44
CLIMATE FUTURES WORKING PAPER SERIES PAPER NO. 3 Date: September 2011 Optimal Carbon Mitigation Including the REDD Option Yaoyao Ji Contact Author Contact Climate Futures

CLIMATE FUTURES WORKING PAPER SERIES PAPER NO. 3 Date ... · 15 challenges associated with the designing of the optimal level of REDD that society must invest in ... 141 potential--which

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    1

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: CLIMATE FUTURES WORKING PAPER SERIES PAPER NO. 3 Date ... · 15 challenges associated with the designing of the optimal level of REDD that society must invest in ... 141 potential--which

CLIMATE FUTURES WORKING PAPER SERIES

PAPER NO. 3 Date: September 2011

Optimal Carbon Mitigation Including the REDD Option Yaoyao Ji

Contact Author

Contact Climate Futures

Page 2: CLIMATE FUTURES WORKING PAPER SERIES PAPER NO. 3 Date ... · 15 challenges associated with the designing of the optimal level of REDD that society must invest in ... 141 potential--which

1

Optimal Carbon Mitigation Including the REDD Option 1

2

Yaoyao Ji 3

Graduate School of the Environment 4

Macquarie University, NSW 2109 Australia 5

email:[email protected]: Ph: +61 2 98506970 6

& 7

Ram Ranjan 8

Graduate School of the Environment 9

Macquarie University, NSW 2109 Australia 10

email:[email protected]: Ph: +61 2 98507989 11

12

Abstract 13

REDD programs offer an attractive option to cheaply mitigate carbon. However, there are 14

challenges associated with the designing of the optimal level of REDD that society must invest in 15

given the risks and non-uniform costs associated with REDD implementation in various countries. 16

This paper develops an integrated assessment model for carbon mitigation incorporating the REDD 17

option and derives the optimal timing and level of REDD participation for key countries based upon 18

their opportunity costs and risks. Additionally, the relevance and importance of REDD programs is 19

explored under the possibility of non-linear damages resulting from the accumulated stock of 20

atmospheric carbon. 21

Keywords: REDD, integrated assessment models, REDD risk, REDD opportunity cost, non-22

linear damages 23

Page 3: CLIMATE FUTURES WORKING PAPER SERIES PAPER NO. 3 Date ... · 15 challenges associated with the designing of the optimal level of REDD that society must invest in ... 141 potential--which

2

1. Introduction 24

Reducing Emissions from Deforestation and forest Degradation (REDD) programs are considered 25

an attractive option to mitigate the global warming problem in the short term as it is cost effective to 26

pay farmers to stop deforestation as compared to other options such as sequestration through 27

afforestation or conventional abatement (Lubowski 2008, Olsen 2009, Boucher 2008 and Borner 28

2008). However, REDD programs are not straightforward to implement due to the diversity in 29

opportunity costs across various regions of the world and the uncertainty associated with 30

implementing, measuring and monitoring carbon preserved under REDD programs (Pagiola 2009, 31

Hufty 2011 and Alvarado 2008). Brazil and Indonesia, which have large REDD potential, offer 32

cheap options of reducing deforestation, as ninety percent of their opportunity costs are less than $5 33

per ton of CO2 (Nepstad 2007 and Swallow et al. 2007). But unresolved challenges exist in the 34

technical aspect for REDD implementation, such as baseline decisions, monitoring and risk of non-35

permanence (Alvarado 2008). 36

The pervious literature has concentrated on the optimal strategies for climate mitigation 37

through mostly considering conventional abatement options (see discussions in Sohngen and 38

Mendelsohn 2003 and Lubowski 2008). Recently Integrated Assessment Models (IAMs) have been 39

developed to examine the possibility of reducing emissions through avoided deforestation 40

(Lubowski 2008). Sohngen and Mendelsohn (2003) integrate the DICE model with the global 41

timber model (GTM) to analyze the potential role of forests in reducing emissions (see also 42

discussion in Lubowski 2008). In their model (see Table 5 in Sohngen and Mendelsohn 2003), 43

optimal reduction increases from 203.1 billion tons to 299.4 billion tons when considering carbon 44

sequestration through avoided deforestation. Carbon sequestration from avoided deforestation 45

contributes about one third of the total mitigation. 46

Page 4: CLIMATE FUTURES WORKING PAPER SERIES PAPER NO. 3 Date ... · 15 challenges associated with the designing of the optimal level of REDD that society must invest in ... 141 potential--which

3

There is an emerging body of literature on REDD and REDD-plus programs basically 47

highlighting the benefits, opportunity costs and the implementation challenges (UN-REDD 48

Programme 2009, Karousakis 2009, Bosetti 2011, Sathaye 2011 and Rose 2011). Besides reducing 49

emissions through deforestation, REDD programs bring other benefits such as promoting forest and 50

ecosystem conservation and improving the forest carbon stocks (UN-REDD Programme 2009 and 51

Karousakis 2009). The implementation of REDD, however, is not without its challenges. It relies 52

heavily on coordination amongst REDD participants (Bosetti 2011) and the timing and eligibility of 53

participants needs to be carefully evaluated (Rose, 2011). 54

Although the forest-based activities may not eliminate deforestation, they can reduce the 55

accelerated deforestation effectively (Rose 2011). The extensive REDD-plus program which “goes 56

beyond deforestation and forest degradation, and includes the role of conservation, sustainable 57

management of forests and enhancement of forest carbon stocks” is considered to be effective for 58

developing countries with large forest areas (Sathaye 2011). Additionally, the side impact of REDD 59

programs is another issue which deserves attention as well. Fuss (2010) argues that the low-cost 60

REDD option, by virtue of being cheaper, may discourage investments in alternative energy and 61

technological innovations. Fuss (2010) uses a real option model to derive the optimal timing of 62

REDD participation, while reducing investment in carbon-intensive energy technology. 63

While a significant amount of work has been done lately, existing REDD based models have 64

not considered certain features that are crucial towards informing the current debate on climate 65

change mitigation strategies. First, none of the models have explored the optimal strategy of climate 66

change mitigation through REDD when damages from carbon crossing a certain threshold could 67

increase in a non-linear fashion. Second, the risk of large scale carbon release from REDD programs 68

due to fires or political instability, is also not adequately considered. Third, IAMs so far have not 69

Page 5: CLIMATE FUTURES WORKING PAPER SERIES PAPER NO. 3 Date ... · 15 challenges associated with the designing of the optimal level of REDD that society must invest in ... 141 potential--which

4

looked at the individual opportunity costs (as well as risks) of countries with large REDD potential 70

to derive their optimal timing and extent of involvement in a global model. An integrated 71

assessment model that includes the REDD option for major countries with high REDD potential, 72

such as Brazil and Indonesia, is still missing. Incorporating REDD into IAMs is a relatively new 73

field (Lubowski 2008). This paper attempts to fill this gap. 74

In this paper, we design an integrated assessment model that has the option of preventing 75

carbon deforestation through REDD for developing countries with large forestry areas. The 76

countries considered are Brazil, Indonesia, Democratic Republic of Congo (DRC), Cameroon and 77

