Corporate Governance Myths Comments on Armstrong, Guay, And Weber - Brickley, Zimmerman

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • University of Rochester

    William E. Simon Graduate School of Business Administration

    The Bradley Policy Research Center Financial Research and Policy

    Working Paper No. FR 10-29

    September 1, 2010

    Corporate Governance Myths: Comments on Armstrong, Guay, and Weber

    James A. Brickley Simon School, University of Rochester

    Jerold L. Zimmerman Simon School, University of Rochester

    This paper can be downloaded from the Social Science Research Network Electronic Paper Collection:

    http://ssrn.com/abstract=1681030

  • Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1681030

    Corporate Governance Myths: Comments on Armstrong, Guay, and Weber*

    James A. Brickley Jerold L. Zimmerman

    William E. Simon Graduate School of Business University of Rochester

    September 21, 2010

    ABSTRACT

    This paper argues that academics, politicians, and the media have six commonly held but misguided beliefs about corporate governance. While Armstrong, Guay, and Weber (2010) discuss some of these misconceptions, a wider recognition that these beliefs are actually myths is important. They include: (1) a common definition of corporate governance exists; (2) a useful distinction is internal versus external governance mechanisms; (3) outside directors perform two separable roles: to advise and monitor managers; (4) research has identified good and bad governance practices; (5) a good governance index can be constructed; and (6) corporate governance best practices can be deduced from peer data.

    Keywords: corporate governance, financial accounting, agency costs, contracting, debt contracts JEL codes: D21, D23, J33, K22, L14, L20, M40, M41

    * We thank Chris Armstrong, Michael Graham, Wayne Guay, Thomas Lys, Eben Moulton, Candy Obourn, Cliff Smith, Joe Weber, and Mark Zupan for comments on earlier drafts.

    1

  • Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1681030

    Armstrong, Guay and Weber (2010) (AGW) review research on the role of

    information and financial reporting in corporate governance and contracting and offer a

    number of compelling insights and suggestions for further work. Rather than providing a

    detailed review of their paper (most of which we agree with), we focus our remarks on

    some key themes (or myths) inherent in AGWs survey and the literature in general.

    AGW and the research literature have recognized some of these myths, while

    others have received little or no attention. We first describe six myths that pervade much

    of the corporate governance research in not just accounting, but also in finance,

    economics, and the legal literatures (section 1). In particular, we highlight six commonly

    held, but misguided, beliefs that are reflected in this literature, and then offer some

    specific comments on AGW (Section 2). Wider recognition that these beliefs are actually

    myths is potentially important, not only for academic researchers but also for politicians,

    regulators, the media and general public.

    1. Six Common Myths about Corporate Governance

    Myth 1: General agreement exists on the definition of corporate governance

    Corporate governance, is a frequently used term by academics, business

    managers, regulators, the media and the general public. Indeed, it is so commonly used

    that commentators often fail to define it. For example, various textbooks on corporate

    governance do not define the term explicitly, either in their texts or glossaries.1

    Similarly, while some corporate governance researchers define the term, others do not.

    AGW (p. 7) view corporate governance as the subset of a firms contracts that help align

    the actions and choices of managers with the interests of shareholders (emphasis added).

    Other researchers use different definitions. For example, Larcker, Richardson and Tuna

    (2007) define the term more generally as the set of mechanisms that influence the

    decisions made by managers when there is separation of ownership and control (p 964).

    It is important for researchers, as well as others, to recognize there is no general

    agreement on the definition of corporate governance and correspondingly to take care in

    defining the term. This choice can have important implications both on the direction and

    interpretation of the research AGW being a case in point.

    1 For example, see Weston, Siu and Johnson (2001).

    2

  • Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1681030

    A simple web search reveals many different definitions of corporate governance.

    While common definitions focus on the separation of ownership and control at the top of

    the corporation, some focus narrowly on the control function of the board of directors,

    and others include a wide range of control mechanisms (boards, incentive compensation,

    auditors, analysts, credit rating agencies, banks, regulators, courts, media, customers, and

    so on). Some commentators take the perspective that the objective of governance is to

    maximize shareholder wealth, while others take a broader stakeholder/social perspective.

    The choice of definitions is important because it can influence the focus,

    structure, and interpretation of the subsequent analysis. For example AGW, who define

    the term narrowly, focus their attention in their governance section (section 3) on the

    board of directors and executive compensation contracts. While they subsequently

    discuss other important contracts, such as debt contracts, except for section 3.2 they do

    not stress the governance implications of these contracts on aligning managers and

    shareholders interests. In contrast, Larker et al. (2007), who define the term more

    broadly, focus not only on the structure of the board and design of compensation

    contracts, but also on other governance mechanisms, including active and institutional

    investors, debt contracts, and anti-takeover policies.

    We think it is useful to employ a broad definition of corporate governance.

    Focusing on the separation of ownership and control at the top levels of the corporation is

    reasonable. However, limiting attention to just boards and top executives ignores

    potential conflicts among various classes of shareholders (see section 4 of AGW).

    Separation of ownership and control can also exist among shareholders, since cash flow

    and control rights need not be identical. In many corporations, particularly outside the

    US and UK, the primary governance problem is controlling incentive conflicts between

    inside-majority and outside-minority shareholders (Bebchuk and Weisbach, 2009). Thus,

    it is useful to include all three of the firms top-level decision makers in the definition:

    shareholders, the board, and key executives.

    Corporate law, government regulation, the corporate charter and by-laws, and

    corporate policy determine the allocation of decision rights among these three groups

    (e.g., consider shareholder voting rights and voting procedures), and thus it is important

    to consider the legal/regulatory system, as well as corporate policies, in analyzing how

    3

  • corporations are governed. Moreover, the allocation of decision rights among the

    contracting parties varies depending on whether the firm is or is not in financial distress.

    To better understand the incentives of the top-level decision makers, one must

    look beyond compensation policy and shareholder/board monitoring. Multiple parties

    and mechanisms (including, auditors, regulators, credit rating agencies, stock analysts,

    courts, the media, monitoring by banks and other creditors, regulation, the markets for

    corporate control, product market competition, and corporate policies relating to

    takeovers) influence the behavior of the top-level decision makers in the corporation.

    Some of these mechanisms are complements, while others are substitutes. To draw

    inferences about how top-level decision makers in a particular firm are likely to act in a

    particular situation requires a general equilibrium analysis that incorporates all material

    contracts.

