Changing the Debate on Europe

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 7/29/2019 Changing the Debate on Europe

    1/101

  • 7/29/2019 Changing the Debate on Europe

    2/101

    Lord Ralf Dahrendorf (19292009)

    1958 to 1969 Professor of Sociology at the Universities of Hamburg, Tbingen and Konstanz1967 to 1970 Chairman of the Deutsche Gesellschaft fr Soziologie

    1968 to 1969 Member of the Parliament of Baden-Wrttemberg

    1969 to 1970 Member of the German parliament for the Freie Demokratische Partei (FDP) and Parliamentary

    Secretary of State in the Ministry of Foreign Affairs, Berlin

    1970 to 1974 Commissioner for External Trade (European Commission under President Franco Maria Malfatti)

    and Commissioner for Science (President Francois-Xavier Ortoli)

    1974 to 1984 Director of the London School of Economics and Political Science (LSE), London

    1976 to 1979 Commissioner of the Royal Commission on Legal Services (Benson Commission)

    1984 to 1986 Professor of Social Science, Konstanz University

    1987 to 1997 Warden of St Antonys College at the University of Oxford and later Pro-Rector

    1993 Appointment as life peer named Baron Dahrendorf of Clare Market of the City of Westminster

    2005 to 2009 Research Professor at the Social Science Research Center in Berlin (WZB)

    Global Policy Volume 3 . Issue Supplement 1 . December 2012

    Global Policy (2012) 3:Suppl. 1 doi: 10.1111/1758-5899.12037 2012 London School of Economics and Political Science and John Wiley & Sons Ltd.

    1

  • 7/29/2019 Changing the Debate on Europe

    3/101

    Introduction: A Moment forEuropean Sturm und Drang?

    Damian ChalmersLondon School of Economics and Political Science

    In a 2003 article Lord Dahrendorf made three striking

    observations about democracy in Europe (Dahrendorf,

    2003, p. 101). The first was that the European Union was

    increasingly occupying the space of technical coopera-

    tion while national democracies were reinforcing their

    hegemony over issues of emotion and affect. The

    boundary between the technical and the emotional

    might move significantly over time so that money might

    become a matter for international technical cooperation

    and cease to be a strong national symbol. Dahrendorf

    lamented this dichotomy. He noted that it was associ-

    ated with a world in which the technisation of important

    issues made them less susceptible to common sense

    and less comprehensible to ordinary people.

    Secondly, independently of this, Europe had generated

    a peculiar cleavage. It had become associated with a

    utopia for the centre left. The centre right was increas-

    ingly identified with scepticism towards the European

    Union and in some cases it replaced the Soviet Union, as

    the political enemy around which the Centre Right or-

    ganised itself. Thirdly, Dahrendorf was concerned about

    the quality of democracy in the European Union. Forhim, democracy was a political process that placed

    checks and balances on political power, allowed all citi-

    zens voice and brought about significant nonviolent

    change in our societies. He saw the European Union as

    an organisation in which administrative power was insuf-

    ficiently checked and in which it was difficult to conceive

    of popular voice at a supranational level except through

    street demonstrations or the media (Dahrendorf, 2003,

    p. 107).

    Since 2009 this has, of course, ceased to be character-

    istic of the Union. Conflict and instability within political

    institutions and popular protest on the streets havebecome leitmotivs of the European Union. Alongside

    this, the demarcation between the technical and emo-

    tional, unstable at the best of times, has broken down.

    The arcane language of inter-bank lending rates, mutual-

    isation of risk, annual structural balances, troika meetings

    and European stability mechanism processes has

    become not merely the object of protest and anger but

    the obsession of blogs and newspaper front pages

    across the Union.

    It is to be wondered what Dahrendorf would make of

    this. He saw popular protest as desirable and necessary;

    a sign that people realised something was wrong and

    were sufficiently engaged to exercise voice about it,

    often at some risk. However, the direction of all this pro-

    test is very unclear. The turmoil may, indeed, lead to the

    political creativity, vibrant debate, curbs on power and

    mutual engagement that Dahrendorf and others saw as

    productive consequences of conflict. They saw this, how-ever, as a consequence of bounded processes in which

    the terms of engagement prevented its abuse and in

    which there was a certain level of clarity about what lay

    at the heart of the conflict. The meaning of these fea-

    tures in the current crisis is unclear. Conflicts have fluidly

    spilled from one arena to the other and the central

    refrain has been anger and protest rather than clear

    political agendas. If one concern is that this might lead

    to extremism or authoritarianism, another is that nothing

    will be left unchanged. There might be disruption and

    political change but the central dynamos leading to the

    current predicament remain fundamentally untouched.

    This issue looks at three of these: the processes thathave led to the Union being a space for technical coop-

    eration rather than vigorous political contestation, the

    resilience of the characterisation of Europe as a utopia

    and finally, Europes need to build a common and demo-

    cratic social space.

    Three elements are identified as contributing to the

    first of these. The first is the presence of a politically

    attractive consensus, noted in Schelkle and Hassels arti-

    cle about economic policy-making, which emphasises the

    pre-eminence of monetary policy, in particular the setting

    of short-term interest rates by independent central banks,

    to anticipate and correct shocks in the economic cycle.The authors ask why this model has remained so popular

    notwithstanding its treatment of the foundations of

    microeconomics as an empty space and its tendency to

    neglect asset or debt bubbles. Their conclusion is that by

    pressurising policymakers to make labour market reforms

    to respond to the pressure from interest rate policy, it

    leads to a preference for cheap labour over higher unem-

    ployment: an electorally attractive idea for both centre

    left and centre right political parties.

    Global Policy Volume 3 . Supplement 1 . December 2012

    Global Policy (2012) 3:Suppl.1 doi: 10.1111/1758-5899.12009 2012 London School of Economics and Political Science and John Wiley & Sons Ltd.

    SurveyArticle

    3

  • 7/29/2019 Changing the Debate on Europe

    4/101

    However, it might be observed that pan-Union politi-

    cal parties do not exist and the levels of political

    contestation in Union institutions are limited. How did

    this consensus, therefore, enter the Unions policy

    space? The second feature of the Union institution set-

    tlement accounts for this policy diffusion. Schwarzers

    article points out how, even during the period of

    intense legislative activity and political engagement dur-ing the crisis, the Union institutional settlement has

    been marked by incrementalism. This incrementalism is

    present in the policies put forward: be it the increased

    commitment to the principles of the excessive deficit

    procedure or the commitment to labour market reform,

    first present in the EU programme on flexicurity and

    now in the Euro-Plus Pact. In all cases there is a sense

    of permeation rather than the debate of ideas. This is

    also present with institutional reform. Schwarzer claims

    there has been a move towards greater intergovern-

    mentalism as a result of the crisis. Yet, in all cases, it

    has developed around and latched itself onto pre-exist-

    ing structures. She concludes that this incrementalism is

    insufficient to generate the reforms necessary for the

    current challenges.

    This brings us on to the third characteristic of Union

    policy-making, leadership. Strong leadership could, after

    all, break this mould. In their study of the backgrounds

    of prime ministers, economic ministers and central bank-

    ers since 1973, Hallerberg and Wehner discover that

    these are significantly more likely to have a legal back-

    ground in EU states than in other OECD states. There is

    only a strong shift to leaders with an economic back-

    ground at moments of economic crisis. They do not

    speculate about the implications of this. However, if thequalities associated with lawyers include training in

    adversarial argument, mastering briefs and public com-

    munication, they also include an interest in rules. And

    the conduct of economic policy through the develop-

    ment and application of rules is very much what the

    Union is about! Furthermore, there is little evidence that

    the shift to economists during moments of crisis is borne

    of a desire to generate a paradigm shift in economic

    policy-making: rather, it is associated with the careful

    deployment of existing economic models undeflected by

    political opposition.

    There is a good chance that Dahrendorf would havebeen critical of all three of these dynamics. Troublingly,

    the first two, at least, have been reinforced by the crisis.

    The European Union still retains the power, however, to

    be the receptacle for normative re-imagination. In her

    contribution, Kaldor argues that many of the concerns

    about loss of sovereignty or centralisation of administra-

    tive power are misplaced. The Union, for her, is a new

    form of political authority different from that of the

    nation-state that could be a model for global gover-

    nance more generally. To make this point, she analyses

    the Common Security and Defence Policy through the

    prism of the human security template, and argues that

    this led the European intervention in Libya to be differ-

    ent in quality from that if NATO had taken the lead.

    Risses piece considers the extent of the hold of

    this vision on policymakers. He notes that foreign pol-

    icy is much more Europeanised than many realise and

    that this Europeanisation rests strongly on the lan-guage of human rights and democracy. However,

    below the surface, he notes deep challenges, and it is

    unclear how strongly this language informs policy-

    making. Risse notes that, on the one hand, it is used

    in areas such as defence at the levels of the Europe-

    anisation of elites. He also notes, in his study of atti-

    tudes to Turkish membership of the Union, that there

    are deep disagreements about how widely it is to be

    deployed. This is taken further in the two pieces by

    Arne Westad and Michael Cox, respectively, on this

    issue, which look at the two central partners, the USA

    and the Union, and the two central competitors in

    foreign policy, the USA and China. Cox notes that if

    resort to the language of common values and ideas

    of the West may have allowed European states to be

    some of the more reliable allies of the USA, it has

    insufficient hold alone to deal with a relationship

    which is fast changing simply by dint of Europe mov-

    ing from being a predominant partner in US foreign

    policy to its becoming an important part of a wider

    jigsaw. By contrast, Westad observes that there is a

    sense of the growing importance of Sino-European

    relations in both Europe and China. If, in China, this

    is marked in part by the Union being seen as a coun-

    terweight to the USA, Westad observes a deep failureon the Union to develop or communicate a clear pol-

    icy on China. He observes that, paradoxically, the cen-

    tral determinant for relations between the European

    Union and China likely to be how United States for-

    eign policy develops.

