60
Conservation of the Sundarbans in Bangladesh through Sustainable Shrimp Aquaculture Soham G. Sen March 14, 2010 Client: Director, Nishorgo Project, Department of Forestry Bangladesh SYPA Section Advisor: Michael Walton Technical Advisor: Rohini Pande Second Year Policy Analysis Paper submitted in fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Master of Public Administration in International Development

Conservation of the Sundarbans in Bangladesh through ... of the Sundarbans in Bangladesh through Sustainable Shrimp Aquaculture Soham G. Sen March 14, 2010 Client: Director, Nishorgo

  • Upload
    vunga

  • View
    216

  • Download
    1

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Conservation of the Sundarbans in Bangladesh through Sustainable Shrimp Aquaculture

Soham G. Sen

March 14, 2010

Client: Director, Nishorgo Project, Department of Forestry – Bangladesh SYPA Section Advisor: Michael Walton

Technical Advisor: Rohini Pande

Second Year Policy Analysis Paper submitted in fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Master of Public Administration in International Development

i

Acknowledgments

No project of this kind is ever possible without the kindness and support of many people and this one

was no exception.

I benefited tremendously from the guidance and encouragement of my wonderful advisors at the

Harvard Kennedy School. Particular thanks go to my SYPA advisors Michael Walton and Rohini Pande. I

must also mention in gratitude Matt Andrews, my academic advisor, and Lant Pritchett who stepped in

whenever asked in the role of general advisor.

I was also fortunate indeed to have the support of several kind people at the World Bank particularly

Ernesto Sanchez-Triana in Washington who pointed me in the direction of the Sundarbans and Shakil

Ahmed Ferdausi, in Dhaka, who kindly hosted me during my field visit to Bangladesh. I cannot name all

the Bank staff who generously shared their time and insights, but I must mention the tireless work of

Nadia Sharmin who arranged my meetings in Dhaka and my journey to the Sundarbans.

There were again too many government officials, statisticians, shrimp farmers, and businessmen to

thank in Bangladesh, but I would like to express my appreciation generally to all who made the time to

speak with me and bore patiently with my anglicized Bengali. A special thanks to the people on the edge

of the forest. It was an honor to be allowed to peek into your lives and work, and I hope our paths cross

again someday in a better future.

Next, I would like to acknowledge the generous support from the Ash Institute for Democratic

Governance and Innovation at the Harvard Kennedy School which made the field visit possible.

Finally, any list of acknowledgement would be incomplete without a kind word of thanks to all those

who help in ways as important but perhaps less direct. Thanks to my fellow MPA/IDs and HKS colleagues

who listened, advised, or poured drinks throughout the process. And Carol Finney, MPA/ID program

director extraordinaire, deserves a general thanks for everything MPA/ID. Last but certainly not least, a

warm note of gratitude to my mom, dad, and sister: without you none of this would have been

possible.

While the guidance and advice I have received has been extraordinary and flawless, the work below is

certainly not. It has been a grand exercise in advancing my own learning if not producing outputs

valuable to others; wherever it falls short, it does so for my faults alone.

ii

Table of Contents

I. Executive Summary ............................................................................................................................ 1

II. The Need for a New Approach to Managing the Sundarbans: Thinking Outside of the Forest .............. 2

A. Importance of the Sundarbans and the Case for Conservation ..................................................... 2

B. The Command and Control Approach to Sundarbans Management: Not Enough ......................... 5

C. Causes of Degradation Inside the Sundarbans from Outside the Forest ........................................ 7

D. Why the Forest Department should Focus on Poverty .................................................................. 9

E. What can be done? Motivating Assumptions ............................................................................. 11

III. The Promise of Shrimp Aquaculture .................................................................................................. 12

A. The Returns to Shrimp Aquaculture ........................................................................................... 12

B. The International Market for Shrimp .......................................................................................... 13

C. Shrimp Industry in Bangladesh ................................................................................................... 14

D. Degradation Continued Despite Shrimp Aquaculture ................................................................. 15

IV. Sundarbans Management and the Nishorgo Program ....................................................................... 16

A. Public Value and Jurisdiction ...................................................................................................... 16

B. Technical and Administrative Capacity ....................................................................................... 17

C. Political and Institutional Environment....................................................................................... 18

V. Why Shrimp Aquaculture has not Delivered ...................................................................................... 19

A. Uneven Distribution of Employment and Wages ........................................................................ 19

B. Direct and Indirect Impacts of Shrimp Production on the Sundarbans ........................................ 29

VI. Fixing a Broken Promise: Towards Sustainable Aquaculture .............................................................. 32

A. What Can the Nishorgo Project Do? ........................................................................................... 32

B. Considerations in Promoting a Switch to Golda Production ........................................................ 36

C. How to Switch from Bagda to Golda? Policy Options .................................................................. 41

VII. Appendix ....................................................................................................................................... 44

A. SYPA Table ................................................................................................................................. 44

B. Estimating the Implications of Input Subsidy .............................................................................. 44

C. Field Visit to Bangladesh ............................................................................................................ 47

D. Additional Figures and Charts .................................................................................................... 48

E. Bibliography ............................................................................................................................... 51

iii

Table of Figures

Figure 1 - Inside the Sundarbans .............................................................................................................. 2

Figure 2 - The Sundarbans in Bangladesh (CEGIS 2006) ............................................................................ 3

Figure 3 - Tree Species in the Sundarbans (1995) ..................................................................................... 4

Figure 4 - Bangladesh Protect Areas Compared to Neighbors and World (Source: UNEP) ......................... 6

Figure 5 - Protected Areas of Bangladesh................................................................................................. 6

Figure 6 - Tree coverage (Iftekar and Islam 2004) .................................................................................... 7

Figure 7 - Trees per hectare (FAO 2000) ................................................................................................... 7

Figure 8 - Changes in Forest Composition (CEGIS 2006) ........................................................................... 7

Figure 9 - Change in Illegal Felling in the Sundarbans (Bangladesh FD) ..................................................... 8

Figure 10 - The Districts Containing the Sundarbans .............................................................................. 10

Figure 11 - Population Growth and Livelihoods in the Impact Zone ........................................................ 10

Figure 12 - Returns from Shrimp, Rice, and Wage Labor ........................................................................ 13

Figure 13 - Volume of Shrimp Imports 1950-2000 .................................................................................. 13

Figure 14 - Quantity and Value of Shrimp Produced ............................................................................... 13

Figure 15 - Price of Shrimp 1990 – 2004 (FAO) ....................................................................................... 14

Figure 16 - The Rise of Frozen Shrimp Exports to Bangladesh (DoF, 2001) .............................................. 15

Figure 17 - Productivity (kg/ha).............................................................................................................. 15

Figure 18 – Shrimp Area Khulna ............................................................................................................. 15

Figure 19 – Types of Shrimp Produced ................................................................................................... 15

Figure 20 - MOEF in the Bangladesh Budget (Source: Bangladesh Ministry of Finance, Author’s

Calculations) .......................................................................................................................................... 18

Figure 21 -- Value Chain Diagram (Souce: USAID) ................................................................................... 20

Figure 22 – Simplified Shrimp Value Chain ............................................................................................. 20

Figure 23: Detailed Shrimp Value Chain (USAID/Bangladesh 2006) ........................................................ 21

Figure 24: Saltwater Shrimp Production. Author and Interviews ............................................................ 23

Figure 25 - Sluice Gate System ............................................................................................................... 23

Figure 26 - Bagda Gher and Trip............................................................................................................. 24

Figure 27 - Shrimp Trap ......................................................................................................................... 24

Figure 28 - Returns to Bagda Farming .................................................................................................... 24

Figure 29 - Golda Farm .......................................................................................................................... 26

iv

Figure 30 - Golda Farm with Rice Adjacent............................................................................................. 26

Figure 31 - Returns to Golda Farming .................................................................................................... 26

Figure 32 - Employment Along the Value Chain (Author Calculations and (USAID/Bangladesh 2006)) .... 29

Figure 33 - Income Along the Value Chain (Author Calculations and (USAID/Bangladesh 2006)) ............ 29

Figure 34 – Comparison of Income and Employment Dispersion (Author Calculations and

(USAID/Bangladesh 2006)) .................................................................................................................... 29

Figure 35 - Mr. Rafiquzzaman, Bagda Farmer near Hadda ...................................................................... 36

Figure 36 - Mr. Mullah, Golda Farmer in Doomoria ................................................................................ 36

Figure 37 - Bagda Suitability Map (CEGIS) .............................................................................................. 37

Figure 38 - Actual Bagda Growth (CEGIS) ............................................................................................... 37

Figure 39 - Golda Suitability Map (CEGIS) ............................................................................................... 38

Figure 40 - Actual Golda Growth ............................................................................................................ 38

Figure 41 - The SYPA-Meter ................................................................................................................... 44

Figure 42 - Services Provided by the Sundarbans (Iftekar and Islam 2004) ............................................. 48

Figure 43 - Extreme Poverty and Travel to Dhaka(BBS 2009) .................................................................. 48

Figure 44 - Hadda FD Post Showing Captured Boats ............................................................................... 49

Figure 45 - Hadda FD Post Showing Illegal Felling ................................................................................... 49

Figure 46 - Growing stock of Sundarbans decreasing (FAO 2000) ........................................................... 49

Figure 47 - Composition II (Iftekar and Islam 2004) ................................................................................ 49

Figure 48 - Shrimp Producing Countries and Market Share (Leung and Eagle 2006) ............................... 50

Figure 49 - Bangladesh Growth in Frozen Shrimp Volume ...................................................................... 50

1

I. Executive Summary

This second year policy analysis paper observes that the command and control approach of the Forest

Department of Bangladesh toward managing the Sundarbans mangrove forest has been unsuccessful. The

Sundarbans, a treasured UNESCO World Heritage Site, have degraded steadily over time. This paper argues

that the Forest Department needs to “think outside of the forest” and address the primary causes of

degradation nearly all of which fall outside the forest. It adopts the perspective of the Nishorgo Program that

was created within the Forest Department to develop and implement strategies to co-manage areas like the

Sundarbans with the involvement of key stakeholders.

While there are many significant factors that are responsible for forest degradation, the paper focuses on a

factor that the Nishorgo Program is most able to influence: the high levels of poverty in the dense population

of over 6 million people that live just outside of the forest in the three districts that contain the Sundarbans.

The forest is degrading due to the dependence of nearly 1.35 million people who earn a living by selling

materials extracted from the forest. The paper argues that conservation of the Sundarbans requires an

alternative livelihood that generates sufficient income for this vulnerable population to curb their

dependence on the forest.

While in many other parts of the world an alternative is not easily available, the same region outside the

Sundarbans hosts one of the most dynamic sectors of the Bangladeshi economy: shrimp aquaculture. This

promising alternative livelihood has developed over the past three decades. Today it accounts for 5% of GDP,

over $300M in exports and 1.2 million jobs. Yet perplexingly, over this time period, forest degradation has

continued, and poverty has remained much the same. This paper examines the shrimp value chain to explain

that productivity is much lower than in other countries; that jobs generated in the industry are poorly, paid

and a majority of earnings accrue to a small number of participants; and that shrimp production itself can

have significant environmental impacts.

The analysis also explores important differences between the saltwater and freshwater shrimp production.

The freshwater variety is found to create more jobs for the poor, be more productive, less costly to produce,

yield higher returns, and have a smaller environmental footprint. The paper proceeds to examine the

feasibility and benefits of switching saltwater shrimp farmers to freshwater and determines that such a

switch would be possible for a majority of the farmers. It concludes with a recommendation to the Nishorgo

Program to facilitate such a switch through the subsidy of an important input for freshwater shrimp

production. The result of such a switch could convert shrimp aquaculture into the alternative livelihood that

people at the edge of the forest need to curb their dependency on the Sundarbans.

2

II. The Need for a New Approach to Managing the Sundarbans: Thinking Outside

of the Forest

A. Importance of the Sundarbans and the Case for Conservation

1. The Sundarbans

To the uninitiated traveler, passing through the endless pastoral scenes of rice fields and shrimp ponds

in the southwestern districts of Bangladesh, the Sundarbans appear abruptly on the horizon – as if by

mistake. The wall of dense greenery seems out of place in the otherwise treeless, delta landscape where

the mighty Ganges, Jamuna, and Mehna rivers finish their long journey down from the Himalayan

Mountains and empty into the Bay of Bengal. Inside the forest is even stranger, the mangrove trees

have adapted to the unique environment of annual flooding, daily tidal fluctuations and the mixture of

saltwater from the Bay and freshwater from the rivers. From the low oxygen soil, the tree roots

protrude sharply up from the ground warning intruders to handle with care the immense biodiversity

that lies within. Some 300 species of plants, 120 types of fish, 300 unique birds, and 32 mammals

including the famous Royal Bengal tiger live in the Forest (Iftekar and Islam 2004). A soft light penetrates

the canopy from where a multitude of birds sing over a herd of deer moving to the water hole. At first

glance, the forest is as the Bengali language name given it implies, a “beautiful (sunder) forest (bon).”

Figure 1 - Inside the Sundarbans

At a second glance however, one begins to notice things amiss; empty spots where trees once were

become apparent. Or, many of the tall trees look as if their tops have been charred by flame. Historical

records give further cause for concern. Less than two hundred years ago, the forest is thought to have

extended along the Bay from Calcutta to the east, to Burma to the west, and nearly to Dhaka to the

3

north (Iftekar and Islam 2004). The forest would not have looked out of place in the delta landscape, it

would have dominated it. Today, the Sundarbans cover significantly less territory (See Figure 2) spanning

just over 10,000 km2 across India and Bangladesh along the Bay of Bengal and still form the world’s

largest mangrove forest. Of the total territory, approximately 577,100 ha (6,017 km2) fall in Bangladesh;

407,100 ha are mangrove forest and 170,000 ha are waterways (CEGIS 2006).

