34
Competition in the Absence of Standards in Enterprise Software Industries: A Social Network Perspective Ramnath K. Chellappa 1 {[email protected] } Tel: (213) 740 3920 Nilesh Saraf 2 {[email protected] } Tel: (213) 740 7283 ebizlab BRI 401, 3670 Trousdale Parkway Department of IOM Marshall School of Business University of Southern California Los Angeles, CA 90089 Fax: 213-740-7313 September 2002 (Please do not quote without permission. Comments will be appreciated) Acknowledgement Research supported in part by the Center for Telecommunications Management, USC. The authors are high indebted to the following people for their valuable comments: Paul Adler, Sriram Dasu, Omar ElSawy, Dan Levinthal, Ann Majchrzak, Mahesh Nagarajan, Barrie Nault and Dan O'Leary. Any error is solely the responsibility of the authors. 1 Ramnath K. Chellappa is an Assistant Professor of Information Systems and co-director of ebizlab at the Marshall School of Business, University of Southern California. 2 Nilesh Saraf is a Ph.D. Candidate in Information Systems at the Marshall School of Business, University of Southern California.

Competition in the Absence of Standards in Enterprise ... · Competition in the Absence of Standards in Enterprise Software Industries: A Social Network Perspective Abstract Whether

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    0

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Competition in the Absence of Standards in Enterprise ... · Competition in the Absence of Standards in Enterprise Software Industries: A Social Network Perspective Abstract Whether

Competition in the Absence of Standards in Enterprise Software Industries: A

Social Network Perspective

Ramnath K. Chellappa1 {[email protected]}

Tel: (213) 740 3920

Nilesh Saraf2 {[email protected]}

Tel: (213) 740 7283

ebizlab

BRI 401, 3670 Trousdale Parkway

Department of IOM

Marshall School of Business

University of Southern California

Los Angeles, CA 90089

Fax: 213-740-7313

September 2002

(Please do not quote without permission. Comments will be appreciated)

Acknowledgement Research supported in part by the Center for Telecommunications Management, USC. The authors are high

indebted to the following people for their valuable comments: Paul Adler, Sriram Dasu, Omar ElSawy, Dan

Levinthal, Ann Majchrzak, Mahesh Nagarajan, Barrie Nault and Dan O'Leary.

Any error is solely the responsibility of the authors.

1 Ramnath K. Chellappa is an Assistant Professor of Information Systems and co-director of ebizlab at the Marshall School of Business, University of Southern California. 2 Nilesh Saraf is a Ph.D. Candidate in Information Systems at the Marshall School of Business, University of Southern California.

Page 2: Competition in the Absence of Standards in Enterprise ... · Competition in the Absence of Standards in Enterprise Software Industries: A Social Network Perspective Abstract Whether

Competition in the Absence of Standards in Enterprise Software Industries: A

Social Network Perspective

Abstract

Whether developed by a firm (de-facto) or set by a committee (de-jure), interface standards are

an important element of competition in software industries. While adopting the right set of

technology standards for their products is crucial for firms in the enterprise software industry, the

absence of a single set of open standards or leading standards from a dominant firm makes this

choice difficult for firms. Despite the absence of standards seamless interaction between

products of different firms is a requisite for organizational end-users. Therefore, firms maintain

alliances to render their products technical compatible. While prior research identifies primarily

access to user bases as the network externality benefits arising from technical compatibility, we

argue that in addition alliances also enhance social compatibility. We view this dimension of

compatibility as the market’s perception of compatibility resulting from reputation transfer and

knowledge spillovers through alliances. We also argue that benefits from such compatibility are

transmitted through both direct and indirect partners in the alliance network. We use the social

network perspective to understand how resources are transferred in this alliance network and

aggregate these resources into a construct that we call Sociotechnical capital. We then propose

that in the absence of uniform industry-wide leading standards the relative prominence of a firm

in this network is a valid surrogate for market power and is correlated with its performance. To

address the limitations of extant social network measures we develop an alternative theoretically

grounded metric for firm prominence that is based on the Sociotechnical resource transfer. An

analysis of 65 enterprise system firms empirically supports our proposition. Our study offers

insights into the behavior of firms in the enterprise systems software industry.

Keywords: Technology standards, software industry, enterprise resource planning (ERP),

software architecture, partnerships, social network theory, standards competition

2

Page 3: Competition in the Absence of Standards in Enterprise ... · Competition in the Absence of Standards in Enterprise Software Industries: A Social Network Perspective Abstract Whether

1. Introduction

"Standards wars (are) battles for market dominance between incompatible technologies

(and) are a fixture of the information age"

-Carl Shapiro and Hal Varian, Information Rules

In the information technology industry an enterprise systems software (ESS) firm’s choice of

interface standards for its products significantly influences competition in its market. This is

because from the perspective of organizations that use information technology (IT) standards

play an important role in the building of IT infrastructure supporting their business processes

(Keen 1991). IT infrastructure at user organizations consists mostly of software components

manufactured by ESS vendor firms such as SAP, I2, JDEdwards, PeopleSoft, etc. (Davenport

1998). Given that these components need to work with each other an ESS vendor has the

alternative to either develop all the components by itself (i.e., the entire system); or to make a

few components that can be easily integrated with complementary components from other ESS

firms. When there are no uniform industry-wide interface standards an ESS vendor has to

incorporate into his own components one or more complementary vendor’s proprietary

standards. Thus, ESS vendors have to make strategic choices in their selection of standards. The

primary goal of this paper is to identify an alternative metric to represent the relative market

power of ESS firms in this industry characterized by: 1) no uniform industry-wide open

standards 2) multiple vendors offering one or more competing or complementary components 3)

integration across components of different vendors being very important for organizational end-

users. Past research suggests that in the absence of uniform industry-wide open standards the

leading set of standards is controlled by the firm(s) with the most market power. As more

functionality is added to enterprise software, for ESS vendors the selection of the right set of

standards becomes important and influences their survival3.

There is little research in information systems (IS) that offers understanding about competition

and how market power is derived in a standards-driven industry. The primary focus has been on

the benefits of adopting uniform standards within an organization - also known as a corporate IT

standard (Gordon 1993). Here an organization frames policies to ensure enterprise-wide 3 “… market selection and incremental innovations induce each firm to converge towards the dominant standard and less adaptive firms are pushed out of the market,” Antonelli, C. (1994). "Localized technological change and the evolution of standards as economic institutions." Information Economics and Policy 6: 195-216..

3

Page 4: Competition in the Absence of Standards in Enterprise ... · Competition in the Absence of Standards in Enterprise Software Industries: A Social Network Perspective Abstract Whether

compatibility of its systems and processes. Benefits of adopting such a corporate IT standard

include improved coordination (Malone 1987), enhanced connectivity from data integration

(Wybo and Goodhue 1995), reduction in IT maintenance costs and local IT responsiveness

(Kayworth and Sambamurthy 2000) among others. Standardization of IT in organizations is also

found to be related to performance of firms (Chatfield and Yetton 2000) and supply chains

(Yang and Papazoglou 2000). However, other than one recent article on competition in the

Japanese PC market (West and Dedrick 2000) research in IS has largely ignored the competition

between ESS manufacturers whose products incorporate standards required by organizational

users. While such competition has been addressed to some extent by economics literature the

impact of organizational user perceptions of compatibility (i.e., corporate IT standards

requirement) on competitive behavior of IT manufacturers has not been explored at all. Our

research attempts to bridge this gap through an analysis of competition in the enterprise software

industry.

In order that organizational users derive the benefits of corporate IT standards it is essential that

components of one ESS vendor works well with multiple other ESS vendors’ components. As

against in the past, currently an organization's enterprise system is often a collection of software

components manufactured by a multitude of vendors (Davenport 1998). For example, a payroll

system that was programmed in COBOL and housed in a mainframe may now consist of

components ranging from Oracle databases, Web servers by Apache, browsers from Netscape

and an application component from an Enterprise Resource Application (ERP) vendor like SAP.

In this industry while there exist standards for low level communication such as at the transport

level and object stages there do not exist a uniform set of high level compatibility rules to enable

a plug-n-play type of operation (Yang and Papazoglou 2000). Thus, to ensure interoperability

among their complementary components ESS vendors may adopt each other’s standards even if

they maybe offering competing components. This is typically accomplished through explicit

alliances between firms such as those involving licensing, product development and release

agreements (David and Greenstein 1990) through which an ESS firm’s technology propagates.

There are also adapters or consultants in this industry who benefit by the lack of common

technological standards (Farrell and Saloner 1992) and are influential in the social interaction

processes. Such social interactions (examples: joint conferences, trade shows, and training

sessions) not only result in knowledge exchange between ESS vendors but also enhance

4

Page 5: Competition in the Absence of Standards in Enterprise ... · Competition in the Absence of Standards in Enterprise Software Industries: A Social Network Perspective Abstract Whether

compatibility perceptions of the organizational user. These perceptions are important for

corporate IT requirements and influence organizational users’ selection of ESS vendors. Thus,

while propagation of technology through alliances contributes to a firm’s dominance along the

supply-side, favorable compatibility perceptions of end-users are demand-side drivers of

dominance (Stewart 1996). In this scenario prominent ESS firms can better influence adoption of

their standards (Kotabe, Sahay et al.), influence consultants and integrators and leverage better

their effort in social promotions to improve firm performance.