Papua New Guinea (PNG). The IAM developed here also considers a non-linear damage function 78

associated with atmospheric carbon stock accumulation which incorporates the possibility of 79

catastrophic outcomes. The hypothesis of our paper is that when faced with non-linear damages and 80

consequential threshold effects, conventional carbon abatement plans that exclude cheaper REDD 81

options could lead to a different (and possibly very high) carbon concentrations as compared to the 82

ones that include REDD options. Additionally, given the risks associated with REDD programs, we 83

also need to discount REDD efforts of different regions based upon their stability. 84

Our paper brings to fore some key insights through the inclusion of above features. First, we 85

note that the abatement strategy is sensitive to an increase in average annual emissions. Once 86

average emissions cross a certain threshold, it leads to significantly higher damages and stock of 87

carbon and reduces optimal abatement over time as high damages do not make it cost-effective to 88

invest significantly in abatement. 89

Second, following from first, adding REDD option actually increases conventional 90

abatement and leads to a decline in the long term atmospheric carbon stock. This is because the low 91

cost of REDD reduces the overall costs of abatement. This makes it optimal to invest more 92

Page 6: CLIMATE FUTURES WORKING PAPER SERIES PAPER NO. 3 Date ... · 15 challenges associated with the designing of the optimal level of REDD that society must invest in ... 141 potential--which

5

abatement effort into avoiding a high stock accumulation. Whereas, without the REDD option it is 93

suboptimal to invest heavily in abatement. Since damages are non-linear there is a threshold effect 94

in terms of stock of carbon. When high abatement is not optimal, either due to high costs of 95

abatement or due to high emissions, the optimal response is to let carbon stock increase and suffer 96

higher damages in the long run rather than have a higher mitigation at the cost of forgone 97

consumption in the current period. Finally, we find that the risk of release from REDD programs 98

could reduce the attractiveness of these programs. At the same time, it also undermines the benefits 99

of conventional abatement strategies. Therefore, more effort should be put into monitoring factors 100

that increase risks. 101

102

2. A Brief Background on the Opportunity Costs of REDD 103

Several studies have pointed towards the significance of the opportunity costs of land use in the total 104

REDD costs. Opportunity cost of REDD is the “largest and most important single component of 105

costs” associated with reducing emissions through REDD programs (Olsen 2009 and Pagiola 2009). 106

Wertz-Kanounnikoff has discussed the two main approaches found in the literature to estimate the 107

opportunity costs of REDD-- the global models and the regional models (Boucher 2008 and Wertz-108

Kanounnikoff 2008). To estimate the supply of REDD services, the global simulation models 109

basically look at the value of a piece of land to be brought under REDD when dedicated to its 110

alternative uses such as agricultural or other potentially economic uses (Wertz-Kanounnikoff 2008). 111

Some of these models, as described in detail in Kindermann et al. (2008), are the Global Timber 112

Model (GTM), the Dynamic Integrated Model of Forestry and Alternative Land Use (DIMA) and 113

the Generalized Comprehensive Mitigation Assessment Process Model (GCOMAP). 114

Page 7: CLIMATE FUTURES WORKING PAPER SERIES PAPER NO. 3 Date ... · 15 challenges associated with the designing of the optimal level of REDD that society must invest in ... 141 potential--which

6

These models differ in scale, extent of global coverage and methodology. The GTM uses a 115

dynamic optimization approach, capturing competition between forest land and agriculture land uses, 116

to predict land use and management of various timber types (Kindermann et al. 2008 and Wertz-117

Kanounnikoff 2008). DIMA derives land-use choices between agriculture and forestry by 118

comparing their net present values at a fine scale of 0.5 degree grid cells, whereas GCOMAP 119

predicts the same at a much coarser level using a partial general equilibrium model (Kindermann et 120

al. 2008). Though differing in scope, all the three models are top-down models (Lubowski 2008). 121

Kindermann et al. (2008) use the above three models to estimate the costs of reducing deforestation 122

by ten percent and fifty percent between 2005 and 2030. From the three models, the carbon price is 123

derived to lie between $1.41 and $3.50 per ton of CO2 for reducing ten percent deforestation, 124

whereas the price of reducing half of deforestation is between $9.27 to $20.57 per ton of CO2 in 125

2030 (see Table 3 in Kindermann et al. 2008). 126

The global opportunity cost can also be evaluated by using the local-empirical estimates 127

(Boucher 2008). The local estimates of opportunity costs are based on the regional carbon density, 128

which is the carbon storage in one hectare of forest land and is different in different areas. Using a 129

global average carbon density one can convert the diverse local opportunity costs into a uniform cost 130

for the world (Boucher 2008). 131

The regional opportunity costs of REDD are evaluated using specific surveys and studies and 132

the local carbon density in these areas (Wertz-Kanounnikoff 2008). Nepstad et al. (2007) evaluate 133

forest land change and opportunity costs on a pixel-level (such as 4km2) (see also Wertz-134

Kanounnikoff 2008). For reducing deforestation to zero in 30 years, ninety percent of the 135

opportunity costs are under $5 per ton of CO2 in Brazil’s Amazon (Nepstad et al. 2007). Besides, the 136

general and random sample survey is another basic method to get data for evaluating opportunity 137

Page 8: CLIMATE FUTURES WORKING PAPER SERIES PAPER NO. 3 Date ... · 15 challenges associated with the designing of the optimal level of REDD that society must invest in ... 141 potential--which

7

costs (Grieg-Grian 2006 and Swallow et al. 2007). Combining local survey and generic estimates, 138

which are from the average results based on surveys, Grieg-Grian (2006) evaluates the opportunity 139

costs of avoiding deforestation. Grieg-Grian (2006) picks eight countries with the most REDD 140

potential--which are Brazil, Indonesia, Papua New Guinea, Cameroon, Congo, Ghana, Bolivia and 141

Malaysia). In our paper, the basic data used for REDD opportunity cost calibration for the five 142

countries selected is taken from Grieg-Grian (2006). 143

A brief outline of the paper is as follows. Section 3 presents the model details. Section 4.1 144

introduces four key scenarios and section 4.2 discusses the results. Section 4.3 performs a 145

sensitivity analysis. Finally, the conclusion section highlights and generalizes the main findings. 146

147

3. Model Description 148

Annual emissions are assumed to be average emissions for the entire time horizon and represented 149

in parts per million. 150

( ) ( ) ( ( )) 151

where ( ) is the percentage of carbon mitigated by conventional abatement methods and is 152

the global annual carbon emission from fossil fuels. We convert the percentage of abatement to 153

