94
CAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND IMPUTATION, CAPITAL GAINS TAX AND THE INVESTMENT TAX CREDIT by Ervin L. Black* Assistant Professor Joseph Legoria** Assistant Professor Keith F. Sellers* Associate Professor *Department of Accounting College of Business University of Arkansas Fayetteville, AR 72701 (501) 575-6803 email: [email protected] email: [email protected] **School of Accountancy College of Business and Industry Mississippi State University Mississippi State, MS 39762-5661 (601) 325-1634 email: [email protected] This paper has benefited from comments of Terry Shevlin, David

CAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND ... · Web viewCAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND IMPUTATION, CAPITAL GAINS TAX AND THE INVESTMENT TAX CREDIT by Ervin L. Black* Assistant

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: CAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND ... · Web viewCAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND IMPUTATION, CAPITAL GAINS TAX AND THE INVESTMENT TAX CREDIT by Ervin L. Black* Assistant

CAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND IMPUTATION, CAPITAL GAINS TAX AND THE INVESTMENT TAX CREDIT

by

Ervin L. Black*Assistant ProfessorJoseph Legoria**Assistant Professor

Keith F. Sellers*Associate Professor

*Department of AccountingCollege of Business

University of ArkansasFayetteville, AR 72701

(501) 575-6803email: [email protected]: [email protected]

**School of AccountancyCollege of Business and Industry

Mississippi State UniversityMississippi State, MS 39762-5661

(601) 325-1634email: [email protected]

This paper has benefited from comments of Terry Shevlin, David Burgstahler and other workshop participants at the University of Washington and participants at the Tenth Asian-Pacific Conference on International Accounting Issues.

Page 2: CAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND ... · Web viewCAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND IMPUTATION, CAPITAL GAINS TAX AND THE INVESTMENT TAX CREDIT by Ervin L. Black* Assistant

CAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND IMPUTATION, CAPITAL GAINS TAX AND THE INVESTMENT TAX CREDIT

Abstract

We examine the effects of specific tax reforms on corporate capital investment in New Zealand, Australia, and Canada. The empirical findings indicate that: (1) tax reform in each of the three countries stimulated corporate capital investment, (2) tax reform altered how dividend payout ratios impacted capital investment in Canada but not in the other two countries, and (3) tax reform altered how capital intensity influenced investment in New Zealand and Australia but not Canada. Additional analyses are performed by dividing the samples into portfolios based on historical dividend payout policies and capital intensity. The findings indicate that tax reform impacted corporate investment differently depending on a firm’s dividend payout and capital intensity. In summary, we demonstrate the impact of specific tax reforms in three countries on corporate investment. Our findings suggest that policy makers can make more informed decisions regarding tax policy as it affects capital investment by examining the impact of tax reforms in other countries.

1

Page 3: CAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND ... · Web viewCAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND IMPUTATION, CAPITAL GAINS TAX AND THE INVESTMENT TAX CREDIT by Ervin L. Black* Assistant

CAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND IMPUTATION, CAPITAL GAINS TAX AND THE INVESTMENT TAX CREDIT

INTRODUCTION

Economic theory has long held that the level of business investment in fixed assets is a

critical determinant of business output and empirical research has clearly demonstrated this

relation.1 Based on this association, the stimulation of capital investment has been one of the

principal objectives of tax policy in the U.S. for decades. Historically, Congress has attempted

to stimulate capital investment through direct incentives such as the investment tax credit (ITC)

or generous accelerated depreciation allowances. Surprisingly, research has shown that these

incentives produce relatively small or no incremental increase in capital investment.

Macroeconomic theory asserts that tax policy should encourage investment in capital

assets if the tax system lowers the marginal cost of investment. This theory has been the

foundation of most investment incentives such as the ITC. For example, by directly lowering

the cost of a fixed asset, the ITC should result in more investment in fixed assets. One

weakness with such a targeted incentive is that all qualifying investment generates a credit, not

just incremental investments. Furthermore, it is clear that at least some targeted tax incentives

have led to sub-optimal investment decisions. An alternative method of lowering the cost of

capital and thus stimulating investment for businesses is to simply lower the overall tax burden

on business profits.

The purpose of this study is to determine the effects of specific income tax reforms on

corporate fixed investment. Specifically, we examine the incremental effects of dividend

imputation, capital gains taxes, and investment tax credits on investment. Evidence that these

specific tax reforms result in increased or decreased investment is relevant for future tax policy

1 See Shapiro (1986) for an excellent summary of this research.2

Page 4: CAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND ... · Web viewCAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND IMPUTATION, CAPITAL GAINS TAX AND THE INVESTMENT TAX CREDIT by Ervin L. Black* Assistant

debates in the U.S. and elsewhere. Ongoing debates over the merits of alternative tax reforms,

such as capital gains tax preferences and dividend imputation, indicate that this is a timely and

relevant research topic.

In order to determine the relative and incremental effects of various tax rates and

incentives, tax policy changes in three countries are examined. In 1987, New Zealand adopted

dividend imputation and significantly lowered corporate tax rates. Dividend imputation has the

effect of eliminating the double tax on corporate profits. The second country examined in the

study is Australia. In 1987, Australia adopted a tax reform plan similar to New Zealand’s.

However, Australia also instituted for the first time a capital gains tax on sales of corporate

stocks. This has the effect of lowering the combined tax on corporate profits which were

distributed, but raising the combined rates on undistributed profit.

The third country to be examined is Canada. In 1972, Canada adopted a tax reform

package similar to the one described above for Australia. Specifically, Canada addressed the

double tax on dividends through a dividend-imputation plan while instituting a first time tax on

capital gains. However, Canada also simultaneously adopted an ITC. It is important to note that

all three countries were attempting to stimulate investment through their respective tax

reforms.2 While all three countries adopted similar forms of dividend imputation in an attempt

to eliminate the double taxation of distributed corporate profits they differed in their

2 The various dividend imputation plans adopted by New Zealand, Australia and Canada do not necessarily eliminate all income taxes on dividends, but are designed to eliminate or sharply reduce double taxation and resulting biases against corporate distributions and investment.

3

Page 5: CAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND ... · Web viewCAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND IMPUTATION, CAPITAL GAINS TAX AND THE INVESTMENT TAX CREDIT by Ervin L. Black* Assistant

approaches on taxing capital gains and for providing direct investment incentives.

This combination of similar and different tax changes among the three countries offers

an ideal setting for our study. By treating the tax changes of these countries as experiments in

tax and investment policy, we can compare the relative and incremental effects of capital gain

taxes and investment tax credits in conjunction with the adoption of dividend imputation.

Economic conditions differed over time and among countries and general economic conditions

certainly impact investment in fixed assets. However, we control for various non-tax variables

that affect corporate investment in property, plant and equipment.

Our empirical findings indicate that: (1) tax reform in each of the three countries

stimulated corporate investment, (2) tax reform altered how dividend payout ratios impacted

investment in Canada but not in the other two countries, and (3) tax reform altered how capital

intensity influenced investment in New Zealand and Australia but not Canada. In summary, we

find evidence that specific tax reforms introduced in each of the three countries impacted

corporate investment. Thus, our findings suggest that policy makers can make more informed

decisions regarding tax policy as it affects capital investment by examining the impact of tax

reforms in other countries.

In the following sections we examine prior research, develop hypotheses, discuss

research design, provide results, and present conclusions and implications from our findings.

PRIOR RESEARCH ON TAXES AND INVESTMENT

Prior research on investment and taxes has generally relied on either the "user cost of

capital" approach developed by Jorgensen (1963) and Hall and Jorgensen (1967) or Tobin's

(1969) q-theory. However, researchers have had only limited success in linking tax changes to

4

Page 6: CAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND ... · Web viewCAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND IMPUTATION, CAPITAL GAINS TAX AND THE INVESTMENT TAX CREDIT by Ervin L. Black* Assistant

changes in investment using these models.3 In fact, simple time series models or ad hoc models

using variables such as output, cash flow, profits, and sales tend to predict total investment

better than tax changes or their anticipated effects to cost of capital.4

Recently, studies utilizing firm specific panel data and/or specific tax reforms have

been more successful in demonstrating a shift in corporate investment in response to tax

changes. For example, Rosacher et al. (1993) examined how effective the ITC was over the

period from its original enactment in 1962 to its repeal in 1986. The authors divide their

sample into a test group consisting of firms qualifying for the ITC and a control group

consisting of firms that do not qualify for the ITC. Using a univariate Box-Jenkins interrupted

analysis, they find that ITC enactments and rate enhancements have a positive effect on

investment whereas repeals have a negative effect on investment. Ayres (1987) employed

financial capital markets research methodology in testing the effects of the ITC on security

returns. She finds a significant association between abnormal security prices and the amount of

ITC received (lost) do to changes in the ITC. Her results indicate that changes in the ITC result

in a reallocation of capital among firms.

Moore et al. (1987) test whether tax advantages offered by various states in the U.S. are

important in the decision of foreign corporations to invest in one state rather than another.

Their findings indicate that tax structures relying on the unitary method of accounting

3 For reviews of these models and empirical studies linking taxes to investment see Auerbach (1983) and Chirinko, (1986; 1993). Chirinko (1993) concludes that the evidence of such a link is weak at best.4 See, for example, Clark (1979; 1993), Bernanke et al. (1988), and Oliner et al. (1995).

5

Page 7: CAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND ... · Web viewCAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND IMPUTATION, CAPITAL GAINS TAX AND THE INVESTMENT TAX CREDIT by Ervin L. Black* Assistant

significantly impact the amounts of investment while corporate tax rates do not.5 However, in a

subsequent article Swenson (1989) used an experimental economics approach to test whether

taxation impacted investment. He found that progressive tax regimes tend to decrease demand

for fixed assets while tax credits resulted in increased demand for those assets. In addition,

Vines et al. (1994) found that states with strong business interests (e.g. large number of firms

and high average business income per firm) tend to have lower state corporate tax rates.

Cassou (1997) studied the impact of tax policy on the flow of foreign investment between the

U.S and other countries. His findings indicate there is a significant negative relation between

U.S corporate tax rates and the level of foreign direct investment. These findings are

consistent with Moore et al. (1987) and provide further evidence that tax policy is an important

consideration for foreign firms when deciding where to invest.

Kern (1994) tested the impact of the Economic Recovery Act of 1981 (ERTA) on

corporate investment. Under the ERTA, long-lived assets received greater benefits than

short-lived assets. Kern divided her sample into three portfolios based on the after-tax benefits

received from ERTA. The findings of her study indicate that firms receiving the greatest tax

benefits exhibited the largest change in investment patterns and suggest that tax policy can

have an effect on investment. However, Courtenay et al. (1989) found evidence that the ERTA

disturbed the degree of neutrality in the tax law existing between capital intensive and

non-capital intensive firms. More specifically, they found that only capital intensive firms

5 Moore et al. (1987, p. 673) define a unitary tax system as one that requires filing a consolidated corporate income tax return that includes affiliates considered to be part of the unitary business. They indicate that most foreign firms are treated as either a worldwide or domestic combination. Under a worldwide combination all of the foreign firm’s affiliates, both domestic and foreign, are included in the tax base. The domestic combination requires just the affiliates in the United States to be included in the tax base.