In this paper we first provide an alternative theoretical framework to address certain limitations

of economic models towards understanding the sources of market power for ESS vendors. Using

the social network perspective we develop a model of resource transfer for industries where

interface technology standards play an important role. We propose that in addition to benefits

from technological compatibility ESS firms also derive social benefits such as reputation and

knowledge spillovers through alliances. The firms attain a favorable structural position due to

their access to resources. First we aggregate these resources into a construct called

“Sociotechnical capital” and then propose that the market power of a firm, termed as a firm’s

relative prominence, can be measured through its structural position in the network. To develop

an empirically tractable metric for such a structural position we improve upon an existing

prominence measures by incorporating flow of benefits from both direct and indirect partners.

By analyzing data on 65 ESS firms and their alliances we verify that our metric is correlated with

firm performance.

The paper is organized as follows: In the following section we present our research questions and

briefly discuss extant literature in the context of the ESS industry. In section 3, we develop a

model of resource transfer in alliance networks and describe the construct of Sociotechnical

capital. In section 4 we develop the modified measure of firm prominence and examine its

applicability in a study of 65 ESS firms. Section 5 concludes with the implications of this work

for future research in information systems as well as for scholars in the field of strategy and

management.

2. Frameworks to study competition in standards-driven IT industries

It is predominantly literature in economics that has addressed firm competition where standards

are involved (Saloner 1990; Axelrod, Mitchell et al. 1995). Examples are the early VCR

5

Page 6: Competition in the Absence of Standards in Enterprise ... · Competition in the Absence of Standards in Enterprise Software Industries: A Social Network Perspective Abstract Whether

industry where VHS emerged as the winning standard and: the operating systems markets where

multiple separate standards such as Unix, Windows, MacOS, etc. still exist. The main element in

these models is the accumulation of externality benefits either by adopting a common standard or

by constructing adapters to enable compatibility. Along these lines Katz and Shapiro (1985)

have argued that firms with small user bases have strong incentives to make their products

compatible with those of players will larger user bases. Even in multi-component markets or in

competition between multiple firms of equal size compatibility is still the desired outcome

(Economides 1989). All these models conclude that it is beneficial to adopt the leading standard

in terms of user bases. However, it is believed that where there are no explicit standards present

for adoption the applicability of these models is limited (Economides 1989, p1180). However, it

has been observed that using economic models such as conventional game-theoretic analysis to

empirically study complex alliance compositions is "especially difficult because payoffs for each

firm depend upon the choices made by all other firms (Axelrod, Mitchell et al. 1995, p. 1497). "

Further, these models imply that that i) externality benefits of adopting standards (measured as

increase in user bases or market share) maybe the only benefits to an ESS vendor through an

alliance and ii) these benefits accrue only due to a direct linkage across vendors.

Though it is suggested that formation of implicit and explicit alliances maybe required for

development and sponsoring of standards (Saloner 1990), little empirical research actually exists

that can be applied to the context of ESS industry. To gain market power individual firms must

be incentivized by coalitions to join them (Axelrod, Mitchell et al. 1995). The authors (Axelrod,

Mitchell et al. 1995) observe earlier that purely analytical models cannot consider complex

alliance compositions since individual firm payoff functions depend on simultaneous choices of

all other firms and as a result define the utility of firm joining an alliance in pair wise relations.

Hence the authors propose modifications for empirical tractability and assume that firms are

either close or distant rivals. However such strong assumptions may not be suitable to study our

industry context as firms compete in multiple component markets and they may complement

each other in one segment while competing in another. More importantly it does not elaborate

on the nature of benefits maybe transferred between the ESS firms and fails to take into account

benefits from their indirectly connected partners.

To devise a surrogate measure of market power we suggest that the understanding offered by the

economics literature has to be combined with the insights from literature on alliance networks. In

6

Page 7: Competition in the Absence of Standards in Enterprise ... · Competition in the Absence of Standards in Enterprise Software Industries: A Social Network Perspective Abstract Whether

the absence of uniform industry-wide open standards we note that ESS firms form alliances that

allow them to absorb other’s standards and propagate their own. Thus these alliances are formed

not only for the purpose of deriving network benefits from access to larger user bases but also for

enhancing learning and knowledge transfer (Hagedoorn and Duysters 1999, p.9). This becomes

especially important in constantly evolving technologies such as enterprise software where, to be

successful, ESS vendors invest in aligning their products along dominant technological designs

(Suarez and Utterback 1995). When ESS vendors form alliances they acquire competencies

through exchange of knowledge bases and align their information processing structures with one

or more alliance partners. Therefore, it becomes important for ESS firms to identify other ESS

firms having higher market power. Towards this end we introduce social network theory as a

framework to study competition among firms in the ESS industry and to devise a measure for

market power of ESS vendors. Just as one approach to analyzing firm behavior in markets is

through economic paradigms more recently theories from social sciences such as economic

sociology (Kogut, Walker et al. 1995) and actor network theory (Monteiro 2000) also are able to

represent complex social, economic and technical perspectives (Chellappa and Saraf 2000;

Fomin and Keil 2000).

2.1. Using social network theory to study competition in enterprise software industry

The goal of this sub-section is to familiarize the reader with basic concepts in social network

theory to be able to understand the development of constructs in the later section that are specific

to the ESS industry. Social network theory has typically been used to study set of individuals

with links between them representing specific social ties including interaction ties (Contractor,

Seibold et al. 1996), friendship ties (Zeggelink, Stokman et al. 1996), and marital ties (Padgett

and Ansell 1993). Research in organizational behavior, human communication and computer-

mediated communication has also adapted this approach to study networks of members within an

organization (Barley 1990). Most of this early work in social networks focused on within-firm

issues where the actors typically represent employees and the relationship linkages were

enclosed in boundaries of the particular organization. During the last decade the social network

metaphor proposed earlier by Tichy et al. (1979) has been considerably extended to analyze

market level behavior where linkages in the network represent various types of relationships

between firms (Ahuja 2000). For example, such networks have been used to study pricing

7

Page 8: Competition in the Absence of Standards in Enterprise ... · Competition in the Absence of Standards in Enterprise Software Industries: A Social Network Perspective Abstract Whether

strategies of investment banks (Podolny 1993), power relations between corporations and

investment banks (Baker 1990) and niche overlap in a patent citation network of firms in the

semiconductor industry (Podolny, Stuart et al. 1996).

In our research, we view the ESS industry as a network of firms with each link between them

representing an alliance through which resources flow between firms. Research in this field has

also developed a variety of network measures with purpose of describing and capturing network

level phenomenon. Of particular interest to us is the measure of relative status (prominence) of a

firm compared to others in its network. This measure can be used to represent the dominance of

the different ESS firms relative to each other. This is consistent with the observations that

“industrial structures can be represented as a set of positions that are arranged hierarchically

according to the prominence of their occupants (Stuart, Hoang et al. 1999, p.318).” In the status-

based models of market competition prominence plays an important role in influencing

organizational performance of a firm as well as that of its affiliates (Ahuja 2000; Burt 2000;

Stuart 2000). According to this literature the status of an actor is influenced by its firm specific

attributes such as past demonstrations of quality, technological pioneering or higher market

share. In addition, in many industry contexts status of firm can also be increased through

linkages with prominent firms. These linkages provide the alliances partners with access to

knowledge, technological capabilities, newer markets, production know-how, R&D joint

ventures, etc. (Liebeskind, Oliver et al. 1996; Walker, Kogut et al. 1997). The prominent a firm

is, the better it can leverage its own position through benefits such as lower transaction costs and

risks (Podolny 1993), preferential treatment from suppliers and higher returns from quality - and

therefore price (Benjamin and Podolny 1999). Other findings are that that higher prominence

increases the chances of survival of a firm in the semiconductor industry (Podolny, Stuart et al.

1996) and that that firms with low status benefited in their market capitalization and time to IPO

due to their partnerships with high status firms (Stuart, Hoang et al. 1999).

The network process through which an ESS vendor achieves prominence varies considerably

across industry contexts in terms of a supply-side or a demand-side rationale. Prior literature has

mostly focused on only a supply-side rationale (Stewart 1996). For example, in the high-

technology semiconductor industry (Podolny, Stuart et al. 1996) or in the biotechnology industry

(Shan, Walker et al. 1994), research and development partnerships between firms are significant

in increasing prominence. Similarly, in the IT industry firms may achieve higher prominence

8

Page 9: Competition in the Absence of Standards in Enterprise ... · Competition in the Absence of Standards in Enterprise Software Industries: A Social Network Perspective Abstract Whether

when they cross-license technologies and interface standards of prominent vendors. We suggest

that in addition to the above supply-side reasoning of why firms achieve prominence, the

demand-side factors, i.e., those that matter from the organizational user's (customer’s)

perspective, also need to be considered. These factors include market’s perceptions of

compatibility influenced by trade-shows, product compatibility announcements and certification

by consultants. The perception of compatibility has a role similar to that of brand in consumer

goods markets. We suggest that in the ESS industry, both supply-side and demand-side

reasoning needs to be considered to understand how firms achieve higher prominence.