( ) which is the amount of carbon represented in parts per million: 154

( ) ( ) ( ) 155

Carbon emissions from deforestation ( ) are measured separately in the model: 156

( ) ( ) ( ), 157

Page 9: CLIMATE FUTURES WORKING PAPER SERIES PAPER NO. 3 Date ... · 15 challenges associated with the designing of the optimal level of REDD that society must invest in ... 141 potential--which

8

where represents the countries (Brazil, Indonesia, Cameroon, Domestic Republic Congo and Papua 158

New Guinea) and ( ) is the annual carbon emissions from forestry. This equals carbon 159

dioxide released from deforestation in countries, ( ), which is estimated as: 160

( ) ( ) ( ) , 161

Where ( ) is the forest stock at time t and is the annual deforestation rate 162

which is modeled as: 163

( ) ( )

where is the time period, , , and are the parameters of the non-linear function 164

which are described in Table 2. The time path of forest stock is given as: 165

( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( )

The current forest area equals ( ) ( ) (previous forest stock minus forest loss). 166

( ) is carbon sequestrated through REDD program for country i. In the model, the annul 167

forest stock is the existing forest area that excludes forest in REDD programs. The constraint 168

function to limit the annual potential of REDD programs to a maximum of annual forest loss is 169

given as: 170

( ) ( ) ( )

The time path of stock of REDD is given as: 171

( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ), 172

Page 10: CLIMATE FUTURES WORKING PAPER SERIES PAPER NO. 3 Date ... · 15 challenges associated with the designing of the optimal level of REDD that society must invest in ... 141 potential--which

9

where ( ) represents the stock of REDD programs in year t. ( ) equals to the pervious 173

stock of REDD plus current year REDD additions and includes the expected losses, where the risk 174

of loss is given by . The stock of the atmospheric carbon evolves as: 175

( ) ( )

( ) ( ) ( ) ( )

( )

where is the rate of decay of atmospheric carbon into deep oceans. In each time period, the carbon 176

stock in the atmosphere includes the carbon stock in the previous year ( ( ) 177

( )) , emissions from fossil fuels ( ( )) and deforestation ( ( )) and 178

carbon release caused by loss through of REDD programs ( ( )). 179

The atmospheric carbon is converted into economic damages assuming a non-linear relationship: 180

( ) ( ) ( ( ( ) )

( ( ) ) ) ( )

Where ( ) describes the economic loss caused by carbon stock, which is in terms of 181

percentage of annual ( )loss. Fig.1 shows the non-linear damage function. Notice that a sharp 182

increase in damages is assumed once the carbon stock crosses about 410 ppm. The value of 183

parameters, , , , and are presented in Table 3. 184

The cost of conventional abatement is assumed to take the following form: 185

( ) ( ) ( ( ))

( ( ))

Page 11: CLIMATE FUTURES WORKING PAPER SERIES PAPER NO. 3 Date ... · 15 challenges associated with the designing of the optimal level of REDD that society must invest in ... 141 potential--which

10

where ( ) represents the cost of conventional abatement which is dependent on the amount 186

of carbon abatement (in parts per million). , , are the non-linear 187

parameters and their values are depicted in Table 4. Fig. 2 illustrates the functional form associated 188

with the conventional abatement costs (presented in annual terms). The conventional cost increases 189

sharply with an increase of the abatement amount. In the beginning, the cost of abating the first 190

3ppm emissions is about $0.7 trillion, whereas it would cost more than $2 trillion dollar when 6ppm 191

emission is abated. We assume that abatement cost eventually stabilizes due to technological 192

advances in future. 193

The cost function of REDD programs is as follows: 194

( ) ( ) ( ( ))

( ( ))

The cost of REDD depends on the quantity of abatement through REDD program ( ( )). The 195

values of parameters, , and are illustrated in Table 5. 196

Next, the GDP growth is modeled as follows: 197

( ) ( ) ( ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ))

The value of ( ) next year depends on the last year’s GDP, net of any economic damage caused 198

by carbon stock ( ( )), economic cost of conventional abatement ( ( )) and the cost 199

of REDD programs ( ( )). Annual GDP is assumed to grow by an amount 200

Society’s objective is to maximize global utility, which is a function of the GDP. Utility is assumed 201

to have a constant elasticity of substitution in GDP: 202

Page 12: CLIMATE FUTURES WORKING PAPER SERIES PAPER NO. 3 Date ... · 15 challenges associated with the designing of the optimal level of REDD that society must invest in ... 141 potential--which

11

( ) ∑( ( ) )

( )

where ( ) is the discount process, is the elasticity parameter and is the sum of 203

the total annual utility. 204

205

4. Scenario Description and Empirical Calibration 206

Data sources and assumptions are provided in the Appendix. We explore optimal abatement 207

scenarios with and without the REDD option. The comparisons between global conventional 208

abatement costs and REDD costs in Brazil, Indonesia, Cameroon, DRC and PNG are provided in 209

Fig.3. In the beginning, conventional abatement costs are much higher than REDD costs, the REDD 210

costs increase gradually and surpass the conventional costs when maximum REDD potential is 211

reached. Fig. 3 (A) depicts the comparison between conventional costs and costs of REDD in Brazil. 212

When abatement exceeds around 0.25ppm, the REDD cost is higher than the cost of conventional 213

abatement. Comparing their relative REDD costs--Brazil being the cheapest one is followed by 214

Indonesia (Fig.3 (B)), Domestic Republic of Congo (Fig.3 (D)), Cameroon (Fig.3 (C)) and Papua 215

New Guinea which has the highest cost of REDD (Fig.3 (E)). 216

We also explore the impacts of risk associated with REDD on optimal REDD enrolment. 217

Several scenarios are considered. 218

4.1 Scenario Description 219

Abatement methods, such as nuclear, new coal, wind, and biodiesel, etc., are estimated synthetically, 220

as conventional abatement method. In the first scenario, we assuming there is only the conventional 221

Page 13: CLIMATE FUTURES WORKING PAPER SERIES PAPER NO. 3 Date ... · 15 challenges associated with the designing of the optimal level of REDD that society must invest in ... 141 potential--which

12

abatement option available. In the second scenario, the REDD option is included in the optimal 222

strategy. Five countries, Brazil, Indonesia, DRC Cameroon and PNG, are chosen to represent the 223

reality of global forest and REDD programs, especially REDD costs. There are three reasons of 224

picking these countries. First, they are located on the main forest areas in the word. More 225

specifically, Brazil sits on the Amazon Basin of South America which is the largest rainforest area 226

in the world. The Congo Basin is home to roughly one fifth of the world’s remaining tropical forests 227

(WWF 2011). DRC and Cameroon are the two largest countries with forestry in this area. Indonesia 228

and PNG are representative of forestry in South Asia. In addition, the forest area in the five 229

countries accounts for fifty one percent of total forestry in developing countries. According to 230