    We find the following very broad definition particularly useful: corporate

    governance is the system of laws, regulations, institutions, markets, contracts, and

    corporate policies and procedures (such as the internal control system, policy manuals,

    and budgets) that direct and influence the actions of the top-level decision makers in the

    corporation (shareholders, boards, and executives). Of particular importance in this

    system are: 1) the allocation of top-level decision making rights among the three groups,

    and the comprehensive set of mechanisms that 2) measure their performance and 3)

    provide performance-based rewards and penalties. We refer to these elements as the

    firms Top-Level Organizational Architecture (Brickley, Smith and Zimmerman,

    2009). The actions of top-level decision makers are a primary determinant of firm value.

    This definition focuses attention on these important decision makers, the specific

    decisions each is allowed to make, and the comprehensive set of incentives they face in

    making these decisions.

    Our preferred definition of corporate governance, based on the Jensen and

    Meckling view that the firm is the nexus of contracts (also see Coase 1937), includes all

    significant formal and informal contracts that affect the behavior of top-level decision

    makers, not just those between debt holders and the firm but also between the firm and

    4

  • senior managers.2 The definition incorporates all potential conflicts of interest including

    those between the firm and its customers and between the firm and its suppliers and

    employees. While empirically challenging to observe all of the firms contracts (and

    other control mechanisms), our definition of corporate governance draws attention to the

    potential correlated omitted variables problem inherent in all studies that just focus on a

    narrower set of agency conflicts. Stated differently, most studies test hypotheses with

    very strong ceteris paribus assumptions. Unless the researcher can observe and hence

    take into account the other contracts (both formal and informal) and other mechanisms

    described above that affect the behavior of the top-level decision makers, then it is likely

    that biased coefficients and incorrect inferences result.

    Myth 2: A useful distinction is internal versus external governance

    mechanisms

    AGW separate the analysis of corporate governance (i.e., corporate boards,

    corporate governance, and majority versus minority shareholders) from the outside

    agency costs of debt.3 This approach, common in the literature (e.g., Chew and Gillian,

    2005), bifurcates so-called internal governance mechanisms (boards and incentive

    compensation) from external governance mechanisms (auditors, security analysts,

    regulators, etc.). We have used similar classifications in some of our writings (see

    Brickley, Smith, and Zimmerman, 2009).

    Jensen and Meckling (1976) in their classic paper warn against this type of

    internal versus external distinction. They define the firm as a nexus for a set of

    contracting relationships among individuals with conflicting objectives. This perspective

    suggests that the behavior of the firm is similar to that of a market the outcome of a

    complex equilibrium process (p. 311). As Jensen and Meckling argue, viewed this

    way, it makes little sense to try to distinguish those things that are inside the firm from

    2 While all contracts potentially can affect the behavior of key decision makers, some are clearly more important than others. For example, small lease contracts and compensation contracts for rank-and-file employees unlikely affect the decision-making authority and incentives of shareholders, the board, and top-level executives. 3 In the Abstract, AGW state, We review recent literature on the role of financial reporting and information transparency in reducing governance-related agency conflicts between managers, directors and shareholders, as well as in reducing agency conflicts between shareholders and outside contracting parties, such as creditors. (Emphasis added.)

    5

  • those things that are outside it (p. 311). For example, in what sense is a contract with

    an outside director (often classified as within the firm), different from a contract with an

    auditor or creditor (often classified as outside the firm)? Rather than focusing on this

    artificial distinction, it is likely to be more productive to focus on the important questions

    of why the particular set of contracts arose, the corresponding consequences, and how

    exogenous changes (such as tax law revisions, a change in government regulation, or an

    unsolicited takeover bid) might affect the organization.4

    An important concern about classifying contracts, as either inside or outside, is

    that it tends to divert attention away from potentially important and complex interactions

    among the set of key contracts that comprise the firm. For example, AGWs have largely

    separate analyses of internal (corporate governance) and external (debt) contracts

    (see section 2 below for additional discussion regarding AGWs separate analyses of

    corporate governance and debt contracts). Corporate debt, however, is a potentially

    important mechanism for mitigating a firms free-cash-flow problem (as AGW briefly

    note) and introduces an additional set of monitors (e.g., banks, other private lenders, and

    credit rating agencies). The optimal board structure and compensation contracts are

    unlikely to be independent of these effects. Separating the analysis into shareholder-

    versus-manager and shareholder-versus-bondholder agency problems deemphasizes the

    interdependent nature of contractual choice (Begley and Feltham, 1999 and Morellec,

    2004).

    Myth 3: Outside directors serve the interests of shareholders by performing two

    distinct and separate roles: to advise and to monitor managers

    a. Common View

    As AGW state, A large theoretical and empirical literature examines the role of

    boards in serving two broad functions: 1) advising senior management, and; 2)

    4 This conclusion focuses on the classification of contracts as either internal or external to the firm. For some other purposes this classification might be useful. For example, from the boards perspective decisions, such as executive compensation, are internal, while the provisions of the Sarbanes Oxley Act are external (i.e., beyond the boards control).

    6

  • monitoring senior management (p. 13).5 Researchers commonly assume that these two

    functions are largely distinct and separable and that they potentially compete for a

    directors time. For example, Chen (2008) develops a model that shows that higher

    advising intensity is associated with lower monitoring quality and higher agency costs

    (p.1). Researchers argue that the demands for monitoring and advice, which vary across

    firms and time, are likely to be important factors in selecting board members. For

    example, Masulis et al. (2010) argue that Despite their monitoring deficiencies, foreign

    independent directors may enhance the advisory capability of boards, to the extent that

    living or working in foreign countries gives them first-hand knowledge of foreign

    markets and enables them to develop and tap a network of foreign contacts (p. 3).

    Board members are commonly classified as either inside or outside directors.

    Researchers (and others) commonly view outside directors as independent parties who

    monitor and advise managers in the interests of shareholders. According to this view, the

    primary cost of having outside directors on the board is that they are less informed than

    managers about corporate strategy. For example, AGW state that a key advantage of

    inside directors is also the key disadvantage of outside directors: specifically the

    differential costs and difficulty in ensuring that the director has adequate information

    with which to make decisions (p. 16). Similar arguments are made in the case of

    separating the roles of the CEO and Chairman of the Board the primary reason for not

    having a separate chairman is that the typical CEO is better informed that the outside

    chairman (e.g., AGW pp. 28). Much of the governance research focuses on how

    informational asymmetries between outside directors and management affect a firms

    selection of directors (e.g., the mix between inside and outside directors).

    b. Problems with the Common View

    The common view has at least three flaws. First, it fails to recognize the most

    fundamental role of the board to serve as the agent for shareholders (the ratification role

    5 It is common for researchers to ignore the advisory role of boards entirely. For example, Boone, et al. (2007) view the function of boards as ratifying and monitoring senior managers decisions, and do not consider the advising/consulting functions in explaining board size and composition.