Despite the fact that nearly a quarter of the world’s tropical coastline, across 112 countries has some

mangrove habitation, the mangrove forest is rare. The total area is between 15.6 to 17 million hectares

(ha) out of total worldwide forest cover of 3,952 million ha (FAO 2007).

Figure 2 - The Sundarbans in Bangladesh (CEGIS 2006)

Forest Composition

It is important to note at the outset that, just as the mangrove forests comprise of many different

animal species, there are numerous tree species as well which are quite different from each other in

significant ways; some can be used for firewood and others not while some have commercial value

while others not. The key point is that conservation of the mangroves is not simply a question of

conserving total forest area, but also forest composition (Salafsky and Wollenbert 2000). In the

Sundarbans, there are nearly thirty species of threes, but three species dominate (CEGIS 2006):

4

(1) The Sundri (Heritiera fomes) gives the forest its name and thrives in more freshwater areas. The

species covers 21% of the Sundarbans as pure forest and 46% as the dominant species in a

mixed forest. In total the Sundri accounts for 10.6 million cubic meters, or 64%, of the total

merchantable volume of the forest. It is a large tree and is the primary source of saw-timber

used for a variety of construction purposes; it can also be used as fuel-wood.

(2) Gewa (Excoecaria agallocha), which is more able to resist saltwater, survives in moderately

salty water zones. The species covers 5% as pure forest and 38% as mixed which accounts for

17% of total volume of the forest. The Gewa is used for pulpwood, matchwood, and bailing.

(3) Goran (Ceripos decandra), which is more a shrub than tree, thrives in the salt-water zone. It

covers 2% of the Sundarbans as pure forest and 14% as mixed. Goran is typically only used for

fuel-wood.

Figure 3 - Tree Species in the Sundarbans (1995)

2. What is the significance of the Sundarbans?

The Sundarbans are important not just to the people that live nearby, the forest provide innumerable

services which are important to Bangladeshis as well as the international community. Over 41% of the

country’s forest revenue (FAO 1998) comes from the Sundarbans. It is also vital to delta region as the

only natural physical barrier to the devastating cyclones and tidal waves that occur frequently.

Mangroves also provide the nursery and breeding habitat which support half of all off-shore commercial

fish stocks. Internationally, the forest became recognized as a UNESCO World Heritage site in 1997 due

to it’s incredible biodiversity. Also, the mangrove forests as a whole sequester 25.5 million tons of

5

carbon dioxide - the main cause of climate change – each year (Miththapala 2008). A comprehensive

overview study of 13 other valuations of mangrove systems, puts the services they provide at between

$1,000 to over $11,000 per hectare annually (Primavera 1997).

B. The Command and Control Approach to Sundarbans Management: Not Enough

The Sundarbans have been under active management for much of recent history by whichever authority

has administered the delta region that Bangladesh now occupies. The Bengal Forest Department of the

British Colonial Administration, applied the Indian Forest Act of 1865 to declare the Sundarbans a

Reserve Forest in 1878 (Millat-e-Mustafa 2002). The end of the British colonial era brought partition to

the sub-continent, and Bengal and the Sundarbans were not spared. 60% of the forest was transferred

to East Pakistan in 1947 which Bangladesh after the independence war in 1971.

While the political world changed much around the Forest, its administration has remained remarkably

consistent up to the present day. The Forest Department (FD) -- specifically, the Sundarbans Division of

the FD (ADB 1998) – brought under the newly created Ministry of Environment and Forests in 1989

(World Bank 2006), continues to manage the forest using the same “command and control policy” as it

did under during the colonial era. The thrust of the policy continues to be one where the forest is

cordoned off as a reserve forest and then entry, exit, and economic activity are controlled through

policing and licenses. If there has been any change, it has been to cordon off more of the forest and

specifically protect wildlife or particular trees. For example, parts of the Sundarbans were declared a

Wildlife Sanctuary in 1974 to conserve animals as well as trees. A moratorium on felling of the dominant

Sundari tree was enacted in 1989, and UNESCO declared the Sundarbans to be a World Heritage Site in

1997. A 20km buffer area around the forest was declared an “Ecologically Critical Area” in 2006. Finally,

after the devastation of Hurricane Aila in 2007, a ban on all forest extraction was put in place. The same

command and control policy, in other words, but taken to the extreme (FAO 2007).

1. The Degradation of the Bangladeshi Forests and the Sundarbans

Some still argue however that this policy has not gone far enough because Bangladesh is nearly at the

bottom of most environmental indicators. Proponents of this view point out that Bangladesh remains far

below Asia and World averages for the total amount of protected area (Figure 4). However, at least for

forest conservation, it seems the policy is the wrong one altogether. For even taken to its extreme as

described above, it has not prevented the forest degradation. Despite management programs in place in

protected areas across the country, deforestation and degradation has proceeded at an alarming rate of

6

3% in the 1980s and over 1% in the 1990s (World Bank 2006). Indeed, USAID and CIDA have conducted a

study concluding that 50% of the nation’s forests have been destroyed in the last 20 years (Huda and

Roy 1999) to which there is real ascribable cost. The World Bank, for example, estimates that this forest

degradation is costing Bangladesh 4% of its annual GDP (World Bank 2006).

Figure 4 - Bangladesh Protect Areas Compared to Neighbors and World (Source: UNEP)

Figure 5 - Protected Areas of Bangladesh

Similarly, the protected status of the Sundabans has served to maintain the area of the forest, but aside

from this the mangroves have been steadily degrading (FAO 1998) from nearly every conceivable

measure such as coverage, density, composition, and overall productivity. Forest cover has decreased

between 1983 and 1995 at an average annual rate of 0.12%, and average stand density of the forest has

been reduced by 87% between 1933 and 1995. Over 215,000 cubic meters of Sundari species (H. fomes),

which comprise the majority of the trees (> 50%), are suffering from top-dying disease (Iftekar and Islam

2004). Indeed it is this top dying disease that makes trees appear as if the tops have been abruptly

truncated or charred by flame. Further, the productivity of the mangrove system had already declined

by 25% in the two decades leading up 1985, and the rate is estimated to be higher for the two decades

since (Millat-e-Mustafa 2002).

0

5

10

15

20

25

Cam

bo

dia

Thai

lan

d

Ch

ina

Asi

a

Nep

al

Wo

rld

Dev

elo

pin

g

Ind

ia

Ban

glad

esh

Bu

rma

Protected Areas% of Total Country Area

7

Table 1 - Degradation of the Sundarbans

Figure 6 - Tree coverage (Iftekar and Islam 2004)

Figure 7 - Trees per hectare (FAO 2000)

Finally, it is possible to see clear changes in Sundari composition in less than a decade in Figure 8 below

which confirms the trend shown throughout the 20th century in Table 1 above which depicts the decline

in tree coverage and tree density by species.

Figure 8 - Changes in Forest Composition (CEGIS 2006)

C. Causes of Degradation Inside the Sundarbans from Outside the Forest

If the focus of the Forest Department inside the forest and the command and control policy discussed

earlier have not prevented degradation and deforestation, then the Forest Department should consider

3940

3960

3980

4000

4020

4040

4060

4080

4100

1926 1983 1996

Tree Coverage (sq km)

0

50

100

150

200

250

300

350

Trees Per Hectare

1959

1983

1996

8

addressing the causes of degradation that occur outside of the forest. The literature suggests several

such causes:

Natural processes shifting the delta east - the tectonic plate structure is such (imagine tilting a

plate of spaghetti over just slightly and watching the noodles slide toward the edge) that the

river delta is naturally shifting away from India toward Burma. This would cause the western

edge of the Sundarbans to wither away (CEGIS and IWM 2007).

Diversion of water away to India – India has build several barrages along the Ganges river which

have diverted freshwater flow towards Indian fields for irrigation and drinking water necessarily

reducing the flow into Bangladesh downstream. Loss of freshwater increases the salinity of the

delta region as the salt water from the Bay of Bengal is able to penetrate further into the delta.

India and Bangladesh have signed a treaty to share water more equitably (World Bank 2009).

Climate Change and Sea Level Rise – Climate change generally greatly threatens the Sundarbans

in the long term. The World Bank reports that even a 25cm increase in the sea level will

inundate 40% of the Sundarbans; and the World Wildlife Fund estimates the rate of increase to

be approximately 3 mm per year implying about 85 years to the partial inundation. However

while the rates and implications are contested, there seems to be a consensus on the general

trend (World Bank 2009).

Organized Illegal Felling – This continues to be a problem, but has reduced somewhat with the

extra crackdown on enforcement policies.

Figure 9 - Change in Illegal Felling in the Sundarbans (Bangladesh FD)

Finally, poverty of the region around the Sundarbans is a significant contributor to degradation

of the Sundarbans (Ambrose-Oji 2003).

9

D. Why the Forest Department should Focus on Poverty

How the Forest Department can address poverty will be the focus of this paper because while the Forest

Department can do little to affect the geological forces associated with plate tectonics, international

politics with India or global climate change, it does have a significant ability to affect the poverty in the

region around the Sundarbans. This is particularly so since many of the poor in the region depend

directly on the forest for their daily livelihood.

It is important to note that the relationship between poverty and forest degradation is not an obvious

one and depends on the nature of the forest, the density of the population living beside it, the isolation

of the population, and property rights to the forest (Chomitz 2007). In Bangladesh however, where the

population is highly dense, not isolated, and lack property rights, one would predict that poverty would

be positively associated with forest degradation. The evidence in the region bears this out as in the ADB

project (ADB 2008) and a study by the Forest Department(Karim 2008). The ADB study noted:

Communities that are reliant on the SRF [Sundarbans Reserve Forest] for subsistence

and income have no formally recognized rights of access to the forest, nor do they act

responsibly to care for the resources. Traditional user practices (e.g., seasonality of

harvesting, gender roles, awareness of the need for regeneration, etc.) have largely

broken down due to increased poverty and population pressure, lack of effective

controls, and a perceived lack of viable alternatives. The un-sustainability of many

current activities and the lack of access to productive resources on fair terms lead

directly to depletion of the SRF and to continuing poverty and inequity (ADB 1998).

1. The People of the Impact Zone

The Sundarbans are located within three districts of Bangladesh. From west to east they are Shatkhira,

Khula, and Bagerhat covering and 12,212 km2. In each district, the southern half contains the forest,

while the northern halves are home to a total population of 6.6 million (Figure 10). Given that the forest

occupies 6,017 km2 the population density of the three rural districts is about 1,066/km2. This is

extremely high for a rural region (nearly a quarter of the density of the city of London) and has increased

16% between 1991 and 2005(CEGIS and IWM 2007).

10

Source: (CEGIS 2006) and Author

Figure 10 - The Districts Containing the Sundarbans

The people of the area (hereafter the “impact zone”) have an age distribution similar to the rest of the

country where 61% are between the age of 15 – 64 (BBS 2009) and about 50% are of working age

Figure 11 - Population Growth and Livelihoods in the Impact Zone

(Mabud 2008) suggesting that nearly 3.3 million people are in the labor force. They are primarily

engaged in agricultural activities (which includes crop cultivation as well as shrimp farming), fishing,

wage labor, or other forest related activities. People do not live inside the forest, and as Figure 11b

shows, 41% or 1.35 million are depend on non-timber forest products from the forest. The main users

are (i) Bowalis (wood cutters, Golpatta collectors); (ii) fisherfolk; (iii) crab and shell collectors; (iv)

Mowalis (honey collectors); and (v) shrimp fry collectors (ADB 1998). 77% of the rural poor are at

breakeven or deficit status, and of these 18% comprise the hardcore poor who are always in deficit. And

0

2

4

6

8

Mill

ion

s

Population Near the Sundarbans

1991

2005

29.7

4.325.0

41.0

Livelihoods (% of Households)

Agriculture

Fisheries

Wage Labor

Other

11

this group, in particular, is entirely dependent on natural resources from the forest (USAID/Bangladesh-

IPAC 2008).

This region is poorer than much of the rest of Bangladesh and more isolated (Figure 43). The 1998 ADB

study found that at least 33% live below extreme poverty, that health indicators are poor, as is access to

water, sanitation services and basic infrastructure such as roads. A separate study found that families

earn between 165-416 USD annually. The bright spot is education: the literacy rate is thought to be

higher than the national average due to the effort of numerous NGOs that operate within the country

(World Bank 2009).

E. What can be done? Motivating Assumptions

The broad point and the normative assumption here is that the Forest Department cannot pursue

conservation of the Sundarbans through a command and control policy focused inside the forest; it will

need a more holistic, integrated approach to forestry management that looks outside the forest and

tackles poverty. Intellectually, environmental policy drivers in Bangladesh (typically multilateral

institutions and NGOs) seem to grasp this point, and government documents in the 1990s mark the

change. Reports referring to the Forest Policy enacted in 1994, the Master Plan enacted in 1995 (Millat-

e-Mustafa 2002) (Muhammed, Koike and Haque 2008) and project documents of several multilateral

institutions (ADB 1998) (FAO 1998) referring to integrated resource management plans (IRMP)

underscore the importance of the FD to actively engage with and manage actors and factors outside of

the forest that affect the forest. There is also some indication that the FD is actively planning to manage

land use near the Sundarbans through the Integrated Coastal Zone Management Project (Iftekhar and

Islam 2004). Finally, the Nishorgo Program of the Forest Department was created in 2004 with support

from USAID and the International Resource Group (IRG) with the stated objective of promoting a co-

management model for administering protected areas of Bangladesh including the Sundarbans by

focusing on building partnerships between the FD and key local, regional and national stakeholders.

