79
Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment Partnership Arguments and Counterarguments March 2015

Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    0

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment Partnership Arguments and Counterarguments

March 2015

Page 2: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

2

This report was requested by the office of Tamas Meszerics (Member of the European

Parliament) via The Greens/EFA group of the European Parliament.

Author:

Whitby Kft, Hungary

http://whitby.hu

[email protected]

Responsible office:

Tamas MESZERICS

Member of the European Parliament

[email protected]

ASP 5 F 252

rue Wiertz 60

B-1047 Brussels

Publication:

Editorial closing date: 10/03/2015

Photo on the cover: TRADES by Pryere on Flickr, CC Attribution/Non-commercial license 2.0

Printed in the European Parliament

The opinions expressed in this document are the sole responsibility of the author and do not

necessarily represent the official position of the European Parliament.

Reproduction and translation, except for commercial purposes, are authorised, provided the

source is acknowledged and provided the publisher is given prior notice and supplied with an

electronic copy of the publication.

Page 3: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

3

Executive Summary

This study gives a brief overview of the projected effects of the proposed Transatlantic

Trade and Investment Partnership between the European Union and the United States, and the

debate which has evolved around it.

First, we give an overview of what is supposed to be the “hard facts” in the core of the

debate, that is, the current state of the EU-US trade and the prospects of negotiating a large scale

regional free trade agreement. There are a few key points to be made:

TTIP is unique in many ways. Transatlantic trade is already relatively free, which

is partly proven by the fact that the EU and US are one of each other's most

important partner (if not the most important partner) in terms of trade and FDI.

Also, there are not much tariffs left to be abolished.

That being said, everyone agrees that if TTIP is going to have significant effect,

which will stem from abolishing what the trade jargon calls “non-tariff barriers”

or “non-tariff measures” (NTMs) - regulations, basically.

Most quantitative studies are predicting effects on national income and wages for

participating countries well below 1% in real terms over a long run of 15 years.

These are understood as one-time level increases, not changes to yearly growth

rates. This is true even with the most ambitious scenarios, where most NTMs are

assumed to be abolished.

These studies are mostly very optimistic in their assumptions on the nature of

NTMs, but are also very similar in their modelling techniques and the data they

use. Studies based on different assumptions show a much worse picture – namely,

significant decrease in all relevant socioeconomic indicators.

We provide an insight into the methodological debate over the quantitative impact

assessments of TTIP.

Second, we look at the arguments around which the public debate crystallizes. Without

taking a stand in the questions, we replicate the main issues raised by TTIP:

Arguments over its general effectiveness: why do we want to have TTIP? It is,

of course, the economic growth. But will there be growth? What does that growth

depend on? If there is growth, is it enough?

Over the costs, benefits and possible means of regulatory convergence:

regulatory convergence means that doing business is made easier. But at what

cost? Do we have to abandon such important EU values such as the precautionary

principle? Do we have to adopt American standards? Are those lower than ours?

Are labour rights doomed under TTIP? Do we have to privatize public services

and open up procurement markets?

Issues that have a potential effect on the environment: does TTIP mean the

enforcement of shale gas on Europe?

Democracy and transparency: is a coup d’état going on against European

democracy by big corporations, or is it just that elected leaders try to come up

with the best agreement they can?

The geopolitical context of TTIP and its effect on the prospects of the world

trade system: does TTIP re-invigorate world trade, or euthanize it? Does it

divide, or does it promote convergence? What should countries hope for which

are not participating, but will nevertheless experience its effects?

The core issues in terms of agriculture and food security: do we have to eat

chlorinated chicken, genetically modified corn, hormone treated beef from now

Page 4: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

4

on, and endure that American companies abuse of Europe’s oldest geographical

brands?

The controversial topic of investor protection under the new trade regime:

are we privatizing justice under the guide of TTIP and Investment-State Dispute

Settlement?

Third, we look at how TTIP might affect each EU members by collecting country-

specific data from the existing impact studies (where available) and data on the their trade with

the US (how important it is in terms of GDP and in which industries it manifests) – this latter

info then can be contrasted with the industry-specific predictions on EU-US trade.

In the appendix we give the list of “non-trade measures” as presented in one of the

studies, and highlight does which are particularly controversial in the light of the TTIP debate.

Page 5: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

5

Table of Contents

Executive Summary ...................................................................................................................... 1

1. Assessment on the large quantitative studies on TTIP and the corresponding criticism –

What is to be expected from TTIP? ............................................................................................. 7

1.1. Chapter introduction ................................................................................................................. 7

1.2. Overview of the US-EU trade .................................................................................................. 8

1.3. Main results in comparison ...................................................................................................... 9

1.4. Detailed results from the quantitative studies ........................................................................ 10

1.4.1. Ecorys (2009) ................................................................................................................. 10

1.4.2. CEPII (2013) .................................................................................................................. 12

1.4.3. CEPR (2013) .................................................................................................................. 13

1.4.4. Bertelsmann/Ifo (2013)................................................................................................... 16

1.4.5. Capaldo (2014) ............................................................................................................... 19

1.5. Criticism of the quantitative studies ....................................................................................... 20

1.5.1. Oversold results .............................................................................................................. 20

1.5.2. Conceptual errors, biased opinions ................................................................................. 21

1.5.3. Bad economics ................................................................................................................ 23

2. Argument Catalog ................................................................................................................... 24

2.1. Effectiveness of TTIP in general ............................................................................................ 24

2.2. Regulatory convergence ......................................................................................................... 25

2.2.1. Regulatory convergence – general remarks.................................................................... 25

2.2.2. Labour rights .................................................................................................................. 26

2.2.3. Privatization of public services....................................................................................... 27

2.2.4. Access to procurement markets ...................................................................................... 27

2.2.5. Regulatory convergence – examples from particular industries .................................... 28

2.3. Environment ........................................................................................................................... 28

2.4. Democracy and transparency ................................................................................................. 30

2.5. Geopolitics, multilateralism vs bilateralism ........................................................................... 30

2.6. Effects on third countries ....................................................................................................... 32

2.7. Agriculture and food security ................................................................................................. 33

2.8. Investment protection ............................................................................................................. 36

3. Country by country assessment ............................................................................................. 39

3.1. TTIP’s possible effects on Austria ......................................................................................... 39

3.2. TTIP’s possible effects on Belgium ....................................................................................... 40

3.3. TTIP’s possible effects on Bulgaria ....................................................................................... 41

3.4. TTIP’s possible effects on Croatia ......................................................................................... 41

3.5. TTIP’s possible effects on Cyprus ......................................................................................... 42

3.6. TTIP’s possible effects on the Czech Republic ..................................................................... 43

Page 6: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

6

3.7. TTIP’s possible effects on Denmark ...................................................................................... 44

3.8. TTIP’s possible effects on Estonia ......................................................................................... 44

3.9. TTIP’s possible effects on Finland......................................................................................... 45

3.10. TTIP’s possible effects on France ........................................................................................ 46

3.11. TTIP’s possible effects on Germany .................................................................................... 47

3.12. TTIP’s possible effects on Greece ....................................................................................... 48

3.13. TTIP’s possible effects on Hungary ..................................................................................... 48

3.14. TTIP’s possible effects on Ireland ....................................................................................... 49

3.15. TTIP’s possible effects on Italy ........................................................................................... 50

3.16. TTIP’s possible effects on Latvia ......................................................................................... 51

3.17. TTIP’s possible effects on Lithuania ................................................................................... 51

3.18. TTIP’s possible effects on Luxembourg .............................................................................. 52

3.19. TTIP’s possible effects on Malta ......................................................................................... 53

3.20. TTIP’s possible effects on the Netherlands .......................................................................... 53

3.21. TTIP’s possible effects on Poland ........................................................................................ 54

3.22. TTIP’s possible effects on Portugal ..................................................................................... 55

3.23. TTIP’s possible effects on Romania .................................................................................... 56

3.24. TTIP’s possible effects on Slovakia ..................................................................................... 56

3.25. TTIP’s possible effects on Slovenia ..................................................................................... 57

3.26. TTIP’s possible effects on Spain .......................................................................................... 58

3.27. TTIP’s possible effects on Sweden ...................................................................................... 58

3.28. TTIP’s possible effects on United Kingdom ........................................................................ 59

References .................................................................................................................................... 61

Appendix ...................................................................................................................................... 65

Page 7: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

7

1. Assessment on the large quantitative studies on TTIP and the

corresponding criticism – What is to be expected from TTIP?

1.1. Chapter introduction

This chapter provides a comparison of the main quantitative assessments of the

hypothesized effects of the proposed Trans-Atlantic free trade area. There are five main studies

we are aware of and several meta-studies which try to argue against both the theoretical and the

empirical validity (and relevance) of the impact assessment studies - we also cover the

arguments provided by these.

The earliest impact assessment study we are aware of was undertaken by the Rotterdam

based research and consultancy firm Ecorys. The document is entitled “Non-Tariff Measure in

EU-US Trade and Investment - An Economic Analysis” (Ecorys, 2009). The study gives model

estimations on the effects of a then hypothetical EU-US free trade agreement, which they base

on trade data, expert opinion and firm surveys. The next study was made four years later at the

Centre for Economic Policy Research at London, and was sponsored by the Directorate General

for Trade of the European Commission (Francois et al, 2013). This study heavily builds on its

precursor using the same modelling technique and assumptions, the main differences being its

increased forecast horizon and more recent baseline data. The predicted economic consequences

also fall in line with those from the Ecorys study. The France based research centre CEPII

published their study in the same year; they started from similar assumptions and arrived at very

similar conclusions. The most important commonality of these studies besides their similarities

in modelling techniques is, unsurprisingly the lack of significant variation in the quantitative

impact on trade and national income, which are both generally predicted to be modest at best.

The only supportive study which substantially moved away from this methodological

canon was the paper by Felberaymr et al. published as a CESifo working paper the next year

(Fabelmayr et al., 2014), later turned into a policy paper of Bertelsman Stiftung. Using a similar

modelling technique but different assumptions on how the economy would adapt to the policy

changes under TTIP the authors provide scenarios of which some show an impact which exceeds

the previous impact estimates multiple times.

The series of supportive studies stop here. Raza et al. provide a thorough meta-analysis of

the previous work pointing out serious issues in terms of theoretical credibility and data use

(Reza et al. 2014) - we replicate the main arguments of their work in this chapter. Jeronim

Capaldo also overviews the precursor studies and gives his very own impact analysis making use

of a wholly different methodology, resulting in completely different results - results which show

that TTIP would hurt the EU economies substantially (Capaldo, 2014). In a very recent paper

Martin Myant and Ronan O’Brien also provide arguments against the widely accepted and

referenced model estimates while also point out that the main discourse of reducing non-trade

barriers misses the whole point of the question (Myant and O’Brien, 2015).

The remaining part of the chapter is organized as follows. First, we sum up the main

quantitative findings of the five impact studies. Then we compare them in terms of methodology

and their use of data. The final part of the chapter summarizes the critical arguments made

against these research practices.

From now on in this chapter we will reference the aforementioned studies for the sake of

simplicity as Ecorys (for Ecorys, 2009), CEPR (for Francois et al. 2013), CEPII (for Fontagné et

al. 2013), Ifo (for Felbermayr et al. 2014a and Felbermayer et al. 2014b) and Capaldo (for

Capaldo, 2014), respectively.

Page 8: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

8

1.2. Overview of the US-EU trade

• Tariffs across the countries are already low

• EU and US are main trading partners, in particular in Chemicals and

Machinery and transport equipment

• They are also the most important source and destination for FDI of each

other as well.

If there is one empirical fact all studies agree upon, that would be the fact that the

proposed trade agreement is in many regards unprecedented. The reasons for this are 1) that the

EU-US trade is already very extensive, the two areas being the main trade partners for each

other, the same being true for foreign direct investment as well 2) that usual trade barriers

(customs duties, quotas) in most sectors are already relative low, close to actual free trade 3) if

TTIP is to have any significant effect, irrespectively of it being a positive or a negative one, that

would stem from the alleviation of the so called non-trade barriers, or non-trade measures.

As the CEPR study correctly points out, US is the most important export market for the

EU (17% of total exports in 2011), and the third most important source of imports (with its 11%

after China and Russia). The US only exports more to Canada than the EU, and only imports

more from China (17% of exports, 11% of imports). As seen in Figure 1, most trade activity

takes place in the chemicals industry and the machinery and transport equipment industry. The

US is the single most important FDI source and destination for the EU (€1201 billion and €1195

billion in 2010, respectively).

Tariffs are already relatively low between the two countries, for most industries ranging

between 1-3%. Notable exceptions are processed foods, motor vehicles and agricultural products

on which the EU levies heavy tariffs (rates are 14.6, 8, 3.7, respectively), while the US tends to

penalize imports of processed foods and agricultural products (3.3% and 3.7%). The Ecorys

study lists the industries with the most serious non-tariff barriers and finds that they are the

industries of chemicals, cosmetics, biotechnology and the aerospace industry for exporting to the

EU, while in the chemicals, cosmetics, biotechnology and the aerospace industries is it the

hardest to export to the US. The studies pose that alleviating these barriers are the key to TTIP’s

success as traditional trade barriers are already quite low.

Figure 1 EU–US trade in goods (taken from CEPR, source: Eurostat)

Page 9: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

9

1.3. Main results in comparison

• Most models use similar methodology and data, and find very modest

positive economic effects of TTIP

• The one study which is different in methodology finds considerable negative

impact.

Table 1-2 Comparison of findings

Ecorys (2009)

1 CEPII (2013) CEPR (2013)

Bertelsmann/ifo

(2013) Capaldo (2014)

Basic Assumptions

CGE GTAP MIRAGE GTAP Simulation of

gravity model

UN Global

Policy Model

Data GTAP 7 GTAP GTAP 8 not specified

Non-tariff measures

(NTM) Ecorys

CEPII

& Ecorys Ecorys ifo

Use predicted

export growth

from previous

studies

Forecast period 2008-2018 2015-2025 2017-2027 10-20 years 2015-2025

No. of Scenarios 7 5 5 3 1

Tariffs reduction 100% of goods

75% of services 100% 98-100% 100%

No tariffs in the

model, use

predicted export

growth from

other studies

NTM reduction in

reference scenario 25% 25% 25%

Reduction

corresponding

to trade creation

effect

Use predicted

export growth

from other

studies

Main Findings

(different scenarios, percentage changes compared to baseline scenario within forecasting period)

EU GDP 0.32-0.72 0.0-0.5 0.02-0.48 0.52-1.313

-0.5-

-0.07

4

US GDP 0.13-0.28 0.0-0.5 0.01-0.39 0.35-4.823 0.36

EU bilateral exports not specified 49.0 2 0.69-28.0 5.7-68.8

3

Taken from

other studies

EU total exports 0.91-2.07 7.6 2

0.16-5.91

(extra-EU only) not specified

Taken from

other studies

EU real wages 0.34-0.78 N/A 0.29-0.51 not specified -4848-

-1654

Unemployment rate

in

EU-OECD countries

(avge. %-points)

unchanged

(assumption)

unchanged

(assumption)

unchanged

(assumption)

-0.42

(deep

liberalization)

-583000 jobs

(EU total)

1 Findings for ambitious and limited scenarios only 2 Reference scenario only 3 Derived from BMWT/ifo (2013), aggregated to EU-27 level 4 Given country by country, these are the minimum and maximum values

Sources: Raza, Werner et al. (2014), Capaldo (2014)

Table 1 contains both the methodological comparison of the main studies and the

differences in core. Out of the five studies in question four employ a computable general

equilibrium (CGE) modelling framework. Out of the 4 CGE studies 3 involve using the same

database (GTAP) and engage in the modelling strategy of quantifying the NTM-s as listed in

Ecorys. In contrast, the Ifo studies make the assumption that the TTIP will have similar effects as

previous big trade deals (such as NAFTA) and extrapolate the empirics of those to the TTIP

case. The Capaldo study uses a different model, the UN Global Policy Model, a large-scale

Page 10: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

10

econometric model which tries to take into account several policy constraints coming from

previous behaviour of states.1

Table 2 shows the results of the four studies at first glance. The results are unsurprising in

one regard: the three studies which are the most closely related present very similar quantitative

results. This shows that long run positive effects are modest. Two studies don’t fall in line with

the others: the Ifo studies are much more optimistic regarding the TTIP’s effects on the Atlantic

economy, while the Capaldo results are exactly the opposite. He finds quite significant negative

effects.

1.4. Detailed results from the quantitative studies

1.4.1. Ecorys (2009)

• The study finds one-time GDP and wage growth under 1% under all

scenarios on long run (over 15 years)

• This is not affecting growth rates, this is affecting levels.

Table 3 Summary of macroeconomic effects (Ecorys)

Ambitious Scenario

(full liberalisation)

– Short Run

Ambitious Scenario

(full liberalisation)

– Long Run

Limited Scenario

(partial liberalisation)

– Short Run

Limited Scenario

(partial liberalisation)

– Long Run

Real income

[billion €]

US 19.0 40.8 7.8 18.3

EU 45.9 121.5 19.4 53.6

Real income

[% change]

US 0.13 0.28 0.05 0.13

EU 0.27 0.72 0.11 0.32

Real household income

[% change]

US 0.16 0.31 0.07 0.14

EU 0.32 0.79 0.14 0.35

Real wages - unskilled

workers [% change]

US 0.24 0.35 0.11 0.16

EU 0.40 0.82 0.17 0.36

Real wages - skilled

workers [% change]

US 0.26 0.38 0.11 0.17

EU 0.36 0.78 0.16 0.34

Value of Exports

[% change]

US 6.12 6.06 2.72 2.68

EU 1.69 2.07 0.74 0.91

Value of Imports

[% change]

US 3.97 3.93 1.76 1.74

EU 1.63 2.00 0.72 0.88

Terms of trade

[% change]

US -0.15 -0.23 -0.06 -0.10

EU 0.11 0.07 0.05 0.03

1 Criticism of the CGE approach found in Grassini 2007, Lance and von Amin 2006, McKitrick 1998

Page 11: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

11

• Most effects take place through the growing output of the Processed foods,

the Chemicals and the Motor vehicles industries.

Table 4 Estimated sectoral effects under different scenarios (Ecorys)

Outcome 1A 1B 2A 2B 3A 3B 4A 4B 5A

Processed foods (food &

beverages) 5.0 0.9 0.0 5.4 0.8 0.9 0.4 5.4

Chemicals, cosmetics,

pharmaceuticals 7.1 2.2 0.4 6.2 1.1 2.2 1.0 6.2

Electrical machinery

(electronics, OICE) 1.6 -5.5 0.4 -4.6 0.8 -5.5 -2.1 -4.6

Motor vehicles

(automotives) 12.0 5.7 2.3 10.7 4.3 5.7 2.3 10.7

Other transport

equipment (aerospace) 0.2 -0.9 1.1 4.2 2.2 -0.9 -0.4 4.2

Metals and metal

products 0.7 -0.5 0.0 2.7 0.5 -0.5 -0.2 2.7

Wood & paper products 1.1 0.0 -0.2 1.6 0.0 0.0 0.0 1.6

Finance 1.2 0.4 0.1 2.6 1.6 0.4 0.2 2.6

Insurance -0.1 1.2 0.7 5.9 4.3 1.2 0.6 5.9

Business services & ICT 0.5 0.5 0.0 0.6 0.0 0.5 0.2 0.6

Communications 1.0 0.2 -0.2 0.3 -0.1 0.2 0.1 0.3

Personal, recreational &

cultural services 0.3 -0.1 -0.1 -0.8 0.5 -0.1 0.0 0.2

Construction 0.0 0.8 0.0 0.2 0.0 0.8 0.4 -0.8

Total 121.5 30.8

1: Summary of changes in national income following NTM alignment (billions €, ambitious scenario – Long Run)

2: Summary of sector level percentage changes in output following NTM alignment (ambitious scenario – Long Run)

3: Summary of sector level percentage changes in exports following NTM alignment (ambitious scenario – Long Run)

4: Percentage change in output at the sectoral level for the EU

5: Percentage change in exports at the sectoral level for the EU

A: Economy-wide NTM reductions (i.e. reductions of NTMs in all sectors simultaneously)

B: Sector-specific NTM reductions (i.e. reductions of NTMs only in the specific sector)

Note: Air/Water transportation left out due to inconsistencies across calculation

Page 12: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

12

1.4.2. CEPII (2013)

• Effects on EU again under 1%, slight decline for agriculture.

