34
Contests with Revisions Emmanuel Dechenaux Kent State University Shakun Mago University of Richmond

Contests with Revisions - University of Technology Sydney · 2019. 7. 15. · We consider two types of winner-take all contests that differ in the “marginal effectiveness of effort”

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    0

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • Contests with Revisions

    Emmanuel DechenauxKent State University

    Shakun MagoUniversity of Richmond

  • Informational Leakage in Competitive Settings

    Bernie Sanders campaign gained access to sensitive information about Clinton

    campaign during 2016 Democratic Presidential Primary due to an error by a third party

    Consultant or contractor have several clients; some of whom are competitors

    Potential for consultant or contractor to leak information to client about competitor’s

    R&D strategy (Baccara, 2007)

    Industrial Espionage

    WestJet vs. Air Canada

    Unilever vs. Procter and Gamble

  • Consider a scenario where:

    initially players make choices simultaneously

    but probabilistically, one player is given the chance to fully revise her choice after

    seeing his rival’s choice

    How does the possibility of information leakage affect expenditure in a contest?

    • Impact on ex-ante expenditure (prior to leakage)?

    • Incentives to revise ex-post (after leakage)?

    Does the recipient of the information benefit from the ability to revise?

    • Does informational leak gives a strategic advantage to the informed player?

    • Does varying the likelihood of informational leak affect the degree of strategic

    advantage?

  • We consider two types of winner-take all contests that differ in the “marginal

    effectiveness of effort” or “degrees of competition.”

    All-pay auction

    vs.

    Lottery contest

    2 x 2 design that compares different degrees of strategic advantage (high vs.

    low probability of informational leakage) with different degrees of

    competition (all-pay vs. lottery).

  • Motivation and Background Model and Predictions Design and Procedures Results Conclusion

    The GameTwo players A and B compete for a single prize of V.

    Two rounds:

    Round 1: Choose xA1 and xB simultaneously

    Round 2: Type A chooses xA2; occurs with probability α

    Random draw

    Outcome is

    determined

    using xA1 and

    xB

    1−α α

    5 / 57

    Player A

    chooses

    xA1

    Player B

    chooses

    xB

    For Player A: she sees xB

    → can revise: chooses xA2

    which may or may not be

    equal to xA1

    Outcome is

    determined

    using xA2 and xB

  • In the all-pay auction, the CSF is deterministic and given by

    𝑝𝑖(𝑥𝑖 , 𝑥𝑗 ) = 1 if xi > 𝑥𝑗0 𝑖𝑓𝑥𝑖 < 𝑥𝑗

    In the lottery contest, the CSF is probabilistic and given by

    𝑝𝑖(𝑥𝑖 , 𝑥𝑗 ) =𝑥𝑖

    𝑥𝑖+𝑥𝑗

  • All-Pay Auction: Equilibrium

    Assume both players are risk neutral

    Simultaneous moves game in round 1 is an asymmetric APA where Type A’s

    valuation is V and Type B’s valuation is (1 −α)V (multiple equilibria)

    In round 1: Both players use non-degenerate mixed strategies randomize on

    the support 0, 1 − α V

    In round 2: Type A wins for sure

    Equilibrium expected expenditures:

    𝐸 𝑥𝐴1𝐴𝑃𝐴 =

    1 − 𝛼 𝑉

    2𝐸 𝑥𝐵

    𝐴𝑃𝐴 =(1 − 𝛼)2𝑉

    2𝐸[𝑥𝐴2

    𝐴𝑃𝐴] =(1 − 𝛼)2𝑉

    2

  • Value of Flexibility

  • Equilibrium Predictions

    V=100 Probability of Informational Leak

    𝛼 = 0.25 𝛼 = 0.75

    All-pay auction

    Player A - Round 1 37.5 12.5

    Player B - Round 1 28.1 3.1

    Player A - Round 2 28.1 3.1

    Probability of Revision 1 1

    Value of Flexibility 36.72 91.41

    Lottery

    Player A - Round 1 25 25

    Player B - Round 1 25 25

    Player A - Round 2 25 25

    Probability of Revision 0 0

    Value of Flexibility 0 0

  • Hypothesis 1. For both levels of α, in round 1: 𝑥𝐴1𝐴𝑃𝐴 > 𝑥𝐵

    𝐴𝑃𝐴 and 𝑥𝐴1𝐿 = 𝑥𝐵

    𝐿

    All-pay: Type A expenditure ≥Type B expenditure

    Lottery: Type A expenditure = Type B expenditure

    Hypothesis 2. For both types of players, 𝑥𝐴𝑃𝐴 0.25 > 𝑥𝐿 0.25 = 𝑥𝐿 0.75 > 𝑥𝐴𝑃𝐴 0.75

    All-pay: Average expenditure is higher when α is lower

    Lottery: Average expenditure does not depend on α

    Hypothesis 3.

