31
1 Cabinet ministers and parliamentary government: How institutions and internal party politics affect ministerial accountability Cristina Bucur 1 Dublin City University Abstract Ministerial accountability is an important problem in political science. To account for it scholars have usually focused on the prime minister’s ability to hire and fire cabinet members. This paper argues that in parliamentary democracies ministers are accountable not only to prime ministers, but also to their own parties and directly-elected presidents. The hypothesis tested in this paper is that each principal’s ability to hold ministers accountable depends on their formal powers and on the party relations between ministers, presidents and prime ministers. Moreover, the presidents’ and prime ministers’ ability to control cabinet composition under certain institutional conditions is thought to derive from their formal or informal positions as party leaders. This expectation is tested on a unique data set on the tenures of French, Portuguese and Romanian ministers during two legislative terms. Survival analyses of ministerial durability find that presidents and prime ministers who act as de facto party leaders are in a better position to influence the process of ministerial deselection certain institutional conditions. Conversely, the party principal’s ability to sanction agency loss declines when either of the two chief executives is a de facto leader. These findings speak to the debate regarding the challenges faced by the party government model in parliamentary democracies and draw attention to the consequences of increasingly autonomous chief executives for ministerial accountability. 1 Paper prepared for presentation at the workshop “The Evolution of Parliamentarism and Its Political Consequences”, Joint Sessions of Workshops of the European Consortium of Political Research, Salamanca, April 10–15, 2014.

Cabinet ministers and parliamentary government: How … · warned that ministers elected as party leaders must give up their cabinet seats to prevent any damage to the prime minister’s

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    0

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 1

    Cabinet ministers and parliamentary government: How institutions and internal

    party politics affect ministerial accountability

    Cristina Bucur1

    Dublin City University

    Abstract

    Ministerial accountability is an important problem in political science. To account for it

    scholars have usually focused on the prime minister’s ability to hire and fire cabinet

    members. This paper argues that in parliamentary democracies ministers are accountable

    not only to prime ministers, but also to their own parties and directly-elected presidents.

    The hypothesis tested in this paper is that each principal’s ability to hold ministers

    accountable depends on their formal powers and on the party relations between ministers,

    presidents and prime ministers. Moreover, the presidents’ and prime ministers’ ability to

    control cabinet composition under certain institutional conditions is thought to derive

    from their formal or informal positions as party leaders. This expectation is tested on a

    unique data set on the tenures of French, Portuguese and Romanian ministers during two

    legislative terms. Survival analyses of ministerial durability find that presidents and prime

    ministers who act as de facto party leaders are in a better position to influence the process

    of ministerial deselection certain institutional conditions. Conversely, the party

    principal’s ability to sanction agency loss declines when either of the two chief executives

    is a de facto leader. These findings speak to the debate regarding the challenges faced by

    the party government model in parliamentary democracies and draw attention to the

    consequences of increasingly autonomous chief executives for ministerial accountability.

    1 Paper prepared for presentation at the workshop “The Evolution of Parliamentarism and Its Political Consequences”, Joint Sessions of Workshops of the European Consortium of Political Research, Salamanca, April 10–15, 2014.

  • 2

    Introduction

    Following his election as President of France in 1995, Jacques Chirac nominated Alain

    Juppé, one of his closest collaborators, for the presidency of the Rally for the Republic

    (RPR) party and appointed him as prime minister. Four years later, Nicolas Sarkozy gave

    up running for the presidency of the Gaullist party after President Chirac warned him that

    the leader of the majority party would not be prime minister in 2002. Despite Sarkozy’s

    abandonment of the party leadership race, he was not appointed as prime minister in 2002

    when Jacques Chirac was re-elected. In 2004, Sarkozy contested the presidency of the

    Union for a Popular Movement (UMP) after Alain Juppé stepped down amid accusations

    of embezzling public funds. Before new party elections were organised, though, Chirac

    warned that ministers elected as party leaders must give up their cabinet seats to prevent

    any damage to the prime minister’s authority over cabinet ministers. As a result, Sarkozy

    stepped down from government in November 2004, when he was elected as UMP leader.

    Six months later, the Raffarin government resigned following the rejection of the

    referendum on the European Constitution and Sarkozy was re-appointed in government as

    interior minister and second in hierarchy only to PM Dominique de Villepin.

    Apart from illustrating the nature of intraparty competition in France, the events

    described above raise an important question for students of party politics. Why did

    President Chirac appoint the leader of the majority party as prime minister in 1995, but

    refused to do so in 2004 and 2005? And why was Nicolas Sarkozy asked to step down in

    2004 as a result of his election as UMP leader, only to be re-appointed in government six

    months later? President Chirac’s concern about the personal loyalty of prime ministers

    and leaders of the majority party suggests that party relations should be taken into account

    when assessing variation in presidential and prime ministerial authority over the cabinet.

    Therefore, this paper focuses on the way in which both political institutions and internal

    party politics structure accountability relations between cabinet ministers and their

    superiors in the government and party hierarchy.

    My aim is to connect the literature on ministerial accountability to the debate on

    the challenges faced by the model of party government in modern democracies (Mair

    2008). Regardless of the definitions given to the concept of party government, one of the

    conditions enabling parties to influence government requires that political leaders are

    selected within parties and held responsible for their actions through parties (Rose 1969;

    Katz 1986, 1987; Mair 2008). The parties’ ability to place their agents in public office is

  • 3

    seen as a form of institutional control that operates for the benefit of the party

    organisation (Kopecký and Mair 2012: 7). However, party government scholars argue

    that simply having party members appointed to cabinet is a weak measure of party control

    over the executive (Andeweg 2000; Müller 2000). Andeweg (2000: 389) argued that only

    a direct link from parties to individual ministers can prevent the problem of agency loss.

    However, he found little evidence that the link between parties and their agents goes

    beyond the appointment of party members to ministerial office and argued that only the

    use of recalls and reshuffles could indicate that parties effectively control their agents in

    ministerial office. Thus, the parties’ ability to contain agency loss by firing their minister

    agents is a good test for the challenges that the model of party government faces in

    modern parliamentary democracies.

    To capture variation in ministerial accountability to different principals in the

    government and party hierarchy, I employ a multiple-principal model of ministerial

    accountability. One-principal models are the industry standard in the literature of

    ministerial turnover (Dewan and Dowding 2005; Fischer et al. 2006; Dewan and Myatt

    2007, 2010; Huber and Martinez-Gallardo 2008; Indridason and Kam 2008). However,

    their use outside Westminster systems is problematic. The institutional rules governing

    the hiring and firing of ministers vary considerably in coalition systems, where ministers

    report separately to prime ministers and their own parties (Dowding and Dumont 2009;

    Fischer et al. 2012). The involvement of multiple principals in the origin and survival of

    cabinets in semi-presidential system further blurs the lines of ministerial responsibility

    and accountability (Protsyk 2006; Schleiter and Morgan-Jones 2009). Therefore, a

    multiple-principal approach is a more adequate choice for the study of ministerial

    accountability outside Westminster systems and one that can also take into account the

    party relations between ministers-agents and their competing principals.

    To take advantage of the largest intra- and inter-case variation in principal-agent

    relations that enable presidents, prime ministers, and political parties to act as competing

    principals for cabinet members, I test the multiple-principal model of ministerial

    accountability in three semi-presidential countries, France, Portugal, and Romania. The

    core of the empirical analysis consists of survival analyses of ministerial durability that

    take into account personal characteristics and performance indicators such as resignation

    calls and conflicts with the three principals. I find that chief executives who act as de

    facto party leaders reduce the party principals’ ability to hold cabinet members

    accountable. Presidents and prime ministers who deliver electoral victories as party

  • 4

    leaders are in a better position to control cabinet composition under certain institutional

    conditions. These findings highlight the impact that formal and informal hierarchies of

    party leadership have on the ability of presidents and prime ministers to limit agency loss

    and explain the discrepancy between the formal powers held by political actors and their

    actual influence over the cabinet.