• Real income effects are again under one time 1% increase.

• German manufacturing industry benefits the most and UK agriculture is hit

the hardest

Table 5 Macroeconomic effects of TTIP (CEPII)

Total (GDP)

Value added

Agriculture Industry Services

USA 0.3 1.9 0.5 0.2

EU27 0.3 -0.8 0.6 0.5

Of which:

Germany 0.4 -1.6 0.9 0.4

UK 0.4 -2.3 0.4 0.5

France 0.2 -0.7 0.5 0.3

Enlargement 0.2 0.0 0.4 0.3

Note: volume, percentage deviation from baseline in 2025.

Table 6 Real income and export changes under different scenarios (CEPII)

Ref

Alternative scenarios

1 2 3 4

Tariffs

only

Targeted

NTM cuts

Harmonization

spillovers

Alternative

NTMs

Export:

USA 10.1 2.1 10.4 14.5 5.4

EU27 2.3 0.4 1.9 3.4 1.3

Of which:

Germany 2.1 0.3 1.7 3.0 1.2

UK 4.2 0.6 3.6 5.5 2.4

France 2.6 0.5 2.2 3.8 1.5

Enlargement 1.3 0.3 0.8 2.5 0.7

Real income:

USA 0.3 0.0 0.3 0.5 0.2

EU27 0.3 0.0 0.2 0.5 0.1

Of which: Germany 0.3 0.0 0.3 0.5 0.2

UK 0.3 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.1

France 0.2 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.1

Enlargement 0.2 0.0 0.1 0.5 0.1

Note: volume, percentage deviation from baseline in 2025.

Page 13: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

13

• US-EU trade flows go up significantly, while there is considerable trade

diversion from the rest of the world

Table 7 Effects on bilateral trade flows (CEPII)

Exporter Importer Total Agriculture Industry Services

Transatlantic trade

USA EU27 52.5 168.5 66.4 14.0

EU27 USA 49.0 149.5 61.8 24.0

Other trade flows

USA RoW -1.4 -1.9 -1.3 -1.6

EU27 RoW -1.4 -0.4 -1.4 -1.4

RoW USA -2.5 -0.8 -2.8 -0.7

RoW EU27 0.2 -1.5 0.1 0.6

EU27 EU27 -1.2 -2.6 -2.3 2.8

RoW RoW 0.1 0.0 0.2 0.2

Note: trade in volume, percentage deviation from baseline in 2025.

• Total trade grows on average.

Table 8 Effects on total trade flows (CEPII)

Imports

Exports

Total Agriculture Industry Services

USA 7.5 10.1 12.6 12.2 3.2

EU27 (excluding intra EU) 7.4 7.6 7.0 8.9 4.5

EU27 (including intra EU) 2.2 2.3 0.6 1.9 3.6

Of which:

Germany 2.5 2.1 -2.6 2.0 2.9

UK 3.0 4.2 0.5 3.9 4.8

France 2.5 2.6 -0.3 2.6 3.1

Enlargement 1.2 1.3 4.2 0.8 3.3

Note: trade in volume, percentage deviation from baseline in 2025.

1.4.3. CEPR (2013)

• CEPR also finds one-time household income growth under 1% after 15

years.

Table 9 Summary of macroeconomic effects (CEPR)

Limited

agreement:

tariffs only

Limited

agreement:

services only

Limited

agreement:

procurement only

Comprehensive

agreement:

less ambitious

Comprehensive

agreement:

ambitious

Change

in GDP

EU 23,753 5,298 6,367 68,274 119,212

US 9,447 7,356 1,875 49,543 94,904

Bilateral

exports FOB

EU to US 43,84 4,591 6,997 107,811 186,965

US to EU 53,777 2,859 3,411 100,909 159,098

Total

exports FOB

extra-EU 43,74 5,777 7,136 125,232 219,97

US 57,33 5,488 5,942 142,071 239,543

Notes: Estimates to be interpreted as changes relative to a projected 2027 global economy. All amounts are shown in million

euros.

Page 14: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

14

• With the most comprehensive agreement accepted, EU households will earn

545 euros more each year.

Table 10 Changes in household disposable income (CEPR)

Limited agreement:

tariffs only

Comprehensive

agreement:

low ambition

Comprehensive

agreement:

high ambition

Total EU [mill. €] 12,934 39,813 70,82

US [mill. €] 5,081 29,982 58,434

EU [%] 0.09 0.28 0.49

US [%] 0.03 0.18 0.35

EU [€ per household] 99 306 545

US [€ per household] 57 336 655

Notes: Estimates to be interpreted as changes relative to a projected 2027 global economy.

Figure 2 Market Access Impact Ranking (CEPR)

• Those industries benefit the most from TTIP which have higher share in

value added.

Page 15: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

15

• Trade in processed food, chemicals, transport equipment, metal and

wood products and business services will increase the most.

• Most trade diversion from EU internal trade to US trade will occur in

the sectors of motor vehicles, chemicals, electrical machinery, metals

and metal products.

Table 11 Sectorial changes in output and trade diversion (CEPR)

Scenario/Sector

Baseline

shares in

value added

Output

change:

Less

ambitious

Output

change:

Ambitious

Export

change (non

US) Total

[million €]

Trade

diverted from

intra-EU

trade Total

[million €]

Agr forestry fisheries 0.040 0.05 0.06 -1 270 269

Other primary sectors 0.019 0.01 0.02 250 345

Processed foods 0.030 0.30 0.57 3 247 -425

Chemicals 0.028 0.09 0.37 5 591 -13 208

Electrical machinery 0.004 -3.74 -7.28 -2 551 -12 829

Motor vehicles 0.015 0.24 1.54 7 559 -36 517

Other transport equipment 0.007 -0.17 -0.08 1 074 -2 468

Other machinery 0.037 0.40 0.37 1 422 492

Metals and metal products 0.021 -0.71 -1.50 4 139 -11 464

Wood and paper products 0.023 0.08 0.08 2 454 -799

Other manufactures 0.029 0.69 0.79 2 243 2 087

Water transport 0.003 0.55 0.99 951 -35

Air transport 0.003 0.30 0.44 810 76

Finance 0.032 0.23 0.42 552 129

Insurance 0.010 0.44 0.83 406 84

Business services 0.222 0.15 0.25 2 808 1 068

Communications 0.023 0.10 0.17 295 53

Construction 0.083 0.31 0.53 336 131

Personal services 0.035 0.15 0.26 898 124

Other services 0.338 0.16 0.28 2 065 795

Total 33 279 -72 092

Notes: Estimates to be interpreted as changes relative to a projected 2027 global economy. All amounts are shown in million

euros.

Page 16: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

16

1.4.4. Bertelsmann/Ifo (2013)

• Under the most likely scenario all effects again are under 1% and are

understood as a one-time increase over the course of 15 years.

Table 12 Estimated changes if only tariffs are lowered (Bertelsmann/ifo)

Country

Percentage

rise in

employment

Change in

unemployment

rate in

percentage points

Percentage

change in real

wages

Australia -0.12 0.11 -0.56

Austria 0.07 -0.07 0.32

Belgium 0.02 -0.02 0.09

Canada -0.15 0.15 -0.71

Czech Republic 0.11 -0.10 0.53

Denmark 0.13 -0.12 0.63

Finland 0.21 -0.19 0.97

France 0.12 -0.11 0.54

Germany 0.12 -0.11 0.54

Greece 0.20 -0.17 0.93

Hungary 0.15 -0.13 0.70

Iceland -0.12 0.11 -0.56

Ireland 0.24 -0.21 1.14

Italy 0.16 -0.15 0.72

Japan -0.03 0.03 -0.14

Netherlands 0.09 -0.08 0.40

New Zealand -0.08 0.07 -0.37

Norway -0.12 0.12 -0.55

Poland 0.15 -0.13 0.69

Portugal 0.22 -0.19 1.20

Slovakia 0.14 -0.12 0.66

South Korea -0.03 0.03 -0.15

Spain 0.20 -0.16 0.92

Sweden 0.18 -0.16 0.85

Switzerland -0.11 0.10 -0.50

Turkey -0.11 0.10 -0.51

United Kingdom 0.37 -0.34 1.72

United States 0.20 -0.18 0.93

Average

(GDP-weighted) 0.13 -0.11 0.59

Page 17: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

17

• Trade partners of the US and EU are hurt significantly by TTIP

under this model.

Table 13 Effects under "deep liberalization” scenario (Bertelsmann/ifo)

Country

Percentage

rise in

employment

Change in

unemployment

rate in percentage

points

Percentage

change in real

wages

Australia -0.47 0.44 -2.14

Austria 0.28 -0.27 1.33

Belgium 0.09 -0.08 0.42

Canada -0.60 0.56 -2.75

Czech Republic 0.46 -0.42 2.14

Denmark 0.54 -0.50 2.54

Finland 0.81 -0.75 3.84

France 0.47 -0.43 2.22

Germany 0.47 -0.43 2.19

Greece 0.78 -0.68 3.68

Hungary 0.60 -0.53 2.81

Iceland -0.46 0.42 -2.12

Ireland 0.97 -0.84 4.61

Italy 0.62 -0.57 2.90

Japan -0.11 0.11 -0.53

Netherlands 0.35 -0.34 1.65

New Zealand -0.30 0.28 -1.40

Norway -0.46 0.44 -2.12

Poland 0.58 -0.53 2.75

Portugal 0.85 -0.76 4.03

Slovakia 0.56 -0.48 2.63

South Korea -0.13 0.12 -0.58

Spain 0.78 -0.62 3.65

Sweden 0.72 -0.65 3.37

Switzerland -0.43 0.41 -1.96

Turkey -0.42 0.38 -1.94

United Kingdom 1.38 -1.27 6.60

United States 0.78 -0.71 3.68

Average

(GDP-weighted) 0.50 -0.45 2.34

Page 18: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

18

Figure 3 Changes in global per capita incomes if only tariffs are reduced (Bertelsmann/ifo)

Figure 3 Changes in global per capita incomes under "deep liberalization" scenario (Bertelsmann/ifo)

• Assumptions of the second scenario are deemed unrealistic by the

European Commission. It only appears in the Bertelsmann policy

paper version of the original study.

Page 19: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

19

1.4.5. Capaldo (2014)

• The only study not using CGE methodology and taking into account

short-term effects in the economy shows considerable negative effects

of TTIP.

• Over 500.000 jobs will be lost, GDP decreases (however, the rate is

under 1%), tax incomes and net exports decrease.

Table 14 Long-term impact of TTIP (Capaldo)

Net Exports

[% GDP]

GDP Growth

[Diff between %]

Employment

[Units]

Empl. Income

[EUR/employee]

Net Taxes

[% GDP]

Depend. Ratio

[Diff between %]

US 1.02 0.36 784 000 699 0.00 -0.97

United Kingdom -0.95 -0.07 -3 000 -4 245 -0.39 0.01

Germany -1.14 -0.29 -134 000 -3 402 -0.28 0.75

France -1.90 -0.48 -130 000 -5 518 -0.64 1.31

Italy -0.36 -0.03 -3 000 -661 0.00 0.02

Other Northern Europe -2.07 -0.50 -223 000 -4 848 -0.34 1.33

Other Southern Europe -0.70 -0.21 -90 000 -165 -0.01 0.33

EU total -583 000

Note: Net Taxes are indirect taxes minus subsidies. Dependency Ratio is defined as ratio of total population to employed

population.

Page 20: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

20

• After a hypothetical TTIP introduction in 2015, projected share of

labour in nation income declines steadily, exacerbating previous

negative trends.

Figure 5 labour incomes as % of GDP (Capaldo). Blue: baseline projection without TTIP. Red: projected labour share

under TTIP

1.5. Criticism of the quantitative studies

1.5.1. Oversold results

• Almost all studies deal studies show one-time level increases in GDP which

are not affecting long term growth.

• Most of the economic benefits predicted are negligible. Myant and O’Brien

point out that by optimistic assumptions the income increase of average Europeans would

amount for the price of a cup of coffee per person per week, which does not justify optimal

optimism (Myant and O’Brien, 2015).

Page 21: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

21

• The actionability of NTMs are overestimated. The studies call a 25% reduction

in total NTMs the “ambitious” scenario. While this seems conservative, according to the Ecorys

survey this reduction amounts to half the NTMs faced by firms engaged in within-EU trade. That

is, the “ambitious” scenario would essentially mean assuming “that the US will be half-way to

becoming an embedded member of the EU” (Myant and O’Brien, 2015). The total social

benefit of the trade agreement is crucially sensitive to the assumed actionability level of the

barriers. The benefits are expected to be higher the more non-trade measures are eliminated,

thus, the estimated net benefits of TTIP are potentially overestimated along this margin as well

(Reza et al. 2014).

• The ifo paper’s later version is considered unrealistically positive by even the

European Commission. The second paper apparently uses gross output instead of GDP,

yielding in 2-4 times higher than realistic effects. (Myand and O’Brien, 2015)

1.5.2. Conceptual errors, biased opinions

• Social costs of dismantling NTMs are neglected. When calling for dismantling

non-trade barriers, all supportive studies assume that this can be done without significant social

costs.

• The nature of NTMs are misunderstood, the calculations are based on

opinions biased in one direction. Also, the catalog of non-trade measures in the EU-US trade is

based on a survey which is seriously biased towards business interests (e.g. only firm managers

and leaders of business associations were interviewed whose opinion, how justified they might

be, are far from being the only valid points in the debate (Raza et al. 2014). Also, these “barriers

to business” are typically measures that facilitate internalizing negative externalities, alleviating

information asymmetries etc. From this it directly follows that by dismantling them the negative

social costs they were trying to prevent from occurring will reappear instantly (Myant and

O’Brien 2015).

• Social costs of adjustment are ignored. The supportive studies assume away

macroeconomic adjustment costs, that is, the costs incurred by societies through the transition to

the new trade regime. These may involve costs of

o labour market adjustments (e.g. unemployment benefits), effects on public

budget balance (through the missing tax revenue from firms going out of

business and people losing their job),

o current account balance (large changes in trade flows might end up in currency

devaluations, which, if become common, can result in a race to the bottom

[Capaldo, 2014]). TTIP, as all trade agreements, is expected to result in a

reallocation of labour and capital across sectors. Essentially this means that

people who lose jobs in one sector are supposed to take up new ones in a totally

different but more competitive sector, which is potentially an unrealistic

assumption.

o If it indeed is, then TTIP will increase not just temporary, but structural

unemployment as well, a phenomenon also assumed away by these models

(Reza et al. 2014).

Page 22: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

22

A back-of-the-envelope calculation for the expected social costs of macroeconomic

adjustment is found in Table 15. The authors estimate that the social costs will be somewhere

between €32 and €60 billion for the next 15 years at 2012 prices.

Table 15 Rough calculation of macroeconomic adjustment costs (from Reza et al. 2014)

Lower Bound

(p.a.)

Lower Bound

(cumulative,

10 year period)

Upper Bound

(p.a.)

Upper Bound

(cumulative,

10 year period)

1. Loss of Public Revenue

Annual Loss of Tariff Revenues of 2.6 bn 2 600 000 000 26 000 000 000

Annual Loss of Tariff Revenues of

(€2.6+€5.4)*0.5

4 000 000 000 40 000 000 000

Adjustment Margin for Phase-Out Periods,

and Carve-Outs for

sensitive products (10%) 260 000 000 2 600 000 000 400 000 000 4 000 000 000

Sub-Total 2 340 000 000 23 400 000 000 3 600 000 000 36 000 000 000

2. Costs of Unemployment

a. Unemployment Benefits

43,000 long-term unemployed post-TTIP

(Year 1) 681 120 000 681 120 000

110,000 long-term unemployed post-TTIP

(Year 1)

1 742 400 000 1 742 400 000

43,000 long-term unemployed post-TTIP

(Year 2 - 5) 423 120 000 1 692 480 000

110,000 long-term unemployed post-TTIP

(Year 2 - 5)

1 082 400 000 4 329 600 000

387,000 short term unemployed post TTIP

(6 months)

3 065 040 000

990,000 short term unemployed post TTIP

(6 months)

7 840 800 000

Sub-Total

5 438 640 000

13 912 800 000

b. Foregone Public Income from Taxes and Social

Contributions

43,000 long-term unemployed post-TTIP

(Years 1 - 5)

2 039 705 000

111,000 long-term unemployed post-TTIP

(Years 1 - 5)

5 217 850 000

387,000 short-term unemployed post TTIP

(6 months)

1 835 734 500

990,000 short-term unemployed post TTIP

(6 months)

4 696 065 000

Sub-Total

3 875 439 500

9 913 915 000

Cumulative Adjustment Costs - TOTAL 32 714 079 500 59 826 715 000

Assumptions: Average duration of long-term unemployment during TTIP implementation phase: 5 years; Average duration of

short-term unemployment during TTIP implementation phase: 0.5 years; Number of displaced persons post-TTIP: 430,000

(lower bound) – 1,100,000 (upper bound), of which 90 % short-term and 10 % long-term unemployment

• Macroeconomic adjustment costs of TTIP range from €32 billion and €60

billion even by a simple calculation.

• Trade diversion effects are downplayed. The studies downplay some of the

negative effects. Trade diversion is most likely to occur, disproportionally hurting low income

partners of EU and the US, and also weakening internal trade relations within the EU. (Raza et

al. 2014)

• Ex post evaluations are usually showing smaller benefits than ex ante impact

studies. While the impact studies refer many times to the benefits of previous big trade

Page 23: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

23

liberalization event (the Ifo paper go as far as assuming that the TTIP’s effects will be identical

to those of NAFTA, for example), they ignore that the ex ante impact studies of these particular

trade agreements tended to prove overestimates of the actual ex post social benefits. In the case

of TTIP the predicted benefits of which are already modest at best, any overestimation can mean

that there will be no positive effect of the agreement at all.