    Frequency of revisions in all-pay auction ≥ lottery contest

    In both contest, frequency is independent of α

    Hypothesis 4. Value of Flexibility:

    All-pay: Type A player’s average payoff ≥ Type B player’s average payoff

    Lottery: Type A player’s average payoff = Type B player’s average payoff

    Hypotheses

  • Behavior in All-pay auction and Lottery contests

    Overexpenditure relative to risk neutral equilibrium in both contests (Dechenaux et al., 2015; Sheremeta, 2013)

    Large Dispersion in Lottery contests (Sheremeta, 2013; Mago et al., 2013; Konrad and Morath, 2019)

    Bimodal bidding in All-pay auction (Gneezy and Smordinsky, 2000)

    Leader-follower games

    Lottery contest: Fonseca (2009)

    All-pay auction: Liu (2018); Jian et al. (2017)

    Comparison of All-pay auction vs. Lottery

    Davis and Reilly (1998), Faravelli and Stanca (2014); Chowdhury et al. (2019)

    Strategic asymmetry: Observability and value of commitment

    Bagwell (1995); van Damme and Hurkens (1997); Huck and Normann (2000); Morgan and Várdy (2004,

    2007)

  • Experimental Design

    Number

    of sessions Contest

    Periods

    1-20

    Periods

    21-40

    Subjects

    per session

    4 All-pay auction 𝛼 = 0.25 𝛼 = 0.75 8

    4 All-pay auction 𝛼 = 0.75 𝛼 = 0.25 8

    4 Lottery 𝛼 = 0.25 𝛼 = 0.75 8

    4 Lottery 𝛼 = 0.75 𝛼 = 0.25 8

    Experiment conducted at VSEEL (Purdue University)

    128 subjects participated

    A typical session:

    Parts 1 and 2: Risk aversion and Loss aversion

    Part 3: Contest, 20 periods, either α = 0.25 or α = 0.75

    Part 4: Contest, 20 periods, change α

    Part 5: Simultaneous moves contest for V = 0 (“joy of winning”)

    Part 6: Demographics and emotions questionnaire

    Lasted ≈ 90 minutes, average earnings = $25.95

  • Experimental Design – Each Period

    • Random assignment of player types – Type A or Type B

    • Random Matching

    • Quasi-Strategy Method

    Round 1:

    Type A chooses xA1 and Type B chooses xB

    Round 2:

    Type A sees xB and chooses xA2 “in case round 2 is reached”

    Type B makes a guess about xA2

    Round 1 or round 2 is randomly drawn (based on α)

  • Decision Screen in Round 1

  • Decision Screen for Type A in Round 2

  • Decision Screen for Type B in Round 2

  • Outcome Screen

  • Equilibrium Comparison

    Result 1A: Expenditure levels are

    higher than the equilibrium prediction.

    All-Pay Auction

  • Equilibrium Comparison

    Result 1B: Expenditure levels are

    higher than the equilibrium prediction.

    Lottery Contest

  • Treatment Effects: 𝛼

    All- Pay Auction Lottery Contest

    Result 2: In the all-pay auction, round 1 expenditure for both players is lower when probability of

    informational leakage, 𝛼 = 0.75.In Lottery contest, round 1 expenditure by both types of players is independent of 𝛼.

  • Treatment Effects: Player type

    All-Pay Auction Lottery Contest

    Result 3: In round 1, there is no significant difference in the average expenditure of type A player

    and type B players.

  • Distribution – Lottery Contest

    Player A Player B

    Contrary to the subgame perfect equilibrium in pure strategies, we find individual

    expenditure ranges from 0 to 100 with large standard deviations.