This last is a particularly promising start, but as we will see later (in Section IV), the Nishorgo program,

like other plans leaves much doubt as to whether it can fulfill its stated mandate. But even before the

implementation stage, it is not clear that these plans and programs have sufficiently overcome the

command and control perspective to really formulate strategy to tackle the poverty around the forest

directly.

12

This paper focuses on, as the ADB report quoted above points out, the need for a viable alternative

livelihood activity to extracting forest resources. It posits that, if the Forest Department’s Nishorgo

Program can work with other stakeholders to harness the economic promise of shrimp aquaculture (the

country’s booming export industry that contributes 5% to GDP and employs 1.2 million) for the people

of the impact zone, then shrimp aquaculture can be the alternative livelihood activity that can reduce

poverty and replace the dependence of this population on the forest and promote conservation of the

Sundarbans. The remainder of the paper proceeds as follows:

(1) Section III describes why shrimp aquaculture is a promising alternative activity to replace forest

dependence.

(2) Section IV explains why the activity has not delivered on this promise so far and what the

objectives of the Forest Deparment’s Nishorgo Program should be with regard to shrimp

aquaculture.

(3) Section V examines how the Nishorgo Program works and why it is suitable for spearheading

this non-traditional forestry management effort.

(4) Section VI concludes with recommendations for the Nishorgo Program to harness shrimp

aquaculture as a means to forest conservation.

III. The Promise of Shrimp Aquaculture

Since the turn of the millennium, Aquaculture has been hailed as the harbinger of a blue revolution that

could supply most of the world’s marine products over the next three decades reducing poverty and

food shortages in poor countries just as the green revolution did with agriculture after World War II. The

downside however, is that aquaculture can cause serious environmental problems (The Economist

2003). So much so that shrimp aquaculture is typically seen as an enemy of both the forest and the

people who live outside of it. This may be for good reasons as will be the topic of Section V below,

however there are three reasons that shrimp makes sense as an alternate livelihood activity: the returns

to the activity are higher than alternatives in the area, these returns might increase over time as the

international demand for shrimp increases, and people of the area have become increasingly familiar

with the activity and therefore are better able to take advantage of their engagement in it.

A. The Returns to Shrimp Aquaculture

First, as noted in Figure 11 above, the majority of people in the impact zone cultivate rice, farm shrimp,

catch fish, work as wage laborers, or depend on forest extractions as a means of livelihood. An

13

estimation of the typical returns from these activities (Figure 12) shows that shrimp production

(particularly the fresh-water variety) yields incomes that are multiples of rice cultivation or wage labor1

(Hossain, Janaiah and Husain 2003).

Figure 12 - Returns from Shrimp, Rice, and Wage Labor

B. The International Market for Shrimp

Second, the international demand for shrimp has gone steadily and continues to trend upward driven by

demand in Japan (11%), the European Union (49%), and the United States(35%) (Figure 13) as has both

the value and quantity of production (Figure 14).

Figure 13 - Volume of Shrimp Imports 1950-2000

Figure 14 - Quantity and Value of Shrimp Produced

1 This is based on assumption that laborers earn 80 BDT per day, that 1 BDT = 70 USD, and that it is possible to find work for about half of the year.

0

500

1000

1500

2000

2500

3000

Freshwater Shrimp (50%)

Saltwater Shrimp (30%)

Rice Culture Minnimum Wages

Typical Economic Returns ($ per ha per year)

14

Still, the price of shrimp on in international markets has held quite steady (Figure 15). Despite

extraordinary growth of the shrimp industry, Bangladesh barely registers is the overall shrimp market

occupying less than 5% of the market. Furthermore, the productivity of Bangladeshi production is

exceedingly poor in comparison to its neighbors (Figure 17) suggesting that significant gains could be yet

realized (USAID/Bangladesh 2006). The upward trend in demand, steady prices despite growing supply,

poor market share, and low productivity suggests that Bangladesh could earn a more from the industry

by producing more and garnering a larger share of the world market. There are significant potential

gains from shrimp farming. Such gains could potentially support the millions currently dependent on the

forest.

Figure 15 - Price of Shrimp 1990 – 2004 (FAO)

C. Shrimp Industry in Bangladesh

Shrimp aquaculture has risen dramatically over the past three decades to become Bangladesh’s second

largest export. The value of exports has increased from $2.9 million in 1973 (EJF 2004) to $380 million in

2005 (Figure 16) (Ahmed 2004).

As would be expected, the land under shrimp cultivation too has exploded as more and more farmers

have adopted the practice; the number of hectares under shrimp cultivation has increased by 400% in

Khulna district alone to over 160,000 ha (Figure 18). Farmers saw others, learned the practice and

replicated themselves. Altogether, the shrimp industry is reported to employ 1.2M people

(USAID/Bangladesh 2006).

Not all shrimp production is the same however as we will discuss at length below, and two particular

types dominate: saltwater or bagda shrimp account for approximately half of the production and

freshwater shrimp, golda accounts for 30% (Figure 19). The productivity as noted above in Figure 17

however is low for both types of shrimp.

15

Figure 16 - The Rise of Frozen Shrimp Exports to Bangladesh (DoF, 2001)

Figure 17 - Productivity (kg/ha)

Figure 18 – Shrimp Area Khulna

Figure 19 – Types of Shrimp Produced

D. Degradation Continued Despite Shrimp Aquaculture

If shrimp aquaculture holds such promise of export earnings and Bangladeshi farmers have taken to

farming shrimp in large swathes, then one would expect the people in the surrounding area to have

become more prosperous over time, and therefore less dependent on the forest which should have had

prevented or slowed the degradation of the Sundarbans. But as the data in Table 1 attest to above, the

Sundarbans have been degrading all the same. This is the focus of Section V below, but first a look at our

protagonist, the Nishorgo Project, itself.

0

500

1000

1500

2000

2500

3000

3500

19

85

19

87

1989

1991

1993

19

95

19

97

19

99

20

01

20

03

20

05

20

07

Val

ue

(M T

aka)

Frozen Shrimp Export Value

0

500

1000

1500

2000

2500

3000

3500

4000

4500

Bangladesh India China Vietnam

Yield (kg/ha)

0

50

100

150

200

19841985198719881993199720032004

Shrimp Area in Khulna(thousand ha)

>400% increase since 1984

Types of Shrimp Produced2007-2008 Khulna (%)

Bagda

Golda

Honna

Chaka

Other

16

IV. Sundarbans Management and the Nishorgo Program

In considering which institution might be most suitable for our purposes, several criteria that might be

used: (1) public values and legal jurisdiction (2) technical and administrative capacity to carry out the

task (3) funding and political support (Moore 1995).

A. Public Value and Jurisdiction

First, as noted earlier, the Sundarbans have been under continuous management since 1878 when the

British declared them reserve forests under the management of the Forest Department (FD). This

structure passed onto Bangladesh through the East Pakistan period from 1947 to 1971. In 1989, the FD

was brought under the control of the Ministry of Environment and Forests along with the new

Department of Environment. As such, while the Ministry of Lands, the Ministry of Fisheries, or the

Ministry of Agriculture might make plausible arguments for jurisdiction over the Sundarbans, that right

legally continues to rest with the Forest Department of the Ministry of Environment and Forests (World

Bank 2006).

Yet, this limited jurisdiction is precisely one of the impediments to achieving the goals outlined above:

shrimp aquaculture potentially holds the key to conservation of the Sundarbans through poverty

reduction, but the FD is wholly inadequate to influence this activity on its own. It has no legal authority

outside the forest nor does it possess the requisite technical capacity to affect the second important

criteria. Therefore the FD as a whole cannot be the right institution of choice. What the FD can do

however, is recognize the need to look outside the forest in order to achieve its stated conservation

goals, and take the lead in creating an agency within itself to pursue these goals.

The Nishorgo Program of the Forest Department was created in 2004 through support from USAID and

the International Resource Group (IRG) with just this goal to promote a co-management model for

administering the protected areas of Bangladesh including the Sundarbans by focusing on building

partnerships between the FD and key local, regional and national stakeholders. The Nishorgo Program

has six official objectives: to create a formal institution to bring together stakeholders to co-manage the

protected areas; to generate alternative incomes; advocate for better management policies; develop

the institutional capacity of the FD; anddevelop infrastructure in protected areas; and actively restore

such areas (K. S. Huda 2006).

17

B. Technical and Administrative Capacity

The FD, USAID, and IRG between them are expected to have sufficient technical capacity particularly

through a dedicated program run by the IRG and funded by USAID called the Nishorgo Support Project.

Administratively, however, the institution is complex. There is a four tiered structure of stakeholders to

form a “Nishorgo Co-Management institution” as follows.

At the national level there is a Wildlife Advisory Board composted of FD leadership, professors,

and other ministry officials. The board was created through the 1974 Wildlife Act as a supreme

authority on wildlife and forests. At the local level there are three tiers which loosely report to

the Advisory Board but have quite a bit of autonomy.

Each protected area (the Sundarbans together constitute three such areas) has a Conservation

Council comprised of 50 members from region, typically elites: NGO leaders, resource owners,

the District Forest Officer, journalists, teachers, and leaders from other relevant government

ministries such as Agriculture, Lands and Fisheries. Their task is to develop a consensus plan on

how forest resources are to be managed in the area.

The conservation council elects a Co-Management Committee which is comprised of 15-19

members from the Council to act as the nodal agency of the NSP and functions as executive

body of Council. The committee serve as liaison between local people and FD. It distributes

benefits from protected areas as agreed in the Council, develops projects to be implemented

with funds from the PA, maintain accounts, protects forests, and facilitates conflict resolution

between local people and FD.

The Committee also coordinates the Forest User Groups comprised of local grassroots

organizations (K. S. Huda 2006).

This multi-party, multi-tiered structure appears to be a significant departure from the standard

command and control management style used by the Forest Department as described above. Yet there

are significant areas of concern in how the Nishorgo Program as an institution functions in reality. For

example, nowhere in the committees is there any inclusion of the poor who truly depend on the forest.

Even when NGOs representing the voice of the super-poor are included in the meetings, they complain

that they are not listened to. Second, the Council cannot be held accountable. Nor does it possess legal

authority over the Forest Department. As a result, it has begun to appear both out of touch as well as

incapable. Finally, there is a lack of strategic or visionary thinking in the council. None of the case studies

seem to indicate that besides this new structure there is any movement away from the command and

18

control way of thinking even if there is significant possibility in the new program to do so (Chowdhury

2008).

C. Political and Institutional Environment

It is difficult to gauge the importance of the environment from speaking to Bangladeshis. Those few I

spoke with were only vaguely familiar with environmental issues, and government officials lamented the

public’s lack of interest (Shameem 2010). Growth and development are priorities, but the link between

development and conservation are poorly understood.

The current administration is said to be supportive of the environment, but if budget allocations can

used an indicator, then in Bangladesh, the environment falls low amongst national priories: Defense has

an allocation 20 times larger, and the MoEF gets less than the Ministry of Youth Sports. The budget

allocation of the Ministry of Environment and Forests ($33M of a total government of about $14.3B, or

about 0.2%) is miniscule (Figure 20). The FD receives around 80% of total budget of the MoEF which

amounts to about 26.4M annually for the FD as a whole. The Nishorgo Project receives some unspecified

portion of that funding in addition to $1.3M per year for the five year project starting in 2005 from

USAID(USAID/Bangladesh 2005).

Figure 20 - MOEF in the Bangladesh Budget (Source: Bangladesh Ministry of Finance, Author’s Calculations)

Given its jurisdiction, mission, technical capacity, and resource availability, the Nishorgo program within

the FD of the MoEF seems to be the ideal institution to spearhead this non-traditional forestry

management effort.

General Service

21%

Social Infrastructur

e32%

Physical Infrastructur

e29%

Interest13%

Memorandum Items

5%

Allocation of National BudgetTotal = $14.28 B (2009)

MOEF, < 1%

Agriculture and Rural

Development Breakout,

57%

Breakout of Physical Infrastructure Budget and Agricultural and Rural

Development Spending

19

V. Why Shrimp Aquaculture has not Delivered

With some understanding of who will be responsible for what needs to be done, we return now to the

problem facing the Nishorgo Program. As we noted before, if shrimp aquaculture holds such promise of

export earnings and Bangladeshi farmers have taken to farming shrimp in large swathes, then one would

expect the people in the surrounding area to have become more prosperous over time, and therefore

less dependent on the forest. This in turn should have had prevented or slowed the degradation of the

Sundarbans. However, as the figures in Table 1 attest to above, the Sundarbans have continued to

degrade all the same.

This section will highlight three reasons why shrimp aquaculture has not delivered on the promise of

lowering poverty. First, as we have seen above, the productivity is too low. That is to say, the total

reward (the size of the pie) is smaller than it could be. Second, a value chain analysis below will show

that even taking the size of the pie as a given, the slices accrue unevenly to the various actors involved in

production; parts of the chain where the most people are involved invariably receive the smallest

portion of the profit. Finally, shrimp production itself has troubling impacts on the environment which

are discussed below.