3. A model of relative prominence in the enterprise software industry

Since our primary goal is to establish that relative prominence in the alliance network as a valid

measure of market power, we proceed in two steps. First, we propose that the alliance network is

indeed a non-trivial network, that is, the occurrence of the number of alliances is not

significantly low compared to other alliance studies in the high-technology industries. In

particular, we also apply the theory of network formation in economics literature (Bala and

Goyal 2000) to better understand the structure of the network4. Second, we shall devise a rational

choice model of network prominence in the ESS industry by theoretically justifying four key

assumptions regarding the characteristics of and benefits from alliances among ESS firms. In this

discussion rigorously grounded to context, we also explain the nature of competition and how

market power accrues to ESS firms.

We consider a model of alliances where a focal ESS firm is a source of benefits that other firms

in the network can access by maintaining an alliance with the focal firm. We propose that while a

focal firm derives benefit from alliances it also benefits from indirect linkages. Further, we also

model benefits from all actors in the network of partners as attenuated before they reach any

focal firm. This model of alliance network formation has parallels with the recent Bala and

Goyal’s (Bala and Goyal 2000) model of social and economic networks. Bala and Goyal (Bala

and Goyal 2000) refer to the attenuated benefits as decay or delay associated with indirect links.

They observe, “in the case of two-way flow of benefits, networks with a single star and linked

stars are strict Nash.” (p. 1186) Note that Bala and Goyal’s model is aimed towards identifying 4 In our results section we present a partial empirical evidence for this proposition.

9

Page 10: Competition in the Absence of Standards in Enterprise ... · Competition in the Absence of Standards in Enterprise Software Industries: A Social Network Perspective Abstract Whether

the most stable alliance network structure, and their findings indicate that if all actors are rational

then eventually the networks will be empty or if connected, they will rapidly converge to a limit

network, i.e., a star or a linked star.

The findings of Bala and Goyal can be interpreted to conclude that three alternative structures of

a limit network in the ESS industry are possible. These are: a. eventually all standards will be

open and no firm will see a need to invest in alliances (empty) or b. there will be a de facto

leader and leading standard and firms will invest only in alliances with this leader (star) or c.

there will be several distinct leaders and leading standards linked to each other and firms will

invest in only one of them (linked star). In fact alternative c, agrees with the findings of

Axelrod, et al (Axelrod, Mitchell et al.) that where technology standards are involved, eventually

distinct coalitions will emerge such that the extent of rivalry within coalitions is minimum.

Proposition 1: The current alliance structure of the enterprise software industry is sub-optimal

(not strictly Nash), representative of a partially matured industry.

Proposition 1 states that it is not possible to clearly identify leaders as the industry structure and

standards have not converged to stability. We argue that understanding the source of market

power is important at this stage of the evolution of the ESS industry since convergence to

uniform industry-wide open standards is unlikely in the long term. Every firm behaves rationally

so as to maximize its returns from alliances. At any point in time the networks resulting from

these actions are intermediate stages converging towards the most stable formation, i.e., strict

Nash (Bala and Goyal 2000). This implies that all firms simultaneously re-evalute their alliance

decisions for their own profit maximization and eventually converge to a strict Nash when there

is no incentive to re-evaluate. We attempt to understand the enterprise software industry at such

an intermediate stage since we believe that this industry will be characterized by non-unified

standards in the longer terms. This conclusion is also supported by economics theory on

standards adoption where existence of adapters retards standards adoption (Farrell and Saloner

1992). As consultants and integrators are active entities in this industry, we propose that waiting

for standards to converge is unrealistic. Hence the relative prominence of an ESS firm in its

alliance network is a strong indicator of its market power. The rest of our paper is focused

towards devising a surrogate metric for market power of ESS vendors. First we formalize the

benefits and costs to each ESS firm in maintaining alliances using which we develop a new

metric for relative prominence of an ESS firm within a network.

10

Page 11: Competition in the Absence of Standards in Enterprise ... · Competition in the Absence of Standards in Enterprise Software Industries: A Social Network Perspective Abstract Whether

3.1. Social and technical resources transferred between ESS firms

To understand more clearly how ESS vendors benefit from their alliance networks, we proceed

in the following two steps. First we discuss the nature of benefits to an ESS vendor from an

alliance with another vendor. Second, we discuss how these benefits flow through the alliance

network. The nature of benefits from an alliance arises from two facets of compatibility,

technical and social compatibility. Technical compatibility results from an alliance when the

partners align their product interface design at the data, application and business process level

(Yang and Papazoglou 2000). Economic models of standards competition primarily describe

benefits from technical compatibility as access to user bases of partners. Social compatibility is

the market’s perception of compatibility between the products of alliance partners. The

investments made by aligning vendors in joint promotions, conferences and pre-announcements

enhance this perception of compatibility. Thus this perception becomes specific to alliance dyad.

It is further enhanced as third party integrators and consultants develop integration tools to

enhance interoperability. In this way alliance benefits including transfer of reputation, third party

investments and access to consultants contribute to enhancing the organizational users’

perceptions of compatibility. Further, along these two dimensions, direct benefits are accrued

through direct and consciously forged alliances with partner firms and indirect benefits are

transferred due to recursive flow from partners of directly connected partners.

Consider a network of ESS firms and a set of linkages among these representing alliances. We

assume that each firm has made a rational decision at a particular point in time in terms of the

choice of its alliances. Further, it has also invested in its relationships such that its net benefits

(less costs incurred in maintaining these) is maximized. We do not assume a dynamic network

where firms choose to expand their market and therefore strike newer linkages as also adopt

other asymmetric strategies. The alliance linkages can be associated with technical and social

compatibility with its partners and with a certain configuration of alliance linkages these firms

gain access to benefits directly and indirectly in this network (Figure 1 represents a subset of our

sample ESS vendors with alliances between them).

n

Technical benefits have been well documented in economics as well as some IS literature (Katz

and Shapiro 1985; Kauffman, McAndrews et al. 2000) as small firms having significant

incentives to make their products compatible with that of larger firms. This is due to the

11

Page 12: Competition in the Absence of Standards in Enterprise ... · Competition in the Absence of Standards in Enterprise Software Industries: A Social Network Perspective Abstract Whether

expectation that user base of the larger firm is now accessible to the smaller firm due to

compatibility, i.e., larger the user base larger is the potential benefit. As discussed before,

demand-side drivers play an important role in emergence of market structure, and the perceptions

of compatibility by the organizational user is one such driver. Therefore, information transfer

through these non-technical (referred to as social) mechanisms such as joint advertising, trade

show, and user conferences contribute to user perceptions of compatibility. In an alliance social

compatibility between a pair of ESS vendors may be enhanced because such ties are transmitters

of reputation as also conduits of knowledge spillover. As third party investors and the industry

experts participate in diffusing knowledge the perception of compatibility is further enhanced as

organizations get embedded in networks or other kinds of super-ordinate relationships (Argote

2000, p.162). This knowledge transfer occurs through people-technology, people-task and task-

technology networks across the partners. Also, investment in alliances increases absorptive

capacity of the partners through which knowledge about product interface design can be

exchanged efficiently (Conner and Prahalad 1996).

In our context, to begin with, every firm by virtue of its own technology and past demonstrations

of quality, brings with it a certain amount of resources (including user bases, reputation, access

pool of consultants, etc.) to the network, that are now available as potential benefits to its

partners. Adler et al., (2000, p.6) observe that a network resource like Social capital is more

commonly complementary to other resources and further it is more akin to a collective good,

rather than a pure private or public good. Unlike a private good, these resources are shared, but

not to every body, as public goods are. These resources are available only to those partners who

have invested in relationships with the firm.

Assumption 1: The greater are the exogenous (non-network based) resources of the alliance

partners greater are the social and technical benefits derived by the focal ESS firms.

Formally we call this exogenous value as ( )0,j j j> ∀e e and normalized for the whole

network1

1n

jj

e=

=

∑ . This value is intrinsic to each firm in the network. It is representative of

resources such as existing user base, consultants, integrators, implementers, etc., all who have

accumulated knowledge about integrating products of the focal ESS vendor. These resources are

12

Page 13: Competition in the Absence of Standards in Enterprise ... · Competition in the Absence of Standards in Enterprise Software Industries: A Social Network Perspective Abstract Whether

useful to alliance partners. Our above assumption is in line with the observation made by Portes5.

In the absence of any network or relationship with other firms a firm’s benefit is only based on

its own resources, i.e.,b f . ( )j je=

i jc s i∝ ∀∑

However these alliances not only need initial investment but they also incur a maintenance cost

(Adler and Kwon 2000). We assume that these costs incurred by a focal ESS vendor increase are

increasing in the prominence of its partners. Given that prominent firms are considered to be

selective in their partnerships (Benjamin and Podolny 1999) the cost of maintaining an alliance

can be considered to be dependent on a firm's prominence. In the ESS industry firms that wish

to make their components compatible with another firm's components incur a cost either in the

form of licensing fees or self-constructed adapters. Therefore, in order to be selected as an

alliance partner a firm may have to invest in upgrading its product quality and developing

additional capabilities that are complementary and useful to partners. In other words the cost of

creating/maintaining technical and social compatibility depends on firm status.

