29
African Development Bank Group Working Paper Series n°274 July 2017 Conflict and Fragile States in Africa J. Paul Dunne and Nan Tian

Conflict and Fragile States in SSA jpd 280317 - Building today, a … · 2019. 6. 29. · 1 Conflict and Fragile States in Africa 1 J. Paul Dunne and Nan Tian JEL Classification:

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    0

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • Africa

    n Deve

    lopme

    nt Ban

    k Grou

    p

    Workin

    g Pape

    r Serie

    s

    n°274

    July 2

    017

    Conflict and Fragile Statesin AfricaJ. Paul Dunne and Nan Tian

  • Working Paper No 274

    Abstract

    This paper considers the determinants of

    conflict in Africa. It revisits the greed–

    grievance debate to consider the specific

    regional context and changing nature of

    conflict in sub-Saharan Africa. This is a

    literature that has grown rapidly in

    economics and political science, but some

    recent developments in modeling and

    conceptualization are providing important

    new contributions. It proposes and uses

    modeling techniques that deal with the

    problem of excess zeros, revisits the

    definition of conflict, and improves upon

    some proxy measures. Understanding the

    nature of conflict in Africa is vital to

    designing post-conflict economic policies

    and interventions, to ensure policies can

    prevent conflict-affected states from

    returning to conflict or remaining fragile.

    This paper is the product of the Vice-Presidency for Economic Governance and Knowledge Management. It is part

    of a larger effort by the African Development Bank to promote knowledge and learning, share ideas, provide open

    access to its research, and make a contribution to development policy. The papers featured in the Working Paper

    Series (WPS) are those considered to have a bearing on the mission of AfDB, its strategic objectives of Inclusive

    and Green Growth, and its High-5 priority areas—to Power Africa, Feed Africa, Industrialize Africa, Integrate

    Africa and Improve Living Conditions of Africans. The authors may be contacted at [email protected].

    Rights and Permissions

    All rights reserved.

    The text and data in this publication may be reproduced as long as the source is cited. Reproduction for commercial purposes

    is forbidden. The WPS disseminates the findings of work in progress, preliminary research results, and development

    experience and lessons, to encourage the exchange of ideas and innovative thinking among researchers, development

    practitioners, policy makers, and donors. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in the Bank’s WPS are

    entirely those of the author(s) and do not necessarily represent the view of the African Development Bank Group, its Board

    of Directors, or the countries they represent.

    Working Papers are available online at https://www.afdb.org/en/documents/publications/working-paper-series/

    Produced by Macroeconomics Policy, Forecasting, and Research Department

    Coordinator

    Adeleke O. Salami

    Correct citation: Dunne J. P. and N. Tian (2017), Conflict and Fragile States in Africa, Working Paper Series N° 274, African

    Development Bank, Abidjan, Côte d’Ivoire.

    mailto:[email protected]://www.afdb.org/en/documents/publications/working-paper-series/

  • 1

    Conflict and Fragile States in Africa 1

    J. Paul Dunne and Nan Tian

    JEL Classification: D74; C3

    Keywords: Civil war; zero-inflation; greed; grievance

    1 J. Paul Dunne: School of Economics and Southern Africa Labour Development Research Unit

    (SALDRU), University of Cape Town, Cape Town, 7701; email: john.dunne @uct.ac.za

    Nan Tian: Stockholm International Peace Research Institute (SIPRI) and SALDRU, University of

    Cape Town; email: [email protected]

  • 2

    1 Introduction

    Civil war has been commonplace over the past 60 years, but until relatively recently received

    little attention from economists. It is not just common, but also persistent, wars lasting longer,

    decade after decade (Fearon, Kasara, and Laitin 2007). Blattman and Miguel (2010) estimated

    that, since 1960, 20 percent of all countries have experienced at least 10 years of civil conflict.

    Civil conflict is devastating to the countries affected, with Collier et al. (2003) suggesting that

    the destructive forces of civil conflict could be large enough to explain the income gap between

    the poorest and richest nations. One could almost see civil war as reversing development,

    diverting resources from productive activities to destruction and having both devastating direct

    costs and opportunity costs, from the loss of productive resources (Collier et al. 2003). These

    potential costs make it important to understand why conflicts start, and the contribution by

    Collier and Hoeffler (2004), which sought to empirically test two competing theoretical

    hypotheses concerning the determinants of intrastate armed conflict—opportunity versus

    grievance led to a large empirical literature. Their finding of overwhelming support in favor of

    the view that rebellion is motivated by greed or opportunity, led to a vigorous debate and an

    impressive empirical literature, that generally accepted the dominance of “greed,” but became

    rather more nuanced (Blatmann and Miguel 2010).

    Researchers started to accept the general framework, but to examine other potential

    determinants that had not already been considered. Nowhere is this move beyond greed and

    grievance more evident than in quantitative studies of conflict prevalence in sub-Saharan

    Africa—where the imposition of artificial state borders, living in “bad neighborhoods” and

    warmer temperatures (increasingly so, in the face of climate change) have come to take central

    focus as explanatory variables of interest in the econometric models employed in these studies

    (Hendrix and Glaser 2007; Burke et al. 2009; Greene 2010).

    A number of developments have led to a point where there is some value to be gained

    from revisiting the debate. First, there are obviously more years of data available, more

    economic shocks, and more conflicts. This provides both more degrees of freedom and

    potentially more leverage for empirical analyses. Second, there have been significant

    improvements in the operationalization of difficult-to-measure indicators of grievance (i.e.,

    income inequality, ethnic divisions). Third there has been some development in the estimation

    methods available for the analysis. In particular, is the recognition that simple probit, or logit

    model, does not perform well in situations where there are a large number of zeroes in the

  • 3

    dependent variable, a likely case for civil conflict since fortunately many country-year

    observations are zero (e.g., peace) (Dunne and Tian 2014).

    Another important issue is the general consensus that, while conflict is detrimental to

    economic development, its impact could be even greater for fragile states (Rodrik 1999).

    Fragile states are weak and failing with severe handicaps in economic development and

    institutional governance, and a conflict can be particularly devastating to these states and their

    neighbors (Dunne and Tian 2014). This combination of fragility and civil conflict is a particular

    concern for Africa, and this paper revisits the greed–grievance debate and fragile states, using

    a database of 33 African countries for the period 1960 to 2013.

    A review of the determinants of civil war literature and the greed–grievance debate,

    together with a review and definition of fragile states, is provided in the next section. Following

    is a discussion and outline of the estimation procedures to be used—in particular, the zero-

    inflated Probit (ZiOP) model. Section 4 then presents the data used and variable construction

    and provides some descriptive statistics, followed by the empirical estimates of a greed–

    grievance model, using the usual methods and the ZiOP model, with various robustness checks.

    The final section offers some conclusions, with discussion on the policy implications.

    2 Causes of Civil Conflict

    There are a range of theoretical perspectives that inform the analysis of civil wars, reflecting

    the interdisciplinary nature of the research and the relatively late involvement of economists.