1.5.3. Bad economics

• The modelling framework might be inappropriate theoretically. The model in

use in 4 out of 5 impact assessment studies is the so called Computable General Equilibrium

(CGE) modelling framework, which not a “general equilibrium model” in a microeconomic

sense (does not describe an optimal welfare allocation), but only in the strict macroeconomic

sense that the aggregate resource constraints of the economy apply. In this sense CGE is a

misnomer, while the feasibility of any microeconomically valid general equilibrium model is

questionable at best (Raza et al. 2014)

• The modelling framework is inappropriate practically.

o These models apply “long run” assumptions of macroeconomics, e.g. they

assume that on the long run all factors of production are allocated in some sector

(e.g. if there is unemployment some sector, wages go down somewhere and firms

suck up the idle workforce). Also, perhaps more importantly, the full factor

employment assumptions make these models unable to model any employment

effect (Raza et al. 2014, Myant and O’Brien 2015).

o The models only consider the average values of the variables, not

distributions. That is, if a model predicts 0.3% growth in GDP, it does not tell

whether that is a very small income growth for all individuals, or a single person

gets very rich. Or many get very rich, and many people get substantially poorer

on average resulting in a slight positive change (Capaldo 2014).

o Two out of four CGE studies consider the EU as a whole, again, saying

nothing about how the economic effects of TTIP are distributed across European

subregions and countries. This holds for income gains, but, perhaps most

importantly for possible displacement effects as well. (Capaldo 2014, Myant and

O’Brien 2015).

o CGE models used by the Ecorys, CEPR and CEPII models disregard the

government as an active entity. Government income and spending is

incorporated in the workings of the representative household, while these models

also assume the budget deficit to be constant (Raza et al. 2014)

o The models disregard foreign direct investment completely. Though one of the

main reasons for the TTIP is to improve conditions for FDI, these general

equilibrium models completely disregard it. The studies present calculations for

FDI effects, but they do not come from the same models, these are completely

separate econometric estimations. (Raza et el. 2014)

While these assumptions are useful for some purposes, they are unfit for saying anything

on the short run consequences on the EU and US economies, which are potentially substantial,

especially in the EU environment which already suffers from persistent unemployment and

anaemic economic growth.

• Quantitative assessment of non-trade measures is unsubstantiated at best in

the models. By their very nature, parts of the trade costs caused by the non-trade measures are

unobservable, and the tariff equivalents of these are hard to measure.

Page 24: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

24

2. Argument Catalog

This chapter presents the main arguments for and against TTIP, broken down into

categories by the content of the argument. For each category we summarized the main lines

along which the arguments go and then categorize the arguments into either “positive”,

“negative” or “mixed” categories. Each argument is followed by a reference to the document it

was taken from.

The categories we defined are:

1 Effectiveness of TTIP in general

2 Regulatory convergence

3 Environment

4 Democracy and transparency

5 Geopolitics, multilateralism vs bilateralism

6 Effects on 3rd countries

7 Agriculture and food security

8 Investment protection

2.1. Effectiveness of TTIP in general

Summary

The positive argument relies on the growth effects of TTIP and that market penetration will be

easier for European companies.

Those against TTIP instead point out the unreliability of the quantitative calculations and that the

envisioned growth effects are minuscule. Another concern is that quantitative studies have close

to no say about the distribution of costs and benefits created by TTIP.

Positive

• Two key arguments behind promoting TTIP: 1) TTIP would create significant

economic gains, 2) it would create new dynamic in the global trading system.

The first is now needed by Europe in particular. (Erixon, 2012a and 2012b)

• The idea of TTIP was embraced as a “last resort” by the EU to invigorate the

economy as monetary policy and fiscal austerity failed them. Also, it was a means

for the EU and the US to reassert global economic leadership. (Ikenson, 2014)

• TTIP will benefit small and medium enterprises which are now unable to

penetrate US markets. (Mildner, 2013)

• Myth says that “TTIP will only benefit big business”, while SMEs and consumers

also will benefit the most. The reason is that streamlined regulations and standards

would decrease the fixed costs of compliance which can be deterring smaller

firms from penetrating the US market. A simpler competition and public

procurement law would benefit small firms who do not have an own legal

department. Consumers would benefit from lower prices and increased varieties.

(FGI, 2014)

• The effects on SMEs are likely to be positive, since TTIP decreases the relative

cost of entering the global market. (DG For international Policies, 2015)

• “Brain drain” type of effects is not expected, since the skill levels of the two

signatory parties are similar. (DG For international Policies, 2015)

Mixed

• The obstacles that need to be overcome for TTIP to function are yet unexplored.

We cannot even estimate the hardship and the costs. (Dieter, 2013)

Page 25: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

25

• The TTIP will not bring equal benefits to all member states, but average increase

is expected. (DG For international Policies, 2015)

Negative

• The main goal of TTIP is to create economic growth. It is achieved through

reducing tariffs and non-tariff barriers. However, while tariffs protect from

competition and thus hinder growth, regulations are designed to protect from

hidden risks in the use of a given product or service. They promote consumer

welfare, essentially. The economic benefits thus depend on the level of regulatory

convergence achieved. (Fabry et al. 2014)

• Most of the studies say that economic gains will stem from alleviating NTM-s, but

the US and the EU are working on those since 1990, without any major success. If

they fail to do again, the economic gains of TTIP are under question. (Karnakar,

2013)

• Reducing tariffs is also harder than expected since they represent vested interests

in sugar, textiles etc. industries. (Karnakar, 2013)

• Since the anticipated “tremendous impact” of TTIP is entirely relying on legal

harmonisation, historical experience suggests that it will not live up to its

expectations. It will not achieve regulatory convergence and new global standards,

but through mutual recognition it will only lead to deregulation and will have no

indirect spillovers on the rest of the world. (De Ville, 2014)

• The previous free trade agreements such as NAFTA brought about job losses, yet

TTIP is sold to the general public as an engine of job creation.(Hartmann, 2014)

• It is possible that all social costs of the TTIP will be concentrated on some

member states of the EU, while the scarce benefits will be enjoyed by others

(Bizzarri, 2013)

2.2. Regulatory convergence

2.2.1. Regulatory convergence – general remarks

Summary

Supporters of TTIP emphasize that regulatory convergence means that doing business is made

easier while retaining the level of previous standards.

Those who oppose TTIP claim that the main thing at stake is the “precautionary principle”, the

general EU principle that for something (that is, a technology, a procedure or a given chemical)

to become legal, its non-harmfulness must be proven. This is not the case in the US.

Positive

• Harmonizing regulations makes doing business easier. The reason why these are

different is not due to divergent policy choices but purely that they were devised

independently. The goal is not to lower the levels of consumer protection, but to

encourage transparency and collaboration. (BusinessEurope,2014)

• TTIP promotes standards that are harmonised, but higher. It would lower costs

and open markets, and the EU – US standards would be promoted beyond the

transatlantic market. (BusinessEurope,2014)

• Myth says that “EU's high standards of consumer and environmental protection are

at risk”. The signing parties say that it is important to uphold the “right to

regulate in the public interest”. The aim is not to reduce the global level of

consumer safety but to achieve regulatory convergence, so that the same rules apply

on both sides of the Atlantic. (FGI, 2014)

Page 26: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

26

Negative

• The EU looks to the Precautionary Principle as the main regulatory principle

(“better safe than sorry” - for new technologies it must be proven that they are not

harmful for human life and the environment) while US employs “risk assessment”

approach linked to cost-benefit analyses, looking at cost for businesses versus

harms to citizens. These are hard to reconcile. Some argue that for US business the

TTIP is just a tool to get rid of the precautionary principle, particularly in the

case of policies such as REACH, the EU directive on Registration, Evaluation,

Authorisation and Restriction of Chemicals (Barker, 2014)

• EU has much stronger protections for consumers and environment in general,

which can be harmed by TTIP (Baker, 2014)

• TTIP is about pushing through regulatory changes which could not have been

pushed through the regular political process (Baker, 2014)

• Many of the factors embedded in TTIP are against the concept of free trade.

Instead of promoting less regulations and bigger liberty, these will extend existing

regulations (Baker, 2014)

• Removing regulatory barriers essentially means removing or downgrading of key

social standards and environmental regulations, such as labour rights and food

safety rules. (Hilary, 2014)

• The EU's use of the “precautionary principle” is a core issue – the TTIP

negotiations will essentially mean that the burden of proof shifts from those who

want to introduce a new chemical or technology to those who claim that it is

unhealthy. (Hilary 2014, Bizarri 2013)

2.2.2. Labour rights

Summary

The main question in the debate is whether TTIP would deteriorate European labour standards.

Supporters say that the trade deal has no provisions on labour, while opponents say that

eliminating “regulatory divergence” can be interpreted this way, and opening up markets can end

up in a “race to the bottom” where both EU and US engage in a series of cuts in labour rights to

ensure competitiveness.

Positive

• Myth says that “TTIP will erode high labour standards”. TTIP does not restrict the

contracting parties' right to maintain domestic regulation on labour affairs.

(FGI, 2014)

Negative

• Currently trade creates winners and losers, not winners and winners. Declining

labour share in income point out that workers in the US and in the EU have been

losing. (AFL-CIO, 2014)

• TTIP will hit employment in a time when youth unemployment is already at over

50% in some EU member states (Hilary, 2014)

• As the US has not ratified ILO Conventions on labour standards such as collective

bargaining and freedom of association, the “removal of trade barriers” in this regard

might mean a race to the bottom in terms of labour rights. (AFL-CIO, 2014 ,

Hilary 2014)

• TTIP might revoke European workers' rights to self-organise if a “race to the

bottom” scenario emerges in labour relations. (Bizzarri, 2013)

Page 27: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

27

2.2.3. Privatization of public services

Summary

Supporters of TTIP argue that privatization of public services is not on the table and it generally

is not there in free trade talks. The debate is on the fact that “opening up” a market to private

providers (which is indeed on the table) is essentially understood as a huge step towards

privatization as the opponents understand it.

Positive

• Myth says that “TTIP will lead to privatization in the areas of water supply,

healthcare and education”. The European Commission has declared that the

special status of public services will not be affected by TTIP. Restrictions on

market access to public services are found even in WTO agreements. Opening of

public procurement markets will not result in privatization but lower prices for

consumers and equal treatment of companies in the US procurement market. (FGI,

2014)

Negative

• TTIP is opening up public services for liberalization in an unprecedented way

(Bizzarri, 2013)

• TTIP should not facilitate replacing state provision of public services with private

provision but it currently defines public services too narrowly, making such an

outcome possible. (AFL-CIO, 2014)

• The US government has confirmed that TTIP will be used to open up service

markets in Europe in areas such as public utilities. The only exceptions the EC

wants to see are those related to the judiciary, border policing and air traffic control.

(Hilary, 2014)

• It will be effectively impossible to restore public services once they have been

privatized. (Hilary, 2014)

• The liberalization is done according to a “negative list”, that is, everything not

included in it is potentially subject to liberalization. The EU traditionally applied a

“positive list” approach to liberalization of public services. (Hilary, 2014)

2.2.4. Access to procurement markets

Summary

One of the main claimed benefits of TTIP is that EU companies would be able to enter the huge

US public procurement market which should withdraw its “buy American” regulations.

Opponents claim that the other side of this coin is that local governments would not have the

option to buy from local, more sustainable producers.

Positive

• EU companies would have access to the US procurement market.

(BusinessEurope, 2014)

Negative

• Opening up of public procurement markets will make local governments unable to

pursue they local social and ecological agendas. (Hilary, 2014)

• If TTIP will liberalize public procurement, then no levels of government in

Europe will be able to explore any alternative economic model to international

free trade (Bizzarri, 2013)

• Opening up public services and government procurement markets essentially

serves transnational corporate interests and will spark waves of privatizations in

sectors such as health and education. (Hilary, 2014)

Page 28: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

28

2.2.5. Regulatory convergence – examples from particular industries

2.2.5.1. Patents

Positive

• Harmonizing intellectual property right would support innovation and R&D

investment. EU and US could lead globally in IPR protection together.

(BusinessEurope,2014)

Negative

• The patent system in the US is frivolous and corrupt, and the patenting practices

raise prices and impede competition. This kind of patenting might arrive to

Europe through TTIP. (Baker, 2014)

• Americans pay on average twice as much on prescription drugs due to the patent

monopolies of drug companies. The pharmaceutical industry wants similar

regulations passed in the EU. (Baker, 2014)

• Adaptation of US patenting standards puts the access to information at risk. E.g. the

pharmaceutical industry seeks to restrict public access to clinical trial data under

the guise of the TTIP. (Hilary, 2014)

• TTIP will be undermining Europeans' access to affordable medicine through US

patent rules (Bizzarri, 2013)

2.2.5.2. Finance

• The financial sector seeks to undo the reforms which came after the crisis of

2008 (Bizzarri 2013, Hilary 2014)

2.2.5.3. Culture

• The cultural sector has relatively low economic performance but has a greater

relevance to society. (Kirchschlager, 2014)

• EU audiovisial markets are relatively open for US companies but not vice versa.

(Kirchschlager, 2014)

• Hollywood movies enjoy huge successes in Europe even under the protection

regime. (Kirchschlager, 2014)

2.2.5.4. Privacy

• There is no comprehensive EU data protection law which would be needed before

any negotiation takes place. TTIP promotes “flow of data”, but not data

protection. Sensitive personal data will be more likely to be stored in the cloud

storage of a US company exposing EU citizens. (Knoll, 2014)

• Some elements of the already rejected Anti-Counterfeiting Trade Agreement

are planned to be reintroduced under TTIP. Elements of these included

requirements of the internet service providers to monitor online activity to see

whether the user commits copyright infringements. (Bizarra 2013, Hilary 2014)

• It will be easier to gain access to personal information for commercial

purposes. (Hilary, 2014)

2.3. Environment

Summary

The main environmental concern of opponents is shale gas, through two channels: 1) enforcing

fracking technology on the European continent, 2) exacerbating fracking activities in America

through driving up demand. They argue that fracking is environmentally harmful. Supporters of

TTIP argue that since shale gas can be sold at a higher price in Asia as in Europe, TTIP will not

increase the demand for fossil fuel.

Page 29: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

29

Positive

• The EC does not foresee the US removal of the ban on crude oil exports (DG

for Internal Policies, 2015)

• Liquid natural gas imports from the US are not likely to increase to a large extent.

Spot prices on the Asia-Pacific markets are much higher than in Europe, so US

exports will probably be directed there.(DG for Internal Policies, 2015)

• Since there will be no significant increase in the EU of US gas and oil exports, it is

not likely to have an adverse effect on competitiveness of EU industries. (DG

for Internal Policies, 2015)

• There will be a positive effect on energy security though (even if the amount

actually traded will not grow significantly, it will be important that there is an

additional source). (DG for Internal Policies, 2015)

• Trade in renewable technologies is likely to increase which will benefit the EU

wind energy manufacturing sector. (DG for Internal Policies, 2015)

Negative

• More stringent regulations in terms of pollution and the use of the precautionary

principle in the use of new chemicals and technologies are labelled as “barriers to

business” under TTIP. (Hartmann 2014)

• Environmental standards will be undermined if “mutual recognition” will be the

way how regulations converge across the Atlantic. (Bizzarri, 2013)

• The “precautionary principle” is weakened to easier adopt technologies in the EU

such as “fracking” in shale gas production. If the liquid natural gas meets high

demand in Europe, hydraulic fracturing will be expanded in the US as well.

(Bizzarri, 2013)

• TTIP will only help reducing CO2 emissions if it involves the phasing out of fossil

fuel subsidies. However, it appears not to be on the table so far. (Adolf et al. 2013)

• Deregulation of crude oil or shale gas exports from the US might drive down

energy prices and would incentivise increased fossil fuel use. (Adolf et al. 2013)

• TTIP is used as a lobby vehicle to attack EU's Fuel Quality Directive, which aims at

reducing the climate impact of transport fuels. The Canadian government (owner of

one of the biggest oil reserves of the world in the form of tar sand) and oil

companies have lobbied extensively against the FQD since its birth in 2009.

(Flues, 2014)

• TTIP threatens to undermine environmental regulations within the EU which are

much stricter than in the US (Hilary, 2014)

• Growing evidence shows huge health and environmental risks associated with

hydraulic fracturing technology of extracting fossil fuels. The dangers of fracking

include increased greenhouse gas emissions, contamination of water, earthquakes.

(Cingotti et al, 2014)

• In the US oil and gas production is exempt of major environmental laws. ISDS can

be a backdoor through which the fracking resistance can be broken. (Cingotti et al,

2014)

Page 30: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

30

2.4. Democracy and transparency

Summary

Proponents of TTIP say that since the European Commission is operating under the mandate of

the European Council and the European Parliament in the trade talks, and because national

assemblies will most likely have to ratify it one by one in the end, the TTIP talks cannot be

labelled undemocratic. Opponents think otherwise, and say that the whole agenda of the trade

talks operates under corporate interests and the optimistic propaganda of the Commission is just

creating a false sensation of transparency.

Positive

• Myth says that “TTIP is being negotiated behind closed doors”. The European

Commission briefs the European Council and the Trade Committee of the European

Parliament regularly. When negotiations are complete, the Council and the

Parliament will have to approve it, and chances are that the individual member

states will also have a separate decision at their hands. The European Commission

has set up the TTIP Advisory Group consisting of NGOs, trade unions and

businesses. (FGI, 2014)

• Confidentiality of the trade talks does not mean that they are undemocratic, as the

negotiating mandate of the European Commission comes from the EU Parliament

and the member states. The United States Congress is also regularly advised on

US positions. (Körnig and Schmicker, 2014)

Negative

• TTIP is developing according to corporate wish lists (IUF, 2014)

• Progress is slowing at WTO, so corporations are pursuing the “fast track” under

the guise of the TTIP and other regional arrangements (IUF, 2014)

• TTIP is a product of twenty years of lobbying on the part of EU and USA

corporations for removal of regulations, starting from the founding of the

TransAtlantic Business Dialogue group of CEOs. (Hilary, 2014)

2.5. Geopolitics, multilateralism vs bilateralism

Summary

This system of arguments revolves around two key points. 1) Was TTIP a logical cure for the

stalled trade multilateralism of WTO? Is it going to give new energy to trade liberalization, or

exactly the opposite, it will divide countries and revert back to the pre-1945 discriminatory

system of world trade? 2) Is the issue of TTIP an attack on emerging powers in a desperate

attempt of the west to regain leadership in the world economy, or is it a healthy initiative which

will have positive spillovers to emerging economies?

Positive

Multilateral free trade agreements are currently dysfunctional. Two key

reasons for promoting bilateral free trade agreements instead are the presence of

globalized supply chains and that they would trigger a positive dynamic of trade

liberalization.(Erixon, 2012)

The main problem of the global trade system is lack of leadership. The EU and the

US could reclaim leadership by signing TTIP.(Erixon, 2012)

The claim that bilateral initiatives poison multilateral trade policy is false.

Multilateral talks have always been urged by one particular actor involved (US

in the Kennedy Round in the GATT tried to reduce trade diversion from the

Page 31: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

31

creation of the Common Market in Europe* the Uruguay Round was driven by the

NAFTA initiative and the single market of Europe) (Erixon, 2012)

The TTIP would create a change in trade preferences for large third country trading

partners as well (like China and Brazil) to move towards liberalization in order

not to risk losing current trade (Erixon, 2012)

TTIP could set an international example for reducing NTB-s. (Erixon, 2012)

If TTIP is a result of an open negotiating process, it can have beneficial effect on

trade multilateralism (Pardo, 2013)

Myth says that “TTIP will damage the multilateral trading system and other

countries”. Such agreements supplement multilateral trade by developing new

rules. Also the agreement pushes 3rd

countries towards liberalization which in

effect help multilateral trade getting a new impetus. (FGI, 2014)

The Transatlantic powers are now in defence within the world economy. TTIP

will give the EU and the US the first mover advantage within the deadlocked World

Trade Organization. (Venhaus, 2014)

TTIP will encourage WTO negotiations, so it is not a substitute for

multilateralism but a complement. (Körnig and Schmucker, 2014)

TTIP is a pragmatic answer for shift from global to regional multilateralism.