Assumption 2: Higher the relative prominence of the focal ESS firm higher is the technological

and social cost required by alliance partners to maintain a relationship with the focal firm.

For a focal firm i let the relative prominence of its alliance partners be and let be the

aggregate cost incurred in forming alliances with these selected vendors. Formally we can state

assumption 2 as .

js ic

, 1j↔ =

Since a firm’s status is lowered if the affiliate has a low quality product (Stuart, Hoang et al.

1999), they strive to maintain their reputation and to signal quality when forming alliances. This

may involve social signaling through hiring of a high profile CIO, engaging a branded, expensive

advertisement firm, partnering with specific adapters, etc. Often these costs are directed at the

type of firm they wish to partner with. In order to exploit and sustain the opportunities afforded

by relationships with partner firms organizations also have to invest in continuous learning

mechanisms (Metcalfe and Miles 1994) where learning is then dependent on the prominence of

partners. Not only may a prominent firm, charge higher licensing fees but it may also require its

partner firms to invest in jointly sponsoring user conventions, trade shows, etc. Thus, these costs

5 He clearly distinguishes between resources themselves from the ability to obtain them by virtue of membership in different social structures. Portes, A., "Social capital: Its origins and applications in modern sociology," Annual Review of Sociology, 24, (1998), 1-24.

13

Page 14: Competition in the Absence of Standards in Enterprise ... · Competition in the Absence of Standards in Enterprise Software Industries: A Social Network Perspective Abstract Whether

not only include the cost of making product interfaces compatible but also aimed at maintaining

relationships at a non-technical sense to enhance market’s perceptions of compatibility with

alliance partners.

A unique element of multi component markets is that while firms have to cooperate in some

complementary component markets to leverage externality benefits, they have to compete with

the same firm in other markets. Therefore, firm relationships or alliances have to be

representative of such co-opetition. We could argue that firms that have more of the same

components and less of complementary requirements would choose to form a weak relationship.

Thus, we could describe a generic term, "strength of the aggregate relationship” as a measure of

the extent to which firms are interdependent due to their competition, cooperation requirements.

The degree of such interdependency between firms can reflect the level to which learning

mechanisms are customized, information-processing structures (Galbraith 1973) are aligned and

absorptive capacities are developed (Cohen and Levinthal 1990). One such measure in our

context could simply be multi-market contact as two firms are unlikely to have a high degree of

interdependency if they have a high multi-market contact (Axelrod, Mitchell et al. 1995). Thus

if a firm chooses to have a very close relationship such as not just mere licensing of technology,

but co-development of products as well, then it would naturally have to invest heavily in both

technical as well organizational mechanism alignments. Consequently due to a strong

relationship, flow of benefits would be better facilitated.

Assumption 3: An ESS firm’s required investment and corresponding benefits from a

partnership, is dependent upon its desired strength of the relationship.

If is representative of the focal firm i ’s strength of relationship with adjacent firms ijr j , and if

is the strength of relationship between firms that one and two path lengths away,

then combining assumptions 1 and 2, we can write the sum total benefits to a firm as

,jkr i k∀ ↔ = 2

l

1=

(1.1) ... , ,

1, 2, 3,...

i ij j ij jk k ij jk kl lj j k j k l

b r e r r e r r r e i j k

i j i k i l

= + + + ∀ ≠

↔ = ↔ = ↔ =

∑ ∑∑ ∑∑∑

Similarly, combining assumptions 2 and 3, the cost of a focal firm in investing in relationships

with its adjacent firms is

(1.2) , ,i ij jj

c r s i j i j= ∀ ≠ ↔∑

14

Page 15: Competition in the Absence of Standards in Enterprise ... · Competition in the Absence of Standards in Enterprise Software Industries: A Social Network Perspective Abstract Whether

By selecting alliance partners firms directly incur the costs of maintaining these relationships.

However, organizational users not only construct their IT systems using components from

alliance partners but they also purchase and implement components from unconnected vendors.

This implies that if a third firm is compatible with a direct partner of a focal firm, then the third

firm's components are likely to more compatible with the focal firm as compared to a completely

unconnected firm. Thus product bundling across different component makers can further

enhance technical benefits to an indirect affiliate of one of the participants in the product

bundling strategy.

Indirect ties

Benefits • Access to user bases • Potential to be bundled with

other components

Benefits • Knowledge spillovers and

information transfer (Holm, Eriksson et al. 1999; Ahuja 2000)

• Acquisition of ideas and practices (Burt 2000)

Direct ties

Benefits • Access to user bases due to

technical compatability (Katz and Shapiro 1985; Matutes and Regibeau 1988; Economides 1989)

• Increases likelihood of bandwagon effect (Katz and Shapiro 1985)

• Increased likelihood of collaborative component design (Henderson and Clark 1990)

Costs

• Licensing fees (Kotabe, Sahay et al. 1996)

• Constructing and maintaining adapters (Farrell and Saloner 1992)

Benefits • Transfer of reputation (Podolny

1993) • Knowledge spillovers and

information transfer (Ahuja 2000; Argote and Ingram 2000)

• Acquisition of ideas and practices (Burt 1987)

• Stimulating third party investments (Metcalfe and Miles 1994)

Costs • Installing learning mechanisms

(Metcalfe and Miles 1994) • Aligning information

processing structures (Galbraith 1973)

• Increasing absorptive capacity (Conner and Prahalad 1996)

Technical dimension Social dimension

Table 1: Sociotechnical Resource Transfer Matrix

The assumption that benefits can flow through multiple network linkages has also been a main

element in network models of firm behavior and competition in strategy literature. Similar to

direct ties indirect ties also are conduits of knowledge spillovers and technical breakthroughs

(Ahuja 2000). It is also argued that new ideas and practices also permeate through the network

of ties (Burt 2000) and these effects from indirect ties are mediated by the intermediate

15

Page 16: Competition in the Absence of Standards in Enterprise ... · Competition in the Absence of Standards in Enterprise Software Industries: A Social Network Perspective Abstract Whether

relationships (Holm, Eriksson et al. 1999, p.475). Thus, while firms do not incur any cost of

having an indirect connection, benefits do accrue indirectly. The indirect effect is consistent with

the notion of decay or delay that has been introduced in recent research on network formation

(Bala and Goyal 2000). Table 1 summarizes our understanding as stated in these four

assumptions.

Assumption 4: An ESS firm derives benefits from indirectly connected firms at no direct cost to

itself. These indirect benefits are mediated by the intermediate firms.

3.2. Socio-technical Capital as an aggregate resource construct

We define a firm's access to the net benefits (Table 1) from its network as the Sociotechnical

capital of a firm. This term is derived from an umbrella concept called "social capital" and is

broadly defined as "the sum of resources accruing to an individual or group by virtue of their

location in the network of their more or less durable social relations (Adler and Kwon 2000)."

Bourdieu and Wacquant's (1992) define social capital as “the aggregate of the actual or potential

resources which are linked to possession of a durable network of more or less institutionalized

relationship of mutual acquaintance or recognition.” While many definitions for social capital

exist in literature (see Adler and Kwon (2000) for a review) we primarily adopt the view that

Sociotechnical capital is a network resource, created in the alliance network of ESS firms, and

results in higher performance in standards immature markets. This resource is not a substitute for

intrinsic capability, exogenous to the network. Rather, as suggested by Portes (1998), it is a

complement to these exogenous abilities of the firm. Also, given that sociotechnical capital is not

"free" and requires a maintenance cost, the choice of alliance partners has to be a strategic

decision. Olson (1965) points out that alliances create collective benefits. Similarly, Coleman

(1988) and Adler et al. (2000) argue that social capital is a collective good, as against one that is

purely private to the creator or purely public to everyone. The sociotechnical capital of an ESS

vendor is a collective good that is available to everyone who invests in an alliance network.

Social capital has been operationalized mainly through network measures such as centrality,

betweeness, brokerage, prominence, etc (Burt 2000). As discussed in section 3.1 the relative

prominence of an ESS firm in its alliance network is an important determinant of the potential

access to network benefits and therefore an indicator of its market power. By virtue of its market

power an ESS vendor is able to enhance it performance. Thus we propose

16

Page 17: Competition in the Absence of Standards in Enterprise ... · Competition in the Absence of Standards in Enterprise Software Industries: A Social Network Perspective Abstract Whether

Proposition 2: The relative prominence of an ESS firm due its access to social and technical

resources, from both directly and indirectly connected partners is correlated with its

performance.