    Beyond policy-making within the European Union and

    the Union as a global actor, a third dimension attracted

    Dahrendorfs attention: the complex relation between

    Europe and its citizens. In their piece, Anheier and Fal-

    kenhain observe that a number of mechanisms (both

    bottom-up and top-down) has been developed to make

    people cross borders and identify as Europeans. Theyfind, however, that most of these mechanisms have a

    social bias and neglect large parts of the population,

    most notably the new precariat and less educated

    people.

    This issue suggests that, both within its own territory

    and more broadly in the world, if the Union retains its

    ability to be associated with a sense of vision, it has a

    limited capacity, for all that, to think the unthinkable, as

    Dahrendorf would have urged, and revisit received

    wisdom. It is both ironic and a tragedy that it is the

    Damian Chalmers4

    2012 London School of Economics and Political Science and John Wiley & Sons Ltd. Global Policy (2012) 3:Suppl.1

  • 7/29/2019 Changing the Debate on Europe

    5/101

    machinations and failures of global finance that have

    led the Union to a position at the December European

    Council, where it will have to make hard choices about

    what sort of Europe it wants for its citizens and to be

    projected more widely. Dahrendorf would have urged

    ambitious, fractious and creative debate where nothing

    is treated as untouchable and where a premium is

    placed on popular engagement. We shall wait and seeif that happens.

    Reference

    Dahrendorf, R. (2003) Making Sense of the EU: The Challenge for

    Democracy, Journal of Democracy, 14 (4), pp. 101114.

    Author Information

    R. Damian Chalmers is Professor of European Union Law of the

    London School of Economics and Political Science, London, UK.

    European Sturm und Drang5

    Global Policy (2012) 3:Suppl.1 2012 London School of Economics and Political Science and John Wiley & Sons Ltd.

  • 7/29/2019 Changing the Debate on Europe

    6/101

    Setting the Stage: Lord RalfDahrendorf and the EuropeanProject

    Helmut K. Anheier

    Dean and Professor, Hertie School of Governance

    Gesa-Stefanie Brincker

    Project Manager, Hertie School of Governance

    Lord Ralf Dahrendorf was convinced of the fundamental

    responsibility of intellectuals to doubt all received wis-

    dom, to wonder at that is taken for granted, to question

    all authority, and to pose all those questions that other-

    wise no-one else dares to ask (Dahrendorf, 1963). With the

    Dahrendorf Symposium series we want to honor his leg-

    acy the legacy of a political intellectual who was an intel-

    lectual politician at the same time. He never took Europe

    and the European Union (EU) for granted. Over the course

    of nearly five decades he repeatedly and publicly raised

    often uncomfortable questions about Europe; its achieve-

    ments, potential and weaknesses; but especially, he

    fought for Europe as a democratic project, as a project of

    citizens continuously seeking a better Europe.

    The 1970s: We need a second Europe!

    After a brief period in the German Parliament, serving as

    State Secretary in the Foreign Office, Dahrendorf became

    Commissioner for External Relations and Trade in the

    European Commission in 1970. In 1971 he published two

    articles in Die Zeit under the nom de plume WielandEuropa. In these two articles he blamed the first Europe,

    that is, the achievements of the European Community

    (EC), for being a project concerned with butter, sugar,

    fish and meat. Dahrendorf criticized an unsupportable

    discrepancy between rhetoric and reality (Dahrendorf,1996) and blamed the institutions for their lack of

    accountability. He called for a second and more political

    Europe to overcome the problems created by the first.

    He suggested the regular consultations of foreign minis-

    ters and habit-forming co-operation in as many areas

    of policy-making as appropriate (Dahrendorf, 1990,

    p. 127). Dahrendorf also advocated differentiated integra-

    tion: Some of this might well be la carte, so that mem-

    bers of the Community can pick and choose whether

    they want to participate (Dahrendorf, 1990, p. 127). The

    two articles provoked controversy; Dahrendorfs pseudo-

    nym did not remain secret for long. His harsh judgment

    (he later called it realism) almost caused his dismissal by

    a motion of censure in the European Parliament. Two

    years later, in 1973, in his book Pldoyer fr die Euro-pische Union he proposed, among other recommenda-tions, making the European Commission an institution

    answerable directly to an elected European Parliament.

    The 1980s: Quelques lueurs despoir dans unciel sombre

    In the early 1980s, as director of the London School of Eco-

    nomics (19741984), against the background of the Winter

    of Discontent and Thatcherism, Dahrendorf drew a verycritical picture of the development of the EC, depicting it

    as a grouping of partly unwilling members, without objec-

    tive, working in an intransparent chaos of institutions, in

    which an elected Parliament acted without functions and

    competencies (Dahrendorf, 1983, p. 190). He raised the

    fundamental question why visions are included in official

    documents although we know that these remain visions

    because nobody knows how we can get rid of the para-

    lyzed Europe of today? (Dahrendorf, 1983, p. 190). At the

    same time he presented the common market as a success

    story. According to Dahrendorf, the European Economic

    Community (EEC) had the potential to become an eco-nomic engine for developments in the world, or at least for

    OECD countries. The collapse of the economic world order

    in the 1970s called on the EEC to respond to global chal-

    lenges. He pointed to the European monetary system as an

    arduous substitute in need of institutional strengthening

    in a post-Bretton Woods world order. Dahrendorf, how-

    ever, also raised the question whether Europes momen-

    tum of the 1950s and 1960s had exhausted itself: LEurope

    reste-t-elle jamais un subjonctif, dans le meilleur des cas

    un optatif? (Dahrendorf, 1982, p. 348).

    Global Policy Volume 3 . Supplement 1 . December 2012

    2012 London School of Economics and Political Science and John Wiley & Sons Ltd. Global Policy (2012) 3:Suppl.1 doi: 10.1111/1758-5899.12010

    SurveyArticle

    6

  • 7/29/2019 Changing the Debate on Europe

    7/101

    The early 1990s: The European Revolution of1989

    As Warden of St Anthonys College in Oxford (1987

    1997), Dahrendorf celebrated his 60th birthday in May

    1989 when the Iron Curtain started to fall. In his book

    Reflections on the Revolution in Europe he rejected thedominant reading that the countries of Central and East-

    ern Europe had chosen capitalism over communism;

    instead, he claimed they aspired to return to Europe

    and to build an open society in which there are 100 dif-

    ferent ways forward to freedom and a handful on offer

    at any one time (Dahrendorf, 1990, p. 109).

    Dahrendorf was convinced that the EC and its mem-

    bers had a central responsibility for the future develop-

    ment of Central and Eastern Europe. The exceptional

    events of 1989 delighted him and encouraged him to

    formulate his vision. On the one hand, he saw Europe as

    a village built around a solid house called the EC

    (Dahrendorf, 1990, p. 136), a house that is not exclusion-

    ary or one bloc divided from others, but a project thatunites citizens. On the other hand, his vision of Europe

    went far beyond the continents borders: [My vision of

    Europe] will forever be the Kantian project of a world

    civil society with truly international institutions to guide

    and to sustain it (Dahrendorf, 1990, p. 129). The demo-

    cratic Europe of citizen democracies was his model.

    The late 1990s: European reform is imperativeif the EU is to survive

    In 1993 Dahrendorf was appointed life peer, Baron

    Dahrendorf of Clare Market in the City of Westminster a prominent location on the LSE site. With his earlier cri-

    tiques still valid, he concentrated on concrete reform

    steps that would make the EU more relevant for its citi-

    zens and the world. He recommended including an

    updated European Convention on Human Rights in EU

    treaties as a way to increase citizens identification with

    Europe, to strengthen the democratic accountability of

    the European Commission and to make social cohesion

    among citizens a crucial objective for the future. Finally,

    he called on the EU to include the new democracies of

    Central and Eastern Europe. Enlargement to the east is a

    vital responsibility of a democratic EU, he noted(Dahrendorf, 1996, p. 1). If this endeavor were to fail, the

    EU would lose its appeal to attract non-members.

    The 2000s: How is democracy in Europepossible?

    In January 2005 Dahrendorf was appointed a Research

    Professor at the Social Science Research Center in Berlin.

    Over the next few years his critique of the EUs demo-

    cratic weakness became more severe, culminating in his

    charge that the EU betrayed its very own democratic

    principles. The EU itself would fail any application for

    membership if it wished to join the Union. The EU

    lacked both the demos and a political class bridging

    Brussels and member states. How is democracy in Europe

    possible? he was asked. Considering the European institu-

    tions that negotiate behind closed doors as an insult for

    democracy (Dahrendorf, 2002, p. 35) he stated that insti-tutional reform preserving the status quo would not solve

    the systemic problem of the EU; neither would any consti-

    tutional treaty not based on popular demand. He called

    on the EU to focus on liberal, not statist principles when

    building a European demos. In 2009, shortly before he

    died, Dahrendorf assessed the economic and financial

    crisis as the result of debt-leveraged capitalism (Pumpkapi-talismus). He argued that the crisis could also give rise to achange in Europes economic-political culture. Concretely,

    he called for a responsible capitalism (Dahrendorf, 2009,

    p. 9) marked by medium-term and long-term thinking on

    the part of its leaders.