    This paper is structured conventionally. The next section discusses theory,

    singling out the factors that explain variation in ministerial accountability in semi-

    presidential systems and outlining the expectations regarding the variation in the authority

    of presidents, prime ministers and party principals over the cabinet. Then I explain the

    case selection and the time period under analysis, and I introduce the measures and

    methods with which I test for the variation in the ability of principals to control cabinet

    composition. After presenting the survival analysis, which is the main method of

    empirical analysis, I summarise the findings and I discuss the implications of the results

    for the comparative study of ministerial accountability in parliamentary democracies.

    Theory

    To explain variation in ministerial accountability in semi-presidential systems, one needs

    to focus on the factors that account for the variation in presidential and prime ministerial

    authority over the political system. Three research approaches are available. The first one

    adopts a purely institutional view on the relationship between institutional conditions and

    the extent of presidential and prime ministerial influence. This idea has been inspired by

    the operation of semi-presidentialism in France. Even before the first occurrence of

    cohabitation in France, there was an expectation that if the president ever had to put up

    with an opposing parliamentary majority, then semi-presidentialism would work not as a

    synthesis of parliamentary and presidential systems, but as an alternation between

    presidential and parliamentary phases (Duverger 1980: 186). Arend Lijphart also defined

    semi-presidential systems as an alternation of presidential and parliamentary phases,

    where the political power shifts from the president to the prime minister depending on

    whether the president’s party has a majority in the legislature (Lijphart 1992: 8). This

    argument, according to which presidents are powerful when they are on the same side of

    the parliamentary majority (a situation known as unified executive) and weak when they

    oppose the majority (the situation defined as cohabitation), has been embraced by many

    French scholars (Parodi 1997; Portelli 1997; Ardant and Duhamel 1999; Peyrefitte 1999).

  • 5

    Despite its popularity in France, the idea that one should expect presidential

    leadership under unified executive and prime ministerial leadership under cohabitation

    has not received unanimous support. For example, Margit Tavits (2008) reckons that

    presidents have few incentives to be politically active during periods of unified

    government, when policy preferences are likely to be compatible across all branches of

    government. She thinks that presidents are likely to pursue their objectives more actively

    during periods of cohabitation, when their party is not in power and they face opposition

    both in the government and parliament (Tavits 2008: 16). Cindy Skach (2005, 2007) also

    expects presidents to be more active when they do not enjoy the support of the legislature

    and during periods of minority government. These competing explanations suggest that

    the variation in presidential and prime ministerial influence under different executive

    scenarios should not be taken at face value. Moreover, the occurrence of unified

    executive and cohabitation may not make any difference for the extent of presidential and

    prime ministerial authority. For example, in countries like Ireland, Austria, Iceland, or

    Slovenia, presidents are always weak regardless of their relationship with parliamentary

    majorities and prime ministers have full control over the cabinet (Elgie 2009: 261).

    Therefore, executive scenarios do not fully capture the variation in presidential and prime

    ministerial powers in semi-presidential systems.

    Secondly, some scholars focus on contextual factors. For example, Tavits (2008)

    does not believe that whether presidents are directly elected or not makes a difference for

    the extent of their activism. She thinks that the level of presidential activism depends on

    the framework of political opportunities. Presidents are more likely to be active when the

    level of political consensus is low, during periods of cohabitation. The incentives for

    activism should be even stronger under conditions of minority government, irrespective

    of whether the cabinet is ideologically opposed to the president, as the other

    policymaking institutions, the government and parliament, are likely to be weak and

    fragmented (Tavits 2008: 39–40). Using the share of non-partisan ministers as a measure

    of presidential activism in both parliamentary and semi-presidential systems, Tavits

    (2008: 49) finds that presidents are more active in the case of minority government and

    during periods of cohabitation irrespective of their mode of election. Therefore, the

    determinant for the variation in presidential authority does not always (or necessarily)

    reside in the institutional structure of semi-presidentialism.

    The third option is to take into account the combined impact of institutional

    scenarios and contextual factors on the extent of presidential and prime ministerial

  • 6

    powers. Here I focus on internal party politics. The party relations between presidents,

    prime ministers, and cabinet members play an important role in the process of delegation

    and accountability in parliamentary democracies. Although political parties take part in

    each step of the delegation process from voters to elected politicians and bureaucrats,

    their direct intervention to control agents in public office is often limited by legitimate

    public concerns regarding the independence of national institutions from anonymous

    party machines (Müller 2000: 311). As a result, party principals have to share control

    over cabinet members with presidents and prime ministers who own the formal or

    informal power to fire ministers.

    The balance of power between party principals and party agents varies across

    different types of political systems. In pure parliamentary systems, where political parties

    retain the power to recall prime ministers, intraparty politics determines who runs the

    government (Samuels and Shugart 2010: 120). This balance of power can change in semi-

    presidential systems. A highly valued presidency loosens the party-government

    relationship, as political parties have no ex-post control mechanisms for their agents in a

    directly elected presidential office (Schleiter and Morgan-Jones 2009: 668). Under certain

    circumstances, presidents may be able to keep a strong grip on the cabinet. Samuels and

    Shugart (2010) argue that the presidents’ influence over the political system derives from

    their de facto position as party leaders. From a principal-agent perspective, ‘when

    presidents are de facto party leaders, the importance of parliamentary confidence to the

    chain of delegation […] vanishes, because the premier becomes an agent of the president’

    (Samuels and Shugart 2010: 43). Presidents who carry on in their role as de facto leaders

    reverse the party-leader principal-agent relationship by turning prime ministers into their

    own agents, which deprives political parties of the ability to control either of their two

    agents (Samuels and Shugart 2010: 121). If parties lose control over the prime minister,

    then they are also likely to lose control over cabinet members to the benefit of the head of

    state. This is how the party hierarchy between presidents and prime ministers may explain

    the asymmetry between weak formal powers and de facto control over the executive.

    To test the hypothesis that the chief executives’ influence over the government

    derives from their de facto position as party leaders, I operationalise the concept of de

    facto partisan authority by taking into account the positions held by presidents and prime

    ministers in the party hierarchy before they take office. Thus, I expect that presidents who

    step down as party leaders, only to be sworn in as heads of state continue to control their

    parties. By contrast, I expect that presidents who did not contest the presidential race as

  • 7

    party leaders have little or no impact on cabinet composition regardless of executive

    scenarios. Consequently, I do not expect them to control the cabinet either. This

    expectation is in line with Duverger’s anticipation that a de facto party leadership position

    is the sine qua non condition for strong presidents during periods of unified executive: ‘If

    the president is not the head of the majority party, while belonging to it or coming under

    it, this means that the party has decided to give its leader the office of prime minister, to

    whom the real power then belongs’ (Duverger 1980: 184). This is how Duverger explains

    the figurehead positions of Austrian and Irish presidents, who have never been regarded

    as leaders of parliamentary majorities, although they have usually been part of it.