A. Uneven Distribution of Employment and Wages

1. Methodology

To determine how to best intervene to improve the distribution of earnings from shrimp production, the

Nishorgo Project could conduct a value chain analysis of the shrimp industry in Bangladesh. Such an

analysis identifies the key actors and steps involved in the production of the final exportable shrimp

product (Figure 21). The analysis might focuses on final markets, income distribution and governance

along the chain (Kaplinsky and Morris 2001), but in the USAID methodology, the primary focus is on

“identifying and exploring the spaces where return is generated. Further: “value chain analysis

recognizes that various configurations of actors may influence capabilities, possess different levels of

bargaining power, and subsequently affect outcomes along the value chain” (Campbell and Downing

2008).

20

Figure 21 -- Value Chain Diagram (Souce: USAID)

What follows in the rest of the section is a “light” analysis of the shrimp production value chain. The

word light is used for several reasons. First, there has not been any statistically representative sampling

of the actors and prices upon which an ideal analysis would be based. Instead, this analysis relies on

data and information from two secondary analyses of the shrimp value chain in Bangladesh, the first by

USAID and a second by the World Bank, and augmented by observations and data collected from a field

visit to the region by the author. Second, the following analysis will be focused on the pieces of the

movement of the shrimp along the steps between larvae stage and export, the actors involved, costs of

production, and the distribution of incomes. A full value chain analysis might include the flow of

information along the chain, dissemination of technology, availability of credit, and so on. These

additional areas of focus are not immediately relevant for the current purpose of uncovering possible

points of intervention in the value chain by the Nishorgo project and are therefore omitted.

2. Overview of the Value Chain

Reduced to its most basic, there are three significant steps to the of shrimp farming analogous to

farming anything else. First, it is necessary to acquire the seed. In the case of shrimp, this means getting

the shrimp larvae, called shrimp fry. Second, the fry needs to be grown out and then harvested. Finally,

the harvest needs to be processed to become the final consumable good to be sold in retail stores or

exported. Interactions between these stages are facilitated by intermediaries.

Figure 22 – Simplified Shrimp Value Chain

Of course the chain is not so simple in reality. This picture becomes more complicated with the inclusion

of various intermediaries of several sizes that have been consolidated into two single intermediary steps

Collect Shrimp Fry

IntermediariesGrowout and

HarvestIntermediaries

Process and Export

21

in Figure 22. Also, as we shall see below, not all shrimp production is the same and therefore the set of

activities and costs associated with “growout and harvest” are quite different between freshwater

shrimp (golda) production and brackish water shrimp (bagda) production. Finally, as with the “collect

shrimp fry” stage for example, which might include shrimp larvae literally collected from the wild or

those purchased from the hatcheries, different activities and actors all-together are consolidated into a

single meta-activity. Thus a more realistic value chain might look as in Figure 23, though even this figure

does not include the input suppliers.

Figure 23: Detailed Shrimp Value Chain (USAID/Bangladesh 2006)

3. Main Actors: Employment and Returns

In total, academic papers and multilateral institutions estimate that approximately 1.2 million people

are directly employed in some portion of the chain above and some 4.8 million are indirectly related.

The industry as a whole earned $380M in exports in 2005, which amount to 5% of the GDP (Ahmed,

Demaine and Muir 2008). The remainder of the section will briefly look in turn at the four major

activities that are included in the value chain as described in the simple chain above: fry collection,

grow-out and harvest, process and export, and finally the role of intermediaries. The number of people

employed in each step, as well as the costs, revenues, and profits are included where possible with the

objective of identifying how earnings and employment are distributed along the chain.

22

Fry Collection

A non-trivial difference between shrimp farming and farming a plant is that the seeds for shrimp

farming, the shrimp post-larvae called fry, are animate and therefore much be caught from the rivers

and coastal waters. This is not an easy job, and either involves casting fine nets into the water from

boats or physically sifting through water hour after hour for post-larvae. Upon collecting the fry or the

brood-stock (pregnant shrimp mothers that will soon “lay” the post-larve they contain), they are sold to

the intermediaries for the former or the hatcheries for the latter.

There are very little direct cost involved in this activity. However, the first method (casting a net) is

particularly harmful to the environment and has been legally banned as is discussed below, and the

second (manual sifting) is harmful to the human body. Extended exposure to water has been shown to

lead to water-borne diseases and other major health ailments particularly to skin infections. An

estimated 423,000 people are engaged in collecting shrimp fry, 40% of whom are women and children.

They earn about $370 which is 16% higher than the typical yearly wage for day-labor ($318

)(USAID/Bangladesh 2006).

Table 2 - Collecting Shrimp Fry

Saltwater Shrimp (Bagda) Farming

There are an estimated 150,000 farmer owners in the area, and 450,000 laborers involved in harvesting,

security, and so on in the region(USAID/Bangladesh 2006). Nearly 98% of shrimp farmers in the region

practice traditional, extensive methods of shrimp farming which require fewer inputs and low technical

expertise, but produce low yields and high loss rates. As with nearly every activity that occurs in the

23

delta, traditional shrimp farming too is intimately connected to and dependent on the unique mixture of

sea and river as well as the ebb and flow of the daily tides.

The average bagda (penaeus monodon) farm (called a gher) is 4.5 ha. Without pumps, most farmers rely

on the tides to bring into their ponds the brackish (semi-salty) water necessary for bagda production.

This brackish water is a unique feature of the region. This is produced through a mixture of the

freshwater from the rivers which flow down from the Himalayas toward the Bay and the salty sea water,

flowing up from the Bay of Bengal due to the tidal activity. The brackish water makes it difficult to grow

rice which requires fresh water. In response, Bangladesh built up embankments alongside all of the

rivers of the area to keep the salt water away from the fields. Typical bagda farms use a system of canals

and sluice gates in the embankments to control the flow of water into and out of the gher (Figure 24).

Figure 24: Saltwater Shrimp Production. Author and Interviews

Figure 25 - Sluice Gate System

In a typical year, the gher is prepared in January and February. This involves repairs, tilling the land as

well as treating the soil with various fertilizers such as lime, urea, and triple super-phosphate (TSP). Then

the water is allowed to flow in during March. A very particular level of saltiness is required and either

additional freshwater from irrigational canals and rivers or indeed more salt may need to be added to

create the right balance. The waters will already contain some wild shrimp, and to these are added post-

larvae or fry purchased from the market or hatchery. Wild post-larvae are thought to have higher

survival rates and as such command much higher fees than post-larvae from the hatcheries. Then as the

the bagda are left to grow for several months, the cycle of tides provides for aeration. Starting in June,

they are periodically harvested about every fortnight until August. Labor is needed for this step, about 5

labor days per harvest, but not as much as one might expect to collect shrimp from such large ponds.

1.

24

Apparently the bagda automatically try to return to the saltier sea upon reaching maturity. Innovative

traps that allow for easy entry but impossible exit are placed in saltier water in the mouth of the gher

and catch the shrimp automatically.

Figure 26 - Bagda Gher and Trip

Figure 27 - Shrimp Trap

At harvest, the local intermediary or middleman makes a visit to the gher to purchase the shrimp. The

monsoon rains come in August and some farmers drain their ghers to prepare the land to grow a crop of

rice. However, the farmers that were interviewed noted that few large farmers bother growing rice;

most grow bagda throughout the year on bigger farms of 10 ha or more. The smaller farms grow rice as

a means of diversification since rice which is a staple of the region.

Figure 28 - Returns to Bagda Farming

Costs Per Unit Unit Quantity Quantity Notes BDT US $ % of Total

Preparation 19,275 275.36 46.59%

Repair Gher 700 per 120 ft (80 hath ) of edge 7 1 ha has perimeter of 835 ft 4900 70.00

Till Land 425 per ha 1 labor costs 425 6.07

Lime 12 per kg 15 kg needed per ha 180 2.57

Ureah 12 per kg 6 kg needed per ha 72 1.03

TSP 22 per kg 9 kg needed per ha 198 2.83

Purchase Wild PL 300 per 1000 PL 7.5 1,500 added per month for 5 mo 2250 32.14

Purchase Hatchery PL 750 per 1000 PL 15 3,000 added per month for 5 mo 11250 160.71

Growth 0 0 0.00%

Grow PL 0 n/a 0 n/a 0 0

Harvest 4,500 64.29 10.88%

Labor 150 per day 30 5 people per 15 days for 3 months 4,500 64.29

Yearly Overhead Costs 17,598 251.39 42.53%

Land Rental 15,015 per ha per year 1 15,015 214.50

Security 75.08 per month per ha 12 12 mo per year 901 12.87

Clerk 90.09 per month per ha 12 12 mo per year 1,081 15.44

Yearly Maintenance 600.60 per year per ha 1 601 8.58

Cost Totals 41,373 591.04

Revenue Per Unit Units BDT US $ % of Total

Big Shrimp (30 pieces/kg) 450 Tk/kg 100 kg/ha 45000

Medium Shrimp (40 pieces/kg) 325 Tk/kg 50 kg/ha 16250

Small Shrimp (60 pieces/kg) 225 Tk/kg 20 kg/ha 4500

Revenue Totals 170 kg/ha 65,750 939.29

Profit Revenue per ha - Costs per ha ==> 348.25 2.05 per kg

25

Throughout the year, there are several overhead costs: land rent, security, accountants, and

maintenance. The costs and revenues as well as the average return per hectare and per kg of shrimp for

a typical bagda farm consolidated from the information collected from five farmers interviewed during a

field visit are shown in Figure 28 above. The average return of $348 per hectare or $2.05 per kg of

shrimp is less than the USAID study which found returns of about $436 per hectare. This is likely because

they assume the study does not grade the different types of shrimp, but uses one price across their

calculation (USAID/Bangladesh 2005).

Freshwater Shrimp (Golda) Farming

Freshwater shrimp, (technically a prawn, macrobracium rosenbergii) called golda, differs in a number of

ways from the bagda production process discussed above. First, freshwater is used for cultivation and is

collected in the pond during the monsoon rains. Pumps are used at times to supplement the water level

from nearby irrigation canals. Second, the land holdings are much smaller, the average being 0.28 ha as

compared to the 4.5 ha noted above for bagda farms (Ahmed, Demaine and Muir 2008). Third, the

timing and combination of production varies as well since Golda production typically occurs only after

the monsoons, and most farmers grow rice during the dry season. Fourth, the post-larvae must all be

artificially stocked since there is no flow of the tides to bring in wild golda post-larvae, and they must be

fed significant quantities of nursery feed (45 kg per acre) for the first month and then fishmeal (2040 kg

per acre) for the remainder of the growth period. Finally, there is additional labor need to build dykes to

hold the rainwater, till the land, and harvest the shrimp. Unlike the bagda, individual golda are more

difficult to capture at maturity and at times must be captured one at a time manually.

26

Figure 29 - Golda Farm

Figure 30 - Golda Farm with Rice Adjacent

Harvest occurs around December. At times the intermediary comes to purchase the shrimp on harvest

day. Though more typically, since the number farm sizes are so small, it is up to the farmer to transport

the catch to the nearest depot. The costs and revenues as well as the average return per acre and per kg

of shrimp are shown in Figure 31 below.

Figure 31 - Returns to Golda Farming

The average return of $2,993 per ha or $5.13 per kg of golda shrimp is just above the USAID study which

found returns of about $2,450 per ha. Again, this is not surprising as the famers I spoke to were working

with BRAC, the premier Bangladeshi NGO, and therefore had access to extension services and inputs not

easily available to the typical golda farmer. They appear to use more inputs increasing costs and

therefore receiving proportionally higher revenues. As such, the return per kg found here of $5.13 is

quite close to the $4.42 found in the study (USAID/Bangladesh 2006). Finally, it is difficult to estimate

Costs Per Unit Unit Quantity Quantity Notes BDT US $ % of Total

Preparation 30,011 428.73 24.41%

Till Land 180 per labor day 100 labor days needed 18000 257.14

Cow Dung 2 per kg 594 kg per ha 1187 16.96

Potash 24 per kg 15 kg per ha 360 5.14

Mustard Oil Cake 25 per kg 15 kg per ha 375 5.36

Lime 12 per kg 100 kg per ha 1200 17.14

Ureah 12 per kg 163 kg per ha 1957 27.96

TSP 22 per kg 88 kg per ha 1932 27.60

Purchase Hatchery PL 500 per 1000 PL 10 10,000 PL per ha 5000 71.43

Growth 67755 967.9286 55.10%

Nursury Feed 55 per kg 45 1.5 kg per day for 1 month 2475 35.36

Fishmeal 32 per kg 2040 From 10 kg to 25 per day over 4 months 65280 932.57

Harvest 3,600 51.43 2.93%

Labor 180 per day 20 4 people per 15 days for 2 months 3,600 51.43

Yearly Overhead Costs 21,601 308.58 17.57%

Land Rental 21,000 per ha per year 1 21,000 300.00

Yearly Maintenance 600.60 per year per ha 1 601 8.58

Cost Totals 122,967 1,756.67

Revenue Per Unit Units BDT US $ % of Total

Shrimp (10-12 pieces/kg) 570 per kg 583 10000 PL which come 12 per kg, 70% live 332500

Revenue Totals 583 kg/ha 332,500 4,750.00

Profit Revenue per ha - Costs per ha ==> 2,993.33 5.13 per kg

27

how many of the 450,000 laborers and 150,000 farmers are working on golda as compared to bagda.

However given the fact that golda production comprises about 30% of total shrimp production, one

might roughly assume that a similar proportion of farmers and laborers are involved in golda

production.