Global Forest Resource Assessment (2010), Brazil, DRC and Indonesia are included in the top ten 231

countries with largest forestry area. The total forest cover of these five countries is 817 million 232

hectares, which is twenty percent of global forest area and fifty one percent of forest in developing 233

countries. Finally, the annual deforestation in these countries accounts for forty three percent of 234

global deforestation. The annual net forest loss in Brazil, Indonesia and DRC are 2194, 685 and 425 235

thousands hectares respectively. Including PNG and Cameroon, annual deforestation in these 236

countries is 3.67 million hectares, which is forty three percent of annual global deforestation (Butler 237

2010). 238

In the third scenario, the risks to REDD programs are taken into account in the model. These 239

risks could undermine the REDD attractiveness. One of risks to REDD projects is illegal logging 240

caused by corruption in REDD countries. Besides, natural disasters, such as bushfires, floods and 241

pest diseases, could adversely influence the REDD programs as well. These risks could vary across 242

countries. While the risk to the entire stock may be seen as coming from fires, pest infestations or 243

political instability, the annual risks can come through improper and inadequate implementation 244

Page 14: CLIMATE FUTURES WORKING PAPER SERIES PAPER NO. 3 Date ... · 15 challenges associated with the designing of the optimal level of REDD that society must invest in ... 141 potential--which

13

which does not give an accurate idea of actual REDD participation. For sensitivity analysis we 245

assume that the risk to annual REDD program is 10 percent per year. There could also be a large 246

scale risk present to the entire stock of REDD, possibly coming from political instability in these 247

countries. This is taken up in the fourth scenario. We assume that the risk to the entire stock is 0.3 248

percent. 249

INSERT TABLE 1 HERE 250

4.2 Simulation Results 251

Fig.4 depicts the change in abatement time paths caused by adding on of the REDD programs. The 252

REDD option could increase the conventional abatement by an amount which is between 0.115 ppm 253

to 0.419 ppm. Considering the abatement through REDD, the total abatement under the second 254

scenario including REDD programs is higher (0.339 ppm to 0.633 ppm) than the first scenario with 255

conventional abatement only. From the above one key observation that can be made is that 256

implement of REDD programs is not only reducing the emissions from forestry, but it also increases 257

the abatement through conventional methods. As the cheaper REDD option reduces the overall 258

abatement costs and the damages, it becomes optimal to further reduce carbon through conventional 259

abatement as well. When high abatement is possible either due to low costs of abatement or due to 260

low emissions, the optimal response is to prevent the carbon stock from crossing a threshold, since 261

damages are non-linear (Fig.1) with a threshold effect in terms of stock of carbon. As a result, the 262

optimal strategy under REDD option has the potential to increase the conventional abatement. 263

In Fig.4, the non-linear damage function is the main reason behind the sudden jump 264

observed in the abatement occurring around time period 45. Once the carbon stock crosses the non-265

linear range (around 410ppm), the damage increases significantly. Hence, the optimal strategy is to 266

Page 15: CLIMATE FUTURES WORKING PAPER SERIES PAPER NO. 3 Date ... · 15 challenges associated with the designing of the optimal level of REDD that society must invest in ... 141 potential--which

14

not allow the carbon stock to cross this threshold. This leads to a hundred percent conventional 267

abatement at this time, which in turn also reduces the atmospheric carbon. Consequently, a 268

fluctuation is observed. 269

The time path of the annual stock of carbon is illustrated in Fig.5. Because of REDD option, 270

the carbon stock under the second scenario is much lower than the carbon stock under no-REDD 271

scenario. Notice that the two scenarios lead to completely different carbon paths in the long term. In 272

the long term, the REDD option has a significant impact on the time path of the carbon stock (Fig.5). 273

The carbon stock without REDD option increase gradually and surpasses the 410pmm threshold in 274

around 50 years. After that, it stays on the sharp rising trend as abatement eventually drops to zero 275

due to cost-benefit considerations. On the other hand, the REDD option makes it feasible to avoid 276

reaching the threshold levels and a maximum abatement is sustained to the end of the time horizon. 277

This leads to a long run decline in the carbon stock. 278

Subsequently, the damages (Fig.6) decrease under the including-REDD options whereas 279

under the no-REDD option they increase significantly. Since the non-linear damage is estimated as 280

the percentage of GDP, its magnitude in the long term decreases as GDP declines. By contrast, the 281

damage under the including-REDD scenario is much lower and stable as the associated carbon stock 282

is low and never exceeds the threshold. 283

Fig.7 depicts the influence of risk on the REDD programs. The second scenario, REDD 284

option without risks, leads to the highest value of REDD participation. When there is an annual risk 285

of 3 percent loss of REDD forestry through fires and other illegal harvesting, optimal REDD 286

participation is significantly reduced. An additional thing to note there is that the impact of a small 287

risk to the whole forest area under REDD is similar to the case of a much larger risk restricted to the 288

annual REDD implementation (Fig.7). 289

Page 16: CLIMATE FUTURES WORKING PAPER SERIES PAPER NO. 3 Date ... · 15 challenges associated with the designing of the optimal level of REDD that society must invest in ... 141 potential--which

15

Notice that the maximum amount of REDD implementation is restricted by the level of the 290

annual forest loss (Fig.8). Under the scenario with no risk of REDD loss, implementation of REDD 291

is to its maximum potential. 292

So far we have looked at the estimated parameter values in a deterministic way. It is likely 293

that the parameter values, especially the ones related to cost of abatement, damages, etc. will vary 294

based upon the scenarios and specific assumptions. In the next section we perform a sensitivity 295

analysis to evaluate the result of key parameter variation. 296

4.3 Sensitivity Analysis 297

In the base case, the average emissions are assumed to be 6ppm (including those from emissions 298

through fossil fuels and deforestation). We also evaluate the impact of higher emissions on optimal 299

abatement strategies. Higher average emissions of 6.5ppm and 7ppm lead to significantly higher 300

damages and stock of carbon (See Fig.9). 301

One key observation that can be made from the above is that abatement strategy becomes 302

sensitive to an increase in average emissions beyond a certain threshold. Specifically, if emissions 303

are increased beyond 6 ppm, optimal strategy is to reduce abatement over time as the associated 304

damages and costs of abatement do not make it cost-effective to invest significantly in carbon 305

abatement. This is primarily due to the non-linear rise in damages once a certain threshold of carbon 306

stock is crossed. 307

Next, we estimate the impact of a much higher non-linear damage function (maximum 308

damages are now eighty percent of the GDP as compared to a maximum of forty percent in the base 309

case) on the optimal strategy. In the no-REDD scenario, the optimal strategy is to reduce higher 310

damages initially by increasing the conventional abatement. This leads to a carbon stock time path 311

Page 17: CLIMATE FUTURES WORKING PAPER SERIES PAPER NO. 3 Date ... · 15 challenges associated with the designing of the optimal level of REDD that society must invest in ... 141 potential--which