    Political scientists focused upon the “grievance” determinants of conflicts, with theories

    emphasizing how modernization could lead to disruption of social order, with social and

    economic change causing the breakdown of social cohesion and alteration of perceptions. This

    can lead to disadvantaged groups feeling threatened, identifying with ethnic or social groups

    and mobilizing for change. It can also ignite of old hatreds, and in times of change and crisis,

    successful ethnic entrepreneurial networks, despite their importance for economic growth, can

    become a source of resentment. A formalization of this perspective was provided by political

    rational choice theories. These focused on the role of political repression, failing institutions,

    transitions, and informational problems, which together with a failure to redress grievances—

    economic or political—can lead to conflict. An alternative was provided by constructivist

    theories, which focus on the social construction of identity, rather than accepting it as some

    fixed attribute. It is then political mobilization that leads to civil violence, with leaders

    constructing ethnic and social identity in ways that benefit themselves (Sambanis 2002).

  • 4

    In contrast, the focus of economists was the greed-based determinants of conflict.

    Grossman (1991) modeled rebellion as an industry, where insurgents gain profits from looting

    and have costs. In this model, insurgents are no different to bandits, and the incidence of

    rebellion is fully explained by atypical circumstances that generate profitable opportunities. In

    a different line, Hirschleifer (1995) asked why fighting occurred between rational agents, given

    it was a Pareto suboptimal situation. A model with preferences, opportunities, and perceptions

    suggested it was possible that opportunities and grievances were wrongly perceived because

    of asymmetric information. Agents overestimate capability and their probability of winning,

    and grievances are based on limited or inaccurate information and/or divergent preferences.

    While economists generally assume property rights are exogenous, a limited body of

    theoretical work has focused on endogenous property rights and economic theories of

    appropriation. Rational agents exist in a lawless setting with competition for resources, and

    predation and defense are alternatives to directly productive activities. Without well-defined

    property rights, contracts cannot be enforced, except by a ruler or hegemon, and they can be

    replaced forcibly. In the contest model, an incumbent and a rebel group allocate resources to

    production or appropriation through a production function, while a contest success function

    determines the probability of success, based on the proportion of arms and the effectiveness of

    technology in an environment of informational asymmetry. The problem with this model is

    that it always gives a fighting outcome (Skaperdas 2001; Dunne and Coulomb 2008).

    These economic theory perspectives suggest that the onset of civil conflict is linked to

    the ability of insurgents to make a profit—the greed hypothesis—rather than the result of

    grievances. Collier and Hoeffler (2004) provided an empirical analysis of the competing

    hypotheses, suggesting that while political grievances are universal, economic incentives are

    not, and so are often decisive in the start of conflict. They use a Hirschleifer-type framework

    (1995), where rebellion is the outcome of rational decision-making, subject to constraints of

    the rebel labor market. The probability of rebel victory depends on the ability of the incumbent

    to defend, which is determined by technology (and although the technology is also available to

    the rebels, it is limited) and military spending, to which the rebels do not have access. So the

    taxable base can be used as a measure of how strong the government is, but it also measures

    the potential gains that rebels can make if they achieve victory. Population is then used as a

    proxy for the rebels’ desire for secession, while per capita income and the duration of the

    conflict serve as proxies for the costs of rebellion, both opportunity costs and economic

    disruption costs. Measures of fractionalization are used as proxy for the costs of coordination,

  • 5

    and the transaction and coordination costs to a rebellion are approximated by ethnic

    fractionalization. Expected utility is then a function of the probability of victory, the size of the

    taxable base of the country, and GDP per capita. The expected gain from the rebellion is an

    increasing function of the size of population, and the probability of conflict will be expected to

    decrease with GDP per capita and expected duration.

    Rebel groups have the potential to finance an insurrection if they can extort natural

    resources, get donations from diaspora, and get support from hostile foreign governments. The

    ratio of primary commodity exports to GDP natural resources in exports, the proportion of the

    population that moved to the United States, and the indicator variable for Cold War all are

    viewed as proxies for these funding sources. Insurrection is considered more likely if

    individuals’ foregone income is low, which will mean the cost of recruits will be low, and this

    will be determined by economic growth and its impact on labor demand, income levels, and

    levels of schooling. It will also be encouraged if the cost of military equipment is low, and this

    is likely to be reflected in the time since the previous conflict, as the shorter it is, the more

    likely weapons will be readily available. Success is more likely if there is weak government

    military capability, and this will be determined by the nature of the terrain—mountainous areas

    assist guerrillas—and the distribution of the population, because if it is spread out thinly, it will

    be harder to police. It is also likely that low social cohesion will make it easier for the rebels,

    which can be approximated by measures of ethnic fractionalization. For objective grievances,

    measures of polarization are used—namely, ethnic and religious differences. The Polity III

    data set and political exclusion is used to approximate political repression, with the Gini

    coeffient acting as a proxy for a measure of ethnic dominance and economic inequality. The

    theorists argue greed and misperceived grievance have important similarities. Opportunity and

    viability provide common conditions for both profit and nonprofit rebel organizations, but the

    groups are observationally equivalent, making it impossible to discern the underlying drive of

    the organization.

    Using five-year averages as data points, researchers estimate separate models for

    opportunity and grievance, finding opportunity is the one that seems to works best. They then

    combine the two models, finding that the probability of conflict is mainly determined by slow

    growth, and the importance of natural resources, which also increases the probability, as well

    as foregone income, measured by secondary school attainment, which also reduces the

    probability as the attainment is increased. The proxies for ethnic fractionalization, inequality

    and democracy, are all insignificant, leading the theorists to conclude that the “greed” factors

  • 6

    dominate the “grievance,” ones. Factors that influence opportunity, finance, cost of rebellion,

    and military advantage are significant in determining civil war, while most proxies of grievance

    are insignificant, though population has an effect and time seems to heal. The finding that

    opportunity explains conflict risk is supportive of the economic interpretation of rebellion as

    motivated by greed (Collier and Hoeffler 2004; 2007).

    Around the same time, Fearon and Laitin (2003) developed a slightly different model,

    a one-shot, reduced-form game of insurgency, where the size of a rebellion is influenced by

    government effort and the scale of the initial rebellion. They also found that political grievance

    had little explanatory power, but that state institutional capacity was significant—suggesting

    that wars are caused by countries having weak institutions. They differed with Collier and

    Hoeffler (2004) in interpreting GDP per capita as reflecting state capacity, rather than as an

    opportunity cost. They also differed in how they coded civil wars and used annual data, rather

    than five-year averages. The two papers had major impacts on research and debate and led to

    a large literature that has advanced understanding, telling us what we do not know, as well as

    what we do. Clearly, it is not enough to assume grievance drive conflicts, and “greed” or

    economic factors have to be considered (Blattman and Miguel 2010).

    While the general cross-country consensus in the literature developed that motivations

    of greed outweigh those of grievance in explaining civil war onset, the literature continued to

    develop and improve in a number of areas. First, political scientists have questioned the

    apparent lack of significance of variables that are proxies for objective grievance. In a recent

    contribution by Buhaug, Cederman, and Gleditsch (2014), the authors argued that the lack of

    significance had to do with the poor proxy variables used in previous research and showed that

    better proxies indicate that grievances do matter. This has led to efforts being made to improve

    measurement and obtain better proxies, with natural resource data being improved for

    resources and better measurement of grievance, better measurement of inequality to include

    horizontal and vertical inequality, and better measures of weak institutions (Lujala, Gleditsch,

    and Gilmore 2005; Wucherpfennig et al. 2011).