4. Operationalization of relative firm prominence

We examined various prominence measures in social network literature, which could be used to

represent prominence as conceptualized in this article. Common measures for prominence are

centrality, power, status, proximity, and brokerage (Wasserman and Faust 1994), Bonacich

centrality (Bonacich 1987) and Knoke and Burt’s prominence (Knoke and Burt 1983). However,

existing prominence measures have limitations for this context. For example, while Freeman’s

degree-based measure considers only adjacent actors, his closeness-based centrality is measures

the aggregate path distance of a focal actor to all other actors. The betweenness centrality

measures how many times a particular actor lies on the shortest connecting path between all pairs

of actors. Though closeness-based and betweenness-based prominence measures capture the

network-wide influence of a focal actor, the moderating effect of intermediating actors’

prominence on the focal actor is not captured (Ibarra and Andrews 1993). Bonacich’s measure

(1987) overcomes both limitations, i.e., it considers not only adjacent actors but also indirectly

connected ones; and it also considers the intermediating influence of other actors. However

Bonacich does not provide a rational argument for the nature of the mediation (refer to (Braun

1997)) for a detailed discussion). Therefore to overcome the above limitations we extend the

rational choice model of status (Braun 1997). The critical assumptions of Braun are also

consistent with the recent model of network formation (Bala and Goyal 2000).

We consider a particular instance of a network where each ESS network has formed alliance

links with selected other vendors using a rational criterion. That is, every vendor seeks to

maximize its benefits in excess of costs. The profit maximization function of each firm is

[ ],max i ij

b c i− ∀ (1.3)

where b and are given by equation (1.1) and (1.2) respectively. If we assume that at any point

in time the industry network is representative of collective rational decisions of all firms then we

can solve equation (1.3) to obtain an empirically measurable , a focal firm’s relative

prominence in its network of alliances. This is given by:

i ic

is

17

Page 18: Competition in the Absence of Standards in Enterprise ... · Competition in the Absence of Standards in Enterprise Software Industries: A Social Network Perspective Abstract Whether

1 1

0 0

1 1

n np p

ik ik kj jp k p k j

i

z zs

n n

− −

= == ++ +

∑∑ ∑∑ ∑ r s

(1.4)

The derivation of the empirical metric is given in the appendix.

5. Empirical Study

We collected data from two independent sources from February to April 1999. Our first source

is an un-biased (not related to any vendor or end-user firm) industry group that employed a

consulting organization to collect revenue and other information for nearly a complete set of ESS

vendors. The consulting organization employed a survey instrument and the response rate was

nearly 100%. For our study we first considered all of the top 100 ESS firms (ranked by revenue)

made available to us. Our second source of data was press releases, corporate partnership

documents, personal telephone interviews and websites of ESS vendors. For each of the hundred

firms we collected information on the identity of its alliance partners who were also ESS

vendors. An alliance in our context refers to any formalized inter-organizational arrangement

that includes technology licensing to co-development of products. As per our coding scheme

whenever an ESS firm had an alliance with another vendors we assigned that as a ‘1’ in our

alliance matrix. This way we had a matrix of 1s (or 0s) signifying alliances (or an absence-of

one) among the top 100 firms.

From these 100 ESS vendors we selected 65 for our study. The criteria for selecting these 65

firms were i) each of these vendors should have at least one alliance with others in this group6

and ii) all vendors should be as higher in the industry ranking as possible iii) the sample of firms

should form a completely connected network (that is, the all firms in the sample should belong to

the same component7 of the 100-firm network). The first two criteria would also avoid the

possibility of a sparse network and capture the alliance behavior more accurately. The third

criterion was included because our measure of socio-technical capital was applicable and

comparable across actors that belong to the same component of the network. A similar sampling

6 A similar sampling criterion is also used by Chung et al. (2000) where they include investment banks in their network sample depending on whether the bank was involved in an underwriting deal (p.8). 7 A component in a network is those set of actors that are reachable from all other actors. Wasserman, S. and K. Faust (1994). Social Network Analysis. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.

18

Page 19: Competition in the Absence of Standards in Enterprise ... · Competition in the Absence of Standards in Enterprise Software Industries: A Social Network Perspective Abstract Whether

criterion8 is also used by Chung et al. (Chung, Singh et al. 2000, p. 8) where they include

investment banks in their network sample depending on whether the bank was involved in an

underwriting deal. This method is mainly used to avoid the possibility of sparse networks and to

capture the role of linkages (in our context, alliances). Accordingly, from this 100X100 we

eliminated 30 vendors who had no alliances with others in the top-100 list and hence were

isolates. A large percentage (>60%) of these isolates were small firms. As for the remaining 70

vendors we used the distance matrix procedure in UCINET IV (Borgatti, Everett et al. 1992) and

found that that five vendors had links among themselves but not with the rest of 65 firms. These

were also then eliminated.

The matrix of remaining 65 vendors had a total of 196 alliance linkages. For the purpose of this

research we assume that benefits flow two-way (Bala and Goyal 2000), i.e., it did not matter

which firm initiated the alliance. Figure 1 presents a selected subset of vendors and the alliances

among them. Our final 65 ESS firms offered components from a list of 15 different components

ranging from advanced planning and scheduling packages to business intelligence software.

Example Set of Enterprise System Firms*

Software Component Market ** (number of participating firms***)

SAP America, Oracle Corp., J.D. Edwards, Baan Company, JBA International, System Software Associates, i2 Technologies, PeopleSoft, Inc., Trilogy Software, Kronos Inc., EXE Technologies,HK Systems, Intellution, Wonderware Corp., Aspect Development, McHugh Software International, SCT Corp., Cincom Systems, Inc., GE Fanuc Automation, ILOG, Inc., Manhattan Associates, LIS Warehouse Systems, SynQuest, Inc., USDATA Corp., Adexa, iBASEt, Camstar Systems, Provia Software, ESI/Technologies, PowerCerv Corp., Friedman Corp., ROI Systems, Intrepa

Advanced Planning and Scheduling (19) Customer Response Management (7) E-Business (16) Enterprise Resource Planning (23) Product Data Management (10) Component Management (10) Groupware (10) Supply Chain Planning (23) Forecasting & Demand Management (9) Supply Chain Execution (17) Transportation & Logistics (9) Warehouse Management (16) Advanced Planning and Scheduling (19) Customer Response Management (7) E-Business (16)

* This is a sample of the set of top 65 enterprise system firms considered for this study ** The component categories are based on classification done by the data collection agency. *** Numbers in parentheses indicate the number of vendors offering the software component.

Table 2: Enterprise system firms and component markets they compete in 8 Sampling for network analysis differs from those employed for survey analysis. As opposed to random selection for survey analysis, network sampling needs to be based upon rules of inclusion for each network element - actors, relations and also events in which actors participate. In a network study, the use of inappropriate rules to include network elements can invalidate the study, whereas in survey analysis for individual level studies, similar drawbacks can be often addressed by eliminating the specific data points Laumann, E. O., P. V. Marsden, et al. (1983). The Boundary Specification Problem in Network Analysis. Applied Network Analysis. M. J. Minor. Beverly Hills, Sage: 18-34..

19

Page 20: Competition in the Absence of Standards in Enterprise ... · Competition in the Absence of Standards in Enterprise Software Industries: A Social Network Perspective Abstract Whether

5.1. Discussion of structural elements of the alliance network

Our sampling ensured that the alliance among 65 ESS vendors form a fully connected network,

i.e, all vendors belong to the same component, where a component is defined as those set of

actors that are reachable from all other actors (Wasserman and Faust 1994). In figure 1 we

visually note that most of the potential ‘sponsor’ nodes are highly central9 (Bala and Goyal

2000). This provides a visual clue that the network maybe compared to a ‘linked star’ limit

network as described earlier (Bala and Goyal 2000). We examine the density of alliance

linkages in the network of 65 firms. The theoretical limit of alliance network density is (i.e.

number of possible links) is ( )! 1 !2080

2n n −

= (Wasserman and Faust 1994). As against this, in

our network there are a total of 196 links that suggests a network density of approximately 9.4%

(196/2080). Prior literature on technology alliances (Hagedoorn and Duysters 1999) refers to

networks with 40% density as being highly dense, and hence by comparison our network with

less than 10% density is a lightly dense network. Some qualitative inferences can be drawn from

this observation. First, this implies that even though alliances may yield various network

benefits as described earlier firms have not formed alliances with every other firm. This implies

that ESS vendors have invested in selected alliances – an indication that they are involved in

rational decision-making. Second, some firms (e.g., SAP, i2, Manugistics, Baan & PeopleSoft

with more than 10 links each) have significantly higher number of linkages with direct links

between them suggesting that our network is closer to the theoretical limit network of a linked-

star (Bala and Goyal 2000). At the same time it is also apparent that the non-sponsor types are

not only connected to the sponsor, rather they have linkages between themselves as well. This

implies that it is not a strict Nash state of the industry and our current network is not a limit

network. A representative sample of linkages (given in Table 3) shows that the distribution of

linkages is highly skewed towards a few vendors.

Vendor Degree Centrality

Oracle 25

SAP 23

9 For clarity the entire set of 65 vendors is not depicted; however, in the complete network graph this observation holds similarly. This figure was generated in UCINET VI with the node labels representing the firm.