    𝛼 = 0.25 𝛼 = 0.75

    Equilibrium Observed Equilibrium Observed

    Type A 25 45.71*** (31) 25 40.76** (33)

    Type B 25 44.76*** (35) 25 45.49*** (34)

  • Distribution – All-pay auction

    Player A Player B

    Mass point at zero is part of the Pareto dominant equilibrium

    for type B player, but not for type A player.

    Type B players: anticipation of the “all-pay loser regret”

    (Hyndman et al. 2012); “calm-down effect” (Konrad and

    Leininger, 2007; Jian et al., 2017)

    Type A players: Over-placement (Jian et al., 2017)

    𝐸𝑥𝑝𝑒𝑛𝑑𝑖𝑡𝑢𝑟𝑒 𝑏𝑒𝑡𝑤𝑒𝑒𝑛 0 𝑎𝑛𝑑 5

    𝛼 = 0.25 𝛼 = 0.75

    Type A 20%*** 37%***

    Type B 34% 44%***

    Bimodal bidding (Gneezy and Smorodinsky,

    2006; Ernst and Thöni (2013)

  • Distribution – All-pay auction

    Player A Player B

    It is possible to construct Pareto-dominated equilibria in which

    type B player places a mass point at 100.

    A combination of utility of winning and fairness concerns likely

    drive some of these choices, especially when 𝛼 = 0.75

    𝐸𝑥𝑝𝑒𝑛𝑑𝑖𝑡𝑢𝑟𝑒 𝑏𝑒𝑡𝑤𝑒𝑒𝑛 95 𝑎𝑛𝑑 100

    𝛼 = 0.25 𝛼 = 0.75

    Type A 5% 6%

    Type B 8% 19%

  • Likelihood of Revision

    Equilibrium Prediction

    All-pay auction Pr (Revise| 𝛼) = 1

    Lottery Contest Pr(Revise| 𝛼) = 0

    Observed Rate of Revision

    (a) More frequent revisions in the all-pay auction than in the lottery contest.

    (b) In the all-pay auction, the frequency of revisions does not depend on the probability of informational

    leakage. In the lottery contest, increasing α has a small but positive impact on the likelihood of revisions.

    𝛼 = 0.25 𝛼 = 0.75

    All-pay 0.89 0.86 p-value = 0.33

    Lottery 0.67 0.74 p-value = 0.03

  • Dependent Variable

    = 1 if 𝒙𝑨𝟏 is revised and = 0

    otherwise

    Random Effects

    (1)

    Round 1 variables

    (2)

    Subject Covariates

    (3)

    Dummy for α = 0.75 0.0661** 0.0846** 0.0625*

    (0.03) (0.03) (0.04)

    1/Period-0.0901 -0.111 -0.134

    (0.08) (0.14) (0.08)

    Dummy for α = 0.75 played first -0.0563 -0.0587 -0.0819

    (0.06) (0.06) (0.06)

    (Absolute) Distance to Best

    Response

    0.0107*** 0.0109***

    (0.003) (0.003)

    Distance to Best Response

    Squared

    -0.000109*** -0.000114***

    (0.00003) (0.00003)

    Dummy for 𝑥𝐴1 > 𝑥𝐵-0.157*** -0.165***

    (0.04) (0.04)

    Risk Tolerance-0.0453***

    (0.02)

    Loss Tolerance0.0147

    (0.01)

    Expenditure for Prize of Zero0.000718

    (0.001)

    Female-0.00392

    (0.06)

    Number of Observations 1280 1248 1044

  • Round 2: Revisions in All-Pay Auction

    Rate of revision = 0.88 (vs. predicted value of 1)

    Examine the difference between Player A and Player B’s

    expenditure: Only 0.01, 0 and −100 should be observed

    Most of the revised expenditure is equal to the best response.