    Second, some attempts have been made at improving causal identification. The

    potential endogeneity of GDP to conflict led to the use of rainfall as an instrument, given that

    it will impact on agrarian economies but not on conflict. Other attempts have used price shocks

    and trade shocks in a similar manner. The identification problems remains an issue, mostly due

  • 7

    to difficulties in finding appropriate instruments (Blattman and Miguel 2010; Miguel,

    Satyanath, and Sergenti 2004).

    Third, some attempts have been made to consider possible spillover effects of conflicts,

    creating conflicts in other countries, with the feedback of refugees keeping conflicts going

    (Salehyan and Gleditsch 2006; Dunne and Tian 2014).

    Fourth, questions have been raised about measures of conflict and violence. In the past,

    war tended to be determined as an event in which there were more than 1,000 battle-related

    deaths, with peace defined as less than this. Initially, this was developed for inter-country

    conflicts and continued in use, even after the focus shifted to civil conflicts in the post-Cold

    War world. This was seen, then, as unsuitable, and a definition of conflict, of when there were

    more than 25 battle-related deaths, was applied. A further development saw Besley and Persson

    (2010, 2014) create a nonbinary ordinal measure of civil violence, with 0 as the value for peace,

    1 for civil repression, based on Banks (2005), and 2 for large-scale civil conflict with more

    than 1,000 battle deaths.2

    Fifth, there has been some concern over the estimation methods used. These have

    generally used a zero–one dependent variable for conflict, but this leads to a lot of zeros (peace

    years), and they are likely to be from different data generation processes. There is a difference

    in interpretation between a a country that is in and out of war and a country that is generally at

    peace, so a 0 value in a particular year for Botswana is rather different to that for the DRC

    (Bagozzi et al. 2015).

    In this study, the focus is, first, on analyzing the determinants of conflict onset in Africa

    by applying a comprehensive “greed–grievance” model to more up-to-date data and using

    better proxies that have been developed over time. Second is to consider the measurement of

    conflict onset and use the wider definition mentioned here, together with relevant econometric

    methods.

    3 Data

    To operationalize a general–greed grievance empirical model, a range of variables were

    collected following developments in the literature. Proxies for greed or opportunity include

    real GDP, growth in GDP per capita, degree of urbanization, life expectancy, and natural

    2 New datasets are allowing more consistent and detailed information to be used, such as the data set of global

    instances of political violence (http://ucdp.uu.se/ged/).

    http://ucdp.uu.se/ged/

  • 8

    resource dependence. For this study, two sets of income variables were collected from the

    World Bank and Penn World Tables 8.0. Degree of urbanization is measured as the proportion

    of a country's population living in an urban environment, while life expectancy follows the

    usual measurement.3 Male secondary school enrollment was not used in the estimations due

    to poor and incomplete data. Following from the literature, natural resource dependence is

    measured by the share of primary commodity exports in GDP. The World Bank provides data

    for the period 1960 to 1999, which was cross-referenced with Fearon (2005) for consistency.

    The remaining 14 years are constructed, using export data (primary commodities) provided by

    the World Trade Organization (WTO), and GDP, from the World Bank.

    Given the ongoing debates on the measure of natural resource dependence and the type

    of commodities used, three additional measurements are considered. A measure of oil

    production in metric tons and oil exports greater than one-third of total exports are used as

    proxy for oil abundance and dependence, respectively. 4 To distinguish fuel and nonfuel

    minerals from other primary commodities, a mineral dependence variable was created. A

    country is considered mineral dependent, if its mineral exports constitute 25 percent or more

    of a country's total tangible exports. Percentage of mountainous terrain in a given country is

    included, as an indicator of military accessibility or safe havens for rebels.

    The grievance variables are, for the most part, common to those identified by Collier

    and Hoeffler (2004) and Fearon and Laitin (2003). This paper considers three general measures

    of grievance: ethnic and religious hatred, political repression or freedom, and income inequality

    (horizontal inequality). Ethnic fractionalization is the most commonly chosen indicator to test

    the linkage between ethnicity and civil conflict.5 Measurements of ethnic fractionalization is

    taken from Collier and Hoeffler (2004), with ethnic dominance, which is measured as a binary

    variable, taking on the value of one if the largest ethnic group in a country amounts to 45–90

    percent of the population, and is used as alternative to ethnic hatred. To measure religious

    3 This data is sourced from the World Bank. The degree of urbanization can also be thought of as a measurement of

    geographic dispersion: the greater the urbanization, the lower the geographic dispersion. All income figures are adjusted

    for purchasing power parity (PPP). 4 Oil production data, in metric tons, are provided by Ross (2013), for the years, 1932 to 2011. The additional two years

    were drawn from the same source used by Ross,, the US Department of Energy website for international energy

    statistics:

    http://www.eia.gov/cfapps/ipdbproject/IEDindex3.cfm 5 Initially used by Easterly and Levine (1997), the fractionalization index follows in accordance with Herfindahl’s

    formula, and is interpreted as the probability that two randomly selected individuals in a population belong to different

    ethnic groups.

    http://www/

  • 9

    hatred, Collier and Hoeffler (2004) constructed a fractionalization index analogous to ethnic

    fractionalization, and this is, in turn, used in the estimation process.

    Other things being equal, political democracy or freedom should be associated with less

    discrimination, repression, and civil war. Data from the Polity IV database is used to measure

    political rights, with the variable polity ranging from –10 (high autocracy) to 10 (high

    democracy). The relationship between political freedom and civil war has often been thought

    of having a nonlinear effect (Hegre et al. 2001). This hypothesis is tested through the inclusion

    of a polity-squared term. In a recent paper by Buhaug, Cederman, and Gleditsch (2014), the

    authors found that new grievance indices of horizontal income inequality and political

    discrimination performed much better than conventional indicators. They argued that economic

    grievance is captured by the relative gap between the mean national income and the income

    level of the poorest and richest groups (positive and negative horizontal inequality), while

    ethnopolitical grievance is measured by the demographic size of the largest ethnic group

    discriminated against.6 This paper uses these alternative variables as substitutes in robustness

    checks for ethnopolitical and economic grievance.

    The control variables included in the model are the standard ones found in the literature

    (i.e., population and cold war). Finally, the dependent variable used here takes on a value of 0

    for all peace year observations and a value of 1 for minor conflict years with combat deaths

    ranging between 25–999, and 2 for full-scale civil wars with annual battle deaths above 1,000.