Processors

The story of the shrimp processing plants in Bangladesh is an odd one and gives some insight to the

perverse incentives that often exist in interactions between business and government. There are 130

processing plants in the country of which 85 are licensed; 55 of these are in our region of interest in

Khulna. 70 of these have EU approval and some 42 have a green channel to the United States. The

shrimp are acquired through a small number of commission agents who are the final aggregators in the

value chain buying large volumes from smaller dealers and depots further downstream. The processing

plants can process both bagda and golda. The plant sorts the shrimp rejecting those that are unsuitable

for export and then grade the remainder into varying standardized sizes before peeling and de-veining

the shrimp. The shrimp are then cooked, quick frozen, packaged and sent to the port in freezer trucks

for export (Kabir 2010). On average the factories earn $1.50 per kg of shrimp processed. Nearly 30,000

non-management workers are employed in the processing factories (USAID/Bangladesh 2005).

What is odd is the utilization rate of these processing plants. While the typical plant has the capacity to

process 270,000 tons per year (World Bank 2008), the World Bank and USAID report that utilization

rates are between 15% to 30%.2 The World Bank reported that this overcapacity is the result of an over-

generous government incentives package that offers a waiver of import duty on machinery, a nine year

tax holiday, cheap loans, and export price supports. The weak institutional environment is unable to

verify that these incentives are being used as intended by lawmakers allowing processing plants to

divert loans and apply tax shields to other businesses (World Bank 2008).

Intermediaries

Intermediaries provide the primary players access to information, credit, and the market. In the shrimp

value chain. First, there are the small (called faria), medium (called aratdar), and large aggregators

(called commission agents) which connect shrimp fry collectors to the farmers. Similarly, there are again

2 USAID reports that the rate is between 20-30%, the World Bank reports 23%, and the director of the Frozen Food Exporters Association claimed a 15% utilization rate.

28

the farias, aratdars, and commission agents who connect the shrimp farmer to the processing plants and

exporters (Rafiquzzaman 2010).

The essential difference between these three types of intermediaries appears to be the volumes that

they deal in which in turn depends on their access to finance. The faria buys directly from the farmer

and often provides working capital loans and inputs supplies for informal purchase agreement. The

farmer or fry collector is vitally dependent on the financing at the beginning of the season and agrees to

sell to a particular faria who will typically use any number of means to both ensure supply and suppress

the buying price. These include fewer grades, inaccurate scales, or even physical threats (Rafiquzzaman

2010) .

The faria is in turn dependent on the aratdar for credit and similarly receives sub-optimal prices. The

aratdar runs local depots where the shrimp are stored, often in poor hygienic conditions, until there is

enough quantity to transport them to the nearest market where he will sell to the commission agent.

These agents of the processing factories are few in number and are typically medium to large scale

entrepreneurs who are either rich themselves or are politically well connected with significant access to

finance. In total, there are estimated to be 30,000 fry middle men who earn a profit of $0.80 per kg of

shrimp on average, and there are 14,000 shrimp middlemen who earn a profit of $2.50 per kg of shrimp

again on average (USAID/Bangladesh 2006).

4. Dispersion of Employment and Earnings along the Value Chain

The examination of the value chain above yields several interesting points about the dispersion of both

employment and earnings along the shrimp value chain. First, the majority of those who find

employment in the shrimp industry are not the owners of the shrimp farms but rather the laborers

(41%) who prepare and till the land and help with the harvest. The second largest group are the are the

fry collectors who comprise 39%. Farmers are only 13% and the intermediaries are the smallest fraction

with about 4% (Figure 32).

The dispersion of profits is different: 31%, the largest portion, accrue to farm owners. Shrimp

middlemen earn 26%, the processing plant earns 15% of the margin, and farm laborers and fry collectors

each earn about 10%. Fry middlemen make out with the smallest slice of 8%. These differences would

only be more exaggerated if the profit margin calculation took into account the number of people that

constitute the groups across whom these profit margins are distributed. Even so, the outcome is telling

if not surprising (Figure 34).

29

Figure 32 - Employment Along the Value Chain (Author Calculations and (USAID/Bangladesh 2006))

Figure 33 - Income Along the Value Chain (Author Calculations and (USAID/Bangladesh 2006))

In sum, those with the largest portion of jobs along the value chain earn the least amount of the gains

from shrimp farming. As such, the onset of shrimp aquaculture in Bangladesh has not made the general

region richer nor reduced the dependence of a significant portion of the population on the Sundarbans.

Figure 34 – Comparison of Income and Employment Dispersion (Author Calculations and (USAID/Bangladesh 2006))

B. Direct and Indirect Impacts of Shrimp Production on the Sundarbans

A second reason that the development of shrimp aquaculture may not have improved the Sundarbans

or reduced their degradation is that the production of shrimp itself can harm the forest. Experience from

Bangladesh as well as other major shrimp producing regions of the world, namely Southeast Asia and

Latin America, point to five major causes for concern: conversion of mangroves, increased salinity, loss

of fry and genetic stock, and socio-economic impacts.

39%

3%13%

41%

1% 3%

Dispersion of Employment(% of total employment = 1.2M)

Fry Catchers Fry Middlemen Farmers Owners

Farm Labor Shrimp Middlemen Processing Plant

10%

8%

31%

10%

26%

15%

Dispersion of Profit MarginsShrimp Price = $15/kg, Total Costs =$5.20

Fry Catchers Fry Middlemen Farmers Owners

Farm Labor Shrimp Middlemen Processing Plant

30

1. Conversion of Mangroves for Aquaculture

For a long period time, before the value of mangrove systems were adequately assessed (for example

see Table 3 above), such areas were considered unproductive waste-land that if possible were

converted into housing or put toward agricultural and aquacultural uses (Millat-e-Mustafa 2002).

Between 1980 and 2000, the FAO estimates that between 3.5 to 5 million ha were lost in Indonesia, Sri

Lanka, India and Thailand alone reducing mangrove cover in those four countries by 28%. Worldwide,

38% of mangroves are estimated to have been lost to shrimp farm conversion directly (EJF 2006). The

Chakaria Sundarbans of eastern Bangladesh, about 8510 ha, were given over by the government for

shrimp farming between 1977 and 1988 (Hossain, Kwei and Hussain 2001). Luckily, the experience for

the Sundarbans themselves has been better on this cause due their long standing protected status.

While the wetlands around the forests have indeed disappeared, the boundaries of the forest have been

more or less protected. As such, forest area has remained more or less constant over the past 25 years

during which shrimp aquaculture has grown in Bangladesh (FAO 2007).

2. Increased Salinity

The second source of impact is increased salinity. In a region were the balance of fresh water and salt

water is critical, any activity that utilizes too much of one or the other will upset the balance. As noted

above, the loss of freshwater due the barrages constructed in India have reduced the flow of water in

Bangladesh, and this effect has been exaggerated by the use of water for shrimp farming. Further the

release of extra salty water after the production of shrimp is complete also affects the balance of

salinity. The increased salinity of the region is thought to cause the top dying of the Sundarbans as noted

in Section II-C above. Loss of freshwater or salinization of water sources have has a number of impacts

on the people of the impact zone as well. Many have experienced drinking water contamination forcing

them to travel long distances to find freshwater. This is a problem that disproportionately affects

women and children. Second, the saltwater from nearby bagda farms may intrude into adjacent rice

farms rendering them unusable for rice (Primavera 1997).

3. Increased Acidity

Third, increased acidity of the soil (hence the heavy use of lime as an input to land preparation; the

alkaline line reduces acidity buildup in the soil) is a common problem that results from the exposure of

the particular type of soil present in mangrove regions to the excessive water which leaches the soil of

alkaline elements necessary for crop growth(Ball 1999). High acidity can weaken plant and shrimp

resistance to parasites and ultimately lead to complete loss of productivity (Azad, Jensen and Lin 2009).

31

4. Loss of Wild-Fry Stock

Fourth, wild fry collection poses a number of challenges for the mangrove system. An estimated 2 billion

shrimp fry are collected each year from the wild and much of it is indiscriminate collection through the

use of fine nets or sifting. In this process, approximately 80% of the by-catch – these are other fish

caught in the net during the search for post larvae – is ultimately wasted (EJF 2004). Collectors often

enter the forest estuaries where brood shrimp release their larvae and end up harming trees and animal

species or they use the opportunity to gather wood.

The government banned the collection of wild fry in 2000, but this ban has mostly gone unenforced

because hatcheries are only able to meet 50% of the demand for bagda post-larvae and only 10% of the

demand for golda (Azad, Jensen and Lin 2009). There is also strong demand for wild post-larvae because

they are perceived to be more robust to disease than hatchery produced fry (Kundu and Islam 2010). In

any case, only 13% of the hatchery operators in Bangladesh use farm reared brood (mother shrimp)

stock, and the rest come from wild brood which must be caught. This process too is quite destructive

since only about around a tenth of percent of the total catch of fishing trawlers are adult brood stock

(Azad, Jensen and Lin 2009). Mangrove degradation is in fact a challenge for the shrimp industry itself

for it relies on the ecosystem for inputs to production such as shrimp stock and clean water (Phillips,

Kwei and Beveridge 1993).

5. Socio-economic Impacts of Aquaculture

Finally, as has been alluded throughout this section, there are significant socio-economic costs to shrimp

farming. The relevance of these adverse impacts on the lives of the forest are indirect and again rest on

the foundational idea of this paper that factors which increase or decrease poverty of the people in the

impact zone indirectly affect the Sundarbans through the reliance of the poor on forest resources

without alternative livelihoods.

As such, we have noted the reduction of potable drinking water and farm land due to increased salinity

and salt water intrusion. Conflict between fisherman and collectors of shrimp fry are not uncommon as

the later in their search for shrimp fry are significantly reducing the fisherman’s catch. The World Bank

estimates that 30% of all inland fish species which provide 66% of the country’s protein are in danger of

extinction (World Bank 2006). Similar effects have been reported for other inputs; snails used for shrimp

feed have nearly disappeared from the region (Ahmed, Demaine and Muir 2008).

32

More broadly, this dramatic change in landscape (ponds for fields) and the introduction of a new

economic activity has deep consequences on the old activities. It is no longer possible to graze livestock

on such terrain, areas of the coast are no longer accessible for fishing, and increasing land values due to

the profitability of shrimp has put rental prices out of reach for many of the area who do not have

access to finance thus transferring effective control of the lands to outsiders with political connections

and financial resources necessary to farm shrimp (Primavera 1997).

The administration of the lands that have been reclaimed from the rivers during the process of creating

embankments(called khas lands), as described by the country director of the IUCN, provides a small

window into the nexus of power and shrimp. Khas lands are meant to be given over to the landless

according to the land reforms of 1989. They are administered by the local district administration but are

held under ownership of the Ministry of Lands in Dhaka which has no local office. There is insufficient

coordination between the two offices allowing powerful interests to pay off both sides and claim the

land. Any legal challenge would take five to ten years, and in any case, no land survey data exist to prove

definitively where the boundaries of disputed khas land actually lie. In such a power vacuum coupled

with weak institutions, it is easy for the powerful to gain the advantage (Khan 2010).

It important to note here that the discussion above has been quite general about shrimp production, but

as we have seen before: there is quite a difference between bagda and gold production. It follows that

their impacts are also quite different. In general, golda production does not suffer from many of the

harmful impacts of bagda production particularly as related to salinity (freshwater is used in production)

and socio-economic impacts (average farm is much smaller and returns higher) (Ahmed 2003).

VI. Fixing a Broken Promise: Towards Sustainable Aquaculture

A. What Can the Nishorgo Project Do?

1. Shrimp Fails Criteria for a Viable Alternative Livelihood

The value chain analysis presents some troubling results for the Nishorgo Project. Presumably it only

makes sense to support shrimp aquaculture as a viable alternative livelihood if the activity meets at least

the following criteria:

1. The activity as a whole generates enough income for those involved to make a living without

relying on the Sundarbans, and is capable of absorbing a significant portion of the roughly 1.35

million people of the area who are currently reliant on the forest.

33

2. The earnings from the activity are sufficiently dispersed such that even those in the value chain

that receive the smallest portions of income are still able to substitute their dependence on the

Sundarbans.

3. The direct environmental impacts of the activity on the Sundarbans do not outweigh the gains

derived through poverty reduction.

Shrimp production is promising because it meets the first criteria (as we saw in Section III however, even

here there is much room for improvements in productivity), but has failed to meet this promise because

it does not seem to meet the second or third criteria (as we saw in Section V).

So where does that leave the Nishorgo project? One obvious option is simply to abandon the idea of

using shrimp as a potential alternative and move on to other projects. But, as has been lamented

elsewhere, few real alternatives exist in the region (ADB 1998). That is, most alternatives do not seem to

meet the first criteria. However, if shrimp is to be retained as an alternative, then interventions of some

form or another are necessary to address the deficiencies in the second and third criteria.

2. Alternative 1: Address One Weakness at a Time

The first approach would be for the Nishorgo Project to tackle each of these weaknesses in shrimp

aquaculture in turn, but in most cases, there are no obvious answers.

Increase Productivity

Much can be done to improve the productivity of the current method of shrimp aquaculture. Extension

services could be deployed to teach farmers how to adopt more intensive farming methods and utilize

inputs more efficiently. As has been noted, other countries dwarf the per acre yields found in

Bangladesh (Figure 17). The state can also invest in cold chains and post-harvest services to reduce

significant losses in this stage which are reported to be a third of the final sale price of shrimp in export

markets (USAID/Bangladesh 2005). Private companies, particularly the idle processing factories could be

incentivized to make some of these investments so they can increase their own utilization rates.