16

under the no-REDD scenario as shown in Fig.10. It is significantly higher than the carbon stock in 312

the base case. In the including-REDD scenario, the REDD option help avoid high increases in the 313

carbon stock (figure 10). However, carbon stock in the twice as much damage case is still higher 314

than the stock compared to the base case. 315

Over time (after time period 70 in Fig.11) the low GDP resulting from a higher damage 316

function makes it costly to continue abating any further, so conventional abatement decreases 317

gradually over time for the higher damage scenario. Comparing with the base case, under the no-318

REDD scenario, GDP with higher damages is much lower as the damages reduce the GDP. 319

However, when there is REDD option available, GDP is higher than the case under the no-REDD 320

option and stays on the rising trend. 321

The influence of higher conventional abatement cost on the carbon stock is depicted in 322

Fig.12. The base case conventional abatement cost would be 2.79 trillion dollars for avoiding 10ppm 323

of carbon emissions, whereas it would cost 5.58 trillion dollars when a higher abatement cost is 324

assumed. The higher cost leads to an optimal strategy of reducing the conventional abatement over 325

time to keep its cost-effective and this in turn leads to a higher atmospheric concentration as 326

compared to the low cost case. However, the long term trend is still declining. One key observation 327

that can be made here is that the combined effect of forestry risks and the higher abatement costs 328

significantly increase the stock of carbon in the long run, whereas just risk or higher abatement costs 329

reduces it in the long term. 330

331

5. Discussion and Concluding Remarks 332

Page 18: CLIMATE FUTURES WORKING PAPER SERIES PAPER NO. 3 Date ... · 15 challenges associated with the designing of the optimal level of REDD that society must invest in ... 141 potential--which

17

In this paper, we designed an integrated assessment model that has explicitly included the REDD 333

option for five main developing countries with large REDD potential. We considered the possibility 334

of a non-linear damage function associated with the atmospheric carbon stock as well as the forestry 335

loss risks brought under REDD. One of the key findings is that the REDD program may prevent the 336

carbon stock from crossing a certain threshold in terms of non-linear damages. 337

The main conclusions from the analysis performed here are that the REDD program is an 338

attractive option to consider in the optimal management of climate change problem, however, there 339

are certain caveats attached to it. One of the key benefits of including REDD into an integrated 340

assessment model is that it leads to significant reduction in costs. One of the findings from our paper 341

points to the fact that REDD participation makes conventional abatement attractive as well when 342

damages evolve non-linearly. Therefore, all cheaper options for REDD should be explored and 343

encouraged globally. The risk of forestry loss makes REDD less attractive and decline of about 12 344

percent in the REDD is observed compared to the case without no risks. There is a distinction to be 345

made between annual REDD loss risks and the risks faced to the entire REDD forestry under REDD 346

as these risks could come from different sources such as large scale structural shifts and political 347

risks. We find that even a small risk to the total stock of REDD has the same effect on discouraging 348

REDD participation as compared to a large increase in annual risk. Specifically, ten percent risk of 349

annual REDD forestry loss reduces 550 thousand hectares of REDD implementation per year, while 350

a 0.3 percent risk to the accumulated stock of REDD forestry reduces 650 thousand hectares of 351

REDD forestry per year as compared to the case when there are no risks. The impact of small risk 352

(0.3 percent) to the stock of REDD programs is similar to the case of a much larger risk (10 percent) 353

restricted to the annual REDD implementation. 354

Page 19: CLIMATE FUTURES WORKING PAPER SERIES PAPER NO. 3 Date ... · 15 challenges associated with the designing of the optimal level of REDD that society must invest in ... 141 potential--which

18

Therefore, countries with lower risks but higher opportunity costs may be more preferable 355

than countries with higher risks and lower opportunity costs. Although there is a significant diversity 356

of opportunity costs amongst different countries, (Brazil being the cheapest one and PNG with the 357

relatively highest cost of REDD), the optimal strategy allows for REDD enrolment over time based 358

not only upon the cost differentials but also their projected future forest losses as well as associated 359

risks. 360

361

Page 20: CLIMATE FUTURES WORKING PAPER SERIES PAPER NO. 3 Date ... · 15 challenges associated with the designing of the optimal level of REDD that society must invest in ... 141 potential--which

19

Reference 362

Alvarado L. X. R. and S. Wertz-Kanounnikoff (2008): Why Are We Seeing REDD? An Analysis of 363

the International Debate on Reducing Emissions from Deforestation and Degradation in Developing 364

Countries, Institut du développement durable et des relations internationales (Iddri). Available at: 365

http://www.iddri.org/Publications/Collections/Analyses/ 366

Bosetti V. and S. K. Rose (forthcoming): Reducing Carbon Emissions from Deforestation and 367

Forest Degradation: Issues for Policy Design and Implementation, Environment and Development 368

Economics. 369

Boucher, D. (2008): What REDD Can Do: The Economics and Development of Reducing Emission 370

from Deforestation and Forest Degradation, Tropical Forest and Climate Initiative-Union of 371

Concerned Scientists, Washington D.C., USA. 372

Borner J. and S. Wunder (2008): Paying for Avoided Deforestation in the Brazil Amazon: from Cost 373

Assessment to Scheme Design, International Forestry Review, Vol. 10 (3): 496-511. 374

Butler, R. A. (2010): Rainforest Loss Slows. Available at http://news.mongabay.com/2010/1006-375

fao_forest_cover.html 376

Dietz S. and N. Stern (2008): Why Economic Analysis Supports Strong Action on Climate Change: 377

A Response to the Stern Review’s Critics, Symposium: The Economics of Climate Change: The 378

Stern Review and Its Critics, Review of Environmental Economics and Policy (2008) 2 (1): 94-113. 379

Fuss S., J. Szolgayova, A. Golub and M. Obersteiner (forthcoming): Options on Low-cost 380

Abatement and Investment in the Energy Sector: New Perspectives on REDD, Environment and 381

Development Economics. 382

Page 21: CLIMATE FUTURES WORKING PAPER SERIES PAPER NO. 3 Date ... · 15 challenges associated with the designing of the optimal level of REDD that society must invest in ... 141 potential--which

20

Grieg-Gran, M. (2006): The Cost of Avoiding Deforestation: report prepared for the Stern Review 383

of the Economics of Climate Change, Paper commissioned by the Office of Climate Change as 384

background work to its report Climate Change: Financing Global Forests (The Eliasch Review) 385

IIED, London, UK. 386

Global Forest Resource Assessment (2010): Food and Agriculture Organization of the United 387

Nations, Forestry Paper no. 163. 388

Hufty M. and A. Haakenstad (2011): Reduced Emissions for Deforestation and Degradation: A 389

Critical Review, The Journal of Sustainable Development, Vol. 5, Issue1: 1-24. 390