    If presidents are de facto party leaders, then they should also be relatively strong

    during periods of divided executive. This is the situation when the president and the

    prime minister belong to different parties in the ruling coalition. This expectation is also

    supported in the literature. For example, Samuels and Shugart (2010: 101) find that

    presidents are able to dismiss prime ministers who are not their co-partisans in semi-

    presidential systems. The president’s unexpected capacity to hold accountable other

    parties’ agents is put down to the functions of alliance-formation: ‘In multiparty systems,

    parties sometimes form coalitions in which one party gets the presidency while another

    gets the premiership. When entering such alliances, parties apparently accept a deal in

    which the president determines how long the premier and the cabinet stay in office’

    (Samuels and Shugart 2010: 105). Hellwig and Samuels (2007: 70) also assume that the

    president leads the government when s/he and the prime minister belong to the same

    ruling coalition but not necessarily to the same party.

    Unless the president enjoys formal constitutional powers over the government

    and/or individual ministers, I do not expect partisan sources of authority to matter for her

    ability to hold cabinet members accountable under cohabitation. Intra-party politics are

    likely to matter more under this executive scenario, when presidents lack both formal and

    partisan means of influence over the cabinet. As a result, ministers no longer need to act

    as presidential agents. To sum up, once de facto leadership positions are taken into

    account, one may expect presidents to be less influential during periods of divided

    executive than under unified executive, but more powerful than under cohabitation.

    Similarly, prime ministers who are party leaders should be able to keep a tighter

    grip on the cabinet. If prime ministers are not party leaders, then I expect them to be

    relatively weak irrespective of whether there is unified executive, divided executive, or

    cohabitation. However, as opposed to presidents, prime ministers enjoy a range of formal

  • 8

    powers over the cabinet, including the right to fire ministers. Due to this institutional

    feature, I expect that prime ministers who are party leaders take advantage of both

    constitutional powers and intraparty mechanisms of control and hold cabinet members

    accountable irrespective of executive scenarios. However, their authority may decrease

    during periods of divided executive if they share executive power with presidents who

    also act as de facto party leaders.

    Lastly, due to their centrality in the chain of democratic delegation in

    representative democracies, party principals should retain a certain amount of influence

    over the cabinet under all circumstances, as long as they can hold accountable their agents

    in government, including the president and the prime minister. Thus, if neither the

    president, nor the prime minister is a party leader, I expect party principals to keep a tight

    grip over cabinet ministers at all times. However, if the president and/or the prime

    minister are party leaders, then party principals will lack the means of sanctioning agency

    loss during periods of unified executive and divided executive. All else equal, party

    principals should be more influential under cohabitation even when the president and the

    prime minister are party leaders. In this case, the president is opposed to the

    parliamentary majority and has fewer means to compete for control over the cabinet,

    while parties can sanction agency loss by replacing the prime minister. Table 1

    summarises the expectations outlined above.

    Table 1 Presidential, prime ministerial, and party influence over cabinet ministers across

    executive scenarios and as a function of de facto party leadership

    PRESIDENT Unified Divided Cohabitation

    President party leader? Y +++ ++ +

    N 0 0 0

    PM Unified Divided Cohabitation

    PM party leader? Y +++ ++ +++

    N 0 0 0

    PARTY Unified Divided Cohabitation

    President and PM party leaders? Y 0 0 +

    N +++ +++ +++

    Controlling for the party hierarchy between presidents and prime ministers allows

    one to determine to what extent and under what circumstances de facto party leadership

    positions account for the discrepancy between the formal powers held by political actors

  • 9

    and their actual influence over the decision-making system. The distinct focus on the joint

    impact of executive scenarios and internal party politics on the balance of power between

    party principals and party agents differentiates this study from other works that associate

    the variation in the authority of presidents and prime ministers over cabinets with the

    occurrence of executive scenarios.

    Case selection, data and variables

    The empirical analysis is carried out on a new data set on the tenure of French,

    Portuguese and Romanian ministers. These countries have been selected according to the

    principles of the most-similar system design. They belong to the premier-presidential sub-

    type of semi-presidential systems, where cabinet members are formally accountable only

    to the legislature (Shugart and Carey 1992). The aim of the empirical analysis is to

    account for the cross-country variation in the ministers’ accountability to presidents,

    prime ministers and party principals despite a common institutional framework.

    The three countries vary in ways that illustrate and put to the test the theoretical

    expectations outlined above. The alternation of dual-executive scenarios in France,

    Portugal and Romania and the variation in the party leadership roles played by presidents

    and prime ministers in these countries provide significant variation in the key explanatory

    variables. The time period under analysis in France includes one spell of cohabitation and

    one of unified executive. The most recent period of cohabitation occurred between 1997

    and 2002, when the Gaullist President Jacques Chirac and the Socialist PM Lionel Jospin

    shared executive power. To control for different styles of prime ministerial leadership, the

    period of unified executive included in the analysis is that between 2007 and 2012, when

    President Sarkozy of the UMP shared executive power with Prime Minister Fillon for the

    entire length of the term. Had the second presidential term of President Chirac between

    2002 and 2007 been included in the analysis, it would have been more difficult to account

    for different prime ministerial leadership styles as two prime ministers held office during

    this period of time (Jean-Pierre Raffarin between 2002 and 2005 and Dominique de

    Villepin between 2005 and 2007).

    The time period under analysis in Portugal spans from 2002 until 2009 and

    includes two spells of cohabitation and one of unified executive. President Mário Soares

    of the Socialist Party cohabited with the Social-Democratic cabinets led by Manuel

    Durrão Barroso and Pedro Santana Lopes between 2002 and 2005. The Socialist Party’s

  • 10

    victory in the 2005 general election generated a period of unified executive, which lasted

    until March 2006, when Ánibal Cavaco Silva of the Social Democratic Party succeeded

    Mário Soares as President of Portugal.

    The time period under analysis in Romania includes the governments that were

    formed between 2000 and 2008. The Social-Democratic government that took office in

    December 2000 operated under a scenario of unified executive, as President Iliescu and

    PM Năstase of the Social Democratic Party shared executive power until 2004. The new

    government formed after the 2004 elections started off under a scenario of divided

    executive, as President Traian Băsescu of the Democratic Party appointed Călin Popescu-

    Tăriceanu of the National Liberal Party as the prime minister of a coalition cabinet that

    was dominated by the two parties. The period of divided executive ended in April 2007,

    when President Băsescu’s party left the government coalition. This event triggered the

    onset of a period of cohabitation that lasted until new legislative elections were organised

    in December 2008. Table 2 maps the cabinets, the occurrence of executive scenarios, and

    the time period under analysis in the three countries.

    Table 2 Countries, cabinets, time period, and executive scenarios

    France Portugal Romania

    Scenario Cabinet Time period Cabinet Time period Cabinet Time period

    Unified

    executive Fillon

    17/05/2007

    10/05/2012 Socrates

    12/03/2005

    11/03/2006 Năstase

    28/12/2000

    28/12/2004

    Divided

    executive Tăriceanu 1

    29/12/2004

    05/04/2007

    Cohabitation Jospin 2/06/1997

    6/05/2002

    Barroso 17/05/2002

    17/07/2004

    Tăriceanu 2 06/04/2007

    22/12/2008 Santana Lopes

    17/07/2004

    13/12/2004

    Socrates 11/03/2006

    26/10/2009

    Table 3 classifies the cabinets under study according to executive scenarios and

    the party leadership positions held by presidents and prime ministers before taking office.