The list could go on and on, but the problem with each of these is that the Nishorgo Project neither has

the technical capacity to manage such changes nor do they have the political authority to do so. Indeed

they lack the funding as well. In any case, productivity alone will not allow them to meet their goal.

34

Increase Distribution of Earnings

They will also need to improve distribution of the earnings across the value chain, and this too, is a

challenging task. One way to improve distribution is to increase the collective bargaining power of the

fry collectors and laborers. This presents significant collective action problems. Addressing these

problems requires technical expertise, time and resources as demonstrated by a project in the Indian

state of Kerala which was undertaken by the Central Marine Fisheries Institute in 1996. The project took

3 years to implement and required over 70 different visits in that time period by extension officers to

the farmer groups; even then, the results were mixed (Srinath, Sridhar and Kartha 2000). Lessons in

collective action from other arenas such as rice production or fruits and vegetables (Reardon, et al.

2003) also point to the tremendous challenges in motivating group formation (Fulton and Hueth 2009).

The main point is that addressing distributional issues directly may not be viable for the Nishorgo

Project.

Environmental Impacts

Addressing the environmental impacts makes more sense given the institutional mandate and general

relevancy to the Sundarbans. For example, the Nishorgo Project can take learn a great deal from the

positive experience of Thailand (at least in this one area) about fostering backyard hatcheries to reduce

the environmentally destructive dependence of the whole industry wild shrimp fry (Kongkeo and Davy

2010). Without pressing for changes to the method of shrimp production however, it does not appear

possible for the Nishorgo Project to affect the other impacts such as conversion, salinity, acidity, or even

the socio-economic factors.

3. Alternative 2: Addresses Weaknesses Simultaneously by Promoting a Switch from Bagda

to Golda Production

A better approach might be for the Nishorgo Project to consider alternatives that have an impact on all

three criteria listed above and can be influenced through the manipulation of policy levers as opposed

to costly or long term projects which require expertise and resources that are scare or simply not

available to the government.

Comparing Bagda and Golda Production

In the preceding discussion, shrimp production has mostly been treated homogenously, but a re-

examination of the significant differences between the two major forms of shrimp aquaculture (bagda

and golda), presents a possible policy option for the Nishorgo Project.

35

First, and perhaps most importantly for the Sundarbans, golda production employs more labor. The

calculations in the value chain analysis shown above show that about 78 labor days per ha are required

for bagda3. In contrast, golda production using 144 labor days per ha or nearly twice as much as golda.

However, the direct labor usage is less significant than the indirect uses of labor across the chain as a

whole. The size of farms, which as noted earlier, are 4.5 ha for the average bagda farm and 0.28 ha for

the average golda farm; as a result, there are about 3.5 times as many golda farmers as there are bagda

farmers (Ito 2004). This is important because even if there is twice as much labor in the variable costs of

production, there is much more labor used for the fixed costs such as gher construction. The effect

moves down the chain as well: more golda farms means not only more employment for laborers and

construction workers but also for middlemen and transporters. Secondary studies support the idea that

that golda production compares similarly to rice production and employs more labor than bagda

production but there is variation in how much more. In India, a rice farm of 40 ha was shown to employ

about 50 laborers while a bagda farm of the same size only employed 5, a multiple of 8 (Shiiva 1995).

Another study, this one from Indonesia, found that a rice crop required 76 labor days per hectare while

an intensive shrimp farm required 45, a multiple of only 1.7 and closer to the doubling derived from the

preceding value chain analysis.

Second, we should note the difference in productivity between the two. The bagda and golda farmers

contacted during the field visit had yields per acre of 170 kg per ha and 583 kg per ha respectively.4

Third, the farmers I spoke with had revenues of about $5.52 per kg of bagda shrimp while costs were

$3.47, implying net income of $2.05 per kg (Figure 28). The golda farmers on the other hand had costs of

$3.01 per kg of shrimp produced and earned $8.14 worth of revenue per kg implying a net income of

$5.13 per kg (Figure 31).5

Fourth, as described earlier, the environmental impacts of golda production are much less than that of

bagda production. While both rely on wild-fry, golda uses freshwater; this does not lead to the salinity

issues pervasive with the saltwater necessary for bagda production. Further, this allows for farmers to

grow other crops including rice in addition to the golda leading to better food security.

3 This is derived by adding up the costs of all labor activities and dividing by cost of a day of labor assumed to be 150 BDT. 4 The USAID study found the corresponding yields to be 133 kg per ha and 496 kg per ha (USAID/Bangladesh 2006). 5 The corresponding figures in the USAID study were $4.16 in costs for each kg of bagda which fetched $5.99 in revenue

implying a net income of $1.85 per kg while the costs for the golda were $3.74 per kg which earned $8.16 revenue per kg implying a net income of $4.42(USAID/Bangladesh 2006).

36

Finally, over the course of my field visit, the bagda farmers appeared qualitatively if not directly

quantitatively different than the golda farmers. For example, the bagda farmer that served as my guide

in Khulna, Mr.Khaliq held several titles in additional to bagda farmer; he was also a lawyer, head of the

Khulna Bar association, and member of the Frozen Food Exporters Association (Figure 35). He dressed

well, spoke English, owned several dozen hectares of land, and was extremely well connected. He was

also on a first name basis with the Forest Department officials, most farmers, as well as the district

leadership. Though I could not verify the claim, he noted his brother was the assistant chief conservators

of the Forest Department in Dhaka and another cousin a general in the Army (a very powerful institution

in Bangladesh). In comparison, Mr. Mullah, a golda farmer I met, did not own the two acres he farmed,

could not speak English, did not dress particularly well, and besides the BRAC connection, he did not

seem to be in with the local elites. This is hardly a representative sample of course, but secondary

sources support the general trend from these two vignettes that bagda farmers own more land, are well

connected, and are more powerful (Primavera 1997).

Figure 35 - Mr. Rafiquzzaman, Bagda Farmer near Hadda

Figure 36 - Mr. Mullah, Golda Farmer in Doomoria

In sum, Golda production creates more jobs, is more productive, less costly to produce per kg, has

higher returns, is better distributed across farmers, better targets the poor and has a smaller

environmental footprint. As such, the Nishorgo Project might consider promoting a switch from one

method of shrimp farming to another. Doing so appears to meet all three criteria outlined above, and

therefore might be a much more suitable alternative.

B. Considerations in Promoting a Switch to Golda Production

Before supporting a policy of promoting a switch from bagda to golda production, there are several

questions that need to be considered. The first pertains to whether or not a switch would be physically

37

possible for most famers, and the second as to whether or not it would be practically possible to switch.

The third question asks why the switch has not been market driven given what appear to be obvious

benefits to golda production. Finally, the last questions considers the net economic implications of a

switch.

1. Physical Feasibility

When asked about switching from bagda to golda, some of the farmers responded that their particular

areas was suitable for bagda but not for golda. In most cases they were incorrect in their perception of

where it was possible to grow bagda and golda according to the Center for Environment and Geographic

Information Systems (CEGIS), a public trust in Bangladesh under the Ministry of Water Resources. Figure

37 delineates bagda suitability in the impact zone around the Sundarbans, and Figure 38 compares

where bagda is actually grown and suitability. The red and blue regions are unsuitable or only

moderately suitable for bagda, but it is being produced there nonetheless.

Figure 37 - Bagda Suitability Map (CEGIS)

Figure 38 - Actual Bagda Growth (CEGIS)

Similarly, Figure 39 delineates golda suitability in the impact zone, and Figure 40 compares where golda

is actually growth and suitability.

Comparing CEGIS satellite data (CEGIS and IWM 2007), it becomes clear that it is possible to grow golda

in many more places than are currently being done while bagda is actually being grown in places where

it is not suitable. Though any policy for switching must take into account certain regions where it is

indeed not possible to grow golda but only bagda and vice versa.

38

Figure 39 - Golda Suitability Map (CEGIS)

Figure 40 - Actual Golda Growth

2. Practical Feasibility

Next, there are several concerns about switching even in places where either bagda or golda might be

grown. There would be some cost in carving up large bagda farms into smaller golda ones, and the

Nishorgo Project would need to keep in mind that initial farm construction costs are estimated to be

$959 per ha (Ahmed 2004). The production method is also different and requires more expensive inputs,

but the cost per kg produced is actually less as described above. Also, there might need to be significant

training necessary to make a smooth transition.

The processing plants are able to handle either type of shrimp so that is not a concern, but there is a

fear echoed by some farmers about the implications of increased supply of golda on (1) the prices of

shrimp as well as the (2) prices of local inputs. The first is not a real worry as over 90% of the golda is

exported and Bangladesh is a small player in the international market with only 4.8% of all cultured

shrimp production (Leung and Eagle 2006). As such, the international price is unlikely to be affected by

whatever additional amount Bangladesh could produce. The possible increase in the price of inputs in

the domestic market, particularly feed which comprises about 33% of the total production cost. This is

indeed a significant worry that must be proactively addressed, but it is important to notice that golda

farming remains more profitable per hectare than bagda even if the price of feed increases threefold.

Generally then, it appears feasible to overcome the practical barriers to switching.

3. Why has the transition not happened automatically?

Golda farming has expanded prolifically over the last two decades or so since it was discovered by trial

and error in Bagerhat district in the mid-1970s. By 1996, there were over 15,000 golda farms in Bagerhat

(the eastern most district of the impact zone) alone and this number was 34,000 by 2002. The increase

39

ing golda farms, however, has mainly been in the conversion of rice farms (though many continue to

integrate shrimp and rice production). In that same period, the number of bagda farms too has mor than

tripled from 2,500 to about 9,500 in Bagerhat (Ito 2004). Why, if a transition from bagda to golda is both

physically possible and more profitable, have farmers bothered to farm bagda at all?

The answer seems to lie in the nature of capital in addition to the costs and risks of golda production as

compared to bagda. Bagda farming started in the coastal zones of the Bay of Bengal when the

profitability of the wild bagda increased when the traditional producers in Thailand and China had

production problems in the early 1980s. These coastal zones and then the reclaimed land from the

embankments discussed earlier are owned by the government and could only be leased at costs that

proved far too high for local residents; well connected, wealthy elites, typically from Dhaka, became

absentee leaseholders. It was not worth it to carve up the land they had acquired to construct smaller

golda farms; instead they relied on volume from the inundation of large swathes of coastal land to earn

higher total incomes. Over time, even as locals have re-acquired leases, they have continued the pattern

of production they have inherited.

Second, such farms are also easier to manage and require fewer capital inputs such as feed which are

increasingly more expensive. Snails which were the primary source of feed in the region have become

nearly extinct and must be brought from further and further away increasing the cost of production(Ito

2004).

Finally, golda has proved to be risky. The haphazard conversion of rice fields to golda farms has led to

significant water drainage issues. This and the poor post harvest handling techniques replete with

numerous intermediaries, poor roads, and a lack of proper cold storage along the chain have led to

various shrimp diseases. At a time when western consumers have increasingly become concerned with

the safety and traceability of their food, the reputation of Bangladeshi shrimp has suffered. Their prices

in the international market have been reduced. At times, for failure to continuously comply with

increasingly stringent regulations, Bangladeshi golda has have been banned outright by the EU, the US,

and Japan (Kundu and Islam 2010). Bagda has fared better because the regular circulation of tides

inherent to coastal and riverside lands reduces the incidence of disease(Rafiquzzaman 2010).

4. Estimated Benefit of a Switched Hectare from Bagda to Golda

Any of these plans to switch farmers to bagda to golda will involve costs, and we must formulate some

idea of the economic benefits switching from bagda to golda viz a vis the forest. The chain of reasoning

40

we have constructed can be simplified for this exercise as follows: (1) convert bagda farm to golda farm

absorbing more labor (2) less labor means lowered dependence on the forest, and (3) lower

dependence means more conservation of the forest. The difficulty appears in being quantitatively

precise about these links for there seems to be a lack of data (see Appendix) and inadequate research

on these topics for Bangladesh (World Bank 2009).

Still, some approximation might be attempted using secondary sources most of which were discussed

above following the concept of marginal opportunity cost as described in (Pearce and Markandya 1987).

As we noted above (in A3 of this section), golda farms were found to absorb between 1.7 and 8

times as much labor as bagda farms; these can form low and high values scenarios.

Second, we can rely on a study that reviews 24 other efforts to value non-timber forest products

(NTFP) to estimate how much forest material is being extracted per person from the forest. The

figures range from $50 to $150 ha-1yr-1 (Godoy, Lubowski and Markandya 1993) for forests

comparable to the Sundarbans.

We also know that those reliant on the forest are earning about quite poor and families earning

between 165-416 USD annually (World Bank 2009). Some portions, perhaps 1.5% to 3.3%, of the

consumption are not renewable and degrades stand density and affects total function of the

forest(Iftekar and Islam 2004). The complete services of mangrove systems, as we saw before,

are between $600 ha-1yr-1 to $11,300 ha-1yr-1 (Primavera 1997).

We now have a upper and lower bound for each of these variables, and we can derive our rough

estimate using the values in between. One person extracting NTFP from 2.5 ha of the forest

annually reduces the value of the forest by $100 ha-1yr-1 to earn about $250 for his family.

Of this about 2% is non-renewable and degrades density and functioning of the total forest. 2%

of 2.5 ha is 0.05 ha which is worth $300 annually if the forest is valued at $6,000 ha-1yr-1.

Therefore, if 5 people receive a job on a golda farm converted from one ha of bagda, then this

leads to a decrease in annual degradation of 5 x $300 or $1,500 per ha switched.