This follows from the judgment that some liberalization is better than no

liberalization (with the multilateral trade talks essentially stalemated). (Straubhaar,

2013)

Equal treatment of the states is infeasible, tailor-made approaches are needed in

trade relations (as well). (Straubhaar, 2013)

TTIP was conceived to compete with Asian countries; it is a step towards an

“economic NATO” as Hillary Clinton put it. In this regard, it is clearly a

geopolitical move. TTIP is a key for Europe to rebalance the “pacific pivot” of the

US (its previous turn towards Asian economic partnerships) (Van Ham, 2013)

TTIP is the best chance the world has for reinvigorating the global trade

liberalization process (Van Ham, 2013)

The TTIP talks now have a security edge as well. In the light of the Ukraine crisis

it is important, especially for countries like Poland, to boost transatlantic

cooperation and recast the Western alliance by all means. (Plociennik, 2014)

TTIP is not a defensive strategy (not targeted against third countries); since both

signatory parties have their own other trade agendas as well (e.g. The EU is

negotiating free trade agreements with several Asian countries, Canada, and wants

to improve its trade with Mexico and Latin America as well). The EU also tries to

improve market access of several African countries through Economic Partnership

Agreements. (Erixon 2012b)

Negative

Regional trade agreements are partly a product of the impasse in the WTO, but also

suck “negotiating energy” out of it. (Draper et al. 2014)

TTIP talks could tie up a considerable proportion of EU and US negotiating

capacity. (Mildner and Schmucker, 2013)

TTIP would lead to a relative decline of traditional European integration to the

benefit of transatlantic integration. The European standards and goals are threatened

(e.g. Automotive industry regulations which are labelled “discriminatory” are in

effect promoting energy efficiency). More importantly, trade diversion will lead to

Page 32: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

32

the political weakening of the integration as trade has been its main driving force

(e.g. UK ties with the EU will be further loosened, Germany will dramatically

decrease its trade with its traditional EU partners). (Mathieu and Hager, 2014)

An exclusive TTIP agreement will force China to follow a balancing strategy

and form competitive regional trade blocks. If TTIP is transparent and open,

China may want to reform constructively instead of expelling the current liberal

global order.(Trigkas, 2014)

The TTIP is part of a strategy in order to contain the rise of emerging nations by “a

new trench of global trade, undermining production networks and diverting the flow

of goods”. As a result, the world will become more divided than united.

(Venhaus, 2014)

Preferential trade agreements contain a lot of different and contradictory

rules. TTIP might exacerbate the “spaghetti bowl effect”. (Mildner and Schmucker,

2013)

TTIP and similar large-scale projects endanger the future of a multilateral

trading order. These agreements betray their principles which aimed to overcome

the trade discrimination of the inter-war years. (Dieter, 2013)

The long term political damage could be considerable. Discrimination is creeping

back into trade policy and this could generate growing conflicts in the new

multipolar world order. Geopolitics is undermining a liberal consensus in trade

policy that has lasted since 1945.(Dieter, 2013)

TTIP will have side effects on the long term development of the European

integration, but it is not clear whether it will push toward more or less

federalization on the long run. (Van Ham, 2013)

2.6. Effects on third countries

Summary

Most quantitative studies agree upon that there will be trade diversion from 3rd

countries to

Transatlantic trade, which means that lower income countries will be hurt by the TTIP through

this channel. The debate is more about whether the eventual benefits outweigh the cost. One

argument is that the countries in question will have the incentive to unilaterally adopt US and EU

standards, while others say that at best this will create double standards (they will export higher

quality goods and produce lower quality varieties for local consumption).

Mixed

If there is regulatory convergence under TTIP, large emerging markets (such as

India, China) must adapt somehow. They might not take the higher product

standards since their emerging middle class is very price sensitive. The most likely

is that they will adapt dual standards in exporting and home market production.

(Karnakar, 2013)

Indirect spillovers (third countries adapting TTIP standards unilaterally) will only

work under proper incentives for those countries. The trade partners of TTIP

countries could be categorized into 3 groups: “closest neighbours” (NAFTA

countries for the US, Switzerland, Iceland, Norway and Turkey for the EU),

“biggest traders” (Brazil, China, India, Indonesia, Japan, Korea, South Africa),

“other developed open economies” (Australia, New Zealand, Singapore, Hong

Kong, Israel and Chile). The authors argue that only “closest neighbours” have

enough incentives to adapt TTIP rules unilaterally. There could be, however,

“domino effects”, meaning that third countries sign defensive FTAs in order to

Page 33: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

33

reduce the effect induced by the primary FTA. The authors consider this unlikely.

(Lejour et al. 2014)

Indirect spillovers (3rd

countries unilaterally adopting higher EU-US standards) can

be expected critically in the electrical equipment and the chemical industries. To

lesser extent there are incentives in the mining and quarrying and transport

equipment industries. (Lejour et al. 2014)

Negative

ACP countries could be particularly hurt by the TTIP through “preference

erosion” (many of these countries had preferential trade agreements with future

TTIP countries which might lose their edge in the future to countries with similar

export structure which will be a TTIP members) (Draper et al. 2014)

Trade costs will increase for areas where requirements and standards are made

stricter. However, harmonization efforts could lower the costs of accessing new

markets. These two effects compete with each other in determining whether third

countries will suffer or benefit from TTIP. (Draper et al. 2014)

Developing countries will suffer from an EU-US agreement. (Hartmann, 2014)

Impact assessments on 3rd countries

Effects on trade with Brazil will be significant: ranging from -0.5% in imports and

exports (if only tariffs are reduced) to -8-10% if NTMs are also reduced. (similar

CGE/GTAP calculations) TTIP is clearly shown in the study as a threat.

(Thorstensen and Ferraz, 2014)

14 countries are exporting to the EU and the US mostly products which are

dependent on sanitary and phitosanitary (SPS) regulations. If the EU-US agreement

results in greater regulatory cooperation, the exports of these countries would

suffer. The countries in question mostly are low income countries of Africa (such

as Nigeria, Ghana, Kenya, Malawi etc.) (Rollo et al. 2014)

A study on the effects of TTIP on the BRICS economies shows that real GDP-s are

going to range from a modest decrease (-0.12% for China) and a negligible increase

(+0.1% for Brazil). Except for Brazil, aggregate exports and imports of the BRICS

economies will decrease between 0.05 and 0.17%. These changes are made up by

a bigger decrease in their EU/US trade and a substitutionary increase in their

trade among themselves. (Cai et al. 2014)

2.7. Agriculture and food security

Summary

Core points in this topic are: 1) Fate of remaining mega-tariffs: US puts high tariffs on tobacco,

EU on dairy products. Will these be lifted? 2) Use of pesticides – will the EU water up its strict

chemical substance regulation policies (REACH)? Will it abandon the “precautionary principle”

3) Chlorination of poultry, hormone-treated beef and pork: EU does not allow these practices,

the US does. 4) Ban on GMO production in Europe, ban on sales of processed foods that use

GMOs: one of the core issues for European consumer. 5) Protection of geographical identifiers:

US does not accept as of now the EU policy that the use of some geographical descriptions is

restricted to producers of some area (e.g. Feta and parmesan cheese).

Supporters of TTIP argue that there is a chance to expand markets for EU companies while

maintaining the higher standards of food security.

Page 34: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

34

Positive

Exports to the US have been grown dynamically for the last 20 years. TTIP

may bring about market gains for the EU in the dairy product sector and the meat

and meat preparation industries. Restrictions do to risks related to “mad cow”

disease could be lifted in the future. Wine and spirits are the main driving force of

the exports to the US. Duties and taxes on EU products are now seen as

discriminatory. Stronger protection of geographical indications in the US could lead

to an increase in exports. (DG for Internal Policies, 2014)

Myth says that “TTIP will undermine European health and food safety standards”.

Especially through GMOs and hormone-treated meat. The TTIP does not affect

the mandate of the European Food Safety Authority and its regulatory

processes so the treatment of GMOs will not be any less strict. Ban on hormone-

fattened meat is non-negotiable. Though in a 1997 decision the WTO ruled that the

EU import ban is not legitimate, the EU decided to carry on with it anyway. (FGI,

2014)

The example of the free trade agreement with Canada showed that existing

hygienic and health standards can be preserved (hormone-treated beef still

cannot be imported from Canada).(Körnig and Schmucker, 2014)

The EC has stressed that basic laws, such as those relating to GMOs are not part of

the negotiations. EU has never changed its GMO approval system even on the urge

of WTO. (Schmucker, 2014)

Mixed

The US GM producers have given up on exporting GM seeds to the EU any time in

the near future, so the debate is essentially about the introduction of food

products that have GM raw materials in them, and about their labelling. (Josling

and Tangermann, 2014)

Implementation of tariff cuts can be facilitated two ways: 1) exclude some sensitive

products 2) define a lengthy transition period. (Josling and Tangermann, 2014)

Another issue is that of subsidies. If the EU and the US are able to agree to reduce

domestic subsidies among themselves, they could “set an example that the rest of

the WTO membership would find difficult not to follow” (Josling and

Tangermann, 2014)

While the US is the most important single country in EU agricultural exports,

the reverse is not true. The importance of the EU as an agricultural trade partner

has been declining steadily for the US. The most important EU exports are

alcoholic beverages (spirits, wine and beer). The highest value items in US exports

to the EU are edible nuts and fruits. Also, there is no significant intra-industry trade

in the agricultural sector. (Josling and Tangermann, 2014)

“In terms of agriculture I don't think it is very win-win. The US ill benefit

more than the EU in the sector.” (Bureau, 2014)

“If some mutual recognition can be reached [in the chemical products regulation], it

will mean that some products could be accredited in the US to export chemical

substances more easily to the EU, even though they don't comply with the ore

demanding EU regulations” (Bureau, 2014)

The average tariff level for the EU is 6.4%, and 3.9% for the US. Trade-weighted

tariff averages are also small. Nevertheless, tariffs are of political concern in the

TTIP regulations, since some sub-sectors are protected by “mega-tariffs” (such

as 600% tariff for the dairy sector in the EU, or a 350% tariff for tobacco in the US)

Page 35: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

35

(Josling and Tangermann, 2014)

The impetus for dealing with NTMs in the agricultural sector comes from the

US. The most important regulatory issues the US agricultural sector wants to see

resolved are 1) growth additives in livestock 2) methods of pathogen reduction in

slaughterhouses 3) approval of genetically modified varieties of corn and soybeans.

The EU producers want milk quotas to be abolished, and protection for

geographical indication for cheese, specialty meats and wine. (Josling and

Tangermann, 2014)

Regulatory divergence could be overcome through the strategies of either

harmonisation (probably only for the least sensitive sectors), or mutual recognition

(either on regulations themselves or conformity tests) or equivalence (by stating

that the aims of different regulations were the same; the effectiveness of the

standards are comparable and trusting the other country that it would carry out its

inspection and verification with at least equal diligence). (Josling and Tangermann,

2014)

Food security will only be harmonised where there is equivalence (Mildner, 2013)

Negative

Beef production in the US is more competitive. The US could supply the EU with

even hormone-free beef as well. Liberalization impact on this sector would be

substantial. EU corn production is less cost-competitive. Regulations impose

different costs on EU and US producers since EU producers are not allowed to use

growth hormone or pathogen reduction treatments or GMOs to lower production

costs. The US also wants to see EU farm subsidies lowered. (DG for Internal

Policies, 2014)

TTIP would open the doors for agricultural exports at dumping prices, hurting

ecologically friendly family businesses on both sides of the Atlantic. (Hartmann,

2014)

Concerns about TTIP's effects on the food supply include (Hansehn-Kuhn,

2013)

1) Food safety: restrictions on GMOs, product labelling, hormone-treated

beef, and chlorinated rinses of poultry are the main points in question. If

the deregulatory approach prevails, it could be carried over to new

technologies, such as nanotechnology in agriculture.

2) In the US the Environmental Protection Agency has to prove that a

chemical is unsafe in order to ban its use in the food industry, on the other

hand, under EU regulations (REACH) the safety of a new chemical is

what needs to be proved. The Trade Representative of the US has been

lobbying against this EU regulation since it was conceived.

3) Procurement policy reform may also mean that local institutions (such as

schools) will not be able to give preference to local producers in procuring

food.

4) If financial transparency rules are included as a TTIP chapter, it will make

financial rules subject to the ISDR mechanism.

EU Geographical Indicators are at risk through the TTIP negotiations. This is

especially important since wine and spirits are one of the biggest items in the EU

export basket. (DG For international Policies, 2015)

A report claims that the pesticide industry actively lobbied for weakening EU

laws on using carcinogens as pesticides, importing pesticide-treated US food,

efforts to regulate hormone disrupting chemicals. These companies seemed to

Page 36: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

36

obstruct efforts to save bee populations, blocked access to information vital to

developing non-toxic alternatives and to install a regulatory ceiling hampering

global pesticide regulation. Maximum residue levels are in many cases 10 times

bigger in the US than in the EU. The report also lists 82 pesticides not allowed in

the EU but allowed in the US. (Smith et al. 2015)

Reforming European agriculture on more sustainable lines will be jeopardized by

cheap US produces. This would lead to a decrease in EU agricultural

employment and incentivize further concentration of EU agriculture along the US

agricultural business model. (Bizzarri, 2013)

2.8. Investment protection

Summary

One of the biggest controversies around the TTIP talks is the planned introduction of an ISDS, or

an Investor-state Dispute Settlement mechanism under which private companies would be able

to seek compensation before an arbitral tribunal for government policies that are perceived as

harming their profits.

The supporters of ISDS say that protecting investors' rights increases investment and investment

into R&D in particular. They also say that some form of ISDS is already in effect in most

countries in question, so it is better to put everything under the same regulatory framework.

Also, ISDS would also help protecting European interests in the US, not just vice versa.

The main arguments of the opponents are that 1) ISDS was designed for dealing with countries

without properly working legal systems, which is not the case now 2) ISDS undermines

democratically elected authorities by being able to sue them over their policies at international

arbitration courts 3) since only foreign firms are able to use the devices given by ISDS, it has a

discriminatory effect against local competitors.

Positive

Excluding ISDS from TTIP might have a negative impact on European

businesses, as they will not be able to protect their investments in the US, while

they competitors there can, since ISDS is already included in NAFTA and perhaps

will be included in TTP. Also, US companies can still use ISDS by setting up

subsidiaries in European countries and use intra-EU ISDS mechanisms. (Pardo

2014)

Myth says that investment protection clauses are not needed and they help US

investors overturn EU legislation. Investment protection agreements are one of the

reasons FDI may exist at all. Existing agreements could be improved through TTIP.

The ideas within ISDS are the same as the US and EU have been promoting in

negotiations with 3rd

parties, so not including it in TTIP would undermine its

legitimacy. Also, ISDS would help EU investors within the US. (FGI, 2014)

The ISDS was initially conceived to protect firms that invest in economies with

fragile legal systems. The EC seeks to implement it in a way that it does not

include compensations for revenue lost due to consumer, environment and health

standards. (Körnig and Schmucker, 2014)

ISDS would help protect the investments of EU companies in the US, and allows

investors to settle disputes on “neutral grounds”. (BusinessEurope, 2014)

The EU has ratified only one treaty containing an ISDS mechanism, the 1994

Energy Charter Treaty which has 53 members. The FTAs with Canada and

Singapore have an ISDS mechanism, but these have not yet been ratified (Fabry and

Garbasso, 2015)

Page 37: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

37

The CETA, TTIP and TTP agreements could help encourage a more coherent

regional approach to investment agreements. Now there is not a common model

for this, bilateral agreements all use their own version of investment protection. An

agreement between the EU and the US could lead to a generalization of standards

around the world. (Fabry and Garbasso, 2015)

International arbitration is neutral, so it is preferable to national courts for

investors. (Fabry and Garbasso, 2015)

International arbitration is generally faster than normal court cases. (Fabry and

Garbasso, 2015)

Agreements with ISDS show a commitment to guaranteeing a predictable

investment environment. (Fabry and Garbasso, 2015)

ISDS is about extending the rule of law. The states would retain their power to

expropriate, but the investors could seek compensation more effectively. ISDS

lowers expected costs for companies thus they will have more resources to serve

consumers. (Zulaga 2014)

Negative

ISDS is prone to procedural flaws, loopholes and controversies. (Pardo 2014)

Investor-state arbitration procedures proposed under ISDS undermine

environmental and social laws of the EU, and fundamental principles of rule of

law. (Hartmann, 2014)

Under the pretext of protecting investors, publishing houses and media companies

increasingly try to control users of culture and information. (Hartmann, 2014)

Investment tribunals never directly invalidate environmental regulations, but

they may decide on the payment of substantial compensatory payments.

(Gerstetter and Meyer-Ohlendorf, 2013)

Since the rule of law is respected in both EU and US legal systems, there is no

reason to include ISDS in the TTIP. Without any such previous regulation the EU

and the US managed to become each other’s most important partners in FDI.

(Gerstetter and Meyer-Ohlendorf, 2013)

The kind of legal support which TTIP gives foreign investors is not available for

domestic competitors, so it is in effect disrupting free competition. (Gerstetter and

Meyer-Ohlendorf, 2013)

Experience with ISDS claims since NAFTA came into effect shows what effect

TTIP would have on dispute settlement in Europe – huge compensations paid

from public money to private interests. (IUF, 2014)

There is no empirical evidence that lack of ISDS limits foreign investment.

There is no ISDS in any agreements Brasil has or between the US and China. (IUF,

2014)

If ISDS is included in the TTIP, foreign investors will be able to sue host countries

for loss of profits caused by reversing earlier privatisation. (Hilary, 2014)

Under ISDS, corporations will be able to claim compensation for any future

improvements in the terms and conditions of employment (Hilary, 2014)

93% of bilateral investment treaties contain an ISDS. But most of the time they are

agreements between developed and developing countries (Fabry and Garbasso,

2015)

The lack of ISDS will not certainly mean that FDI is diverted towards 3rd

Page 38: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

38

countries, since the EU and the US are already very important partners in terms of

FDI, while there is no comprehensive ISDS mechanism in their relations (Fabry and

Garbasso, 2015)

Even the prospect of paying compensations may lead some governments to

withdraw or modify laws. This is called the “regulatory chill”. (Fabry and

Garbasso, 2015)

In developed legal systems, such as the EU and the US, the investors have many

other devices to cover regulatory risks, such as private insurance policies. (Fabry

and Garbasso, 2015)

If ISDS is part of TTIP, reverse discrimination may occur: US companies gain the

right to begin international arbitration, while European investors must stick with

national courts. (Fabry and Garbasso, 2015)

Delegating authority to transnational tribunals has a political cost. It is a huge

political issue to determine what restrictions on sovereignty are acceptable. (Fabry

and Garbasso, 2015)

ISDS has a hybrid public/private nature, and states have a transparency obligation

towards their citizens, so arbitration procedures taking place behind closed

doors are not preferable. (Fabry and Garbasso, 2015)

Law firms specializing in international arbitration have an influence over the

selection of panel members, and may be able to choose those people who are not

impartial. (Fabry and Garbasso, 2015)

The cost of proceedings is generally very high, on the order of magnitude of

millions of dollars. Logical consequence would be that it is only affordable for big

corporations. On the other hand, one quarter who lay complaints currently are

individuals or small companies, medium and large multinationals only amount of

half of the investors. (Fabry and Garbasso, 2015)

In the EU, the compensation payouts ranged from USD$0.46 million to USD$800

million, while in the US they ranged between USD$0.5 million and USD$1800

million (Fabry and Garbasso, 2015)

The formulation of ISDS provisions is often misleading for the public. E.g.

