ClimatSphere. The newsletter on the economics of climate change

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 8/14/2019 ClimatSphere. The newsletter on the economics of climate change

    1/6

    Baptiste Raymond and Anas Delbosc

    also describe the benefits of project-based

    mechanisms, which are being adopted around

    the world as complements to emissions tra-

    ding schemes. Although everyone agrees onthe benefits of either a cap-and-trade or a

    mandatory tax, their practical implementation

    in the short term, as well as the coverage of all

    sectors at once, would be difficult if not impos-

    sible. Project-based mechanisms can help,

    making these instruments more effective by

    extending a price signal for carbon and by

    indirectly linking different carbon markets.

    On the international scale, the implemen-

    tation of emissions abatement measures

    comes in general with discussions on the

    competitiveness of the economic players or

    national economies affected. These discus-

    sions have been exacerbated by the econo-

    mic crisis: if financing emissions reductions

    efforts halfway around the world becomes

    more difficult to justify, financing investments

    at home begins to look more attractive.

    Therein lies the attraction of the domestic off-

    set project mechanisms which are being

    created in Europe, the US and Japan.

    Our survey of project mechanisms would

    ClimatSphereThe newsletter on the economics of c l imate change

    not be complete without mentioning the

    agricultural and forestry sectors, for which,

    in the medium term, project-based mecha-

    nisms seem to be more effective. This is the

    subject of the final article by Mariana

    Deheza and Valentin Bellassen.

    Three lessons can be drawn from this survey

    of projects. First, projects make it possible to

    identify new sources of emissions reductions.

    Second, the perfect project-based mecha-

    nism does not exist; we have to learn how to

    live with imperfect mechanisms and improve

    them as time goes on. Finally, project-basedmechanisms improve the effectiveness of

    existing tools by broadening the scope of the

    price signal sent to the players under a carbon

    constraint. They can link two mechanisms and

    supplement either a cap-and-trade system or

    taxes. This latter point is important to remem-

    ber, with the discussion on the French level

    about the climate-energy contribution, on the

    European level about the proposed introduc-

    tion of a carbon tax, and also on the interna-

    tional level regarding both the plans for federal

    a cap-and-trade system in the US and the

    upcoming Copenhagen conference. G

    Benot Leguet

    [email protected]

    Tel. : +33 1 58 50 98 18

    Regardless of the outcome of the

    Copenhagen negotiations, one thing is

    certain: the post-Kyoto world will include

    project-based mechanisms. Project-based

    mechanisms, the best known of which is theClean Development Mechanism (CDM), are

    frequently criticized for being difficult to

    implement, letting host countries off the hook

    because they are voluntary, and even for

    being bad for the environment. Criticisms can

    lead to improvements in such mechanisms.

    However, they must be balanced by conside-

    rations of the context, and their benefits.

    This kind of critical and necessary analysis

    has been offered by two project-based

    mechanism specialists, Noriko Fujiwara, of the

    Center for European Policy Studies (CEPS),

    and Maria-Bernadete Sarmiento Gutierrez, of

    the Brazilian Institute for Applied Economic

    Research (IPEA). They describe the potential

    evolution from project mechanisms to "pro-

    grammatic" mechanisms, the purpose of

    which is to accredit programs of activities that

    reduce emissions, up to and including secto-

    ral emissions reduction commitments. We

    would like to take this opportunity to thank

    them for agreeing to answer our questions.

    Project mechanisms: Ancient history?

