30
Competitive Equilibrium Robert A. Miller 712-010 Structural Econometrics November 2016 Miller (712-010 Structural Econometrics) Competitive Equilibrium November 2016 1 / 30

Competitive Equilibrium

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Competitive Equilibrium

Competitive Equilibrium

Robert A. Miller

712-010 Structural Econometrics

November 2016

Miller (712-010 Structural Econometrics) Competitive Equilibrium November 2016 1 / 30

Page 2: Competitive Equilibrium

Law of One PriceCompetitive equilibrium

Competitive equilibrium is the bedrock of economics:

Consumers reveal their preferences through their choices (three axiomssupporting consumer choice theory);Given the price of each commodity, consumers and producers buy orsell as many units as they wish (individual optimization);At those prices the market for each commodity clears, supply matchingdemand (existence of equilibrium);All potential gains from trade are realized, the economy achieving aPareto e¢ cient allocation (welfare theorems).

Assuming complete markets (Debreu, 1959 Chapter 7) is the dynamicanalogue to a static model of competitive equilibrium:

Commodities are indexed by time and the state of the world;States evolve over time according to a probability distribution.

Miller (712-010 Structural Econometrics) Competitive Equilibrium November 2016 2 / 30

Page 3: Competitive Equilibrium

Law of One PriceAuxiliary assumptions

Most econometric analysis also make several auxiliary assumptions.

1 The expected utility hypothesis holds.2 Subjective beliefs match probability transitions.3 Preferences are time additively separable up to a �nite vector ofhuman capital, habit persistence and nondurables.

4 Current utility payo¤s are su¢ ciently smooth that individual agentsonly require a small number of securities to achieve the equilibriumallocations of the complete markets.

Miller (712-010 Structural Econometrics) Competitive Equilibrium November 2016 3 / 30

Page 4: Competitive Equilibrium

Portfolio Choices in Competitive EquilibriumThe investor consumer optimization problem

Suppose there are J �nancial securities.Let ptj denote the price of the j th security in period t consumptionunits, and qt�1,j the amount a consumer investor owns at thebeginning of the period.Let rtj denote the real return on assets purchased in period t � 1.The investor�s budget constraint is:

ct +J

∑j=1ptjqtj �

J

∑j=1rtjpt�1,jqt�1,j

At t the consumer investor maximizes a concave objective functionwith linear constraints, choosing (qs1, ..., qsJ ) to maximize:

u (ct ) + Et

"T

∑s=t+1

βs�tu (cs )

#subject to the sequence of all the future budget constraints.

Miller (712-010 Structural Econometrics) Competitive Equilibrium November 2016 4 / 30

Page 5: Competitive Equilibrium

Portfolio Choices in Competitive EquilibriumFirst order conditions

Nonsatiation guarantees:

ct =J

∑j=1(rtjpt�1,jqt�1,j � ptjqtj )

The interior �rst order condition for each k 2 f1, . . . , Jg requires:

ptku0

J

∑j=1(rtjpt�1,jqt�1,j � ptjqtj )

!

� Et

"ptk rt+1,k βu0

J

∑j=1(rt+1,jptjqtj � pt+1,jqt+1,j )

!#

with equality holding if qtj > 0.

Miller (712-010 Structural Econometrics) Competitive Equilibrium November 2016 5 / 30

Page 6: Competitive Equilibrium

Portfolio Choices in Competitive EquilibriumThe fundamental theorem of portfolio choice

Substituting ct and ct+1 back into the marginal utilities andrearranging yields:

1 = Et

�rt+1,k β

u0 (ct+1)u0 (ct )

�� Et [rt+1,kMRSt+1]

Recall from the de�nition of a covariance:

cov (rt+1,k ,MRSt+1) = Et [rt+1,kMRSt+1]� Et [rt+1,k ]Et [MRSt+1]= 1� Et [rt+1,k ]Et [MRSt+1]= 1� Et [rt+1,k ] /rt+1

where the second line uses the fundamental equation of portfoliochoice, and the third the de�nition of the risk free rate.Rearranging this equation gives the risk correction for the k th asset:

Et [rt+1,k ]� rt+1 = �rt+1cov (rt+1,k ,MRSt+1)Miller (712-010 Structural Econometrics) Competitive Equilibrium November 2016 6 / 30