  • 11

    Table 3 Executive scenarios and party leadership positions before elections

    SCENARIO

    LEA

    DE

    RS

    HIP

    Unified Cohabitation Divided

    PR (RO) Năstase (2000/04)

    (FR) Fillon (2007/12)

    PM (PT) Socrates (2005/06)

    (PT) Barroso (2002/04)

    (PT) Santana Lopes (2004)

    (PT) Socrates (2006/09)

    PR, PM

    (FR) Jospin (1997/02) (RO) Tăriceanu 1

    (2004/07) (RO) Tăriceanu 2

    (2007/08)

    Neither

    The distribution of party leadership roles across the three countries confirms the

    expectation that if the presidency is a highly valued office, then political parties are likely

    to nominate their leaders as presidential candidates. This is the case in France and

    Romania. The French and the Romanian cases also vary as far as the party leadership

    positions held by prime ministers before and after elections are concerned. While Lionel

    Jospin stepped down from the presidency of the Socialist Party after he became prime

    minister, newly appointed PM Năstase succeeded Ion Iliescu as president of the Social-

    Democratic Party. Party relationships do not vary in Portugal, where political parties do

    not nominate their leaders as presidential candidates. Although the Portuguese presidents

    covered in this study had also been party leaders at some point during their political

    career, they had not contested the presidency of the country from this position. The

    importance of party leadership roles in Portugal is borne out by the fact that all prime

    ministers included in the analysis held the presidency of their parties before and after

    elections, regardless of the executive scenario under which their government operated.

    The data set covers 232 ministerial appointments and includes all ministers and

    delegated ministers who served in the two governments under study. State secretaries are

    excluded from the analysis because their subordination to specific ministries rules out

    their accountability to multiple principals. The data set includes the exact dates when

    ministers take and leave office. The dependent variable records the length of ministerial

    tenure. A ministerial spell is defined as the uninterrupted length of time served by the

    minister upon appointment. The ministers’ observed tenure is right-censored if they leave

    office collectively as a result of a government termination. The duration in office is not

    interrupted if ministers are assigned to different portfolios. However, if the same

  • 12

    ministers leave the cabinet and return after a certain period of time, they are recorded as

    new cases. Of the 232 ministerial appointments included in the analysis, 120 were early

    exists2 from office.

    While the units of observation in the data set are the 232 ministers, the units of

    analysis are the events experienced by ministers. Overall, 5,058 observations related to

    the events experienced by ministers were recorded from 50,921 full-text articles

    published in Le Figaro, Diário de Notícias, and Evenimentul zilei. The articles were

    accessed through the newspapers’ online archives and using LexisNexis and were

    selected using a similar range of keywords3.

    Two types of events that are used as indicators of ministerial performance and

    measures of principal-agent relationships make up the main explanatory factors. The

    indicator of individual performance is the number of resignation calls experienced by

    ministers while in office. A resignation call is recorded each time a cabinet member is

    asked to resign over a personal, professional, departmental, policy, or party issue.

    Multiple resignation calls over the same issue are recorded only if different actors ask for

    the minister’s resignation or if new information is added to the case. The Resignation

    calls variable records 374 episodes of this type across the three countries.

    The literature that uses single-principal models to study agency relationships at

    cabinet level sees resignation calls as one of the main instruments that prime ministers

    can use to decide how long cabinet members can continue in office (Dewan and Dowding

    2005; Fischer et al. 2006; Berlinski et al. 2010, 2012). The relationship between

    resignation calls and firing decisions is not as straightforward in multiple-principals

    models, where this indicator of ministerial performance cannot indicate the principal who

    decides on when ministers should go. To identify who can hold ministers accountable a

    direct measure of each principal-agent relations is needed. The chosen measures for

    principal-agent relations are three explanatory variables that record conflicts between

    2 While in some cases ministers may be ‘pulled’ from the cabinet to be promoted to prestigious positions in international organizations (Dowding and Dumont 2009: 12), most resignations follow overt criticism from political actors and mass media and are seen as ‘pushed’ resignations (Fischer et al. 2006: 712). Due to the lack of theoretical criteria that could be used to differentiate between different types of early exists from the cabinet, I have preferred to lump together resignations and dismissals. 3 Year-by-year searches were carried out for each ministerial appointment included in the data set for as long as the ministers held office. Each search included the full name of the minister and a list of keywords. The keywords used for the selection of articles on French ministers were: animosit!, arbitrag!, bras de fer, critiq!, confli!, contr*d!, contest!, démiss!, demett!, destit!, désac!, discord!, dissens!, élimin!, écart!, erreur, revoc!, revoq!, reman!, responsab!. The keywords used for the selection of articles on Portuguese ministers were: demissao, demitir-se, remodelacao, erro, acusacao, responsabilidade, conflito, divergencia, contestacao, protesto, queda, polemica. Where possible, the searches included wildcard characters in order to maximise the number of articles returned.

  • 13

    ministers and presidents (PR Conflicts), prime ministers (PM Conflicts) and party

    principals (PARTY Conflicts). This data is collected in the same way as the resignation

    calls and indicates the number of times ministers are criticised by their principals, as

    reported in the press. Similarly to resignation calls, one conflict for each issue over which

    ministers are criticised by their principals is recorded. I assume that the risk of losing

    office increases when conflicts are made public. The accumulation of conflicts between

    ministers, presidents, prime ministers and parties is therefore a proxy for agency loss that

    each principal should aim to contain. If the principals have the power to fire agents, then

    they should be in a position to do so when the level of conflict with their agents increases.

    If the ministers’ risk of losing office does not increase in the presence of conflicts with

    principals, then I assume that the latter do not have the ability to sanction agency loss.4

    The remaining variables included in the analysis of ministerial durability control

    for other events that ministers may experience during their time in office. The Reshuffles

    variable records individual shifts from one portfolio to another. To check whether

    personal characteristics influence the risk of deselection I control for gender and political

    experience. Cabinet experience indicates the ministers who have previously served as full

    cabinet members. Parliamentary experience records the number of ministers who were

    selected from among incumbent parliamentarians5 and who were not at their first

    legislative mandate at the moment of appointment. Local office is a proxy for experience

    in local administration and records ministers who held an elective position in local

    administration at the moment of appointment. Next are the party experience variables.

    Party executive controls for the importance of political partisanship as a channel for

    ministerial appointments and equals one for ministers who are members in their parties’

    4 Several alternative explanations regarding the conditions under which conflicts between ministers and their principals can be observed must be considered. While public evidence of conflicts between ministers and their principals is a strong indicator of agency loss, some principals choose to keep some conflicts outside the public arena and may see it in their best interest not to take action even when they make other conflicts public. For example, presidents, prime ministers and parties outside public office may not wish to harm their electoral chances by publicly exposing the mismanagement errors of their representatives in government. In this case, the reasons for the ministers’ demotion may be difficult to observe. Unpopular principals may also find it disadvantageous to criticise or sanction popular ministers. Principals who lack the formal power to fire ministers, such as presidents under a situation of cohabitation, may criticise cabinet members simply to draw attention upon themselves. By contrast, principals who can actively exercise the power to fire may choose not to criticise their ministers in public. Other strategic reasons might determine principals to keep ministers who perform badly in office so that they suffer long-term damage (Dowding and Dumont 2009: 15). Overall, while there are numerous reasons why some conflicts are made public while others are not, their systematic recording can provide valuable information about the circumstances under which principals decide to make public their perception of agency loss and to sanction their agents. 5 Romanian senators are included in this category, due to perfect bicameralism of the Romanian Parliament. However, French senators are excluded from this count, due to the fundamental differences between the methods of election and the powers of the Chamber of Deputies and the Senate in this country.

  • 14

    national executive bodies, while Local party leader indicates the ministers leading local

    party organisations at the moment of appointment. Table 4 provides summary statistics

    for events and fixed characteristics across executive scenarios.

    Table 4 Average events and personal characteristics across executive scenarios

    Unified Divided Cohabitation Overall

    Variables Mean Std.

    dev. Mean

    Std.

    dev. Mean

    Std.

    dev. Mean

    Std.

    dev.