    The role of projects in the futureinternational climate agreement

    Beginning of

    negotiations

    on the Kyoto

    Protocol project

    mechanisms

    Kyoto Protocol Marrakesh

    agreements

    on Kyoto

    projects

    First recorded

    CDM project

    1989 1995 1997 2001 2004 2007 2009 2012

    Copenhagen

    Conference: expected

    reform of project

    mechanisms

    Initial voluntary

    project

    mechanisms

    Projects Directive

    linking the EU ETS

    to Kyoto project

    mechanisms

    Implementation

    of domestic offset

    projects in

    New Zealand

    Implementation

    of domestic

    offset projects

    in France,

    Germany

    and Spain

    Development

    of project

    mechanisms in

    the US and

    Australia

    Introduction

    of the

    "programmatic"

    CDM

    N15 3rd quarter 2009

    Including developing countries in

    the future international agreement

    through project-based mechanisms

    Insights from Noriko Fujiwara and

    Maria-Bernadete Sarmiento Gutierrez

    A bull market for domestic

    offset projects

    Benot Leguet

    Projects: a complement to the ETS

    Baptiste Raymond and Anas Delbosc

    Project mechanisms in figures

    Antoine Samzun

    and Raphal Trotignon

    Conciliating national caps and

    incentives for projects

    Valentin Bellassen and Mariana Deheza

    Content

    E ditorial

    Source: Mission Climat of Caisse des Dpts.

    The earliest projects, which were implemented on a voluntary basis, date back to 1989. Nevertheless, project

    mechanisms were codified by the United Nations only in 2001 in Marrakesh. Since then, an increasing

    number of countries have been using them as a supplement to their national emissions reduction policies.

  • 8/14/2019 ClimatSphere. The newsletter on the economics of climate change

    2/6

    2

    I nterview

    Including developing countries

    in the future international

    agreement through project-based mechanismsInsights from Noriko Fujiwara, Head of Climate Change

    at the Centre for European Policy Studies (CEPS),

    and Maria-Bernadete Sarmiento Gutierrez, Senior

    Researcher at the Institute of Applied Economic

    Research (IPEA) in Rio de Janeiro.

    Could the cap-and-trade systems

    developed in industrialized countries

    (EU, USA, Australia, Japan) be

    extended to the major emerging

    countries?

    Noriko Fujiwara (N.F.) : Yes, as far as a

    cap-and-trade system appeal to them as a

    viable mitigation option. An international

    framework could be created to reward

    national mitigation actions by developing

    countries in exchange for financial andtechnical assistance. The governments

    would then find an opportunity to benefit

    from early additional domestic measures

    such as a cap-and-trade system. Another

    approach would be voluntary adoption of

    binding sectoral targets supported by a

    sectoral trading system.

    Maria-Bernadete Sarmiento Gutierrez

    (M-B.S.G.): The principle of common but

    differentiated responsibilities has to be

    adapted. Any effective international climate

    change agreement will have to include

    major emerging countries, so as to avoid

    cross-border carbon leakages. There are no

    major conceptual and logistical impedi-

    ments to extending existing cap-and-trade

    systems. The major one is of a political

    nature: governments from emerging coun-

    tries, by and large, refuse to take responsi-

    bility for a net contribution to reduce GHG

    gases on the basis of the historical respon-sibility criterion.

    How do you expect the Kyoto

    Protocols project-based mechanisms

    to evolve in such a post-2012 frame-

    work?

    M-B.S.G.: So far, the roles the Clean

    Development Mechanism (CDM) and Joint

    Implementation (JI) have played in finan-

    cing sustainable development have been

    limited by high transaction costs, policy

    uncertainty, technology risk, etc. To be

    more effective, these project mechanisms

    will have to be streamlined through pro-

    grammatic, sectoral, and/or policy-based

    approaches, which will complement each

    other. Reforms will be needed to provide

    new methodologies for energy efficiency

    projects, new ways of evaluating projects

    with long pay-back periods, or to foster

    strategic transfers of new technology.

    N.F.: The main challenge is how to

    transform the CDM from pure offsetting to

    crediting. One approach could be sectoral

    crediting based on no-lose targets.

    Baselines could be gradually tightened

    and translated into absolute caps for a

    cap-and-trade system. An emerging

    country could thus voluntarily adopt bin-

    ding sectoral targets, operate sectoral JI,

    and introduce a mandatory sectoral tra-

    ding system. Least developed countries

    should however remain eligible to the

    CDM.

    Are global sectoral agreements

    realistic for including major emerging

    countries?