    7

  • in decision control).6 Second, it understates the incentive problems related to having

    outside directors and independent chairmen. Third, it fails to capture what board

    members actually do and how they are selected.

    Boards Decision Making Authority

    It is inefficient for shareholders to take an active role in decision-making in a

    widely held corporation due to information, incentive, and coordination costs. Corporate

    law, regulation, and the firms chartering documents assign most of the firms decision

    rights to the board of directors. Shareholders elect the board and vote on key items such

    as changes in the corporate charter, ratification of auditors, and merger proposals.

    However, their power is limited in that they do not have the right to initiate binding

    resolutions on corporate policies, such as executive compensation, or to vote on most

    firm decisions (e.g., shareholders do not ratify the firms operating budget).7

    In practice, boards delegate substantial decision rights to executive managers

    (AGW make this point on p. 90). However, these managers would not have authority to

    purchase paper clips with company funds without the implied or expressed authority from

    the board. The board also has the right to fire the CEO. In the typical firm, the board

    maintains voting rights on key items, such as the annual budget, major capital

    expenditures including acquisitions, executive compensation, dividends, and strategic

    plans. Boards not only advise executives in their development of strategic initiatives

    they also must approve them.

    A fundamental principle in agency theory is that it is necessary to separate

    decision control and decision management when the executive is not the owner of the

    firm (Fama and Jensen, 1983). Without this separation, there would be no control over

    the agency conflict between the executive and the owners, and the owners claim would

    likely have little value. This separation is important, even if in the limit outside directors

    normally play no active role in either monitoring or advising managers. The key point is

    6 Fama and Jensen (1983) define decision management as the initiation and implementation of decisions and decision control as the ratification and monitoring of these decisions. 7 The Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act of 2010 grants additional authority to the SEC to issue requirements that if met permit shareholders to nominate directors to be included in the firms proxy materials. This law also requires publicly traded companies to conduct shareholder votes on the compensation plans for named executive officers at least every three years. However, the votes are nonbinding boards maintain the ultimate decision rights on the design of these plans. Institutional investors are required to report, at least annually, on how they voted on these proposals.

    8

  • that a board with a majority of outsiders has the latent power to monitor and replace top-

    level executives, as well as to change the strategic direction of the firm. Outside

    pressures, such as a hostile merger proposal, media/shareholder pressure, legal threats,

    and large stock price declines have the potential to stir even an inactive board into action.

    Indeed, there are numerous examples of seemingly powerful CEOs who have been fired

    by boards when sufficient external pressure to do so exists (Hermalin and Weisbach,

    1998). If boards comprised of a majority of insiders are less responsive to these

    pressures, then most firms likely have boards comprised of a majority of outside

    directors, regardless of their information environment (unless the insiders essentially own

    the firm). Even in the pre-Sarbanes Oxley era, most firms had boards with more than 50

    percent outside directors (in 1990 the typical percentage was between 60 percent and 65

    percent outside directors). By 2004, the typical percentage was closer to 70 percent;

    insiders dominated only about 10 percent of the boards (see AGW p. 21).

    Incentives of Outside Directors

    Individuals make decisions based on both their knowledge and incentives. The

    academic literature, regulators, and the public often downplay the incentive issues related

    to outside directors. For example, it is often asserted that boards with outside chairmen

    are more likely to work in the interests of shareholders.8 The academic literature, as

    summarized by AGW, also tends to abstract from the incentive issues and instead focuses

    on asymmetric information between outsiders and insiders as evidenced by their

    prediction that when outside directors face greater information acquisition and

    processing costs, they are likely to be less effective advisors and monitors, and are less

    likely to be invited to sit on boards (p. 17).

    In the Federalist Papers (#51), James Madison observed that if men were angels,

    no government would be necessary and that if angels were to govern men, neither

    external or internal controls on government would be necessary. From the shareholders

    perspective, outside directors are unlikely to be angels. Outside directors, who typically

    own few shares in the firm, have their own agendas and incentives.9 For example, they

    have incentives to shirk and to use corporate resources to increase their utility (e.g., an

    8 See Lorsch and Zelleke (2005) for a discussion of the conventional wisdom for splitting the CEO and chairman positions. 9 Bebchuk and Weisbach (2009) review the literature on the incentives of independent directors.

    9

  • outsider might favor social and political objectives over the maximization of share price).

    Outside directors can also have different risk preferences than the typical diversified

    shareholder (e.g., reputational concerns might motivate outside directors to oppose highly

    risky, but positive NPV projects). AGW discuss how Linck et al. (2008) fail to find a

    significant relation between information asymmetry and the combined roles of the CEO

    and chairman (p. 21). The costs of monitoring the monitor potentially help to explain

    why the vast majority of firms do not combine the two positions. That is, if chairmen

    provide little additional monitoring of the CEO, then there is no obvious reason to

    separate the CEO and chair roles. Stock ownership, incentive compensation, and

    reputational concerns in principle can motivate a CEO to be more concerned about

    maximizing stock price than the typical outside director or a separate chairman.

    What Outside Directors Do and How they are Selected

    A more careful consideration of what board members actually do and the criteria

    firms use to recruit them is likely to aid in our understanding of board structure.

    Rigorous evidence on these issues is limited. However, there is a large descriptive

    literature on these topics (see Adams, et al., 2009), as well as publicly available

    statements from board nominating committees and executive search firms, concerning

    their director-search criteria. These sources, along with our own experience in working

    with and serving on corporate boards, suggest that the approach in the accounting

    literature of separating a board members activities into two distinct tasks (monitoring

    and giving advice to managers) does not reflect either how board members allocate their

    time or the criteria used to recruit new directors.

    As previously discussed, a primary role of board members is to ratify and monitor

    important decisions. To perform this role, directors require knowledge of the firm and

    the ability/skill to exercise these decision rights to enhance shareholder value. They

    obtain this knowledge primarily by active participation in strategic policy setting and

    review of operations. For example, the board must ratify dividend payouts. Assessing

    whether the proposed dividend is too high or too low requires the board to understand the

    firms investment opportunity set, and the managers incentives to over- or under-invest.