    Challenges and tensions

    Looking back and looking forth, it is remarkable how valid

    Lord Dahrendorfs criticism, and how relevant his sugges-

    tions for Europes future remain. His reflections about the

    EU capture some of the fundamental challenges concern-

    ing its architecture, performance and communication.

    Dahrendorf repeatedly rejected the argument that Europe

    would develop automatically and inevitably by some

    functional logic towards a political Union. History does

    not work that way (Dahrendorf, 1989, p. 8), he stated.

    Instead he argued that concrete, pragmatic and politicalsteps are needed to move the EU forward albeit demo-

    cratically legitimated steps. He rejected the idea of Eur-

    opes finalit but rather saw it as an ongoing politicalbattle between federalists and confederalists (Dahrendorf,

    1973). As any vision of Europe from generations past may

    ring hollow to those that follow he was convinced that

    every generation has to reinvent Europe.

    Concerns about the Europe of citizens were centre-

    stage in Dahrendorfs reflections. Dahrendorf asked him-

    self how to reconcile citizenship and the EU, how to

    make democracy and freedom in a post-national context

    work (Garton Ash, 2009). He argued that in absence ofdirect democracy, forms of deliberative democracy, as

    part of an emerging European civil society, are a second

    best option. Europe is part of the West, as a normative

    concept that stands for human rights, the rule of law

    and checks and balances (Winkler, 2010). The EU should

    play an appropriate role in the world, if possible, in con-

    junction with the USA. In the absence of global rules

    and agreements, the European Project serves an impor-

    tant model for others. These challenges involve tensions,

    some of which become even more blatant in the current

    Setting the Stage7

    Global Policy (2012) 3:Suppl.1 2011 London School of Economics and Political Science and John Wiley & Sons Ltd.

  • 7/29/2019 Changing the Debate on Europe

    8/101

    financial and Euro crisis: The desire to construct a stable

    EU that serves as a model for post-national cooperation

    seems, for instance, hardly compatible with the need for a

    continuous reinvention of Europe from the inside. More-

    over, an emerging European civil society actively engaged

    in shaping the European project is not backed by broader

    societal support. By contrast, the majority of citizens are

    indifferent to the EU and how it operates. Finally, there isa discrepancy between the principle of democracy and

    the reality that EU institutions remain too remote from the

    citizens. Dahrendorfs legacy and challenge to us is to

    come to terms with these tensions in the changed context

    of the crisis-prone early 21st century.

    The 2011 Dahrendorf Symposium

    Following these thoughts, the inaugural Dahrendorf

    Symposium focused on the ambiguity of positive and

    negative meta-narratives for debating the future of the

    European integration project. The Symposium and itscore themes engaged with central issues of the Euro-

    pean debate in the field of politics, economics and soci-

    ology as well as with ideological and global questions.

    The Hertie School of Governance, the London School of

    Economics and Political Science and Stiftung Mercator

    jointly organized the Dahrendorf Symposium 2011 at the

    Berlin-Brandenburg Academy of Sciences and Humanities

    on 910 November 2011. They brought together leading

    academics, policymakers and the media from across Eur-

    ope and beyond. The inaugural symposium took as its

    theme Changing the Debate on Europe: Moving Beyond

    Conventional Wisdoms. Five international research

    groups, lead by faculty members based at either the Her-tie School or the London School of Economics, involved

    academics from other European institutions. In this con-

    text renowned members of this newly established

    research network developed several working papers, a

    number of which are included in this special issue.

    All articles, contributions and speeches included

    in this issue were developed for the 2011 Dahren-

    dorf Symposium, a joint initiative of the Hertie

    School of Governance, London School of Econom-

    ics and Political Science and Stiftung Mercator.

    References

    Garton Ash, T. (2009) On Liberty. The Dahrendorf Questions. Oxford:Medical Informatics Unit, NDCLS, University of Oxford.

    Dahrendorf, R. (1963) Der Intellektuelle und die Gesellschaft, DieZeit, 29 March.

    Dahrendorf, R. (1973) Pldoyer fr die Europische Union. Munichand Zurich: Piper.

    Dahrendorf, R. (1982) Quelques Lueurs Despoir dans un Ciel Som-bre, in A. Miguel de and Dahrendorf, R (eds) La crise en Europe.Paris: Fayard.

    Dahrendorf, R. (1983) Die Chancen der Krise: ber die Zukunft desLiberalismus. Stuttgart: Deutsche Verlagsanstalt.

    Dahrendorf, R. (1989) The Future of Europe, in Dahrendorf, R., Hos-

    kyns, J., Curzon Price, V., Roberts, B., Wood, G.E., Davis, E. and

    Sealy, L.S., (eds) Whose Europe? Competing Visions for 1992.London: Institute of Economic Affairs.

    Dahrendorf, R. (1990) Reflections on the Revolution in Europe: In aLetter Intended to Have Been Sent to a Gentleman in Warsaw.London: Chatto & Windus.

    Dahrendorf, R. (1996) Why Europe Matters: A Personal View, Report,20 September 1996. London: Centre for European Reform.

    Dahrendorf, R. (2002) Die Krisen der Demokratie. Ein Gesprch mitAntonio Polito. Munich: Beck.

    Dahrendorf, R. (2009) Nach der Krise: Zurck zur protestantischen

    Ethik?, Merkur, 720 (May).Winkler, Heinrich (2010) Greatness and Limits of the West: Reflec-

    tions on an Uncompleted Project, Lecture on 7 October 2010,London School of Economics and Political Science.

    Author Information

    Helmut Anheier is Dean and Professor, Hertie School of Govern-

    ance. He also holds a chair of Sociology at Heidelberg University

    and is Academic Director of the Center for Social Investment.

    Gesa-Stefanie Brincker, Dahrendorf Manager, Hertie School of

    Governance, is a manager for the research project Changing the

    European debate at the Hertie School of Governance and seminar

    coach for the Schwarzkopf Stiftung Young Europeans.

    Helmut K. Anheier and Gesa-Stefanie Brincker8

    201x London School of Economics and Political Science and John Wiley & Sons Ltd. Global Policy (2012) 3:Suppl.1

  • 7/29/2019 Changing the Debate on Europe

    9/101

    The Educational Competence ofEconomic Policymakers in the EU

    Mark HallerbergHertie School of Governance

    Joachim Wehner

    London School of Economics and Political Science

    AbstractThis article compares the competence of the principal economic policymakers in 27 European Union (EU) memberstates with those in other advanced economies. Following earlier work on specialists in government, we considerwhether prime ministers, finance ministers and central bank governors have an education in economics or a relatedfield like business. We find that EU prime and finance ministers are more likely to have legal than economics training,

    which distinguishes them from their OECD peers. Among the most recent accession countries, economic policymakerswere better trained prior to accession than after it. Eurozone economic policymakers have essentially the same overalllevel of education as their EU peers outside the eurozone, but eurozone prime ministers, in particular, are much lesslikely to have advanced economics training. Among the exceptions are countries experiencing a high frequency offinancial crises. In these cases the level of economics training is comparatively high. We speculate that these countrieshave little choice but to appoint policymakers who, at least in terms of background, appear to be competent.

    Policy Implications Educational backgrounds of Europes economic policymakers vary considerably. These differences may translate into policy differences.

    While there are countless volumes of biographies of

    individuals, there has been little systematic study of

    the personal characteristics of economic leaders. One

    exception is the work by Blondel (1985), who presents

    a systematic global survey of government ministers

    from 1945 to 1980, including their occupational back-

    ground. He discusses differences between amateurs

    and specialists, with specialization indicated by minis-

    terial appointments to posts that correspond with their

    prior training. Others have considered the backgrounds

    of political leaders (Besley and Reynal-Querol, 2011;

    Dreher et al., 2009; Goemans et al., 2009) and of cen-

    tral bankers (for example, Ghlmann and Vaubel, 2007).

    There is also a body of literature on the traits of top

    managers in the private sector (for example, Kaplan

    et al., 2008). The only work we know of to date that

    focuses specifically on finance ministers is that of Blon-

    del (1991), although Chwieroth (2007; see also 2010)

    does consider whether central bankers and finance

    ministers in developing countries have neoliberal edu-

    cational backgrounds. Even then, little attention has

    been paid to variations in the level of educational

    attainment and differences in specialization of eco-

    nomic leaders.

    In this article we review certain personal characteris-

    tics of the principal economic policymakers in European

    Union (EU) member states, focusing on their educa-

    tional background. Our sample includes the 27 coun-

    tries when they were democracies since 1973. To study

    whether the patterns are EU-specific or found more gen-

    erally in the advanced market democracies, we also

    include comparative data from most OECD countries that

    are not members of the EU. The main goal of the article is

    descriptive to map out patterns in education. We also

    make no claims that certain types of policymaker neces-

    sarily lead to better economic policies more generally

    (for example, Besley et al., 2011; Rogoff, 1985). At the

    same time, there are patterns that suggest possible cau-

    sal relationships, which we intend to explore in follow-

    up research. However, before one can more fully

    Global Policy Volume 3 . Supplement 1 . December 2012

    Global Policy (2012) 3:Suppl.1 doi: 10.1111/1758-5899.12006 2012 London School of Economics and Political Science and John Wiley & Sons Ltd.