6

Page 8: CAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND ... · Web viewCAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND IMPUTATION, CAPITAL GAINS TAX AND THE INVESTMENT TAX CREDIT by Ervin L. Black* Assistant

demonstrated significantly positive abnormal returns during their test period surrounding the

passage of ERTA. They concluded that all ERTA may have accomplished was a reallocation of

resources from non-capital intensive firms to capital intensive firms. In addition, Swenson

(1987) determined that the Accelerated Cost Recovery System (ACRS) passed under ERTA

was non-neutral during periods of high inflation.6

In 1984, the United Kingdom passed tax reform legislation which reduced corporate tax

rates and lengthened the asset lives for many depreciable assets. Moon and Hodges (1989)

examined how the 1984 U.K. tax reform affected the after-tax cost of capital facing firms.

Their analysis indicates that the 1984 U.K. tax reform resulted in many investments in plant

and equipment becoming less attractive than they were before. Morgan (1992) surveyed the

largest U.K. firms to determine how sensitive these firms were to the 1984 U.K. tax reform. He

found that most of the firms sensitive to the 1984 tax changes (e.g. firms with high marginal

tax rates) would have scaled back their investment rather than have increased it.

In an examination of the Tax Reform Act (TRA) of 1986, Cummins and Hassett (1992)

find a significant relation between the cost of capital and the level of investment in equipment

and structures. Auerbach et al. (1991) find that the TRA of 1986 resulted in less investment

than what was predicted based on investment behavior from 1953 to 1985. Cummins et al.

(1994) found that after every tax reform enacted in the United States since 1962, the level of

investment changed. In a subsequent article, Cummins et al. (1996) examine various tax

6 The 1980s were a period of low inflation for the United States. To analyze the impact of inflation on ACRS, Swenson (1987) conducted a Monte Carlo simulation.

7

Page 9: CAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND ... · Web viewCAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND IMPUTATION, CAPITAL GAINS TAX AND THE INVESTMENT TAX CREDIT by Ervin L. Black* Assistant

reforms in 14 countries and find evidence that taxes, in general, can be linked to changes in

investment.

Finally, Kinney and Trezevant (1993) analyzed whether taxes impact the timing of

capital expenditures. More specifically, they argue that the present value of investment-related

tax shields is greater if a depreciable asset is purchased and placed in service in the current year

compared to the subsequent year. As a result, they predict greater capital expenditures are

made in the fourth quarter of the current year, as opposed to the first of quarter of the

following year. They find support for this prediction as their results indicate firms make greater

capital expenditures in the fourth quarter of current year rather than first quarter of the next

year.

In summary, prior research has determined that the long suspected link between taxes

and investment does exist. Unfortunately, no previous research has successfully demonstrated

the investment effects of specific tax reforms such as reduction of corporate tax rates or

elimination of the double tax on dividends. Thus, while tax policy-makers know that their

decisions might impact the level of investment, they do not have information as to which

specific tax changes result in changes in actual investment behavior.

The objective of our research study is to increase understanding of the impact of

specific tax changes; i.e., changes in the structure of the tax system on distributed and

non-distributed corporate earnings and their effect on corporate investment behavior. By

examining the investment effects in countries that have implemented specific tax reforms, we

derive implications of the potential effects of similar changes in the U.S. and other countries.7

7 We provide an appendix that outlines the details of the tax reform acts in each of the three countries. See Appendix.

8

Page 10: CAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND ... · Web viewCAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND IMPUTATION, CAPITAL GAINS TAX AND THE INVESTMENT TAX CREDIT by Ervin L. Black* Assistant

HYPOTHESIS DEVELOPMENT

Taxes, the Cost of Capital, and Capital Investment

The purpose of this section is to demonstrate the various linkages between components

of a capital investment model and the various tax changes examined in this study. Firms should

accept additional investment opportunities if the net present value of the marginal investment is

positive. Assuming the firm has sufficient capital resources, it would invest if:

(1)

where: CFt = the net cash flows during period t, and

k = the investor’s required rate of return

Therefore, taxes and tax changes impact the investment decision to the extent that they

impact the timing of projected net cash flows (t), the amount of projected net cash flows (CF),

discount rates (k), or a combination of these factors. Corporate level taxes clearly affect the

timing and amount of cash flows. Shareholder level taxes affect corporate investment decisions

less directly, through their impact on the corporate cost of capital. In the absence of

shareholder level taxes, the corporate cost of equity is equal to the expected rate of return to

shareholders in the form of dividends and appreciation. When shareholder level taxes are

imposed, the corporate cost of equity capital and total shareholder return differ by the amount

of total shareholder level taxes. Assuming that a corporation’s risk adjusted required rate of

return on marginal investments is equal to the corporate cost of capital, the relationship

between individual shareholder taxes and the cost of capital under a classical double tax system

9

Page 11: CAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND ... · Web viewCAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND IMPUTATION, CAPITAL GAINS TAX AND THE INVESTMENT TAX CREDIT by Ervin L. Black* Assistant

can be represented as:

(2)

where:

Ce = corporate cost of equity,

Ts = total shareholder level taxes,

Rs = total expected after-tax return to shareholders,

Rd = expected shareholder return in the form of dividends,

Td = marginal tax rates on dividend income, and

Rcg = expected shareholder return in the form of share appreciation (capital gain)

The corporation’s cost of equity capital differs from the shareholders’ after-tax return

by the amount of the shareholder-level tax, in this case equal to Rd*Td.8 Prior to the tax

reforms examined in this study, neither Australia, Canada nor New Zealand imposed a tax on

realized capital gains. Thus, Rcg is equal to a shareholder’s pre and post-tax return in the form

of share appreciation. It should be noted that, in most instances where statutory rates for Td are

non-zero, its marginal value is non-observable. Various tax clienteles will naturally concentrate

their investments in appropriate stocks based on their tax position and the expected amount and

form of the return. This clientele effect, combined with variations in the timing of dividend

distributions, make the present value of the tax impossible to estimate.

8 For purposes of brevity, equation (2) reflects the cost of capital for an unlevered corporation. Aside from the change in corporate tax rates, the major tax legislation examined in this study was generally designed to directly impact equity rather than debt financing by adding or removing biases against equity financing. Indirect effects to the cost of debt financing, arising from a change in equilibrium debt to equity ratios for firms, may have occurred.

10

Page 12: CAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND ... · Web viewCAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND IMPUTATION, CAPITAL GAINS TAX AND THE INVESTMENT TAX CREDIT by Ervin L. Black* Assistant

New Zealand

Dividend imputation modifies the tax on dividends by attaching a credit, equal to the

taxes already paid by the corporation on behalf of the dividend, to dividend distributions. As

outlined in the appendix, if individual tax rates exceed corporate tax rates, the imputation credit

will only partially offset the individual level taxes. While some view this as only partially

reducing the classic double tax, the resulting cumulative tax burden on distributed corporate

earnings is equal to only the higher individual tax rate. In the case where the corporate tax rate

exceeds the tax rate of the recipient shareholder and the imputation credit can be fully utilized,

the resulting cumulative tax burden is once again equal to the individual shareholder’s marginal

tax rate. However, the after-tax dividend return, as viewed by the shareholder, is actually

higher than the pre-tax return. These conclusions are evident in the following when we add the

tax benefit of the imputation credit:

Rs = Rd – (Rdg * Td) + (Rdg * Tc) + Rcg (3)

where:

Rdg = the dividend return paid to shareholders, “grossed-up” by the amount of corporate level tax paid on account of the dividend, and

Tc = the corporate tax rate paid on the grossed-up distributed earnings.

Equation (3) captures the cost of capital in New Zealand after the tax reform and

accurately reflects the effects of the imputation credit when the shareholder has a positive tax

rate and sufficient income. If the recipient has insufficient income, some or all of the

imputation credit will be lost. Subtracting equation (2), which measures the after-tax return to

shareholders prior to dividend imputation from equation (3), the after-tax return after the tax

reform, reveals that shareholders’ after-tax return in New Zealand changed by an amount equal

11

Page 13: CAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND ... · Web viewCAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND IMPUTATION, CAPITAL GAINS TAX AND THE INVESTMENT TAX CREDIT by Ervin L. Black* Assistant

to (Rdg * Tc) - (Rdg * Tc * Td). When shareholder tax rates (Td) fall between zero and 100

percent, this will result in a positive change in shareholder’s after-tax returns. Thus, the tax

reform in New Zealand clearly enhanced shareholder after-tax returns for non-tax exempt

shareholders.

Tax clientele theory, however, suggests that the higher rate of after-tax return arising

from lower explicit taxes will be offset by higher implicit taxes. Investors will bid the price of

dividend-paying stocks up until the after-tax return returns to its equilibrium state. This market

adjustment results in an unambiguous reduction in the corporate cost of additional equity

financing, and a corresponding reduction in required rates of return on corporate capital

investments.9 This leads to our first hypothesis:

H1: The introduction of a dividend imputation tax system in New Zealand significantly

increased corporate capital investment.

Australia

In Australia, where the tax reform also included the imposition of a new tax on capital

gains, the effect on shareholder returns of the new tax is shown by modifying equation (3) as

follows:

Rs = Rd – (Rdg*Td) + (Rdg*Tc) + Rcg*(1-Tcg) (4)

where: Tcg = the tax rate on capital gains.

9 Empirical evidence of this anticipated market adjustment is reported by Amoako-Adu (1983). He reports that high-dividend paying stocks increased significantly in value as a result of the Canadian tax reform.

12

Page 14: CAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND ... · Web viewCAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND IMPUTATION, CAPITAL GAINS TAX AND THE INVESTMENT TAX CREDIT by Ervin L. Black* Assistant

As with Td, the value for the capital gain tax rate (Tcg) is unobservable. Like the U.S.,

both Canada and Australia defer the tax on share appreciation until gains are realized by the

shareholder. The period of this deferral is determined by the shareholder, and can even extend

beyond the life of an individual shareholder. Once again, by subtracting equation (2) from

equation (4), one can determine that the after-tax return for shareholders in Australia increased

by an amount equal to (Rdg*Tc - Rdg*Td*Tc) - (Rcg*Tcg). Conclusions as to the net effect of

this tax reform on shareholder’s after-tax returns, and thus the cost of corporate equity capital,

are ambiguous. The change arising from dividend imputation (Rdg * Tc – Rdg * Td * Tc)

increased shareholder returns while the new capital gains tax reduced shareholder returns by an

amount equal to Rcg * Tcg. As we cannot observe values for the marginal shareholder-level tax

rates Td and Tcg, our hypothesis for Australia is non-directional. To determine the net impact

of dividend imputation and the imposition of the capital gains tax on shareholder after-tax

returns, and thus corporate cost of equity capital and corporate capital investment, we

empirically test the following:

H2: The introduction of a dividend imputation tax system and a capital gains tax

significantly impacted corporate capital investment in Australia.