20

Page 21: Competition in the Absence of Standards in Enterprise ... · Competition in the Absence of Standards in Enterprise Software Industries: A Social Network Perspective Abstract Whether

i2 13

Baan, Manugistics , PeopleSoft 11

J.D. Edwards 10

Kronos, Vastera 8

Manhattan Associate 7

Optum, McHugh, SCT, Trilogy 6

Foxboro, SynQuest, Descartes, Camstar, LIS, Logility, Intellution, ILOG 5

EXE, SSA, JBA, Indus, iBASEt, OSDI, Adexa 4

Western Data, Provia, ABB, Symix, Wonderware, POMS, Aspen, Industri-Matematik,

STG, Gensym, Datastream 3

Table 3: Degree centrality of vendors ranked by their software revenue

5.2. Analysis and discussion of relative firm prominence in the alliance network

We computed the relative firm prominence of each firm given by equation 1.4 as also Braun’s

measure using Matlab. The alliance matrix was the input variable to the Matlab procedure. Since

we had assumed that in any alliance initiated by any firm the benefits flow both ways the input

the alliance matrix was first dichotomized. Further, both alliance partners were assumed to

equally incur costs when either licensing their product interfaces or involving in joint product

development. Then we transformed the matrix of relationships into a normalized column matrix.

For example, for all 23 partners who maintained alliances with a top focal vendor the strength of

relationship of each alliance partner with the focal vendor was normalized to 1/23 in the matrix.

The result matrix was asymmetric since each vendor had varying number alliance linkages. We

computed the measure of prominence (equation 1.4) and Braun’s measure using this transformed

matrix.

Other social network measures of centrality and prominence are already available in UCINET IV

(Borgatti, Everett et al. 1992). In Table 4 the correlation coefficients of the firm prominence

metrics with the performance are reported. While it is less meaningful to compare the Pearson

correlation coefficient of different prominence measures these are more useful as supplements to

the theoretical arguments presented earlier since most research on prominence and status utilizes

centrality measures incorporated in UCINET IV. We computed Bonacich’s power measure for

two different values of β (0.05 and 0.12) - the attenuation factor in Bonacich’s power measure

21

Page 22: Competition in the Absence of Standards in Enterprise ... · Competition in the Absence of Standards in Enterprise Software Industries: A Social Network Perspective Abstract Whether

(1987). The maximum value of β we tested was 0.12 which is the theoretical maximum10

specified by Bonacich. Other measures presented are Freeman’s closeness and betweenness

centrality. We also computed the correlations for sub-samples. We reasoned, as discussed earlier,

that maintaining alliances requires substantial investments, which small vendors (with smaller

resource base) may not be able to afford. By computing correlations for the top 30 and top 20

vendors we controlled for the differences in vendors’ resource bases. We found that the socio-

technical capital is more strongly correlated with performance indicating that for larger players

who are able to afford maintaining alliances – increasing socio-technical is a more effective

strategy.

Network Measure N=65 *

Correlation

(Sig. Prob)

N=30 *

Correlation

(Sig. Prob)

N=20 *

Correlation

(Sig. Prob)

Modified firm prominence

(equation ..) 0.5517 (0.000) 0.774 (0.000) 0.767 (0.000)

Freeman's Closeness 0.212 (0.0899) 0.587 (0.001) 0.626 (0.0899)

Braun's Status Measure 0.5504 (0.000) 0.760 (0.000) 0.748 (0.000)

Freeman's Betweeness 0.5327 (0.000) 0.764 (0.000) 0.790 (0.000)

Bonacich's Power (beta=+0.05) 0.4902 (0.000) 0.753 (0.000) 0.755 (0.000)

Bonacich's Power (beta=+0.12) 0.4024 (0.0009) 0.717 (0.00) 0.729 (0.0009)

Outdegrees 0.3179 (0.0099) 0.646 (0.000) 0.699 (0.0099)

Table 4: Correlation of Network Prominence Measures with Revenue

While the modified measure of firm prominence has among the highest correlation with revenue,

closeness centrality is the least correlated. However, in general all measures of a firm’s relative

status or firm prominence by virtue of their alliances are significant thus lending support to

proposition 2. Interestingly, the correlation of Bonacich’s power measure with firm performance

decreases with increasing value of β, implying that while indirectly connected firms do

contribute to firm prominence, their relative influence is small. Similarly, Braun's measure is

also well correlated well with firm performance. The difference between our modified firm

prominence and that of Braun’s is that while we consider all indirectly connected actors, Braun

10 The maximum theoretical value is the reciprocal of the largest eigenvalue of the input matrix.

22

Page 23: Competition in the Absence of Standards in Enterprise ... · Competition in the Absence of Standards in Enterprise Software Industries: A Social Network Perspective Abstract Whether

only considers the influence of adjacent ones and those that are two path lengths away.

Outdegrees, closeness and betweenness measures are presented as examples of common network

measures and it should be noted that these are measure of alliances only without any

consideration of intrinsic firm capabilities. It is to be noted that while closeness and betweenness

measures capture the network wide influence they do not satisfy all our conceptual requirements

of how relative prominence evolves in our industry. They are presented as a matter of academic

interest and may have more meaning in relation to other network constructs such as clustering,

and multi-mode exchanges that are beyond the scope of this paper.

6. Theoretical and managerial implications

A key practical implication of this research is that in multi-component industries with

complementary products, alliances are initiated not merely to provide technical compatibility,

but also to garner social resources. Firms benefit by complementing their intrinsic resources with

collective benefits from an alliance network, and are successful if they increase their relative

prominence in the network. This work also suggests that software product managers should not

only consider resources of their direct partners but also those of indirect partners in any decisions

regarding alliances.

6.1. Implications for IS research

The contribution of this paper to IS research is many fold. First, it is one of the first works to

study standards competition in IS literature. While standards have been studied from an intra-

organizational perspective in IS, a second important contribution of this work pertains to linking

the notion of corporate IT standards to standards based competition of the software firms

themselves. The need to incorporate such demand-side mechanisms into determining prominence

at the supply side has been called for in other fields as well (Stewart 1996). In the software

industry, the most important supply side mechanism that contributes to the prominence of a firm

is its choice of standards for technical compatibility. However, we point out that that an

organization's selection of its ESS vendors is based on its own corporate IT standards. Given

that corporate standards include other organizational considerations such as availability of

consultants, training programs, etc., we argue that ESS firms take these considerations into

account during the selection of their partners. We term these non-technical factors as creating

benefits in the social dimension and contributing to organizational user perceptions of

23

Page 24: Competition in the Absence of Standards in Enterprise ... · Competition in the Absence of Standards in Enterprise Software Industries: A Social Network Perspective Abstract Whether

compatibility. This research then incorporates both the social and technical benefits in its

conceptualization of sociotechnical capital. A third contribution of this work is the introduction

of social network theory to understanding standards competition of software firms. The richness

of this framework in creating empirically tractable measures allows us to overcome the

limitations of some of economics based modeling as discussed in section 2.

Finally, the theories and model outlined in this work is rich enough to help examine realistically,

a variety of issues in any industry that is dependent on standards. For example, a longitudinal

study of a software industry using our model can provide insights into the standards formation

process itself. Even though we consider the transient stage of this industry, i.e., during the

absence of uniform standards, we could easily represent equilibrium or end stages such as pure

oligopolies or a technological monopoly by manipulating the level of the exogenous resources of

the software firm. This research can also be extended to understand competition even in the

presence of industry wide, open standards, as the social dimension becomes the only

differentiating basis for competition. For example, it may help to understand how software firms

use the resources in the social dimension such as reputation signaling from trade shows, joint

product announcements, etc., to derive competitive advantage. Our model can also be applied to

IS decisions in intra-organizational situations. For example, systems supporting organizational

units can be modeled as a network with linkages between them representing flow of resources

such as data on the technical side and expertise, process skills on the social end. While semantic

data integration and a common infrastructure platform (Wybo and Goodhue 1995) will call for a

common vendor and can deliver the technical benefits, it may deliver lesser benefits on the non-

technical dimension as compared to a "best-of-breed" system. If best-of-breed systems imply

full user commitment and involvement at the organizational sub-unit level, and common vendor

implies full technical compatibility, our measures can provide a way to compute the efficiency of

each organizational unit under varying system heterogeneity.

Further, identifying the right unit to invest systems resources is of great importance in IS (Keen

1991), and our network model can help guide this decision. For example, one can construct an

intra-organizational network of workflow and resource inter-dependence (Wybo and Goodhue

1995). This network can then be compared to a systems network, with each link representing

component compatibility. Similar to the operationalization of Sociotechnical capital, network

measures can be used to explore the relationship between organizational resource networks and

24

Page 25: Competition in the Absence of Standards in Enterprise ... · Competition in the Absence of Standards in Enterprise Software Industries: A Social Network Perspective Abstract Whether

systems compatibility networks. High prominence in the organizational network maybe a

pointer towards greater systems investments.

6.2. Implications for research in other areas

Our work has implications for researchers interested in studying tie-strength of alliances. In the

information systems context, firms exhibit varying degrees of partnerships depending upon their

level on involvement with each other. For example, Oracle (http://partner.oracle.com) facilitates

three levels of partnerships with decreasing levels of access to product knowledge, and

marketing and sales information; Program Member Level Certified Solution Partner (CSP) and

Certified Advantage Partner (CAP) Each of the above implies a different level of commitment

both financial and strategic. The concept of aggregate strength of relationship proposed in our

theory can help model the levels of these strategic partnerships seen in the software industry.