    Research

    Article

    9

  • 7/29/2019 Changing the Debate on Europe

    10/101

    examine causal mechanisms relating to policy, one must

    first understand why certain types of people and not

    others are appointed. We would also prefer to map out

    our data on a case-by-case basis to examine causality

    more directly. This article must be more humble and

    focused on description.

    To preview, we find that EU finance ministers are less

    likely to have training in economics or business thantheir peers in OECD countries. We also find, however,

    that competence, as assessed by training, is higher

    among economic policymakers in some eurozone coun-

    tries like Greece and Portugal that have had financial

    difficulties (Reinhart and Rogoff, 2009). Our assumption

    is that countries that face severe economic problems

    have little choice but to appoint policymakers that, at

    least in terms of their background, appear to be

    competent.

    1. European Integration and Economic

    CompetenceThere are good reasons to concentrate on the back-

    grounds of European economic policymakers in particu-

    lar. First, the responsibilities of the EU more generally

    are strongly weighted towards economic policy. The EU

    is especially active in regulation (for example, Majone,

    1996) but it is responsible for additional economic poli-

    cies as well. It negotiates exclusively trade treaties. Inter-

    nally, capital, labor, services and goods can mostly

    circulate freely because of EU statutes and their enforce-

    ment through the European Commission and rulings

    from the European Court of Justice. Member states have

    coordinated exchange rate policies with varying degreesof success since the final collapse of the Bretton Woods

    system in 1973, culminating in the introduction of the

    euro in 1999. Economic and finance ministers meet regu-

    larly in the Economic and Financial Affairs Council

    (ECOFIN). Hence, economic competence is relevant not

    only domestically at the cabinet table but across Euro-

    pean governments as well.

    In addition, the creation of the euro also diminished

    the overall importance of the domestic foreign minis-

    tries in Europe. Traditionally, the Committee of Perma-

    nent Representatives (COREPER), whose members come

    from the foreign ministries, prepared the Council ofMinister meetings. With the advent of the euro, how-

    ever, the Economic and Financial Committee, composed

    of representatives from the member state finance min-

    istries, replaced COREPER as the key body that sets the

    agenda for ECOFIN meetings. Ministers from eurozone

    countries also meet separately in the Eurogroup. Hence,

    the Economic and Monetary Union (EMU) has elevated

    the importance of finance ministers through ECOFIN

    and now, increasingly, through the Eurogroup. These

    developments lead to expectations about the level of

    competence of European economic policymakers, in

    particular:

    H1: Joining the EU leads to a demand for more

    competent ministers who can represent a given

    country before economic policymakers from

    other countries; the competence level of policy-

    makers should therefore increase with member-ship.

    H2: EMU increases the competence of finance

    ministers.

    In the following section we introduce our dataset,

    describe selected cross-national patterns and examine

    some of the data in relation to these expectations.

    2. EU Policymakers in Comparative Perspective

    We have collected data on the backgrounds of the

    prime minister, finance minister and central bank gover-

    nor for 38 countries on a monthly basis for the period

    1973 to 2010. We include all 27 EU countries as well as

    11 non-EU OECD countries, and we use data from coun-

    tries only when they were democracies. There are two

    principle ways to examine our data. First, we can analyze

    individual policymakers, which is particularly useful for

    studying the circumstances that surrounded their

    appointment. Alternatively, we can examine the time

    share in office of individual policymakers. The latter

    approach can be used to assess the dominance of cer-

    tain personal characteristics across countries by effec-

    tively weighting all individuals by their time in office.Here, we adopt the second approach and compare data

    according to country-months instead of per leader. This

    yields a total of about 15,000 country-month observa-

    tions. We use standard international conventions for clas-

    sifying our data. Education codes come from the United

    Nations Educational, Scientific and Cultural Organization

    (UNESCO, 1997) International Standard Classification of

    Education (ISCED).

    To begin with general statistics for education, Table 1

    compares EU and non-EU countries. For the sake of brev-

    ity and exposition, we refer to the non-EU countries in

    our sample as the OECD countries in the remainder ofthe article even though a number of EU countries are

    also members of the OECD. The first two columns dis-

    play the percentage of country-months with a given

    type of economic policymaker whose highest degree is

    at the graduate (up to a Masters degree) or postgradu-

    ate (doctorate or equivalent) level, with any remainder

    suggesting less than a graduate degree.1 In aggregate,

    there is almost no difference between OECD and EU

    countries. The exception is for central bank governors,

    with OECD countries having more months (39 versus 30

    Mark Hallerberg and Joachim Wehner10

    2012 London School of Economics and Political Science and John Wiley & Sons Ltd. Global Policy (2012) 3:Suppl.1

  • 7/29/2019 Changing the Debate on Europe

    11/101

    percent) of an office holder with the equivalent of a

    doctorate.

    The third and fourth columns on the field of study are

    more interesting. Clearly, there are more country-months

    with economic policymakers who have a legal rather

    than an economic background in EU countries. Twice as

    many EU country-months have a legally trained prime

    minister (or president). Moreover, finance ministers have

    a slight edge in law over economics in EU countries. The

    trend is very different in OECD countries, where the ratiois 55:17. When looking at postgraduate training, the dif-

    ference between the two samples narrows somewhat.

    Finance ministers have an advanced degree in either

    business administration or economics 55 percent of the

    country-months in OECD countries, but only 40 percent

    of the time in the EU group. This difference is smaller

    among the central bankers, although OECD countries

    remain somewhat more likely to have economists in this

    role.

    We also present tables that break down some of the

    data by country. Tables 2 and 3 examine the educational

    background of prime and finance ministers, respectively.For prime ministers, Table 2 indicates that Germany and

    Finland had the longest time with a prime minister in

    office with a degree in either the humanities or the

    social sciences, while Table 3 shows that German finance

    ministers are most likely to have such degrees. For

    finance ministers, law backgrounds are most common in

    Belgium and Luxembourg. If one considers the original

    members of the EU, or the EU-6, their finance ministers

    have an economics graduate degree just 22 percent of

    the time. Of course, it could be that European finance

    ministers are more likely to do advanced degrees in eco-

    nomics, which we examine in Table 4. Indeed, our data

    show that EU-6 finance ministers have a doctoral equiva-

    lent in economics in 32 percent of all country months.

    This is right at the average for all countries in our data-

    set.

    Looking at EU countries, it is noteworthy that Central

    and East European countries have a larger percentage of

    time in office by individuals with natural science under-

    graduate degrees. At the graduate level, 21 percent ofthe time their finance ministers have an equivalent of a

    doctorate in economics. There are three countries under

    joint EUInternational Monetary Fund supervision in the

    summer of 2012, and their backgrounds vary. Greek eco-

    nomic policymakers are some of the best educated in

    the developed world prime ministers and finance min-

    isters in this country have advanced degrees 98 percent

    and 90 percent of the time, respectively. Greek finance

    ministers have an equivalent of a PhD in economics 58

    percent of the time. Portugal is similar prime ministers

    have some sort of an advanced degree 81 percent of

    the time while the equivalent for finance ministers is 94percent, with that degree being a PhD in economics

    fully half of the time. In Ireland the proportions of time

    where the prime minister and finance minister has an

    advanced degree is 57 percent for both positions, and

    just 3 percent of the time does the finance minister have

    an advanced degree in economics.

    To have a better sense of EU effects, we examined sta-

    tistics for the same countries before they joined the

    Union and afterwards. We separated them according to

    waves of joining the EU, with Greece, Spain, Portugal,

    Table 1. Comparison of OECD and EU educational background (% of country-months)

    Graduate Postgraduate

    Graduate, fieldPostgraduate,EconomicsBus.Econ. Law

    Prime ministerOECD 62 27 25 17 19

    EU 63 29 19 38 19Finance ministerOECD 57 35 55 17 55EU 61 34 37 39 40

    Central bankerOECD 61 39 66 16 81EU 70 30 63 19 74

    Source: Official national government sources including parliamentary archives, finance ministry websites and central bank websites;

    international institutions including the European Parliament, European Commission, OECD, Club of Rome, European Investment Bankand the UN; biographical encyclopedias, including Munzinger, Britannica and national biographical databases; personal websites of

    politicians; newspaper reports. This table presents for EU and OECD countries the percentage of country-months when the relevantindividual was a college graduate, studied law or businesseconomics as a primary field, and received a postgraduate degree in eco-nomics. On the International Standard Classification of Education (UNESCO, 1997) six-point scale, this corresponds to a 5 equivalentto the first level of tertiary education completed (for example, Masters degree in many European countries) as well as a 6 (for

    example, PhD).

    Economic Policymakers11

    Global Policy (2012) 3:Suppl.1 2012 London School of Economics and Political Science and John Wiley & Sons Ltd.

  • 7/29/2019 Changing the Debate on Europe

    12/101

    Austria, Finland and Denmark in the early wave and the

    Central and European countries, Cyprus and Malta in thelate wave. There is an increase in competence among

    the early joiners, with the percentage of time of finance

    ministers with advanced economic degrees increasing

    from 24 percent prior to EU membership to 51 percent

    afterwards. In the latter group, however, the results are

    reversed finance ministers had advanced economic

    degrees 78 percent of the time prior to accession but

    only 57 percent afterwards. Still, the post-accession aver-

    age for the late wave countries remains somewhat

    higher than for the early members.