Protection from “indirect expropriation” means protection from lowering future

profits, and legitimate environmental and public policies can easily interpreted this

way. Guaranteeing the “free transfer of funds of capital and payments by investors”

means that the investor can always withdraw all money, increasing

macroeconomic risks of sudden huge in- and outflows of capital for countries.

Private lawyers will decide which policies are necessary to pursue public policy

objectives – they are often not independent. (Seattle to Brussels Network, 2013)

Page 39: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

39

3. Country by country assessment

3.1. TTIP’s possible effects on Austria

Country factsheet

• GDP/capita: 49039 $ (2014) (http://countryeconomy.com/)

• GDP: 428322 Mill. $ (2014)

• 10th

biggest economy in 2013 in Europe, 28th

biggest economy in the world (UN)

• Unemployment in 2014: 4.9% (EuroStat)

TTIP general impact according to the core quantitative studies

• Long-term effects on welfare depending on scenario taken: +0.22 to 4.73% (CESifo)

• Less skilled labour: change in employment: +0.528% ; More skilled labour: change in

employment: +0.511% and change in wages +1.059% (less skilled labour), +1.025%

(more skilled labour) (FIW-Research Reports)

• Changes in Austrian exports: to USA +43.7%, to EU -0.6%. Changes in Austrian

imports: from USA +85.3%, from EU +1.1% (FIW-Research Reports)

Trade with the US (US Census Bureau)

Trade with the US in 2014:

• Import: 3.7 billion $, 0.87% of GDP

• Export: 10.2 billion $, 2.37% of GDP

• Total: 3.24% of GDP

5 product categories exported at biggest value to US (2014 value, thousand $)

• Transportation Equipment (1,727,585)

• Chemicals (1,612,363)

• Machinery, Except Electrical (1,652,792)

• Computer & Electronic Products (1,158,633)

• Fabricated Metal Products, Nesoi (806,257)

5 product categories imported at biggest value from US (2014 value thousand $)

• Chemicals (1,784,517)

• Transportation Equipment (476863)

• Computer & Electronic Products (290,970)

• Machinery, Except Electrical (262,857)

• Special Classification Provisions, Nesoi (181,071)

Other impact assessments

• A distinct impact study was carried out for Austria by FIW – Research Centre

International Economics (Francois – Pindyuk, 2012 [Note: Joseph Francois was also

one of the authors of the Ecorys study, and the authors here implement a similar

methodology]). The study predicts a 1.7% increase in national income ($ 5568

million), 0.5% increase in wages and 1% increase in employment for both skilled and

unskilled labour. Notably there is no reference to the time horizon of these changes,

but the modelling framework suggests that this should be understood as

macroeconomic “long run” (perhaps about 15 years, as in the quantitative studies).

Page 40: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

40

• The study suggests that the industries of Motor vehicles, Textiles and that of

Construction will benefit the most. While Other transport equipment, Other goods

industries will shrink in terms of output. Employment in the former industries will

grow between 9 (Motor vehicles) and 1.5 percent (Textiles), while the Transport and

Other transport equipment industries and Other goods will shrink between 1% and

2%.

• The study predicts minuscule trade diversion in terms of the EU partners of Austria:

only the Other transport equipment category's EU exports will shrink over 10 percent,

while Textiles and Other transport equipment exports to the US roughly doubles by

the prediction. Processed foods, Chemicals, Metals, Electrical machinery, Motor

vehicles and Other machinery are predicted to have an US export increase between

1/3 and 1/2.

3.2. TTIP’s possible effects on Belgium

Country factsheet

• GDP/capita: 45538$ (2014) (http://countryeconomy.com/)

• GDP: 524806 Mill. $ (2014)

• 9th

biggest economy in 2013 in Europe, 24th

biggest economy in the world (UN)

• Unemployment in 2014: 8.4% (EuroStat)

TTIP general impact according to studies

• Long-term effects on welfare depending on scenario taken: +0.09 to 4.12% (CESifo)

• Though does not give a country specific estimate, for the region (“Other Northern and

Western Europe”) it predicts a 2.07% decrease in net exports, 0.50% decrease in

GDP, -4848 Euros of per capita income per employee, and a 1.33% increase in

dependency ratio. (Capaldo)

Trade with the US (US Census Bureau)

Trade with the US in 2014:

• Import: 34.8 billion $, 6.63% of GDP

• Export: 21.0 billion $, 4.01% of GDP

• Total: 10.64% of GDP

5 product categories exported at biggest value to US (2014 value, thousand $)

• Chemicals (5,998,768)

• Miscellaneous Manufactured Commodities (4,243,422)

• Petroleum & Coal Products (3,301,829)

• Transportation Equipment (1,351,525)

• Machinery, Except Electrical (976,020)

5 product categories imported at biggest value from US (2014 value, thousand $)

• Chemicals (14,499,346)

• Miscellaneous Manufactured Commodities (7,268,481)

• Machinery, Except Electrical (2,827,188)

• Computer & Electronic Products (2,159,320)

• Transportation Equipment (1,677,063)

Page 41: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

41

3.3. TTIP’s possible effects on Bulgaria

Country factsheet

• GDP/capita: 7499$ (2014) (http://countryeconomy.com/)

• GDP: 54480 Mill. $ (2014)

• 22th

biggest economy in 2013 in Europe, 78th

biggest economy in the world (UN)

• Unemployment in 2014: 10.8% (EuroStat)

TTIP general impact according to studies

• The Ifo study predicts 3.9% growth of per capita income for Bulgaria under the

“preferred” scenario (which was coined “unrealistic” by the European Commission)

(Bertelsmann/ifo)

• Though does not give a country specific estimate, for the region (“Other Southern

Europe”) it predicts a 0.7% decrease in net exports, 0.21% decrease in GDP, -165

Euros of per capita income per employee, and a 0.33% increase in dependency ratio.

(Capaldo)

• Long-term effects on welfare depending on scenario taken: +0.33 to 5.90% (CESifo)

Trade with the US (US Census Bureau)

Trade with the US in 2014:

• Import: 359 million $, 0.66% of GDP

• Export: 622 million $, 1.14% of GDP

• Total: 1.80% of GDP

5 product categories exported at biggest value to US (2014 value, thousand $)

• Chemicals (88,791)

• Apparel & Accessories (85,340)

• Computer & Electronic Products (77,982)

• Machinery, Except Electrical (69,602)

• Agricultural Products (50,399)

5 product categories imported at biggest value from US (2014 value, thousand $)

• Machinery, Except Electrical (90,552)

• Computer & Electronic Products (69,888)

• Agricultural Products (28,145)

• Petroleum & Coal Products (26,310)

• Chemicals (25,980)

3.4. TTIP’s possible effects on Croatia

Country factsheet

• GDP/capita: 13518$ (2014) (http://countryeconomy.com/)

• GDP: 57869 Mill. $ (2014)

• 21th

biggest economy in 2013 in Europe, 74th

biggest economy in the world (UN)

• Unemployment in 2014: 16.4% (EuroStat)

TTIP general impact according to studies

Page 42: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

42

• The Ifo study predicts a per capita GDP growth of 5.3% under “preferred” scenario,

which was called unrealistic by the European Commission. More conservative

estimates are between 0.34 and 0.5%.

• Though does not give a country specific estimate, for the region (“Other Southern

Europe”) it predicts a 0.7% decrease in net exports, 0.21% decrease in GDP, -165

Euros of per capita income per employee, and a 0.33% increase in dependency ratio.

(Capaldo)

• Long-term effects on welfare depending on scenario taken: +0.38 to 5.49% (CESifo)

Trade with the US (US Census Bureau)

Trade with the US in 2014:

• Import: 344 million $, 0.59% of GDP

• Export: 478 million $, 0.83% of GDP

• Total: 1.42% of GDP

5 product categories exported at biggest value to US (2014 value, thousand $)

• Chemicals (205,889)

• Fabricated Metal Products, Nesoi (98,945)

• Machinery, Except Electrical (55,163)

• Computer & Electronic Products (19,877)

• Food & Kindred Products (16,005)

5 product categories imported at biggest value from US (2014 value, thousand $)

• Minerals & Ores (189,306)

• Machinery, Except Electrical (27,256)

• Chemicals (24,726)

• Computer & Electronic Products (23,834)

• Transportation Equipment (11,187)

3.5. TTIP’s possible effects on Cyprus

Country factsheet

• GDP/capita: 19201$ (2014) (http://countryeconomy.com/)

• GDP: 21911 Mill. $ (2014)

• 27th

biggest economy in 2013 in Europe, 107th

biggest economy in the world (UN)

• Unemployment in 2014: 16.4% (EuroStat)

TTIP general impact according to studies

• Though does not give a country specific estimate, for the region (“Other Southern

Europe”) it predicts a 0.7% decrease in net exports, 0.21% decrease in GDP, -165

Euros of per capita income per employee, and a 0.33% increase in dependency ratio.

(Capaldo)

• Long-term effects on welfare depending on scenario taken: +0.37 to 6.33% (CESifo)

Trade with the US (US Census Bureau)

Trade with the US in 2014:

• Import: 154 million $, 0.70% of GDP

• Export: 66 million $, 0.30% of GDP

Page 43: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

43

• Total: 1.00% of GDP

5 product categories exported at biggest value to US (2014 value, thousand $)

• Computer & Electronic Products (29,208)

• Goods Returned (exports For Canada Only) (12,651)

• Food & Kindred Products (6,541)

• Machinery, Except Electrical (2,682)

• Chemicals (2,563)

5 product categories imported at biggest value from US (2014 value, thousand $)

• Transportation Equipment (33,938)

• Machinery, Except Electrical (27,826)

• Computer & Electronic Products (24,163)

• Fabricated Metal Products, Nesoi (14,764)

• Special Classification Provisions, Nesoi (8,199)

• Paper (6,060)

3.6. TTIP’s possible effects on the Czech Republic

Country factsheet

• GDP/capita: 18871$ (2014) (http://countryeconomy.com/)

• GDP: 208796 Mill. $ (2014)

• 16th

biggest economy in 2013 in Europe, 48th

biggest economy in the world (UN)

• Unemployment in 2014: 5.8% (EuroStat)

TTIP general impact according to studies

• Though does not give a country specific estimate, for the region (“Other Southern and

Eastern Europe”) it predicts a 0.7% decrease in net exports, 0.21% decrease in GDP, -

165 Euros of per capita income per employee, and a 0.33% increase in dependency

ratio. (Capaldo)

• Long-term effects on welfare depending on scenario taken: +0.24 to 4.96% (CESifo)

Trade with the US (US Census Bureau)

Trade with the US in 2014:

• Import: 2.3 billion $, 1.10% of GDP

• Export: 4.2 billion $, 2.02% of GDP

• Total: 3.13% of GDP

5 product categories exported at biggest value to US (2014 value, thousand $)

• Transportation Equipment (766,531)

• Machinery, Except Electrical (619,341)

• Computer & Electronic Products (483,044)

• Electrical Equipment, Appliances & Components (407,270)

• Chemicals (397,342)

5 product categories imported at biggest value from US (2014 value, thousand $)

• Computer & Electronic Products (808,253)

• Machinery, Except Electrical (326,747)

Page 44: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

44

• Transportation Equipment (306,442)

• Chemicals (129,651)

• Electrical Equipment, Appliances & Components (123,283)

3.7. TTIP’s possible effects on Denmark

Country factsheet

• GDP/capita: 59129$ (2014) (http://countryeconomy.com/)

• GDP: 335878 Mill. $ (2014)

• 11th

biggest economy in 2013 in Europe, 34th

biggest economy in the world (UN)

• Unemployment in 2014: 6.4% (EuroStat)

TTIP general impact according to studies

• Though does not give a country specific estimate, for the region (“Other Northern and

Western Europe”) it predicts a 2.07% decrease in net exports, 0.50% decrease in

GDP, -4848 Euros of per capita income per employee, and a 1.33% increase in

dependency ratio. (Capaldo)

• Long-term effects on welfare depending on scenario taken: +0.28 to 5.38% (CESifo)

Trade with the US (US Census Bureau)

Trade with the US in 2014:

• Import: 2.3 billion $, 0.70% of GDP

• Export: 7.8 billion $, 2.33% of GDP

• Total: 3.02% of GDP

5 product categories exported at biggest value to US (2014 value, thousand $)

• Chemicals (3,682,276)

• Machinery, Except Electrical (945,138)

• Computer & Electronic Products (905,273)

• Food & Kindred Products (483,075)

• Miscellaneous Manufactured Commodities (314,504)

5 product categories imported at biggest value from US (2014 value, thousand $)

• Computer & Electronic Products (446,965)

• Chemicals (306,288)

• Transportation Equipment (303,913)

• Machinery, Except Electrical (274,674)

• Electrical Equipment, Appliances & Components (143,725)

3.8. TTIP’s possible effects on Estonia

Country factsheet

• GDP/capita: 18852$ (2014) (http://countryeconomy.com/)

• GDP: 24880 Mill. $ (2014)

• 26th

biggest economy in 2013 in Europe, 106th

biggest economy in the world (UN)

• Unemployment in 2014: 6.6% (EuroStat)

Page 45: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

45

TTIP general impact according to studies

• Long-term effects on welfare depending on scenario taken: +0.36 to 6.29% (CESifo)

Trade with the US (US Census Bureau)

Trade with the US in 2014:

• Import: 308 million $, 1.24% of GDP

• Export: 572 million $, 2.30% of GDP

• Total: 3.54% of GDP

5 product categories exported at biggest value to US (2014 value, thousand $)

• Computer & Electronic Products (358,240)

• Electrical Equipment, Appliances & Components (37,442)

• Miscellaneous Manufactured Commodities (32,311)

• Chemicals (31,819)

• Machinery, Except Electrical (17,330)

5 product categories imported at biggest value from US (2014 value, thousand $)

• Computer & Electronic Products (67,820)

• Machinery, Except Electrical (52,211)

• Transportation Equipment (38,879)

• Chemicals (33,517)

• Miscellaneous Manufactured Commodities (22,689)

3.9. TTIP’s possible effects on Finland

Country factsheet

• GDP/capita: 49147$ (2014) (http://countryeconomy.com/)

• GDP: 267329 Mill. $ (2014)

• 12th

biggest economy in 2013 in Europe, 41st biggest economy in the world (UN)

• Unemployment in 2014: 8.9% (EuroStat)

TTIP general impact according to studies

• Though does not give a country specific estimate for the region (“Other Northern and

Western Europe”) it predicts a 2.07% decrease in net exports, 0.50% decrease in

GDP, -4848 Euros of per capita income per employee, and a 1.33% increase in

dependency ratio. (Capaldo)

• Long-term effects on welfare depending on scenario taken: +0.39 to 6.58% (CESifo)

Trade with the US (US Census Bureau)

Trade with the US in 2014:

• Import: 2.2 billion $, 0.81% of GDP

• Export: 5.0 billion $, 1.88% of GDP

• Total: 2.69% of GDP

5 product categories exported at biggest value to US (2014 value, thousand $)

• Chemicals (918,846)

• Paper (862,507)

• Machinery, Except Electrical (691,587)

Page 46: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

46

• Petroleum & Coal Products (672,379)

• Computer & Electronic Products (528,105)

5 product categories imported at biggest value from US (2014 value, thousand $)

• Computer & Electronic Products (426,759)

• Transportation Equipment (363,625)

• Machinery, Except Electrical (234,038)

• Minerals & Ores (203,133)

• Chemicals (202,370)

3.10. TTIP’s possible effects on France

Country factsheet

• GDP/capita: 44099$ (2014) (http://countryeconomy.com/)

• GDP: 2806428 Mill. $ (2014)

• 2nd

biggest economy in 2013 in Europe, 5th

biggest economy in the world (UN)

• Unemployment in 2014: 10.3% (EuroStat)

TTIP general impact according to studies

• +0.2% GDP by 2025, changes in exports between +0.5% and +3.8%, changes in real

incomes between 0% and 0.4% depending on the scenario taken (CEPII)

• +0.12% employment, -0.11% change in the unemployment rate in percentage points

and +0.54% in real wages if only tariffs are reduced; +0.47% employment gains, -

0.43% change in the unemployment rate and +2.22% change in real wages under

“deep liberalization” (Bertelsmann/ifo)

• -1.9 net exports (% of GDP), -0.48 percentage points of GDP growth, 130000 jobs

destroyed, -5518 EUR income per employee, -0.64 tax revenue (as % of GDP),

dependency ratio up by 1.31 percentage points (total population / employed

population) (Capaldo)

• Long-term effects on welfare depending on scenario taken: +0.28 to 5.32% (CESifo)

Trade with the US (US Census Bureau)

Trade with the US in 2014:

• Import: 31 billion $, 1.11% of GDP

• Export: 47 billion $, 1.68% of GDP

• Total: 2.79% of GDP

5 product categories exported at biggest value to US (2014 value, thousand $)

• Chemicals (7,407,590)

• Beverages & Tobacco Products (3,511,324)

• Machinery, Except Electrical (3,441,139)

• Computer & Electronic Products (2,672,693)

• Used Or Second-hand Merchandise (2,516,403)

5 product categories imported at biggest value from US (2014 value, thousand $)

• Chemicals (4,565,781)

• Petroleum & Coal Products (4,065,732)

• Computer & Electronic Products (2,969,549)

• Machinery, Except Electrical (2,098,082)

Page 47: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

47

• Miscellaneous Manufactured Commodities (1,716,410)

3.11. TTIP’s possible effects on Germany

Country factsheet

• GDP/capita: 46269 $ (2014) (http://countryeconomy.com/)

• GDP: 3856928 Mill. $ (2014)

• 1st biggest economy in 2013 in Europe, 4

th biggest economy in the world (UN)

• Unemployment in 2014: 4.9% (EuroStat)

TTIP general impact according to studies

• +0.4% GDP by 2025, changes in exports between +0.3% and +3%, changes in real

incomes between 0% and 0.5% depending on the scenario taken (CEPII)

• +0.12% employment, -0.11% change in the unemployment rate in percentage points

and +0.54% in real wages if only tariffs are reduced; +0.47% employment gains, -

0.43% change in the unemployment rate and +2.19% change in real wages under

“deep liberalization” (Bertelsmann/ifo)

• -1.14 net exports (% of GDP), -0.29 percentage points of GDP growth, 134000 jobs

destroyed, -3402 EUR income per employee, -0.28 tax revenue (as % of GDP),

dependency ratio up by 0.75 percentage points (total population / employed

population) (Capaldo)

• Long-term effects on welfare depending on scenario taken: +0.28 to 5.28% (CESifo)

Trade with the US (US Census Bureau)

Trade with the US in 2014:

• Import: 49 billion, 1.28% of GDP

• Export: 124 billion, 3.21% of GDP

• Total: 4.49% of GDP

5 product categories exported at biggest value to US (2014 value, thousand $)

• Transportation Equipment (40,266,203)

• Chemicals (23,156,397)

• Machinery, Except Electrical (19,491,277)

• Computer & Electronic Products (9,723,730)

• Fabricated Metal Products, Nesoi (4,647,713)

5 product categories imported at biggest value from US (2014 value, thousand $)

• Transportation Equipment (13,317,123)

• Computer & Electronic Products (7,114,488)