    The proposed dividend may be too high because the managers mistakenly under-

    estimate the investment opportunity set. Alternatively, the proposed dividend could be

    10

  • too high because the managers are shirking and do not want to exert the extra effort to

    undertake positive NPV projects. Directors are simultaneously both advising the CEO on

    the optimum dividend policy (and ultimately ratifying the final decision) and monitoring

    the CEO as they perform their basic decision-making role (Lorsch and MacIver, 1989).

    The two functions are being performed simultaneously and are complementary. They are

    not distinct. Directors do not choose separately how much time to spend on the two tasks

    of advising and monitoring. Just because managers have greater firm-specific knowledge

    than outside directors does not negate the fact that outside directors can spot decision-

    making errors and can add value by being informed of major corporate strategic efforts.10

    Outside directors may have better, or at least different, information on the value of the

    firms investment opportunity set given their different industry/firm backgrounds.

    As an analogy, thesis advisors (or seminar participants) often offer valuable input

    into a research paper and identify problems even though they are not necessarily experts

    on the topic. In working with a student, the advisor also obtains information about the

    quality of the student and the work. Giving advice and monitoring are jointly conducted

    as the advisor performs the basic role of supervising the student. And ultimately, the

    thesis advisor must decide whether to recommend whether the thesis is acceptable (the

    monitoring role). Thesis advisors do not allocate their time between advising and

    monitoring the doctoral student. Rather, these are joint, complementary products that

    occur concurrently.

    Outside directors prepare for board meetings by reading materials supplied by

    managers. During meetings, they listen to various reports and discuss and vote on agenda

    items, such as approving the annual operating and capital expenditure budgets. They may

    also meet in executive session (without management) and from time-to-time meet with

    the CEO individually and with other members of the management team. It is through

    these activities that board members gain knowledge to make informed decisions about

    strategy, monitor the management team, and develop succession plans (Lorsch and

    MacIver, 1989, p. 181).

    10 Bowen (2008) describes boards role in policy setting as (Boards) raise questions, debate policy choices, and eventually adopt or reject recommendations brought to them by them by the president or CEO (p. 22).

    11

  • Adding an outsider to a board does not necessarily imply an increase in the

    amount of managerial monitoring or produce better decisions, since all outside directors

    are given the same basic reading material and attend many of the same meetings.

    Potentially more important than the absolute or relative number of outside directors are

    their backgrounds. Bowen (2008) argues that the right people to add to the board

    possess the traits of integrity, competence, reliability, good judgment, independence of

    mind, and dedication to the cause (p. 136), and diversity of both backgrounds and

    perspectives (p. 142). Adding a director with very similar backgrounds and experience

    to the board is unlikely to produce new insights after reviewing the same material, either

    for monitoring or advising. This suggests that there is no one person who would be an

    ideal director for all firms, since being ideal depends on the backgrounds of the other

    board members and top managers. The ideal next director also depends on the specific

    circumstances facing the firm. Having the right mix of outsiders can promote

    productive discussions and monitoring in a confidential setting.11

    Consistent with this discussion, evidence from board nominating committees and

    executive search firms indicates that firms focus their attention on getting the right mix

    of board members (e.g., in terms of experience, age, training, and geography). In contrast

    with much of the academic literature, practitioners primary emphasis in selecting new

    board members is not on monitoring skills, but on obtaining the right mix of individuals

    to promote useful discussions and decisions on corporate strategy. Nominating

    committees and search firms appear to believe that the primary differentiating factor

    among prospective board members is their potential contribution to strategy -- not

    differential abilities to monitor managers or to perform other board tasks.12 Consistently,

    the descriptive literature, which is largely based on fieldwork and surveys of board

    members, suggests that many board members view their role in strategic decision making

    as being more important than their role in monitoring managers.

    The evidence on board member roles and selection is limited, and our discussion

    of these topics is largely conjectural. We suggest, however, that deeper insights 11 There is likely to be a limited set of outsiders with the appropriate backgrounds and skills to be productive board members for any given firm. Observed board structures suggest that many firms consider individuals with prior CEO experience as particularly useful board members. 12 Some firms have added financial experts to their boards in response to requirements in the Sarbanes Oxley Act of 2002.

    12

  • concerning board structure will be obtained through a more careful consideration of the

    boards role in strategic decision-making and what it means for a given firm to get the

    right mix of board members.

    Myth 4: Research has taught us much about corporate governance, including what

    are good and bad governance practices13

    There is a substantial body of theoretical and empirical work on corporate

    governance. As summarized in AGW, accountants have published numerous papers on

    the roles that information and financial reporting play in the contracting process (e.g., in

    board design, executive compensation, and debt contracts). Armed with selected results

    from this research, prominent academics have expressed strongly worded opinions on

    what are good versus bad governance practices and have provided correspondingly

    assertive prescriptions to corporate leaders, politicians, and regulators on how to improve

    corporate governance via books, op-eds, congressional testimony, and consulting

    engagements. But have we really learned enough from our study of corporate

    governance to provide well-founded normative advice to either managers or policy

    makers? We think that the answer is no; a heavy dose of skepticism is warranted when

    academics, consultants, or regulators unconditionally classify a particular governance

    practice as good versus bad, or weak versus strong.

    The firm consists of a nexus of contracts that are jointly designed and change

    through time. A firms corporate governance system is largely defined by these various

    contracts. Unfortunately, there is no well-developed theory that encompasses the multi-

    dimensional, inter-temporal nature of the contract design problem. Existing theory

    focuses on specific, limited issues, often utilizing many simplifying assumptions. While it

    has provided useful insights, our understanding of the overall problem is extremely

    limited.

    Empirical researchers, in turn, have produced a large body of research that

    documents various correlations and associations in the data. Frequently, the authors of

    these studies stress how their results are consistent with some model or conjecture about

    corporate governance. Upon more careful reflection, however, most of these results are

    13 AGW (Section 3.4) discusses in greater detail many of the same points we make in this myth.

    13

  • also consistent with alternative explanations. Moreover, causality often is impossible to

    infer (Adams, et al., 2009). For example, Core et al. (2006) document a statistical

    association between firms with weak governance and stock market underperformance

    but conclude that other factors likely explain this association (e.g., time-period specific

    returns or differences in expected returns).