Page 7: Competitive Equilibrium

Portfolio Choices in Competitive EquilibriumEstimation and testing (Hansen and Singleton, 1982)

For any r � 1 vector xt belonging to the information set at t and all k:

0 = Et

�rt+1,k β

u0 (ct+1)u0 (ct )

� 1�= E

�rt+1,k β

u0 (ct+1)u0 (ct )

� 1 jxt�

and hence:

0 = E�xt

�rt+1,k β

u0 (ct+1)u0 (ct )

� 1��

Given a sample of length T we can estimate the 1� l vector (β, α)for a parametrically de�ned utility function u (ct ; α) by solving:

0 = ATT

∑t=1xt

�rt+1,k β

u0 (ct+1; α)u0 (ct ; α)

� 1�

where AT is an l � r weighting matrix.Clearly this estimator easily generalizes to any number of assets withan interior condition.

Miller (712-010 Structural Econometrics) Competitive Equilibrium November 2016 7 / 30

Page 8: Competitive Equilibrium

Representative Consumer ModelEstimates from aggregate consumption data (Hansen and Singleton, 1984, Table I)

Miller (712-010 Structural Econometrics) Competitive Equilibrium November 2016 8 / 30

Page 9: Competitive Equilibrium

Representative Consumer ModelEstimates from aggregate consumption data (Hansen and Singleton, 1984, Table III)

Miller (712-010 Structural Econometrics) Competitive Equilibrium November 2016 9 / 30

Page 10: Competitive Equilibrium

Representative Consumer ModelInterpreting estimates from aggregate data

To interpret these results, lifetime utility is:

∑t=1

βtu (ct ) = (1+ α)�1∞

∑t=1

βtc1+αt

NDS (nondurables plus services)ND (nondurables)EWR (NYSE equally weighted average returns)VWR (NYSE value weighted average returns)Chemicals, transportation and equipment, and other retail, comprisedthe three industries.

Note that:

10 out of 12 speci�cations in Table III are rejected at the 0.05 level.Since α > 0 implies convex increasing u (ct ), the 2 remainingspeci�cations in Table III not rejected in a statistical sense do not makeeconomic sense.

Miller (712-010 Structural Econometrics) Competitive Equilibrium November 2016 10 / 30

Page 11: Competitive Equilibrium

Representative Consumer ModelPossible explanations for the rejections

There are several ways of interpreting these rejections:1 Competitive equilibrium does not adequately model outcomes from themarket microstructure of the NYSE.

2 Di¤erent goods are not perfect substitutes for each other.3 The preferences of the representative consumer are not CRRA.4 The representative consumer does not obey the expected utilityhypothesis (Epstein and Zin, 1990).

5 The primitives who optimize are individuals belonging to a population,and their aggregate behavior does not match that of any representativeconsumer.

Miller (712-010 Structural Econometrics) Competitive Equilibrium November 2016 11 / 30

Page 12: Competitive Equilibrium

Relaxing the Assumption of a Representative ConsumerApplying time series data to an individual consumer investor

Subscript current utility, consumption and instruments by individualn 2 f1, . . . ,Ng and de�ne the forecast error εnt as:

εnt ��rtk βu0n (ct+1)

�u0n (ct )

�� 1

Then if the FOC asset for k holds with equality for n:

Et [εnt jxnt ] = 0 =) E [εnt jxnt ] = 0 =) E [xntεnt ] = 0

Noting f. . . , xnt , xn,t+1, . . .g is a Martingale di¤erence sequence, theEuler equation approach to estimation could be applied, since for alln 2 f1, . . . ,Ng:

0 = E [xntεnt ] = p limT!∞

�1T ∑T

t=1 xntεnt

�The large sample properties of this estimator rely on the length of thetime series, or more intuitively, the fact that successive forecast errorsare uncorrelated with each other.

Miller (712-010 Structural Econometrics) Competitive Equilibrium November 2016 12 / 30

Page 13: Competitive Equilibrium

Relaxing the Assumption of a Representative ConsumerWhy Euler equation estimation methods fail on a cross section (Altug and Miller, 1990)

Suppose un (ct ) = u (ct ) and the data only comprise a small numberof periods (say 2), but a large number of individuals.