• Chemicals (6,960,533)

• Machinery, Except Electrical (4,607,334)

• Miscellaneous Manufactured Commodities (3,258,491)

Other impact assessments

• The Bertelsmann policy paper (based on the ifo study) predicts that a comprehensive

liberalization can cause huge trade diversion (e.g. US-Germany trade doubles,

Germany – UK trade down by half, and down by a quarter in the case of Italy and

France. These numbers are probably unrealistically high. Also, the study predicts that

TTIP will enhance Germany's trade with Japan and shrink its trade with China. Sharp

Page 48: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

48

decline in trade is anticipated with the PIIGS economies (trade down by one third)

and also with all BRICS countries. (Bertelsmann 2013)

3.12. TTIP’s possible effects on Greece

Country factsheet

• GDP/capita: 21956$ (2014) (http://countryeconomy.com/)

• GDP: 242230 Mill. $ (2014)

• 13th

biggest economy in 2013 in Europe, 43rd

biggest economy in the world (UN)

• Unemployment in 2014: 25.8% (EuroStat)

TTIP general impact according to studies

• Though does not give a country specific estimate, for the region (“Other Southern and

Eastern Europe”) it predicts a 0.7% decrease in net exports, 0.21% decrease in GDP, -

165 Euros of per capita income per employee, and a 0.33% increase in dependency

ratio. (Capaldo)

• Long-term effects on welfare depending on scenario taken: +0.35 to 6.17% (CESifo)

Trade with the US (US Census Bureau)

Trade with the US in 2014:

• Export: 1.1 billion $, 0.46% of GDP

• Import: 0.8 billion $, 0.32% of GDP

• Total: 0.78% of GDP

5 product categories exported at biggest value to US (2014 value, thousand $)

• Food & Kindred Products (260,475)

• Primary Metal Mfg (144,606)

• Fabricated Metal Products, Nesoi (120,903)

• Transportation Equipment (79,742)

• Nonmetallic Mineral Products (78,708)

5 product categories imported at biggest value from US (2014 value, thousand $)

• Computer & Electronic Products (132,632)

• Transportation Equipment (120,165)

• Chemicals (71,273)

• Petroleum & Coal Products (57,981)

• Machinery, Except Electrical (57,536)

3.13. TTIP’s possible effects on Hungary

Country factsheet

• GDP/capita: 13481$ (2014) (http://countryeconomy.com/)

• GDP: 133424 Mill. $ (2014)

• 18th

biggest economy in 2013 in Europe, 59th

biggest economy in the world (UN)

• Unemployment in 2014: 7.3% (EuroStat)

Page 49: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

49

TTIP general impact according to studies

• Though does not give a country specific estimate, for the region (“Other Southern and

Eastern Europe”) it predicts a 0.7% decrease in net exports, 0.21% decrease in GDP, -

165 Euros of per capita income per employee, and a 0.33% increase in dependency

ratio. (Capaldo)

• Long-term effects on welfare depending on scenario taken: +0.28 – 5.44% (CESifo)

Trade with the US

Trade with the US in 2014:

• Import: 1.8 billion $, 1.38% of GDP

• Export: 5.2 billion $, 3.90% of GDP

• Total: 5.28% of GDP

5 product categories exported at biggest value to US (2014 value, thousand $)

• Transportation Equipment (2,014,454)

• Computer & Electronic Products (996,874)

• Machinery, Except Electrical (643,668)

• Electrical Equipment, Appliances & Components (503,956)

• Chemicals (202,704)

5 product categories imported at biggest value from US (2014 value, thousand $)

• Machinery, Except Electrical (588,430)

• Computer & Electronic Products (483,515)

• Transportation Equipment (201,476)

• Electrical Equipment, Appliances & Components (125,933)

• Fabricated Metal Products, Nesoi (116,765)

3.14. TTIP’s possible effects on Ireland

Country factsheet

• GDP/capita: 50503$ (2014) (http://countryeconomy.com/)

• GDP: 232077 Mill. $ (2014)

• 14th

biggest economy in 2013 in Europe, 44th

biggest economy in the world (UN)

• Unemployment in 2014: 10.5% (EuroStat)

TTIP general impact according to studies

• Though does not give a country specific estimate, for the region (“Other Northern and

Western Europe”) it predicts a 2.07% decrease in net exports, 0.50% decrease in

GDP, -4848 Euros of per capita income per employee, and a 1.33% increase in

dependency ratio. (Capaldo)

• Long-term effects on welfare depending on scenario taken: +0.39 to 6.70% (CESifo)

Trade with the US (US Census Bureau)

Trade with the US in 2014:

• Import: 8 billion $, 3.35% of GDP

• Export: 33 billion $, 14.32% of GDP

• Total: 17.67% of GDP

Page 50: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

50

5 product categories exported at biggest value to US (2014 value, thousand $)

• Chemicals (23,473,239)

• Miscellaneous Manufactured Commodities (4,322,280)

• Computer & Electronic Products (1,899,423)

• Goods Returned (exports For Canada Only) (1,260,360)

• Beverages & Tobacco Products (615,005)

5 product categories imported at biggest value from US (2014 value, thousand $)

• Chemicals (2,630,732)

• Computer & Electronic Products (1,244,447)

• Transportation Equipment (844,791)

• Machinery, Except Electrical (822,014)

• Miscellaneous Manufactured Commodities (739,143)

3.15. TTIP’s possible effects on Italy

Country factsheet

• GDP/capita: 35926$ (2014) (http://countryeconomy.com/)

• GDP: 2149485 Mill. $ (2014)

• 4th

biggest economy in 2013 in Europe, 8th

biggest economy in the world (UN)

• Unemployment in 2014: 12.9% (EuroStat)

TTIP general impact according to studies

• -0.36 net exports (% of GDP), -0.03 percentage points of GDP growth, 3000 jobs

destroyed, -661 EUR income per employee, -0.00 tax revenue (as % of GDP),

dependency ratio up by 0.02 percentage points (total population / employed

population) (Capaldo)

• Long-term effects on welfare depending on scenario taken: +0.32 to 5.74% (CESifo)

Trade with the US (US Census Bureau)

Trade with the US in 2014:

• Import: 17 billion $, 0.79% of GDP

• Export: 43 billion $, 2.00% of GDP

• Total: 2.79% of GDP

5 product categories exported at biggest value to US (2014 value, thousand $)

• Machinery, Except Electrical (8,310,251)

• Transportation Equipment (5,007,579)

• Chemicals (4,734,102)

• Leather & Allied Products (2,544,059)

• Fabricated Metal Products, Nesoi (2,509,683)

5 product categories imported at biggest value from US (2014 value, thousand $)

• Chemicals (3,342,400)

• Transportation Equipment (2,232,353)

• Computer & Electronic Products (1,739,692)

• Machinery, Except Electrical (1,656,248)

• Primary Metal Mfg (843,485)

Page 51: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

51

3.16. TTIP’s possible effects on Latvia

Country factsheet

• GDP/capita: 15187$ (2014) (http://countryeconomy.com/)

• GDP: 30957 Mill. $ (2014)

• 25th

biggest economy in 2013 in Europe, 98th

biggest economy in the world (UN)

• Unemployment in 2014: 10.7% (EuroStat)

TTIP general impact according to studies

• Long-term effects on welfare depending on scenario taken: +0.34 to 6.09% (CESifo)

Trade with the US (US Census Bureau)

Trade with the US in 2014:

• Import: 428 million $, 1.38% of GDP

• Export: 291 million $, 0.94% of GDP

• Total: 2.32% of GDP

5 product categories exported at biggest value to US (2014 value, thousand $)

• Computer & Electronic Products (26,263)

• Machinery, Except Electrical (20,804)

• Food & Kindred Products (4,179)

• Transportation Equipment (1,055)

• Chemicals (8,470)

5 product categories imported at biggest value from US (2014 value, thousand $)

• Computer & Electronic Products (81,931)

• Machinery, Except Electrical (68,249)

• Food & Kindred Products (51,817)

• Transportation Equipment (40,482)

• Chemicals (32,433)

3.17. TTIP’s possible effects on Lithuania

Country factsheet

• GDP/capita: 15649$ (2014) (http://countryeconomy.com/)

• GDP: 45932 Mill. $ (2014)

• 24th

biggest economy in 2013 in Europe, 87th

biggest economy in the world (UN)

• Unemployment in 2014: 9.4% (EuroStat)

TTIP general impact according to studies

• Long-term effects on welfare depending on scenario taken: +0.33 to 5.94% (CESifo)

Trade with the US (US Census Bureau)

Trade with the US in 2014:

• Import: 732 million $, 1.59% of GDP

• Export: 1.1 billion $, 2.36% of GDP

• Total: 3.95% of GDP

Page 52: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

52

5 product categories exported at biggest value to US (2014 value, thousand $)

• Petroleum & Coal Products (713,112)

• Furniture & Fixtures (127,081)

• Chemicals (65,172)

• Food & Kindred Products (38,115)

• Computer & Electronic Products (26,225)

5 product categories imported at biggest value from US (2014 value, thousand $)

• Used Or Second-hand Merchandise (204,222)

• Machinery, Except Electrical (85,468)

• Petroleum & Coal Products (78,147)

• Computer & Electronic Products (57,843)

• Transportation Equipment (54,486)

3.18. TTIP’s possible effects on Luxembourg

Country factsheet

• GDP/capita: 110697$ (2014) (http://countryeconomy.com/)

• GDP: 60131 Mill. $ (2014)

• 20th

biggest economy in 2013 in Europe, 73rd

biggest economy in the world (UN)

• Unemployment in 2014: 5.9% (EuroStat)

TTIP general impact according to studies

• Though does not give a country specific estimate, for the region (“Other Northern and

Western Europe”) it predicts a 2.07% decrease in net exports, 0.50% decrease in

GDP, -4848 Euros of per capita income per employee, and a 1.33% increase in

dependency ratio. (Capaldo)

• Long-term effects on welfare depending on scenario taken: +0.19 to 4.48% (CESifo)

Trade with the US (US Census Bureau)

Trade with the US in 2014:

• Import: 1.5 billion $, 2.52% of GDP

• Export: 779 million $, 1.29% of GDP

• Total: 3.81% of GDP

5 product categories exported at biggest value to US (2014 value, thousand $)

• Primary Metal Mfg (290,014)

• Fabricated Metal Products, Nesoi (59,393)

• Plastics & Rubber Products (50,820)

• Textiles & Fabrics (31,474)

• Machinery, Except Electrical (27,537)

5 product categories imported at biggest value from US (2014 value, thousand $)

• Transportation Equipment (809,465)

• Used Or Second-hand Merchandise (141,947)

• Chemicals (129,735)

• Machinery, Except Electrical (100,014)

• Computer & Electronic Products (64,870)

Page 53: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

53

3.19. TTIP’s possible effects on Malta

Country factsheet

• GDP/capita: 22780$ (2014) (http://countryeconomy.com/)

• GDP: 9642 Mill. $ (2014)

• 28th

biggest economy in 2013 in Europe, 141st biggest economy in the world (UN)

• Unemployment in 2014: 5.8% (EuroStat)

TTIP general impact according to studies

• Though does not give a country specific estimate, for the region (“Other Southern and

Eastern Europe”) it predicts a 0.7% decrease in net exports, 0.21% decrease in GDP, -

165 Euros of per capita income per employee, and a 0.33% increase in dependency

ratio. (Capaldo)

• Long-term effects on welfare depending on scenario taken: +0.41 to 6.86% (CESifo)

Trade with the US (US Census Bureau)

Trade with the US in 2014:

• Import: 969 million $, 10.05% of GDP

• Export: 183 million $, 1.89% of GDP

• Total: 11.95% of GDP

5 product categories exported at biggest value to US (2014 value, thousand $)

• Computer & Electronic Products (96,251)

• Chemicals (26,398)

• Electrical Equipment, Appliances & Components (19,736)

• Miscellaneous Manufactured Commodities (11,442)

• Goods Returned (exports For Canada Only) (5,482)

• Machinery, Except Electrical (5,060)

5 product categories imported at biggest value from US (2014 value, thousand $)

• Petroleum & Coal Products (828,282)

• Transportation Equipment (46,046)

• Machinery, Except Electrical (28,841)

• Special Classification Provisions, Nesoi (15,280)

• Computer & Electronic Products (10,028)

3.20. TTIP’s possible effects on the Netherlands

Country factsheet

• GDP/capita: 50816$ (2014) (http://countryeconomy.com/)

• GDP: 868143 Mill. $ (2014)

• 6th

biggest economy in 2013 in Europe, 17th

biggest economy in the world (UN)

• Unemployment in 2014: 6.7% (EuroStat)

TTIP general impact according to studies

• Though does not give a country specific estimate, for the region (“Other Northern and

Western Europe”) it predicts a 2.07% decrease in net exports, 0.50% decrease in

Page 54: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

54

GDP, -4848 Euros of per capita income per employee, and a 1.33% increase in

dependency ratio. (Capaldo)

• Long-term effects on welfare depending on scenario taken: +0.22 to 4.73% (CESifo)

Trade with the US (US Census Bureau)

Trade with the US in 2014:

• Import: 44 billion $, 5.03% of GDP

• Export: 21 billion $, 2.45% of GDP

• Total: 7.48% of GDP

5 product categories exported at biggest value to US (2014 value, thousand $)

• Chemicals (4,558,679)

• Machinery, Except Electrical (4,378,208)

• Petroleum & Coal Products (3,308,272)

• Beverages & Tobacco Products (1,122,448)

• Computer & Electronic Products (1,034,643)

5 product categories imported at biggest value from US (2014 value, thousand $)

• Chemicals (9,312,221)

• Petroleum & Coal Products ( 8,167,277)

• Computer & Electronic Products (6,828,475)

• Miscellaneous Manufactured Commodities (4,388,746)

• Machinery, Except Electrical (2,738,539)

3.21. TTIP’s possible effects on Poland

Country factsheet

• GDP/capita: 13435$ (2014) (http://countryeconomy.com/)

• GDP: 525866 Mill. $ (2014)

• 8th biggest economy in 2013 in Europe, 23th biggest economy in the world (UN)

• Unemployment in 2014: 8.0% (EuroStat)

TTIP general impact according to studies

• Long-term effects on welfare depending on scenario taken: +0.28 to 5.44% (CESifo)

Trade with the US (US Census Bureau)

Trade with the US in 2014:

• Import: 3.7 billion $, 0.70% of GDP

• Export: 5.2 billion $, 1.00% of GDP

• Total: 1.70% of GDP

5 product categories exported at biggest value to US (2014 value, thousand $)

• Transportation Equipment (1,087,650)

• Computer & Electronic Products (729,510)

• Machinery, Except Electrical (592,033)

• Electrical Equipment, Appliances & Components (487,481)

• Furniture & Fixtures (429,012)

Page 55: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

55

5 product categories imported at biggest value from US (2014 value, thousand $)

• Transportation Equipment (1,104,357)

• Computer & Electronic Products (455,709)

• Machinery, Except Electrical (398,280)

• Chemicals (337,226)

• Electrical Equipment, Appliances & Components (163,179)

3.22. TTIP’s possible effects on Portugal

Country factsheet

• GDP/capita: 21733$ (2014) (http://countryeconomy.com/)

• GDP: 227324 Mill. $ (2014)

• 15th

biggest economy in 2013 in Europe, 45th

biggest economy in the world (UN)

• Unemployment in 2014: 13.4% (EuroStat)

TTIP general impact according to studies

• Though does not give a country specific estimate, for the region (“Other Southern and

Eastern Europe”) it predicts a 0.7% decrease in net exports, 0.21% decrease in GDP, -

165 Euros of per capita income per employee, and a 0.33% increase in dependency

ratio. (Capaldo)

• Long-term effects on welfare depending on scenario taken: +0.40 to 6.80% (CESifo)

Trade with the US (US Census Bureau)

Trade with the US in 2014:

• Import: 1.1 billion $, 0.50% of GDP

• Export: 3.2 billion $, 1.43% of GDP

• Total: 1.93% of GDP

5 product categories exported at biggest value to US (2014 value, thousand $)

• Petroleum & Coal Products (812,260)

• Chemicals (328,717)

• Wood Products (223,275)

• Apparel & Accessories (192,801)

• Paper (175,951)

5 product categories imported at biggest value from US (2014 value, thousand $)

• Agricultural Products (297,699)

• Transportation Equipment (218,592)

• Computer & Electronic Products (93,929)

• Chemicals (74,171)

• Oil & Gas (72,274)

Other impact assessments:

• CEPR conducted a separate CGE study for Portugal. They found that Portugal would

benefit proportionally more from tariff reduction than other EU member states.