    Table 2 presents descriptive statistics of the aforementioned variables with a breakdown by

    conflict experience and always zeroes or always peaceful. These results seem to support the

    central thesis that the different zeroes in the sample are formed through completely separate

    processes. For the always zero or “complete peace” group, GDP per capita, per capita GDP

    growth, rate of urbanization, life expectancy, and political freedom are all higher than the “not

    always zero” group. Moreover, countries that are potentially completely peaceful have lower

    levels of ethnic and religious fractionalization and income inequality.7 Estimated correlations

    suggest some association between income and inequality variables and the likelihood of a

    country being completely peaceful versus incompletely peaceful. In episodes of civil conflict,

    6 For full description and derivation of the variables, see Buhaug, Cederman, and Gleditsch (2014). 7 LDG = largest discriminated (against) ethnic group, PHI = positive horizontal inequality (relative gap between mean national income and income level of the richest group), NHI = negative horizontal inequality (relative gap between

    mean national income and income level of the poorest group)

  • 10

    GDP per capita, GDP growth, rate of urbanization, life expectancy, and political freedom are

    all lower compared to times of peace. Similarly, ethnic divisions, income inequality, and

    substantial amounts of rough terrain are higher in cases of civil war. Interestingly, primary

    commodity exports as a share of GDP is on average lower in episodes of civil war compared

    to no civil war.

    Table 1. Descriptive Statistics—Means

    Full

    Sample

    Always

    0

    Not

    Always 0

    Civil War

    No

    Civil War

    Opportunity

    Primary commodity 0.156 0.178 0.139 0.109 0.164

    exports/GDP

    GDP per capita 7931 14069 3311 3172 8699

    GDP per capita growth 0.018 0.022 0.016 0.010 0.019

    Mountains 16.38 14.93 18.11 23.16 15.33

    Rate of urbanization 46.94 56.00 39.73 40.61 47.92

    Life expectancy 61.61 66.15 57.98 59.41 61.95

    Oil production 17000 13700 19300 19100 16700

    (metric tons 000’s)

    Mineral dependence 0.493 0.415 0.545 0.550 0.484

    Oil exports 0.187 0.155 0.208 0.168 0.189

    Grievance

    Ethnic frac (C&H) 63.02 52.06 69.85 77.47 60.05

    Ethnic dominance 0.470 0.483 0.467 0.549 0.457

    Religious frac (0–100) 36.47 36.07 36.58 0.36 0.37

    Polity IV (–10 to 10) 1.13 3.84 -0.73 0.97 1.30

    LDG 0.056 0.024 0.081 0.142 0.042

    NHI 1.189 1.064 1.278 1.398 1.155

    PHI 1.201 1.086 1.287 1.224 1.197

    4 Greed vs. Grievance Revisited

    Estimating the probability of civil conflict using an ordered probit gave the results in Table 2.

    The civil conflict dependent variable takes the value of 1 if deaths total over 25 in a given

    battle, 2 if there are over 1,000 battle deaths in a given year, and 0 otherwise.

  • 11

    Table 2. Ordered Probit of Civil War Prevalence 1960–2013

    (1) (2) (3)

    Probit Probit Probit

    Outcome Outcome Outcome

    Opportunity

    Pri exports/ GDP -5.329** -5.601** -4.091**

    (0.966) (0.978) (0.963)

    Pri exports/ GDP2 7.801** 9.045** 5.908**

    (1.585) (1.595) (1.597)

    log real GDP -0.024 -0.137** -0.202**

    (0.052) (0.052) (0.050)

    RGDPPC growth -2.496** -2.455** -2.492**

    (0.523) (0.520) (0.527)

    log mountains 0.054* 0.118** 0.062*

    (0.028) (0.030) (0.028)

    Grievance

    Polity Index -0.015 -0.018 0.001

    (0.032) (0.032) (0.031)

    Polity Index2 0.001 0.003 -0.005

    (0.005) (0.005) (0.004)

    Ethno frac (F&L) 6.022**

    (0.998)

    Ethno frac2 (F&L -5.529**

    (0.934)

    Ethno frac (C&H) 0.011

    (0.008)

    Ethno frac2 (C&H) -0.001

    (0.001)

    Ethnic dominance 0.210* 0.292*

    (0.086) (0.119)

    Continued on next page

  • 12

    Table 2. continued

    (1) (2) (3)

    Probit Probit Probit

    Outcome Outcome Outcome

    Religious frac 0.967** 0.218

    (0.301) (0.275)

    LDG 1.264**

    (0.168)

    PHI -01.72*

    (0.078)

    NHI 0.859**

    (0.125)

    Control

    Log population 0.340** 0.413** 0.514**

    (0.066) (0.068) (0.679)

    Cold War -0.024 -0.008 -0.043**

    (0.097) (0.096) (0.104)

    Observations 1,519 1,519 1,542

    Log likelihood -941.824 -944.336 -901.834

    AIC 1913.65 1918.67 1835.67

    Notes: Dependent variable: Conflict prevalence; AIC = Akaike Information Criterion; Standard errors in

    parentheses; Significance levels: ** p < 0.01,* p < 0.05, t p < 0.1; LDG = largest discriminated (against)

    ethnic group, PHI = positive horizontal inequality (relative gap between mean national income and income

    level of the richest group), NHI = negative horizontal inequality (relative gap between mean national income

    and income level of the poorest group) .

    The results (columns 1–3) provide the standard ordered Probit model with a number of

    alternative specifications considered. These additional estimates replace ethnolinguistic

    fractionalization used by Fearon and Laitin (2003) with that from Collier and Hoeffler (2004)

    (specification 2) and introduce a new ethnic discrimination measure and income inequality

    (specification 3). The results reveal that in the case of the normal ordered Probit, irrespective

    of the specification, primary commodity exports, as a share of GDP, have a nonlinear

    relationship on civil conflict incidence, first decreasing and then increasing. This is a finding

    that is opposite to that found in the existing literature, however, and in light of the summary

    statistics in Table 2, where primary commodity exports, as a share of GDP, are lower for

  • 13

    countries not in civil conflict, the result makes some empirical sense. GDP and per capita GDP

    growth are significant in decreasing the probability of civil war, while presence of mountainous

    terrain seems to increase civil war risk through the proxy of geographic dispersion, which

    inhibits government or military capacity.

    As for grievance variables, the results from the three specifications offer a similar

    conclusion: first, political freedom or opportunity does not matter—the coefficient and its

    square term are insignificant in determining chances of civil war. Second, ethnicity matters,

    conditional on the choice of the ethnic fractionalization variable. The coefficient that is a proxy

    for ethnic grievance, which measures a systematic inequality in ethnopolitical opportunities, is

    positive and statistically significant, with its square term negative and significant when the

    Fearon and Laitin (2003) variable (1) is used, but is insignificant on the Collier and Hoeffler

    (2004) variable (2). As expected, ethnic dominance increases civil war risk, while religious

    fractionalization has a mixed effect.

    Given the differing results on ethnolinguistic fractionalization between specification 1

    and 2, specification 3 looks for an alternative measure and also includes horizontal income

    inequality. The variable LGD, which is a proxy for ethnic and political inequality, is positive

    and highly significant.8 Additionally, of the horizontal measures of economic inequality, the

    relative gap between the country-level GDP per capita and the mean per capita income for the

    poorest ethnic group in a given country, NHI, is positive and statistically significant at the 10

    percent level, suggesting that African countries with one or more ethnic group(s) radically

    poorer than the national average have a higher risk of conflict onset. The opposite, however, is

    also true for the relative gap between the per capita GDP mean and that of the richest group,

    PHI, which is negative and significant. Here, income inequality has less meaning to the richest

    group, and there is an incentive to keep peace and retain wealth rather than to rebel. As for the

    control variables, population has a positive and significant effect on an African countries’ civil

    war prevalence, while the Cold War dummy is only negative and significant for the last

    specification.