    In general, it is difficult to draw strong conclusions from this work because of the

    joint endogeneity of the observed features of the firms contracts including the

    characteristics of the firms information and accounting system. For example, Lehn et al.

    (2003) study 81 publicly traded U.S. firms surviving over the period of 1935 through

    2000. They conclude that board size and composition evolve endogenously as firms

    grow and their investment opportunities change.

    Without a more comprehensive theory, it is difficult to ascertain whether an

    observed association (e.g., between board structure and characteristics of the firms

    financial reporting system) is driven by cause and effect (and if so in which direction) or

    omitted exogenous factors that jointly determine both variables. Without additional

    assumptions, it is even impossible to tell whether two governance design features are

    complements or substitutes from the sign of their cross-sectional correlation (Holmstrom

    and Milgrom, 1994).

    While we know much more about the basic principles and descriptive facts

    pertaining to corporate contracting and financial reporting than we did 20 years ago, we

    still have very limited ability to explain or predict the specific organizational design of

    any given firm, let alone categorize whether a specific firm has good or bad

    governance.14 We expect and encourage continued research on this important topic.

    AGW (section 3.4) offer some specific research guidance. Ideally, theoretical work will

    advance to the point where more structured empirical work can be conducted.

    Unfortunately, due to the overall complexity of the problem, we do not expect substantial

    developments in the foreseeable future.

    14For example, researchers and corporate activists often classify staggered boards as bad governance because they potentially reduce the threat of a hostile takeover. Yet Mayers and Smith (2005) find that mutual insurance companies often have classified boards. Since it is impossible to acquire a mutual company, there must be other motives for staggered boards that are not currently well understood.

    14

  • Myth 5: A good governance index can be constructed

    A firms governance system consists of multiple components (board structure,

    compensation structure, auditors, the corporate charter, debt contracts, government

    regulation, etc.). Presumably, the quality of a firms governance does not depend on just

    one component, but its overall system of governance. Following Gompers et al. (2003),

    many researchers have constructed indices to rank firms based on their overall quality of

    governance. Consultants and the media have produced similar indices.15 But can a

    meaningful measure of good governance really be constructed? We think the answer is

    no.

    To construct an index of good governance, the typical researcher or consulting

    firm selects a set of key governance variables and classifies each in terms of contributing

    to good or bad governance (e.g., large board size is often classified as bad, while a

    high percentage of outside directors is classified as good). The variables are then

    weighted and summed to form the index. A common practice in this literature is to

    express each of the governance characteristics as a dummy variable; the index is then

    formed by their simple sum (e.g., if there are ten variables the index would range from 0

    to 10). The index is then used as the key explanatory variable in testing whether the

    quality of governance is related to performance or economic outcomes, such as an

    accounting restatement. Or, consulting firms estimate the weights by regressing some

    performance measure (stock returns or accounting return on assets) on the governance

    variables (board composition, board size, number of meetings, etc.).

    These approaches are highly problematic for at least three reasons. First, as we

    have already discussed, a firms entire governance system is endogenous (see AGW,

    especially section 3.4). Without additional structure, the driving forces behind any

    observed associations among endogenous variables (such as a governance index and

    performance) are impossible to determine. Second, the current state of knowledge is not

    sufficient to allow us to classify meaningfully any specific governance feature (or

    combination of features) as either good or bad. Third, extant research similarly does not

    allow us to select a meaningful set of weights (i.e. we do not know the relative

    15 For example, see RiskMetrics Group (formerly Institutional Shareholders Services), Governance Metrics International (GMI), and The Corporate Library (TGL).

    15

  • importance of various governance mechanisms and how the weights might vary across

    firms).

    Larcker, et al. (2007) discuss the potential problems caused by arbitrarily

    weighting a limited set of government mechanisms to form a governance index. They

    collect a variety of structural measures of corporate governance on a large sample of

    firms and use principal components analysis to identify numerous dimensions of

    governance. Based on past work, they rate each of these dimensions as either increasing

    in bad or good governance. These variables are then used as explanatory variables to

    determine if there is an association between good and bad governance and firm

    performance (and outcomes, such as accounting restatements).

    While Larker et al. (2007) is arguably an improvement over past work, it is

    subject to many of the same criticisms. Curiously, after critiquing the existing literature

    as being potentially biased, they turn around and rely on this literature to classify their

    indices as reflecting either good or bad governance. As one example, they classify board

    size as increasing in bad governance based on Yermack (1996). Interpreting

    Yermacks results in this manner, epitomizes succumbing to Myth #4 believing that

    governance features can be meaningfully rank ordered, as either good or bad, based on

    existing empirical work. In reflecting on the documented board size/performance

    association, Hermalin and Weisbach (2002) question why so many large boards continue

    to exist in a competitive marketplace if they are as inefficient as claimed in much of the

    governance literature. They reasonably conclude that the observed negative relation

    between performance and board size potentially reflects an equilibrium phenomenon

    not cause and effect.16 Similar concerns can be expressed for all the other classifications

    made by Larcker et al. (2009). As these authors note, they are also unable to address

    entirely concerns about the joint endogeneity of firm governance and performance.

    Myth 6: Corporate governance best practices can be deduced from peer data

    Practitioners and researchers often assess a firms corporate governance relative

    to a peer group. For example, managers and analysts try to infer best practice from the

    16 In fact Lehn et al. (2007) conclude that firm performance (measured by market-to-book ratios) causes popular governance indices (GIM and BCF) to increase, not vice versa.

    16

  • governance practices used by the preeminent firms in the economy or a particular

    industry. Compensation committees use peer-group comparisons to make decisions on

    the level and form of executive compensation, while the SEC requires firms to present

    peer-group comparisons in proxy statements. The Department of Treasury, the Federal

    Reserve Board, and the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation intend to actively

    monitor the actions being taken by banking organizations with respect to incentive

    compensation arrangements and will review and update this guidance as appropriate to

    incorporate best practices that emerge (emphasis added).17 Provisions of the Dodd-

    Frank Act of 2010 are based on popular notions of best practices (e.g., those relating to

    incentive compensation and board committees). Some academics have concluded that

    specific governance practices are good or bad based on estimated associations

    between industry-adjusted performance and firm-specific governance features, such as

    the structure of executive compensation (e.g., see Bebchuk, et al. 2009).

    We do not argue that all benchmarking of governance practices is useless or that it

    should never be performed. It is a myth, however, to assume that best practices can be

    deduced readily from peer data. In fact, benchmarking can be highly misleading and can

    lead to erroneous inferences.