    N.F.: Technology cooperation would

    hold the key for global sectoral approaches

    to evolve from a voluntary industry-driven

    exercise to agreements endorsed by

    governments of both industrialized andmajor emerging countries. One interesting

    example would be the Asia-Pacific

    Partnership on Clean Development and

    Climate aimed at enhancing incentives for

    development, deployment and transfers of

    clean technologies and built upon a public-

    private joint effort.

    M-B.S.G.:A definite positive response

    has already been made by certain indus-

    tries. The Cement Sustainability Initiative

    illustrates this: major companies from

    Annex and non-Annex I countries have

    agreed to common standards for monito-

    ring and reporting CO2 with the final objec-

    tive of developing a trading scheme. For

    other sectors not exposed to international

    competition, governments will have to take

    the lead, for example in the transportation

    and energy sectors. G

    Interview by Nicolas Stephan

    [email protected]

    Tel.: +33 1 58 50 98 39

    The views expressed are attributable only to the

    authors in a personal capacity and not to any

    institution with which they are associated.

    Emissions trends in developing countries:

    the contribution of the CDM

    By 2012, the Kyoto

    Protocols project-based

    mechanisms are likely

    to generate significant

    emissions abatement in

    developing countries.

    Indeed in 2012, about 3 %

    of their emissions should be

    avoided. Renegotiating the

    rules of project mechanisms

    and completing them withother mitigation instruments

    is necessary to further limit

    emissions growth in

    developing countries.

    28

    Estimated GHG

    emissions

    without CDM

    +116% Estimated GHG

    emissions

    with CDM: +110%

    26

    Greenhousegase

    missions

    innon-

    AnnexIcountries(

    GtCO2e/y)

    24

    22

    20

    18

    16

    14

    12

    1990 1995 2000 2005 2008 2012

    10

    Source: estimates of Mission Climat of Caisse des Dpts, from UNEP Risoe and World Resources Institute data.

  • 8/14/2019 ClimatSphere. The newsletter on the economics of climate change

    3/6

    P olicies and measures

    A bull market for domestic

    offset projects

    Joint ImplementationCreated by the Kyoto Protocol, Joint

    Implementation (JI) was the first mecha-

    nism for "domestic offset projects", rewar-

    ding emissions reductions in the countries

    subject to a Kyoto commitment with carbon

    credits. Four years after the JI was laun-

    ched in late 2005, more than 200 projects

    are in development with potential emissions

    reductions of approximately 350 MtCO2 by

    2012. The majority of these projects is loca-

    ted in Russia and Ukraine and employs avariety of technologies: flaring methane

    with recovery of heat or electricity in the

    power generation sector, incineration of

    industrial greenhouse gases, power gene-

    ration from renewable energy sources and

    improvements in energy efficiency. The cre-

    dits generated can be traded on the

    European market, which de facto finances

    most of these emissions reductions.

    JI in Europe, the source of

    "domestic offset projects"Joint Implementation projects in Europe

    are ineligible for allowances if they reduce

    directly or indirectly emissions that are

    already covered by the European Union

    Emissions Trading Scheme for CO2 (EU

    ETS). In spite of this limitation, almost all of

    the new Member States and several older

    Member States have established proce-

    dures to accept JI projects. In France, the

    system of domestic offset projects took

    shape in late 2007. The objective was topromote the emergence of fifteen projects,

    the majority of which have a strong territo-

    rial basis. For example, a project developed

    by alfalfa dehydration industry in

    Champagne-Ardenne is introducing the

    wood-energy generation model at the local

    level. The project implemented by the

    Urban Community of Lille will supply urban

    transit buses with biogas produced from

    the processing of municipal waste.

    In these times of tight budgets, other

    European countries are looking with inter-

    est at these projects which are co-financed

    by the market. In Germany, the Rhineland

    Energy Agency in Nordrhein-Westfalen has

    created a regional energy efficiency pro-gram, a portion of the financing for which is

    provided by the sale of JI credits. In Spain,

    a regulatory framework has been created.