    N. Ministers 105 37 111 253

    N. Failures 44 29 47 120

    Length of

    tenure (days) 762.64 459.12 446.34 267.70 838.81 556.45 759.55 504.49

    Personal characteristics

    Gender 0.21 0.41 0.14 0.35 0.16 0.37 0.18 0.38

    Cabinet

    experience 0.27 .0.45 0.14 0.35 0.26 0.44 0.25 0.43

    MPs & 2

    mandates 0.43 0.50 0.24 0.44 0.37 0.48 0.38 0.49

    Local office 0.39 0.49 0.17 0.38 0.31 0.46 0.32 0.47

    Party executive 0.25 0.44 0.41 0.50 0.27 0.45 0.28 0.45

    Local party

    leader 0.16 0.37 0.21 0.41 0.06 0.24 0.12 0.33

    Events

    Conflicts PR 1.02 1.99 1.03 1.94 1.07 2.17 1.05 2.06

    Conflicts PM 0.79 1.19 1.45 2.56 0.93 2.12 0.94 1.88

    Conflicts PARTY 2.15 3.72 1.55 1.99 1.47 2.90 1.75 3.17

    Resignation

    calls 1.74 2.78 2.07 2.59 1.39 2.63 1.61 2.68

    Reshuffles 0.48 0.86 0.03 0.19 0.23 0.53 0.30 0.67

    The length of ministerial tenure and the risk of losing office appear relatively

    balanced under unified executive and cohabitation. By comparison, ministers incur a

    much greater risk of losing office during periods of divided executive. The variation in

    the mean length of tenure observed under unified executive and cohabitation on the one

    hand and during periods of divided executive on the other hand is explained by the

    existence of only one spell of divided executive in the data set. The breakup of the

    Romanian ruling coalition in April 2007 resulted in the simultaneous stepping down of

    several ministers and triggered a change of executive scenario outside a general or

  • 15

    presidential election. Hence the decrease in the length of mean observed tenure

    corresponding to the spell of divided executive.

    The data related to fixed characteristics shows that the ministers included in this

    study make up a relatively homogenous population. About one fifth of the ministers

    appointed under each executive scenario were women. One quarter of the cabinet

    members were experienced ministers and around one third had some experience as

    parliamentarians. About one third of the ministers also had an elective position in local

    administration at the moment of appointment. As far as the experience in a political party

    is concerned, at least one quarter of the ministers in office under any of the three

    executive scenarios were holding a position in their party’s national leadership. The

    relative homogeneity of personal characteristics across the three executive scenarios

    reduces the risk that the results might be driven by idiosyncratic factors related to the

    process of ministerial appointment at different moments of time.

    Model specification

    The technique used to estimate the impact of principal-agent relationships on the

    likelihood of ministerial deselection is parametric survival analysis. Exponential,

    Gompertz, Weibull, log normal and log-logistic models were tested for goodness of fit

    according to the Akaike Information Criterion across the hazard of ministerial deselection

    in the three countries under study. As the Weibull model performed best, the analysis is

    presented in the form of Weibull regressions in the relative hazard metric.

    Simply summing up events and conflicts between ministers and their principals

    might overestimate the extent of career-control powers. In this context, a simple additive

    model is completely oblivious to the passing of time and fails to take into account the

    relativity of the principals’ powers because it has no capacity to ‘forget’. As a result, the

    influence of a particular conflict on the resulting risk of ministerial deselection cannot be

    observed since all conflicts are equipotent. The additive model can be improved by

    adding a specification that allows it to ‘forget’ events when the time of their occurrence is

    sufficiently far back into the past with respect to the moment of ministerial deselection.

    The use of decay functions is a common modelling strategy in the study of civil war

    durations, as it allows scholars to estimate the declining utility of third party interventions

    over time (see for example Regan 2006 and Gent 2008). To weigh the impact of events

    on the hazard of early exits from the cabinet by the time left until the moment of

  • 16

    deselection or collective government termination, we use the following exponential decay

    function

    ������������� The value of lambda is determined with respect to the event half-life, defined as

    the period of time after which the likelihood of being fired because of that event drops to

    50%. As a result:

    λ = − log�0.5t���� The value of lambda is estimated from the data by iteratively fitting the Weibull

    model for all half-time values between 1 and 1816 days (which is the maximum length of

    tenure corresponding to the ministerial appointments included in this dataset). The model

    that best fits the data across executive scenarios (i.e. the one with the highest log-

    likelihood) is attained for a half-time value of 138 days. All models failing the link test at

    the 0.05 level (which verifies the use of an adequate parameterisation) were not

    considered in the estimation of lambda. The decay function allows one to model the

    declining impact over time of the events ministers experience while in office. The event’s

    half-life indicates that following a certain period of time after its occurrence, the

    likelihood of being fired due to that event is halved. The half-time value corresponding to

    our data is 138 days. Thus, every 138 days after an event occurs, the likelihood of being

    fired because of that particular event drops by 50 per cent. New values for the event’s

    half-life are computed each time a model is estimated by interacting the conflict variables

    with scenario6 and leadership7 dummies.

    Results

    Table 6 presents four models that estimate the impact of personal characteristics, events,

    and party relations on the length of ministerial tenure. Model 1 estimates the impact of all

    variables across executive scenarios and serves as a baseline for comparison. Model 2, 3,

    6 The best event half-life values fitting the data under unified executive, divided executive and cohabitation are 151, 118, and 102 days respectively. 7 The best event half-life value fitting the model that takes into account the formal party leadership roles held by prime ministers after they take office is 161 days. The event half-life values fitting the models that take into account the presidents’ and prime ministers’ positions in the party hierarchy before elections are 148 and 151 days respectively.

  • 17

    and 4 assess the extent to which conflicts with presidents, prime ministers, and party

    principals affect the ministers’ risk of losing office under each executive scenario. To

    adjust for within-minister correlation without biasing the cross-minister estimators

    cluster-robust standard errors are used. The observations are clustered by ministerial

    spells and the data set includes 232 clusters. The models present coefficients from

    Weibull regressions and report standard errors clustered by ministers. Positive

    coefficients indicate that the risk of deselection increases and indicate a shorter length of

    tenure, while negative coefficients decrease the hazard rate and are expected to increase

    the length of tenure.

    Overall, the four models highlight the relatively limited explanatory power of

    personal characteristics. Interestingly, the models emphasise that previous experience in

    full cabinet positions increases the risk of losing office. Although one may expect that

    experience correlates with ability and greater durability, this finding is in line with similar

    evidence produced for the survival of British ministers, which shows that ministers

    without previous experience are less predisposed to a premature departure from office

    (Berlinksi et al. 2009). From a principal-agent perspective, the longevity of less

    experienced ministers may be accounted for by the longer period of time they need to

    master their jurisdictions. Inexperienced ministers are less likely to deviate from the

    preferred positions of their principals during the course of their first term in office and

    less prone to conflictual relationships. The local politics route to national office also

    seems to have a significant impact on the length of tenure. Ministers who held an elective

    position at local level are shown to incur a lower risk of losing office. A high position in

    the party hierarchy also emerges as a strong determinant of ministerial survival. These

    findings substantiate the expectation that local strongholds and party experience increase

    a minister’s standing at the cabinet table (Duhamel 2011: 604). The robustness of these

    results across the four models confirms the limited impact of fixed characteristics on the

    length of ministerial tenure with regard to institutional context.

    The results shown in Table confirm that resignation calls increase the risk of

    losing office (Dewan and Dowding 2005; Fischer et al. 2006; Berlinski et al. 2010).