    In most analyses on the determinants of civil conflict, an ordered dependent variable is

    used, in which a given country-year is assigned a value of 0 for peace and a value of 1 when

    violence between the state and another side reaches a given threshold, thereby classifying it as

    8 For full explanation of the largest discriminated (against) ethnic growth (LGD), see Buhaug, Cederman, and Gleditsch (2014).

  • 14

    a civil war. This would generally mean that there are a large number of zero observations, since

    peaceful years will dominate conflict years. These zeros can be considered as reflecting rather

    different states, one where the structural and societal forces ensure a zero probability of civil

    conflict regardless of greed or grievance incentives and another that reflects a break in fighting

    and a high probability of returning to conflict.

    The first group of zeros will often be non-fragile states, such as South Africa or

    Botswana, and can be labeled “complete-peace” while the second group are often found in

    fragile regions such as Central, West, or East Africa, from which the zeroes can be labeled as

    “incomplete-peace.” The main difference between the first and second case of zero is that while

    the probability of transition into war for first type is zero, the probability for the

    “incomplete-peace” group is not. In the case of “incomplete-peace,” incentives resulting from

    opportunity or grievance can induce violent conflict. Given the high proportion of

    heterogeneous zeroes in the analysis, using ordinary probit or logit models may not be

    appropriate tools for statistical inference and can potentially give biased estimates (Bagozzi et

    al. 2015).

    A more satisfactory estimation method is the split population or two-part model

    proposed by Harris and Zhao (2007) and Vance and Ritter (2014). This is typically in the form

    of zero-inflated models, or in this case, a zero-inflated Probit model, where estimations follow

    two stages. The first of the two latent equations, stage one, is a selection equation, while the

    second stage is a Probit outcome equation. This splits the observations into two processes, each

    potentially having different sets of explanatory variables. In the context of civil war prevalence,

    zero observations in process 0 (wi = 0) include inflated zeroes, consistent with countries that

    never experience civil conflict (e.g., Sweden), while zero observations in process 1 (wi = 1)

    includes cases for which the probability of transitioning into a civil conflict is not zero, and

    civil war casualties have not reached the lower bound (or limit) of 1,000 battle-related deaths.

    The binary variable w indicates the split between process 0 (with wi = 0 for no war) and process

    1 (with wi = 1 for war). The variable w is related to the latent dependent variable 𝑤𝑖∗ so that wi

    = 1 for 𝑤𝑖∗ > 0 and wi = 0 for 𝑤𝑖

    ∗ 0, where 𝑤𝑖∗ now represents the propensity to enter process

    1 and is given by the split probit (1st stage) equation:

    𝑤𝑖∗ = 𝑥𝑖𝛾 + 𝜇𝑖 (1)

  • 15

    where 𝑥𝑖 is a vector of covariates, 𝛾 is its coefficients and 𝜇𝑖 is the error term. The

    probability of 𝑖 falling into process 1 is Pr(𝑤𝑖 = 1|𝑥𝑖) = Pr(𝑤𝑖∗ > 0|𝑥𝑖) = Ψ(𝑥𝑖𝑔), and the

    probability that it is in process 0 is Pr(𝑤𝑖 = 0|𝑥𝑖) = Pr(𝑤𝑖∗ ≤ 0|𝑥𝑖) = 1 − Ψ(𝑥𝑖𝛾), where (.)

    is the standard normal cumulative distribution function. For the Probit outcome equation, the

    propensity for participation in which the response variable 𝑌𝑖 (i.e, conflict) has a distribution

    given by:

    Pr(𝑌𝑖 = 𝑦𝑖) = {𝑤𝑖 + (1 − 𝑤𝑖)

    𝑒(−𝜆𝑖) , 𝑦𝑖 = 0

    (1 − 𝑤𝑖)𝑒(−𝜆𝑖) 𝜆𝑖

    𝑦𝑖

    𝑦!𝑖 , 𝑦𝑖 > 0

    (2)

    where the parameters 𝜆𝑖 and 𝑤𝑖 depend on vectors of covariates 𝑥𝑖 and zi,, respectively, which

    are modeled as:

    log(𝜆𝑖) = 𝑥𝑖𝑡𝛽 (3)

    and

    log (𝑤𝑖

    1−𝑤𝑖) = 𝑧𝑖

    𝑡𝛾 (4)

    with mean and variance as E(𝑌𝑖 ) = (1 − 𝑤𝑖)i and 𝑣𝑎𝑟(𝑌𝑖) = 𝜇 + (𝑤𝑖

    1−𝑤𝑖) 𝜇2.

    In this ZIP model, the matrices z and x contain different sets of experimental factor and

    covariate effects that relate to the probability of the “zero- state” (zero probability of civil war)

    and the Poisson mean in the “nonzero- state” (probable civil war), respectively. Thus, the ’s

    have interpretations in terms of the factor level effect on the probability that there is a zero

    probability of conflict and the /3’s have the interpretation of the effect on the average risk of

    civil war when the probability is non-zero. Following Lambert (1992), the ZIP model (Equation

    2) can be regressed using maximum likelihood with an Expectation-maximum (EM)

    algorithm.9

    The use of ZioP model allows more accurate estimates to be obtained, compared to

    standard probit or logit models. The probability of a zero observation is now modeled

    9 For full derivation of the model, see Lambert (1992) and Hall (2000).

  • 16

    conditionally on the probability of zero from the Probit process plus the probability of being in

    process 0 from the splitting equation. It should be noted that the usefulness of the model (i.e.,

    unbiased estimates) declines when the size of the split in the sample population becomes very

    big or very small, leading to biased results.10 Bagozzi et al. (2015) suggested that this becomes

    an issue when there is less than 10 percent or greater than 90 percent of zero observations.

    Estimating the general greed grievance models using the zero-inflated ordered probit

    model give the results in Table 3. The specification for the inflation equation is limited to GDP,

    per capita GDP growth, political freedom (Polity) and ethnic divisions (Eth Frac), as such

    factors promote a compatibility of interests between the state and its citizens, which in turn

    influences the probability that a country is in the always zero group and always experiences

    peace. That said, to ensure that the zero-inflated ordered probit (ZiOP) estimates in Table 3,

    specification 1, are not driven by choice of variables, a model in which all the covariates in the

    outcome equation are included in the inflation equation is also estimated (Table 3, specification

    2).