Averaging over n 2 f1, . . . ,Ng gives:

1N ∑N

n=1 xnt

�rtk β

u0 (ct+1)u0 (ct )

� 1�=1N ∑N

n=1 xntεnt

where:

p limN!∞

�1N ∑N

n=1 xntεnt

�� vt 6= 0 = p lim

T!∞

�1T ∑T

t=1 xntεnt

�Since vt is instrument speci�c, treating vt as a time dummy inestimation requires as many time dummies as there are instruments.

Hence u (ct ) is not identifed o¤ a panel.

Miller (712-010 Structural Econometrics) Competitive Equilibrium November 2016 13 / 30

Page 14: Competitive Equilibrium

Complete MarketsModeling complete markets with time additive preferences (Altug and Miller, 1990)

Let fFtg∞t=0 denote a sequence of σ-algebras with measure P that

re�ects how history unfolds as the economy evolves.Each period t 2 fn, . . . , ng household n consumes (cnt1, . . . , cntK ).Households obey the expected utility hypothesis and have rationalexpectations, preferences taking the time additive form:

E0

"n

∑t=n

βt�nut�n (cnt1, . . . , cntK )

#(1)

Let pt (A) denote the date zero price of receiving a unit of k in theevent of A 2 Ft occurring:

pt (A) =ZA

λtk (ω)P (dω)

The lifetime budget constraint for n is:

E0h∑nt=n ∑K

k=1 λtkcntki� Bn (2)

Miller (712-010 Structural Econometrics) Competitive Equilibrium November 2016 14 / 30

Page 15: Competitive Equilibrium

Complete MarketsMaximization and the �rst order condition

Let:1 ηn denote the Lagrange multiplier associated with (2)2 ptk denote the spot price of k at t (conditional the state)3 the �rst good be a numeraire and de�ne λt � λt1.4 tn � t � n denote the age of the household5 cnt � (cnt1, . . . , cntK ) denote the consumption vector of n at t.

Household n maximizes (1) subject to (2).

Then the �rst order condition for an interior solution for k is:

βtnutn ,k (cnt ) � βtn∂utn (cnt )

∂cntk= ηnλtk � ηnλtptk (3)

Miller (712-010 Structural Econometrics) Competitive Equilibrium November 2016 15 / 30

Page 16: Competitive Equilibrium

Complete MarketsRelative risk aversion and aggregation

Suppose K = 1 and znt is a vector di¤erentiating consumer investors:

unt (cnt ) � (α+ 1)�1 δ (znt ) cα+1nt (4)

Then (3) simpli�es to:

βtnδ (znt ) cαnt = ηnλt

Hence the asset pricing equation can be expressed as:

1 = βEt

�rt+1,k

δ (zn,t+1)δ (znt )

�cn,t+1cnt

�α�= Et

�rt+1,k

λt+1λt

�(5)

Solving for consumption and averaging over a population of N yields:

ct � ∑Nn=1 cnt = λ

1αt ∑N

n=1

�ηn�

βtnδ (znt )� 1

α

or the shadow value of consumption:

λt = cαt

n∑Nn=1

�ηn�

βtnδ (znt )� 1

α

o�α

Miller (712-010 Structural Econometrics) Competitive Equilibrium November 2016 16 / 30

Page 17: Competitive Equilibrium

Complete MarketsEconometric implications of heterogeneity in CRRA preferences with complete markets

Substituting the expression for λt into (5) gives: the Euler equationfor a representative consumer investor:

1 = βEt

24rt+1,k8<: ∑N

n=1

�ηn�

βtnδ (znt )� 1

α

∑Nn=1

�ηn�

βtn+1δ (zn,t+1)� 1

α

9=;α �ct+1ct

�α35

1 If consumers are only di¤erentiated by some �xed characteristics andtheir initial wealth, and znt � zn then:

β (ct+1 /ct )α = λt+1 /λt

2 However to achieve a representative consumer style portfolio equationif znt changes over time, returns must reweighted to re�ect shiftingpriorities for consumption in t by di¤erent segments of the population.

Therefore one reason for rejecting the representative consumerinvestor model is time varying heterogeneity.