Portugal may expect a GDP growth between 0.35-0.78% growth in GDP, 0.73-1.73%

growth in exports, 0.58-0.9% increase in low skill wages, somewhat lower increase in

medium- and high skill wages. (CEPR, 2014)

Page 56: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

56

3.23. TTIP’s possible effects on Romania

Country factsheet

• GDP/capita: 9499$ (2014) (http://countryeconomy.com/)

• GDP: 189638 Mill. $ (2014)

• 17th

biggest economy in 2013 in Europe, 53rd

biggest economy in the world (UN)

• Unemployment in 2014: 6.4% (EuroStat)

TTIP general impact according to studies

• Though does not give a country specific estimate, for the region (“Other Southern and

Eastern Europe”) it predicts a 0.7% decrease in net exports, 0.21% decrease in GDP, -

165 Euros of per capita income per employee, and a 0.33% increase in dependency

ratio. (Capaldo)

• Long-term effects on welfare depending on scenario taken: +0.38 to 5.82% (CESifo)

Trade with the US (US Census Bureau)

Trade with the US in 2014:

• Import: 978 million $, 0.52% of GDP

• Export: 2.1 billion $, 1.13% of GDP

• Total: 1.64% of GDP

5 product categories exported at biggest value to US (2014 value, thousand $)

• Computer & Electronic Products (413,510)

• Primary Metal Mfg (244,975)

• Fabricated Metal Products, Nesoi (219,674)

• Machinery, Except Electrical (191,573)

• Apparel & Accessories (188,690)

5 product categories imported at biggest value from US (2014 value, thousand $)

• Machinery, Except Electrical (192,118)

• Petroleum & Coal Products (160,362)

• Computer & Electronic Products (156,162)

• Transportation Equipment (120,504)

• Electrical Equipment, Appliances & Components (58,860)

3.24. TTIP’s possible effects on Slovakia

Country factsheet

• GDP/capita: 17706$ (2014) (http://countryeconomy.com/)

• GDP: 97707 Mill. $ (2014)

• 19th

biggest economy in 2013 in Europe, 63rd

biggest economy in the world (UN)

• Unemployment in 2014: 12.5% (EuroStat)

TTIP general impact according to studies

• Though does not give a country specific estimate, for the region (“Other Southern and

Eastern Europe”) it predicts a 0.7% decrease in net exports, 0.21% decrease in GDP, -

165 Euros of per capita income per employee, and a 0.33% increase in dependency

ratio. (Capaldo)

Page 57: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

57

• Long-term effects on welfare depending on scenario taken: +0.27 to 5.34% (CESifo)

Trade with the US (US Census Bureau)

Trade with the US in 2014:

• Import: 445 million $, 0.45% of GDP

• Export: 2.1 billion $, 2.16% of GDP

• Total: 2.61% of GDP

5 product categories exported at biggest value to US (2014 value, thousand $)

• Transportation Equipment (1,190,172)

• Machinery, Except Electrical (213,522)

• Plastics & Rubber Products (168,354)

• Computer & Electronic Products (88,552)

• Electrical Equipment, Appliances & Components (82,983)

5 product categories imported at biggest value from US (2014 value, thousand $)

• Computer & Electronic Products (96,601)

• Transportation Equipment (90,468)

• Machinery, Except Electrical (66,081)

• Minerals & Ores (55,282)

• Miscellaneous Manufactured Commodities (20,961)

3.25. TTIP’s possible effects on Slovenia

Country factsheet

• GDP/capita: 23317$ (2014) (http://countryeconomy.com/)

• GDP: 47987 Mill. $ (2014)

• 23rd

biggest economy in 2013 in Europe, 83rd

biggest economy in the world (UN)

• Unemployment in 2014: 9.7% (EuroStat)

TTIP general impact according to studies

• Long-term effects on welfare depending on scenario taken: +0.25 to 5.06% (CESifo)

Trade with the US (US Census Bureau)

Trade with the US in 2014:

• Import: 306 million $, 0.64% of GDP

• Export: 714 million $, 1.49% of GDP

• Total: 2.12% of GDP

5 product categories exported at biggest value to US (2014 value, thousand $)

• Chemicals (162,002)

• Electrical Equipment, Appliances & Components (94,191)

• Primary Metal Mfg (83,405)

• Transportation Equipment (76,637)

• Machinery, Except Electrical (66,513)

Page 58: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

58

5 product categories imported at biggest value from US (2014 value, thousand $)

• Chemicals (63,002)

• Fabricated Metal Products, Nesoi (55,224)

• Petroleum & Coal Products (39,718)

• Computer & Electronic Products (24,425)

• Minerals & Ores (21,913)

3.26. TTIP’s possible effects on Spain

Country factsheet

• GDP/capita: 29150$ (2014) (http://countryeconomy.com/)

• GDP: 1406176 Mill. $ (2014)

• 5th

biggest economy in 2013 in Europe, 13th

biggest economy in the world (UN)

• Unemployment in 2014: 23.7% (EuroStat)

TTIP general impact according to studies

• Though does not give a country specific estimate, for the region (“Other Southern and

Eastern Europe”) it predicts a 0.7% decrease in net exports, 0.21% decrease in GDP, -

165 Euros of per capita income per employee, and a 0.33% increase in dependency

ratio. (Capaldo)

• Long-term effects on welfare depending on scenario taken: +0.48 to 7.55% (CESifo)

Trade with the US (US Census Bureau)

Trade with the US in 2014:

• Import: 10.1 billion $, 0.72% of GDP

• Export: 14.9 billion $, 1.06% of GDP

• Total: 1.77% of GDP

5 product categories exported at biggest value to US (2014 value, thousand $)

• Chemicals (2,588,883)

• Petroleum & Coal Products (2,334,580)

• Transportation Equipment (2,032,432)

• Food & Kindred Products (1,259,787)

• Machinery, Except Electrical (1,247,936)

5 product categories imported at biggest value from US (2014 value, thousand $)

• Chemicals (2,893,569)

• Agricultural Products (1,532,674

• Transportation Equipment (1,041,851)

• Computer & Electronic Products (705,169)

• Machinery, Except Electrical (522,076)

3.27. TTIP’s possible effects on Sweden

Country factsheet

• GDP/capita: 60430$ (2014) (http://countryeconomy.com/)

• GDP: 579680 Mill. $ (2014)

• 7th

biggest economy in 2013 in Europe, 22nd

biggest economy in the world (UN)

Page 59: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

59

• Unemployment in 2014: 7.8% (EuroStat)

TTIP general impact according to studies

• Though does not give a country specific estimate, for the region (“Other Northern and

Western Europe”) it predicts a 2.07% decrease in net exports, 0.50% decrease in

GDP, -4848 Euros of per capita income per employee, and a 1.33% increase in

dependency ratio. (Capaldo)

• Long-term effects on welfare depending on scenario taken: +0.35 to 6.20% (CESifo)

Trade with the US (US Census Bureau)

Trade with the US in 2014:

• Import: 4.3 billion $, 0.75% of GDP

• Export: 10.3 billion $, 1.79% of GDP

• Total: 2.54% of GDP

5 product categories exported at biggest value to US (2014 value, thousand $)

• Machinery, Except Electrical (2,702,306)

• Transportation Equipment (1,413,989)

• Chemicals (970,707)

• Computer & Electronic Products (917,863)

• Primary Metal Mfg (836,151)

5 product categories imported at biggest value from US (2014 value, thousand $)

• Chemicals (787,606)

• Transportation Equipment (747,371)

• Computer & Electronic Products (636,451)

• Machinery, Except Electrical (569,202)

• Special Classification Provisions, Nesoi (225,231)

3.28. TTIP’s possible effects on United Kingdom

Country factsheet

• GDP/capita: 39366$ (2014) (http://countryeconomy.com/)

• GDP: 2523216 Mill. $ (2014)

• 3rd

biggest economy in 2013 in Europe, 6th

biggest economy in the world (UN)

• Unemployment in 2014: 5.9% (EuroStat)

TTIP general impact according to studies

• +0.4% GDP by 2025, changes in exports between +0.6% and +5.5%, changes in real

incomes between 0% and 0.4% depending on the scenario taken (CEPII)

• +0.37% employment, -0.34% change in the unemployment rate in percentage points

and +1.72% in real wages if only tariffs are reduced; +1.38% employment gains, -

1.27% change in the unemployment rate and +6.60% change in real wages under

“deep liberalization” (Bertelsmann/ifo)

• -0.95 net exports (% of GDP), -0.07 percentage points of GDP growth, 3000 jobs

destroyed, -4245 EUR income per employee, -0.39 tax revenue (as % of GDP),

dependency ratio up by 0.01 percentage points (total population / employed

population) (Capaldo)

Page 60: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

60

• Long-term effects on welfare depending on scenario taken: +0.43 to 7.05% (CESifo)

Trade with the US (US Census Bureau)

Trade with the US in 2014:

• Import: 53.9 billion $, 2.13% of GDP

• Export: 54.6 billion $, 2.16% of GDP

• Total: 4.30% of GDP

5 product categories exported at biggest value to US (2014 value, thousand $)

• Transportation Equipment (11,367,733)

• Chemicals (9,011,091)

• Machinery, Except Electrical (6,030,282)

• Petroleum & Coal Products (5,410,056)

• Goods Returned (exports For Canada Only) (4,336,539)

5 product categories imported at biggest value from US (2014 value, thousand $)

• Transportation Equipment (12,131,907)

• Chemicals (6,430,593)

• Computer & Electronic Products (5,502,556)

• Primary Metal Mfg (4,509,394)

• Machinery, Except Electrical (3,974,621)

Other impact assessments

• A separate study has been carried out by CEPR to predict TTIP outcomes for the UK.

The study projects 0.14-0.27% increase in GDP, 1.22-2.21% growth in exports, 1.03-

1.87% increase in imports. Real national income is expected to grow between 0.13-

0.26%. Real wages of the less and more skilled both will grow between 0.21-0.38%.

(CEPR, 2013)

Page 61: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

61

References

10 myths about TTIP. Confederation of Danish Industries, 2014.

11 myths about TTIP. Swedish Enterprise, 2014.

A transatlantic corporate bill of rights – Investor privileges in EU-US trade deal threaten

public interest and democracy. Seattle to Brussels Network, October 2013

Adolf, Constanze, Jacqueline Cottrell, Amani Joas, Claudia Schulz: TTIP and Fossil Fuel

Subsidies: Using international policy processes as entry points for reform in the EU and the US.

GreenBudget Europe, 2013. Heinrich Böll Foundation TTIP Series.

AFL-CIO: An American Labor Perspective on TTIP. In: Christoph Scherred (Ed.): TTIP:

Implications for Labor. ICDD, Rainer Hampp Verlag. München, 2014

Baker, Dean: TTIP: It's not about trade (atlantic-community.org, 2014)

Berden, Koen G., Joseph Francois, Martin Thelle, Paul Wymenga and Saara Tamminen:

Non-Tariff Measures in EU-US Trade and Investment – An Economic Analyisis. Ecorys, 2009-

Bizzarri, Kim: Brave New Transatlantic Partnership. Seattle to Brussels Network, 2013

Bureau, Jean-Christophe : EU industry will gain from TTIP, not the food sector.

Interview. Europost, 12 September 2014

Cai, Songfeng, Yaiong Zhang and Bo Meng: Spillover Effects of TTIP on BRICS

Economies: A Dynamic GVC-Based CGE model. IDE Discussion papers, 2015

Capaldo, Jeronim: The Trans-Atlantic Trade and Investment Partnership: European

Disintegration, Unemployment and Instability. Global Development and Environment Institute

Working Paper Np. 14-03. October, 2014

CEPR: Estimating the Economic Impact on the UK of a Transatlantic Trade and

Investment Partnership (TTIP) Agreement between the European Union and the United States,

Final Project Report March 2013

Choblet, Matthieu, Werner Hager: TAFTA/TTIP: New dawn for Atlanticists, sunset for

Old Europe? In: The Transatlantic Colossus, 2014

Cingotti, Natcha, Pia Everhard, Timothé Feodoroff, Antoine Simon and Ilana Solomon:

No fracking way: how the EU-US trade agreement risks expanding fracking. Sierra Club Issue

brief, March 2014.

Dean Baker: TTIP: It's not about trade (atlantic-community.org)

Debbie Barker: TTIP – impacts on food and farming. Center for Food Safety, 2014 May.

Dieter, Hervert: The Structural Weaknesses of TTIP. Stiftung Wissenschaft und Politik,

2013

Draper, Petern, Simon Lacey and Yash Ramkolowan: Mega-regional trade agreements:

implications for the African, Caribbean and Pacific countries. ECIPE Occasional Paper No

2/2014

ENVI Relevant Legislative Areas of The EU-US Trade and Investment Partnership

Negotiations – DG for Internal Policy

Erixon, Fredrik: The New Transatlantic Trade Initiative: Is It the Real Thing? Boao

Review, July 2013

Erixon, Fredrik: The TTIP and the Shifting Structure of Global Trade Policy. CESIfo

Forum 4/2012

Fabry, Elvire and Giorgio Garbasso: ISDS in the TTIP – the devil is in the details. Policy

paper 122, 16 January 2015. Notre Europe – Jacques Delors Institute.

Page 62: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

62

Fabry, Elvire, Giorgio Garbasso, Romain Pardo: The TTIP Negotiations: A Pirandello

Play. Notre Europe, Jacques Delors Institute and EPC. 23 January 2014.

Felbermayr, Gabriel, Benedikt Heid and Sybille Lehwald: Transatlantic Trade and

Investment Partnership (TTIP) – Who benefits from a free trade deal? Part 1: Macroeconomic

Effects. Bertelsmann/ifo. 2014

Felbermayr, Gabriel, Benedikt Heid, Mario Larch and Erdal Yalcin: Macroeconomic

Potentials of Transatlantic Free Trade: A High Resolution Perspective for Europe and the

World. CESifo working paper No. 5019. October 2014

Ferdi De Ville: Why the TAFTA/TTIP will not live up to its promises. In: The

Transatlantic Colossus, 2014

Flues, Fabian: Dirty Deals – how trade talks threaten to undermine EU climate policies

and bring tar sands to Europe. 2014, Heinrich Böll Foundation TTIP Series.

Fontagné, Lionel, Julien Gourdon and Sébastien Jean: Transatlantic Trade: Whither

Partnership, Which Economic Consequences? CEPII Policy Brief No.1, September 2013

Francois, Joseph: Reducing Transatlantic Barriers to Trade and Investment – An

Economic Assessment. Final Project Report, March 2013. CEPR

Frederik Erixon: Transatlantic Free Trade: An Agenda for Jobs, Growth and Global

Trade Leadership. CES, March 2012.

Gerstetter, Christiane and Nils Meyer-Ohlendorf: Investor-state dispute settlement under

TTIP – a risk for environmental regulation? Ecologic Institute, 2013. Heinrich Böll Foundation

TTIP Series.

Grassini, Maurizio: Rowing along the Computable General Equilibrium Modelling

Mainstream. Studi e Note di Economia Anno XII, n 3-2007, pagg. 315-343

Hansen-Kuhn, Karen and Steve Suppan: Promises and Perils of the TTIP: Negotiating a

Transatlantic Agricultural Market. Institute for Agriculture and Trade Policy, 2013. Heinrich

Böll Foundation TTIP Series.

Hartmann, Alessa: TAFTA/TTIP: No thank you! That's not what a transatlantic

partnership means. In: The Transatlantic Colossus, 2014

Hilary, John: The TTIP: A charter for deregulation, an attack on jobs, an end to

democracy. Rosa Luxemburg Stiftung, 2014. Brussels Office.

Ikenson, Daniel: Fresh ideas for a successful TTIP. CESifo Forum 4/2013

IUF: Trade Deals that Threaten Democracy. In: Christoph Scherred (Ed.): TTIP:

Implications for Labor. ICDD, Rainer Hampp Verlag. München, 2014

Karnakar, Suparna: Prospects for regulatory convergence under TTIP. Bruegel Policy

Contribution Issue 2013/15, October 2013

Kirchschlager, Markus A.: In between curious economics and l'exception culturelle:

implications of TAFTA/TTIP for the culturel sector. In: The Transatlantic Colossus, 2014

Knoll, Katharina, Michaela Zinke and Jutta Jaksche: Safeguarding consumer rights and

protection in the TAFTA/TTIP. In: The Transatlantic Colossus, 2014

Körnig, Johanna and Claudia Schmucker: TTIP: A chance for Europe. German Council

on Foreign Relations, 2014.

Lance, Taylor and Rudiger von Amin: Modelling the Impact of Trade Liberalisation: A

critique of computable general equilibrium models. Oxfam Research Reports, 2006

Lejour, Arjan, Federica Mustilli, Jacques Pelkmans and Jacopo Timini: Economic

Incentives for Indirect TTIP Spillovers. CEPS, No 94 / Octover 2014, TTIP Series No 2.

Page 63: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

63

McKitrick, Ross R. : The econometric critique of computable general equilibrium

modelling: the role of functional forms. Economic Modelling, Volume 15, Issue 4, October

1998, Pages 543-573

Mildner, Stormy-Annika and Claudia Schmucker: Trade Agreement with Side-Effects?

Stiftung Wissenschaft und Politik, 2013

Myant, Martin and Ronan O'Brien: The TTIP's impact: bringing in the missing issue.

Working paper 2015.01, European Trade Union Institute

Pardo, Romain: ISDS & TTIP: A miracle cure for a systemic challenge? EPC

Commentary, 2014

Pardo, Romain: The Transatlantic Trade and Investment Partnersip – A long hard road

to multilateralism? EPC Commentary, 19 July 2013

Pelkmans, Jacques, Arjan Lejour, Lorna Schrefler, Federica Mustilli and Jacopo Timini:

The impact of TTIP – The underlying economic model and comparisons. CEPS, No 93. / October

2014. TTIP Series No 1.

Plociennik, Sebastian: German Scepticism on TTIP: The Need for a Polish Correction.

The Polish Institute of International Affairs., Bulletin No 44., 2014

Quantifying the Impact of a Transatlantic Trade and Investment Partnership (T-TIP)

Agreement on Portugal. Final Report, CEPR, 2014

Raza, Werner, Jan Grumiller, Lance Taylor, Bernhard Tröster and Rudi von Arnim:

Assessing the Claimed Benefits of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment Partnership (TTIP)

Austrian Foundation for Development Research, Vienna, 2014

Risks and opportunities for the EU Agri-Food sector in a possible EU-US trade

agreement. DG for Internal Policies, 2014

Rollo, Jim, Peter Holmes, Spencer Henson, Maximillamo Mendez Parra, Sarah

Olleranshaw, Javier Lopez Gonzalez, Xavier Ciera and Matteo Sandi: Potential effects of the

proposed TTIP on selected developing countries. Ideas consulting, 2014

Schmucker, Claudia: Uncompromised Food and Safety Standards. German Council of

Foreign Relations, 2014.

Smith, Erica, David Azoulay and Baskut Tuncak: Lowest common denominator – How

the proposed EU-US trade deal threatens to lower standards of protection from toxic pesticides.

Center for International Environment Law, 2015

Storny-Annika Mildner: Defending TTIP: Experts Respond to Mounting Criticism

(atlantic-community.org)

Straubhaar, Thomas: TTIP: From Global to Regional Multilateralism. Transatlantic

Academy, 2013

Thorstensen, Vera and Lucas Ferraz: The impacts of TTIP and TPP on Brazil. Centro do

Comércio Global e Investimento, 2014.

Tim Josling and Stefan Tangermann: Agriculture, Food and the TTIP – Possibilities and

Pitfalls. CEPS Special Report No 99., December 2014

Transatlantic Trade and Investment Partnership: Myths, Facts & Arguments. Position

paper of the Federation of German Industries. 2014

Trigkas, Vasilis: The strategic implications of TAFTA/TTIP: Will it engage or contain

China? In: The Transatlantic Colossus, 2014

TTIP Impacts on European Energy Markets and Manufacturing Industries – DG for

Internal Policies, 2015

Van Ham, Peter: The Geopolitics of TTIP. Clingendaél Policy Brief No 23, 2013 October

Page 64: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

64

Venhaus, Marc: The TTIP as a new strategy to marginalize emerging powers: a divided

free trade order in the making? In: The Transatlantic Colossus, 2014

Why the TTIP matters to European Business. BusinessEurope, 2014

Zulaga, Diego: NHS patients and taxpayers will benefit from TTIP. Intitute of Eonomic

Affairs, blog entry (26 November 2014)

Page 65: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

65

Appendix

Appendix: Non-Trade Barriers in US-EU trade

In this Appendix we give a short summary of the non-trade barriers to trade identified in

the Ecorys study (Berden et al. 2009) and highlight which of those are subject to controversy in

the TTIP debate.

Aerospace industry

Table 1 NTMs from the EU perspective

Rank NTM or Diverging Regulation Trend

Trade measures

1 US support to Boeing (aeronautics) Constant

2 Restrictions on foreign launching services (space) Increasing

3 US support to aircraft engine manufacturers (aeronautics) Increasing

4 Very limited access of foreign companies to US government support

programmes (e.g. Technology Innovation Programme) Increasing

5 International Traffic in Arms Regulations (ITAR) (space sector) Increasing

6 Buy American Act Increasing

7 US product standards which differ from international standards Constant

8

On-board equipment and instruments: Safety Standards for Flight

Guidance Systems and Proposed Revisions to Advisory Circular 25-

1329-1A, Automatic Pilot Systems Approval

Decreasing

Investment measures

1 Limits to investment due to national security and strategic

considerations Increasing

Table 2 NTMs from the US perspective

Rank NTM or Diverging Regulation Trend

Trade measures

1 Government support for Airbus Constant

2 Government support for Airbus Suppliers Increasing

3 Government support for Aircraft Engines producers Constant

4 Prior authorisation for sensitive product categories Constant

5 Trade measures due to technical specifications Constant

6

Double certification need caused by The European Union’s Authorized

Economic Operator (AEO) program and the US Customs-Trade

Partnership against Terrorism (C-TPAT)

Decreasing

7 EU Patent System Constant

Investment measures

1 Limits to investment due to national security and strategic

considerations Increasing

Page 66: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

66

Automotives industry

Table 3 NTMs from the EU perspective

Rank NTM or Diverging Regulation Trend

Trade measures

1

US product standards (FMVSS) differ from the international standards

(UNECE); for instance with regards to roof crush resistance and

occupant protection in interior impact.