Such a construct can then be used to understand the implications of firm strategies such as the

trade-offs between tight coupling with smaller firms (presumably at a lower cost, and hence a

larger number of them) versus those with select larger firms.

This research also makes significant contributions to research in social network theory. Burt

(2000) says, “Research will better accumulate if we focus on network mechanisms responsible

for social capital effects rather than trying to integrate across metaphors of social capital loosely

tied to distant empirical indicators”. In our research we identify some of these mechanisms by a

grounded study of the software industry through theories that support the underlying the linkage

formation. Our paper contributes to network theory by developing a model of resource transfer

and conceptualizing a new prominence measure that is applicable to any context where resources

can flow from indirectly connected actors, even in the absence of direct investments. The paper

also attempts to answer a call for integrating substantive theories from other disciplines in order

develop network analysis and proceed from a unit level of analysis to a network level (Monge

and Contractor 1998). We have attempted to bring together diverse literature on compatibility

standards; technological change and resource transfer in order to synthesize our network level

theory of resource transfer.

25

Page 26: Competition in the Absence of Standards in Enterprise ... · Competition in the Absence of Standards in Enterprise Software Industries: A Social Network Perspective Abstract Whether

6.3. Limitations

A limitation of our research is that we have not explicitly considered adapters and integrators

directly into the network representation as actors. This may be important since a firm gains

prominence through relations with consultants and adapters thus perpetuating the perception of

compatibility. Multi-mode network analysis allows for this inclusion of heterogonous actors.

Similarly we have not explicitly parameterized the number of markets in which firms compete

versus cooperate; this may be needed for an empirical extension to this study. Further,

measurement of knowledge spillover effects, advantages of absorptive capacity and other factors

in the social dimension may be necessary to analytically compute actual social resources. These

limitations may be addressed through an extensive empirical study.

Figure 1: Alliance network of a subset of our sample of the ESS industry

References

Adler, P. S. and S. Kwon (2000). Social Capital: The good, the bad and the ugly. Knowledge and

Social Capital. E. L. Lesser. Boston, MA, Butterworth-Heineman: 89-115.

26

Page 27: Competition in the Absence of Standards in Enterprise ... · Competition in the Absence of Standards in Enterprise Software Industries: A Social Network Perspective Abstract Whether

Ahuja, G. (2000). "Collaboration, networks, structural holes, and Innovation: A longitudinal

study." Administrative Science Quarterly 45(-): 425-455.

Ahuja, G. (2000). "The Duality of Collaboration: Inducements and Opportunities in the

Formation of Interfirm Linkages." Strategic Management Journal 21(-): 317-343.

Antonelli, C. (1994). "Localized technological change and the evolution of standards as

economic institutions." Information Economics and Policy 6: 195-216.

Argote, L. and P. Ingram (2000). "Knowledge transfer: A basis for competitive advantage for

firms." Organizational behavior and human decision process 82(1): 150-169.

Axelrod, R., W. Mitchell, et al. (1995). "Coalition formation in standard-setting alliances."

Management Science 41(9): 1493-1508.

Baker, W. (1990). "Market networks and corporate behavior." American Journal of Sociology

96(3): 589-625.

Bala, V. and S. Goyal (2000). "A noncooperative model of network formation." Econometrica

68(5): 1181-1229.

Barley, S., R (1990). "The alignment of technology and structure through roles and networks."

Administrative Science Quarterly 35(1): 61-103.

Benjamin, B. A. and J. M. Podolny (1999). "Status, quality, and social order in the California

wine industry." Administrative Science Quarterly 44(3): 563-589.

Bonacich, P. (1987). "Power and Centrality: A family of measures." American Journal of

Sociology 92(5): 1170-1182.

Borgatti, S. P., M. G. Everett, et al. (1992). UCINET IV network analysis software: Reference

manual and User’s Guide. Columbia, SC, Analytic Technologies.

Bourdieu, P. and L. J. D. Wacquant (1992). An invitation to reflexive sociology. Chicago, IL,

University of Chicago Press.

Braun, N. (1997). "A rational choice model of network status." Social networks 19(-): 129-142.

Burt, R. S. (1987). "Social contagion and innovation, cohesion versus structural equivalence."

American Journal of Sociology 92(-): 1287-1335.

Burt, R. S. (2000). The Network Structure of Social Capital. Research in organizational

behavior. B. M. Staw. Greenwich, CT, JAI Press. -: -.

Burt, R. S. (2000). Structural Holes versus Network Closure as Social Capital. Social Capital:

Theory and Research. R. S. Burt. Chicago, Aldine de Gruyter. 2001: -.

27

Page 28: Competition in the Absence of Standards in Enterprise ... · Competition in the Absence of Standards in Enterprise Software Industries: A Social Network Perspective Abstract Whether

Chatfield, A., Takeoka and P. Yetton (2000). "Strategic payoff from EDI as a function of EDI

embeddedness." Journal of Management Information Systems 16(4): 195-224.

Chellappa, R. and N. Saraf (2000). Standards and compatibility in non-standardized software

industries. Americas Conference on Information Systems, Long Beach, CA, AIS.

Chung, S., H. Singh, et al. (2000). "Complementarity, status similarity and social capital as

drivers of alliance formation." Strategic management journal 21(-): 1-22.

Cohen, W. M. and D. A. Levinthal (1990). "Absorptive capacity: A new perspective on learning

and innovation." Administrative Science Quarterly 35(-): 128-152.

Coleman, J., S (1988). "Social capital in the creation of human capital." American Journal of

Sociology 94(-): S95-S120.

Conner, K. R. and C. K. Prahalad (1996). "A knowledge-based theory of the firm: Knowledge

versus opportunism." Organization Science 7(5): 477-501.

Contractor, N., S, D. Seibold, R, et al. (1996). "Interactional influence in the structuring of media

use in groups." Human Communication Research 22(4): 451-481.

Davenport, T. H. (1998). "Putting the Enterprise into the Enterprise system." Harvard Business

Review July-August: 121-131.

David, P. A. and S. Greenstein (1990). "The economics of compatibility standards: An

introduction to recent research." Economics of Innovation and New Technology 1-2(1):

3-42.

Dwyer, F. R., P. H. Schurr, et al. (1987). "Developing buyer-seller relationships." Journal of

Marketing 51(2): 11-27.

Economides, N. (1989). "Desirability of Compatibility in the Absence of Network Externalities."

The American Economic Review 79(5): 1165-1181.

Farrell, J. and G. Saloner (1992). "Converters, Compatibility, and the Control of Interfaces."

Journal of Industrial Economics 40(1): 9-35.

Fomin, V. and T. Keil (2000). Standardization: bridging the gap between economic and social

theory. Proceedings of ICIS 2000, Brisbane, Australia, -.

Galbraith, J. R. (1973). Designing complex organizations. Reading, MA, Addison-Wesley.

Gordon, S. (1993). "Standardization of Information Systems and Technology at Multinational

Companies." Journal of Global Information Management 1(4): 5-14.

28

Page 29: Competition in the Absence of Standards in Enterprise ... · Competition in the Absence of Standards in Enterprise Software Industries: A Social Network Perspective Abstract Whether

Hagedoorn, J. and G. Duysters (1999). Learning in dynamic inter-firm networks - the efficacy of

multiple contacts. Work-in-progress US NSF. -, -: -.

Henderson, R., M and K. Clark, B (1990). "Architectural innovation: The reconfiguration of

existing product technologies and the failure of established firms." Administrative

Science Quarterly 35(-): 9-30.

Holm, D. B., K. Eriksson, et al. (1999). "Creating value through mutual commitment to business

network relationships." Strategic Management Journal 29(-): 467-486.

Ibarra, H. and S. B. Andrews (1993). "Power, social influence, and sense making: Effects of

network centrality and proximity on employee perceptions." Administrative Science

Quarterly 38: 277-303.

Katz, M. L. and C. Shapiro (1985). "Network Externalities, Competition and Compatibility." The

American Economic Review 75(3): 424-440.

Kauffman, R. J., J. McAndrews, et al. (2000). "Opening the "Black Box" of Network

Externalities in Network Adoption." Information Systems Research 11(1): 61-82.

Kayworth, T. R. and V. Sambamurthy (2000). "Facilitating localized exploitation and enterprise-

wide integration in the use of IT infrastructures: The role of PC/LAN infrastructure

standards." The DATA BASE for advances in information systems 31(4): 54-77.

Keen, P. W. (1991). Shaping the Future. Cambridge, MA, Harvard Business School Press.

Knoke, D. and R. S. Burt (1983). Prominence. Applied Network Analysis. R. S. Burt and M.

Minor, J. Beverly Hills, CA, Sage.

Kogut, B., G. Walker, et al. (1995). "Cooperation and entry induction as an extension of

technological rivalry." Research Policy 24(-): 77-95.

Kotabe, M., A. Sahay, et al. (1996). "Emerging role of technology licensing in the development

of global product strategy: Conceptual framework and research opportunities." Journal of

Marketing 60(1): 73-88.