Because of the counteracting effects of dividend imputation and capital gains tax we

cannot predict the directional impact on capital investment. Therefore, we formally test the

following hypotheses.

H2(a): if the positive effects of dividend imputation on shareholder returns exceeded the

negative effects of capital gains taxes on shareholder returns, corporate capital

investment in Australia increased after tax reform.

H2(b): if the negative effects of capital gains taxes on shareholder returns exceeded the

13

Page 15: CAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND ... · Web viewCAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND IMPUTATION, CAPITAL GAINS TAX AND THE INVESTMENT TAX CREDIT by Ervin L. Black* Assistant

positive effects of dividend imputation on shareholder returns, corporate capital

investment in Australia decreased after tax reform.

H2(c): if the negative effects of capital gains taxes on shareholder returns equally offset the

positive effects of dividend imputation on shareholder returns, corporate capital

investment in Australia was unaffected after tax reform.

Canada

The Canadian tax reform examined in this study was similar to that of Australia’s in

that it implemented both dividend imputation and a new capital gains tax. For this study, a

critical difference between the Canadian tax reform and that of Australia is that the Canadian

tax act also provided a new investment tax credit. Unlike changes in shareholder level taxes,

investment tax credits directly influence corporate capital investment by enhancing net cash

flows from investments (CF in equation 1), rather than the cost of capital. Thus, as with

Australia, the Canadian tax reform introduced provisions with both positive and negative

implications for corporate capital investment. We examine the net effects of these various

provisions on capital investment by testing the following hypothesis:

H3: The introduction of a dividend imputation tax system, a capital gains tax and an

investment credit significantly impacted corporate capital investment in Canada.

As in Australia, because of the counteracting effects of dividend imputation, the capital

gains tax, and an investment tax credit, we cannot predict the direction of the impact on

investment in Canada. Thus, we formally test the following hypotheses.

14

Page 16: CAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND ... · Web viewCAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND IMPUTATION, CAPITAL GAINS TAX AND THE INVESTMENT TAX CREDIT by Ervin L. Black* Assistant

H3(a): if the positive effects of dividend imputation and the investment tax credit exceeded

the negative effects of capital gains taxes, corporate capital investment in Canada

increased after tax reform.

H3(b): if the negative effects of capital gains taxes exceeded the positive effects of dividend

imputation and the investment credit, corporate capital investment in Canada

decreased after tax reform.

H3(c): if the negative effects of capital gains taxes equally offset the positive effects of

dividend imputation and the investment credit, corporate capital investment in Canada

is unaffected by tax reform.

Because we predict offsetting effects of the tax changes, examination of an aggregate

sample of Australian and Canadian corporations can only reveal the net impact, if any, of the

tax reforms of those countries. By segregating corporations by the form of return provided to

shareholders, it may be possible to draw inferences as to the effects of the specific tax changes,

individually and interactively. For example, assume Australian shareholders invested in a

corporation with the expectation of receiving returns solely in the form of dividends. In this

case, the change in shareholder returns, and thus the corporation’s cost of equity capital, would

only be impacted by dividend imputation. Expected after-tax returns in the form of share

appreciation remained zero and played no part in the market’s valuation of those shares. For a

portfolio of such firms, the effects of the capital gains tax are assumed to be zero and any

observed change in corporate investment could be attributable to dividend imputation.

Similarly, for Australian firms with expected returns solely in the form of share appreciation,

only the imposition of the new capital gains tax should impact the cost of equity.

15

Page 17: CAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND ... · Web viewCAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND IMPUTATION, CAPITAL GAINS TAX AND THE INVESTMENT TAX CREDIT by Ervin L. Black* Assistant

In an effort to disaggregate the effects of dividend imputation from capital gains taxes

and investment tax credits, we divide the sample from each country into four portfolios based

on dividend payout policies and capital intensity.10 As shown in Table 1, the four portfolios, I,

II, III, and IV, include low dividend payout/low capital intensity, high dividend payout/low

capital intensity, low dividend payout/high capital intensity, and high dividend payout/high

capital intensity firms, respectively. These portfolios are partitioned based on the median

values of dividend payout and capital intensity ratios. Table 1 describes expectations of how

tax reform impacts each of the four portfolios in each of the three countries.

RESEARCH DESIGN

Variable Selection and Measurement

Dependent Variable

Investment (INV): An ideal measure of capital investment would be the amount of cash

spent on capital expenditures obtained from the cash flow or funds statement. While Canada

requires firms to disclose this information, this measure is not available to us for firms from

New Zealand and Australia. Thus, to measure investment consistently across the three

countries, we follow Kinney and Trezevant (1993) and measure capital investment as the

change in gross property, plant, and equipment (GPPE). In addition, we add a firm’s annual

R&D expenditures to its change in GPPE for each year. Most countries require firms to

10 While Canada enacted all three of these changes, Australia two, and New Zealand only one, all three samples are partitioned the same to provide comparability.

16

Page 18: CAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND ... · Web viewCAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND IMPUTATION, CAPITAL GAINS TAX AND THE INVESTMENT TAX CREDIT by Ervin L. Black* Assistant

expense R&D in the current period because it is difficult to determine the future revenues that

will result from current R&D costs. However, Lev and Sougiannis (1996) find that the market

capitalizes R&D costs and this capitalization provides useful information about future earnings.

Therefore, we feel that a measure of investment that captures both a firm’s investment in fixed

assets and R&D more accurately reflects a company’s investment decisions.

We scale investment by total sales consistent with Kern (1994) to obtain a measure of

investment to control for inflation and growth. Therefore, our measure of investment is the

change in GPPE plus R&D divided by sales.11

Independent Variables

Independent variables for this study can be categorized as either tax variables or firm

specific variables. The tax variables represent the variables of interest for this study, and are

designed to capture the effects of the various tax changes. Firm specific variables are used to

control for other determinants of corporate capital investment behavior, primarily the firm’s

investment opportunities.

Tax Variables

A common problem in the analysis of tax law changes is that legislatures tend to make

many, often significant, tax changes simultaneously. Disentangling the effects of the various

changes presents a challenge

Tax Act (TREF): The variable of primary interest in this study indicates the effect of

tax reform in the various countries. Thus, TREF is set to zero in years preceding the effective

date of tax reform and one in years in which dividend imputation is in effect. In New Zealand,

this variable measures only the impact of dividend imputation. In Australia, this variable also

11 Prior research (Kinney and Trezevant 1993; Kern 1994) finds that various deflators have no impact on the results.

17

Page 19: CAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND ... · Web viewCAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND IMPUTATION, CAPITAL GAINS TAX AND THE INVESTMENT TAX CREDIT by Ervin L. Black* Assistant

measures any impact of implementing capital gains taxes. Finally, in the Canadian sample this

variable will capture the effects of dividend imputation, the imposition of a capital gains tax,

and the implementation of an investment tax credit.

Statutory Tax Rate (RATE): During the years surrounding the adoption of reform, each

country significantly reduced corporate and individual income tax rates. Because both tax rates

theoretically impact corporations’ investment decisions, ideally, both individual and corporate

rates would be included in the model to account for these effects. However, individual and

corporate income tax rates exhibit a high empirical correlation over the sample period of this

study, and the presence of both variables would introduce multicollinearity into the model.

Thus, for this study RATE is defined as the maximum of either the federal corporate tax rate or

the individual tax rate, expressed as a percentage. Since RATE proxies for both individual and

corporate tax rates, the sign of its effect on capital investment is ambiguous.12

Firm Specific Variables

Net Operating Loss (DNOL): As a firm’s taxable income decreases, the possibility of

incurring a tax net operating loss (NOL) increases, resulting in a lower projected marginal tax

rate. Firms with relatively low taxable income may thus respond differently to tax reforms

such as dividend imputation and lower tax rates. For example, imputation credits may be

12 Corporate and individual tax rates could impact the investment equation in a number of ways. Corporate taxes clearly decrease the net after-tax cash flows from an investment. However, most capital investments provide attractive tax shields which increase net cash flows. Individual rates, as illustrated in the development of our hypotheses, affect corporate cost of capital.

18

Page 20: CAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND ... · Web viewCAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND IMPUTATION, CAPITAL GAINS TAX AND THE INVESTMENT TAX CREDIT by Ervin L. Black* Assistant

unavailable if a company is not paying sufficient corporate level taxes, greatly diminishing any

impact of dividend imputation. Similarly, the incentives provided by traditional tax shields or

lower statutory rates decrease as a firm’s marginal tax rate decreases. In order to capture the

effects of low marginal tax rates, we use a dummy variable set equal to one if the firm is likely

to have a net operating loss, zero otherwise. A firm is deemed likely to have a net operating

loss if it has had one in the immediate past. We determine this by examining each of the last

five years. DNOL is equal to one if the firm had a net operating loss in any one of the five

years, zero otherwise.13

Book-to-Market Equity Ratio (BKMKT): Perhaps the most widely used estimate of a

firm’s investment opportunity set is the ratio of the market value of equity to the book value of

equity (and its inverse). Collins and Kothari (1989) assert that the market-to-book ratio

captures the difference between a firm’s return on both existing and future assets and its

required rate of return on equity. Thus, a lower ratio indicates greater investment opportunities

which are expected to yield returns in excess of the required rate of return.14 Since this is a

control variable, we also try other theoretically sound proxies of a firm’s investment

opportunities including the earnings to price ratio and measures of variability (as used by

Christie (1989) and Smith and Watts (1992).15

Debt to Equity Ratio (D/E): In an efficient market, is reasonable to assume that capital

is provided to firms with better investment opportunities. However, as discussed above, each of

13 Realizing that this is at best a proxy measure for low marginal tax rates, we also tested alternative classification schemes. Firms were alternatively classified as NOL firms if they had an NOL during the most recent year, a cumulative NOL during the past three years, or an NOL in the succeeding year. None of these alternative classification schemes changed the significance of the variables of interest.14 Lewellen, Loderer and Martin (1987) and Chung and Charoenwong (1991) also use this measure to control for growth opportunities.15 We do not use research intensity since R&D is incorporated in our measure of investment, the dependent variable.

19

Page 21: CAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND ... · Web viewCAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND IMPUTATION, CAPITAL GAINS TAX AND THE INVESTMENT TAX CREDIT by Ervin L. Black* Assistant

our direct proxy measures of investment opportunity are sensitive to the capital structure of the

firm.