Suppose the job multiple is 2 instead of 5, which is approximately the multiple derived above; the

degradation is a more conservative 1% instead of 2%; the value of the NTFP reduced to 70 ha-1yr-1 ;and,

the value remains the same for the value of the forest, then each switch is worth about $430 annually.

Similarly, if the family earns $300 per year; the value of NTFP remains 70 ha-1yr-1 ; the degradation is 2%,

the value of the forest is $11,300 ha-1yr-1 (the high value which might be the case for Bangladesh where

41

the forest serves additional functions such as tidal wave protection); and, the job multiple is 2, then the

value of a switch is $1,900 per ha switched. The purpose is not to establish an exact figure, but only to

establish a approximate range of possible values between $430 per switch to $1900 per switch. The

positive values within this range underscore the need, as described throughout the paper, to do

something rather than nothing at all.

C. How to Switch from Bagda to Golda? Policy Options

If right move for the Nishorgo Project is to switch as many bagda farmers to golda production as is

feasible in order to advance a form of aquaculture that better meets the criteria for an alternative

livelihood set out above (in Section VI-A-1), then the next consideration is to determine what policy

options might be used to accomplish this goal. We proceed by making several assumptions, first that the

shrimp farmers are rational and second, that they are interested primarily in earning the as much

income from their efforts and inputs as possible meaning they want to maximize their profits by

choosing an optimal level of outputs. Based on these two assumptions, we can frame the goal of the

Nishorgo Project to affect specific policy levers so as to increase the profitability of golda production

relative to bagda production including the costs of switching.

This equation simply shows that profits are revenues (price times quantity produced) less the costs of

production (price of inputs times how much was needed). Profit π for a farmers is dependent on p (the

price of shrimp), and w (the vector of corresponding input prices) and the farmer maximizes by choosing

the, xj the set of inputs (i to k) used to produce f() quantity of shrimp such as labor, feed, fertilizer. If we

let πG and πB be the expected net present value of a perpetual stream of profits incorporating the risk of

a future ban6, of golda and bagda respectively, the Nishorgo project must make:

πG – C > πB

Here C is the fixed cost of conversion noted above to be about $959 per ha. Considering even a simple

profit equation provides ideas for possible options by which the Nishorgo project might affect the

profitability of golda vs bagda. To increase the profitability, one must (1) increase price of shrimp, (2)

6 A perpetuity is annual profit divided by the discount rate, r, which is assumed to be constant over time. And a simple approximation of the expected value of profit assumping the probability of a ban, b: E[NPV(πG)] = (1-b)*πG /r – b* πGb / r where πGb is the profit in the event of a ban; the equation for bagda would be similar.

42

increase the quantity of shrimp produced, (3) decrease the quantity of inputs needed or (4) decrease

the respective costs of production inputs. An additional option (5) here is to decrease the cost of

conversion (6) decrease the discount rate of golda vs. bagda, or (7) decrease the probability of a future

ban. Each of these would increase the profitability of golda relative to bagda, of course, the opposite of

each of these could be done for bagda to decrease profitability.

Bangladesh is a price taker in the international market, so (1) is not a realistic option nor is (6) practical.

The Nishorgo project as noted in above (in Section IV) is small and limited in its resources and capacity,

and as such (2), (3), and (7) are eliminated outright for each of these require broad structural changes in

the shrimp industry to increase productivity and develop infrastructure. Two options remain as viable

from the list: (4) and (5) that is, those that involve altering the price of inputs or reducing the cost of

conversion.

1. Reduce the Cost of Conversion?

Returning then to the first of our remaining options: to increase profitability of golda by reducing the

cost of conversion. Clearly the cost of nearly $1,000 ha-1 is quite prohibitive particularly in the face of

risks of golda production. One way to reduce this cost is discounted credit or even subsidies up to the

value of per switch as described in the previous sub-section. This might in theory work both technically

and politically to incentivize a conversion, but it is not difficult to foresee implementation issues.

Recalling the experience with loans for processing plants (Section V-A-3 above on p27) which were

diverted from their original purpose, one might imagine a similar diversion here. Also, there would be a

need for monitoring to ensure compliance. This is difficult to do and requires resources the Nishorgo

Program lacks.

2. Tax Bagda Production?

A second way might be to implement taxes on bagda production, perhaps on their inputs or simply on

the finished product itself. This might technically work, but it would be a political non-starter given the

close connections that the bagda farmers maintain with the government and their general wealth and

influence (Khan 2010). It would also be difficult to collect such taxes which are generally a problem in

Bangladesh (Sarkar 2008).

3. Recommendation: Subsidize Golda Inputs

The third and most supportable option might be to subsidize the cost of conversion in a way that better

ensures compliance. For example, the price of feed has been shown to have the most significant impact

43

on shrimp farm expansion on a study done in Thailand (Barbier and Cox 2004). Freshwater shrimp feed,

typically fishmeal, is not used for bagda production and would only benefit those who had switched. It is

also a significant portion: between 33% to 55% of the production costs. We noted above that there are

approximately 150,000 farm owners(USAID/Bangladesh 2005), and that there are about three times as

many golda farmers as bagda farmers. That is, about one fourth or 37,500 bagda farm owners who

control about 4.5 ha on average and therefore 168,750 ha would be eligible. Of these, 35% or so are

areas that physically cannot be switched over as discussed above (in section VI-B-1 p37) leaving

approximately 110,000 ha. The subsidy for fishmeal which should amount to the total cost of converting

a gher of $1000 per ha which is incidentally the cost per ha of fishmeal necessary per year for golda

farming.

The subsidy should be phased in however so the purchased fishfeed is not simply re-sold to existing

golda farmers. Instead, there should be increasing subsidy that provides $200 per ha the first year, $300

per ha the second year assuming the farmer has converted his gher and completed one year of

production. The remaining $500 can be given the following year, again only if there has been compliance

the second year. The total cost of the subsidy would amount to $110 million over three years if all

possible bagda famers who were eligible switched, but this is unlikely. In any case, this is not an

exorbitant sum for a subsidy in Bangladesh; a diesel subsidy launched this year cost $107 million

(Weiwei 2010).

Besides being well targeted, it would be relatively easy for the Nishorgo Project to implement since it

could utilize the existing infrastructure the government already has for providing agricultural input

subsidies to over 9 million farmers(Weiwei 2010). The government provides an input assistance card to

those eligible for a subsidy and opens a bank account for them; the subsidies are transferred directly to

the accounts and can only be accessed by the cards for the intended use: in this case to purchase shrimp

freed.

Ideally, the program would be launched in a small sub-district first to determine its viability. The

immediate next step for the Nishorgo Project then would be to acquire enough money 50 bagda farmers

and offer an opportunity to participate in the program. Even if they all joined, the first year would cost

$45,000. The program could be expanded if successful in converting bagda farmers, absorbing labor, and

reducing dependence on the forest.

44

VII. Appendix

A. SYPA Table

Figure 41 - The SYPA-Meter

B. Estimating the Implications of Input Subsidy

This appendix item directly follows (Barbier and Cox 2004) and summarizes the relevant part of their

paper. Barbier and Cox assume that mangroves are open-access resources freely available to shrimp

farmers who can gain access these areas and claim them. They suggest that by modeling the land

clearing assumptions of commercial shrimp farmers under such open access conditions, it is possible to

determine the key economic factors influencing mangrove conversion for aquaculture expansion.

In any time period t, let the profit function of a representative shrimp farmer be the profits gained by

choosing a profit maximizing level of inputs:

where:

Nj = mangrove cleared by jth farm

xj = vector of other i, …, k inputs used in production of shrimp such as labor, feed, fertilizer

w = vector of corresponding input prices

p = price of shrimp

wN= rental price of land. If farmers own or clear their own land, this is the opportunity cost, and if

farmers rent land, this is the rental price.

The demand function for cleared land derived by Hotelling’s Lemma:

If all farms have the same technology, which is a reasonable assumption in Bangladesh where all but 2%

of the famers are using traditional shrimp farming methods, then this demand function for cleared land

Option

Technically

Correct

Politically

Supportable

Administratively

Feasible

Do Nothing X

Provide Credit for Conversion X

Tax Bagda Production X X

Subsidize Golda Inputs

45

can be aggregated into a total demand for converted mangroves. Additional factors may affect the

aggregate level of conversion such as income, population, land area, and total number of farms; these

are included in vector Z:

Further, since shrimp farms supply themselves with cleared mangrove land, N, this can be viewed as a

production process in and of itself. Barbier and Cox apply the following conditions: (1) source of cleared

land is open access so land is cleared to the point where producer surplus generated by clearing

additional land is zero; (2) the principal input to clearing land is labor, L, which is paid exogenously

determined wage, wL; (3) the production process is homogenous; (4) exogenous accessibility factors, α,

might affect the conversion process such roads, infrastructure, distance to the nearest town, and so on.

Then it is possible to specify a cost function based on the minimum cost for the shrimp farm to produce

a given level of cleared mangrove area N for some fixed level wL and α:

Under open access conditions, each shrimp farm will convert mangrove area up to the point where the

total revenues gained from converting Nj units of land, wnNj = cj. If a shrimp farm clears its own area,

note Barbier and Cox, then wn is the household’s implicit rental price or opportunity cost of utilizing

additional converted land. But, since the shrimp farm is essentially supplying land to itself, then in

equilibrium, the implicit price ensures that the farm’s costs of supplying its own land will be equated

with its derived demand for converted land:

Together with the derived demand for converted land, this equation, determines the equilibrium level

of mangrove clearing by shrimp farm as well as its implicit price which is not observed. The two

equations (1) and (2) can be used together to solve for the reduced form equation for the equilibrium

level of cleared mangrove area:

46

Aggregating across all J farms in the area, including exogenous factors Z, and separating labor from

other input costs, leads to a reduced form relationship for the aggregate equilibrium level of cleared

mangrove land:

The impact of wage rate and other input prices is ambiguous, and Barbier and Cox proceed to estimate

the model with the following variables:

Data

A goal of this project was to gather this same information for Bangladesh to be able to estimate this

model specifically for Bangladesh. Unfortunately the data proved elusive during a short field visit to

Dhaka. Significant cost and effort, much beyond the scope of this data, would be necessary to collect

some of it that exist, but often there is a general lack of reliable data. Shrimp farm registration has only

begun in the last two years, and surveys of mangrove area have not been done regularly or using the

same methods and estimates vary (ADB 2008). Even prices of shrimp or feed over time are not

maintained by the Bangladesh Bureau of Statistics. As such, the results presented by Barbier and Cox for

Thailand are relied on to provide some guidance for what may be happening in Bangladesh:

47

C. Field Visit to Bangladesh

Information and data for this research project was collected from several sources: secondary research

conducted in Cambridge, MA and from a field visit from Jan 3 - Jan 11, 2009 to Dhaka, Khulna, and the

edge of the Sundarbans made possible by a generous grant from the Ash Institute for Democratic

Governance and Innovation at the Harvard Kennedy School.

Field Visit Itinerary

Day (Date) Meetings Activities/Objectives 1 (Jan 3 – Su) None Arrive in Dhaka

2 (Jan 4 – Mo) World Bank Country Office Dr. Kaliquzzaman, WB Water Expert

Mr. Shakil Ahmed Ferdausi (TTL Sunderbans NLTA)

Dr. Rafiquzzaman, WB Fisheries Expert

Mr. Rahman, Dir. Inst. For Water Modeling

Validate research plan Validate and finalize itinerary

Contextual Information

3 (Jan 5 – Tu) Dr. Niaz Khan, IUCN Country Dir.

Dr. RamSharma and Mr. Winterbottom, IPAC Country Dir.

Mr. Tapan K. Dey, Bangladesh Conservator of Forests

Bangladesh Bureau of Statistics Dr. Shaper Salim, Environmental

Policy Expert at WB

Collect Statistical Data

Conduct Interviews

4 (Jan 6 – We) Travels

Mr. Rafiquzzaman (Guide and Shrimp Farmer)

Continue Interviews

Travel to Khulna

5 (Jan 7 – Th) Mr. Shahidul Islam, Deputy Ranger FD Khulna

Mr. Nitya Nanda Das, District Fisheries Office

BRAC Hatchery in Doomoria Local Freshwater Shrimp Cultivators

Mr. Humayun Kabir, Dir. Bangladesh Frozen Foods Association

Conduct Interviews

6 (Jan 8 – Fr)* Visit edge of Sundarbans

Visit Brackish water shrimp farms and speak with farmers and villagers

Conduct Interviews

Observe Shrimp Production Observe Hatcheries

7 (Jan 9 – Sa)* Last interviews with villagers Return to Dhaka

8 (Jan 10 – Su) Bangladesh Bureau of Statistics

Mr. Shameem, Deputy Dir of Department of Environment

Follow up work in Dhaka

Additional Meetings

Collect Data from BBS 9 (Jan 11 – Mo) None Depart Dhaka

48

D. Additional Figures and Charts

Figure 42 - Services Provided by the Sundarbans

(Iftekar and Islam 2004)

Table 3 - Value of the Sundarbans(Primavera 1997)

Figure 43 - Extreme Poverty and Travel to Dhaka(BBS 2009)

49

Figure 44 - Hadda FD Post Showing Captured Boats

Figure 45 - Hadda FD Post Showing Illegal Felling

Figure 46 - Growing stock of Sundarbans decreasing (FAO 2000)

Figure 47 - Composition II (Iftekar and Islam 2004)

0

5

10

15

20

25

1959 1983 1996

Growing Stock (million cubic meters)

50

Figure 48 - Shrimp Producing Countries and Market Share (Leung and Eagle 2006)

Figure 49 - Bangladesh Growth in Frozen Shrimp Volume

0

10000

20000

30000

40000

50000

60000

1985

19

87

19

89

19

91

19

93

19

95

19

97

19

99

20

01

20

03

20

05

20

07

Qu

anti

ty (m

etr

ic t

on

s)

Frozen Shrimp Export Quantity

51

E. Bibliography

ADB. Bangladesh: Sundarbans Biodiversity Conservation. Project Completion Report, Asian Development Bank, 2008.