Miller (712-010 Structural Econometrics) Competitive Equilibrium November 2016 17 / 30

Page 18: Competitive Equilibrium

Complete MarketsMarginal rates of substitution in equilibrium

Temporarily dropping for convenience the subscript n, the individualidenti�er, and setting pt1 � 1, there are:

1 (K � 1) (n� n) equations corresponding to the spot markets:

MRStk (ct ) �utk (ct )ut1 (ct )

= ptk

2 (n� n)� 1 equations pertaining to the numeraire that intertemporallybalance consumption:

MRSt (ct , ct+1) �βut+1,1 (ct+1)ut1 (ct )

=λt+1

λt

Given ηn, we can show that these K (n� n)� 1 marginal rates ofsubstitution equations fully characterize an interior equilibriumconsumption of n.

Miller (712-010 Structural Econometrics) Competitive Equilibrium November 2016 18 / 30

Page 19: Competitive Equilibrium

Complete MarketsThe remaining marginal rates of substitution and their equilibrium conditions

All remaining marginal rates of substitution functions are fullydescribed by MRStk (ct ) and MRSt (ct , ct+1) because:

MRSt ,s ,k ,l (ct , cs ) �βs�tusl (csl )utk (cnt )

=MRSsl (cs )MRStk (ct )

∏sr=t MRSr (cr , cr+1)

Likewise all the remaining contingent prices are described by thevector sequence of spot prices f(pt2, . . . , ptK )gnt=n along with thecontingent price sequence for the numeraire fλtgnt=n, because:

pslptk

∏s�1r=t

λr+1λr

=λspslλtptk

It follows that additional equalities of the form:

MRSt ,s ,k ,l (ct , cs ) =λspslλtptk

provide neither additional restrictions nor additional parameters.Miller (712-010 Structural Econometrics) Competitive Equilibrium November 2016 19 / 30

Page 20: Competitive Equilibrium

Complete MarketsExample (Altug and Miller, 1990)

For example suppose:

ut (cnt ) �K

∑k=1

exp (xntBk + εntk )

αk + 1cαk+1ntk

Focusing on the �rst two goods we have:

pt2 = MRSt2 (cnt )

= exp [xnt (B2 � B1) + εnt2 � εnt1]cα2nt2

cα1nt1

Taking logarithms:

εnt2 � εnt1

= xnt (B1 � B2) + α1 ln (cnt1)� α2 ln (cnt2) + ln pt2

Miller (712-010 Structural Econometrics) Competitive Equilibrium November 2016 20 / 30

Page 21: Competitive Equilibrium

Complete MarketsEstimation

For any instrument vector znt satisfying:

E [εnt jznt ] = 0

we have:

E fznt [xnt (B1 � B2) + α1 ln (cnt1)� α2 ln (cnt2) + ln pt2]g = 0

A GMM estimator now comes from setting

0 = AN

∑n=1

znt [xnt (B1 � B2) + α1 ln (cnt1)� α2 ln (cnt2) + ln pt2]

The usual large sample properties apply.

Miller (712-010 Structural Econometrics) Competitive Equilibrium November 2016 21 / 30

Page 22: Competitive Equilibrium

Complete MarketsEstimation of intertemporal rates of substitution

Similarly:

λt+1λt

= β exp [(xn,t+1 � xnt )B1 + εn,t+1,1 � εnt1]

�cnt+1,1cn,t+1,1

�α1

or in logarithmic form:

∆ lnλt � ln β = ∆xntB1 + ∆εnt1 + α1∆ ln cnt1

where:

∆xnt � (xn,t+1 � xnt ) ∆εnt1 � (εn,t+1,1 � εnt1)

∆ lnλt � lnλt+1 � lnλt ∆ ln cnt1 � ln cnt+1,1 � ln cnt1If E [εnt jznt ] = 0 then:

E fznt [∆ lnλt � ln β� α1∆ ln cnt1 � ∆xntB1]g = 0A GMM estimator with the usual large sample properties can beformed from the sample analogue.

Miller (712-010 Structural Econometrics) Competitive Equilibrium November 2016 22 / 30

Page 23: Competitive Equilibrium

Complete MarketsThe rate of time discounting cannot be identifed o¤ short panels

Suppose the model is generated by contingent prices λet and β0.