    Similarly, the positive and statistically significant coefficients of PR Conflicts, PM

    Conflicts, and PARTY Conflicts in Model 1 indicate that, overall, conflicts with any of

    the three principals increase the risk of deselection. The results shown in Table 6 confirm

    that resignation calls increase the risk of losing office (Dewan and Dowding 2005;

    Fischer et al. 2006; Berlinski et al. 2010). Similarly, the positive and statistically

  • 18

    Table 6 Determinants of ministerial durability: Weibull regressions in proportional hazard form

    Across scenarios Unified executive Divided executive Cohabitation

    __________________________________________________________________________________________________________________

    Fixed characteristics

    Gender -0.25 (0.26) -0.23 (0.25) -0.21 (0.27) -0.22 (0.25)

    Cabinet experience 0.43 (0.22)+ 0.47 (0.21)* 0.56 (0.23)* 0.40 (0.23)+

    MP & 2 mandates -0.07 (0.20) 0.01 (0.20) 0.03 (0.22) -0.01 (0.22)

    Local office -0.64 (0.24)** -0.68 (0.24)** -0.53 (0.25)* -0.74 (0.26)**

    Party executive -0.44 (0.22)* -0.49 (0.22)* -0.55 (0.22)* -0.40 (0.23)+

    Local party leader 0.21 (0.30) 0.33 (0.38) 0.04 (0.31) 0.01 (0.31)

    Events

    Reshuffles 1.04 (0.77) 1.13 (0.89) 1.45 (0.87)+ 1.50 (0.94)

    Resignation Calls 0.78 (0.11)*** 0.81 (0.10)*** 0.78 (0.14)*** 0.77 (0.12)***

    PR Conflicts 0.55 (0.12)*** 0.33 (0.16)** 0.72 (0.12)*** 1.01 (0.27)***

    PM Conflicts 0.41 (0.11)*** 0.38 (0.11)*** 0.70 (0.41)+ 0.42 (0.12)***

    PARTY Conflicts 0.31 (0.11)** 0.36 (0.11)*** 0.28 (0.19) 0.40 (0.15)**

    Executive scenario

    Unified -0.24 (0.22)

    PR Conflicts × Unified 1.09 (0.33)**

    PM Conflicts × Unified -1.21 (0.66)*

    PARTY Conflicts × Unified -0.20 (0.29)

    Divided 1.23 (0.27)***

    PR Conflicts × Divided -0.51 (0.45)

    PM Conflicts × Divided -0.42 (0.42)

    PARTY Conflicts × Divided 0.15 (0.22)

    Cohabitation -0.38 (0.21)+

    PR Conflicts × Cohabitation -0.20 (0.28)

    PM Conflicts × Cohabitation 1.02 (0.39)**

    PARTY Conflicts × Cohabitation -0.29 (0.24)

    Shape parameter (p) 1.36 (0.13) 1.34 (0.13) 1.48 (0.14) 1.42 (0.13)

    Log likelihood -116.75 -114.04 -104.42 -105.21

    LR Chi2 526.91*** 542.57*** 603.32*** 564.80***

    Observations 5,058 5,058 5,058 5,058

    ____________________________________________________________________________________________________________________

    Note: Robust standard errors clustered by ministers in parentheses; + p

  • 19

    significant coefficients of PR Conflicts, PM Conflicts, and PARTY Conflicts in Model 1

    indicate that, overall, conflicts with any of the three principals increase the risk of

    deselection. The results in Models 2-4 indicate to which extent the impact of conflicts

    with principals varies across different executive scenarios. Table 7 presents the

    coefficients corresponding to the interaction of conflict variables with the scenario

    dummies and their level of significance8.

    Table 7 Principal-agent relations and risk of deselection across executive scenarios

    Unified executive Divided executive Cohabitation

    PR Conflicts 1.42*** 0.21 0.82***

    PM Conflicts -0.83 0.28** 1.44***

    PARTY Conflicts 0.17 0.43*** 0.12

    Note: * p

  • 20

    power. Figures 1-3 show hazard rates for ministerial durability at maximum level of

    conflicts with the three principals under each executive scenario.

    Figure 1 Impact of principal-agent relations under unified executive

    Figure 2 Impact of principal-agent relations under cohabitation

    President

    Prime minister

    Party

    0.5

    11

    .52

    Ris

    k o

    f te

    rmin

    ation

    0 500 1000 1500 2000

    days

    Conflicts under unified executive

    Prime minister

    PresidentParty

    0.5

    11

    .52

    Ris

    k o

    f te

    rmin

    ation

    0 500 1000 1500 2000

    Days

    Conflicts under cohabitation

  • 21

    Figure 3 Impact of principal-agent relations under divided executive

    Next, the paper examines how party relations affect the ability of presidents,

    prime ministers and party principals to hold cabinet ministers accountable. Party relations

    vary as a function of whether presidents and prime ministers hold a party leadership

    position or not. To account for the influence that presidents and prime ministers may

    derive from their informal position as party leaders, I record their position in the party

    hierarchy before and after they take office. The analysis should reveal if the ministers’

    risk of losing office as a result of conflicts with the three principals varies as a function of

    the formal or de facto party relation taken into account.

    First I consider the formal leadership positions occupied by prime ministers after

    they take office. To determine whether leadership roles make a difference for the prime

    ministers’ ability to fire ministers, the conflict variables are interacted with a dummy

    variable that is one for prime ministers who held a formal position as party leaders during

    their time in office and zero otherwise9. Table 8 presents the coefficients for the conflict

    variables interacted with the leadership dummy and their level of significance. The

    9 For example, Lionel Jospin, who stepped down as party leader when he became a prime minister is coded with 0, while Adrian Năstase, who succeeded Ion Iliescu as party leader in 2004 is coded with 1. The other prime ministers who preserved their position as party leaders in the aftermath of elections are coded with 1.

    Party

    Prime minister

    President

    0.0

    1.0

    2.0

    3

    Ris

    k o

    f te

    rmin

    ation

    0 500 1000 1500 2000

    Days

    Conflicts under divided executive

  • 22

    variation in the length of ministerial tenure is estimated across executive scenarios, as

    well as separately under unified executive and cohabitation. Due to the existence of only

    one spell of divided executive in the data set, a separate model could not be estimated for

    this scenario.

    Table 8 Impact of principal-agent relations and party relations after elections

    Party leadership roles after elections PR Conflicts PM Conflicts PARTY Conflicts

    PM is NOT Leader Across scenarios 0.74** 0.91** 0.14

    PM Leader Across scenarios 0.33* 0.28** 0.31**

    PM is NOT Leader Unified 1.78*** 0.10 -0.38

    PM Leader Unified 1.13 -1.60*** 0.58**

    PM is NOT Leader Cohabitation 0.63 1.38*** 0.41*

    PM Leader Cohabitation 0.60** 0.50* -0.16

    Note: * p

  • 23

    cohabitation means that the variation in the length of ministerial tenure cannot be

    estimated separately within each scenario. The alternative is to separate the risk of losing

    office in one scenario compared to the other two scenarios.