    The basic problem in deducing best practices from benchmarking exercises

    arises from using an inappropriate peer group. Valuable benchmarking exercises require

    identifying a peer group with similar agency problems and corporate structures that can

    offer meaningful comparisons. However, basic economics suggests it is not easy to

    identify homogeneous peers. Profit-maximizing firms often adopt differentiating

    business strategies. The more successful (and profitable) a firm, the less likely it faces

    perfect competitors. Flourishing firms face few direct competitors and have evolved

    optimal governance structures that allow them to implement successfully their

    differentiating business strategies. For example, the firms business strategy drives its

    optimal investment, capital structure, outsourcing, and vertical integration policies. A

    firm jointly chooses these policies, along with its governance structure, endogenously.

    Emulating the governance structure of a best of breed firm is unlikely to prove useful

    to other firms in the same industry. Without copying the peers business model (which

    17Department of Treasury et al. (2010), p. 17.

    17

  • seems unlikely because successful firms remain successful precisely because they have

    erected meaningful entry barriers such as patents or brand name), the benchmarking firm

    very likely follows a different business model/strategy. There is little reason to believe

    that the benchmarking firms business model generates exactly the same set of agency

    problems as the best of breed, and therefore it is unlikely that both share exactly the

    same set of optimal governance methods. Stated differently, the more a firm can

    differentiate itself from its competitors, the less benchmarking will prove useful in

    assessing that firms governance structure.

    On the other hand, if all firms in the industry are identical in terms of following

    identical business strategies, competing for the same customers, and operating in the

    same regulatory environment, then they face very similar (identical) agency problems.

    But if these firms are identical in all dimensions, they are likely to evolve through

    competition to similar governance practices, unless alternative practices are neutral

    mutations (value irrelevant). In either case, benchmarking industry best practices is

    unlikely to be prove useful. It is of course possible for identical firms to adopt inefficient

    governance practices (due to imperfect information or an environmental change that

    makes a long-standing practice inefficient). It is within very homogeneous industries

    (i.e., one or two firms have successfully innovated best governance practices) where

    industry benchmarking is likely to prove productive. However, it is still important to

    consider carefully whether the change is appropriate for a given firm. For example,

    Armour and Teeces (1978) study of diffusion of the multidivisional form of organization

    in the oil industry suggests while this innovation was value-increasing for most firms in

    the industry, some firms were better off not changing (smaller and less complex firms).

    Boards of directors have an advantage in industry benchmarking compared to

    academics, regulators, and consultants. Boards typically know which peers employ

    similar business models, strategies, and customer bases, and thereby share a common set

    of agency problems. Hence, boards likely are able to assess better than researchers and

    regulators why different governance structures exist within a peer group and whether

    adopting a particular governance mechanism is value enhancing for their firm.

    Absent detailed knowledge of each firms competitors, academics, regulators, and

    outside consultants typically rely on pre-defined industries to construct peer groups such

    18

  • as the Standard Industry Classification (SIC), North American Industry Classification

    System (NAICS), Global Industry Classifications Standard (GICS), or Fama and French

    industries (1997). It is well known that such pre-defined industry classifications

    misclassify firms.18 For example, heavy equipment producers for the oil and gas

    industry, producers of video games, manufacturers of lawn mowers, and makers of

    personal computers share the same two-digit SIC code (Bernard and Skinner, 1996),

    while SIC code #53 contains a mix of low and high-end retailers, including Wal-Mart,

    Target, Kohls, and Neiman Marcus. Dopuch, et al. (2008) document that these four

    firms, even though classified in the same two-digit SIC industry, have significantly

    different cash generating processes and operating cycles.

    Bhojraj, et al. (2003) report the average R2 between a firms monthly stock return

    and the monthly return of an equally weighted portfolio of all the firms in its industry is

    at most about 26 percent when using any of the common industry classification schemes

    (SIC, NACIS, GICS, or Fama-French industries). Likewise, industry sales growth,

    leverage, and price-earnings ratios are able to explain on average no more than 15 to 20

    percent of the variation in the same variable at the individual firm level.19 Hence, three

    quarters of the variation in monthly stock returns, sales growth leverage, and PE ratios is

    NOT explained by industry-wide events. This evidence suggests that considerable

    heterogeneity exists among firms even in the same standard industry classification.

    Given that substantial firm-specific heterogeneity exists within most standard

    industry classifications, firms within these industries likely have evolved very different

    optimal governance structures. It is hard to envision that Wal-Mart, Neiman Marcus, and

    Kohls share a common optimal governance structure. Hence, any inferences regarding

    the optimality of any given firms corporate governance structure based on industry

    benchmarks are likely to be incorrect. A significant deviation in some governance

    practice from the industry average is just as likely to be the result of a difference in the

    firms business model from the average business model in the industry as it is a

    difference from an optimal governance structure. In turn, cross sectional variation in

    18 For example see, Clarke (1989), Guenther and Rosman (1994), Kahle and Walkling (1996), Fan and Lang (2000), Ramnath (2001), Krishnan and Press (2003), and Bhojraj, et al. (2003). 19 In particular, Bhojraj, et al. (2003) estimated time series models at the firm level where firm-level sales growth, leverage, and PE ratios were regressed on the same equally weighted industry variable.

    19

  • performance among firms within an industry may well be driven by differences in

    competitive advantage, rather than by differences in governance practices.

    Several studies reach similar conclusions regarding a single optimal governance

    structure. Linck, et al. (2008) find pronounced differences in the determinants of board

    structure between small and large firms (p. 326) and go on to conclude that our results

    show strong relations between board structure and firm characteristics, suggesting that

    any regulatory framework that imposes uniform requirements on board structure could be

    ill-conceived ( p. 327). Likewise, Coles, et al. (2008) posit that boards provide both

    monitoring and advising roles (see Myth 3 above). They conclude that complex firms

    (i.e., diversified firms, large firms, or highly leveraged firms) likely have greater advising

    requirements) and are more likely to benefit from a larger board of directors, particularly

    from outside directors who possess relevant experience and expertise, while firms for

    which the firm-specific knowledge of insiders is relatively important, such as R&D-

    intensive firms, are likely to benefit from greater representation of insiders on the board

    (p. 351).20

    1. Comments on AGW While discussants can always quibble about a survey papers organization and the

    papers included and excluded in the review, we begin by stressing that we agree with

    much of AGW. In particular, we endorse AGWs call for more careful consideration

    (and more research) of endogeneity and causality issues by accounting researchers

    studying corporate governance issues. In addition, we echo their major theme that

    informal contracts are important, and often overlooked components of corporate

    governance. Nonetheless, this argument should be extended to include managerial

    reputation and repeat business as likely significant policing mechanisms that constrain

    managerial rent seeking behavior. Consider the following experience of a retired CEO,

    Most of our products were custom-made. Customers called in their orders over the

    phone. The customers word alone was enough. In my 20-year stint as CEO, not once

    20 One consulting firm that eschews the existence of best practices is Grahall. This firm states, There is no such thing as best practices. The only best practices are those that work best for your company. (Grahall 2009, p. 23)

    20

  • did a customer go back on it. Unusual? Not at all. Without such trust, business couldnt

    be conducted.21

    Besides the preceding observations, we have two additional comments on AGW.