Cash Flow Ratio (CF): In addition to externally generated capital a firm generates

capital internally. The cash flow ratio, measured as operating cash flow divided by net sales, is

a measure of the firm’s ability to internally finance its capital expenditures/investments. A firm

with limited ability to internally fund investment opportunities is less likely to be able to

increase investment. Conversely, a firm with a large cash flow ratio would be able to increase

investment more easily.

Dividend Payout Ratio (DP): Shareholders receive returns on corporate investments in

the form of share appreciation and dividends. When these two forms of return are taxed

differentially, as they are in each of the tax systems examined in our study, shareholders are

attracted to appropriate clienteles as a means of maximizing their total after-tax return.

Dividend imputation is designed to eliminate the effects of the traditional double-tax on

corporate earnings. However, many firms never pay cash dividends and are thus not directly

affected by the double-tax system. It is anticipated that these firms will experience little or no

impact from dividend imputation while traditionally high-dividend paying firms will be more

strongly impacted. On the other hand, low dividend paying firms are more strongly impacted

by capital gains taxes. Thus, we expect some interaction between a firm’s dividend payout and

its response to a package of tax reform initiatives which include dividend imputation and a

capital gains tax. We test for the difference in the coefficient of this variable before and after

the tax reform acts.

Capital Intensity (CINT): The decision to invest in fixed assets (Property, Plant, and

Equipment) is dependent not only on the tax system, but also on the firm’s industry or type of

20

Page 22: CAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND ... · Web viewCAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND IMPUTATION, CAPITAL GAINS TAX AND THE INVESTMENT TAX CREDIT by Ervin L. Black* Assistant

business. Firms in service industries that are not capital intensive would not be expected to

significantly adjust their investment based on tax effects. Therefore, it is expected that capital

investment by firms with high capital intensity are more affected by tax reforms than are firms

with relatively lower capital intensity. Capital intensity is measured as the ratio of fixed assets

to total assets. We test for the difference in the coefficient of this variable before and after the

tax reform acts.

Size: Size of the firm also affects its ability to finance additional investment and is used

as a control variable. Size is measured as the natural log of total assets.

Lagged Investment (LINV): Over time, the level of investment should tend to correlate

with certain industry characteristics. Also, firms in various life stages may be experiencing

relatively higher or lower levels of capital investment. In both cases, capital investment for a

firm in any year should be correlated with investment in the succeeding year. Thus, we

included a measure of capital investment for the prior year, scaled by total sales to be

consistent with our dependent variable. Because it is possible that capital investment might

display a cyclical nature, with large investments followed by periods of lower investment, we

do not predict a sign for this coefficient.

Data Selection

We examine pooled cross-section firm-year data from three countries that experienced

major tax reform believed to affect corporate capital investment: New Zealand, Australia, and

Canada. In 1987, New Zealand adopted dividend imputation and significantly lowered

corporate tax rates. Also in 1987, Australia adopted a dividend imputation plan similar to that

of New Zealand. However, Australia also instituted for the first time a capital gains tax on sales

21

Page 23: CAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND ... · Web viewCAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND IMPUTATION, CAPITAL GAINS TAX AND THE INVESTMENT TAX CREDIT by Ervin L. Black* Assistant

of corporate stocks.16 The third country to be examined is Canada. In 1972, Canada adopted a

tax reform package similar to the one described above for Australia. However, Canada also

simultaneously adopted an ITC. The tax reform acts in each of these countries is summarized

in the Appendix.

Financial statement information for New Zealand and Australia is obtained from the

Compustat Global Vantage database for 1982 through 1991. The Canadian data is obtained

from Canadian Compustat for 1968-1977. Firm-year observations are deleted if the necessary

data to calculate regression variables are not available. These data allow us to observe several

years before and after tax reform in each country. After deleting observations due to lack of

data, the New Zealand sample consists of 158 firm-year observations, Australia has 1,010 firm-

year observations, and the Canadian sample has 1,776 observations.

Descriptive Statistics

Maximum corporate and individual tax rates in effect during the periods examined in

the study are shown in Table 2. Although there were annual variations, rates for both

individuals and corporations were generally lower in years after the tax reform in all three

countries. During the years preceding tax reform in New Zealand and Australia tax rates were

constant for both these countries. During 1987-88 rates initially went up at the corporate level

16 The capital gains tax went into effect in 1986. As a sensitivity test we also examine Australian data by removing this transition year, 1986. This did not qualitatively affect the results.

22

Page 24: CAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND ... · Web viewCAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND IMPUTATION, CAPITAL GAINS TAX AND THE INVESTMENT TAX CREDIT by Ervin L. Black* Assistant

and down for individuals. Australian and New Zealand corporate and individual rates

decreased in 1989, but went down relatively farther in New Zealand. Corporate rates in New

Zealand went from 48 percent to 28 percent in 1989 (33 percent for 1990-92), while individual

rates settled to 33 percent by 1990, as well. Corporate rates went from 49 percent to 39 percent

in Australia in 1989, while individual tax rates did not go down until 1990 to 48 percent, and

then to 47 percent for 1991-92. In Canada, corporate rates increased in 1972 and 1973, then

dropped below pre-reform levels in 1974. Canadian individual rates dropped during the years

surrounding adoption of the tax reform, then rebounded partially in 1977.

Descriptive statistics, means and medians, are given in Table 3 for the dependent and

independent variables used in the regression model. The dependent investment measure is

similar in all three countries. The DNOL variable is similar in New Zealand and Australia,

slightly above 0.5 indicating that the majority of firms had an operating loss in the past five

years. This variable is less than 0.5 in Canada. The cash flow ratio is much higher in Australia

(0.48) than in either New Zealand (0.11) or Canada (0.22), although this appears to be skewed

as the medians are similar across countries. Book-to-market and debt-to-equity ratios are higher

in New Zealand than in Australia or Canada. The capital intensity and size variables are similar

across countries, although Canada has slightly smaller firms on average. In Australia, 53

percent of the observations are after the tax reform act in 1988; in New Zealand, 58 percent of

the observations are after tax reform; and in Canada 60 percent of the observations are after tax

reform.

Table 4 provides Pearson correlation coefficients of the dependent and independent

variables. Of particular note is the high negative correlation between the tax reform dummy

variable and the statutory tax rate variable in each of the countries. This high collinearity

23

Page 25: CAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND ... · Web viewCAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND IMPUTATION, CAPITAL GAINS TAX AND THE INVESTMENT TAX CREDIT by Ervin L. Black* Assistant

makes it harder to find results on our specific variable of interest, TREF, which measures the

effect of the tax reform acts in our study countries. However, if we did not include the tax rate

variable we could not distinguish between the effects of the tax reforms and the effects of the

statutory tax rate changes. Other variables with significant partial correlations include capital

intensity (CINT) with size and lagged investment. To the extent there is multicollinearity it

should not bias the coefficients, but makes it less likely to reject the null hypothesis of no

significant relation with a firm’s investment.

Research Methodology

Regression analysis is used to test the effects of each country’s tax reform package on

investment. The major tax change that is consistent across all three countries, implementation

of a dividend imputation plan, was implemented in 1972 in Canada, 1988 in Australia and

during the second half of 1987 in New Zealand. These countries are fairly homogeneous in

their culture, tax and accounting systems.

The basic research model is the following:

(5)where,

INVit = measure of investment for firm i, at time t.

TREFt = dummy measure of whether the tax reform has become effective.

RATEt = the maximum of either the statutory corporate tax rate or the individual tax rate at time t.

24

Page 26: CAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND ... · Web viewCAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND IMPUTATION, CAPITAL GAINS TAX AND THE INVESTMENT TAX CREDIT by Ervin L. Black* Assistant

DNOLit = measure of the likelihood of a net operating loss for firm i, at time t. If the firm has had a net operating loss in the last five years DNOL = 1, 0 otherwise.

BKMKTit = book-to-market ratio for firm i, at time t.

DEit = debt-to-equity ratio for firm i, at time t.

CFit = cash flow ratio for firm i, at time t.

PREDPit = interactive TREF dummy measure with the dividend payout ratio (DP) for firm i, at time t: (1-TREF)*DP. This measure yields the pre-tax reform coefficient.

PRECINTit = interactive TREF dummy measure with the capital intensity ratio (CINT) for firm i, at time t: (1-TREF)*CINT. This measure yields the pre-tax reform coefficient.

POSTDPit = interactive TREF dummy measure with the dividend payout ratio (DP) for firm i, at time t: TREF*DP. This measure yields the post-tax reform coefficient.

POSTCINTit = interactive TREF dummy measure with the capital intensity ratio (CINT) for firm i, at time t: TREF)*CINT. This measure yields the post-tax reform coefficient.

SIZEit = a measure of the size of firm i, at time t.

LINVit = lagged measure of investment for firm i, at time t-1.

This regression equation is estimated for each of the three countries to analyze effects

of different tax changes. The coefficient on TREF is expected to be significant if tax reform

affects investment, but may vary across country.

25

Page 27: CAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND ... · Web viewCAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND IMPUTATION, CAPITAL GAINS TAX AND THE INVESTMENT TAX CREDIT by Ervin L. Black* Assistant

RESULTS

Regression Results by Country

Regression results for each country are reported in Table 5. By testing and comparing

tax reforms in the three countries, we provide evidence on the incremental and combined

effects of various reforms on corporate fixed investment.

New Zealand

In New Zealand, where the tax reform consisted primarily of the adoption of dividend

imputation,17 the positive relation which we observe between the TREF variable and corporate

investment supports our hypothesis, indicating that dividend imputation stimulated corporate

fixed investment in New Zealand. The other major tax change in New Zealand was a lowering

of statutory tax rates. Tax rates, indicated by the variable RATE, were insignificant indicating

that tax rates did not impact corporate investment. The negative relation between DNOL and

corporate investment indicates that a firm’s earnings status impacts its level of capital

investment. This negative relation could be due to the lack of benefits provided by dividend

imputation to corporations with low marginal tax rates.

The variable PREDP, which measures the pre-imputation dividend payout ratio, was

significant in New Zealand indicating that dividend payout ratio impacted corporate

investment.

17 The tax reform also resulted in reduced individual and corporate tax rates, but we control for this with the net operating loss dummy variable and the statutory tax rate variables. To test the sensitivity of these variables to our definition, we also test the model using dummy variables based on the most current year taxable income (negative = 1, 0 otherwise) and the next two years taxable income (negative =1, 0 otherwise) as a measure of net operating loss. These alternate forms did not affect the results; signs and significance of the test variables remained the same. To test the sensitivity of the results to the measure of the statutory tax rate, we used both the maximum corporate and maximum individual rates, rather than the maximum of either rate, with no effect to our results. We also used an estimate of firm specific marginal tax rates (Kinney and Trezevant 1993), which did not impact the results on TREF. In addition, we added a gross national product (GDP) variable, however this did not affect the model. Tax rates vary by year and are also a proxy for the macroeconomic environment in any given year.