    Table 5 looks at overall levels of education of euroz-

    one leaders. There is no difference when comparingprime ministers and finance ministers. There is, however,

    a statistically significant difference between eurozone

    and non-eurozone members of the EU when it comes to

    policymakers with advanced economics degrees, but it

    runs counter to our expectation above eurozone poli-

    cymakers consistently are less likely to have advanced

    degrees in economics.2 This is especially striking for

    prime ministers just 1 percent of prime ministerial

    months in eurozone countries have had an office holder

    with an advanced degree in economics. The trend is also

    Table 2. Prime ministerial educational background, university degree, 19732010 (% of country-months)

    HumanitiesSoc. Science Economics

    BusinessAdmin. Law

    ScienceMaths Engineering Other None

    Australia* 33 23 0 56 0 0 0 11Austria 28 18 36 32 8 0 0 0Belgium 57 31 0 79 0 0 0 1

    Bulgaria 20 33 10 10 21 7 27 0Canada* 32 13 0 62 0 0 0 0Chile* 0 0 4 47 0 28 22 0Cyprus 13 19 0 68 0 0 0 0

    Czech Republic 23 31 35 4 3 15 0 0Denmark 22 23 0 32 0 0 0 23Estonia 48 6 0 10 32 14 0 0

    Finland 115 1 0 2 0 0 4 0France 51 13 0 36 0 3 11 0

    Germany 110 22 0 19 13 0 0 0Greece 8 33 0 95 0 0 1 0Hungary 23 58 0 25 0 0 22 0Iceland* 1 7 5 65 0 18 0 5Ireland 26 7 48 25 0 0 0 8

    Italy 10 8 2 75 0 0 0 10Japan* 33 20 8 23 8 2 0 5Latvia 30 30 0 6 60 29 0 0Lithuania 11 23 4 0 18 50 0 0Luxembourg 0 0 0 100 0 0 0 0Malta 0 61 0 92 17 0 0 0Mexico* 0 28 43 29 0 0 0 0Netherlands 22 43 21 35 0 0 0 0

    New Zealand* 27 3 5 16 0 0 5 46Norway* 17 30 0 3 0 0 29 22Poland 27 11 4 18 3 30 0 6

    Portugal 13 20 9 20 0 38 0 0Romania 37 29 0 35 0 28 0 0Slovakia 3 0 0 55 0 43 0 0Slovenia 29 71 0 0 10 0 0 0South Korea* 28 28 16 28 0 0 0 0Spain 0 0 0 94 0 6 0 0Sweden 32 25 11 0 0 0 2 54Switzerland* 11 21 8 50 0 8 5 3UK 18 0 20 24 30 0 0 8USA* 58 32 0 0 0 0 11 0Total 29 20 7 38 5 6 3 7

    Note: This table presents the percentage of country-months a country had a prime minister with the given degree. Because some indi-viduals had several degrees, the percentages may add up to more than 100. An asterisk (*) indicates a non-EU country.

    Mark Hallerberg and Joachim Wehner12

    2012 London School of Economics and Political Science and John Wiley & Sons Ltd. Global Policy (2012) 3:Suppl.1

  • 7/29/2019 Changing the Debate on Europe

    13/101

    present, if less dramatic, for finance ministers and central

    bankers.

    3. Concluding Remarks

    There are clear differences in education levels and the

    specialization of economic policymakers between EU

    policymakers and those from other industrialized democ-

    racies. EU prime and finance ministers are more likely to

    have legal than economics training, which distinguishes

    them from their OECD peers. Among the most recent

    accession countries, economic policymakers were better

    trained prior to accession than after it. Eurozone eco-

    nomic policymakers have essentially the same overalllevel of education as their EU peers outside the euroz-

    one, but eurozone prime ministers in particular are much

    less likely to have advanced economics training. Among

    the exceptions are countries with a high frequency of

    financial crises in these cases, the level of economics

    training is comparatively high. We speculate that these

    countries have little choice but to appoint policymakers

    who, at least in terms of background, appear to be

    competent. We plan to explore this finding further in

    follow-up work.

    Table 3. Finance ministerial educational background, university degree, 19732010 (% of country-months)

    HumanitiesSoc. Science Economics

    BusinessAdmin. Law

    ScienceMaths Engineering Other None Unknown

    Australia* 0 9 19 45 0 0 5 22 0Austria 0 5 86 11 3 0 11 0 0Belgium 8 1 1 89 0 0 0 0 5

    Bulgaria 0 100 1 0 10 0 0 0 0Canada* 48 0 17 51 0 0 0 6 2Chile* 18 0 60 0 0 21 0 0 0Cyprus 0 50 37 25 0 0 0 0 15

    Czech Republic 0 29 25 23 6 18 0 0 0Denmark 21 38 19 11 0 9 3 0 0Estonia 11 60 27 0 9 4 6 0 0

    Finland 18 3 0 31 0 13 7 23 4France 9 21 1 59 3 19 0 8 0

    Germany 74 39 0 28 1 0 0 0 0Greece 13 57 0 30 0 13 0 0 0Hungary 0 63 0 12 0 7 19 0 0Iceland* 16 23 0 36 5 0 9 11 0Ireland 7 13 27 35 0 7 0 16 0

    Italy 7 21 11 65 0 0 0 7 0Japan* 8 21 30 41 1 0 0 0 0Latvia 0 39 3 0 35 24 0 0 33Lithuania 14 76 20 0 31 5 0 0 2Luxembourg 0 13 13 87 0 0 0 0 0Malta 11 11 83 21 0 0 0 0 0Mexico* 0 100 0 0 0 0 0 0 0Netherlands 12 71 13 14 0 0 0 0 0

    New Zealand* 34 4 18 13 15 0 0 23 0Norway* 15 26 21 12 0 0 6 20 0Poland 0 75 24 0 0 1 0 0 0

    Portugal 0 66 12 19 0 16 0 0 0Romania 0 50 40 0 3 5 0 0 10Slovakia 0 84 0 0 8 29 5 0 0Slovenia 0 85 0 10 0 0 0 0 10South Korea* 0 37 11 43 0 0 0 0 18Spain 0 73 0 51 8 5 0 0 0Sweden 31 19 8 5 0 0 25 23 0Switzerland* 16 50 0 3 0 21 0 11 0UK 60 7 0 34 0 0 0 3 0USA* 50 35 7 5 0 4 0 0 0Total 16 34 16 27 3 5 3 6 2

    Note: This table presents the percentage of country-months a country had a finance minister with the given degree. Because someindividuals had multiple degrees, the percentages may add up to more than 100. An asterisk (*) indicates a non-EU country.

    Economic Policymakers13

    Global Policy (2012) 3:Suppl.1 2012 London School of Economics and Political Science and John Wiley & Sons Ltd.

  • 7/29/2019 Changing the Debate on Europe

    14/101

    This article focused on describing meaningful differ-ences across countries and time and not on strictly cau-

    sal relationships. These findings, however, do lead one

    to wonder whether a lack of economics training among

    prime ministers and finance ministers has led to deci-

    sions in the EU that focus more on legal issues than on

    economic sense. One should be careful about pushing

    this speculation too far ministers sit at the top of min-

    istries with many trained staff. Management skills may in

    day-to-day affairs be more important than specialized

    knowledge. At the same time, in crisis situations where

    time is short, these differences could have an effect on

    the decisions leaders take.

    Notes

    We thank Tim Besley, Scott Gehlbach and two anonymous review-

    ers for helpful comments and suggestions. Luca Giapelli, Claudia

    Granados, Linnea Kreibohm, Roberto Martinez, Santiago Massons

    and Juan Camilo Taborda provided superb research assistance.

    1. In many European countries prior to the Bologna process, the

    first degree one could receive at the university was the rough

    equivalent of an MA.

    2. All t-tests are significant at the P < 0.01 level.

    References

    Besley, T. and Reynal-Querol, M. (2011) Do Democracies Select

    More Educated Leaders? American Political Science Review, 105

    (3), pp. 552566.

    Besley, T., Montalvo, J. G. and Reynal-Querol, M. (2011) Do Educated

    Leaders Matter? Economic Journal, 121 (554), pp. F205227.

    Blondel, J. (1985) Government Ministers in the Contemporary World.

    London: Sage.

    Blondel, J. (1991) Ministers of Finance in Western Europe: A Special

    Career? European University Institute Working Paper SPS 9111.

    Florence: European University Institute.

    Chwieroth, J. (2007) Neoliberal Economists and Capital Account Lib-

    eralization in Emerging Markets, International Organization, 61(2), pp. 443463.

    Chwieroth, J. (2010) Shrinking the State: Neoliberal Economists and

    Social Spending in Latin America, in R. Abdelal, M. Blyth and C.

    Parsons (eds) Constructing the International Economy. Ithaca, NY:

    Cornell University Press, pp. 2346.

    Dreher, A., Lamla, M. J., Lein, S. M. and Somogyi, F. (2009) The

    Impact of Political Leaders Profession and Education on

    Reforms, Journal of Comparative Economics, 37 (1), pp. 169193.