    Table 9 Impact of principal-agent relations and party relations before elections

    Party leadership roles before elections PR Conflicts PM Conflicts PARTY Conflicts

    PM is NOT Leader Across scenarios 1.42*** -0.83 0.17

    PM Leader Across scenarios 0.33** 0.38*** 0.36***

    PM is NOT Leader Unified & Cohab 1.44*** -0.79 0.27

    PM Leader Unified & Cohab 0.49** 0.86** 0.19

    PM is NOT Leader Unified & Divided 1.41*** -0.80 0.11

    PM Leader Unified & Divided -0.04 0.24** 0.34**

    Note: * p

  • 24

    Figure 4 Impact of principal-agent relations under unified executive and cohabitation as a

    function of the prime ministers’ position in the party hierarchy before elections

    Lastly, I assess whether the presidents’ position in the party hierarchy ahead of

    their election makes a difference for the extent of their influence over cabinet

    composition. Table 10 presents the coefficients and level of significance for the conflict

    variables interacted with a leadership dummy that indicates presidents who were party

    leaders before elections11. The lack of variation in the party leadership roles held by

    presidents before elections during periods of unified and divided executive means that the

    impact of party relations on the risk of deselection can be estimated separately only

    during periods of cohabitation. The results indicate a statistically significant relationship

    between conflicts with presidents and shorter lengths of tenure only in the case of

    presidents who were party leaders ahead of elections. This finding substantiates the

    hypothesis that the presidents’ position in the party hierarchy ahead of elections makes a

    difference for the extent of their authority over cabinets.

    11 In this set of models the French and the Romanian presidents are coded with 1, while the Portuguese presidents are coded 0.

    Prime minister

    PresidentParty

    0.5

    11.5

    2

    Ris

    k o

    f te

    rmin

    ation

    0 500 1000 1500 2000

    days

    PMs are party leaders before elections

    President

    PartyPrime minister

    0.5

    11.5

    2

    0 500 1000 1500 2000

    days

    PMs are not party leaders before elections

    Conflicts under unified executive and cohabitation

  • 25

    Table 10 Impact of principal-agent relations and party relations before elections

    Party leadership roles before elections PR Conflicts PM Conflicts PARTY Conflicts

    PR is NOT Leader Across scenarios 1.51* 1.62*** 0.64

    PR Leader Across scenarios 0.52** 0.40*** 0.31**

    PR is NOT Leader Cohab 1.00 2.03** 1.08

    PR Leader Cohab 0.80** 1.14** 0.49

    PR is NOT Leader Unified & Cohab 1.18 1.60** 0.91

    PR Leader Unified & Cohab 0.68*** 0.65* 0.26

    PR is NOT Leader Divided & Cohab 1.57* 1.76** 0.51

    PR Leader Divided & Cohab 0.37** 0.43*** 0.46***

    Note: * p

  • 26

    difference for the ability of presidents and prime ministers to control cabinet composition:

    presidents are in a better position to influence the deselection of ministers during periods

    of unified executive, while prime ministers gain control over cabinet members under

    cohabitation. The fact that conflicts with the president are not completely risk-free even

    under cohabitation confirms Duverger’s (1996: 517) expectation that although presidents

    have fewer power than prime ministers when this scenario occurs, they are still not

    completely powerless. However, the expectations regarding the balance of power between

    party principals and party agents have not been met.

    Second, party principals do not seem to increase their control over cabinet

    composition under cohabitation compared to periods of unified executive. This finding

    indicates that the party principal’s influence over ministers does not depend only on

    whether presidents are able to turn cabinet members into their own agents, but also on the

    authority and autonomy of prime ministers relative to their own parties. In other words,

    the leadership resources and autonomy of prime ministers from their parties have the

    same effect on limiting the party principal’s control over its minister agents as

    unaccountable agents in a directly elected presidential office. Surprisingly, party

    principals appeared in a better position to hold ministers accountable during a period of

    divided executive, when the president and the prime minister were both acting as the

    facto party leaders. These results may indicate that intra-executive deadlock between the

    president and the prime minister may shift the balance of power in the favour of party

    principals. However, as the data related to ministerial turnover under divided executive is

    limited to just one occurrence of this scenario in only one country, this result should be

    interpreted with caveats.

    Third, by taking into account the positions held by prime ministers and presidents

    in the party hierarchy before and after elections, one can explain why executive scenarios

    make a difference for the authority of some presidents and prime ministers over cabinet

    composition but not for others. Both presidents and prime ministers have more control

    over cabinet members if they contest elections as party leaders. Due to the institutional

    configuration of semi-presidential systems, prime ministers were shown to keep a strong

    grip over cabinet members during periods of cohabitation regardless of their position in

    the party hierarchy before or after elections. However, the analysis has also shown that

    prime ministers who led their parties during the preceding general elections were able to

    control the cabinet under all executive scenarios, not only during cohabitation. Similarly,

    presidents who are party leaders before elections are able to preserve some influence over

  • 27

    cabinet composition even under cohabitation. However, due to the institutional

    configuration of semi-presidential systems, prime ministers were shown to keep a strong

    grip over cabinet members during periods of cohabitation regardless of their position in

    the party hierarchy before or after elections. These findings highlight not only the

    considerable weight of intraparty politics on executive politics, but also the impact of

    informal hierarchies of party relationships on the extent of political leadership. They

    provide substantial evidence that de facto leadership positions and informal party

    hierarchies make a difference for the extent of both presidential and prime ministerial

    leadership in cabinet governments.

    Conclusion

    The findings of this paper cast a new light on the joint impact of political

    institutions and formal and informal party hierarchies on ministerial accountability.

    Institutional factors account to a certain extent for the variation in presidential and prime

    ministerial influence over cabinet composition. Nevertheless, institutional factors alone

    cannot explain why some presidents are more powerful than others under similar

    institutional conditions and why some prime ministers keep a tight grip on their cabinets

    regardless of the variation in institutional conditions. By taking into account both

    institutions and internal party politics, this paper has shown that presidents are able to

    influence cabinet composition only when they come to office as party leaders. Similarly,

    prime ministers who take office as party leaders keep a tight grip on their cabinets

    regardless of variation in institutional conditions, while prime ministers who are not de

    facto leaders are faced with an increased level of presidential activism. These findings

    bear out the impact of internal party politics on ministerial accountability in semi-

    presidential systems and account for the discrepancy between the formal powers held by

    political actors and their actual influence over the cabinet.

    The findings of this paper also speak to the debate regarding the challenges faced

    by the party government model in modern democracies. Party politics scholars have

    highlighted the challenges faced by party government over time (Katz 1986, 1987; Mair

    2008) and the need to assess how well this model fits contemporary democracies, whether

    new or long-established (Webb et al. 2002; Webb and White 2007). This paper has

    focused on one aspect of party government, the personnel involved in the governing

    process. As the ideological differences between political parties wane, the parties’ ability

  • 28

    to place their agents in governmental institutions is seen as one of the sinews of party

    government (Kopecký et al. 2012). However, the selection and deselection of ministers

    should be regarded as twin conditions for party government. After all, if patronage is

    regarded as a mechanism through which parties ensure the provision of safe pair of hands

    in key corners of the policy-making process (Kopecký and Mair 2012: 12), then parties

    should also be able to remove the office-holders who deviate from the preferred positions

    of their patrons. So, the extent to which parties can fire their agents is a good

    complementary test for the extent of their control over the executive decision-making

    process and can be used as a direct and measurable indicator of party government.

    Finally, the variation in the balance of power between party principals and party

    agents as a function of the president’ and the prime minister’s leadership resources draws

    attention to the trend towards the “presidentialisation” of political leadership in modern

    democracies (Poguntke and Webb 2005a). This paper adds to the literature pointing to

    increase in the leadership resources and autonomy of chief executives from their parties

    across regime types (Poguntke and Webb 2005a; Webb et al. 2012). By studying the

    implications of this phenomenon for the chief executives’ ability to hold cabinet members

    accountable, this paper speaks to the “executive” and the “party” faces of

    presidentialisation that characterise the tension between political parties and their leaders

    (Poguntke and Webb 2005b).