26

Page 28: CAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND ... · Web viewCAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND IMPUTATION, CAPITAL GAINS TAX AND THE INVESTMENT TAX CREDIT by Ervin L. Black* Assistant

After dividend imputation dividend payout ratio was no longer associated with corporate

investment as the coefficient on the variable POSTDP was not significant. Moreover, the F-

value testing this change (POSTDP-PREDP=0) is insignificant at 2.55. Thus, we cannot

conclude that dividend imputation significantly impacted this relation. PRECINT, which

measures the pre-imputation level of capital intensity, was significant at the 0.01 level

indicating that the level of capital intensity influenced corporate investment in New Zealand.

Conversely, after dividend-imputation, corporate investment is no longer influenced by the

level of capital intensity as the coefficient on POSTCINT is insignificant. The F-value of 7.50

obtained from testing whether the coefficient on POSTCINT is significantly different from the

coefficient on PRECINT (POSTCINT-PRECINT=0) is significant at the 0.01 level. Thus, the

tax reform significantly changed the relation between capital intensity and capital investment.

Australia

In Australia, the coefficient on TREF is again positive (0.67) and is significant at the

0.01 level, supporting our hypothesis that Australia’s tax reform, consisting of dividend

imputation and the adoption of a capital gains tax, stimulated corporate capital investment. The

variables DNOL and RATE are insignificant indicating no relation between NOL status and

corporate tax rates and capital investment by Australian corporations.

For Australia, dividend payout ratios were not associated with corporate investment

either before or after tax reform as the coefficients on both PREDP and POSTDP were

insignificant. On the other hand, capital intensity influenced corporate investment before as

well as after tax reform as the coefficients on PRECINT and POSTCINT were both positive and

significant at the 0.01 level. However, the coefficient on POSTCINT is smaller than the

coefficient on PRECINT. The F-value testing whether this difference is significantly different

27

Page 29: CAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND ... · Web viewCAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND IMPUTATION, CAPITAL GAINS TAX AND THE INVESTMENT TAX CREDIT by Ervin L. Black* Assistant

from zero (POSTCINT-PRECINT=0) is 23.38 and significant at the 0.01 level. Consistent with

our New Zealand results, this suggests that capital intensity does not influence corporate

investment as much after the tax reform as it did prior to the tax reform.

Canada

As in Australia, the Canadian tax reform package included dividend imputation and the

imposition of capital gains taxes, as well as an investment tax credit directly targeting capital

investment. As shown in table 5, the tax reform variable (TREF) is significant at the 0.10 level,

indicating that its passage had an impact on corporate capital investment in Canada. In

addition, the coefficient on RATE is positive (0.004) and significant at the 0.01 level indicating

that the higher the corporate tax rate the greater the level of corporate investment. The

coefficient on DNOL was not significant for the Canadian sample.

In Canada, dividend payout ratios impacted corporate investment both before and after

tax reform as the coefficients on PREDP and POSTDP were significant at the 0.01 level and

0.05 level, respectively. However, the tax reform significantly affected the magnitude of the

coefficients on dividend payout, indicating that the higher the dividend payout after tax reform

the lower is the firm’s capital investment. The F-value of the test in difference of the

coefficients on POSTDP and PREDP is 2.77 and is significant at the 0.10 level. The level of

capital intensity also influenced corporate investment both before tax reform and after tax

reform as the coefficients on PRECINT and POSTCINT were both significant at the 0.01 level.

The F-Value testing whether there is a significant difference between the coefficients on

POSTCINT and PRECINT is 0.84 and insignificant. Thus, we can conclude that the Canadian

tax reform did not impact how capital intensity influenced corporate investment.

28

Page 30: CAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND ... · Web viewCAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND IMPUTATION, CAPITAL GAINS TAX AND THE INVESTMENT TAX CREDIT by Ervin L. Black* Assistant

Control Variables

With regards to the control variables, the variable CFO, which measures cash flow

ratio, had a significant positive impact on investment in all three countries while lagged capital

investment (LINV) was significantly and positively related to current capital investment in

Canada and New Zealand. Finally, the coefficients on the variables BKMKT and DE were

insignificant for all three countries while the coefficient on SIZE was negative and significant

in Canada and insignificant in the other two countries.

Portfolio Regression Results

We divide each of the three country samples into four portfolios based on dividend

payout policies and capital intensity. Results in Table 6 provide evidence that New Zealand

firms differed in their response to the tax legislation based on their historical dividend payout

ratio and capital intensity. For Portfolio IV, high dividend payout and high capital intensity

firms, the tax act variable (TREF) is significant and positive at the 0.10 level while for the

other three portfolios TREF is not significant. This finding supports our hypothesis; the

coefficient on PREDIV is positive and significant indicating that before tax reform, dividend

policy influenced corporate investment in New Zealand whereas after tax reform, dividend

policy no longer impacted investment as the variable POSTDIV was insignificant. The F-value

to test whether the coefficients on POSTDIV and PREDIV are equal is 4.7 and is significant

which indicates that post tax reform firms invest for economic reasons regardless of dividend

policy. In contrast to the overall results reported in Table 4, the effect of capital intensity on

investment was unaltered by tax reform in any of the four portfolios.

In Australia, a significant relationship between TREF and corporate investment

indicates that the tax reform was successful in stimulating investment in fixed assets. Since

29

Page 31: CAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND ... · Web viewCAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND IMPUTATION, CAPITAL GAINS TAX AND THE INVESTMENT TAX CREDIT by Ervin L. Black* Assistant

Australia also adopted capital gains taxes for the first time, division of the Australian sample

into high and low dividend portfolios enables us to disaggregate the effects of dividend

imputation and capital gains taxes. Thus, by utilizing portfolios and variables measuring tax

rates, we can determine the separate and combined effects of lower tax rates, dividend

imputation and capital gains on fixed investment.

Results from Table 7 provide evidence tax reform impacted Australian firms

differently. The coefficient on TREF was positive and significant for Portfolio III, while it was

insignificant for the other three portfolios. These findings suggest that firms in Portfolio III

were driving the results reported in Table 4. However, the predicted sign on TREF for

Portfolio III was negative. A possible explanation for this finding is that the median dividend

payout ratio for Australian firms (0.46) is still relatively high compared to the other two

countries. For Portfolio I, tax reform changed how capital intensity influenced investment as

the coefficient on POSTCINT is positive and significant. The F-value testing whether

POSTCINT equals PRECINT is 3.66 and is significant at the 0.05 level and indicates that tax

reform significantly altered how capital intensity impacted investment for firms in Portfolio I.

For firms in Portfolio II, dividend policy did not influence investment either before tax

reform or after tax reform as the coefficients on PREDP and POSTDP were both insignificant.

However, tax reform did significantly change how dividend policy influenced investment as

the F-value from testing POSTDP equals PREDP is 11.74 and significant at the 0.01 level.

This indicates that after tax reform, dividend policy has less influence on investment than

before tax reform. Capital intensity impacted investment both before and after tax reform, as

the coefficients on PRECINT and POSTCINT were both positive and significant at the 0.05

level. In addition, there was no change in how capital intensity impacted investment as the F-

30

Page 32: CAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND ... · Web viewCAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND IMPUTATION, CAPITAL GAINS TAX AND THE INVESTMENT TAX CREDIT by Ervin L. Black* Assistant

value testing whether PRECINT equals POSTCINT was 0.12 and not significant.

For Australian firms in Portfolio III, dividend policy did not impact investment either

before or after tax reform as the coefficients on PREDIV and POSTDIV were insignificant.

However, tax reform in Australia altered how capital intensity influenced investment as the

coefficient on PRECINT was positive and significant at the 0.01 level while the coefficient on

POSTCINT was insignificant. In addition, the F-value which test whether PRECINT equals

POSTCINT was 18.25 and significant at 0.01 level indicating that tax reform in Australia

significantly impacted how capital intensity influenced investment.

Finally, for Australian firms in Portfolio IV dividend policy and capital intensity did

not impact investment either before tax reform or after as the coefficients on PREDIV,

POSTDIV, PRECINT and POSTCINT were all insignificant.

Table 8 provides the results for the portfolio regressions for Canada. The results

indicate that tax reform in Canada impacted the four Portfolios differently. For Portfolio IV,

the coefficient on TREF had the predicted sign and was positive and significant at the 0.05

level. This indicates that tax reform impacted the capital investment of high dividend

payout/high capital intensity firms and suggests dividend imputation and the ITC outweighed

the increase in the capital gains tax. The coefficient on TREF for firms in Portfolio II, and III

was insignificant while it was positive and significant for Portfolio I. However, the predicted

sign for Portfolio I was negative. A possible explanation for this finding is that these firms are

growing firms that expect to have a greater need for capital assets in the future. Thus, they used

the advantages of tax reform to make major capital investments.

In Portfolio I, capital intensity had an impact on investment before tax reform as the

coefficient on PRECINT was positive and significant while after tax reform, this was no longer

31

Page 33: CAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND ... · Web viewCAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND IMPUTATION, CAPITAL GAINS TAX AND THE INVESTMENT TAX CREDIT by Ervin L. Black* Assistant

the case as POSTCINT was insignificant. However, the F-Value of 2.47 to test whether there

was a difference between POSTCINT and PRECINT was not significant. Also, for Portfolio 1

dividend policy did not influence investment either before or after tax reform.

For Portfolio II, dividend policy impacted investment before tax reform as the

coefficient on PREDIV was significant whereas the insignificant coefficient on POSTDIV

indicates that after tax reform, dividend policy no longer influenced investment. Conversely,

capital intensity did not impact investment before tax reform as the coefficient on PRECINT

was not significant while it did impact investment after tax reform as the coefficient on

POSTCINT was positive and significant. However, for both dividend policy and capital

intensity, the F-values to test whether POSTDIV equals PREDIV and POSCINT equals

PRECINT were both insignificant indicating that tax reform did not significantly alter the

influence dividend policy and capital intensity had on investment.

For Portfolio III, dividend policy had no impact on investment either before or after tax

reform. On the other hand, capital intensity impacted investment both before and after tax

reform as the coefficients on PRECINT and POSTCINT were both positive and significant. In

addition, the coefficients on PRECINT and POSTCINT were not significantly different as the

F-value to test whether there was a difference between the two was not significant.