    First, as discussed under Myth #2 (A useful distinction is internal versus external

    governance mechanisms), AGW have largely separate discussions of how financial

    reporting is used in corporate governance (section 3) and debt contracting (section 5).22

    We appreciate the enormity of the task AGW have assumed in writing their survey and

    understand the pedagogical advantages of structuring their review around corporate

    governance and debt contracting. However, these two major sections of the paper are not

    well integrated, and are written as almost standalone papers. While section 3.2.6 (how

    outside directors mitigate agency costs of debt) and section 3.2.8 (how debt acts as a

    commitment device for financial reporting transparency) are a good start to integrate their

    two major themes, the remainder of section 3 ignores the interaction between the agency

    costs of the separation of ownership and control and the agency costs of debt. Section 5

    only references governance four times. AGW (p. 55) conclude that few studies exist

    on how financial reporting by creditors influences the agency problem between directors

    and managers and how financial reporting substitutes or complements monitoring by the

    firms creditors. Nonetheless, we believe that a productive line of inquiry would involve

    the interaction among financial reporting and other mechanisms designed to control

    manager-shareholder conflicts and shareholder-debt holder conflicts. Stated differently,

    instead of examining just the role of financial reporting in mitigating managerial

    opportunism or examining the role of financial reporting in mitigating agency costs of

    debt, future research should explore how financial reporting complements or substitutes

    for other mechanisms to control both agency problems in a more general equilibrium

    setting.

    Second, one important governance mechanism excluded by AGW in their review

    is how competition in a firms product markets affects corporate governance and debt

    contracting. On the one hand, managers facing very competitive product markets have

    little free cash flow to expropriate, and hence strong governance mechanisms are less

    21 Aaron (1994) p. A14. 22 Section 4 of AGW is a terse, but interesting review of the agency problems between majority and minority shareholders.

    21

  • important.23 On the other hand, surviving firms in highly competitive product markets

    must adopt cost minimizing production methods, including governance and organization

    costs. Therefore, these firms require effective governance systems. Hence, it strikes us

    that the role of product market competition in corporate governance is an empirical issue.

    While the role of product market competition has been explored in the theoretical

    and empirical executive compensation and incentives literature (for example, see Raith,

    2003 and Karuna, 2003), accounting-based corporate governance research has generally

    ignored this potentially important implicit governance device. This omission is

    particularly important to accounting researchers studying corporate governance because

    various characteristics of the financial reporting system such as transparency, timeliness,

    and conservatism likely affect both the ability of the board and shareholders to monitor

    managers and entry by potential competitors. For example, the voluntary disclosure

    literature usually views proprietary costs (entry by potential competitors) as a constraint

    on firms voluntary disclosures (Darrough and Stoughton, 1990 and Verrecchia, 1990).

    Without controlling for the correlated-omitted-variables-problem of potential entry (i.e.,

    product market competition), researchers might erroneously conclude that an observed

    statistical association between an endogenous financial reporting characteristic and a

    corporate governance measure is causal.

    2. Conclusions To explain all nature is too difficult a task for any one man or even for any one age. Tis much better to do a little with certainty, and leave the rest for others that come after you, than to explain all things. Isaac Newton 24

    While Newton was addressing research in the natural sciences, we believe his

    views apply equally to social science research in general and specifically corporate

    governance research. As reviewed by AGW, accountants (and other researchers) have

    produced a large body of research on corporate governance. We have discussed six

    commonly held beliefs that are reflected in this literature, which we believe are

    misguided. Our intent is not to criticize past researchers for failing to develop a 23 Firms in competitive product markets can still have quasi rents (i.e., firm-specific investments) that short horizon managers can expropriate. 24 Statement from unpublished notes for the Preface to Opticks (1704) quoted in Never at Rest: A Biography of Isaac Newton (1983) by Richard S. Westfall, p. 643.

    22

  • comprehensive model and understanding of the complex topic of corporate governance.

    Echoing Newton, to explain all of corporate governance is too difficult a task for any

    one man or even for any one age. Nonetheless, since Berle and Means (1932)

    researchers have improved our understanding of agency problems and the associated

    control mechanisms. AGW offer a number of specific suggestions for advancing our

    understanding of the role of financial reporting in mitigating agency problems. Our

    intent is to emphasize the conceptual and empirical impediments that require attention.

    Greater sensitivity to the view that these beliefs are myths potentially could lead to

    more productive future research, as well as more careful interpretation of existing work.

    It could also prove useful in the regulatory process and to other audiences. Meanwhile, it

    is important not to make overly strong or misguided claims about how a given firm

    should design its governance system. Tis much better to do a little with certainty, and

    leave the rest for others that come after you, than to explain all things.

    23

  • References

    Aaron, H. (1994), The Myth of the Heartless Businessman, The Wall Street Journal (February 7), A14. Adams, R., 2000. The Dual Role of Corporate Boards as Advisors and Monitors of Management: Theory and Evidence, Working paper, Federal Reserve Bank of New York. Adams, R., Mehran, H., 2002. Board structure and banking firm performance. Working paper, Federal Reserve Bank of New York. Adams, R., B. Hermalin, and M. Weisbach, 2009. The Role of Boards of Directors in Corporate Governance: A Conceptual Framework & Survey Working paper, Ohio State University. Armour, H., and D. Teece, 1978. "Organization Structure and Economic Performance: A Test of the Multidivisional Hypothesis." Bell Journal of Economics 9:10622. Armstrong, C., W. Guay, and J. Weber, 2010. The Role of Information and Financial Reporting in Corporate Governance and Debt Contracting, Working paper, University of Pennsylvania and Massachusetts Institute of Technology (March 14). Bartov, E., Gul, F., Tsui, J., 2000. Discretionary-Accruals Models and Audit Qualifications, Journal of Accounting & Economics 30, 421-452. Bebchuck, L.A, M. Cremers and U. Peyer, 2009. The CEO Pay Slice, Working paper, Harvard Law School, NBER, Yale School of Management and INSEAD. Bebchuk, L. and M. Weisbach, 2009. The State of Corporate Governance Research, Working paper, Harvard University and NBER.