Kindermann, G., M. Obersteiner, B. Sohngen,J. Sathaye, K. Andrakso, E. Rametsteiner, 391

B.Schlamadinger, S. Wunder and R. Beach (2008): Global cost estimates for reducing carbon 392

emissions through avoided deforestation in Proceedings of the National Academy of Science of the 393

Unites States of America. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 105(30): 10302-10307, 394

Available online at: http://www.pnas.org/content/105/30/10302.full 395

Karousakis, K. (2009): Promoting Biodiversity Co-Benefits in REDD, OECD Environment 396

Working Papers, No. 11, Available at: http://www.cbd.int/doc/meetings/for/ewredd-01/other/ewredd-01-oth-397

oecd-en.pdf 398

Lubowski, R. N. (2008): The Role of Reducing Emissions from Deforestation and Forest 399

Degradation in Stabilizing Greenhouse Gas Concentrations: Lessons from Economic Models, Center 400

of International Forestry Research (CIFOR), No.18. 401

Laporte N., F. Merry, A. Baccini, S. Goetz, J. Stabach, M. Bowman (2007): Reducing CO2 402

Emission from Deforestation and Degradation in the Democratic Republic of Congo: A First Look, 403

the Woods Hole Research Center. 404

Page 22: CLIMATE FUTURES WORKING PAPER SERIES PAPER NO. 3 Date ... · 15 challenges associated with the designing of the optimal level of REDD that society must invest in ... 141 potential--which

21

Nepstad, D., B. Soares-Filho, F. Merry, P. Moutinho, H. Oliveira-Rodriguez, M. Bowman, S. 405

Schwartzman, O. Almeida and S. Rivero. (2007): The Cost and Benefits of Reducing Carbon 406

Emission from Deforestation and Forest Degradation in the Brazilian Amazon. WHRC-IPAM-407

UFMG. 408

Olsen, N. and J. Bishop (2009): The Financial Costs of REDD: Evidence from Brazil and Indonesia. 409

2009 International Union for Conservation of Nature and Natural Resources, Gland, Switzerland: 410

IUCN. 64pp. 411

Pagiola S. and B. Bosquet (2009): Estimating the Costs of REDD at the Country Level, Forest 412

Carbon Partnership Facility (FCPF). 413

Rose S. K. and B. Sohngen (forthcoming): Global Forest Carbon Sequestration and Climate Policy 414

Design, Environment and Development Economics. 415

Swallow, B., M. van Noordwijk, S. Dewi, D.Murdiyarso, D. White, J. Gockowski, G. Hyman, 416

S.Budidarsono, V. Robiglio, V. Meadu, A. Ekadinata,F. Agus, K. Hairiah, P. Mbile, D.J. Sonwa and 417

S. Weise (2007): Opportunities for Avoided Deforestation with Sustainable Benefits. An Interim 418

Report of the ASB Partnership for the Tropical Forest Margins. ASB Partnership for the Tropical 419

Forest Margins, Nairobi, Kenya. 420

Sohngen, B. and R. Mendelsohn (2003): An Optimal Control Model of Forest Carbon Sequestration. 421

American Journal of Agricultural Economics 85(2): 448-457. 422

Sathaye J., K. Andrasko and P. Chan (forthcoming): Emissions Scenarios, Costs, and 423

Implementation Considerations of REDD-plus Programs, Environment and Development Economics. 424

Page 23: CLIMATE FUTURES WORKING PAPER SERIES PAPER NO. 3 Date ... · 15 challenges associated with the designing of the optimal level of REDD that society must invest in ... 141 potential--which

22

The McKinsey Quarterly (2007): A Cost Curve for Greenhouse Gas Reduction, the McKinsey 425

Quarterly 2007 Number 1. 426

UN-REDD Programme (2009): Multiple Benefits-Issues and Options for REDD, FAO, UNDP, 427

UNED. 428

Wertz-Kanounnikoff S. (2008): Estimating the Costs of Reducing Forest Emissions, Center of 429

International Forestry Research (CIFOR), Working paper No.42 430

WWF (2011): Protecting Africa’s Tropical Forests. http://www.worldwildlife.org/what/wherewework/congo/ 431

432

433

434

435

436

Page 24: CLIMATE FUTURES WORKING PAPER SERIES PAPER NO. 3 Date ... · 15 challenges associated with the designing of the optimal level of REDD that society must invest in ... 141 potential--which

23

APPENDIX: Model Calibration 437

Table 1. Scenario Description 438

Scenarios Scenarios description

Scenario 1 No-REDD option

Scenario 2 With REDD option

Scenario 3 REDD option with 10 percent risk rate to the annual REDD programs

Scenario 4 REDD option with 0.3 percent risk rate to the REDD stock

439

440

Page 25: CLIMATE FUTURES WORKING PAPER SERIES PAPER NO. 3 Date ... · 15 challenges associated with the designing of the optimal level of REDD that society must invest in ... 141 potential--which

24

Table 2. Parameters of Forest Loss Rate Function for Each Country 441

Country Parameter Value (scalar)

Brazil ηfl_brazil 1.16

afl_brazil 4.48

bfl_brazil 46x109

cfl_brazil 0.0042

Indonesia ηfl_indonesia 1.52

afl_ indonesia 5.7

bfl_ indonesia 39x1010

cfl_ indonesia 0.0073

Cameroon ηfl_cameroon 8.62

afl_ cameroon 4.96

bfl_ cameroon 1x1010

cfl_ cameroon 0.011

DRC ηfl_DRC 6.8

afl_DRC 6.02

bfl_DRC 708x1013

cfl_DRC 0.00277

PNG ηfl_PNG 2.32

afl_PNG 5.76

bfl_PNG 1x1013

cfl_PNG 0.00499

442

443

Page 26: CLIMATE FUTURES WORKING PAPER SERIES PAPER NO. 3 Date ... · 15 challenges associated with the designing of the optimal level of REDD that society must invest in ... 141 potential--which

25

Table 3. Parameters of the Carbon Stock Related Damage Function 444

Parameter Value

percarb 280

ηdam 42.1

adam 6.58

bdam 440

cdam 0.01

445

446

Page 27: CLIMATE FUTURES WORKING PAPER SERIES PAPER NO. 3 Date ... · 15 challenges associated with the designing of the optimal level of REDD that society must invest in ... 141 potential--which

26

Table 4. Parameters of Conventional Abatement Cost Function 447

Parameter Value

cabcst 0.01

ηabcst 3.2

aabcst 2.6

babst 60

448

449

Page 28: CLIMATE FUTURES WORKING PAPER SERIES PAPER NO. 3 Date ... · 15 challenges associated with the designing of the optimal level of REDD that society must invest in ... 141 potential--which

