17
Chapter 7 Physicians as Providers of Health Care

Chapter 7 Physicians as Providers of Health Care

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Chapter 7 Physicians as Providers of Health Care

Chapter 7

Physicians as Providers ofHealth Care

Page 2: Chapter 7 Physicians as Providers of Health Care

A. Market Structure of Physician Practices

The market for physician services is best characterized as

monopolistically competitive, although there are examples of

monopoly (cartels).

This market is one in which physician practices are not perfect

substitutes for each other, but in which there is competition in most

communities. Thus, we can think of physician practices as being

characterized by downward sloping demand curves.

Page 3: Chapter 7 Physicians as Providers of Health Care

A. Market Structure of Physician Practices

Figure 7.1: A Monopolistically Competitive Physician Firm

Page 4: Chapter 7 Physicians as Providers of Health Care

B. Behavior of Physician Practices (Firms)

The market for physician services is known to be one in which pricediscrimination is employed.

Does price discrimination result from altruism or does it result fromrational economic motivation, e.g. an attempt to profit maximize?

Historically, there was much anecdotal evidence that physicianswere motivated by altruism and would accept whatever peoplecould pay. We can explain this by noting that physicians’ utility function maytake the form of: U = f (I, L, A)

where I = income, L = leisure and A = altruism.

Page 5: Chapter 7 Physicians as Providers of Health Care

B. Behavior of Physician Practices (Firms)

Price discrimination may also result from an economically motivated

strategy to maximize profits.

Economically motivated price discrimination can occur where: (a) markets can be segmented by price elasticity of demand

(b) products or services cannot be resold.

Both of these conditions apply in the market place for physicians’

services.

Page 6: Chapter 7 Physicians as Providers of Health Care

B. Behavior of Physician Practices (Firms)

Profit-Maximizing Price Discrimination:

Use the general rule of setting marginal cost (MC) equal to marginalrevenue (MR) in each sub-market.

To understand how this leads to profit-maximizing pricediscrimination, we must understand the relationship betweenmarginal revenue (MR), price elasticity of demand (η) and price (P):

MR = P (1 + 1/η)

To maximize profits, the firm sets the marginal cost equal to themarginal revenue in each sub-market:

MC = MR1 = MR2

MC = P1 (1 + 1/η1) = P2 (1 + 1/η2)

Page 7: Chapter 7 Physicians as Providers of Health Care

B. Behavior of Physician Practices (Firms)

Figure 7.2: Two-Way Price Discrimination

Page 8: Chapter 7 Physicians as Providers of Health Care

B. Behavior of Physician Practices (Firms)

Cost-Shifting

Cost shifting occurs when firms charge higher prices to one group of

consumers in order to offset lower payments from others.

Many people think that physicians (and hospitals) do this in order to

compensate for charity care lower payments from Medicare,

Medicaid, or managed care third-party payers.

Cost-shifting is only profitable if firms are not already charging the

profit maximizing price to the unconstrained part of the market, e.g.

charging a price < p* in the following diagram.

Page 9: Chapter 7 Physicians as Providers of Health Care

B. Behavior of Physician Practices (Firms)

Figure 7.3: Limits to Cost Shifting

Page 10: Chapter 7 Physicians as Providers of Health Care

C. Alternative Model of Physician Practices

A model proposed by Thomas McGuire (2000) treats physicians asquantity setters rather than price setters. It has a great deal ofplausibility in an age of managed care, and when Medicare andMedicaid set rates of reimbursement.

It treats consumers (patients) as having marginal benefit rather thandemand functions for services purchased.

Total benefit is a function of quantity of service received, B(x),where x is the unit of service.

If price of a unit of service = p, Net benefit is:

NB(x) = B(x) – p(x).

Page 11: Chapter 7 Physicians as Providers of Health Care

C. Alternative Model of Physician Practices

In this model patients do have choices among physicians.

In order to remain with the same physician practice, a patient must

receive a minimum level of net benefit, NB0.

A physician can satisfy this condition while providing varying

amounts of service since some care is perceived as having positive

value while other care is perceived as having negative value. Figure

7.4 illustrates this.

Page 12: Chapter 7 Physicians as Providers of Health Care

C. Alternative Model of Physician Practices

Figure 7.4: The McGuire Model

Based on McGuire, T.G., “Physician Agency” in Handbook of Health Economics,Vol. 1A, A.K. Culyer and J.P. Newhouse, eds., (Amsterdam, Elsevier, 2000) Fig 3, p. 480

Page 13: Chapter 7 Physicians as Providers of Health Care

D. Physicians as Agents

Because of asymmetric information, in which physicians’ specialized

knowledge gives them an advantage in diagnosing and

recommending treatment, patients delegate authority to physicians

to make decisions about their health care. This creates the potential

for principal/agent problems.

Physicians can either be perfect or imperfect agents. If they behave

as perfect agents, they act in the patient’s best interest in

recommending treatment. In the case of imperfect agency,

physicians substitute their own self-interest.

Page 14: Chapter 7 Physicians as Providers of Health Care

D. Physicians as Agents

Physicians who are perfect agents will tend to recommend the same

treatment, regardless of the way in which they are reimbursed.

Imperfect agency will manifest itself differently depending upon

whether physicians are reimbursed on a fee-for service basis,

salaried, or paid on a capitation basis.

Page 15: Chapter 7 Physicians as Providers of Health Care

D. Physicians as Agents

Imperfect Agency in a Fee-for-Service Regime may take the form of

“Physician Induced Demand” (PID).

This can be illustrated, using Figure 7.4, as providing the quantity of

service, (x* - x0) when it is deemed by the physician to be medically

unnecessary.

Figure 7.4 also allows for the possibility that a physician is acting as

a perfect agent in prescribing x* amount of treatment, since his/her

superior information may cause the physician to understand the

advantage of treatment which the patient may prefer to avoid.

Page 16: Chapter 7 Physicians as Providers of Health Care

D. Physicians as Agents

Imperfect Agency, when physicians are either salaried or paid on acapitation basis, is likely to be manifested in skimping rather thanproviding unnecessary treatment.

Imperfect Agency is likely to enter into a physician’s utility functionas a negative term since it directly conflicts with professional ethics.The disutility associated with inducing demand is a limiting factor. (Robert Evans).

It can be argued that skimping on care would also involve disutility.

Moreover, the need to satisfy patients’ NB0 limits imperfect agency.

Page 17: Chapter 7 Physicians as Providers of Health Care

E. Malpractice and Defensive Medicine

The main aim of medical malpractice law is to reduce medicalmistakes resulting from carelessness or incompetence.

However, it also leads to increases in cost of medical care due to(a) the high cost of malpractice insurance (b) the practice of defensive medicine

– This is fear-of-liability-induced changes in medical practice. Itmay be hard to distinguish in practice from physician-induceddemand, which is motivated by enhancing physician income. Bothare easier to do when patients have generous health insurance orare not cost-conscious.