Assume neither λet nor β0 are directly observed.

Treat β and ∆ lnλt as parameters in the estimated model. Setting:

β = β�

∆ lnλ�t = ∆ lnλet � ln β0 + ln β�

It immediately follows that a speci�cation with:

(β,∆ lnλt ) = (β�,∆ lnλ�t )

is observationally equivalent to:

(β,∆ lnλt ) = (β0,∆ lnλet )

Thus the rate of time discounting is not identi�ed o¤ short panels.

Miller (712-010 Structural Econometrics) Competitive Equilibrium November 2016 23 / 30

Page 24: Competitive Equilibrium

Complete MarketsThe degree of aggregate uncertainty cannot be identifed o¤ short panels

In a world of perfect foresight where the one period interest rate is it ,then:

λt = 1�(1+ it )

and:

MRStn (cnt , cn,t+1) �βutn+1,1 (cn,t+1)utn ,1 (cnt )

=1

(1+ it )

We cannot tell from panel data whether this is one of several pathsthe world could be taking, or whether it is the unique path.

Confusing "complete markets" with a "full insurance" model, as someauthors have done, is misleading.

Complete markets might fail because of borrowing constraints, ratherthan a lack of insurance opportunities.

Miller (712-010 Structural Econometrics) Competitive Equilibrium November 2016 24 / 30

Page 25: Competitive Equilibrium

An International Comparison (Miller and Sieg, 1997)Descriptive statistics for the U.S. and Germany

Miller (712-010 Structural Econometrics) Competitive Equilibrium November 2016 25 / 30

Page 26: Competitive Equilibrium

An International ComparisonA model of male labor supply and housing demand

The following notation applies to household n at time t:l0nt female leisurel1nt male leisurehnt housing servicesxnt observed demographics(ε0nt , . . . , ε3nt ) unobserved disturbance iid over n

Current utility takes the form:

u (l0nt , l1nt , hnt , , xnt ) � α�10 exp (xntB0 + ε0nt ) hα0nt l

α20nt

+α�11 exp (xntB1 + ε1nt ) lα11nt l

α30nt + . . .

The wage rate is the value of the marginal product for a standardlabor unit times the e¢ ciency rating of n:

wnt � wt exp (xntB2 + ε2nt )

Similarly:rnt � rt exp (xntB3 + ε3nt )

Miller (712-010 Structural Econometrics) Competitive Equilibrium November 2016 26 / 30

Page 27: Competitive Equilibrium

An International ComparisonEstimates of the marginal rate of substitution functions

Miller (712-010 Structural Econometrics) Competitive Equilibrium November 2016 27 / 30

Page 28: Competitive Equilibrium

An International ComparisonInterpreting Table 3

The column key is:1 MRS between housing and male leisure plus housing rental function2 Adds wage equation3 Adds intertemporal MRS for male leisure over consecutive periods andsubtracts rent equation

4 Both MRS conditions plus wage and rent equations

The number of observations is about 400 sopN is about 20.

J is asymptotically χdwhere d = # overidentifying restrictions.

None of the speci�cations is rejected, all the coe¢ cients aresigni�cant and are signed according to economic intuition.

Contingent claims prices (inversely) track aggregate consumptionquite well.

Miller (712-010 Structural Econometrics) Competitive Equilibrium November 2016 28 / 30

Page 29: Competitive Equilibrium

An International ComparisonAggregate consumption (solid line) and estimated contingent prices (dotted) for Germanyand the U.S.

Miller (712-010 Structural Econometrics) Competitive Equilibrium November 2016 29 / 30

Page 30: Competitive Equilibrium

An International ComparisonTesting equality of prices, preferences and e¢ ciency ratings

We reject the null hypotheses that:

contingent claims prices between Germany and US are equalcontingent claims prices between di¤erent regions in the US are equalat the 0.05 but not at the 0.1 levelpreferences between the two countries are the same

With respect to purchasing power parity we:

do not reject the null that the value of marginal product of labor isequalized across both countriesreject the null that the premium to education is the same.

Miller (712-010 Structural Econometrics) Competitive Equilibrium November 2016 30 / 30