    Goemans, H. E., Gleditsch, K. S. and Chiozza, G. (2009) Introducing

    Archigos: A Dataset of Political Leaders, Journal of Peace

    Research, 46 (2), pp. 269283.

    Table 4. Finance ministers with PhDs, 19732010 (% ofcountry-months)

    Economics Other None Unknown

    Chile* 100 0 0 0Poland 84 0 16 0Mexico* 83 0 17 0

    Hungary 63 6 31 0Greece 58 0 42 0Spain 56 35 9 0Portugal 50 7 43 0

    Slovenia 44 0 51 5Romania 40 25 30 5Bulgaria 38 0 62 0

    South Korea* 37 5 49 9Netherlands 31 0 69 0

    USA* 29 0 71 0Slovakia 27 0 73 0New Zealand* 24 0 76 0Lithuania 23 5 71 1Austria 21 16 63 0

    Switzerland* 18 50 32 0Estonia 16 0 84 0Latvia 14 3 66 16France 12 4 84 0Cyprus 11 20 61 8Italy 11 32 57 0Czech Republic 9 2 89 0Belgium 8 59 30 2

    Luxembourg 8 30 62 0Sweden 8 29 63 0Australia* 2 0 98 0

    Canada* 0 7 93 0Denmark 0 0 100 0Finland 0 8 92 0Germany 0 55 45 0Iceland* 0 7 93 0Ireland 0 0 100 0Japan* 0 0 100 0Malta 0 21 79 0Norway* 0 0 100 0UK 0 24 76 0Total 21 13 65 1

    Note: This table presents the percentage of country-months acountry had a finance minister with a doctoral degree. Anasterisk (*) indicates a non-EU country.

    Table 5. EU policymakers educational levels and advancedeconomics degrees inside and outside the eurozone, 19732010

    Primeminister

    Financeminister

    Centralbanker

    Non-eurozone 5.17 (26%) 5.25 (42%) 5.27 (75%)

    Eurozone 5.19 (1%) 5.24 (35%) 5.39 (69%)

    Note: The first number is the average educational level on the

    International Standard Classification of Education (UNESCO,1997) six-point scale, in which 5 is equivalent to the first levelof tertiary education completed (for example, a Masters degreein many European countries) and 6 the second (for example, aPhD). The number in parentheses is the percent of time thatthe office holder had an advanced degree in economics.

    Mark Hallerberg and Joachim Wehner14

    2012 London School of Economics and Political Science and John Wiley & Sons Ltd. Global Policy (2012) 3:Suppl.1

  • 7/29/2019 Changing the Debate on Europe

    15/101

    Ghlmann, S. and Vaubel, R. (2007) The Educational and Occupa-

    tional Background of Central Bankers and Its Effect on Inflation:

    An Empirical Analysis, European Economic Review, 51 (4),

    pp. 925941.

    Kaplan, S. N., Klebanov, M. M. and Sorensen, M. (2008) Which CEO

    Characteristics and Abilities Matter? National Bureau of Eco-

    nomic Research Working Paper 14195. Cambridge, MA: NBER.

    Majone, G. (ed.) (1996) Regulating Europe. London: Routledge.

    Reinhart, C. and Rogoff, K. (2009) This Time is Different. Princeton,NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Rogoff, K. (1985) The Optimal Degreeof Commitment to an Intermedi-

    ate Target, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 100(4), pp. 11691190.

    United Nations Educational, Scientific and Cultural Organization

    (UNESCO)(1997) International Standard Classification of Education.

    Available from http://www.unesco.org/education/information/

    nfsunesco/doc/isced_1997.htm [Accessed 21 October 2012].

    Author Information

    Mark Hallerberg is Professor of Public Management and Political

    Economy at the Hertie School of Governance. He is Director of

    Herties Fiscal Governance Centre.

    Joachim Wehner is Senior Lecturer in Public Policy at the London

    School of Economics and Political Science.

    Economic Policymakers15

    Global Policy (2012) 3:Suppl.1 2012 London School of Economics and Political Science and John Wiley & Sons Ltd.

  • 7/29/2019 Changing the Debate on Europe

    16/101

    The Policy Consensus Ruling EuropeanPolitical Economy: The Political

    Attractions of Discredited Economics

    Waltraud Schelkle

    European Institute, London School of Economics

    Anke Hassel

    Hertie School of Governance

    AbstractSince the Great Recession in 2008 academic economics has come under heavy criticism. But a straightforward

    alternative is not in sight either. We analyse in this article how the major flaws of applied economics are the mirrorimage of its attractions to policymakers, mainstream political parties and reform-minded administrations. We firstassess what the consensus until recently has been and how it could have been implicated in the crisis. Secondly, weargue, following Hall, that the policy consensus continues to persist because it is politically attractive. The article endswith observations of how the management of the Euro area crisis still shows the attractiveness of the consensus.

    Policy recommendations: Introduce greater pluralism in advisory bodies on economic policy to include civil society organizations, such as

    trade unions, and consumer organizations as well as academic disciplines other than economics. Review compensation policy for representatives on advisory committees to create a level playing field for experts

    from civil society organizations and independent consultants with financial sector lobbyists. Support and back up critical voices in the financial industry and in regulatory bodies against those who defend

    regulatory neglect and the privilege of rent-seeking for the financial industry.

    1. Whose crisis?

    Since 2008 crises in financial markets have forced gov-

    ernments to unprecedented monetary and fiscal inter-

    vention, unprecedented both in scale and degree of

    coordination. Sovereign debtors are under sustained

    attack by financial markets for their poor growth andpitiful public finances that the crisis of 20082009 gener-

    ated. Governments are desperate for advice on how to

    stop contagion and a new recession. The situation is par-

    ticularly difficult in Europe where the future of the Euro-

    pean Union (EU) and the common currency in particular

    are at stake. This seems a pertinent moment for taking

    stock of what the economic policy consensus of the

    recent past has been, whether it is to blame for the

    recent crises or whether it can help policymakers now in

    their attempts at effective crisis management.

    In similar previous situations, namely the Great

    Depression of the interwar years and the stagflation

    following the oil crises in the 1970s, the economic policy

    consensus of the time came under close scrutiny and

    eventually shifted to Keynesianism and monetarism,

    respectively. Today, criticism of academic economics is

    not in short supply but a straightforward alternative isnot in sight either. The critics and mainstream econo-

    mists do not agree even on how to label the consensus

    of recent years. The less favourable characterizations

    span from privatized Keynesianism (Crouch, 2009) and

    neoliberal market fundamentalism (Hall and Lamont,

    2011) to macroeconomics based on models of a centrally

    planned economy (Buiter, 2009). For evidence of a para-

    digm in crisis, the critics can point to over-indebtedness

    of households and increasing inequality, but also to the

    Global Policy Volume 3 . Supplement 1 . December 2012

    2012 London School of Economics and Political Science and John Wiley & Sons Ltd. Global Policy (2012) 3:Suppl.1 doi: 10.1111/1758-5899.12012

    Research

    Article

    16

  • 7/29/2019 Changing the Debate on Europe

    17/101

    unravelling of institutional fundamentals such as central

    bank independence.1

    In defence, mainstream economics can point out that

    they explore market imperfections and outright failure in

    controlled variations of the perfect-competition-full-flexibility

    benchmark (for example, Smets and Wouters, 2003). The

    use of the consensus model by many central banks and

    supranational, applied research outfits proves that macroec-onomists are not only scientists but also engineers engaged

    in fixing real world problems (Woodford, 2009). The defend-

    ers are bolstered by the fact that the lessons, which govern-

    ments seem to have drawn from the various crises, suggest

    that the economic policy consensus of the last two decades

    is less obsolete than the critics think. As before, suprana-

    tional policy reports and summit conclusions end with calls

    for structural reform, budget consolidation and commit-

    ment to price stability. Global financial regulation is still

    orchestrated by men in grey suits meeting in Basel and

    relies heavily on the same old instrument of (modest if

    somewhat raised) capital requirements. Put less favourably,

    a distinct possibility is that mainstream economics is a

    pathology (Hay, 2011) that simply lingers on without killing

    the patient outright.

    But what does the consensus consist of? Those who

    see the financial crisis also as an ideational or intellectual

    crisis tend to characterize mainstream economics as the

    embodiment of neoliberalism that assumes that markets

    get it right. Those who acknowledge that there may

    have been some oversight but that there is no alterna-

    tive to the new synthesis insist that there is a well-devel-

    oped analysis of market failure in mainstream economics

    and it merely has to be updated in light of the new

    experience. An alternative to both, for which we arguein this article, is the position that accepts that it was not

    neoliberalism that got into crisis but a synthesis of neo-

    classical and new Keynesian economics that takes market

    failures into account; yet the alternative also concedes

    that the policy consensus has serious flaws that made it

    overlook all the factors leading up to this crisis, such as

    systemic risk.

    2. New Keynesianism and neoliberalism theargument in brief

    Our contribution addresses the policy consensus on theEuropean political economy in one fundamental way. In

    much of the writings on the shift from the post-war

    golden years to a new economic paradigm after the late

    1970s, the contrast is drawn between the Keynesian wel-

    fare state on the one hand and neoliberalism on the

    other hand.2 Many political scientists and political econo-

    mists therefore portray mainstream economics, its policy

    advice and the politics of market regulation as if it was

    under the spell of a decidedly neoliberal thrust (for

    example, Hay, 2011; McNamara, 2006; Stiglitz, 2008).