    References

    Andeweg, Rudy B. (2000). "Ministers as double agents? The delegation process between cabinet and ministers", European Journal of Political Research, 37:3, 377–95.

    Ardant, Philippe, and Olivier Duhamel (1999). "La Dyarchie", Pouvoirs, revue française d’études constitutionnelles et politiques, 91, 5–24.

    Berlinksi, Samuel, Torun Dewan, Keith Dowding, and Gita Subrahmanyam (2009). "Choosing, moving and resigning at Westminster, UK", in Keith Dowding and Patrick Dumont (ed.), The Selection of Ministers in Europe: Hiring and Firing. London: Routledge, 58–78.

    Berlinski, Samuel, Torun Dewan, and Keith Dowding (2010). "The Impact of Individual and Collective Performance on Ministerial Tenure", The Journal of Politics, 72:2, 559–71.

  • 29

    Berlinski, Samuel, Torun Dewan, and Keith Dowding (2012). Accounting for ministers: scandal and survival in British government, 1945-2007. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Dewan, Torun, and Keith Dowding (2005). "The Corrective Effect of Ministerial Resignations on Government Popularity", American Journal of Political Science, 49:1, 46–56.

    Dewan, Torun, and David P. Myatt (2007). "Scandal, Protection, and Recovery in the Cabinet", American Political Science Review, 101:1, 63–77.

    Dewan, Torun, and David P. Myatt (2010). "The Declining Talent Pool of Government", American Journal of Political Science, 54:2, 267–86.

    Dowding, Keith, and Patrick Dumont (2009). "Structural and strategic factors affecting the hiring and firing of ministers", in Keith Dowding and Patrick Dumont (eds.), The Selection of Ministers in Europe: Hiring and Firing. London: Routledge, 1–20.

    Duhamel, Olivier (2011). Droit constitutionnel et institutions politiques. Second Ed. Paris: Seuil.

    Duverger, Maurice (1980). "A New Political System Model: Semi-Presidential Government", European Journal of Political Research, 8:2, 165–87.

    Duverger, Maurice (1996). Le système politique français. 21st ed. Paris: PUF.

    Elgie, Robert (2009). "Duverger, Semi-presidentialism and the Supposed French Archetype", West European Politics, 32:2, 248–67.

    Fischer, Jörn, Keith Dowding, and Patrick Dumont (2012). "The duration and durability of cabinet ministers", International Political Science Review Online, 33:5, 505–19.

    Fischer, Jörn, André Kaiser, and Ingo Rohlfing (2006). "The Push and Pull of Ministerial Resignations in Germany, 1969–2005", West European Politics, 29:4, 709–35.

    Gent, Stephen E. (2008). "Going in When it Counts: Military Intervention and the Outcome of Civil Conflicts", International Studies Quarterly, 52:4, 713–35.

    Hellwig, Timothy, and David Samuels (2007). "Electoral Accountability and the Variety of Democratic Regimes", British Journal of Political Science, 38:01, 65–90.

    Huber, John D., and Cecilia Martinez-Gallardo (2008). "Replacing Cabinet Ministers: Patterns of Ministerial Stability in Parliamentary Democracies", American Political Science Review, 102:02, 169–80.

    Indridason, Indridi H., and Christopher Kam (2008). "Cabinet Reshuffles and Ministerial Drift", British Journal of Political Science, 38:04, 621–56.

  • 30

    Katz, Richard S. (1986). "Party Government: A Rationalistic Conception", in Francis G. Castles and Rudolf Wildenmann (eds.), Visions and Realities of Party Government. Florence & Berlin: EUI & de Gruyter, 31–71.

    Katz, Richard S. (1987). "Party Government and its Alternatives", in Richard S. Katz (ed.), Party Governments: European and American Experiences. Florence & Berlin: EUI & de Gruyter, 1–26.

    Kopecký, Petr, and Peter Mair (2012). "Party Patronage as an Organisational Resource", in Petr Kopecký and Peter Mair (eds.), Party patronage and party government in European democracies. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 3–16.

    Kopecký, Petr, Peter Mair, and Maria Spirova, eds. (2012). Party patronage and party government in European democracies. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Lijphart, Arend (1992). "Introduction", in Arend Lijphart (ed.), Parliamentary versus Presidential Government. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1–28.

    Mair, Peter (2008). "The Challenge to Party Government", West European Politics, 31:1-2, 211–34.

    Müller, Wolfgang C. (2000). "Political parties in parliamentary democracies: Making delegation and accountability work", European Journal of Political Research, 37:3, 309–33.

    Parodi, Jean-Luc (1997). "Le premier ministre sous la Ve République: Une popularité dominée", Pouvoirs, revue française d’études constitutionnelles et politiques, 83, 89–99.

    Peyrefitte, Alain (1999). "Les trois cohabitations", Pouvoirs, revue française d’études constitutionnelles et politiques, 91, 25–31.

    Poguntke, Thomas, and Paul Webb, eds. (2005a). The presidentialization of politics: a comparative study of modern democracies. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Poguntke, Thomas, and Paul Webb (2005b). "The Presidentialization of Politics in Democratic Societies: A Framework for Analysis", in Thomas Poguntke and Paul Webb (eds.), The presidentialization of Politics: A Comparative Study of Modern Democracies. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1–25.

    Portelli, Hugues (1997). "Les Premiers ministres: essai de typologie", Pouvoirs, revue française d’études constitutionnelles et politiques, 83, 21–30.

    Protsyk, Oleh (2006). "Intra-Executive Competition between President and Prime Minister: Patterns of Institutional Conflict and Cooperation under Semi-Presidentialism.", Political Studies, 54, 219–44.

    Regan, P. M. (2006). "Diplomacy and Other Forms of Intervention in Civil Wars", Journal of Conflict Resolution, 50:5, 736–56.

  • 31

    Rose, Richard (1969). "The Variability of Party Government: A Theoretical and Empirical Critique", Political Studies, 17:4, 413–45.

    Samuels, David, and Matthew Søberg Shugart (2010). Presidents, parties, and prime ministers: how the separation of powers affects party organization and behavior. Cambridge, New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Schleiter, Petra, and Edward Morgan-Jones (2009). "Party government in Europe? Parliamentary and semi-presidential democracies compared", European Journal of Political Research, 48:5, 665–93.

    Shugart, Matthew Søberg, and John M. Carey (1992). Presidents and assemblies: constitutional design and electoral dynamics. Cambridge, New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Skach, Cindy (2005). Borrowing Constitutional Designs: Constitutional Law in Weimar Germany and the French Fifth Republic. Princeton, Oxford: Princeton University Press.

    Skach, Cindy (2007). "The “newest” separation of powers: semi-presidentialism", International Journal of Constitutional Law, 5:1, 93–121.

    Stan, Lavinia, and Razvan Zaharia (2007). "Romania", European Journal of Political Research, 46:7-8, 1082–95.

    Tavits, Margit (2008). Presidents with prime ministers: do direct elections matter? Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Webb, Paul, David Farrell, and Ian Holliday, eds. (2002). Political parties in advanced industrial democracies. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Webb, Paul, Thomas Poguntke, and Robin Kolodny (2012). "The Presidentialization of Party Leadership? Evaluating Party Leadership and Party Government in the Democratic World", in Ludger Helms (ed.), Comparative Political Leadership. Houndmills, Basingstoke, Hampshire: Palgrave Macmillan, 77–98.

    Webb, Paul, and Stephen White, eds. (2007). Party Politics in New Democracies. Oxford: Oxford University Press.