For Portfolio IV, the coefficient on PREDIV was not significant and indicates that

dividend policy had no impact on investment before tax reform while after tax reform, the

coefficient on POSTDIV is negative and significant. The F-value to test whether PREDIV

equals POSTDIV is 4.92 and significant at the 0.05 level. This indicates that tax reform altered

how dividend policy influences the investment decisions of firms in Portfolio IV. The positive

and significant coefficients on PRECINT and POSTCINT indicate that capital intensity had an

32

Page 34: CAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND ... · Web viewCAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND IMPUTATION, CAPITAL GAINS TAX AND THE INVESTMENT TAX CREDIT by Ervin L. Black* Assistant

impact on investment both before and after tax reform. In addition, tax reform did not

significantly change in how capital intensity impacted investment as the F-value to test whether

PRECINT equals POSTCINT was not significant.18

SUMMARY AND CONCLUDING REMARKS

The potential misallocation of economic resources has historically been a major

concern about the efficiency of traditional corporate tax systems. For example Harberger

(1962) demonstrates that the traditional double tax on corporate profits causes capital to flow

out of the corporate sector, artificially reducing capital investment by corporations. This bias

against capital investment in the corporate sector in turn results in inefficient pricing and

consumption of corporate products. Continuing research indicates that these distortions can

have significant macroeconomic economic effects, including lower growth of GNP.19 An

overriding objective of dividend imputation, the common tax reform enacted by New Zealand,

Australia and Canada and examined in this study, was to reduce biases against the corporate

form of business believed to be induced by traditional double tax systems.

By determining the impact of tax reforms on capital investment, policy-makers in the

U.S. and elsewhere can make more informed decisions regarding tax policy as it affects capital

investment. This study determines that dividend imputation resulted in increased corporate

capital investment in all three countries. Moreover, in Australia it appears that the stimulus to

corporate investment provided by dividend imputation overshadowed the possible negative

18 Sensitivity to the macroeconomic environment is examined by including a gross domestic product (GDP) variable is added to equation (1) to control for effects to the economy in general. Adding this variable does little to the explanatory power of the model. The variables’ coefficients and signs are unaffected.19 A more detailed discussion of this area of research is beyond the scope of this paper. However, Gravelle (1991) and Gravelle and Kotlikoff (1989) provide excellent summaries and discussions of the ongoing research into the macroeconomic effects of corporate taxation.

33

Page 35: CAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND ... · Web viewCAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND IMPUTATION, CAPITAL GAINS TAX AND THE INVESTMENT TAX CREDIT by Ervin L. Black* Assistant

effects of new capital gains taxes. In Canada, where the tax reform also resulted in enhanced

capital investment, it is more difficult to disentangle the beneficial effects of dividend

imputation and the new ITC. However, the results indicate that tax reform packages that

combine various attributes including dividend imputation resulted in increased corporate

capital investment.

Our tests of portfolios are based on the assumption that each portfolio is composed of

firms which are completely unaffected by some aspect of its country’s tax reform. Obviously,

relatively few corporations will remain unaffected by tax reforms of this magnitude. Thus,

while only tentative conclusions can be drawn from our portfolio tests, the results support our

primary findings. Furthermore, the results from the portfolios clearly indicate that corporations

respond differently to tax reforms based on firm specific characteristics. Tax policy makers

need to be aware that tax reforms may result not only in increased or decreased capital

investment overall, but in a shifting of investment, with wealth effects, from one sector of the

economy to another.

This possible shifting of investment raises one limitation in the interpretation of our

results. The results indicate that capital investment by relatively large corporations was

enhanced through tax reform. However, data limitations restrict our ability to measure capital

investment within other sectors of the economy, and to control for non-tax influences on

investment within those sectors. Thus, part of the increased investment that we document could

represent a shift of investment from another economic sector rather than an outright increase.

Another limitation, common to all such studies, is that major tax reforms rarely

represent discrete events. Most major tax reforms are composed of numerous changes with

potentially offsetting effects. Moreover, time lags in the form of political debates and actual

34

Page 36: CAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND ... · Web viewCAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND IMPUTATION, CAPITAL GAINS TAX AND THE INVESTMENT TAX CREDIT by Ervin L. Black* Assistant

implementation of enacted changes raise many timing and measurement issues. In response to

these issues, we have explored reasonable alternatives in how and when several variables are

measured. The consistency of our results indicate that these issues do not materially affect the

reliability of our findings, nor conclusions based upon them.

35

Page 37: CAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND ... · Web viewCAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND IMPUTATION, CAPITAL GAINS TAX AND THE INVESTMENT TAX CREDIT by Ervin L. Black* Assistant

APPENDIX

This appendix outlines the basic mechanics of a typical dividend imputation plan and

provides details of the tax reforms studied in this paper. The objective of a dividend imputation

scheme is to levy only one level of tax on corporate income. It should be noted that this

objective is already achieved in the taxation of traditional “pass through” business entities such

as subchapter S corporations and partnerships. However, dividend imputation differs

fundamentally from those taxation schemes in that under dividend imputation the tax is levied

on the corporation, using corporate tax rates. At the corporate level a dividend imputation plan

is quite similar to the traditional double tax system currently used in the U.S. Thus, it is the

taxation of dividend distributions that sets dividend imputation plans apart from the traditional

corporate tax system. An example of a typical dividend distribution under an imputation

system clearly outlines these differences.

Assume a corporation earns $100 of taxable income and that the corporate tax rate is 35

percent. The corporation will pay $35 of tax on account of this income, leaving $65 available

for distribution to shareholders. Assume now that the corporation declares and pays all $65 as a

dividend to a noncorporate shareholder. That shareholder must include the amount of the

dividend in his taxable income. The amount that the shareholder includes, however, is “grossed

up” for the amount of tax that has been paid by the corporation and is attributable to the

dividend. Thus, the shareholder includes in taxable income the $65 cash distribution as well as

the $35 of taxes that the corporation paid.

At this point, it appears that the shareholder is worse off under dividend imputation

than with a traditional double tax system since his taxable income is $35 higher. However, the

tax relief takes the form of a tax credit that the shareholder now receives. The amount of the

36

Page 38: CAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND ... · Web viewCAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND IMPUTATION, CAPITAL GAINS TAX AND THE INVESTMENT TAX CREDIT by Ervin L. Black* Assistant

credit is equal to the amount of tax that the corporation has paid on the grossed up dividend,

$35 in this example. Assuming that individual and corporate tax rates are identical at 35

percent, the shareholder will have a gross tax increase of $35 (35 percent of the grossed-up

dividend) and a perfectly offsetting tax credit of $35. In summary, the cash dividend has no net

tax effect on the shareholder and the income has been subjected to only one level of tax.

This example can be modified to illustrate the outcome of dividend imputation when

individual and corporate rates vary. Assume that the individual tax rate in the example above is

40 percent. As before, the shareholder will have to report grossed-up dividend income of $100.

However, the $35 imputation credit for taxes paid by the corporation will not entirely offset the

$40 of individual taxes due. As can be seen, an imputation system where individual tax rates

exceed corporate tax rates results in only partial elimination of double taxation.

In cases where the corporate tax rate exceeds individual tax rates, the results can be

more complex. Moreover, since most tax systems have graduated individual tax rates, this

situation can occur at almost any time even if maximum individual rates exceed maximum

corporate rates. Continuing the original example where a corporation distributes a $65 cash

dividend, now assume that the recipient is an individual shareholder in a 20 percent marginal

tax bracket. The shareholder includes the grossed-up dividend of $100 in taxable income,

which results in an increased tax due of $20. However, the dividend carries a $35 imputation

credit which, if fully allowed, will result in a total net tax of just $20, or 20 percent, on the

original corporate income. An individual shareholder under these circumstances would actually

reduce his tax liability whenever he receives a cash dividend.

In order to insure that all corporate income is subject to at least one level of tax,

corporations generally maintain a cumulative record of taxes paid. The balance of this account

37

Page 39: CAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND ... · Web viewCAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND IMPUTATION, CAPITAL GAINS TAX AND THE INVESTMENT TAX CREDIT by Ervin L. Black* Assistant

represents the amount of tax credits available on future dividend distributions and is increased

when corporate income taxes are paid and reduced whenever the corporation makes a dividend

distribution. Once the account balance is zero, any additional dividend distributions will not

carry an imputation credit.

Under certain imputation systems, one possible result of this is that corporations may

find less incentive to make use of traditional tax shields. By using a tax shield, the corporation

can successfully reduce its corporate tax. However, this strategy also reduces the imputation

credits available to shareholders. If the corporation makes distributions in excess of taxable

income, shareholders will have to include the grossed-up dividend in their taxable income but

receive no offsetting imputation credit. In summary, an additional tax shield for a high-

dividend corporation may simply “shift” the tax burden from the corporation to the

shareholders.

Tax Reform in Australia

The dividend imputation plan enacted by Australia became effective on July 1, 1987,

and closely resembles the generic plan described above. It is important to note that excess

imputation credits are not refundable to any shareholder, including tax exempt shareholders.

This is not a major factor in Australia for superannuation funds since such funds have been

subject to a 15 percent tax rate since 1988. However, imputation credits on dividends paid to

tax exempt shareholders or shareholders with relatively low taxable income might be lost.

In addition to dividend imputation, the Australian government imposed a capital gains

tax on assets acquired after September 19, 1995.20 This had the effect of grandfathering not

20 Although dividend imputation and the capital gains tax had different effective dates, they were clearly part of a integrated package of tax reforms. Head (1993) states that “imputation … did in fact form part of a substantial package of income tax reforms which included the introduction of a new indexed realisations tax on capital gains and other base-broadening measures..”

38

Page 40: CAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND ... · Web viewCAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND IMPUTATION, CAPITAL GAINS TAX AND THE INVESTMENT TAX CREDIT by Ervin L. Black* Assistant

only unrealized gains as of that date, but any additional gains on assets already held by

shareholders on September 19, 1995. Recognized capital gains receive no preference in the

form of lower rates in Australia. However, when determining the amount of gain to be

recognized on disposition of a capital asset, the owner’s basis is indexed for inflation.

Tax Reform in Canada

Canada’s dividend imputation scheme, which became effective in January of 1972,

differs from that of most countries in that there is no direct link between taxes paid at the

corporate level and the generation of imputation credits to shareholders. Shareholders receive a

credit based on grossed-up dividends regardless of the amount of taxes actually paid, or not

paid, by the distributing corporation. One effect of this is that traditional tax shields which

reduce corporate taxes will not limit dividend credits as they can in New Zealand and

Australia. Canadian corporations are also relieved of the burden of tracking the amount of

imputation credits available to shareholders. As with Australia and New Zealand, credits in

excess of pre-credit tax liability are not refundable.

Canada’s tax reform also imposed a capital gains tax on stock held for investment. One-

half of realized gains were taxes at ordinary income tax rates. This is similar to Australia’s

system, except there was no grandfathering of pre-existing gains and no indexing for inflation.

Finally, Canada instituted an ITC for investment in non-real estate business assets.