    We think that this contrast is flawed. Keynesianism has

    not given way to a neoliberal agenda but to a new

    Keynesian-neoclassical synthesis that took price and

    wage rigidities into account, as a fact of economic life,

    with costs and benefits. The new Keynesian macro-eco-

    nomic policy that followed from it combined activist

    inflation targeting with structural supply-side policies,

    which means policies that aim at changing certain insti-tutions like employment protection or wage-bargaining

    patterns.

    Structural supply-side labour market policies are fre-

    quently seen as a defining element of neoliberalism.

    Activation, in the sense of privatizing the responsibility

    for finding a job, in contrast to an active labour market

    policy, was therefore seen as a cornerstone of a neolib-

    eral agenda that abandoned the Keynesian welfare state.

    However, we argue that the turn to supply-side labour

    market policy was a response to political demands of

    core electoral constituencies rather than the biggest

    parcel in a neoliberal package.

    In other words, both trends the change in labour

    market policies and the demise of the Keynesian welfare

    state went in parallel and were even connected, but

    not because of a macro-economic paradigm that was

    dismissive of the welfare state as such. At first glance,

    this difference sounds overly subtle, but we maintain

    that it helps us to understand the persistence of the

    policy consensus even after the financial crisis.

    A challenge to our view is Crouchs interesting hypoth-

    esis that the distinction between new Keynesian macro-

    economic policy and a supply-side policy agenda can

    explain why neoliberalism did not die (Crouch, 2009).

    Crouchs answer is to claim that private Keynesianismsucceeded the Keynesian welfare state, which kept

    demand steady and helped neoliberalism to continue

    even though it meant a harsher economic environment

    for the working population. He maintains that the Key-

    nesian system of public demand management was not

    followed by a neoliberal turn to pure market rule, but

    rather to market liberalism combined with extensive con-

    sumer debt incurred by low-income and medium-income

    households (Crouch, 2009, p. 382). Privatized Keynesian

    demand management thus helped to maintain the

    rather unpopular and unwanted neoliberalism and

    liberalization.We argue that new Keynesianism and supply-side poli-

    cies interact in a somewhat different way. First of all,

    privatized Keynesianism, as portrayed by Crouch (2009),

    is not demand management at all but a reinforcement

    of the pro-cyclical movements of market demand. The

    new Keynesian policy consensus meant, above all, a

    move from the macro-level to the micro-level of eco-

    nomic management. This micro-level economic manage-

    ment addresses the supply side of the economy, that is,

    price and wage rigidities. It also tackles the denial of

    Policy Consensus17

    Global Policy (2012) 3:Suppl.1 2012 London School of Economics and Political Science and John Wiley & Sons Ltd.

  • 7/29/2019 Changing the Debate on Europe

    18/101

    market access for certain consumers that is supposedly

    caused by a lack of competition between financial pro-

    viders. However, liberalization cannot be sustained on a

    purely ideological basis for long. Policymakers must be

    seen to solve labour market problems and thereby

    respond to political demands by the electorate. We sug-

    gest that this is what the synthesis model delivered and

    why even a flawed model of new Keynesian policy-making became entrenched in our political system.

    In the following, we will assess what the consensus

    until recently was and what its potential flaws were.

    Next, we explore what made the consensus attractive. In

    this, we follow Hall (1989, pp. 370375), who proposed

    that the political power of economic ideas requires, at a

    minimum, their economic, administrative and political

    viability. That is to say, ideas must resolve economic

    problems deemed pressing and relevant by policymak-

    ers; they must be in accord with bureaucratic practices

    and not overstretch implementation capacities; and they

    must appeal to broader constituencies and possibly

    allow policymakers to forge new coalitions. We conclude

    that, paradoxically, the flaws could be the flip-side of

    what made the consensus attractive, in particular to

    European governments with their perception of pressing

    low employment problems.

    This is followed by an assessment how the economic

    policy consensus worked in practice and may have actu-

    ally contributed to the crisis. The obsession with labour

    market reforms made policymakers miss the gathering

    storm in financial markets. The contribution ends with

    our observations of euro area crisis management that

    shows that the discredited economic consensus is still

    alive and well. The formation of politically cross-cuttingcoalitions that aim at defending the real economy

    against financial havoc has only started to form and the

    jury is still out on whether it will succeed.

    3. What was the economic consensus of thelast two decades?

    This section presents the main elements of the work-

    horse model of mainstream macroeconomics, that is not

    its theoretically most advanced version but the analytical

    worldview with which applied economists are brought

    up. This workhorse model is called the new neoclassicalsynthesis or new Keynesianism; labels that can be used

    interchangeably, as we argue below.3 It is necessary to

    recall the basics because we want to revisit the critique

    from within that accuses the economic mainstream of a

    naive trust in markets and an obsession with general

    equilibrium in a complete market system (for example,

    Buiter, 2009; Krugman, 2009). These informed critiques

    are often taken up in more popular versions as the neo-

    liberal policy consensus in ideology and practice. In

    our view, the new mainstream has been much more

    interested in market imperfections and their policy impli-

    cations than the critics acknowledge. This raises the

    question whether the economic policy consensus is at

    all to blame for the crisis. If it is to blame, we are in dee-

    per trouble than even the critics think. It simply will then

    not do for economics to take account of the real world

    if that is what they already did.

    The workhorse model for economic policy-making

    The consensus model has three building blocks (Carlin

    and Soskice, 2006, pp. 8190). In the first, aggregate

    demand (household consumption and possibly firm

    investment) are determined as resulting from income

    and the real interest rate it is the conventional IS curve

    of the old neoclassical synthesis. In the second, the sup-

    ply-side of the economy is characterized as resulting

    from wage and price setting in imperfectly competitive

    labour and commodity markets this is the resurrected

    Phillips curve in a form that has absorbed the monetarist

    critique. This supply side determines a natural rate of

    unemployment, given the structural and institutional fea-

    tures of the economy, such as transaction costs and cor-

    poratist arrangements that keep it from attaining full

    employment. In principle, this long-run equilibrium is

    compatible with any level of nominal prices. So we need,

    finally, a monetary rule that gives the economy a nomi-

    nal anchor and gets it back into a low-inflation equilib-

    rium after a shock. The central bank uses the interest

    rate, not money supply, which is the defining difference

    from monetarism. The rule describes the monetary

    authoritys preferences over the inflationunemployment

    trade-off that characterizes the supply side of theeconomy.

    How does a capitalist economy work in this stylized

    depiction? The standard situation is that the economy is

    in its long-run equilibrium and then hit by a shock, that

    is, an exogenous disturbance in demand (a change in

    investment or consumption) or in supply (a change in

    input prices), which pushes the economy off track. Since

    the natural (un-) employment rate is determined by

    wage andor price setters, this leaves only inflation as a

    choice variable for policymakers (Akerlof et al., 1996,

    p. 1), typically with zero as the optimal inflation rate.4

    The central bank perceives shocks as making the econ-omy deviate from its inflation target. If then prices rise

    more, the central bank must raise the interest rate (or

    vice versa), which reduces the demand for credit that

    would sustain the existing level of investment and con-

    sumption. Higher unemployment will dampen wage and

    price increases, depending on the features of the labour

    and product market such as employment protection or

    costs of price adjustment that determine short-run

    trade-offs between inflation and employment. The cen-

    tral bank moves the economy along these short-run

    Waltraud Schelkle and Anke Hassel18

    2012 London School of Economics and Political Science and John Wiley & Sons Ltd. Global Policy (2012) 3:Suppl.1

  • 7/29/2019 Changing the Debate on Europe

    19/101

    Phillips curves back to the long-run equilibrium. The

    more inertia there is in price and wage setting, the

    longer this will take and the more unemployment will

    be necessary to force down inflation. From the point of

    view of the central bank, the supply side (the Phillips

    curve) is thus the constraint on its stabilization policy

    while the demand side (the IS curve) is the transmission

    channel through which monetary policy works.The first observation that will strike most readers is

    the central role of monetary policy for the working

    and stabilization of the economy. The first surveys of

    Goodfriend and King (1997) and Clarida et al. (1999)

    codified the macroeconomic consensus by pointing out

    the role of monetary policy in it. The consensus could

    be formulated without any reference to fiscal policy.5

    The new synthesis considers fiscal policy to be distort-

    ing, determined by a political process and thus ruled

    by other than efficiency considerations (Goodfriend and

    King, 1997, pp. 237, 245, 280). In their extensive survey

    of the new Keynesian consensus on the conduct of

    monetary policy, Clarida et al (1999 p. 1702) mention

    fiscal policy only once, namely, when they note that in

    a low inflation environment, nominal interest rates may

    hit the zero bound and so the important open ques-

    tion arises as to whether cooperation from fiscal pol-

    icy is necessary (p. 1702). It would probably have

    perplexed Keynes to find that this is considered an

    open question by economists who align themselves

    with his name.

    Monetary policy here is activist (Goodfriend and King

    1997, p. 256), in the sense that the central bank does

    not simply wait and see after a disturbance. But the

    monetary authority is also not pro-actively seeking toshift the long-run equilibrium this is the role left for

    government and their structural reforms of labour and

    product markets. The monetary rule is therefore a

    response function, summarizing (averse) preferences over

    inflation and unemployment. A central bank with high

    preferences for price stability chooses a radical disinfla-

    tion strategy even if costs in terms of employment are

    high, and chooses a more gradualist one if it is less

    inflation-averse.