27

Table 5. Parameters of REDD Cost Function for Each Country 450

Country Parameter Value

Brazil crdcst_brazil 0.66

ηrdcst_brazil 3.4

ardcst_brazil 4.64

brdcst_brazil 0.276

Indonesia crdcst_ indonesia 0.525

ηrdcst_indonesia 1.82

ardcst_indonesia 3.86

brdcst_ indonesia 0.152

Cameroon crdcst_ cameroon 0.41

ηrdcst_cameroon 1.82

ardcst_cameroon 2.16

brdcst_cameroon 0.64

DRC crdcst_DRC 0.7

ηrdcst_DRC 0.45

ardcst_DRC 2.06

brdcst_DRC 0.415

PNG crdcst_PNG 0.25

ηrdcst_PNG 0.76

ardcst_PNG 1.68

brdcst_PNG 0.276

451

452

Page 29: CLIMATE FUTURES WORKING PAPER SERIES PAPER NO. 3 Date ... · 15 challenges associated with the designing of the optimal level of REDD that society must invest in ... 141 potential--which

28

Table 6. Other Parameters of the Model 453

Parameter Definition Value Equation

emi Global annual carbon emission 6 (1)(2)

δ Rate of decay of atmospheric carbon 0.0038 (9)

inrate Growth rate of global economy 1.03 (13)

η Elasticity Parameter in the CES utility function 0.1 (14)

454

455

Page 30: CLIMATE FUTURES WORKING PAPER SERIES PAPER NO. 3 Date ... · 15 challenges associated with the designing of the optimal level of REDD that society must invest in ... 141 potential--which

29

Table 7. Forest Loss Rate Estimation 456

Brazil Indonesia Cameroon DRC PNG

2005-2010 annual carbon

emissions from forest loss (ppm)1

0.112686 0.048561 0.018798 0.0363 0.01

Forest loss rate in 2010 (%)2 0.4236 0.7361 1.1294 0.2774 0.4994

Forest loss rate in 2020 (%)3 0.4585 0.8486 1.4176 0.292 0.5548

Forest loss rate in 2030 (%) 0.5084 1.022 1.9786 0.3101 0.6163

Forest loss rate in 2040 (%) 0.5615 1.2846 3.2743 0.3306 0.703

Forest loss rate in 2050 (%) 0.6325 1.7287 9.4868 0.354 0.818 1. Source: MONGABAY.COM, http://rainforests.mongabay.com/ 2. Source: MONGABAY.COM, 457 http://rainforests.mongabay.com/ 3. After 2010, forest loss rates assumed to stay constant. 458

459

Page 31: CLIMATE FUTURES WORKING PAPER SERIES PAPER NO. 3 Date ... · 15 challenges associated with the designing of the optimal level of REDD that society must invest in ... 141 potential--which

30

Table 8. Conventional Abatement Cost Function Estimation 460

Gt CO23 Cost per

ton ($)3

CO2 without

REDD(Gt)4

CO2 without

REDD(ppm)5

Total cost without

REDD(trillion$)

McKinsey1 18 38 16 2.047 0.608

McKinsey 26 61 24 3.07 1.464

McKinsey 33 77 31 3.966 2.541

Dietz and Stern2 40 100 38 4.861 3.8

1. Source: The McKinsey Quarterly (2007) 461 2. Source: Dietz and Stern (2008) 462 3. The first two columns show the CO2 abated by conventional methods with different costs. Gt=Giga ton 463 4. REDD programs could abate 2Gt of CO2 every year. 464 5. CO2 is divided by a factor of 7.8171 to get CO2 in terms of ppm. 465 466

Page 32: CLIMATE FUTURES WORKING PAPER SERIES PAPER NO. 3 Date ... · 15 challenges associated with the designing of the optimal level of REDD that society must invest in ... 141 potential--which

31

Table 9. REDD Cost Function Estimation 467

Country Land use US$/

ha

No

of ha

(000)

Carbon

storage/

ha1

Ton of

CO2_e

/ha7

Amount

of CO2_e

(ppm)8

US$/ppm

CO2_e

(trillion)

Cameroon 1822

667.94

Annual food crops short fallow 774 86 0.0073 0.0138

Annual food crops long fallow 346 44 0.0038 0.004

Cocoa with marketed fruit 1365 66 0.0056 0.0156

Cocoa without marketed fruit 740 22 0.0019 0.0087

Oil palm and rubber 1180 2 0.0002 0.0091

DRC 1463 535.82

Annual food crops short fallow 774 124 0.0085 0.0113

Annual food crops long fallow 346 64 0.0044 0.005

Cocoa with marketed fruit 1365 96 0.0066 0.0199

Cocoa without marketed fruit 740 32 0.0022 0.0108

Oil palm and rubber 1180 3 0.0002 0.0172

Brazil 1104 403.7

Beef cattle medium/large scale 626 1955 0.101 0.0121

Beef cattle small scale 2 217 0.0112 0.00004

Dairy 154 217 0.0112 0.003

Soybeans 2135 155 0.008 0.0413

Manioc/rice 2 496 0.0256 0.00004

Perennials 239 31 0.0016 0.0046

Tree plantations 2614 31 0.0016 0.0506

Indonesia 1515 554.17

Large scale oil palm 2705 380 0.0269 0.0382

Supported growers 2085 109 0.0077 0.0294

High yield independent 2205 30 0.0021 0.0311

Low yield independent 1515 79 0.0056 0.0214

Smallholder rubber 1071 561 0.0398 0.0151

Rice fallow 26 355 0.0252 0.0004

Cassava monoculture 18 355 0.0252 0.0003

PNG 1516 554.17

Oil palm estates 2705 46 0.0033 0.0382

Smallholder oil palm 1515 23 0.0016 0.0214

Smallholder subsistence crops 1737 70 0.005 0.0245 Source: Grieg Gran (2006), Table 5 Global and National Costs of Foregone Land Uses (medium scenario of one-off 468 timber harvesting) 469 1. To get REDD cost (US$/ton of CO2_e), we need to know the amount of carbon stocked in one hectare in each 470 country’s forestry. 471 2. Source of carbon storage: Swallow(2007) 472 3. Source of carbon storage: Laporte (2007) 473 4. Source of carbon storage: Olsen (2009) 474 5. Source of carbon storage: Olsen (2009) 475 6. Source of carbon storage: for PNG we use the same carbon stock per hectare as Indonesia. Olsen (2009) 476 7. Multiply hectares of land by the amount of CO2_e per hectare to get the amount of CO2_e for this land use category 477 and convert it to ppm. 478 8. Calculate the total cost of different categories and divided by the amount of CO2_e to get the unit cost. 479 480

Page 33: CLIMATE FUTURES WORKING PAPER SERIES PAPER NO. 3 Date ... · 15 challenges associated with the designing of the optimal level of REDD that society must invest in ... 141 potential--which

32

481

Fig.1. Non-Linear Damages as a Function of Atmospheric Stock of Carbon 482

483

Non-Linear Increase Region

Page 34: CLIMATE FUTURES WORKING PAPER SERIES PAPER NO. 3 Date ... · 15 challenges associated with the designing of the optimal level of REDD that society must invest in ... 141 potential--which