39

Page 41: CAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND ... · Web viewCAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND IMPUTATION, CAPITAL GAINS TAX AND THE INVESTMENT TAX CREDIT by Ervin L. Black* Assistant

References

Amoako-Adu, B. The Canadian Tax Reform and Its Effect on Stock Prices: A Note. Journal of Finance (December 1983), 1669-1675.

Auerbach, A.J. 1983. Taxation, Corporate Financial Policy and the Cost of Capital. Journal of Economic Literature 21: 905-940.

_______., and K.A. Hassett. 1991.Recent U.S. Investment Behavior and the Tax Reform Act of 1986: A Disaggregate View. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 35: 185-215.

Ayres, Frances L. 1987. An Empirical Assessment of the Effects of the Investment Tax Credit Legislation on Returns to Equity Securities. Journal of Accounting and Public Policy 6: 115-137.

Bernanke, B.S., H. Bohn, M. Devereux and F. Schiantarelli. 1994. Alternative Non-Nested Specification Tests of Time-Series Investment Models. Journal of Econometrics 37:1-38.

Cassou, S.P. 1997. The Link Between Tax Rates and Foreign Direct Investment. Applied Economics 29: 1295-1301.

Chirinko, R.S. 1986. Business Investment and Tax Policy: A Perspective on Existing Models and Empirical Results." National Tax Journal 39 (2): 137-155.

______,. 1993. Business Fixed Investment Spending: A Critical Survey of Modelling Strategies, Empirical Results, and Policy Implications. Journal of Economic Literature 31: 1875-1911.

Christie, A.A. 1990. Aggregation of Test Statistics: An Evaluation of the Evidence on Contracting and Size Hypotheses. Journal of Accounting and Economics 12: 15-36.

Chung, K., and C. Charoenwong. 1991. Investment options, assets in place, and the risk of stocks. Financial Management 10 (Autumn): 21-33.

Clark, P.K. 1979. Investment in the 1970s: Theory, Performance, and Prediction. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1: 73-113.

_______,.1993. Tax Incentives and Equipment Investment. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1: 317-339.

Collins, D.W., and S. P. Kothari. 1989. An analysis of the intertemporal and cross-sectional determinants of the earnings response coefficients. Journal of Accounting and Economics 9: 111-138.

40

Page 42: CAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND ... · Web viewCAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND IMPUTATION, CAPITAL GAINS TAX AND THE INVESTMENT TAX CREDIT by Ervin L. Black* Assistant

Courtenay, Stephen M., Robert P. Crum, and Stuart B. Keller. 1989. Differential Reactions to Legislative Signaling During the Enactment of ERTA and TEFRA: An Empirical Investigation of Market Returns and Volume. Journal of Accounting and Public Policy 8: 283-321.

Cummins, J.G. and K.A. Hassett. 1992. The Effects of Taxation on Investment: New Evidence From Firm Level Panel Data. National Tax Journal 45(3): 243-251.

_______., K.A. Hassett, and R.G. Hubbard. 1994. A Reconsideration of Investment Behavior Using Tax Reforms as Natural Experiments. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 2: 1-74.

_______., K.A. Hassett, and R.G. Hubbard. 1996. Tax Reforms and Investment: A Cross-Country Comparison. Journal of Public Economics 62: 237-273.

Galeotti, M., F. Schiantarelli and F. Jaramillo. 1994. Investment Decisions and The Role of Debt, Liquid Assets and Cash Flow: Evidence from Italian Panel Data. Applied Financial Economics 4: 121-132.

Gilchrist, S. and C.P. Himmelberg. 1995. Evidence on The Role of Cash Flow For Investment. Journal of Monetary Economics 36: 541-572.

Gravelle, J. 1991. Corporate Tax Integration: Issues and Options. Washington, D.C.: Congressional Research Service.

Gravelle, J. and L.J. Kotlikoff. 1989. The Incidence and Efficiency Costs of Corporate Taxation When Corporate and Noncorporate Firms Produce the Same Goods. Journal of Political Economy 97: 749-790.

Hall, R.E., and D.W. Jorgenson. 1967. Tax Policy and Investment Behavior. American Economic Review 57: 391-414.

Harberger, A.C. 1962. The Incidence of the Corporate Income Tax. Journal of Political Economy 70: 215-240.

Head, J.G. 1993. Imputation in the context of taxation reform. Bureau of Industry Economics, Dividend Imputation: Policy Forum September 1993 (p. 9-69). Canberra: Australian Government Publishing Service.

Hubbard, R. G., A.K. Kashyap, and T.M. Whited. 1995. Internal Finance and Firm Investment. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 27(3): 683-701.

Jorgenson, D.W. 1963. Capital Theory and Investment Behavior. American Economic Review 53: 247-259.

41

Page 43: CAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND ... · Web viewCAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND IMPUTATION, CAPITAL GAINS TAX AND THE INVESTMENT TAX CREDIT by Ervin L. Black* Assistant

Kern, Beth B. 1994. The Redistribution of Corporate Plant and Equipment as a Result of the Economic Recovery Act of 1981. Journal of Accounting and Public Policy 13: 225-252.

Kinney, Michael and R.H. Trezevant. 1993. Taxes and the Timing of Corporate Capital Expenditures. The Journal of the American Taxation Association 15 (Fall): 40-62.

Lewellen, W., C. Loderer, and K. Martin. 1987. Executive compensation and executive incentive problems: An empirical analysis. Journal of Accounting and Economics 9: 287-310.

Lev, Baruch and Theodore Sougiannis. 1996. The Capitalization, Amortization, and Value-Relevance of R&D. Journal of Accounting and Economics 21(1): 107-138.

Moon, Philip, and Stewart Hodges. 1989. Implications of the Recent Tax Changes For Corporate Capital Investment. Journal of Business Finance and Accounting 16(1): 25-39.

Moore, Michael L., B.M. Steece and C.W. Swenson. 1987. An Analysis of the Impact of State Income Tax Rates and Bases on Foreign Investment. The Accounting Review 4: 671-685.

Morgan, E.J. 1992. Investment Behaviour and Government Tax Policy: A Survey of The Largest UK Firms. Journal of Business Finance and Accounting 19(6): 789-815.

Oliner, S., G. Rudebusch and D. Sichel. 1995. New and Old Models of Investment: A Comparison of Forecasting Performance. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 27: 806-826.

Omer, T., K. Molloy, and D. Zeibart. 1991. Measurement of Effective Corporate Tax Rates Using Financial Statement Information. Journal of the American Taxation Association 13(Spring): 57-72.

Rosacker, Robert E. and R.W. Metcalf. 1993. United States Federal Tax Policy Surrounding The Investment Tax Credit: An Empirical Investigation of Enactments, Rate Enhancement, and Repeals. Advances In Taxation 5: 219-246.

Schulman, C.T., D.W. Thomas, K.F. Sellers, and D.B. Kennedy. 1996. Effects of Tax Reform and Capital Gains on Corporate Leverage. National Tax Journal 1: 31-54.

42

Page 44: CAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND ... · Web viewCAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND IMPUTATION, CAPITAL GAINS TAX AND THE INVESTMENT TAX CREDIT by Ervin L. Black* Assistant

Shapiro, M. 1986. Investment, Output and the Cost of Capital. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1: 111-152.

Smith, C.W. and R.L. Watts. 1992. The investment opportunity set and corporate financing, dividend, and compensation policies. Journal of Financial Economics. 263-292.

Swenson, Charles W. 1989. Tax Regimes and the Demand for Risky Assets: Some Experimental Market Evidence. The Journal of the American Taxation Association (Fall): 54-76.

_______,. 1987. An Analysis of ACRS During Inflationary Periods. The Accounting Review 1: 117-136.

Tobin, J. 1969. A General Equilibrium Approach to Monetary Theory. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 1(1): 15-29.

Vines, Cynthia C., C.W. Swenson, and W. Rodgers. 1994. Testing the Determinants of State Business Tax Burdens. Journal of Accounting and Public Policy 13: 205-224.

43

Page 45: CAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND ... · Web viewCAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND IMPUTATION, CAPITAL GAINS TAX AND THE INVESTMENT TAX CREDIT by Ervin L. Black* Assistant

Table 1Expected Relation of Tax Reform with Capital Expenditures

for New Zealand, Australia, and Canada

Portfolios Partitioned by Dividend Payout and Capital Intensity

A: New Zealand

C IA NP T I E LowT NA SL I T High Y

DIVIDEND PAYOUT

Low High

Insignificant TREFCoefficient

I

Significant Positive TREF Coefficient

IISignificant PositiveTREF Coefficient

III

Significant PositiveTREF Coefficient

IV

B: Australia

C IA NP T I E LowT NA SL I T High Y

DIVIDEND PAYOUT

Low High

Insignificant TREFCoefficient

I

Significant Positive TREF Coefficient

IISignificant Negative TREF

Coefficient

III

Significant Positive TREF Coefficient

IV

C: Canada

C IA NP T I E LowT NA SL I T High Y

DIVIDEND PAYOUT

Low High

Significant Negative TREFCoefficient

I

Significant Positive TREF Coefficient

II

?

III

Significant Positive TREF Coefficient

IV

44

Page 46: CAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND ... · Web viewCAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND IMPUTATION, CAPITAL GAINS TAX AND THE INVESTMENT TAX CREDIT by Ervin L. Black* Assistant

Table 2

Descriptive Data on Tax Rates in Australia and New Zealand

New Zealand Australia Canada

YEARMaximumCorporate Tax Rate

MaximumIndividual Tax Rate

MaximumCorporate Tax Rate

MaximumIndividual Tax Rate

YEARMaximumCorporate Tax Rate

MaximumIndividual Tax Rate

1982 45% 60% 46% 60% 1968 51.4% 60%

1983 45% 66% 46% 60% 1969 51.4% 60%

1984 45% 66% 46% 60% 1970 46.7% 60%

1985 45% 66% 46% 60% 1971 46.5% 57.6%

1986 45% 66% 46% 60% 1972 49% 45.6%

1987 48% 57% 49% 57% 1973 50.6% 47%

1988 48% 48% 49% 49% 1974 48.2% 47%

1989 28% 40.5% 39% 49% 1975 46% 47%

1990 33% 33% 39% 48% 1976 46% 47%

1991 33% 33% 39% 47% 1977 46% 51.7%

45

Page 47: CAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND ... · Web viewCAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND IMPUTATION, CAPITAL GAINS TAX AND THE INVESTMENT TAX CREDIT by Ervin L. Black* Assistant

Table 3

Descriptive Statistics of Regression VariablesMeans (Medians)

Variable New Zealand Australia Canada

Investment (INV) 0.15(0.04)

0.16(0.04)

0.15(0.04)

Tax Reform Dummy (TREF)

0.58(1.00)

0.53(1.00)

0.60(1.00)

Net Operating Loss Dummy (DNOL)

0.57(1.00)

0.56(1.00)

0.37(0)

Statutory Tax Rate (RATE)

0.49(0.48)

0.54(0.49)

0.53(0.51)

Book-to-Market Ratio (BKMKT)

5.15(1.52)

2.23(0.93)

0.95(0.61)

Debt-to-Equity Ratio (DE)

1.78(1.16)

1.01(1.05)

1.48(1.12)

Cash Flow Ratio (CF)

0.11(0.07)

0.48(0.10)

0.22(0.11)

Dividend Payout Ratio (DP)

0.31(0.42)

0.21(0.46)

0.48(0.28)

Capital Intensity Ratio (CINT)

0.40(0.35)

0.43(0.41)

0.45(0.42)

SIZE 5.75(5.57)

5.85(5.81)

3.81(4.07)

Lagged Investment (LINV)

0.19(0.05)

0.17(0.03)

0.15(0.04)

46

Page 48: CAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND ... · Web viewCAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND IMPUTATION, CAPITAL GAINS TAX AND THE INVESTMENT TAX CREDIT by Ervin L. Black* Assistant

Definition of Variables:

INV = measure of investment for firm i, at time t.TREF = dummy measure of whether tax reform is available for firm i, at time t.DNOL = measure of the likelihood of a net operating loss for firm I, at time t. If the

firm has had a net operating loss in the last five years DNOL = 1, 0 otherwise.