    An activist central banks own preferences over the

    short-run Phillips trade-off that capitalist economies face

    imply a credibility problem. This arises when the centralbank is more unemployment-averse than wage and price

    setters and can manipulate the very constraint it faces,

    here: inflation expectations. This difference in prefer-

    ences seems to be a far-fetched assumption, given that

    central bankers are not normally recruited from the rank-

    and-file of trade unions. The rationale offered is that

    even independent central banks may come under pres-

    sure from governments with an inflation bias (Carlin and

    Soskice, 2006, p. 167). This has allowed intense study of

    how a central bank with an inflation bias can be com-

    mitted to price stability, and was extremely influential in

    the design of the European monetary union (Blinder,

    1997; Schelkle, 2006).

    The consensus as synthesis

    In what sense does this amount to a policy consensus

    and a new synthesis of once opposed schools of macro-economic thought, Keynesianism and monetarism? In

    methodological terms, mainstream economists have

    come to accept most of the critique that neoclassical

    macroeconomists, from Milton Friedman to Robert Lucas,

    launched against the old neoclassical synthesis, meaning

    the pump-priming of the IS-LM model. Expectations

    must not be treated ad hoc but given careful thought,

    which has been turned into the stipulation that expecta-

    tions must be rational in the sense of model-consistent.6

    This has been generalized to a call for micro-founda-

    tions; that is, all macroeconomic relationships and

    responses must be grounded in individually rational

    behaviour that translates into aggregate behaviour. The

    synthesis makes extensive use of the eternally living rep-

    resentative agent that optimizes over an infinite time

    horizon. It is the basis for dynamic stochastic general

    equilibrium models that many central banks and the

    European Commission now use (Buiter, 2009).

    In substantive theoretical terms, adherents of the syn-

    thesis accept the crucial role of monetary policy for stabi-

    lizing the economy and that even in the presence of

    under-employment, inflationary pressures may arise. It is

    a moot point which school of thought compromised

    more here. Monetarism and its offspring, real business

    cycle theory, claimed that the central bank should simplyfollow a strict money supply rule that endows the econ-

    omy with enough additional transactions media to grow

    at price stability. This has been replaced by an inflation-

    targeting central bank that uses the interest rate actively

    to stabilize an economy prone to shocks. At the same

    time, (macro) economists have adopted the monetarist

    lens of the central bank that grasps the entire macro-

    economy by adding the reinterpreted Phillips curve as a

    constraint on its policymaking. The Phillips curve is now

    an aggregate supply curve fixing output and equilibrium

    employment in the long run and the adjustment path in

    the short run. It makes labour and product markets ulti-mately determine equilibrium while financial markets

    play only a residual role.7 One can thus argue that,

    strictly in terms of economic theory, the notion of a neo-

    classical synthesis is more pertinent while the policy

    activism of the central bank can be characterized as Key-

    nesian. The terms can thus be used interchangeably,

    depending on whether the authors want to stress the

    supply-side determined, natural equilibrium or the real-

    istic imperfections that can give the demand side and

    monetary policy a lasting influence.

    Policy Consensus19

    Global Policy (2012) 3:Suppl.1 2012 London School of Economics and Political Science and John Wiley & Sons Ltd.

  • 7/29/2019 Changing the Debate on Europe

    20/101

    The reconceptualization of the price mechanism is the

    most relevant example to illustrate what a rich research

    programme opened up thanks to this synthesis: the

    evidence from mature economies suggests that firms are

    not price takers but price setters in markets for less than

    fully substitutable goods or brands, that is, in monopo-

    listically competitive markets (Akerlof et al., 1996, p. 21;

    Goodfriend and King, 1997, p. 249). The price settingthat corresponds to this form of competition, namely

    mark-up pricing, can grasp a rich set of economic phe-

    nomena, such as pricing-to-market in volatile markets

    and smoothing over the business cycle. In contrast to

    marginal cost-pricing in atomistically competitive mar-

    kets, it provides a surplus that can be the subject of

    negotiations with organized labour. Inflation can thus

    arise from distributional conflict [among] different social

    groups held only in check by a credibly inflation-averse

    central bank (Carlin and Soskice, 2006, pp. 133134,

    160168).

    Its flaws in general

    Our overview of the economic policy consensus before

    the crisis contained three possible candidates that may

    be relevant to the question Whose crisis that of neo-

    liberalism or of something called new neoclassical

    synthesisnew Keynesianism? It may be helpful to sum-

    marize them briefly at this point, mainly to show that

    what could be dismissed as rather esoteric squabbles

    among academics before the crisis might be serious

    flaws contributing to the crisis from hindsight.

    At the most obvious level, we agree with the critics

    of mainstream economics that the underlying bench-mark of a dynamic general equilibrium is a problem

    (see Prosser [2006] for a particularly insightful critique).

    This reference point gives the impression that the

    enlightened Visible Hand can shift the economy gradu-

    ally and continuously towards this benchmark by get-

    ting rid of rigidities, by aligning incentives through

    more transparent information and by allowing for the

    emergence of missing markets through permissive regu-

    lation. Financial markets cannot alter this underlying

    equilibrium; if anything they should facilitate its attain-

    ment. This is the source of the label, market fundamen-

    talism for the trend in economic policy over recentdecades (Hall and Lamont, 2011). It also paints a much

    more optimistic image of capitalist economies than we

    can find in Keynes (1936). In this mainstream economics

    perspective, capitalist economies may be full of micro-

    economic imperfections but they have no systemic

    flaws. Market adjustment may work imperfectly but it

    does not work perversely, as Keynes (1936, p. 291)

    maintained for a situation of deflation, to be outlined

    presently, and Shiller (2003) claimed for a situation of

    asset market bubbles.

    Secondly, the micro-foundations agenda, while seem-

    ingly esoteric to non-economists, served to restore the

    superior role of price adjustment. Only non-economic

    explanations, such as political forces (insider power) or

    psychology (the representative worker resents inequal-

    ity), can make sense of real rigidity, for instance wage

    earners resisting wage cuts even when faced with rising

    unemployment. This goes directly against the Keynesianproposition that quantity adjustment may trump price

    adjustment in capitalist economies and that this may be

    functional. For the latter, take the case of why market

    forces cannot lead an economy out of deflation: even if

    unemployment has risen, there may be no tendency for

    real wages to fall. Rising unemployment makes desper-

    ate workers to offer their services at ever lower wage

    rates while desperate firms lower prices to sell the goods

    they already produced. But if both wages and prices fall,

    then real wages stay roughly constant and in any case

    do not necessarily fall as much as needed to make firms

    keep their work force, let alone hire more workers at

    lower nominal wages. Thus, the synthesis does not con-

    sider the case that nominal flexibility can generate real

    rigidity, and arguably suffers from a fallacy of composi-

    tion. It takes the whole for its parts, here: by assuming

    that both wages and prices are rigid while they can be

    both flexible, making the whole rigid.8 In macroeconom-

    ics, (nominal) flexibility can be the problem rather than

    the solution. But the micro-foundations agenda is based

    on the premise that macroeconomics is not a field of

    study in its own right because the whole is equal to the

    sum of its parts, neither more nor less. This is too strong

    an assumption, as Keynes (1936, pp. 358361) illustrated

    also with his paradox of thrift9 and social choice theo-rists like Thomas Schelling (1978) have confirmed since

    then.

    Finally, the consensus model has a sensible take on

    the Phillips curve, namely that it may exist but it cannot

    be exploited (Carlin and Soskice, 2006, p. 75). Yet, by

    making it the prime constraint on monetary policy and

    macroeconomic stabilization generally, it focuses all

    attention on labour and commodity markets. Financial

    markets come in only as an afterthought regarding the

    transmission of monetary policy. Policymakers were busy

    looking under the lamppost of the new synthesis for yet

    another necessary structural reform while financial bub-bles were allowed to grow. This was despite the fact

    that there have been plenty of warnings about asset

    market bubbles (even Alan Greenspan admitted that

    there may be irrational exuberance in financial markets),

    yet the moment passed after markets rebounded after

    the 2001 crash. By concentrating on markets for (the

    flow of) services and goods, there was an in-built analyti-

    cal bias against considering the catastrophic stock flow

    dynamics resulting from asset and debt accumulation.

    These dynamics would come to trump any rigidities in

    Waltraud Schelkle and Anke Hassel20

    2012 London School of Economics and Political Science and John Wiley & Sons Ltd. Global Policy (2012) 3:Suppl.1

  • 7/29/2019 Changing the Debate on Europe

    21/101

    labour and commodity markets upon which inflation

    targeters and structural reformers so obsessively concen-

    trated.

    4. What were the attractions of this economicpolicy consensus?

    The flaws of the new synthesis did certainly not dimin-ish its political attractions. They may even have contrib-

    uted to its attraction, which we can understand

    following Hall (1989) by assessing its economic, adminis-

    trative and political viability. He synthesizes three

    approaches. There is, firstly, an economist-centred

    account that claims it is expert advice in government

    that gives economic ideas powerful influence; which is

    typically proposed by academics who served for some

    time in government or in a central bank (recent exam-

    ples can be found in Bussire and Stracca, 2010). Sec-

    ond, a stat