    Even the Netherlands, which have been

    historically cool to the idea of JI projects,

    have displayed interest. A study submitted

    to the Minister of the Environment in mid-

    2009 concludes that these mechanisms are

    advantageous means of financing emis-

    sions reductions in the construction, trans-

    portation and agriculture sectors.

    A strategic advantage

    The United States has gotten the mes-

    sage. Its current proposed federal cap-and-

    trade system, which aims to cover 85% of

    its emissions, also calls for domestic offset

    projects, specifically in the agricultural and

    forestry sectors . In Japan, credits origina-

    ting from domestic offset projects can be

    used in the voluntary test market in opera-

    tion until 2012. In Europe, the adoption of

    harmonized domestic offset projects is an

    opportunity created by the EU ETS

    Directive for the period 2013-2020. This

    opportunity remains to be transformed into

    reality.

    At the moment, the international discussions

    revolve to a great extent around ways to

    improve the CDM. This is a strategic error.

    The objective of the negotiations should be

    to encourage countries to accept emissions

    reductions commitments; the importance of

    the CDM will decrease over time. On the

    contrary, the implementation of a system

    that provides sufficient incentives for JI and

    "domestic offset" projects could help bringthe emerging countries on board for a future

    international agreement. G

    Benot Leguet

    [email protected]

    Tel.: +33 1 58 50 98 18

    Domestic offset projects under development in France

    3

    The fifteen domestic offset projects under development in France are projected to reduce emissions by

    the equivalent of more than 5 MtCO2by 2012. The incineration of industrial gases represents more than

    half of the reduction by volume, although the number of these projects is limited. The majority of the

    projects take place in the power generation sector.

    Source: CDC-Climat, July 2009.

    To date, the project mechanism par excellence has

    been the Clean Development Mechanism (CDM), which

    finances emissions reductions in developing countries.

    The economic crisis has brought forward domestic

    offset projects which finance investments in the

    developed countries. This article focuses on the

    advantages of this mechanism.

    Type Number of projects

    Emissions reductions projected

    for the period 2008-2012(in tCO2e)

    Energy efficiency 3 600,000

    Renewable heat generation 6 1,400,000

    Fuel replacement 1 80,000

    Cooling 1 16,000

    Transportation 1 46,500

    HFC 1 1,000,000

    N2O 2 > 2,000,000

    Total 15 > 5,000,000

  • 8/14/2019 ClimatSphere. The newsletter on the economics of climate change

    4/6

    E missions Trading Schemes

    Projects: a complement

    to the ETS

    In emissions trading schemes, the use of credits

    originating from project mechanisms allows the

    issuers to reduce their compliance costs without

    compromising the overall environmental objective.

    This article surveys the principal existing and

    proposed emissions trading markets.

    Emitters who are subject to the require-

    ments of a carbon market must return car-

    bon assets that match the level of their

    greenhouse gas emissions. Emissions and emissions reductions have the same

    impact on the climate regardless of where

    they originate. Hence the idea of issuing

    credits originating from emissions reduc-

    tion projects outside an individual market,

    in other industrial sectors or geographic

    areas. The cost of compliance can then be

    minimized by juggling carbon assets,

    depending on their relative prices, without

    threatening the overall environmental

    objective.

    Limited importation of credits

    In general, there are limitations on the

    importation of credits. Why? The creators

    of the market want to realize a portion of

    the reduction effort on the sites operated

    by the industries that are subject to the

    cap. For example, the European Union

    Emissions Trading Scheme (EU ETS)

    authorizes the use of Kyoto credits up toan average of 13.5% of a company's allo-

    cation between 2008 and 2012. The

    European commitment is motivated by two

    objectives: to support developing coun-

    tries in accordance with international

    agreements and to ensure European indus-

    tries flexibility in reducing the cost of emis-

    sions reductions. This possibility will

    remain in place after 2012, although in

    reduced proportions.

    The ceiling on the importation of credits is

    lower in the Regional Greenhouse Gas

    Initiative (RGGI), which caps CO2 emissions

    by electric power producers in the

    Northeastern US: 3.3% of their allocation.