RATE = the maximum of the statutory corporate tax rate or the individual tax rate at time t.

BKMKT = book-to-market ratio for firm i, at time t.DE = debt-to-equity ratio for firm i, at time t.CF = cash flow ratio for firm i, at time t.DP = dividend payout ratio for firm i, at time t.CINT = capital intensity ratio for firm i, at time t.SIZE = a measure of the size of firm i, at time t.LINV = lagged measure of investment for firm i, at time t-1.

47

Page 49: CAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND ... · Web viewCAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND IMPUTATION, CAPITAL GAINS TAX AND THE INVESTMENT TAX CREDIT by Ervin L. Black* Assistant

Table 4Correlation Analysis

A: New Zealand – Pearson Correlation CoefficientsINV TREF DNOL RATE BKMKT DE CF DP CINT SIZE

TREF -0.221DNOL 0.097 -0.108RATE 0.227 -0.947 0.081BKMKT 0.006 -0.279 0.012 0.276DE 0.491 -0.110 0.075 0.096 -0.056CF 0.202 0.073 0.121 -0.060 -0.010 0.033DP 0.056 -0.031 0.064 -0.018 0.016 0.004 0.031CINT 0.399 -0.027 0.179 0.014 0.161 0.214 0.008 0.055SIZE 0.174 0.037 -0.228 -0.038 0.060 0.174 0.097 0.035 0.307LINV 0.639 -0.187 0.146 0.211 0.010 0.637 0.159 0.029 0.456 0.192

B: Australia – Pearson Correlation CoefficientsINV TREF DNOL RATE BKMKT DE CF DP CINT SIZE

TREF 0.075DNOL -0.229 -0.195RATE -0.094 -0.984 0.172BKMKT -0.094 -0.023 0.075 0.030DE -0.003 -0.037 -0.002 0.023 0.044CF 0.38 -0.062 0.054 0.067 -0.035 -0.006DP 0.002 -0.019 -0.031 0.018 0.012 -0.012 -0.001CINT 0.150 0.012 0.107 -0.026 0.067 -0.058 0.041 0.029SIZE 0.131 0.166 -0.273 -0.179 0.239 0.043 -0.161 0.010 -0.041LINV 0.168 0.127 -0.110 -0.148 -0.042 0.027 0.070 0.002 0.094 0.125

C: Canada – Pearson Correlation CoefficientsINV TREF DNOL RATE BKMKT DE CF DP CINT SIZE

TREF 0.043DNOL -0.019 -0.228RATE -0.060 -0.787 0.264BKMKT -0.063 0.103 -0.261 -0.084DE 0.102 0.061 0.038 -0.042 -0.062CF 0.175 -0.024 -0.005 0.022 0.020 -0.038DP -0.017 -0.022 0.029 0.019 -0.016 -0.013 0.334CINT 0.471 -0.063 0.016 0.061 -0.076 0.161 -0.025 -0.026SIZE 0.308 0.127 -0.382 -0.126 0.158 -0.0003 0.007 0.001 -0.177LINV 0.571 0.062 0.073 -0.092 -0.052 0.103 0.147 -0.014 0.468 -0.300

Bold indicates significant p-value < 0.05

48

Page 50: CAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND ... · Web viewCAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND IMPUTATION, CAPITAL GAINS TAX AND THE INVESTMENT TAX CREDIT by Ervin L. Black* Assistant

Table 5Regression Results by Country

(5)

New ZealandN = 158

AustraliaN = 1,010

CanadaN = 1,776

Independent Variable

Expected Sign Parameter Estimate Parameter Estimate Parameter Estimate

Intercept ? -0.61 -2.45*** -0.21

TREF + 0.46** 0.67* 0.04***

RATE ? 0.003 .034 0.004*

DNOL - -0.11*** 0.01 -0.002

BKMKT - 0.004 -0.01 0.02

DE ? 0.03 -0.01 0.003

CF + 0.45* 0.002* 0.00004*

PREDP - 0.16** -0.01 -0.0001*

PRECINT + 1.21* 1.87* 0.43*

POSTDP - 0.006 0.0001 -0.02**

POSTCINT + -0.03 0.68* 0.39*

SIZE ? 0.003 -0.001 -0.02*

LINV + 0.31* 0.01 0.34*

Model F-Value 13.57* 27.94* 140.99*

Adjusted R-square 0.49 0.24 0.49TEST:

PREDP-POSTDP = 0F-Value

2.55 0.68 2.77***

TEST: PRECINT – POSTCINT = 0

F-Value7.50* 23.38* 0.84

*indicates significance at 0.01 level. **indicates significance at 0.05 level. ***indicates significance at 0.10 level.

49

Page 51: CAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND ... · Web viewCAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND IMPUTATION, CAPITAL GAINS TAX AND THE INVESTMENT TAX CREDIT by Ervin L. Black* Assistant

Table 6New Zealand Portfolio Regression Results

(5)

IndependentVariables

ILow DP

Low CINTN = 42

IIHighDP

Low CINTN = 38

IIILow DP

High CINTN = 29

IVHigh DP

High CINTN = 49

Intercept -0.04 0.02 -1.30 -1.63

TREF -0.01 -0.11 0.86 1.37***

RATE 0.001 0.001 0.01 0.01

DNOL -0.06*** 0.04 -0.06 -0.05

BKMKT 0.0004 -0.001 0.01 0.01

DE 0.01 0.01 0.03 -0.06

CF 0.09 -0.02 0.88** 2.35*

PREDP -0.03 -0.04 -0.17 0.50**

PRECINT 0.02 -0.44 1.81 0.65

POSTDP 0.004 -0.07 0.13 -0.18

POSTCINT -0.14 0.06 -0.20 -0.59

SIZE 0.01 0.02 0.01 0.02

LINV -0.21 0.23 0.13 0.48

Model F-Value 1.01 0.96 1.84 5.85*

Adjusted R-square 0.003 0.00 0.27 0.55TEST:

PREDP-POSTDP = 0F-Value

0.48 0.03 0.34 4.70**

TEST: PRECINT – POSTCINT = 0

F-Value0.06 0.23 1.69 0.52

*indicates significance at 0.01 level.**indicates significance at 0.05 level.***indicates significance at 0.10 level.

50

Page 52: CAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND ... · Web viewCAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND IMPUTATION, CAPITAL GAINS TAX AND THE INVESTMENT TAX CREDIT by Ervin L. Black* Assistant

Table 7Australia Portfolio Regression Results

(5)

IndependentVariables

ILow DP

Low CINTN = 244

IIHighDP

Low CINTN = 256

IIILow DP

High CINTN =244

IVHigh DP

High CINTN = 265

Intercept -2.05 -0.07 -8.54 0.16

TREF -0.07 0.07 4.29* -0.20

RATE 0.03 -0.001 10.88 -0.14

DNOL -0.03 -0.003 -0.29 0.08**

BKMKT 0.0004 0.01 -0.02 -0.01

DE -0.002 0.05** -0.07 0.02

CF 0.001 0.06*** 0.002* 0.62*

PREDP -0.0002 -0.004 -0.87 -0.002

PRECINT 0.34 0.33*** 6.04* -0.16

POSTDP 0.0001 -0.16 -0.001 -0.01

POSTCINT 1.39* 0.44** -0.06 0.01

SIZE 0.04** 0.003 -0.04 0.01

LINV -0.02 0.01 -0.06 0.06

Model F-Value 3.06* 5.72* 9.03* 7.33*

Adjusted R-square 0.09 0.18 0.28 0.22TEST:

PREDP-POSTDP = 0F-Value

0.003 11.74* 1.58 0.09

TEST: PRECINT – POSTCINT = 0

F-Value3.66** 0.12 18.26* 0.21

*indicates significance at 0.01 level.**indicates significance at 0.05 level.***indicates significance at 0.10 level.

51

Page 53: CAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND ... · Web viewCAPITAL INVESTMENT EFFECTS OF DIVIDEND IMPUTATION, CAPITAL GAINS TAX AND THE INVESTMENT TAX CREDIT by Ervin L. Black* Assistant

Table 8Canada Portfolio Regression Results

(5)

IndependentVariables

ILow DP

Low CINTN = 509

IIHighDP

Low CINTN = 376

IIILow DP

High CINTN =411

IVHigh DP

High CINTN = 480

Intercept -0.23 0.07 -0.42 -0.35*

TREF 0.07*** -0.05 0.14 0.13**

RATE 0.004** 0.001 0.36 0.004***

DNOL 0.02 0.05 -0.10* 0.11*

BKMKT 0.02 -0.11 0.05 -0.17***

DE -0.003 -0.01*** -0.00001 0.01***

CF 0.000005* 0.000003* 0.00001* 0.00004*

PREDP 0.03*** -0.0001* -0.15 0.023

PRECINT 0.31* 0.03 0.76* 0.67*

POSTDP 0.02 0.004 -0.31 -0.05*

POSTCINT 0.07 0.17** 0.57* 0.59*

SIZE -0.01 -0.0013 -0.01 -0.02*

LINV 0.15* 0.33* 0.36* 0.25*

Model F-Value 5.89* 14.98* 13.80* 102.77*

Adjusted R-square 0.10 0.31 0.27 0.72TEST:

PREDP-POSTDP = 0F-Value

0.14 0.06 0.68 4.92**

TEST: PRECINT – POSTCINT = 0

F-Value2.47 1.23 0.77 0.74

*indicates significance at 0.01 level.**indicates significance at 0.05 level.***indicates significance at 0.10 level.

52