    10 Statistical inference becomes increasingly difficult as the proportional of zeroes gets close to one.

  • 17

    Table 3. Probit and ZIP Regression of Civil War Prevalence 1960–2013

    (1) (2)

    ZiOP ZiOP

    Outcome Inflation Outcome Inflation

    Opportunity

    log RGDP -0.238** -0.290* -0.242* -0.480**

    (0.064) (0.152) (0.096) (0.147)

    RGDPPC growth -2.537** -1.507 0.783* -2.144t

    (0.550) (1.299) (0.803) (1.243)

    Pri exports/GDP -9.079** -12.171** 13.882**

    (1.122) (1.473) (2.535)

    Pri exports/ GDP2 11.316** 16.374** -20.059**

    (1.709) (2.604) (3.504)

    log 3 mountains 0.044 0.247** 0.781**

    (0.030) (0.628) (0.083)

    Grievance

    Polity Index -0.039** 0.317** -0.074** 0.336**

    (0.010) (0.108) (0.012) (0.110)

    Polity Index2 -0.015** -0.028* -0.022** -0.285*

    (0.002) (0.014) (0.003) (0.012)

    Eth frac (F&L) 7.097** 2 .784** 5.463** -13.739**

    (1.188) (0.673) (2.006) (3.048)

    Continued on next page

  • 18

    Table 3 - Continued from previous page

    (1) (2)

    ZiOP ZiOP

    Outcome Inflation Outcome Inflation

    Eth frac2 (F&L) -6.143** -6.934** 18.619**

    (1.069) ( 1.599) (3.248)

    Ethnic dominance 0.417** -2.106** 0.576** -0.332

    (0.096) (0.467) (0.119) (0.269)

    Religious frac 0.488 0.734t 0.669

    (0.328) (0.439) (0.786)

    Controls

    log Population 0.112** 1.818** -0.042 1.544**

    (0.032) (0.243) (0.104) (0.283)

    Cold War 0.008 0.464*

    (0.102) (0.212)

    Constant -6.312** -21.890** -2.435t -17.699**

    (0.977) (3.004) (1.364) (3.228)

    Observations ≈ 1,519 1,519

    Log likelihood -859.48 -820.04

    AIC 1768.95 1696.08

    Notes: AIC = Akaike Information Criterion; Dependent variable: Conflict prevalence; Standard

    errors in parentheses; Significance levels: ** p < 0.01,* p < 0.05, tp < 0 .1

    Estimating the probability of civil conflict, the zero-inflated ordered probit model in

    Table 3 can be directly compared to the ordered probit model in Table 2, specification 1. To

    start with, the coefficients reported in the first stage, inflation equation, of the ZiOP model

    reveal that GDP per capita has a negative and significant effect on the likelihood of a country-

    year not being among the always-zero or peace group and then experiencing any level of civil

    violence. Additionally, political freedom seems to have the usual nonlinear effect of increasing

    the likelihood of civil conflict and then decreasing it past a certain point. Ethnicity also plays

    an important role in the different observed zeroes; here the more ethnically diverse a county's

    population is, the more likely it is to experience any form of violence, while a country with one

    ethnic dominant group has the opposite effect in decreasing chances of a civil conflict.

  • 19

    Turning towards the outcome equation, the estimates here are conditioned only for

    countries that are able to experience a civil conflict. In other words, the estimates are for

    country-years that are not in the “always peaceful” group. As mentioned previously, the key

    feature of this group is that there are societal forces that make the probability of transitioning

    into violence non-zero. These would essentially be African fragile states. By distinguishing

    between the different types of zeroes, or types of countries, the ZiOP provides some new

    insights on the greed–grievance estimates. While the ZiOP model (1) gives signs that are

    consistent with the standard ordered probit, there are substantial differences in the significance

    of the grievance terms. Primary commodity exports as a proportion of GDP show the same

    effect as before, albeit at a higher turning point of 40 percent. Income, both its level and its

    growth, decreases the likelihood that a country experiences civil conflict, conditional on that

    country being able to experience a conflict. Or in other words, a condition on it being a fragile

    state.

    Proxies for ethnopolitical grievance are better represented using the zero-inflated

    models than the ordered probit, with political freedom now a significant predictor of civil war

    prevalence. This effect, however, is not of the usual inverse u-shape of first increasing and then

    decreasing, but rather decreases throughout. This is a very interesting finding and suggests that

    for the fragile states any kind of improvement in political freedom (less political oppression)

    will substantially lower the likelihood of any form of civil violence, with the impact

    diminishing as political grievance decreases. Ethnolinguistic fractionalization remains

    significant and of the correct sign, first increasing the risk and then decreasing when the

    probability of randomly selecting 2 individuals from different ethnic group reaches 57 percent.

    In addition to having more explanatory power and significance in the grievance variables, the

    zero-inflated ordered probit estimates are shown to have lower standard errors than the normal

    probit. An Akaike Information Criterion (AIC) test is run for both the probit and ZiOP, with

    the lower AIC value from the ZiOP suggesting that the zero-inflated models fits the data better

    than the probit. As suggested in Cameron and Trevidi (2010), all regressions are estimated

    using robust standard errors, while the proportion of zero observations in the sample (76.3

    percent) falls within the accepted band of 10 to 90 percent (Bagozzi et al. 2015).

    Specification 2 represents the full model with all the covariates of the outcome equation

    also in the inflation equation. Here a comparison between (1) and the full model (2) is also a

    test for researcher’s degrees of freedom, whereby a researcher could selectively choose

    specifications in order to generate significant results or false positives Simmons, Nelson, and

  • 20

    Simonsohn (2011). The similar results in (1) and (2) suggest the model is well specified,

    consistent to various specifications and not sensitive to researcher's degrees of freedom.

    To consider the robustness of the results, a number of alternative specifications (Table

    2, specifications 2 and 3) are reestimated using the zero-inflated probit model. Table 4 in the

    Appendix is one example, with horizontal income inequality and ethnic discrimination added

    in place of ethnic dominance and religious fractionalization and Fearon and Laitin’s (2003)

    ethnic fractionalization measure is replaced with Collier and Hoeffler’s (2004). These results

    remain consistent with the estimates in Table 3, where the zero-inflated ordered probit model

    is preferred to the ordered probit model in almost all instances.

    Other variants of the zero-inflated ordered probit were estimated replacing primary

    commodity exports with either mineral dependence, oil production, or oil export; replacing the

    polity index with the freedom house measure, democracy, and autocracy dummies; substituting

    income variables with urbanization rate and life expectancy. The results are shown to be

    relatively robust, with primary commodity dependence increasing civil war risk, democracy

    political freedom, and higher urbanization decreasing civil war risk.

    5 Conclusion

    This paper has revisited the greed-grievance debate within the context of fragility, using a data

    set of 33 African countries for the period 1960 to 2013. This seemed justified for a number of

    reasons: the existence of more years of data including more economic shocks and more

    conflicts, the significant improvements in the operationalization of difficult-to-measure

    indicators of grievance (i.e., income inequality, ethnic divisions), and the development of new

    estimation methods that seem well suited to the subject. It is also important to undertake such

    an analysis within the context of fragile states, as conflict is likely to be even more detrimental

    to their economic development. Thus, it is even more important to understand the drivers of

    conflict onset.

    Empirical estimations using a standard order Probit estimation technique do not account

    for the heterogeneous zeroes, and a zero-inflated model is also used, which distinguishes

    between observations that come from countries with a low probability of conflict and others.

    In essence, this is distinguishing between an important factor in determining fragile and non-

    fragile states.