    Indeed, the electric power generation sec-

    tor is relatively sheltered from international

    competition so the cost of emissions

    reductions can be more easily shifted to

    consumers, which limits the need for redu-

    cing the compliance costs. Moreover, the

    RGGI emissions constraint for 2018 is

    considered relatively small.

    Finally the US and Australian federal market

    projects are distinguished by the need to

    ensure the players flexibility in exchange for

    the imposition of a cap on at least 85% of

    their emissions, especially in the current

    economic context. The importation of cre-

    dits would therefore be a minimum of 15%

    in the US and unlimited in Australia.

    Protected Designation

    of Origin

    The majority of the carbon markets

    draw a distinction between domestic cre-

    dits that originate from projects outside the

    carbon market but within their national ter-

    ritory and international credits such as

    Kyoto credits. Currently, the most restricti-

    ve market is the RGGI which allows only

    domestic credits. The projected future US

    federal system is expected to allow up to

    2 billion credits originating in equal portions

    from domestic and international projects, in

    conformity with US standards. A similar

    approach is planned in the European mar-

    ket. Between 2008 and 2012, domestic off-set projects will be implemented only on

    the initiative of the Member States. After

    2012, if efforts will focus on enlarging the

    European market to new industries, a sys-

    tem of domestic offset projects could also

    complete it.

    Toward a link

    between markets?

    Project mechanisms could indirectly

    link several emissions trading markets

    which accept the same credits and therefo-

    re represent an international carbon curren-

    cy. That would increase the overall efficien-

    cy of the markets. Given the reluctance of

    the US to accept the standards of Kyoto

    mechanisms, the question will be whether

    the coexistence of several standards, at dif-

    ferent qualities and prices, will allow a satis-

    factory interconnection of carbon markets

    on a worldwide level. G

    Baptiste Raymond

    [email protected]

    Tel.: +33 1 58 50 77 72

    Anas Delbosc

    [email protected]

    Tel.: +33 1 58 50 99 28

    Utilization of credits originating from project mechanisms

    in carbon markets

    4

    Source: Mission Climat of Caisse des Dpts.

    Existing carbon markets Planned carbon markets

    EU ETS(European Union)

    RegionalGreenhouseGas InitiativeRGGI (USA)

    CPRS(Australia,

    federal project)

    US ETS(USA, Waxman-

    Markey draftenergy bill)

    Cap as a %of allocation

    13.5% averageover 2008-2012.Sharp reductionbeginning in 2013.

    3.3%Increase to 5%or 10% in case ofsudden price rises.

    Unlimited15% in 2012,increasing to 33%in 2050.

    Types of projects

    All types ofprojects, exceptnuclear andforestation.

    Forestry projectsand certainemissions ofmethane, CO2and SF6.

    All typesof projects.

    All typesof projects.

    Project frameworkKyoto Projects(CDM and JI).

    RGGI States andNorth Americanjurisdictionshaving anagreementwith the RGGI

    Domestic offsetprojects and Kyotoprojects.

    Domestic offsetprojects (50%)and internationalprojects (50%)

  • 8/14/2019 ClimatSphere. The newsletter on the economics of climate change

    5/6

    5

    K ey figures

    Project mechanisms in figures

    12 countries currently account for 90%

    of the potential credit supply

    The demand for credits originating from emissions reduction projects (CDM, JI and

    domestic offset projects) is also very concentrated. Presently, it comes essentially from

    Europe. Additional demand will soon come from the US, Australia and New Zealand. G

    The CDM: Cap on energy

    Reductions of emissions of industrial gases (HFC and N2O) were the first CDM projects

    because of their low cost. There has been since a sharp increase in energy efficiency and

    renewable energy projects, for which the volume of credits issued is expected to exceed

    that of the HFC and N2O projects in 2012, with approximately 370 Mt avoided. These rela-

    tively small-scale projects should also be encouraged by the recent implementation of the

    programmatic CDM projects, the purpose of which is to accredit program activities. G

    Since 2004, credits have

    accounted for approximately

    30% of carbon assets

    transactions by volume

    and 25% by value

    The secondary market has grown signi-

    ficantly since 2005 (an average of +240%

    annually), with the appearance of standar-

    dized spot and futures contracts on the

    principal European exchanges (BlueNext,

    ECX, Nordpool). The primary CDM market

    has simultaneously slowed in the face of

    uncertainty about the post-2012 period.