Laumann, E. O., P. V. Marsden, et al. (1983). The Boundary Specification Problem in Network

Analysis. Applied Network Analysis. M. J. Minor. Beverly Hills, Sage: 18-34.

Liebeskind, J. P., A. L. Oliver, et al. (1996). "Social networks, learning and flexibility: Sourcing

scientfic knowledge in new biotechnology firms." Organization Science 7(-): 428-443.

Malone, T. W. (1987). "Modeling Coordination in Organizations and Markets." Management

Science 33(10): 1317-1331.

29

Page 30: Competition in the Absence of Standards in Enterprise ... · Competition in the Absence of Standards in Enterprise Software Industries: A Social Network Perspective Abstract Whether

Matutes, C. and P. Regibeau (1988). ""Mix and match": product compatibility without network

externalities." RAND Journal of Economics 19(2): 221-234.

Metcalfe, J. S. and I. Miles (1994). "Standards, selection and variety: an evolutionary approach."

Information Economics and Policy 6: 243-268.

Monge, P. and N. C. Contractor (1998). Emergence of communication networks. Handbook of

organizational communication. L. L. Putnam. Thousand Oaks, CA, Sage. -: -.

Monteiro, E. (2000). ANT and information infrastructure. The Dynamics of Global

Infrastructures. C. Ciborra, Oxford University Press. In press...

Nonaka, I. and N. Konno (1998). "The concept of "Ba": Building a foundation for knowledge

creation." California Management Review 40(3): 40-54.

Olson, M. J. (1965). The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups.

Cambridge, MA, Harvard University Press.

Padgett, J. F. and Ansell (1993). "Robust Action and the Rise of the Medici, 1400-1434."

American Journal of Sociology 98(6): 1259-1319.

Podolny, J., M (1993). "A status-based model of market competition." American Journal of

Sociology 98(4): 829-872.

Podolny, J. M., T. E. Stuart, et al. (1996). "Networks, Knowledge and Niches: Competition in the

Worldwide Semiconductor Industry, 1984-1991." American Journal of Sociology 102(2):

659-89.

Saloner, G. (1990). "Economic Issues in Computer Interface Standardization." Economic

Innovation and New Technology 1: 135-156.

Shan, W. J., G. Walker, et al. (1994). "Interfirm Cooperation and Startup Innovation in the

Biotechnology Industry." Strategic Management Journal 15(5): 387-394.

Stewart, D. (1996). "Managing Market Structure: Achieving Competitive Advantage and Market

Dominance." Journal of Management Issues 8: 13-34.

Stuart, T. E. (2000). "Interorganizational alliances and the performance of firms: A study of

growth and innovation rates in high technology industries." Strategic Management

Journal 21(-): 791-811.

Stuart, T. E., H. Hoang, et al. (1999). "Interorganizational endorsements and the performance of

entrepreneurial ventures." Administrative Science Quarterly 44(2): 315-349.

30

Page 31: Competition in the Absence of Standards in Enterprise ... · Competition in the Absence of Standards in Enterprise Software Industries: A Social Network Perspective Abstract Whether

Suarez, F. F. and J. M. Utterback (1995). "Dominant Designs and the Survival of Firms."

Strategic Management Journal 16(6): 415-430.

Tichy, N. M., M. L. Tushman, et al. (1979). "Social Network Analysis for Organizations."

Academy of Management. The Academy of Management Review 4(4): 507.

Walker, G., B. Kogut, et al. (1997). "Social Capital, Structural Holes and the Formation of an

Industry Network." Organization Science 8(2): 109-125.

Wasserman, S. and K. Faust (1994). Social Network Analysis. Cambridge, Cambridge

University Press.

West, J. and J. Dedrick (2000). "Innovation and Control in Standards Architectures: The Rise

and Fall of Japan's PC-98." Information Systems Research 11(2): 197-216.

Wybo, M. D. and D. L. Goodhue (1995). "Using interdependence as a predictor of data

standards: Theoretical and measurement issues." Information & Management 29(-): 317-

329.

Yang, J. and M. P. Papazoglou (2000). "Interoperation support for electronic business."

Association for Computing Machinery, Communications of the ACM 43(6): 39-47.

Zeggelink, E., P.H., F. Stokman, N, et al. (1996). "The emergence of groups in the evolution of

friendship networks." Journal of Mathematical Sociology 21(1-2): 29-55.

31

Page 32: Competition in the Absence of Standards in Enterprise ... · Competition in the Absence of Standards in Enterprise Software Industries: A Social Network Perspective Abstract Whether

Appendix A

Our goal is to reduce the solution to equation … to an empirically tractable form. Since all our

relationships are normalized, we represent as a fraction of vendorijr j ’s dependence on all other

vendors directly connected to it. Therefore we can construct an adjacency matrix R as a nXn

column stochastic matrix with elements , such that for eachijr j , 1i

rij =∑ . From equation … and

… we have

...

i ij jj

i ij j ij jk k ij jk kl lj j k j k l

c r s

b r e r r e r r r e

=

= + +

∑ ∑∑ ∑∑∑ +

z

(1.5)

We can simplify the benefits equation by using power matrices of R. Consider an array of power

matrices where 0 1 21 ( 0) , , ,.... nij i j i j ij ij ik ij jk in

j

z z r z r r= ≠= = = =∑ . In matrix notation can be

represented as , and similarly

2ikz

2 .z R R= p pz R= where p is the path length between two firms.

Therefore equation … can be re-written in matrix notation as

(1.6) 2 3

1

PP

i ij j ij j ij j ij j i ik kj j j j p k

b r e z e z e z e b z=

= + + + − − − ⇒ =∑ ∑ ∑ ∑ ∑∑ pe

)e

or further reduced to

(1.7) 1

( .n

p

p

b Z=

= ∑

Therefore we can now write the profit maximization problem of a firm as

1

max ( . )n

pij j

p jZ e r s

=

∑ ∑ (1.8)

We assume that all firms are rational and will allocate their investments so as to maximize

their profits, so we consider the first order condition of equation (1.8) by differentiating with

respect to , and re-arranging the terms we have

ijr

ijr

(1.9) 1

0

np

jp k

s z−

=

= ∑∑ jk ke

and in matrix notation this can be written as

32

Page 33: Competition in the Absence of Standards in Enterprise ... · Competition in the Absence of Standards in Enterprise Software Industries: A Social Network Perspective Abstract Whether

(1.10) 1

0

( .n

p

p

S Z−

=

= ∑ )e

a

where is the column vector of statuses of the firms. S

Benefit is a function of the intrinsic capability of a firm, similar to Braun (1997) we assume a

linear form ofb , and substituting for cost, we have for any k , (1 ) 1a n e= + −

11 1

kk

cen n

+= =

+ +1 1 .

1 jn+

+ ∑ kj jr s . Multiplying both sides by1

0

np

ikp k

z−

=∑∑ , we have from

equation(1.9):

1 1

0 0

1 1

n np p

ik ik kj jp k p k j

i

z zs

n n

− −

= == ++ +

∑∑ ∑∑ ∑ r s (1.11)

and in matrix notation we have

1

0 1

. .

1

n np p

p p

Z J ZS

n

= =

+

=+

∑ ∑ S

J

(1.12)

We can further reduce these terms for empirical assessment. Re-arranging equation (1.12), we

have where 1( )S I X Y−= −

1

0 ,1 1

n np p

p p 1

Z ZX

n n

== =Y =

+ +

∑ ∑ . The power series of is as follows S

1

1 10 1

1 0

1 1. .1 1 1 1

ln np p

n l np pp p

p l p

Z ZS I Z J Z

n n n n

− =∞ −= =

= = =

= − = + + + +

∑ ∑∑ ∑ ∑

0J (1.13)

The above power series is valid since 1 11

n pZp

n

∑= <+

. From Kincaid and Cheney (1996), we can

confirm the existence of the inverse if the norm0

0 11

1n

p

p

n pZp

nZ n

=

∑= ≤ ⇒+

≤ +∑ , where 0

np

pZ

=∑ is also

33

Page 34: Competition in the Absence of Standards in Enterprise ... · Competition in the Absence of Standards in Enterprise Software Industries: A Social Network Perspective Abstract Whether

a stochastic matrix with column sums equal to . Letn0

1 np

p

Z Gn =

=∑ , then the inverse is always

said to exist if and only if ( )1nG

n+

≤ . MatrixG , being a column stochastic, its norm is

1 1max 1

n

ijj n i

G a≤ ≤

=

= ⇒∑ . Since in our case, the existence of the inverse is confirmed. ( )1n + >

11

0 0

1. .l n

p

l p

Z−

=

= =

∑ ∑ 1 1

n n

+ +

∑ ∑p

=∞

1S e= ⇒

l

pZ

n n

n

For further empirical measurements e and can be reduced to: c

1

0 1

11 1

l lp p

l np

l p

Z Zc Rs R J Z J

n n n n

=∞=

= =

= = = + +

∑ ∑ . This can be further

reduced to 1

11

0 0

( )1 1

n

n lpp

p l

J−

− =∞=

= =

= + +

∑∑ ∑e Z .

.p

34