33

484

Fig.2. Conventional Abatement Cost as a Function of ppm Abated 485

486

487

Page 35: CLIMATE FUTURES WORKING PAPER SERIES PAPER NO. 3 Date ... · 15 challenges associated with the designing of the optimal level of REDD that society must invest in ... 141 potential--which

34

488

A. Brazil B. Indonesia 489

490

C. Cameroon D. DRC 491

492

E.PNG 493

Fig.3.Comparions between Conventional Abatement and REDD Costs 494

495

Page 36: CLIMATE FUTURES WORKING PAPER SERIES PAPER NO. 3 Date ... · 15 challenges associated with the designing of the optimal level of REDD that society must invest in ... 141 potential--which

35

496

Fig.4.Time Path of Abatement under no-REDD and REDD Scenarios 497

498

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

1 5 9

13

17

21

25

29

33

37

41

45

49

53

57

61

65

69

73

77

81

85

89

93

97

pp

m

Year

conventional abatement_no REDD

conventional abatement_including REDD

total abatement (conventional abatement and REDD)

Page 37: CLIMATE FUTURES WORKING PAPER SERIES PAPER NO. 3 Date ... · 15 challenges associated with the designing of the optimal level of REDD that society must invest in ... 141 potential--which

36

499

Fig.5.Time Path of Carbon Stock under no-REDD and REDD Scenarios 500

501

0

500

1000

1500

2000

2500

1

21

41

61

81

10

1

12

1

14

1

16

1

18

1

20

1

22

1

24

1

26

1

28

1

30

1

32

1

34

1

36

1

38

1

40

1

42

1

44

1

46

1

48

1

pp

m

Year

carbon_no REDD carbon_including REDD

Page 38: CLIMATE FUTURES WORKING PAPER SERIES PAPER NO. 3 Date ... · 15 challenges associated with the designing of the optimal level of REDD that society must invest in ... 141 potential--which

37

502

Fig.6. Time Path of Damages under no-REDD and REDD Scenarios 503

504

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

1

17

33

49

65

81

97

11

3

12

9

14

5

16

1

17

7

19

3

20

9

22

5

24

1

25

7

27

3

28

9

30

5

32

1

33

7

35

3

36

9

38

5

Tiri

llio

n $

Year

damage_no REDD damage_including REDD

Page 39: CLIMATE FUTURES WORKING PAPER SERIES PAPER NO. 3 Date ... · 15 challenges associated with the designing of the optimal level of REDD that society must invest in ... 141 potential--which

38

505

Fig.7. Time Path of REDD Implementation under Various Scenarios 506

507

0

0.05

0.1

0.15

0.2

0.25

1

13

25

37

49

61

73

85

97

10

9

12

1

13

3

14

5

15

7

16

9

18

1

19

3

20

5

21

7

22

9

24

1

25

3

26

5

27

7

28

9

pp

m

Year

total REDD_no risk

total REDD_0.3% risk of the REDD stock

total REDD_10% risk of the annual REDD

Page 40: CLIMATE FUTURES WORKING PAPER SERIES PAPER NO. 3 Date ... · 15 challenges associated with the designing of the optimal level of REDD that society must invest in ... 141 potential--which

39

508

Fig.8. Time Path of Annual Forest Loss under Various Scenarios 509

510

0

0.05

0.1

0.15

0.2

0.25

1

10

19

28

37

46

55

64

73

82

91

10

0

10

9

11

8

12

7

13

6

14

5

15

4

16

3

17

2

18

1

19

0

19

9

20

8

21

7

22

6

23

5

pp

m

Year annual forest loss_no risk

annual forest loss_0.3% risk of the REDD stock

annual forest loss_10% risk of the annual REDD

Page 41: CLIMATE FUTURES WORKING PAPER SERIES PAPER NO. 3 Date ... · 15 challenges associated with the designing of the optimal level of REDD that society must invest in ... 141 potential--which

40

511

Fig.9. Time Path of Carbon Stock under Various Assumptions over Average Annual Emissions 512

513

0

200

400

600

800

1000

1200

1400

1600

1800

2000

1

18

35

52

69

86

10

3

12

0

13

7

15

4

17

1

18

8

20

5

22

2

23

9

25

6

27

3

29

0

30

7

32

4

34

1

35

8

37

5

39

2

40

9

pp

m

Year

carbon_no REDD_base case carbon_including REDD_base case

carbon_no REDD_emi=6.5 carbon_including REDD_emi=6.5

carbon_no REDD_emi=7 carbon_including REDD_emi=7

Page 42: CLIMATE FUTURES WORKING PAPER SERIES PAPER NO. 3 Date ... · 15 challenges associated with the designing of the optimal level of REDD that society must invest in ... 141 potential--which

41

514

Fig.10. Time Path of Carbon Stock under Varying Damage Functions 515

516

0

500

1000

1500

2000

2500

1

21

41

61

81

10

1

12

1

14

1

16

1

18

1

20

1

22

1

24

1

26

1

28

1

30

1

32

1

34

1

36

1

38

1

40

1

42

1

44

1

46

1

48

1

pp

m

Year

carbon_no REDD_base case carbon_including REDD_base case

carbon_no REDD_twice damage carbon_including REDD_twice damage

Page 43: CLIMATE FUTURES WORKING PAPER SERIES PAPER NO. 3 Date ... · 15 challenges associated with the designing of the optimal level of REDD that society must invest in ... 141 potential--which

42

517

Fig.11. Time Path of GDP under Varying Damage Functions 518

519

0

200

400

600

800

1000

1200

1

20

39

58

77

96

11

5

13

4

15

3

17

2

19

1

21

0

22

9

24

8

26

7

28

6

30

5

32

4

34

3

36

2

38

1

40

0

41

9

43

8

45

7

47

6

49

5

Trill

ion

$

Year

GDP_no REDD_base case GDP_including REDD_base case

GDP_no REDD_twice damage GDP_including REDD_twice damage

Page 44: CLIMATE FUTURES WORKING PAPER SERIES PAPER NO. 3 Date ... · 15 challenges associated with the designing of the optimal level of REDD that society must invest in ... 141 potential--which

43

520

Fig.12. Time Path of Carbon Stock under Varying Abatement Costs 521

Note: abc = abatement cost. 522

0

100

200

300

400

500

600

700

1

21

41

61

81

10

1

12

1

14

1

16

1

18

1

20

1

22

1

24

1

26

1

28

1

30

1

32

1

34

1

36

1

38

1

40

1

42

1

44

1

46

1

48

1

pp

m

Year

carbon_including REDD_base case

carbon_including REDD_twice abc

carbon_including REDD_10% risk of the annual REDD_base case

carbon_including REDD_10% risk of the annual REDD_twice abc