    The main results are: first, unlike much of the earlier literature, civil war risk is not

    wholly dominated by greed, with grievance terms significant. Second, the zero-inflated ordered

  • 21

    probit models seem to perform better than the standard probit models and be better able to

    statistically account for observable and latent factors that produce different types of peace

    observations. The results suggest that using the ordinary probit, has biased the estimates, giving

    greater weighting to opportunity variables over grievance variables. This led to most empirical

    work finding opportunity or income variables as the main determinant of civil conflict. As one

    takes a deeper look at what type of country is mostly associated with the always zero or

    “complete peace” group, the answer is often high-income countries. By not distinguishing the

    different zeroes, the normal probit gave a likelihood of war calculation that included countries

    conditioned to not experience such an event. These countries’ main attribute is high income,

    and thus income variables were estimated with greater emphasis and significance, crowding

    out the grievance variable's explanatory power. By using a zero-inflated model and splitting

    the estimation process into two stages, greed and grievance variables are given equal emphasis,

    which makes it clear that both ethnopolitical and economic grievance matter, with substantial

    explanatory power in predicting civil war risk.

    Clearly, economic factors are important in determining conflict onset, but so are

    grievances, and this is clearer when the lower probability of higher income/peaceful countries

    is considered. In post-conflict situations, it is important to distinguish between fragile and non-

    fragile states and to carefully study the causes of the conflicts, both in terms of greed and

    grievance factors, and to deal with the underlying problems, rather than believing that general

    prescriptive policies will suffice (Brauer and Dunne 2012).

    References

    Bagozzi, B. E., D. W. Hill, W. H. Moore, and B. Mukherjee. 2015. “Modelling Two Types of

    Peace: The Zero-inflated Order Probit (ZiOP) Model in Conflict Research.” Journal of Conflict

    Resolution 59 (4): 728–52.

    Besley, T., and T. Persson, 2010. “State Capacity, Conflict and Development.” Econometrica

    78(1) :1–34.

    Besley, T., and T. Persson. 2014. “The Causes and Consequences of Development Clusters:

    State Capacity, Peace and Income.” Annual Review of Economics 6: 927–49.

    Blattman, C., and E. Miguel. 2010. “Civil War.” Journal of Economic Literature 48 (1): 3–57.

    Brauer , J., and J. P. Dunne. 2012. Peace Economics: A Macroeconomic Primer for Violence-

    Afflicted States. Washington, DC: US Institute of Peace.

    Buhaug, H., L.-E. Cederman, and K. S. Gleditsch. 2014. “Square Pegs in Round Holes:

    Inequalities, Grievances, and Civil War.” International Studies Quarterly 58 (2): 418–31.

  • 22

    Burke, M. B., E. Miguel, S. Satyanath, J. A. Dykema, and D. B. Lobell. 2009. “Warming

    Increases the Risk of Civil War in Africa.” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences

    (USA) 106 (49): 20670–4.

    Cameron, A. C., and P. K. Trivedi. 2010. Microeconometrics Using Stata. Rev Ed. College

    Station, TX: Stata Press.

    Collier, P., and A. Hoeffler. 2004. “Greed and Grievance in Civil War.” Oxford Economic

    Papers, 56 (4): 563–95.

    Collier, P., and A. Hoeffler. 2007. “Civil War.” In Handbook of Defense Economics, Vol. 2,

    edited by K. Hartley and T. Sandler, 711–39. Amsterdam: North Holland.

    Collier, P., V. L. Elliot, H. Hegre, A. Hoeffler, M. Reynal-Querol, and N. Sambanis. 2003.

    Breaking the Conflict Trap: Civil War and Development Policy. Washington, DC: The World

    Bank.

    Dunne, P., and F. Coulomb. 2008. “Peace, War and International Security: Economic

    Theories.” In War, Peace and Security, Vol. 6, edited by J. Fontanel and M. Chatterji, 13–36.

    Bingley, UK: Emerald.

    Dunne, J. P. and N. Tian. 2014. “Conflict Spillovers and Growth in Africa.” Peace Economics,

    Peace Science and Public Policy 20 (4). DOI: https://doi.org/10.1515/peps-2014-0038.

    Easterly, W. and Levine, P. 1997. “Africa’s Growth Tragedy: Policies and Ethnic Divisions”

    The Quarterly Journal of Economics 112 (4): 1203-1250.

    Fearon, J. D. 2005. “Primary Commodity Exports and Civil War.” Journal of Conflict

    Resolution 49 (4): 483–507.

    Fearon, J. D., and D. D. Laitin. 2003. “Ethnicity, Insurgency, and Civil War.” American

    Political Science Review 97 (1): 75–90.

    Fearon, J. D., K. Kasara, and D. D. Laitin. 2007. “Ethnic Minority Rule and Civil War Onset.”

    American Political Science Review 101 (1): 187– 93.

    Greene, W., 2010. “Testing hypotheses about interaction terms in nonlinear

    models.” Economics Letters, 107(2): 291-96.

    Grossman, H. I. 1991. “A General Equilibrium Model of Insurrections.” American Economic

    Review 81 (4): 912–21.

    Hall, D. B. 2000. “Zero-inflated Poisson and Binomial Regression with Random Effects: A

    Case Study.” Biometrics 56 (4): 1030–9.

    Harris, M. N., and X. Zhao. 2007. “A Zero-inflated Ordered Probit Model with an Application

    to Modelling Tobacco Consumption.” Journal of Econometrics 141 (2) :1073–99.

    Hegre, H., T. Ellingsen, S. Gates, and N. P. Gleditsch. 2001. “Toward a Democratic Civil

    Peace? Democracy, Political Change, and Civil War, 1816–1992. American Political Science

    Review 95(1): 33–48.

    Hendrix, C. S., and S. M. Glaser. 2007. “Trends and Triggers: Climate, Climate Change and

    Civil Conflict in Sub-Saharan Africa.” Political Geography. 26: 695–715.

    https://doi.org/10.1515/peps-2014-0038

  • 23

    Hirschleifer, J. 1995. “Theorizing about Conflict.” In Handbook of Defense Economics, Vol.

    1, edited by K. Hartley and T. Sandler, 165–89. Amsterdam: Elsevier.

    Lambert, D. 1992. Zero-Inflated Poisson Regression, with an Application to Defects in

    Manufacturing.” Technometrics 34 (1): 1–14.

    Lujala, P., N. P. Gleditsch, and E. Gilmore. 2005. “A Diamond Curse? Civil War and a

    Lootable Resource.” Journal of Conflict Resolution 49 (4): 538–62.

    Miguel, E., S. Satyanath, and E. Sergenti. 2004. “Economic Shocks and Civil Conflict: An

    Instrumental Variables Approach.” Journal of Political Economy 112 (4): 725–53.

    Rodrik, D. 1999. “Where did all the Growth go? External Shocks, Social Conflict and Growth

    Collapses.” Journal of Economic Growth 4(4): 382-412.

    Ross, M. L. 2013. “Oil and Gas Data, 1932–2011. Harvard Dataverse, v.2,

    DOI_1902.1_20369.xml

    Salehyan, I., and K. S. Gleditsch. 2006. “Refugees and the Spread of Civil War.” International

    Organization 60 (2): 335–66.

    Sambanis, N. 2002. “A Review of Recent Advances and Future Directions in the Quantitative

    Literature on Civil War.” Defence and Peace Economics 13 (3): 215–43.