    Difference in

    Expenditure

    α = 0.25 α = 0.75

    0.01 - 5 83.1 74.8

    0 0.9 1.3

    -100 2.5 8.2

    Total 86.5 84.3

    All

    observations

    Revised

    Expenditure

  • Revisions in Lottery Contest

    Best Response Function: 𝑅𝐴(𝑥𝐵) = 10 𝑥𝐵 − 𝑥𝐵

    Regression Equation: 𝑥𝑖,𝑡 = 𝛽0 + 𝛽1𝑥−𝑖,𝑡 + 𝛽2 𝑥−𝑖,𝑡 + 𝛽3(1/𝑡) + 𝜀𝑖,𝑡

    Dependent variable: 𝒙𝑨𝟐All Observations Revised Expenditure

    𝜶 = 𝟎. 𝟐𝟓 𝜶 = 𝟎. 𝟕𝟓 𝜶 = 𝟎. 𝟐𝟓 𝜶 = 𝟎. 𝟕𝟓

    𝑥𝐵-0.548** -0.661*** -0.607** -0.596***

    (0.21) (0.17) (0.25) (0.18)

    𝑥𝐵

    8.090*** 10.26*** 10.04*** 10.49***

    (2.02) (1.56) (2.29) (1.46)

    1/Period17.38 34.95*** 18.91 22.86*

    (10.82) (8.37) (11.53) (13.21)

    Constant 17.85*** 11.85*** 7.423* 8.832***

    (5.02) (3.91) (3.77) (3.31)

    Number of Observations 640 640 434 476

    R-square 0.0959 0.203 0.192 0.242

  • Revisions in Lottery Contest

    “Outspending the rival” even slightly drives a lot of

    type A players’ expenditure choices.

    • 72% of the choices are above type B player’s round

    1 expenditure choice.

    For both levels of 𝛼, revised expenditure levels are significantly higher than the risk neutral best

    response function.

    All

    observations

    Revised

    Expenditure

  • Revisions in Lottery Contest

    Is the revised expenditure levels closer to the best response compared to the initial expenditure?

    57% when 𝛼 = 0.25 46% when 𝛼 = 0.75

    Conditional on moving in the direction of the best response, how does type A player’s round 1

    expenditure compare to their rival’s?

    When 𝑥𝐴1 > 𝑥𝐵 77% of the time Player A moves in the direction of the best response.

    When 𝑥𝐴1 < 𝑥𝐵 33% of the time Player A moves in the direction of the best response.

    Conditional on moving away from the best response, are subjects more likely to increase their

    expenditure?

    90% when 𝛼 = 0.25 91% when 𝛼 = 0.75

  • Value of Flexibility: Is Type A better off than Type B?

    We define the value of flexibility as the difference between Player A’s and Player B’s expected payoffs

    Δ𝐴𝑃𝐴 =𝛼𝑉

    23 − 𝛼2 Δ𝐿 = 0

    • The value of flexibility is higher in the all-pay auction than in the lottery contest.

    • In both contests, the value of flexibility is increasing in the probability of informational leakage.

    Contest 𝜶 = 𝟎. 𝟐𝟓 𝜶 = 𝟎. 𝟕𝟓

    Predicted Observed Predicted Observed

    All pay auction

    Type A's winning rate in round 1 0.625 0.59 0.875 0.56

    Type A's winning rate in round 2 1 0.96 1 0.89

    Value of flexibility 36.72 19.79 91.41 66.37

    Lottery

    Type A's winning rate in round 1 0.5 0.53 0.5 0.49

    Type A's winning rate in round 2 0.5 0.58 0.5 0.6

    Value of flexibility 0 7.04 0 18.24

  • Conclusion: Study the effect of informational leakages and revisions in contests

    Initial Expenditure Levels.

    𝛼 has a strong impact on expenditure in the all-pay auction, but not in the lottery contest.

    𝑥𝐴𝑃𝐴 0.25 > 𝑥𝐿 0.25 = 𝑥𝐿 0.75 > 𝑥𝐴𝑃𝐴 0.75

    The likelihood of revision.

    In the All-pay auction, likelihood of revision does not depend 𝛼In the Lottery Contest, increasing 𝛼 has a small positive impact on the likelihood of revision

    Revised Expenditure levels.

    In the All-pay auction, revised expenditure levels are consistent with best response.

    In the Lottery Contest, revised expenditure levels are significantly higher than best response.

    The value of flexibility.

    In the all-pay auction, value of flexibility is positive but less than predicted.

    In the lottery contest, value of flexibility is significantly higher than predicted when 𝛼 = 0.75Value of flexibility is higher in the all-pay auction vs. lottery contest