    Trades of primary credits decreased from

    552 MtCO2e in 2007 to 259 MtCO2e in2008. G

    Antoine Samzun

    [email protected]

    Tel.: +33 1 58 50 98 19

    Raphal Trotignon

    [email protected]

    Tel.: +33 1 58 50 96 04

    CDM: Clean Development Mechanism

    JI: Joint implementation

    AAU: Assigned Amount Unit, a States Kyoto assets

    EU ETS: European Union

    Emissions Trading Scheme

    0%

    20%

    40%

    60%

    80%

    100%

    CERs issued by type of project

    2006 2007 2008 2012

    Renewable energies

    Energy efficiency

    Replacement among fossil fuels

    Reduction of CH4 in the energy sector

    Processes (agriculture, cement)

    and transportation

    Reduction of HFC or N2O

    Forestation/Reforestation

    States that have established (or plan to) an ETS that allows credits originating from projects

    Main States hosting CDM projects (90% of the potential supply of CDM credits)

    Secondary States hosting CDM projects (additional 9% of the potential supply of CDM credits)

    States hosting JI or domestic offset projects

    Updated cumulative value of carbon assets

    since 2004

    (Total 156.6 billion )

    EU ETS116.1 billion ; 74%

    CDM

    18.5 billion ; 12%

    JI - 0.8 billion ; 1%

    Voluntary market

    0.4 billion ; 0%

    AAU 0 billion ; 0%

    Cumulative value of carbon transactions

    since 2004

    (Total 9,956 MtCO2)

    EU ETS6,578 Mt; 66%

    CDM -

    1,786 Mt; 18%

    Secondary CDM

    1,347 Mt; 14%

    JI - 106 Mt; 1%

    Voluntary market

    120 Mt; 1%

    AAU - 18 Mt; 0%

    Source: World Bank, 2009

    Source: Mission Climat of Caisse des Dpts.

    US MARKETS10% of worldwide emissions

    Maximum 1,000 Mt/year

    of international credits (CER+ERU)

    and 1,000 Mt/year of domestic

    credits, after 2012

    EU ETS4% of worldwide emissions

    Minimum 1,500 Mt

    over the period 2008-2020

    (i.e. 115 Mt/year; 82 Mt already

    imported in 2008)

    AUSTRALIAN AND

    NEW ZEALAND MARKETSless than 1% of

    worldwide emissions

    On the order of 20 Mt/year,

    after 2012

    Source: UNEP-Risoe, June 2009 and estimates by the Mission Climat of Caisse des Dpts.

  • 8/14/2019 ClimatSphere. The newsletter on the economics of climate change

    6/6

    6

    restation (see Climate Sphere n 11 & 14).

    To materialize this opportunity, countries

    engaging in the REDD framework will be

    confronted to the same quandary currently

    faced by forestry projects in Annex I coun-

    tries: how to transfer a national incentive to

    the local level, where it actually results in a

    change of practices?

    Accounting rules under debate

    The complex accounting rules of forest

    carbon in Annex 1 countries are defined in

    Articles 3.3 deforestation/reforestation

    carbon balance and 3.4 carbon balance

    of forest remaining forests of the Kyoto

    Protocol (see figure). The no-lose accoun-

    ting of changes in forest cover under Article3.3 has often complicated the transfer of

    national forestry credits (Removal Units, or

    RMUs) to the domestic project level: a fra-

    mework for forestry domestic offset projects

    is up and running in New Zealand, whose

    carbon budget is likely to be positive; inFrance where the carbon budget should

    only be slightly positive, regulation is under-

    way and may link the national budget to the

    generation of carbon credits at project level.