ADB. Report and Recommendation of the President to the Board of Directors On a Proposed Loan and Technical Assistance Grant to the People's Republic of Bangladesh for the Sundarbans Biodiversity Conservation Project. Asian Development Bank, 1998.

Ahmed, Nesar. "Environmental Impacts of Freshwater Prawn Farming in Bangladesh." Shellfish News (Center for Environnment, Fisheries, and Aquaculture Science (UK)) 15 (May 2003): 25-28.

Ahmed, Nesar. "Freshwater Prawn Farming in Bangladesh: How Cultivation is Financed." Shellfish News (Center for Environnment, Fisheries, and Aquaculture Science (UK)) 18 (November 2004): 17-19.

Ahmed, Nesar, Harvey Demaine, and James F. Muir. "Fresh Water Prawn Farming in Bangladesh: History, Present Status and Future Prospects." Aquaculture Research, 2008: 1-14.

Ambrose-Oji, B. "The contribution of NTFPs to the livelihoods of the ‘forest poor’." International Forestry Review, 2003: 106-117.

Azad, A. Kalam, Kathe R. Jensen, and C. Kwei Lin. "Coastal Aquaculture Development in Bangladesh: Unsustainable and Sustainable Experiences." Environmental Management 44 (2009): 800-809.

Ball, Jeff. Understanding and Correcting Soil Acidity. January 1999. http://www.noble.org/AG/Soils/SoilAcidity/index.htm (accessed February 12, 2010).

Barbier, Edward B., and Mark Cox. "An Economic Analysis of Shrimp Farm Expansion and Mangrove Conversion in Thailand." Land Economics 80, no. 3 (August 2004): 389-407.

Barbier, Edward, and Mark Cox. "Does Economic Development Lead to Mangrove Loss? A Cross Country Analysis." Contemporary Economic Policy 21, no. 4 (2003): 418-432.

Barbier, Edward, and Suthawan Sathirathai. Shrimp Farming and Mangrove Loss in Thailand. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing, 2004.

BBS. "Updating Poverty Maps of Bangladesh." Bangladesh Bureau of Statistics. February 2009. http://www.bbs.gov.bd/dataindex/povertymb.pdf (accessed February 21, 2010).

Campbell, Ruth, and Jeanne Downing. "Microlinks." Key Elements of the Value Chain Approach. July 2008. http://www.microlinks.org/ev.php?ID=24002_201&ID2=DO_TOPIC (accessed January 9, 2010).

CEGIS and IWM. Investigating the Impact of Relative Sea-Level Rise on Coastal Communities and their Livelihoods in Bangladesh. Dhaka: UK Department of Environment Food and Rural Affairs, 2007.

CEGIS. Impact of Sea Level Rise on Landuse Suitability and Adaptation Options. Coastal Land Use Zoning in the Southwest, Dhaka: Ministry of Environment and Forest Bangladesh and UNDP, 2006.

Chomitz, Kenneth M. At Loggerheads?: Agricultural Expansion, Poverty Reduction, and Environment in the Tropical Forests. Washington, D.C.: The World Bank, 2007.

52

Chowdhury, Ruhul Mohaiman. "Governance through Protected Area Conservation Co-Management Committees: A Case Study at Lawachara National Park." In Connecting Communities and Conservation: Collaborative Management of Protected Areas in Bangladesh, by Jefferson Fox, Bryan Bushley, Wendy Miles and Shimona Quazi, 49-72. Dhaka: East-West Center and Nishorgo Program of Bangladesh Forest Department, 2008.

Dixon, John A., and Paul B. Sherman. "Economics of Protected Areas." Ambio 20, no. 2 (April 1991): 68-74.

DoE. Annual Report 2006. Dhaka: Bangladesh Ministry of Environment and Forests - Department of Environment , 2006.

EJF. Desert in the Delta. A Report on the Environmental, Human Rights and Social Impacts of Shrimp Production in Bangladesh, London: Environmental Justice Foundation, 2004.

EJF. Mangroves: Nature's Defense Against Tsunamis. A Report on the Impact of Mangrove Loss and Shrimp Fram Development on Coastal Defenses, London: Environmental Justice Foundation, 2006.

FAO. Forest Resources of Bangladesh - Country Report. Forest Resource Assessment Programme, Rome: FAO - Forestry Department, 2000.

FAO. Integrated Resource Development of the Sundarbans Reserve Forest Project - Finding and Recommendations. Final Project Report, Rome: Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations, 1998.

FAO. The World's Mangroves 1980 - 2005. FAO Forestry Paper 153, Rome: Food and Agricultural Organization of the UN, 2007.

Fulton, Murray, and Brent Hueth. "Cooperative Conversions, Failures and Restructurings: An Overview." Journal of Cooperatives 23 (2009): i-xi.

Godoy, Ricardo, Ruben Lubowski, and Anil Markandya. "A Method for the Economic Valuation of Non-Timber Tropical Forest Products." Economic Botany 47, no. 3 (1993): 220-133.

Hossain, Mahabub, Aldas Janaiah, and Muazzam Husain. "Hybrid Rice in Bangladesh." Economic and Political Weekly, 2003: 2517-2522.

Hossain, Md. Shahadat, Lin C. Kwei, and M. Zakir Hussain. "Goodbye Chakaria Sunderban: The Oldest Mangrove Forest." Tropical Coastal Zone Management-Asian Institute of Technology, 2001: 19-22.

Huda, Khawja Shamsul. "Co-Management Of Protected Areas In Bangladesh: A Strategy For Establishing An Institutional Framework." Nishorgo Web Site. 2006. http://www.nishorgo.org/files_pdf/ (accessed February 8, 2010).

Huda, N, and M. K. Roy. State of the Forests in Bangladesh State of Environment Report 1999. Dhaka: Dhaka: Forum of Environmental Journalists of Bangladesh, 1999.

Iftekar, M.S., and M.R. Islam. "Degeneration of Bangladesh's Sundarbans Mangroves: A Management Issue." International Forestry Review 6, no. 2 (2004): 123-135.

53

Iftekhar, M.S., and M.R. Islam. "Managing mangroves in Bangladesh: A strategy analysis." Journal of Coastal Conservation 10 (2004): 139-146.

Ito, Sanae. "From Rice to Prawns: Economic Transformation and Agrarian Structure in Rural Bangladesh." Journal of Peasant Studies 29, no. 2 (January 2002): 47-70.

Ito, Sanae. "Globalization and agrarian change: a case of freshwater prawn farming in Bangladesh." Journal of International Development 16, no. 7 (November 2004): 1003-1013.

Kabir, S. Humayun, interview by Author. Director - Bangladesh Frozen Foods Exporters Association Khulna, (January 7, 2010).

Kaplinsky, Raphael, and Mike Morris. "Handbook for Value Chain Research." 2001. http://asiandrivers.open.ac.uk/documents/Value_chain_Handbook_RKMM_Nov_2001.pdf (accessed December 28, 2009).

Karim, Quazi Md. Nurul. " Can Alternative Income Generating Activities Reduce Dependency on Protected Areas? Evidence from Teknaf Game Reserve." In Connecting Communities and Conservation: Collaborative Management of Protected Areas in Bangladesh, 191-208. Dhaka: East-West Center and Nishorgo Program of Bangladesh Forest Department, 2008.

Khan, Niaz Dr., interview by Soham Sen. Country Director - International Union for Conservation of Nature (IUCN) (January 5, 2010).

Knowler, D, and Others. "Assessing prospects for shrimp culture in the Indian Sundarbans: A combined simulation modelling and choice experiment approach." Marine Policy 33 (2009): 613–623.

Kongkeo, Hassanai, and F. Brian Davy. "Backyard Hatcheries and Small Scale Shrimp and Prawn Farming in Thailand ." In Success Stories in Asian Aquaculture, by Sena De Silva and F. Brian Davy, 67-83. Springer Netherlands, 2010.

Kundu, Ram Prasad, and Md. Sirajul Islam, interview by Soham Sen. Managers BRAC Prawn Hatcheries - Doomoria (January 7, 2010).

Leung, PingSun, and Carole Eagle. Shrimp Culture: Economics, Market, and Trade. Ames, IA: Blackwell Publishing, 2006.

Mabud, Mohammed A. "Bangladesh Population: Prospects and Problems." National Seminar on Bangladesh Population. Dhaka: Organization for Population and Poverty Alleviation, 2008. 1-14.

Mangrove Action Network. "Sustainable Alternatives to Shrimp Aquaculture." http://www.mangroveactionproject.org/issues/shrimp-farming/sustainable-alternatives-of-shrimp-aquaculture (accessed December 25, 2009).

Merrett, Neill. "Shrimp certification boost for Vietnam exports." Mangrove Action Network. May 29, 2007. http://www.mangroveactionproject.org/news/current_headlines/shrimp-certification-boost-for-vietnam-exports-1/ (accessed January 11, 2010).

Millat-e-Mustafa, Md. "A Review of Forest Policy Trends in Bangladesh." Policy Trend Report, 2002: 114-121.

54

Miththapala, Sriyanie. Mangroves. Colombo, Sri Lanka: International Union for Conservation of Nature and Natural Resources, 2008.

Moore, Mark H. Creating Public Value: Strategic Management in Government. Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1995.

Muhammed, Nur, Masao Koike, and Farhana Haque. "Forest policy and sustainable forest management in Bangladesh; an analysis from national and international perspectives." New Forests 36, no. 2 (2008).

Pearce, David, and Anil Markandya. "Marginal Opportunity Cost as a Planning Concept in Natural Resource Management." The Annals of Regional Science 21, no. 3 (1987): 18-32.

Phillips, M.J., Lin C. Kwei, and M.C.M. Beveridge. "Shrimp Culture and the Environment: Lessons from the World's Most Rapidly Expanding Warmwater Aquaculture Sector." In Environment and Aquaculture in Developing Countries, by R.S.V Pulin, H. Rosenthal and J.L. Maclean, 171-197. Manila: International Center for Living Aquatic Resources Management (ICLARM), 1993.

Primavera, J. Honculada. "Socio-Economic Impacts of Shrimp Culture." Aquaculture Research 28 (1997): 815-827.

Rafiquzzaman, M., interview by Soham Sen. Bagda Farmer and Head of Khulna Bar Association (January 6, 2010).

Reardon, Thomas, C. Peter Timmer, Christopher Barrett, and Julio Berdegue. "The Rise of Supermarkets in Africa, Asia, and Latin America." American Journal of Agricultural Economics 85, no. 5 (December 2003): 1140-1146.

Salafsky, Nick, and Eva Wollenbert. "Linking Livelihoods and Conservation; A Conceptual Framework and Scale for Assessing the Integration of Human Needs and Biodiversity." World Development 28, no. 8 (2000): 1421-1438.

Samsuddoha, M. The Sundarban of Bangladesh. Salinity Threatens the World Heritage, COAST Trust, Dhaka: Equity and Justice Working Group, 2007.

Sarkar, Tapan. "Incidence of income taxation in Bangladesh." UN Public Administration Network. 2008. http://unpan1.un.org/intradoc/groups/public/documents/UNPAN/UNPAN014405.pdf (accessed December 21, 2009).

Shameem, Masud Iqbal Md., interview by Author. Deputy Director - Technical, Department of Environment (January 10, 2010).

Shiiva, V. "The damaging social and environment effects of aquaculture." Third World Resurgenc 59 (1995): 22-24.

Srinath, Krishna, Manpal Sridhar, and P.N.R. Kartha. "Group farming for sustainable aquaculture." Ocean and Coastal Management 43 (2000): 557-571.

The Economist. "The promise of a blue revolution." The Economist , August 7, 2003.

USAID/Bangladesh. "A Pro-Poor Analysis of The Shrimp Sector in Bangladesh." USAID Website. Keywords: Women in Development. 2006. http://www.usaid.gov/our_work/cross-

55

cutting_programs/wid/pubs/Bangladesh_Shrimp_Value_Chain_Feb_2006.pdf (accessed February 2, 2010).

USAID/Bangladesh. Conservation of Tropical Forests and Biological Diversity in Bangladesh. FAA 118/119 Analysis, USAID, 2005.

USAID/Bangladesh-IPAC. Work Planning Session With Department of Environment on Co-Management of Protected Areas. Summary Report, Dhaka: USAID, 2008.

Weiwei, Xu. "Bangladesh to Launch Agriculture Subsidy Card System ." Xinhua - China Radio International. February 11, 2010. http://english.cri.cn/6826/2010/02/11/1601s549781.htm (accessed February 14, 2010).

World Bank. Bangladesh: Country Environmental Analysis. Bangladesh Development Series: Paper 12, Dhaka: The World Bank, 2006.

World Bank. High-value Agriculture in Bangladesh: An Assessment of Agro-business Opportunities and Constraints. Bangladesh Development Series #21, Sustainable Development Department, Agricultural and Rural Development Unit, South Asia Region, Dhaka: The World Bank, 2008.

World Bank. The Sundarbans in Bangladesh (Forthcoming). Background Paper, The World Bank, 2009.