    Simmons, J. P., L. D. Nelson, and U. Simonsohn. 2011. “False-positives Psychology:

    Undisclosed Flexibility in Data Collection and Analysis Allows Presenting Anything as

    Significant. Psychological Science 22 (11): 1359–66.

    Skaperdas, S. 2001. “An Economic Approach to Analyzing Civil Wars” In World Bank

    Conference on “Civil Wars and Post-war Transitions.” UC Irvine, 2001.

    Vance, C., and N. Ritter. 2014. “Is Peace a Missing Value or a Zero? On Selection Models in

    Political Science.” Journal of Peace Research 51 (4): 528–40.

    Wucherpfennig, J., N. B. Weidmann, L. Girardin, L.-E. Cederman, and A. Wimmer. 2011.

    “Politically Relevant Ethnic Groups across Space and Time: Introducing the GeoEPR Dataset.”

    Conflict Management and Peace Science 28 (5): 423–37.

  • 24

    Appendix

    Table 4. Additional Results of ZIP Model—Varying in Primary Commodity

    (1) (2) (3)

    ZIP ZIP ZIP

    Outcome Inflation Outcome Inflation Outcome Inflation

    Opportunity

    Min dependence 0.287*

    (0.075)

    Oil export 0.148

    (0.108)

    Oil production -0.042

    (0.140)

    Oil production2 0.002

    (0.005)

    log real GDP -0.092* -0.409** -0.070 0.416* -0.306** 0.249*

    (0.042) (0.064) (0.042) (0.061) (0.069) (0.114)

    RGDPPC Growth -2.079** -2.067 -2.342** -1.418 -3.080** -2.343

    log % Mountains

    (0.589)

    0.127**

    (1.837) (0.623)

    0.101**

    (1.198) (0.723)

    0.137**

    (1.809)

    (0.027) (0.026) (0.038)

    Grievance

    Polity Index 0.043** 0.078** 0.044** 0.073** 0.080** 0.318**

    (0.008) (0.021) (0.008) (0.019) (0.009) (0.062)

    Polity Index2 -0.004** -0.003** -0.004**

    (0.001) (0.001) (0.002)

    Eth frac (F&L) 5.265** 1.191** 5.367** 1.187** 5.254** 1.123

    (0.737) (0.384) (0.741) (0.374) (1.037) (0.656)

    Eth frac2 (F&L) -4.392** -4.288** -4.908**

    (0.672) (0.673) (1.007)

    LDG 0.436*

    -12.58** 0.374* -12.39** 1.169** -20.61**

    Continued on next page

  • 25

    Table 4. Continued

    (1) (2) (3)

    ZIP ZIP ZIP

    Outcome Inflation Outcome Inflation Outcome Inflation

    (0.191) (1.704) (0.192) (1.621) (0.288) (3.585)

    PHI -0.094 0.596** -0.103 0.589** -0.103 1.246**

    (0.091) (0.091) (0.098) (0.088) (0.105) (0.185)

    NHI 0.224* -0.710** 0.195** -0.774** 0.381** -0.261

    (0.072) (0.210) (0.072) (0.225) (0.097) (0.244)

    Controls

    log Population 0.126** -0.966** 0.104* -0.943** 0.233** -1.291**

    (0.049) (0.086) (0.048) (0.081) (0.097) (0.198)

    Cold War -0.117 -0.095 -0.225*

    (0.073) (0.075) (0.095)

    Africa 0.126 0.172 0.630**

    (0.096) (0.096) (0.143)

    Constant -2.768** 5.591** -2.788** 5.128** 0.389 13.058**

    (0.742) (1.091) (0.754) (1.000) ( 1.855) (2.997)

    Observations 4460 4460 2478

    Zero observations 3543 3543 1910

    Log likelihood -2335.26 -2341.71 -1308.27

    Vuong test 8.16 8.13 7.13

    Notes: Dependent variable: Conflict prevalence; Standard errors in parentheses; Significance

    levels: ** p < 0.01,* p < 0.05, t p

  • 26

    Table 5. Additional Results of ZIP Model: Varying in Income and Democracy

    (1) (2) (3)

    ZIP ZIP ZIP

    Outcome Inflation Outcome Inflation Outcome Inflation

    Opportunity

    log real GDP -0.066* 0.403**

    (0.032) (0.056)

    RGDPPC growth -2.262** 0.774

    (0.457) (0.822)

    Pri exports/ GDP -2.212** -1.838** -1.605*

    (0.667) (0.686) (0.739)

    Pri 1.958 1.618 1.522

    exports/GDP2

    (1.129) (1.147) (1.253)

    Urbanization rate -0.103* 1.217**

    (0.049) (0.242)

    Life expectancy -0.887** 1.861**

    (0.233) (0.575)

    .0.Life expectancy -7.353** 8.988

    log % Mountains

    0.048*

    (2.280)

    0.075**

    (6.213)

    0.079**

    (0.029) (0.024) (0.026)

    Grievance

    Polity Index 0.034** 0.277** 0.032** 0.102**

    (0.006) (0.058) (0.007) (0.028)

    Polity Index2 -0.006** -0.008**

    (0.001) (0.001)

    Democracy -0.420** 1.123**

    (0.099) (0.186)

    Eth frac (F&L) 5.702** 0.253 6.011** 1.116** 5.859** 1.346**

    Continued on next page

  • 27

    Table 5, Continued

    (1) (2) (3)

    ZIP ZIP ZIP

    Outcome Inflation Outcome Inflation Outcome Inflation

    Eth frac2

    (F&L)

    (0.658)

    -4.570**

    (0.472) (0.669)

    -4.710**

    (0.403) (0.733)

    -4.526**

    (0.372)

    LDG

    (0.593)

    1.134**

    -17.76**

    (0.603)

    0.767*

    -11.63**

    (0.674)

    0.476**

    -12.89**

    (0.139) (2.687) (0.187) (2.006) (0.181) (1.645)

    PHI -0.199* 1.153** -0.186* 0.717** -0.178* 0.575**

    (0.077) (0.167) (0.081) (0.089) (0.081) (0.075)

    NHI 0.185** -0.652* 0.207** -0.439t 0.203** -0.773**

    (0.064) (0.268) (0.074) (0.283) (0.072) (0.242)

    Controls

    log Population 0.093** -0.703** 0.031 -0.642** 0.072 -0.967**

    Cold War

    (0.294)

    -0.197**

    (0.085) (0.032)

    -0.239**

    (0.089) (0.046)

    -0.222**

    (0.077)

    (0.064) (0.072) (0.068)

    Africa 0.057 -0.066 0.200*

    (0.083) (0.088) (0.095)

    Constant -3.802** 4.673** 0.574 1.667 -2.647** 5.228**

    (0.549) (1.350) (1.048) (2.327) (0.701) (0.865)

    Observations 5083 4998 4446

    Zero observations 4018 3945 3528

    Log likelihood -2775.87 -2730.70 -2342.33

    Vuong test 9.47 7.97 8.46

    Notes: Standard errors in parentheses; significance levels: ** p < 0.01,* p < 0 .05, t p < 0.l; LDG = largest

    discriminated ethnic group, PHI = positive horizontal inequality (relative gap between mean national income

    and income level of the richest group), NHI = negative horizontal inequality (relative gap between mean

    national income and income level of the poorest group).