    Begley, J. and G. Feltham, 1999. An empirical examination of the relation between debt contracts and management incentives, Journal of Accounting and Economics 27, 229-259. Bernard, V., Skinner, D., 1996. What motivates managers choice of discretionary accruals?, Journal of Accounting & Economics 22, 313-325. Bhojraj, S., C. Lee, and D. Oler, 2003. Whats My Line? A Comparison of Industry Classification Schemes for Capital Market Research, Journal of Accounting Research 41, 745-774. Boone, A., L. Casares Field, J. Karpoff, and C. Raheja, 2007. The Determinants of Corporate Board Size and Composition: An Empirical Analysis, Journal of Financial Economics 85, 66101.

    24

  • Bowen, W., 2008. The Board Book: An Insiders Guide for Directors and Trustees, (W. W. Norton & Company, New York). Brickley, J., C. Smith, and J. Zimmerman, 2009. Managerial Economics and Organizational Architecture, Fifth edition (McGraw-Hill, Boston). Chen, D., 2008. The Monitoring and Advisory Functions of Corporate Boards: Theory and Evidence, Working paper, University of Baltimore. Chew, D. and S. Gillian, 2005. Corporate Governance at the Crossroads, A Book of Readings (McGraw-Hill Irwin, New York). Clarke, R., 1989. SICs as Delineators of Economic Markets, Journal of Business 62, 1731. Coase. R.H.. 1937. The Nature of the Firm, Economica. New Series, IV, 386305. Reprinted in: Readings in Price Theory (Irwin, Homewood, IL) 331-351. Core, J., W. Guay, and T. Rusticus, 2006. Does Weak Governance Cause Weak Stock Returns? An Examination of Firm Operating Performance and Investors' Expectations, Journal of Finance 61, 655-687. Darrough, M. and N. Stoughton, 1990. Financial Disclosure Policy in an Entry Game, Journal of Accounting and Economics 12, 219-243. Defond, M.L., Park, C.W., 1999. The effect of competition on CEO turnover, Journal of Accounting and Economics 27, 3356. Department of Treasury, Federal Reserve Board, Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, and Office of Thrift Supervision, 2010 Guidance on Sound Incentive Compensation Policies, http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/press/bcreg/bcreg20100621a1.pdf Engel, E., R. Hayes, X. Wang, 2003. CEO Turnover and Properties of Accounting Information, Journal of Accounting and Economics 36,197226 Fama, E., and K. French, 1997. Industry Costs of Equity, Journal of Financial Economics 43, 15393. Fama, E., and M. Jensen, 1983. Separation of Ownership and Control, Journal of Law and Economics 26, 301-325. Gompers P., J. Ishii, and A. Metrick, 2003. Corporate Governance and Equity Prices, Quarterly Journal of Economics 118, 107-155. Grahall, 2009. Executive Rewards: 2009 Research Series.

    25

  • Guenther, D., and Rosman, 1994. Differences between COMPUSTAT and CRSP SIC Codes and Related Effects on Research, Journal of Accounting and Economics 18,11528. Hermalin, B., and M. Weisbach, 2003. Boards of Directors as an Endogenously Determined Institution: A Survey of the Economic Literature, Economic Policy Review 9, 7-26. Holmstrom, B., and P. Milgrom, 1994. The Firm as an Incentive System, American Economic Review 84, 972-991. Hribar, P., and C. Nichols, 2006. The use of unsigned earnings quality measures in tests of earnings management, Working paper, Cornell University. Jensen, M., and W. Meckling, 1976. Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency Costs and Ownership Structure, Journal of Financial Economics 3, 305-360. Kahle, K., and R. Walkling, 1996, The Impact of Industry Classifications on Financial Research, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 31, 30935. Karuna, C., 2007. Industry Product Market Competition and Managerial Incentives, Journal of Accounting and Economics 43, 275297. Larcker, D., S. Richardson, and I. Tuna,2007. Corporate Governance, Accounting Outcomes, and Organizational Performance, The Accounting Review 82, 963-1008. Lehn, K., S. Patro, and M. Zhao, 2003. Determinants of the Size and Structure of Corporate Boards: 1935-2000, Working paper, University of Pittsburgh (November). Lehn, K., S. Patro, and M. Zhao, 2007. Governance Indexes and Valuation: Which Causes Which? Working paper, University of Pittsburgh (April). Linck, J., J. Netter, and T. Yang, 2008. The Determinants of Board Structure, Journal of Financial Economics 87, 308-328. Lorsch, J. and E. MacIver, 1989. Pawns or Potentates (Harvard Business School Press, Boston). Lorsch, J. and A. Zelleke, 2005. Should the CEO Be the Chairman? MIT Sloan Management Review 46 (Winter), 71-74. Masulis, R., C.Wang, and F. Xie, 2010. Globalizing the Boardroom - The Effects of Foreign Directors on Corporate Governance and Firm Performance, Working paper, Vanderbilt University.

    26

  • Mayers, D. and C. Smith, 2005. Agency Problems and the Corporate Charter, Journal of Law Economics and Organization 21, 417-440. Morellec, E., 2004. Can Managerial Discretion Explain Observed Leverage Ratios? Review of Financial Studies 17, 257-294. Raith, M., 2003. Competition, Risk, and Managerial Incentives, American Economic Review 93 (September), 1425-36. Verrecchia, R., 1990. Information Quality and Discretionary Disclosure, Journal of Accounting and Economics 12 (1990) 365-380. Weston, J., J. Siu and B. Johnson, 2001. Takeovers, Restructuring, and Corporate Governance, Third Edition (Prentice Hall, Upper Saddle River, NJ). Yermack D., 1996. Higher Market Valuation of Companies with Small Boards of Directors, Journal of Financial Economics 40, 185-211. Westfall, R., 1983. Never at Rest: A Biography of Isaac Newton (Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK).

    27