Constant

2 Taxation of cars with high fuel consumption (CAFE = Corporate

Average Fuel Economy) Increasing

3 Gas Guzzler Tax Increasing

4 American Automobile Labelling Act

5 Very limited access of foreign companies to US government subsidy

programmes (e.g. Technology Innovation Programme) Constant

6 Different cetane levels in diesel fuel between EU and US – leading costs

to tune engines to these different levels Constant

7

Double certification need caused by The European Union’s Authorized

Economic Operator (AEO) program and the US Customs-Trade

Partnership against Terrorism (C-TPAT)

Decreasing

8 Reporting requirement on container transport: 10+2 regulation Increasing

9 Buy American Act, which causes measures affecting access to the US

government procurement markets Increasing

10 US Intellectual property right system (with first to invent principle) Constant

Investment measures

1 State level investment regulations on tax benefits and infrastructure that

differ Constant

2

US product standards (FMVSS) differ from the international standards

(UNECE); for instance with regards to roof crush resistance and

occupant protection in interior impact

Constant

3

Civil Penalties for violations of statutes and regulations NHTSA

pertaining to motor vehicle safety, bumper standards, and consumer

information.

Constant

Page 67: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

67

Table 4 NTMs from the US perspective

Rank NTM or Diverging Regulation Trend

Trade measures

1

EU/international product standards (UNECE) differ from US standards

(FMVSS). Constant

2 Trade measures due to numerous technical specifications. Increasing

3 REACH regulation Decreasing

4 Safety and health measures Constant

5 Different cetane levels in diesel fuel between EU and US – leading to

costs to tune engines to these different levels Constant

6 Patent system Constant

7

Double certification need caused by the European Union’s Authorized

Economic Operator (AEO) program and the US Customs-Trade

Partnership against Terrorism (C-TPAT)

Decreasing

8 Customs administration differences between EU Member States Decreasing

Investment measures

1 EU/international product standards (UNECE) differ from US standards

(FMVSS). Decreasing

2 Security related prohibitions on investments Constant

3 EU member state level differences in investment regimes (e.g. infra-

structure, taxes, training or R&D support) Decreasing

Chemicals industry

Table 5 NTMs from the EU perspective

Rank NTM or Diverging Regulation Trend

Trade measures

1 Classification and labelling requirements for chemical products

Constant -

Decreasing in

longer term

(UN GHS)

2 Threat of 100% container scanning Increasing

3 Restrictions on use of specific chemicals Constant

4 Different state level chemical security regulations Constant -

Increasing

5 Different local governments (below state level) implementing chemical

security regulations Constant

6 Evaluation and notification of new significant new uses Increasing

7 Pesticide/biocide testing and evaluation for licensing Increasing

8 Indirect effects from food safety legislation – packaging in contact with

food Increasing

Investment measures

1 Discrimination of foreign companies in public procurement Constant

2 Foreign Investment and National Security Act, which can

create excess costs for FDI Constant

3 Very limited access of foreign companies to US government support

programmes (e.g. Technology Innovation Programme) Constant

4 Tax Code Reporting Requirements applied to foreign owned companies Constant

5 US Intellectual Property Right system (with first to invent principle) Constant

6 US Accounting Standards (affected by Sarbanes-Oxley Act) Increasing

Page 68: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

68

Table 6 NTMs from the US perspective

Rank NTM or Diverging Regulation Trend

Trade measures

1

Divergence in risk assessment requirements between REACH and

TSCA Constant

2 Classification of chemicals under the Dangerous Substances

Directive Decreasing

3 RoHS and restrictions on hazardous substances Constant -

increasing

4 Product Labelling requirements (including ecolabelling) Constant

5 Testing requirements / Risk assessment for plant protection and

biocidal products Constant

6

Double certification need caused by the European Union’s Authorised

Economic Operator (AEO) program and the US Customs-Trade

Partnership against Terrorism (C-TPAT)

Decreasing

7 Different Member State legislation on chemicals security Constant

8 Customs administration differences between EU Member States Constant

9 Pre-shipment inspections Increasing

Investment measures

1 EU Intellectual property rights definition which is less broad than

the US ones Constant

Communications services industry

Table 7 NTMs from the EU perspective

Rank NTM or Diverging Regulation Trend

Trade measures

1 ATSC technology which is not compatible with DVB-T standards in EU Constant

2 Licenses Decreasing

3 US standards differ from international standards Constant

4 Monopoly of the USPS in the US market Decreasing

5 Restricted access to high speed internet connections for foreign firms Constant

6 US Intellectual property right system (with first to invent principle) Constant

7 Transfer delays, slow custom procedures (postal) Constant

8 US Customs Refusal of “Made in EU” Constant

Investment measures

1 Restrictions in the access to local finance Constant

2 Discrimination of foreign companies in public procurement Constant

3 Limits imposed by CFIUS on the number/share of (foreign) firms Constant

4 Requirements regarding professional qualifications for foreign firms Constant

5 Very limited access of foreign companies to US government subsidy

programmes (e.g. Technology Innovation Programme) Constant

6 Tax Code Reporting Requirements applied to foreign owned

corporations Decreasing

7 Limitations on land ownership Constant

8 Buy American Act, which causes measures affecting Increasing

Page 69: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

69

Table 8 NTMs from the US perspective

Rank NTM or Diverging Regulation Trend

Trade measures

1

Delays in implementation of opening up telecom markets in EU in

some member states Decreasing

2 ATSC technology which is not compatible with DVB-T standards in

EU Constant

3 National monopolies in the postal market Decreasing

Investment measures

1 Delays in implementing Utilities directive Decreasing

2 National monopolies in the postal markets in some EU member states Decreasing

3 Takeover directive Constant

4 Use of defensive measures against hostile takeovers Constant

5 Specific EU member legislations and practices related to utilities

investments Decreasing

Cosmetics industry

Table 9 NTMs from the EU perspective

Rank NTM or Diverging Regulation Trend

Trade measures

1 Restrictions on use of chemicals used in cosmetics Constant

2 Classification and labelling requirements for chemical products

Constant -

Decreasing

UN GHS1

3 US state level safety certifications Constant

4 Threat of 100% container scanning Increasing

5 Prior authorisation for sensitive product categories Constant

6 Restrictions on formulation changes Constant

7 Labelling differences Constant

Investment measures

1 Discrimination of foreign companies in access to government subsidy

programmes Decreasing

2 Discrimination foreign firms in public procurement Constant

3 Foreign Investment and National Security Act, which can create excess

costs for FDI Constant

4 US Intellectual Property Right system (with first to invent principle) Constant

5 US Accounting Standards (affected by SOX) Increasing

Page 70: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

70

Table 10 NTMs from the US perspective

Rank NTM or Diverging Regulation Trend

Trade measures

1

Animal testing: a ban on animal testing of cosmetic products and on

products containing ingredients tested on animals Increasing

2 Product notifications differ from Member State to Member State Constant

3 Notification: Compulsory in EU, not in US Constant

4 Evaluation by SCCP Increasing

5 Access to information – different requirements in US Increasing

6 Use of CMR substances Constant

7 Differing requirements for labelling products Increasing

8 US non-retail products exempt from certain labelling requirements but

not in the EU Constant

Investment measures

1 A ban on animal testing of cosmetic products and on products

containing ingredients tested on animals Increasing

2 Product notifications differ from Member State to Member State. Increasing

Electronics industry

Table 11 NTMs from the EU perspective

Rank NTM or Diverging Regulation Trend

Trade measures

1 US product standards that differ from international standards Constant

2 US state level safety certifications requirements Increasing

3 3rd party testing for import products with EU declarations of conformity Constant

4 Non-transparency of standards Increasing

5 Energy Conservation Program for Commercial and Industrial Equipment

(EPCA) Increasing

6 Safety of electrical and electronics products Nonharmonized standards –

differences per State Increasing

7

Standards developed by different bodies, e.g. the Occupational Safety and

Health Administration (OSHA), and National Electric Code and Industry

Safety Standards, e. g. Underwriter’s Laboratories (UL)

Constant

8 Encryption Control Policy not in line with the Wassenaar arrangement

(new US requirements on crypto functionality). Constant

Investment measures

1 Nationality or residence requirements for staff Increasing

2 US legal liability philosophy Increasing

3 US IPR system (with first to invent principle) Increasing

4 US government aid and subsidies (e.g. Advanced tech programme),

accessible only for US companies Constant

Page 71: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

71

Table 12 NTMs from the US perspective

Rank NTM or Diverging Regulation Trend

Trade measures

1 Restriction on Hazardous Substances (RoHS) Directive Constant

2 WEEE Decreasing

3 REACH regulation Constant

4 Several directives for energy efficiency, e.g. Framework for Energy-

using Products, Low Voltage Directive Increasing

5 EU standards in the field of information technology and

telecommunications Decreasing

6 Differences in testing standards and certification procedures Decreasing

7 Customs and border protection/controls Decreasing

8 European patent system Constant

9 Pre-shipment inspections Increasing

Investment measures

1 EU Data Protection Directive (1995/46) Constant

2 European patent system Constant

3 Local licensing requirements Constant

4 Requirement for professional qualifications for foreign firms Decreasing

Financial services industry

Table 13 NTMs from the EU perspective

Rank NTM or Diverging Regulation Trend

Trade measures

1

Discriminatory taxation of European financial institutions that

apply IFRS instead of US GAAP1

Decreasing

2

Section 319 of the PATRIOT Act that requires US correspondent

banks to maintain certain records concerning foreign banks with a

US correspondent account

Increasing

3 Tax Code Reporting Requirements applied to foreign-owned

corporations Constant

4 Registration requirements for foreign banks in the US providing

global custody and related services directly to US investors Increasing

5 Differences in the implementation of the Basle II framework for

banks Constant

6 Sarbanes Oxley Act Constant

7 Lack of convergence in the regulation of financial services across

US states Increasing

Investment measures

1 Duplicative consolidated supervision of EU Central Bank and

Federal Reserve Constant

2 Local licencing requirements Constant

3 Absence of convergence regulations in reporting standards Decreasing

4 Requirement for professional qualifications for foreign firms Decreasing

Page 72: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

72

Table 14 NTMs from the US perspective

Rank NTM or Diverging Regulation Trend

Trade measures

1

Differences in the implementation of the Basle II framework for

banks Constant

2 Auditor oversight and lack of cooperation between EU and US

financial regulators Decreasing

3 EU intellectual property rights which are less broad than the

US ones Constant

4

US and other investment firms from non-EU countries may

operate with authorisation from Italy’s securities market

regulator, CONSOB, only.

Constant

5 Different regulatory requirements and local licensing

requirements Decreasing

6 National treatment may be applied to non-EC branches of Foreign

Credit Institutions (FCIs) on the basis of reciprocity. Constant

7 Absence of convergence between EU Member States Constant

Investment measures

1 Individual Member State authorisation and regulation applied to

direct branches of non-EU financial service institutions Constant

2 Government procurement only open to national companies Decreasing

Food & beverages industry

Table 15 NTMs from the EU perspective

Rank NTM or Diverging Regulation Trend

Trade measures

1

Direct and indirect government support by means of subsidies,

protective legislation and tax policies to US farmers Constant

2 Container Security Initiative, causing delays for all sea cargo Constant

3 US product standards which differ from international standards Constant

4 Custom surcharges Constant

5

US prohibition to register/renew a trademark or a trade name

which is identical or similar to a trademark or trade name used

in connection with a confiscated business

Constant -

increasing

6 Threat of 100% container scanning Constant

7

Double certification need caused by the European Union’s

Authorized Economic Operator (AEO) program and the US

Customs-Trade Partnership against Terrorism (C-TPAT)

Decreasing

8 US Customs Refusal of “Made in EU” Constant

Investment measures

1

Need to get a re-export license for products that contain content

of US origin and that have both commercial and military or

proliferation applications

Increasing

2 US Buy American Act Constant

3 High and different level of SPS measures Increasing

4 State-level regulations that differ across states Constant

Page 73: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

73

Table 16 NTMs from the US perspective

Rank NTM or Diverging Regulation Trend

Trade measures

1

EU product standards (SPS) which are higher than international

standards Constant

2 Custom surcharges Constant

3 EU labelling requirement laws Increasing

4 Double certification need caused by the European Union’s AOE

program and the US C-TPAT) Decreasing

5 Direct and indirect government support by means of

protective legislation and tax policies to EU farmers Constant

6 Traceability and labelling of biotechnology foods Increasing

7 Maximum limits on mycotoxins for a variety of foodstuffs

(including cereals, fruit and nuts) Constant

8 US product requirement to classify them as “organic” Constant

Investment measures

1 Different Member State- level regulations on some food

products Constant

2 High level of food and safety standards resulting in high SPS

measures Increasing

3 Long and difficult authorisation procedures Constant

Insurance services industry

Table 17 NTMs from the EU perspective

Rank NTM or Diverging Regulation Trend

Trade measures

1

Collateral requirements (or especially US reinsurance

services) Increasing

2 Lack of federal legislation and differences in state legislation Constant

3 Federal excise tax for insurers (cascading tax) Increasing

Investment measures

1 Diverging state-level regulations Increasing

2 No operating licenses for government controlled insurance

companies Constant

Page 74: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

74

Table 18 NTMs from the US perspective

Rank NTM or Diverging Regulation Trend

Trade measures

1

Solvency II regulations – equivalence determination and

group-wide supervision Increasing

2 Other licenses Constant

3 Lack of convergence in insurance and reinsurance regulation

in the EU Constant

4 Compulsory national services Decreasing

5 Regulatory capital requirements in reinsurance Increasing

Investment measures

1 “Reciprocal” national treatment clauses in EU banking,

insurance and investment services directives Decreasing

2 The proposed EC legislation known as Solvency II Increasing

3 Requirements regarding professional qualifications for

foreign firms Decreasing

Office Information & Communications Equipment Industry

Table 19 NTMs from the EU perspective

Rank NTM or Diverging Regulation Trend

Trade measures

1

US product standards which differ from the international

standards Constant

2 US state-level safety and power supply certifications Increasing

3 Third party testing for import products with EU declarations

of conformity Constant

4 Non-transparency of standards Increasing

5 Conformity assessment procedures Increasing

6 Threat of 100% container scanning Increasing

7 Energy efficiency programme for certain commercial and

industrial equipment Constant

8 US patent legislation Constant

Investment measures

1 Nationality or residence requirements for staff Increasing

2 US legal liability philosophy Increasing

3 US product standards which differ from the international

standards Increasing

4 Safety of electrical and electronics products, nonharmonised

standards, different from state to state Constant

5 US intellectual property rights system (with first to invent

principle) Increasing

Page 75: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

75

Table 20 NTMs from the US perspective

Rank NTM or Diverging Regulation Trend

Trade measures

1 Waste electric and electronic equipment directive Decreasing

2 Other technical measures Decreasing

3 Customs and border protection Decreasing

4 EU standards in the field of information technology and

telecommunications Decreasing

5 European patent system Constant

6 Transfer delays, slow custom procedures

7

Council Decision 93/465/EEC concerning the modules for

the various phases of the conformity assessment

procedures

Constant

8 EU Electromagnetic Compatibility requirements Constant

Investment measures

1 Waste electric and electronic equipment directive Decreasing

2 EU Member States to adopt DVB-H as the main

technology for networks Increasing

3 Other technical measures Decreasing

4 European patent system Constant

5 Local licensing requirements Constant

Page 76: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

76

Pharmaceuticals industry

Table 21 NTMs from the EU perspective

Rank NTM or Diverging Regulation Trend

Trade measures

1 Restrictions or bans on use of specific chemicals

Constant -

Increasing

2 Classification and labelling requirements for chemical

products

Constant -

Decreasing

3 Threat of 100% container scanning Increasing

4 FDA New Drug Approval Process Increasing

5 Drug precursor legislation Constant

6

Double certification need caused by the European

Union Authorized Economic Operator programme and

the US Customs CTPAT program

Constant

7 US state level safety certifications Constant -

Increasing

8 Prior authorization for sensitive product categories Increasing

Investment measures

1

Very limited access of foreign companies to US

government subsidy programmes (e.g. Technology

Innovation Programme)

Decreasing

2 Restricted access for foreign companies in public

procurement (especially due to BAA) Constant

3 Foreign Investment and National Security Act

(FINSA), which can create excess costs for FDI Constant

4 Long/difficult authorisation and registration procedures Increasing

5 US Intellectual Property Right system (with first to

invent principle) Constant

Page 77: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

77

Table 22 NTMs from the US perspective

Rank NTM or Diverging Regulation Trend

Trade measures

1 EU pricing policy – Member State differences Increasing

2 Health technology assessment differences Increasing

3 Different rules in various Member States

concerning authorization of pharmaceuticals Constant

4 International reference pricing Constant

5 Therapeutic reference pricing Constant

6 Differences in the enforcement of the unified customs

system across EU Member States Decreasing

7 Parallel trade allowance Constant -

Decreasing

8 Restrictions concerning information distribution to

patients Constant

Investment measures

1 Export restraint arrangements Increasing

2 Different rules in different Member States concerning

authorization of pharmaceuticals

Decreasing -

Constant

3 Prohibitions against investment by foreign companies

(e.g. security, sensitive products, etc.) Increasing

Page 78: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

78

Transportation services industry

Table 23 NTMs from the EU perspective

Rank NTM or Diverging Regulation Trend

Trade measures

1 Foreign ownership restrictions Constant

2

Fly American Act, which demands that all federal

government-funded flights are provided by US-flag air

carriers

Constant

3

Requirement for all items procured/owned by the

military departments be carried exclusively on US-flag

vessels

Constant

4 Proposal of 100% container scanning Increasing

5 Environmental regulations (e.g. Clean Air Act) Increasing

6 Requirement for at least 50% of all US government

generated cargos to be transported on US-flag vessels Constant

7 Security data collection (e.g. fingerprints) Constant

8

Requirement for 100% of any cargos generated by US

Government loans (i.e., commodities financed by

Export- Import Bank loans) to be carried on US flag

vessels

Constant

Investment measures

1 Foreign ownership restrictions Constant

2 Restrictions on the use of foreign temporary workers Constant

3

Requirement for US airlines to be under the majority

control of US citizens in order to be licensed for

operation.

Decreasing

4 Lack of unified state level investment legislation

across US Constant

Page 79: Consequences of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment ...ttip2016.eu › files › content › docs › Full documents › ttip... · This study gives a brief overview of the projected

79

Table 24 NTMs from the US perspective

Rank NTM or Diverging Regulation Trend

Trade measures

1 Restrictions on foreign ownership and control Constant

2

Double certification need caused by the European

Union’s Authorized Economic Operator (AEO)

program and the U.S. Customs

Constant

3 Differences in privacy laws vs. security

considerations Increasing

4 Introduction of ETS (future) Increasing

5 Operating restrictions at airports (access to customs,

flying times, etc.) Constant

6

Technical EU regulations (e.g. product

characteristics requirements, labelling requirements,

testing requirements, etc.)

Constant

7 Differences in the enforcement of the unified

customs system across EU member states Decreasing

Investment measures

1 Restrictions on the use of foreign temporary workers Constant

2

Lack of unified investment legislation across EU

member states. (This does not apply to air

transportation services.)

Decreasing

3 Airline investments limited due to strategic &

security concerns in the EU Constant