20 % (as ratio of

import value) for all sectors and regions, which can be reduced in time with the size depending

on the specific scenario, region and sector.

Page 52: CPB Document - Purdue University

52