    Providing project-level incentives for impro-

    ved forest management under Article 3.4

    has proven even more challenging: no

    country has yet managed a way around the

    issue. In the meantime, project developers

    could turn to voluntary markets if rigorous

    methodologies are developed under the

    existing quality labels.

    On the road to Copenhagen, several propo-

    sals to overhaul forestry accounting rules

    have been put on the table. Under the bar

    accounting proposed by the EU, carbon

    credits would be credited above (or debited

    below) a bar reference level. This bar

    could be set equal to a historical level, and

    adjusted for the age-class legacy effect: no

    penalty for countries with old forests and no

    hot air for countries with young forests.

    Most Annex 1 countries are in the view thatonly emissions and sinks coming from

    human intervention should be accounted

    for, factoring out major disturbances such

    as exceptional storms or pest outbreaks.

    Furthermore, many countries are pushing

    for the accounting of harvested wood pro-

    ducts, which has so far been left out of

    national inventories.

    One question will certainly be in the back

    of negotiators minds for both REDD and

    forestry in Annex 1 countries: how to devi-

    se a national cap and its related accoun-

    ting rules so that they are both environ-

    mentally sound and inciting for project

    developers? G

    Valentin Bellassen

    [email protected]

    Tel.: +33 1 58 50 19 75

    Mariana Deheza

    [email protected]

    Tel.: +33 1 58 50 99 85

    Key negotiations issues on

    forestry

    Eight years after the launch of the

    Kyoto protocol project mechanisms in

    Marrakesh, forestry mitigation projects are

    still waiting to take off. The latest figures

    released by the World Bank put their share

    of transacted carbon credits below 1% in

    2008. Close to nothing compared to the

    17% of global emissions due to deforesta-

    tion, and to the hundreds of millions of tons

    of yearly mitigation potential through refo-

    restation and sustainable management.

    The current climate negotiations on

    Reducing Emissions from Deforestation

    and Degradation (REDD) could broaden

    both supply and demand of forestry-basedoffsets. A consensus is emerging on a

    REDD+ framework, a sectoral approach

    that would reward countries whose forest

    carbon ends up higher than expected,

    either by reforestation or by avoided defo-

    Forestry accounting: the example of France

    The Mission Climat of Caisse des Dpts is a research centre on climate change economics.

    It is part of CDC Climat, the department of Caisse des Dpts in charge of carbon finance activities.

    Director of publication: Benot Leguet, Tel.: +33 1 58 50 98 18

    Caisse des Dpts 16 rue Berthollet 94113 Arcueil Cedex ISSN : 1952-7659

    Source: Mission Climat of Caisse des Dpts, from the French National GHG Inventory (2007).

    Under article 3.3, the balance between reforestation and deforestation activities leaves France with a small

    net sink. The uncertainty in the forest inventory combined with an unpredicted increase in deforestation could

    still tip the boat before 2012: in this case the deficit would be compensated by the surplus resulting from

    article 3.4. This latter accounts on a voluntary basis for net emissions from forest management. France will

    receive an additional maximum of 3.2 millions of carbon credits, far below the actual 80 million sink.

    Improving the sequestration of carbon through forest management projects will therefore not increase the

    amount of credits perceived.

    Carbon balance

    Reforestation/Deforestation

    Net sink

    (2,406 ktCO2eq)

    Emissions (Deforestation)

    Removals

    (Afforestation/Reforestation)

    Emissions

    (Decomposition/Harvesting)

    Removals (Growth)

    Net sink

    (72,614 ktCO2eq)

    Carbon balance

    Forest management

    Article 3.3 Article 3.4

    3.2 Mt ceiling

    F orestry Projects

    Conciliating national caps

    and incentives for projects

    Some of the obstacles that have hindered the developmentof forest mitigation projects could be overcome

    in Copenhagen. One of the most challenging issues

    is to devise sectoral accounting rules that translate

    a national cap into project-level incentives.